PAGENO="0001"
86th Congress
2d Session
JOINT COMMITTEE PRINT
~L 1efriie~
~. ~4ML I~UGU
~ ~
STUDY PAPER NO. 17
PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING
INDUSTRIES
BY
CHARLES L. SCHULTZE AND JOSEPH L. TRYON
MATERIALS PREPARED IN CONNECTION WITH THE
STUDY OF EMPLOYMENT, GROWTH, AND
PRICE LEVELS
FOR CONSIDERATION BY THE
JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE
CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES
L ~ 7 JANUARY 25, 1960
Pv7 7/'//ho. /7
- \ For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U. S. Government Printing Office
Washington 25, D. 0. . Price 20 cents
-
Printed for the use of the Joint Economic Committee
UNITED STATES
GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE
49350 WASHINGTON: 1960
PAGENO="0002"
II
JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE
(Created pursuant to sec. 5(a) of Public Law 304, 79th Cong.)
PAUL H. DOUGLAS, Illinois, Chairman
WRIGHT PATMAN, Texas, Vice Chairman
HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES
RICHARD BOLLING, Missouri
HALE BOGGS, Louisiana
HENRY S. REUSS, Wisconsin
FRANK M. COFFIN, Maine
THOMAS B. CURTIS, Missouri
CLARENCE E. KILBURN, New York
WILLIAM B. WIDNALL, New Jersey
STUDY OF EMPLOYMENT, GROWTH, AND PRICE LEVELS
(Pursuant to S. Con. Res. 13, 86th Cong., 1st sess.)
OFro ECKSTEIN, Technical Director
Jomv W. Linn,e~n, Administrative Qfficer
J~tss W. KNowLES, Special Economic Counsel
SENATE
JOHN SPARKMAN, Alabama
J. WILLIAM FULBRIGHT, Arkansas
JOSEPH C. O'MAHONEY, Wyoming
JOHN F. KENNEDY, Massachusetts
PRESCOTT BUSH, Connecticut
JOHN MARSHALL BUTLER, Maryland
JACOB K. JAVITS, New York
PAGENO="0003"
This is one of a series of papers being prepared for consider-
ation by the Joint Economic Committee in connection with
their Study of Employment, Growth, and Price Levels. The
committee and the committee staff neither approve nor dis-
approve of the findings of the individual authors.
in
PAGENO="0004"
PAGENO="0005"
LETTERS OF TRANSMITTAL
JANUARY 21, 1960.
To Members of the Joint Economic Committee:
Submitted herewith for the consideration of the members of the
Joint Economic Committee and others is a paper on "Prices and Costs
in Manufacturing Industries."
This is one of a number of subjects which the Joint Economic Com-
mittee requested individual scholars to examine and report on in
connection with the committee's study of "Employment, Growth, and
Price Levels."
The findings are entirely those of the author, and the committee and
the committee staff indicate neither approval nor disapproval of this
publication.
PAUL. H. DOUGLAS,
Chairman, Joint Economic Committee.
JANUARY 8, 1960.
Hon. PAW4 H. DOUGLAS,
Chairman, Joint Economic Committee,
U.S. Senate, Washington, D.C.
DEAR SENATOR DOUGLAS: Transmitted herewith is one of a series
of papers prepared for the "Study of Employment, Growth, and Price
Levels" by outside consultants and members of the staff. The
authors of this paper are Prof. Charles L. Schultze, of Indiana Uni-
versity, and Joseph L. Tryon, of Georgetown University.
All papers are presented as prepared by the authors, for considera-
tion by the committee and staff.
O~r~ro EcK5TEIN,
Technical Director,
St'ady of Employment, Growth, and Price Levels.
V
PAGENO="0006"
PAGENO="0007"
CONTENTS
STUDY PAPER NO. 17, "PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING
INDUSTRIES," BY. CHARLES L. SCHULTZE AND JOSEPH L. TRYON
Page
I. Introduction 3
Basic method 3
Foodandkindredproducts 6
Data and statistical methods used 7
Warnings on the use of the unit cost indexes 8
II. The pattern of changes in output, prices, and costs 10
Output 10
Prices and costs 15
Unit labor costs, average earnings, and demands 39
Wages, productivity, and unit labor costs 42
Unit labor costs and "product mix" 45
Prices and costs in recession and recovery 46
Summary of conclusions 52
Appendixes:
Appendix A. Sources of data and derivation of basic series for cost
indexes 54
Wages and salaries 54
Net business income 54
Capital consumption allowances 55
Indirect business taxes 55
Index of physical output 56
Appendix B. The adjustment of aggregates to convert from a company
reporting basis to an establishment reporting basis 56
Table B-i. Percent of gross product originating subtracted from
and added to each industry to shift the basic series from com-
pany reporting basis to establishment reporting basis, 1954 - - 58
TABLES
Table 1. Percent of total change in manufacturing output contributed by
various industries 14
Table 2. Unit cost indexes for all manufacturing except petroleum and coal
products 17
Table 3. Point contribution of each industry to unit cost index for all
manufacturing 18
Table 4. Year to year changes in points of manufacturing industries in unit
and cost index for all manufacturing 19
Table 5. Cost indexes for manufacturing industries 20
Table 6. Percent changes in prices, component costs per unit, gross mar-
gins, and output in manufacturing, 1948-56 32
Table 7. Relationship of changes in demands, unit labor costs and gross
margins, 1948-56 34
Table 8. Consistency of actual behavior with expectations, 19 manufactur-
ing industries, 1948-56 35
Table 9. Relationship of change in employment to change in average hourly
earnings of production workers 40
Table 10. Relationship of changes in output to changes in average hourly
earnings of production workers 40
Table 11. Relationship of changes in employment to change in average
annual earnings (wage and salary workers) 42
Table 12. Percent changes in compensation per employee, output per man-
hour, and unit labor costs, manufacturing industries, 1948-56 43
VII
PAGENO="0008"
VIII CONTENTS
Page
Table 13. Comparison of unit labor costs, average compensation, and
productivity, 15 manufacturing industries, 1948-56 44
Table 14. Comparison of productivity, average compensation, and unit
labor costs, 15 manufacturing industries, 1948-56 44
Table 15. Comparison of 2 indexes of unit labor costs, all manufacturing
industries 46
Table 16. Changes in various prices in postwar recessions 47
Table 17. Changes in prices and unit costs in postwar recessions, manu-
facturing industries 49
Table 18. Behavior of labor cost and capital consumption per unit during
declines and recoveries in output 51
PAGENO="0009"
STUDY PAPER NO. 17
PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES
(BY CHARLES L. SCHULTZE AND JOSEPH L. TRYON)
1
49350-60---2
PAGENO="0010"
PAGENO="0011"
STUDY PAPER NO. 17
PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING
INDUSTRIES
(By Charles L. Sehultze and Joseph L. Tryon l)
I. INTRODUCTION
This paper presents a study of the behavior of output and costs
in manufacturing industries over the period 194'7-58. The analytical
method used is consistent with the national income framework of the
Department of Commerce and the data presented may be readily re-
lated to the published national income data. Since the data are so
constructed that prices may be resolved into their various cost com-
ponents, they should prove valuable in the study of price fluctuations.
The statistical part of this study covers the 21 manufacturing indus-
tries of the Standard Industrial Classification Manual with ordnance
and fabricated metals combined.2 The analytical method, however,
is a general one which may be applied to any industry groupings for
which the necessary data are available. A broader study using the
same basic methods and covering all major industries has been pub-
licized recently.3 In view of this fact, the presentation here of the
general method will be brief. For a more detailed discussion of the
method and its shortcomings, the reader is referred to that study.
By means of the method described below it is possible to. show the
following for any industry:
1. The part of gross national product contributed by the industry.
2. The part of any general price rise or fall which is contributed by
the industry.
3. The behavior of labor, capital, and other costs per unit of output
in the industry.
4. The relative growth of output per man-hour in the industry.
BASIC METHOD
Gross national product is the value of all goods and~ services pro-
duced in the economy, valued at market prices. As such it includes
all costs entering into the final prices of the goods produced: labor
cost, capital consumption, taxes, rent, interest, and profits. The inclu-
sion of profits in the concept of "total costs" is a terminological con-
venience, adopted to avoid the repeated use of the awkward phrase,
"total costs plus profits." This use of the term implies no judgment
iThe authors wish to acknowledge the invaluable assistance of Mr. Ahmad Al-Samarrie, who performed
a large share of the computations for the study. Without his work, the study could not have been com-
pleted. Mr. John Degara also assisted in the statistical computations.
2 For certain purposes satisfactory data for the petroleum and coal products industry were not available,
and in these cases this industry was omitted from the analysis. .
a Charles L. Schultze, "Prices, Costs, and Output for the Postwar Period: 1947-57," Committee for
Economic Development (Washington, D.C., 1960).
3
PAGENO="0012"
4 PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES
with respect to the nature of profits as a cost. It is, nevertheless, a
useful reminder that, in the long run, "normal" profits are a cost of
production. Consistent with this treatment of profits, total cost will
therefore equal the sum of the returns to factors of production,
including capital consumption, plus taxes. Since the returns to the
factors of production, including capital consumption allowances, are
actually gross incomes, total cost will be equal to the sum of these
gross incomes plus taxes. Thus total cost may be measured by sum-
ming gross incomes and taxes as well as by valuing output at market
prices.
Within a given industry relations similar to those outlined above
will hold. The gross product originating in the industry equals the
value added in the industry and the valueadded is equal to the total
costs originating in the industry.4 The total costs originating in the
industry are in turn the sum of the gross incomes to factors of produc-
tion used in the industry, including capital consumption allowances,
and taxes. Thus total costs originating within an industry may be
measured by the sum of gross incomes and taxes originating there.
The relationships described will hold generally. However, in order
to be consistent with the Department of Commerce national income
accounts, gross income and taxes must be defined as they are by
Commerce. Therefore in this study the gross income of any factor
will equal its income including direct taxes on that income. The
remaining taxes which must then be added to the gross incomes to
obtain total cost originating in an industry will be the indirect business
taxes levied on the industry.
In accordance with the treatment described in the previous para-
graph, the measure of total cost originating in an industry is the sum
of gross returns to factors of production utilized in the industry,
including the taxes thereon, plus indirect business taxes. The classi-
fication of factors of production may be as fine as the available data
will permit. For this study only the two very broadly defined factors,
labor and property, were used. A finer breakdown is technically
possible, but the available data do not warrant a finer classification.
The returns to these factors are shown as three separate items:
compensation of employees, capital consumption allowances, and
net business income. Thus the total cost originating in an industry
would be the sum of these three items plus indirect business taxes.
For certain purposes the sum of capital consumption allowances and
net business income is a useful figure. This sum we have labeled
gross business income.
An explanation of the calculation of the four cost items is given in
appendix A. It should be noted, however, that net business income
has been calculated by subtracting compensation from net income
originating in each industry. It therefore is the net income to all
factors except labor, and includes such diverse elements as corporate
profits, interest, and income of"unincorporated business.
The sum of the four items which equal total cost is also equal to
gross product measured by value added. This sum will therefore be
referred to as gross product originating or GPO in any given industry.
The estimation of GPO for an industry is oniy the first step in deter-
mining the behavior of unit costs in the industry. Without relating
While there are certain technical statistical differences between "value added," as employed in census
data, and "gross product originating," conceptually the two terms may be treated as identical.
PAGENO="0013"
PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES 5
total costs to physical output, nothing can be said about unit costs.
If an industry produced only one product and this product were iden-
tical for all time periods, it would be a simple matter to divide total
cost by total units produced, giving true unit costs. These unit costs
could in turn be divided into labor costs, etc. Unfortunately such
homogeneity of output does not usually exist even for an individual
firm, much less for the aggregation of firms which we call an industry.
Under these circumstances true unit costs cannot be calculated.
However, an approximate index of unit costs may be constructed in
the following fashion. For each year the total costs of output valued
at current prices is divided by the total cost of output valued at con-
stant base year prices. This ratio for each year has a simple and direct
interpretation. It tells what a dollar's worth of output at base year
prices cost in each year. Thus if 1947 is the base year, and the ratio
for an industry is 1.42 in 1954, we may say that $1 worth of production
in 1947 prices cost $1.42 in 1954, and therefore costs for this industry
had risen 42 percent in the period 1947-54. Thus these ratios are
unit costs where outputs of diverse products are made commensurable
by expressing them as dollars of output at constant prices. Since this
dollar's worth of output is not a physical unit, the ratios are only
indexes of unit costs and not absolute unit costs. As is conventional
with most indexes, the base in this study, 1947, is 100 rather than
1.00. This conversion to a base of 100 does not affect the interpre-
tation suggested above. The index of unit costs in each industry
reflect, however, not only changes in the unit costs of producing the
various products of the industry, but also shifts within the industry
between high and low unit cost products. Thus even if the unit costs
of producing each individual product were to remain unchanged, a
shift in the composition of output toward products with a higher than
average unit cost could affect our unit cost index. We have been
able to construct a unit cost index for all manufacturing which ex-
chides the effects of changes in the distribution of output among the
20 industries. The unit cost indexes for each industry, however, still
reflect the effects of changes in product mix within each industry.
The index described above is an index of all costs per unit of output
in a given industry. It is a simple matter to divide this total cost per
unit into its components. As noted above, the four components
identified in this paper are compensation, capital consumption, net
business income, and indirect taxes. Letting Y equal the total cost of
output in current prices and Z equal the cost of output in constant
prices, we have the following relationship:
Y_L+C+B+I_L C B I
-~- z
Total cost Labor cost Capital con- Net business Indirect
per unit of = per unit of + sumption per + income per + taxes per
output output unit of output unit of output unit of output
The four terms on the right side show the point contribution of each
of the cost items to the index of total cost per unit of output. By
examining the behavior of the points of the cost components over time,
it is possible to see how much each has contributed to the rise or fall
in unit total costs; whether there have been offsetting movements of
the cost elements, etc.
PAGENO="0014"
6 PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES
A numerical example will demonstrate the use of the unit cost
indexes.
Food and kindred products
[Billions of dollars]
1947
1957
Compensation
Net business income
Capital consumption allowance
Indirect taxes
Gross product originating current prices
Grossproductoriginatingl947prices
4,282
1,489
345
2,654
8,770
8,770
7,085
1,866
722
3,438
13, 111
10,419
1947
1057
Point
change
Percent
change
Index of total unit costs -
100.0
125.8
25.8
25.8
Compensation
Net business income -
48.8
17.0
3.9
30.3
68.0
17. 9
6.9
33. 0
19.2
.9
3.0
2.7
39.3
5.3
76.9
8.9
Capital consumption allowance -
Indirect taxes
In this example total unit costs rose 25.8 percent in the period
1947-57. The increase in unit compensation cost contributed 19.2
points of this rise, net business income 0.9 point, capital consumption
3 points, and indirect taxes 2.7 points. (All of these numbers can
perhaps be better understood as simply the cost of producing, in 1957,
an amount of output valued in 1947 at $1. Thus the total cost of
producing that output rose to 81.258 in 1957; unit labor costs rose
from 49 cents to 68 cents, etc.). The last column shows the percent
change in each individual component rather than its contribution to
the total unit cost change. These percent change figures show which
of the individual components have changed relatively faster or slower
than the total or other components.
The indexes for 19 manufacturing industries are given in table 5.
The industries for which the data are presented are the two-digit
manufacturing industries of the Standard Industrial Classification
(SIC), except for petroleum and coal products, and with ordnance and
fabricated metals combined. Table 3 shows the total unit cost indexes
for each industry in the form of points which add up to a unit cost
index for all manufacturing except petroleum and coal products. The
points for each industry are simply its unit cost index weighted by its
relative contribution to total output in the weight year, 1954. Thus
food and kindred products points for 1958 are 14.53 which is equal to
its 1958 unit cost index, 125.8, multiplied by its proportion of total
manufacturing output (except petroleum and coal products) in 1954,
0.1155.
It should be noted that the indexes explained above are not ordinary
price indexes for the goods produced by an industry. They are
calculated from the value added in an industry, and are therefore
indexes only of the costs originating in the industry. The cost of raw
materials, fuel, and anything else purchased out&ide the industry
are not reflected in these indexes for they are neither part of the returns
to the factors used in the industry nor indirect taxes levied on the
industry. Hence these indexes may move differently from a price
index of the prices charged for goods produced by the industry.
PAGENO="0015"
PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES 7
The ordinary price index reflects the behavior of all costs and not
just those originating within the industry in question. Conceptually
the price (or total unit cost) which we have calculated is equal to the
market price of the product minus the unit cost of raw materials and
supplies purchased from other industries. In the discussion in the
remainder of this paper, unless otherwise indicated, the term price
will be used in this special sense of total unit cost of the product
originating within a given industry.
The last type of information developed in this study is an index
of output per man-hour in an industry. This productivity index is
obtained by dividing the constant price output figure for each year
by the total man-hours used to produce that output. The resulting
series may then be shifted to a particular year as 100 in order to obtain
the usual index with a base of 100.
DATA AND STATISTICAL METHODS USED
The techniques described above require that for each year the
gross product originating in each industry be calculated both in current
prices and base-year prices. The current price GPO estimates were
made using the income and cost data published by the Department of
Commerce adjusted in various ways. The details of these adjust-
ments are given in appendixes A and B. The most important neces-
sary adjustment is to modify the capital consumption allowances, net
business income, and indirect taxes for the fact that they are estimated
on the basis of company reports rather than establishment reports.
The wage, salary and output estimates are based on establishment data
and therefore need no adjustment.
The desirability of making an adjustment for the influence of the use
of company reports is obvious. The reports of companies classified in a
given industry may be seriously influenced by establishments which
that company owns in other industries; further, a substantial share
of the products of some industries are produced in establishments
of companies classified in other industries.
Adjustments were possible in all industries except petroleum and
coal products. In petroleum and coal products it proved to be im-
possible to remove the influence of the oil producing properties of the
integrated refining companies, and this industry was therefore ex-
cluded from the analyses which required net business income, capital
consumption or indirect taxes. Integrated companies with establish-
ments outside manufacturing exist in other manufacturing industries,
of course, but the problem is far more extreme in the petroleum prod-
ucts industries than in any other. Where the problem existed in
other industries, either it was possible to make adjustments or the
error was small enough to ignore.
No really satisfactory method is available for making the necessary
adjustments to convert data based on company reports to an establish-
ment basis. In this study conversion of company data into establish-
ment data was accomplished principally by the use of cross-classifica~
tion tables from the 1954 census. In these tables employment is cross-
classified by industry according to both establishment and company
industry classifications. The use of these data is explained in ap-
pendix B.
PAGENO="0016"
8 PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES
The use of the Census employment data for adjusting data reported
on a company basis is based on two heroic assumptions. First, since
the data are available only for 1954, it is assumed that the relative
size of the necessary adjustments is the same for all years covered by
the study. Second, it is assumed that for any given industry, the net
business income per employee, capital consumption allowance per
employee, and indirect business taxes per employee are the same for
all employees who are classified in the industry on an establishment
basis. The correctness of these assumptions is rather doubtful.
Therefore, it seems that at best, the adjustments based on employment
data are very crude and can only be assumed to be in the right direc-
tion. Substantial error from this source undoubtedly still affects the
data of some industries. The importance of this problem varies con-
siderably from industry to industry. In appendix B the magnitude
of these adjustments is indicated for each industry.
The gross product originating valued in constant prices was ob-
tained by multiplying an index of physical output for each industry
by the value of the industry's output in the base year. This method
provides a dollar value series which moves as physical output, i.e.,
without any price changes, and is therefore the constant price GPO
desired.5
The procedure used to obtain the data used in this study, both
those used to derive the unadjusted data and those used to adjust
the data for the company-reporting problem, make it unwise to put
too much faith in the significance of any one figure. It is the opinion
of the authors that the general patterns which appear in the data
are reliable, particularly the relative movements of the various series.
Thus, although reference may be made to individual figures for indi-
vidual industries, it should be kept in mind that no figure considered
by itself can be considered reliable enough to sustain a firm conclusion,
particularly where small changes or minor differences among various
industries are concerned.
WARNINGS ON THE USE OF THE UNIT COST INDEXES
The data developed in this paper make it possible to trace the
behavior of costs within a given industry. It is very important to
note, however, that the mere possession of price and cost data does
not permit us to infer the causes of changes in prices. There is far
too much interdependence between costs and prices to permit this
sort of direct inference. An example will show the danger of such
inferences. It is clear that costs must rise even in the purest sort of
"demand pull" inflation. The reason for this is that the increased
demand cannot be sustained unless incomes rise, but incomes, i.e.;
labor and business income, are the basic costs which we have identi-
fied. The mere fact that unit labor costs in an industry have risen
does not mean that they caused the price rise; we cannot say, from
price and cost data alone, whether prices rose because unit labor costs
rose, or unit labor costs rose because prices rose-or more likely,
whether the final result grew out of a combination of both causal
factors.__Similarly, the fact that business incomes per unit in an
The output index required for this method is one based on value added weights. Value added weights
are necessary In order to be consistent with the cost concepts which are based on value added. The
Federal Reserve Board kindly furnished unpublished production indexes with 1954 value added weights
based on the "Standard Industrial Classification Manual," 1954 edition.
PAGENO="0017"
PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES 9
industryThave risen gives us no warrant to assert that prices were
"pushed" up by monopolistic firms attempting to raise their profit
margins. In sum, historical facts about prices and costs provide us
with useful information with which to combine other information in
an analysis of economic events. But such data, in themselves, pro-
vide no answers to the questions of why prices and costs behaved the
way they did. As a cOnsequence, a substantial part of the analysis
which follows relates the price and cost data to other data on changes
in output and expenditures in an attempt to provide some insights
into the basic factors determining the movements of relative prices
and costs.
* Changes in the unit cost indexes may occur for a variety of reasons.
Changes in the prices of factors of production are, of course, important
ones. There are, however, several other sources of change in these
indexes. The reader should keep in mind that some of the behavior
of the cost indexes may be accounted for by reasons not investigated
in this study.
One source of change that is independent of factor prices is a shift
in demand between products within an industry.
A shift in demand between products within an industry means that
the output product mix for the industry changes. Such a change may
not be reflected in a change in total output, but it may very well lead
to different requirements for labor and capital, and may also alter
compensation, business income, and indirect taxes for the industry,
all without changing price or total unit costs for any individual prod~
ucts. When there are internal shifts in demand, no set of weights-
base year, weights, current year weights, or some combination of the
two-will give a wholly satisfactory index of output because the effect
of the output shift on the index will depend on the weighting system.
This problem is more acute over long periods than short simply be-
cause demand patterns have more time to change, and the difference
between current and base year weights will widen. How long a period
may be before it is seriously affected by such demand shifts is impossi-
ble to say a priori. A discussion of the effects of certain known shifts
in demand in the postwar period is presented in the section following
this one.
A second source of change unrelated to factor price changes is
change in productivity. If factor prices and proportions remain the
same, but productivity increases, then unit costs will decrease. This
source of unit cost change is discussed in the section "Wages, pro-
ductivity, and unit labor costs."
Finally, any change in factor proportions may lead to a change in
unit costs without changes in factor prices. It is, of course, true that
changes in factor prices are likely to lead to changes in factor pro-
portions. In such a situation unit cost changes will reflect the
combined effect of the factor price changes and the shift in factor
proportions. Technological changes may also lead to a change in
factor proportions. For whatever reasons, there appears to have
been a shift toward a greater proportion of capital, particularly
machinery, in the period covered by this study. This fact is probably
one factor in explaining the persistent rise in the share of total unit
costs going to capital consumption over the period. Although changes
in factor proportions undoubtedly had some effect on the unit costs,
49350-60-3
PAGENO="0018"
10 PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES
this is one area of investigation which was not undertaken for this
study.
The warnings raised above indicate that the data presented below
must not be interpreted uncritically. Neither causal direction nor
the exact nature of the unit cost changes may be deduced without
analyzing the data very carefully and taking into account influences
of the sort noted above. The data do, however, provide an excellent
basis for such an analysis, and with due care, important insights may
be made about the causes for price and cost changes in the economy.
II. THE PATTERN OF CHANGES IN OUTPUT, PRIcEs, AND CosTs
OUTPUT
Essential to any interpretation of the price and cost data with which
this study is primarily concerned is a knowledge of the behavior of
output during the period under consideration. This first section will
therefore be devoted to an analysis of output in manufacturing in-
dustries during the postwar period.
There are three major technical features of the data on manufactur-
ing output which are of particular importance in an analysis of the
industrial pattern of output changes. In the first place the classifi-
cation of all industries into only 20 major groups inevitably means that
some of these groups will contain individual industries which are
quite heterogenous in nature. For example, the nonelectrical ma-
chinery industry includes establishments manufacturing such diverse
products as agricultural equipment, construction machinery, air-
conditioning units, refrigerators, and gas ranges. The total output
of this industry, therefore, includes not only establishments whose
primary output is some type of producers' equipment but also estab-
lishments which specialize in the production of consumer durable
goods. There are many periods in which the demand for consumer
durables moves in the opposite direction from the demand for pro-
ducers goods. The overall output of the industry group in such
periods will thus reflect the balancmg of divergent forces.
A second problem of data interpretation arises from the fact that
we are working with an establishment rather than a commodity classi-
fication. A manufacturing estabhshment is assigned to an industry
on the basis of its principal product. All of the output (and all of the
wages, employment, etc.) of the establishment is counted in this one
industry. Thus an establishment whose principal product is, say,
textile machinery is classified in the nonelectrical machinery group.
All of the output of this establishment, including any of its secondary
products, is included in the output of the nonelectrical machinery
industry. In this case the statistics, which are designed to measure
economic activity in each industry, simply reflect the diversity of
output which characterizes American industry. Since our industry
group classifications are quite wide, most of the secondary products of
particular establishments wifi be products which belong in the major
industry group. Consequently the problem of secondary products is
not too troublesome. There appears to be one major exception, how-
ever-military output. Part of military output will be produced in
in establishments which specialize in producing military equipment,
and the remainder will be in establishments where military equipment
PAGENO="0019"
PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTtTRING INDUSTRIES 11
is normally a secondary output. Those establishments primarily pro-
ducing military aircraft and missiles are included in the transportation
equipment industry group, and those primarily producing other mili-
tary equipment are classified in the ordnance industry, which is in-
cluded in our fabricated metal products industry group. Because the
establishments producing the remainder of military output are classi-
fied according to the primary, nonmilitary part of their output, exact
data on the location of the remainder are not available. It is clear,
however, that a large part of the expansion in military output be-
tween 1950 and 1953 was in establishments normally producing
civilian goods. For example, there were automobile firms producing
tanks, textile machinery plants turning out machineguns, and radio
receiver establishments manufacturing signal equipment. It appears
that the increases in military output after 1950, both in establishments
specializing in military goods and in those normally producing pri-
marily other goods, show up in our statistics mostly as increased out-
put in the fabricated metal products, nonelectrical machinery, elec-
trical machinery, and transportation equipment industries. Later,
though again exact data are not available, the cutback in military
production after 1953 appears to have been concentrated in items of
equipment other than aircraft and missiles. As a consequence it is
reflected in a reduction of "secondary" output in establishments nor-
mally producing civilian goods. Precisely because these products
were secondary, it is difficult to trace, industry by industry, the specific
impact of changes in the defense program.. We do know, however,
that the four industries most directly affected were those named above
-fabricated metal products, nonelectrical machinery, electrical ma-
chinery, and transportation equipment, which includes automobiles.
Despite the substantial investment boom of 1955, 1956, and 1957,
the total output of the nonelectrical machinery industry during those
3 years averaged less than it did in 1953-on an annual basis only in
the single year 1956 did it exceed the 1953 level. This does not
mean, hOwever, that the output of machinery did not increase during
this period.0 Rather the rise in machinery output was offset by a
decline in the output of military equipment produced by the ma-
chinery industries. Similarly the fabricated metal products industry
group reached an output peak in 1953 which it did not reach again
at any time during the 1955-58 period. The decline in output of the
ordnance industry proper-which is included in this industry group-
and the military output produced as a secondary product by other
establishments in this industry group accounts for the failure of total
output to reach the 1953 peak.
There is a third statistical characteristic of the data which must be
taken into account in interpreting the relative rates of output growth
among different industries. This is the bias introduced into the
measurement of output by changes in the quality of products. The
basic output measures were derived by deflating data on the value of
shipments to remove the effects of price changes. Often, however,
even the best price indexes cannot make sufficient allowances for
quality change. What appears as a price change may really be an
increase in cost reflectmg improved quality. In general, the greater
6 Indeed there was substantial excess demand for machinery and equipment during the period. See
Thomas A. Wilson, "An Analysis of the Inflation in Machinery Prices," Study Paper No.3, loint Economic
CommIttee, Nov. 6, i959~
PAGENO="0020"
12 PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES
the proportion of complex "made to order" products in the total
output of an industry, the harder it is to adjust for quality improve-
ments in the price index; conversely the more the output of an in-
dustry is concentrated on standard "shelf" goods, the more likely is
it that the price index will reflect the true picture of price changes in
the industry. If all industries were alike in the proportion of "made
to order" versus "shelf" goods, and if the quantity and rapidity of
improvements were uniform through all industries, then the under-
statement of output gains which results from deflating value data
with "imperfect" price indexes would be the same in all industries.
Thus, while our measures of output might understate total output,
the relative pattern of output changes among different industries
would be faithfully depicted. The various manufacturing industries
do not, however, exhibit such homogeneity in the nature of their
output or the rapidity with which they change their products. It is
much more likely, for example, that our data understate the rise in
machinery output than that they understate the rise in lumber or
textile output. `While we shall proceed to analyze the relative rates
of change in output, as shown by our data, it is well to remember the
qualifications which must attach to any conclusions drawn from the
analysis. Fortunately the very industries which have shown the
largest gain in output are usually those in which the possibility of
understating output is the greatest. An allowance for such under-
statement would simply strengthen the trends already observable
in the data.
In most of our calculations we have excluded the petroleum and coal
products industry because of the difficulty of estimating the profits,
capital consumption allowance and indirect taxes of this industry on
an establishment basis. However, the output and labor compensa-
tion data for the industry are collected and published on an establish-
ment basis. Hence in the discussion of manufacturing output which
follows, we have included the petroleum and coal products industry
in the data. Only its price weight will be affected by the probable
errors incorporated in our adjustment to an establishment basis, and
this should not be, in itself, large enough to invalidate the measure of
total manufacturing output. Similarly, in discussing unit labor costs,
wage rates, and productivity we have included the petroleum and coal
products industry in the discussion, since all of the relevant data do
not involve a dubious conversion of company to establishment classifi-
cation. However, in the discussion of relative prices, and the behavior
of cost components relative toeach other, we have excluded the petro-
leum and coal products industry, since in the estimation of "value
added" prices, gross business income, and indirect taxes are subject
to a wide margin of error arising out of classification problems. The
analytic tables are appropriately footnoted to indicate any cases where
the petroleum and coal products industry has been excluded from total
figures for all manufacturing industries.
It is clear from an examination of the data that the rates of growth
in output among various industries have been quite diverse during
the postwar period. Table 1 indicates the contribution to the overall
gain in manufacturing output made by each industry. In analyzing
the postwar change in output pattern the period 1948 to 1956 was se-
lected, rather than the full span, 1947 to 1958; 1947 was a year in which
the distortions in output caused by the war and the postwar recon-
version had not yet been eliminated. The output pattern in 1957
PAGENO="0021"
PRICES AND COSTS IN MANtfl3~ACTtJRING INDUSTRIES 13
and 1958 was significantly affected by the recession; as a consequence
the basic longer run trends in output are best understood after these
years are eliminated.
For the period as a whole, the durable goods industries grew at a
faster rate than nondurable. Accounting for 51 percent of output in
1948, the durable goods industries contributed 62 percent of the overall
rise in output. Nondurable goods industries, which accounted for
49 percent of output in 1948 contributed only 38 percent of the rise
in production. Indeed if we eliminate the chemical industry, the
other nondurable goods industries contributed only 26 percent of the
rise in manufacturing output.
A greater than average rise in durable goods output did not charac-
terize the entire period. From 1948 to 1953 durable goods industries
accounted for 72 percent of the total increase in manufacturing produc-
tion; from 1953 to 1956, however, durables contributed only 37 percent
of the output rise. The major factor behind this particular pattern of
output behavior is, of course, the defense program. If we single out
the industries most directly affected-fabricated metal products, non-
electrical machinery, electrical machinery, transportation equipment,
and instruments-we find that these five industries alone were respon-
sible for 60 percent of the gain in total manufacturing production be-
tween 1948 and 1953. If we add chemicals, a strong growth industry,
to the list, this group of industries accounts for 71 percent of the total
rise in output. From 1953 to 1956, on the other hand, these five dur-
able goods industries account for only 18 percent of the increase in
manufacturing output. It was during this latter period that defense
procurement was being reduced. Indeed, of the 18 percent contribu-
tion to output made by this group of industries, 13 percent came from
the electrical machinery and instrument industries alone, which, be-
cause of their importance in missile procurement, were less subject to
the impact of defense cuts.
The industries whose rates of growth were slower than average dur-
ing the 1948-53 period were primary metals, lumber, furniture, stone,
clay, and glass, miscellaneous manufacturing, textiles, apparel, rubber,
leather, printing and publishing, food and beverage, and tobacco.
Although accounting for 55 percent of total output in 1948, they con-
tributed only 23 percent of the increase in output from 1948 to 1953.
The slower than average rate of growth in these industries is in large
part explained by two basic factors. First, a large number of them
are heavily oriented to the consumer sector of the economy. During
these 6 years, as the defense program took an increasing share of total
output, consumer purchases accounted for a declining share. And,
of course, the industries principally serving the consumer sector of the
economy reflected this shift in the pattern of overall demand. Sec-
ond, the other industries in the slowly expanding group are those
whose output is only one stage removed from raw materials-they are
the first step in the several stages of processing which eventually re-
sults in finished goods. One of the outstanding characteristics of
economic growth has always been the growing amount of fabrication
per unit of raw materials. In other words the output of finished
products has risen faster than the output of raw or semifabricated
materials. The growth of labor and capital inputs applied to the
fabricating process has steadily risen in relation to the inputs applied
at lower stages of production. As a consequence the output of the
PAGENO="0022"
14 PRICES AND COSTS IN MANtFACTURING INDUSTRIES
raw or semifabricated material industries-like primary metals,
lumber, leather, textiles, etc.-tends to grow at a slower rate than
manufacturing output generally.
From 1953 to 1956 the rates of growth among various industries
continued to exhibit substantial divergence, although less so than in
the prior 6 years. Electrical machinery, instruments, and chemicals
continued to rise at greater than average rates. All three are strong
growth industries, and the former two have been particularly aided
by the swift rise in missile procurement. Other industries whose rate
of growth was significantly above average were stone, clay, and glass,
furniture, paper, and printing and publishing. The output of two
other large industries, petroleum and coal products and food and
kindred products, rose at about average rates. On the other hand
fabricated metal products, nonelectrical machinery, primary metals,
lumber, textiles, apparel, and rubber, experienced less than average
output gains.7
In summary, some of the major features of the shift in output pat-
terns during the postwar period can be explained by two major fac-
tors: the increase and subsequent cutback in the demand for military
hard goods and the continuation of the longrun trend toward greater
fabrication per unit of materials input. Barring any major shifts in
the proportion of output taken by defense, the years immediately
ahead should probably witness a more even distribution of output
increases between durable and nondurable goods. There is no reason
to believe, however, that there will be any cessation of the long-term
trend toward a more rapid increase in the output of finished goods
industries relative to raw materials industries.
TABLE 1.-Percent of total change in manufacturing output contributed by various
industries
Relative im-
portance,
1948
Percent of total change
1948-53
1953-56
1948-56
Total manufacturing
Durables:
Primarymetals
Fabricated metal products, ordnance
Nonelectrical machinery
Electrical machinery
Transportation equipment
Stone, clay, and glass products
Lumber and products
Furniture and fixtures
Miscellaneous manufacturing
Instruments
-
100.0
100.0
100.0
51.0
71. 7
36.6
62.2
8.0
6.4
10.0
5.2
8.9
3. 1
3.8
1.7
2.6
1.4
5.8
9.6
10.3
12.4
25. 1
2.2
1. 1
.8
1.7
2. 7
3.5
-6.2
3.5
9.8
8.2
5.2
1.6
3.8
5.0
2.3
5.2
5.4
8. 5
11.7
20.5
3.0
L 2
1.6
2.6
2.6
Nondurables:
Textile mill products
Apparel
Rubber products
49.0
28.3
63.4
37.8
7.3
4.9
1.6
1. 7
3.4
4.6
6.3
4.0
12.8
2.4
. 5
2.0
1.4
. 2
3. 4
2.3
10.5
2. 9
4.3
.8
2.7
3.9
1.0
1. 5
8. 5
8.5
20.7
3. 5
13.0
.2
1. 1
2.5
1.3
. 6
4.8
4.0
13.2
3. 1
6.7
.6
Leather and leather products
Paper and aUied products
Printing and publishing
Chemicals and allied products
Petroleum and coal products
Food and kindred products
Tobacco manufactures
7 Again, the reader should remember that the output of machinery is not the same thing as the output
of the machinery industry.
PAGENO="0023"
PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES 15
The particular pattern of output changes during the postwar period
is interesting not only for its own sake but also because it is related
to the price and cost behavior of the different industries. It is to this
aspect of the problem that we shall devote the remaining portion of
our study.
PRICES AND COSTS
Table 2 presents the unit cost, or price 8 indexes, and the points con-
tributed by the four component costs for all manufacturing except
petroleum and coal products. The year 1947 is 100. Beneath the
indexes are the year-to-year changes in the index, and the component
points expressed as a percent of the total index for the individual
years. Data for the individual industries, both the points of each
component adding up to the price index and the points of each corn.-
ponent expressed as a percentage of the price for each year, are
presented in table 5.
Before attempting to analyze the cost data, it will be most helpful
to have the general pattern of behavior of costs in mind. Over the
period 1948-1956, total unit costs or price increased by 23 percent.
The increase in compensation per unit contributed 16.3 points to the
overall increase, or 72 percent of the total increase; net business in-
come contributed 0.9 point, or 4 percent of the total increase; capital
consumption contributed 3.5 points, or 16 percent of the total in-
crease; and indirect taxes contributed 1.9 points, or 8 percent of the
total increase. The significance of the contributions of the com-
ponents to the increase depends, of course, on the share which each
receives of the gross product originating (GPO) in manufacturing.
Over the period 1948-56 the share of compensation was somewhat
variable, but averaged 66 percent of GPO. Thus its 16.3 points, or 72
percent of the total increase, were very close to its average share of
the GPO. Net business income's share of GPO was highlyvariable, as
would be expected of the residual component. It averaged 21 percent
of GPO, but its contribution to the increase was 0.9 points, only 4
percent of the total increase. Capital consumption, on the other hand,
had a steady rise over the entire period. It averaged 5 percent of
GPO, but its contribution of 3.5 points was 16 percent of the total
increase. Thus, it contributed far more to the rise than its average
share of GPO. It should be noted, however, that the combination of
net business income and capital consumption averaged 26 percent of
the GPO and contributed 25 percent of the rise. Thus, gross business
income contributed approximately its proportionate share to the total
cost rise. Indirect taxes averaged 8 percent of GPO and contributed
only 8 percent of the rise, just its proportionate share of GPO.
If the shares of the four components of GPO are taken for 1948
instead of being averaged for all nine years, the disparities are some-
what greater between contributions to the total rise in unit costs and
the shares of GPO, but the same general pattern prevails.
Examining the yearly indexes, we find that total unit cost has risen
in each year except 1953, when it stayed practically even The year-
to-year changes range from a high of the 10.3 point increase in 1951
to the no change of 1953.
8 The reader is reminded that the word "price" as used here refers to the price or cost only of the product
originating within the industry or industries under consideration; i.e., it is the market price of the final
product minus the cost of all purchased materials and supplies.
PAGENO="0024"
16 PRICES AND COSTS IN MANJJFACTURING INDUSTRIES
Compensation per unit was quite variable. It increased in each
year except 1950 and 1955. The declines in 1950 and 1955 appear
to be due to improved utilization of the labor force as output recovered
from recession lows. Exactly the same pattern occurred for capital
consumption, declines in 1950 and 1955 only.
Net business income behaved quite differently from compensation
and capital consumption. It decrea.sed in 5 of the 12 years, and the
decreases were m 1952, 1953, 1954, 1956, and 1958. These are years
when compensation and capital consumption per unit were increasing.
Thus, in 7 of 12 years, the change in compensation and capital con-
sumption per unit was partly offset by an opposite change in net
business income per unit.
Indirect taxes decreased in 3 of 12 years. The timing appears to
be haphazard rather than systematic in relation to the business cycle.
The figures for the yearly share of GPO of each of the four com-
ponents show net business income securing its greatest share in 1950
and 1951, the years when the major influence of the Korean war was
felt. The share of compensation dropped in those two years, but
recovered, and by 1958 it had reached its largest value, as net business
income per unit declined to its lowest value. Capital consumption
accounted for an ever-increasing share of GPO, starting at 3.8 percent
and rising fairly steadily to 6.3 percent in 1957 and 6.9 in 1958. In-
direct taxes appeared to maintain its share fairly consistently over the
whole period.
Any aggregate series is likely to show significant variation in the
behavior of its individual components, and these unit cost indexes
are no exception. Table 3 shows the price indexes of each manufac-
turing industry (except petroleum and coal products) as a point con-
tribution to the manufacturing price index. These points are simply
the individual price indexes multiplied by their respective GPO's as
a share of the total manufacturing GPO in 1954. Table 4 shows the
net change from year to year of each of the series in table 3. It is
clear from examining the table of year-to-year changes that unit costs
in some industries behaved quite differently from others. In spite of
the fact that in each year except 1953 total costs rose for all manu-
facturing, pluses clearly dominate the picture in only 4 of the 11 pairs
of year-to-year changes. The four pairs where pluses dominate are
1947-48, 1950-51, 1955-56, and 1956-57. In the other year-to-year
comparisons, decreases are nearly as common as increases. A com-
parison of individual industries over the entire period shows that
certain industries rose far more consistently than others. At one
extreme are four industries~-printing and publishing; stone, clay, and
glass products; fabricated metals; and instruments-in each of which
unit costs rose in all but one year. At the other extreme are five
industries-textile products, apparel, lumber and wood products,
paper and allied products, and leather and leather products---in each
of which there were declines in at least 6 of the 11 year-to-year move-
ments. This latter group included one industry, apparel, in which
total unit costs declined for the period as a whole.
PAGENO="0025"
_____ 00
140. 38
98.48 ~
20. 83
9.69 Cl
11.38 0
___ 00
30.52
2.49
4.12
-3.34
1.05 ~s.
.66 Cl
-2.29 ~
0
cc
Total unit cost index
TABLE 2.-Unit cost indexes for all manufacturing except petroleum and coal products
UNIT COST INDEX AND COMPONENTS
1947
1948
1949
1950
1951
1952
1953
1954
1955
1956
1957
1958
Compensation
Net business income
Capital consumption
Indirect taxes
Gross business income
100. 00
108. 57
112. 82
116. 07
126. 35
127.03
127. 01
128.82
130. 81
133. 15
137.89
68. 87
18. 77
3. 79
8.57
72. 50
23. 01
4.26
8. 80
73. 66
24. 81
5. 03
9. 31
72. 58
28. 98
4. 74
9. 77
80. 83
30. 77
5. 17
9. 57
84.43
26.42
5. 83
10.34
86.05
24. 51
6. 36
10. 08
88. 08
22. 54
7.75
10.45
85.93
26. 67
7.73
10.49
90.20
24.02
8.07
10. 85
94.36
24. 17
8. 64
10. 73
22. 56
27.27
29.84
33. 72
35. 94
32.25
30. 87
30. 29
34. 40
32. 09
32.81
NET Cl-lANGE FROM PREVIOUS YEAR
IN UNIT COST
INDEX
AND COMPONENTS
Total unit cost index
8. 57
4.24
3. 25
10. 28
0. 68
-0. 02
1. 81
1.99
2. 34
4.75
Compensation
Net business income
Capital consumption
Indirect taxes
Gross business income
.
3. 63
4.24
.48
.23
1. 16
1.80
.77
. 51
-1. 08
4. 17
-.29
. 46
8.25
1.79
.43
-.20
3. 61
-4.35
. 66
.77
1. 62
-1.91
. 53
-. 26
2. 03
-1.97
1. 38
.37
-2. 16
4. 13
-.02
. 04
4.28
-2.65
.35
. 36
4. 15
. 15
. 57
-. 13
4. 72
2. 57
3.88
2.22
-3.69
-1. 38
-. 59
4. 11
-2.30
.72
COMPONENTS
OF UNIT COST AS
PERCENTAGE
OF TOTAL UNIT COST
Total unit cost 100.0 100.0
Compensation
Net business income
Capital consumption
Indirect taxes
Gross business income
100.0 100. 0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100. 0 100.0 100. 0
68.9
18. 8
3. 8
8. 5
66.8
21.2
3. 9
8. 1
65.3
22.0
4. 5
8.2
62. 5
25. 0
4. 1
8. 4
64.0
24.3
4. 1
7. 6
66. 5
20.8
4. 6
8. 1
67.8
19. 3
5. 0
7.9
68.4
17. 5
6. 0
8. 1
65. 7
20.4
5. 9
8. 0
67. 7
18. 0
6. 1
8. 2
68.4
17. 5
6.3
7.8
22. 6
25. 1
26. 5
29. 1
28. 4
25. 4
24. 3
23. 5
26.3
24. 1
23.8
100.0
70.2 ~
14.8 00
6.9 `-3
8.1
21.7 ~
PAGENO="0026"
18 PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES
cc ccc- ~ ~ cc cc cc cc cc cc ccci r- ~ cc cc
cc cc cc cc ccci cc cc ~ cc cc cc cc cc cc cc
cc ~ ci cc ~ ccci ~ ccci - cc cc cc - ccci c-cc cc cc
cc - ccci ci ccci cc ccc ~c cc c-cc ccci ccci
ccc ccci & ccc - ccc ccc cc cc cc ccc
~ cc cc cc ccci cc ccci -ccc ccccc ccci c-cc cc
ccci cc cc ccci cc ccci ccc cc ccc ci cc ccc
cc ccc ccc -~ c- cccccc cc c-ct-cc cc
c ci cc cc cc cc cc - -ccc cc cc ccci ci ~o c-cc
cc cc ci cc - cc ccc cc ccc cc ccc cc cc cc -
ccci cc ccc- ci cc cc-c cc cc ccc cc ci ccc cc
-~
cc
cc
cc ccc- ci ccc- cc cc cc ccc -c &~c ccc- ccc
cc
cc'
cc
C-
cc
cc
C
0
C
cc
ccc ccc cc cc-cc c-cc ccc cc - ccci cc
c-cc ccc ccc- ccc cc ccc ccci ccci ccc ccc
ccci ccc c- ci cc ccc cc ccci ccc ccc
PAGENO="0027"
19
0~
PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES
00000-0-00 ~ 00 ~ 000000000000000000 00
Eo~
~ Q
*C~00~
Eoo
0)
Z .E
0-00 00 0'- 000'- 000000000000000-00
~
00
00
~00
00~0000000000000D0000~ 00000
00 + ~
~)0000
CO
2
p
;+l+i+i+++++~++i;÷+
~)
0
000000000000000000000-0000 ~ 00
0000
0000
~
2
C) CO 000000 CO 0000000)0-0000000000000
0) 00-o 00000000000000000000
~~+l++I++j++I++i ~
00000-
0)00
00
2
7+111 I++I
~coco
2
p
~C0C00'00
;+l+I1l+1++++I+llIl
~C)0
~
2
;+IIl+lI+I+©l+ll+I+
C0000
~-)
p
000)000000000-00000~C0~
~-~++++++++++;+++~i
000000
~
2
~
©C)00~ooooo
I I + +1 I ++++++++ç.
0)000-
~o
7+1 11+1+1
0
00
0
00
cC
0
00
0
(C
0
C
00
00
C
PAGENO="0028"
20 PRICES AND COSTS IN MANDPACTURING INDUSTRIES
TABLE 5.-Cost indexes for manufacturing industries
FOOD AND KINDRED PRODUCTS
Unit price
Compensation
Net business income
Capital consumption-
Indirect taxes
Gross business income~
1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958
Unit price index and points of cost components
Unit price index
Compensation
Net business income
Capital consumption~
Indirect taxes
Gross business income__
Unit price
Compensation
Net business income..._..~
Capital consumption-
Indirect taxes -
Gross business income~ --
TOBACCO MANUFACTURING
1947 1948
100.0
103.4
Unit price index
Compensation
Net business income
Capital consumptiou
Indirect taxes
Gross business income --
100. 0
110. 5
108.
2 110.5
113.
2 120.3
124.5
121.3
126.4
124.6
125.8
125.8
48.8
17.0
3.9
30.3
53. 1
23.3
4.7
29.4
53.
20.
5.
29.
3 54.9
0 18.9
2 5.4
7 31.3
59.
16.
5.
31.
5 60.7
4 20.0
9 5.9
4 33.7
63.8
20.3
6. 0
34.4
64.1
17.8
6. 3
33. 1
64.3
22.6
6.8
32.7
66.0
17.7
6.7
34.2
68.0
17.9
6.9
33.0
67.3
17.9
7.2
33.4
20.9
28.0
25.
2 24.3
22.
3 25.9
26. 3
24. 1
29.4
24.4
24.8
25. 1
Component
costs as
percent
of unit prices
100.0
100.0
100.
0 100.0
100.
0 100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
48.8
17.0
3.9
30.3
48. 1
21. 1
4.2
26.6
49.
18.
4.8
27.
3 49.7
5 17. 1
4.9
4 28. 3
52.
14.
5.2
27.
6 50. 5
5 16. 6
4.9
7 28.0
51.3
16.3
4.8
27.6
52.8
14. 7
5.2
27. 3
50.9
17.9
5.4
25.8
53.0
14.2
5.4
27.4
54. 1
14.2
5.5
26.2
53.5
14.2
5.7
26.6
20.9 25.3 23.3 22.0 19.7 21. 5 21.1
19.9 23.3 19.6 19.7
19.9
1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956
price index and
points of cost components
108.3
107. 5
1957
111. 1
[20.7
126.7
127.8
128. 1
[29.9
1958
133.6
131.8
12.
9.
77.
4
5
.6
5
12. 5
12.2
.7
78.0
13.
15.
78.
2 13.7
7 13. 5
.8 .8
6 79. 5
14.
15.
80.
8 15.0
1 15.8
.8 .9
4 89. 0
16. 1
21.5
.9
88.2
17. 5
20.7
1.0
88. 6
17. 5
20. 5
1.1
89.0
18. 5
21. 1
1.3
89.0
18.4
24.4
1.4
89.4
17. 5
23. 5
1.4
89.4
10.
1
12.9
16.
5 14.3
15.
9 16.7
22.4
21.7
21.6
22.4
25.8
24.9
Component
costs as
percent
of unit prices
100.
0
100.0
100.
0 100.0
100.
0 100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
12.
9.
77.
4
5
.6
5
12. 1
11.8
.7
75.
12.
14.
2 12.7
5 12.6
.7 .7
472.674.172.4
13.
13.
3 12.4
6 13. 1
.7 .7
~3. 8
12.7
17.0
.7
69. 6
13.7
16.2
.8
69.3
13.6
16. 0
.9
69.5
14.2
16. 3
1.0
68. 5
13. 8
18.3
1.0
66.9
13.3
17.8
1.1
67.8
10.1 12.5 15.2
16.9
17.3 19.3 18.9
13.3 14.3 13.8 17. 7 17.0
PAGENO="0029"
PRICES AND COSTS IN MANtrACTtJRING nmusmiEs 21
TABLE 5.-Cost indexes for manufacturing industries-Continued
TEXTILE-MILL PRODUCTS
1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958
Unit price index and points of cost components
APPAREL AND OTHER FINISHED FABRIC PRODUCTS
1947
1948
1949
1950
1951
1952
1953
1954
1955
1956
1957
1958
Unit price index
Compensation
Net business income
Capital consumption. ..
Indirect taxes
Gross business incOme....
Unit price
Compensation
Net business income
Capital consumption.
Indirect taxes
Gross business income.....
Uni
t price
index
and p0
ints of
cost components
100. 0
98. 6
95.0
91. 4
103. 9
101. 6
103. 3
102. 7
99. 8
105. 5
105. 7
104. 6
78. 5
18. 6
1. 3
1. 6
81. 4
13. 9
1. 5
1. 8
79. 5
11. 9
1. 7
1. 9
80. 2
7. 7
1. 6
1. 9
85. 4
14. 7
1. 0
1. 9
85. 0
12. 9
1. 7
2. 0
88. 8
10. 8
1.8
1. 9
89.3
9. 2
2. 0
2. 2
86. 3
9. 4
1. 9
2. 2
91.0
10.3
2.0
2. 2
93. 9
7. 8
1. 9
2. 1
92.8
7.4
2. 0
2.4
19. 9
15.4
13.6
9.3
16. 6
14. 6
12. 6
11. 2
11.3
12. 3
9. 7
9.4
C
ompon
ent co
sts as p
ercent
of uni
t prices
100. 0
100. 0
100. 0
100. 0
100. 0
100. 0
100. 0
100. 0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
78. 5
18.6
1.3
1.6
82. 6
14. 1
1. 5
1.8
83. 7
12. 5
1. 8
2.0
87. 7
8. 4
1. 8
2. 1
82. 2
14. 2
L 8
1.8
83.6
12. 7
L 7
2.0
86.0
10. 5
1. 7
1.8
87. 0
9.0
1. 9
2. 1
86. 5
9.4
1. 9
2.2
86. 2
9. 8
1. 9
2. 1
88. 8
7.4
1. 8
2.0
88. 7
7. 1
1. 9
2.3
19.9
15. 6
14.3
10. 2
16. 0
14.4
12. 2
10. 9
11.3
11. 7
9. 2
9.0
Unit price index
Compensation
Net business income
Capital consumption....
Indirect taxes
Gross business income...
Unit price...
Compensation
Net business income
Capital consumption..
Indirect taxes
Gross business income...
100.
0
104. 7
93.
0 90. 3
105.
7 95. 0
90. 3
84.4
87. 4
88. 1
87. 5
86.7
65.
29.
3.1
1.6
9
4
70. 7
28. 9
3.4
1.7
69.
17.
4.2
1.9
2 69. 6
7 14. 8
4.0
1.9
74.
24.
4.6
2.1
2 72. 5
8 15. 7
4.7
2.1
71. 7
11. 6
5.0
2.0
69. 1
7. 4
5.7
2.2
66. 8
12. 5
5.8
2.3
67. 5
12. 2
6.1
2.3
68. 6
9. 9
6.6
2.4
66. 9
10. 4
6.9
2.5
32.
5
32. 3
21.
9 18. 8
29.
4 20. 4
16.6
13. 1
18. 3
18.3
16. 5
17.3
Component
costs as
percent
of unit prices
100.
0
100. 0
100.
0 100.0
100.
0 100. 0
100. 0
100. 0
100. 0
100.0
100. 0
100. 0
65.
29.
3.
9
4
1
1.6
67. 5
27. 6
3. 3
1.6
74.
19.
4.
2.1
4 77. 1
0 16.4
5 4. 4
2.1
70.
23.
4.
2.0
2 76. 3
4 16. 5
4 5. 0
2.2
79.4
12. 9
5. 5
2.2
81. 9
8. 8
6. 7
2.6
76.4
14.3
6. 7
2.6
76.6
13.9
6.9
2.6
78. 4
11.3
7.6
2.7
77. 2
12.0
7. 9
2.9
32. 5 30. 9 23. 5 20. 8 27. 8 21. 5 18. 4 15. 5
21.0
20.8
18. 9
19.9
PAGENO="0030"
22 PRICES AND COSTS IN MANuFACTURING INDUSTRIES
TABLE 5.-Cost indexes for manufacturing industries-Continued
LUMBER AND WOOD PRODUCTS
1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958
Unit price index and points of cost components
FURNITURE AND FIXTURES
1947 1948 1949
1950 1951
1952 1953
1954
1955
1956 1957
1958
Unit price index
Compensation
Net business income
Capital consumption - --
Indirect taxes
Gross business income.~
Unitprice
Compensation
Net business income
Capital consumption- - --
Indirect taxes
Gross business income
Uni
t price
index
and points of
cost components
100.0
110.9
117.1
116.4
134.3
135.9
131.1
121.4
123.0
128.4
133.3
130.2
84. 2
11. 4
2. 7
1.7
89.0
17. 1
3.0
1.8
91.9
19. 5
3.6
2.1
92.3
18.4
3.6
2.1
102.6
25.3
4. 1
2.3
106. 1
23.0
4.4
2.4
107.6
16.7
4.4
2.4
98.4
15.8
4.6
2.6
97.6
18.4
4.4
2.6
100.9
20.4
4. 4
2.7
107. 8
17.9
4. 8
2.8
110. 1
12. 3
4. 8
3.0
14. 1
20. 1
23. 1
22.0
29.4
27.4
21. 1
20.4
22. 8
24.8
22.7
17. 1
C
ompon
ent co
sts as percent
of uni
t prices
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
84.2
11.4
2. 7
1.7
80.
15.4
2.7
1.6
378.5793
16.6
3. 1
1.8
15. 8
3. 1
1.8
76.4W
18. 8
3. 1
1.7
i8.1
16.9
3.2
1.8
82.1
12.7
3.4
1.8
81.1
13.0
3.8
2.1
79.3
15.0
3.6
2.1
78.6
15.9
3.4
2.1
80.9
13.4
3.6
2.1
84.6
9.4
3. 7
2.3
14. 1
18. 1
19.7
18. 9
21. 9
20. 1
16. 1
16. 8
18.6
19.3
17.0
13. 1
Unit price index
Compensation
Net business income
Capital consumption - --
Indirect taxes
Gross business income...
Unit price
Compensation
Net business income
Capital consumption - - --
Indirect taxes
Gross business income --
100.0
lii. 7
107.
2 112. 8
127.
5 121.9
115. 7
112.2
119. 1
124.0
117.6
113.6
72.2
22. 1
4.1
1.6
76.3
28. 2
5.4
1.8
76.3
22.
6.8
2.0
75.6
1 29.0
6.1
2.1
87.1
31.
7.3
2.1
88.7
0 23. 1
7.8
2.3
85.2
20.2
8.0
2.3
83.1
19. 1
7.6
2.4
84.0
24. 4
8.1
2.6
89.5
22.9
8.7
2.9
88.8
16.4
9.4
3.0
85.8
15. 7
9.0
3.1
26.2
33.6
28.
9 35. 1
38.
3 30. 9
28.2
26. 7
32. 5
31.6
25. 8
24. 7
Component
costs as
percent
of unit prices
100.0
100.0
100.
0 100.0
100.
0 100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
72. 2
22. 1
4.1
1.6
68.3
25.3
4.8
1.6
71.
20.
6.3
1.9
2 67.0
6 25. 7
5.4
1.9
68.
24.
5.7
1.7
3 72. 8
3 18. 9
6.4
1.9
73.6
17. 5
6.9
2.0
74. 1
17.0
6.8
2.1
70. 5
20. 5
6.8
2.2
72.2
18. 5
7.0
2.3
75. 5
13.9
8.0
2.6
75.6
13. 8
7.9
2.7
26.2 30. 1 26.9 31. 1 30.0 25. 3
24.4 23. 8 27.3 25. 5 21. 9
21.7
PAGENO="0031"
PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES
TABLE 5.-Cost indexes for manufacturing industries-Continued
PAPER AND ALLIED PRODUCTS
23
1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958
CHEMICAL AND ALLIED PRODUCTS
1947
1948
1949
1950
1951
1952
1953
1954
1955
1956
1957
1958
Unitpriceindex
Compensation
Net business income
Capital consumption - - -
Indirecttaxes
Gross business income - -
Unit price
Compensation
Net business income
Capital consumption - -
Indirect taxes
Gross business income --
Uni
t price
index
and po
ints of
cost components
100.0
110.8
115.1
111.0
119.3
112.9
113.4
117.1
119.2
115.2
116.8
115.4
58. 4
32. 6
6. 6
2.4
59.2
41.6
7. 5
2.5
60. 4
43. 1
8. 8
2.8
54. 0
46.4
8. 1
2.6
58.2
50. 2
8. 5
2.4
60. 6
39. 5
10. 2
2.6
63.2
36. 1
11. 5
2.6
65.9
34. 9
13. 4
2.9
60. 4
42. 7
13. 3
2.8
62. 3
36. 7
13. 3
2.9
64. 5
35. 8
13. 5
3.0
65. 1
33. 0
13. 9
3.4
39. 2
49. 1
51. 9
54. 5
58. 7
49. 7
47. 6
48.3
56. 0
50.0
49.3
46.9
Component co
sts as percent
of uni
t prices
100. 0
100. 0
100. 0
100. 0
100. 0
100. 0 100. 0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
58. 4
32. 6
6. 6
2. 4
53.4
37. 5
6. 8
2. 3
52. 5
37. 4
7. 7
2. 4
48. 6
41. 8
7. 3
2. 3
48. 8
42. 1
7. 1
2. 0
53. 7 55. 7
35. 0 31. 8
9. 0 10. 2
2. 3 2. 3
56. 3
29. 8
11. 4
2. 5
50. 7
35. 8
11.2
2.3
54. 1
31. 9
11. 5
2. 5
55. 2
30. 7
11. 5
2. 6
56. 4
28. 6
12. 0
3. 0
39.2
44. 3
45. 1
49. 1
49. 2
44.0 42.0
41.2
47. 0
43. 4
42. 2
40. 6
Unit price index and points of cost components
Unit price index
Compensation
Net business income
Capital cOnsumption. - - -
Indirect taxes
Gross business income - - -
Unit price
Compensation
Net business income
Capital consUmption. - - -
Indirect taxes
Gross business inCome. - -
100.
0
104.1
101.
3 104.2
123.2
121.0
118.3 119.2
118.5
127.2
124.3
122.1
58.
34.
4.6
1.9
8
7
64.4
32. 3
5.4
2.0
65.
27.
6.3
2.3
7 63. 0
0 33. 2
5.8
2.2
68. 4
46. 0
6.4
2.4
74. 7
36. 1
7.6
2.6
76. 0
31.8
8.0
2.5
77. 3
29. 8
9.2
2.9
74. 7
30.8
10.1
2.9
77. 6
35. 8
10.7
3.1
81. 5
28. 5
11.0
3.3
82. 1
25. 3
11.2
3.5
39.
3
37. 7
33.
3 39. 0
52. 4
43. 7
39. 8
39. 0
40. 9
46. 5
39. 5
36. 5
Component costs as percent
of unit prices
100.
0
100. 0
100.
0 100. 0
100. 0
100. 0
100. 0
100. 0
100. 0
100.0
100. 0
100.0
58.
34.
4.6
1.9
8
7
61. 9
31. 0
5.2
1.9
64.
26.
6.2
2.3
8 60. 4
7 31. 9
5.6
2.1
55. 5
37. 3
5.2
2.0
61. 7
29. 8
6.3
2.2
64. 2
26. 9
6.8
2.1
64. 8
25. 0
7.7
2.5
63. 0
26. 0
8.5
2.5
61. 0
28. 2
8.4
2.4
65. 6
22. 9
8.8
2.7
67. 2
20. 7
9.2
2.9
39.3 36.2 32.9
37. 5
42. 5
36. 1
33. 7
32. 7
34. 5
36. 6
31. 7
29. 9
PAGENO="0032"
24 PRICES AND COSTS IN MANTJFACTURING INDUSTRIES
TABLE 5.-Cost inde~ves for manufacturing inãustries-Oontinued
RUBBER PRODUCTS
1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958
Unit price index and points of cost components
68. 4
14.9
3.4
13.3
[00.0
96.8
96. 4
89.7
127. 0
132.0
123. 5
109.8
113.0
136.0
141.4
144.6
69.3
10.8
3.8
12.9
70. 1
8.0
4.3
14.0
69.3
2.4
3.6
14.4
78. 7
31.3
4.0
13.0
84. 5
30. 1
4.3
13.1
Unit price index
Compensation
Net l)usrness income
Capital consumptIon.
Indirect taxes
Gross business income_....
Unit price
Compensation
Net business income
Capital consumption
Indirect taxes
Gross business income -.
85. 6
22.1
4.6
11.2
83. 3
9.0
5.6
11.9
84.6
11.5
5.7
11.2
90. 6
23.3
6.6
15. 5
95.4
21.6
7.2
17.2
96.9
20.6
8.2
18. 9
18.
3
14.6
12.
3 6. 0
35.
3 34.4
26.7
14. 6
17.2
29.9
28.8
28.8
Component
costs as
percent
of unit prices
100.
0
100.0
100.
0 100.0
100.
0 100.0
100.0
100. 0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
68.
14.
3.4
13.
4
9
3
71.6
11.2
3.9
13.3
72.
8.
4.5
14.
7 77.2
3 2. 7
4.0
5 16. 1
62.
24.
3.2
10.
0 84.0
6 22. 8
3.3
2 9.9
69.3
17.9
3.7
9. 1
75.9
8.2
5.1
10.8
74. 9
10.2
5.0
9.9
66. 6
17. 1
4.9
11.4
67.4
15.3
5.1
12.2
67.0
14.2
5.7
13. 1
18.3
15. 1 12.8 6.7 27.8 26. 1 21. 6 13.3 15.2 22.0 20.4
LEATHER AND LEATHER PRODUCTS
19.9
1947
1948
1949
1950
1951
1952
1953
1954
1955
1956
1957
1958
Unit price index
Compensation
Net business income
Capital consumptiOn.
Indirect taxes
Gross business income....
Unit price
Compensation
Net business income
Capital consumption....
Indirect taxes
Gross business income.....
Unit
price
index
and
points of
cost components
100.0
116.9
109.4
101.2
129. 8
121. 5
122. 1
121.3
115.7
121.4
123.8
119. 3
85.7
11.0
1.8
1.5
93.0
20.2
2. 1
1.6
94.0
11. 6
2.1
1.7
92.6
4.8
2.1
1.7
100. 7
24.8
2.5
1.8
101. 4
16.0
2.4
1.7
104. 7
13. 3
2.4
1.7
102.0
15. 1
2.4
1.8
101. 6
9.8
2.6
1.7
104.3
12.7
2.6
1.8
107.4
11.9
2.7
1.8
107.5
6. 8
3.0
2.0
12.8
22.3
13. 7
6.9
27.3
18.4
15. 7
17.5
12.4
15.3
14.6
9. 8
*
Component
costs as percent
of unit
prices
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
85.7
11.0
1.8
1. 5
79.5
17.3
1.8
1.4
85.9
10.6
1.9
1.6
91.5
4.7
2.1
1.7
77.6
19. 1
1.9
1.4
83.4
13.2
2.0
1.4
85.7
10. 9
2.0
1. 4
84.1
12.4
2.0
1. 5
87.8
8.5
2.2
1. 5
85.9
10. 5
2.1
1.5
86.7
9.6
2.2
1. 5
90.1
5.7
2.5
1.7
12.8
19. 1
12.5
6.8
21.0
15.2
12.9
14.4
10. 7
12. 6
11.8
8.2
PAGENO="0033"
a
~1 ~0'CDO ~
~
*C~ ~1*
0
~*
2
~
o
~2 ~OC) a
~
~
0
~
~
o ~
o ~
E :o~
0
000
o ~iO2~
2
o
E
CD
~4C2ZO ~
U) U)
~. 2~8~ E
~ 0)
2
2 ~:
00
0
L~i
a
100
00
(12
Cd
0
a
(/2
- C)C)C~03 0
0CC) C)
00 -`C)C)C) ©
001 400~ C)
00 0CC) C)
p ~po~.o 0
00 -4000000 0
00 0000 C)
~j0 0-C)
0)3 0CC)
0
- 0)000000 C)
* ~
00 0040)3 C)
0 000000oD C)
00 00)0)00 0
~
CC C)C)00-3 0
C) -`000000 0
CC C) C)
~C ~ p
00 00000)30 0
CC 0CC) C'
03000CC) C)
C) ~CCbD0- 0
a
0
E
0
0
0
00
0
0
00 0000000)3
~3 000)0000'
C) 000)0000
00 000000)3
C) 0C)o-'C)
)~ 0)300
~C
C) 00000-'
~0 ~300©)3~
~3 C)®004
-3 03C)C)00
~
0 00-40000
C) ~©0b0
C) -~C)C)0~
C)
C)
C)
`9
p
to
to
C)
CC
0
0'
04
00
0
0'
0
0
0
0
0
0
C)
~4
CD
Co
0
0
0
C-C
CD
~0
0000000)3
C) ~-4tC-4
0-) 00-4
-4 C)C)0000
-40000
~
C) C)C)0)3C)
~ C))
p ~-`~09)00
o00 C)C)000
p ~-`~~P:-~
C) C)C)C)C)
H ~`-~~°
C) 4C)C)-3
0) 00C)00C)
p ~-`o0-9'~-~
0 *0~0-C)3©
0000000
0
L*Tj
CI)
0
0
CI)
CI)
p
C)
C)
p
C)
C)
p
C)
p
0
C)
p
C)
p
C)
C)
0
p
C)
0
0)3 o-'000-4 to
~00 C)0~C) 00
~ #-`Co3~ ~
C) 00)3~C)0) C)
0- 400C)00 C)
CC 00C-'tOC) C)
~ ~-)tU~~ ~
~ C)0)~-'0 0)3
CC 000C)C) C)
CC 00C)C)C) ~
to CCC) 00
-4 0DC)00-) -4
C) 000C)C3D C)
4 C0C)00C) C)
C) 0)3000)300 -~
tO 000 CC
3 C0C)00C) C)
C) C)C)000 C)
00C)C)0
00 C)C)00-3 ~
a
0
0
0
(1
0
03
C)
0
0
/2
0
C)
0
C)
0)
34
0)
(1
0)
C)
0
0
0
0
C)
0
0
0
PAGENO="0034"
D~
~
~
~
~
~
~
a
~
g~cD CO
(_0cO_.~
:
~aF~
:~i8:
:~~:
:0:
C~
~
~
~.
~
~
~
~c~ic~ a
ai~;
CO~CO ~*
O+cO_.~
~
rh~ ~
:~8:
~
:~:
co~d
C~
C
~
~Efl
0
~
~`
~
0
00
z
0
0
z
z
0
00
0000
~
-`1 00-~0000
00
0' O00~1CO
-
P
030)0000
o ~ooo~c
P ~
oo
- 3)0~C)
~- ~03~-~
P
00
*0
00
00
P
00
P
0
0
0
0
*0
*0
0
0
0
00
(-3
0
0O
00
0
00
01
co t~ococ~
:0
~3
(:3 t~00
C:)
(:0 (:300
C) ~
C~ C34000
~
*0 ~
~
~ CO0~
:0
;o ~
~ 030)
(:3~)
00 (:30000)
~
P ~
C) 00-'00~
*0
P
0
P
0)
:0
:0
a
00
~i.
0)
C)
0)
00
0
0
0
C)
0
00
Fl
0
Co
(-3
~
00 00-0 00
- CJoC000)- 0
00
00 000) 00
*40 -~)(00300
~ (-:00~ ~
JO ~
C:) ~00C-C 00
*0
~
- 0)-)0C0 0
-0 0000(30 00
-000000) 0
(JO 0000
00
0) 000) 00
00 00
- 00CJOC)00 0
(0 o-'000000 00
w
C
Co
0
0
00
0
C)
00
a
0
CO
00 0000000- 0
00 (000 0)
C) C)0004~ 0)
(0 0300C) 00
~) 0000)
P !0:0~JOP 3
oo
(:3 00(000
-0 (000)0) (JO
- 000000C: 00
P ~ ~
~0(0 0
C)
(3 C0) C)
0 (0CJO~C) 00
-1 -000000) 0
P P
0) 0~CO~ :0~
00 00
(:3 00 -00000
00 (0-000- 00
(0
C) (-000(0 00
00 00C)-~) 00
Cl
a
00
0
0)
0)
00
0
0
0
00
0
0
:3-
(0
(:3
00
00
PAGENO="0035"
27
PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES
TABLE 5.-Cost indccses for manufacturing industries-Continued
INSTRUMENTS
1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958
Unit price index and points of cost components
16.8
Unit price index
Compensation
Net business income
Capital conumption
Indirect taxes
Gross business income - -
Unit price
Compensation
Net busineos income
Capital consumption - - - -
Indirect taxes
Gross business income
21.9
100. 0
109. 3
120. 7
129. 3
145. 8
135. 9
138. 2
142. 4
143. 4
150. 7
154. 3
160. 8
80. 3
13. 6
3.2
2.9
84. 5
18. 5
3.4
2.9
90.6
22. 2
4.3
3.6
91.6
29. 9
4.1
3.7
102. 1
34. 5
5.6
3.6
97. 8
29. 5
5.2
3.4
101. 6
27. 8
5.4
3.4
103. 0
29. 7
6.2
3.5
102. 3
30. 4
7.1
3.6
107. 4
31.3
8.2
4.1
112. 2
29. 2
8.6
4.3
415. 1
31. 0
9.9
4.8
26. 5
34.0
40.1
34.7
33.2
35.9
37.5
39.5
Component
costs as
percent
of unit
prices
37.8
40. 9
100. 0
100.0
100. 0
100. 0
100. 0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100. 0
100.0
100.0
80. 3
13. 6
3.2
2.9
77. 3
16.9
3.1
2.7
75. 1
18.4
3.5
3.0
70. 8
23. 1
3.2
2.9
70. 0
23. 7
3.8
2.5
72. 0
21. 7
3.8
2.5
73. 5
20. 1
3.9
2.5
72. 3
20. 9
4.3
2.5
71. 3
21. 2
5.0
2.5
71. 0
20. 8
5.5
2.7
72. 7
18. 9
5.6
2.8
71.6
19. 3
6.1
3.0
16. 8 20. 0 21. 9 26. 3 27. 5 25. 5 24. 0
MISCELLANEOUS MANUFACTURING
25. 2
26.2 26.3 24.5
25.4
1947
1948
1949
1950 1951
1952 1953
1954 1955
1956
1957
1958
Ilnitprice index 100.0
Compensation 73.0
Net business income 17.2
Capital consumption - -- 5. 5
Indirect taxes 4.3
Gross2businessincome_ - 22. 7
Unit'price 100.0
Compensation 73.0
Net business income 17.2
Capital consumption - -- 5. 5
Indirect taxes 4.3
Gross business income 22.7
Unit
price
index
and points of
cost components
108. 8
108.0
109. 5
124. 2
123. 2
120. 6
120.6
118. 1
118. 5
117. 7
117.3
76. 8
22. 4
5.2
4. 4
76. 9
20. 7
5. 7
4. 7
73.7
26. 5
4.9
4. 4
85. 0
28. 4
6.0
4. 8
86.0
25.6
6.2
4.9
89.6
20. 2
6. 1
4. 7
90. 5
18. 5
6.8
4. 8
85. 4
21.0
7.0
4. 7
87. 3
19.0
7. 1
5. 1
90. 1
15. 2
7.2
5.2
91. 8
13.9
6.4
5.2
27. 6
26. 4
31.4
34. 4
31. 8
26. 3
25. 3
28.0
26. 1
22.4
20.3
Component
costs as
percent
of unit
prices
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
400.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
70.6
20.6
4. 8
4.0
71. 2
19. 2
5. 3
4.3
67. 3
24.2
4.5
4.0
68.4
22. 9
4. 8
3.9
70. 2
20. 8
5.0
4.0
74. 3
16.7
5. 1
4.9
75.0
15.3
5. 6
4.0
72.3
17.8
5.9
4.0
73.7
16.0
6.0
4.3
76. 6
12.9
6. 1
4.4
78. 3
11.8
5. 5
4.4
25.4
24. 5
28. 7
27. 7
25. 8
21. 8
20.9
23.7
22.0
19.0
17.3
PAGENO="0036"
B
0) ~-~C~j ~
~
~ 01~U)~. C)
~
o
B ~:
ci ci
Q ~0~CD ~ CD ~CDZCD ~
~
0) -oC~0) ~
~ CO~OC) ~
CO ~ro ~
Co ~.
~ ~CC)~ I ~ C)
~
~
o
~
- 004 10
~~n~0P~oP
Co 000 -0 4 00
~ 1.
C) COO 0000 C) 00
~
C) 0)000000 0
hO hO C)
Co -40000-3 10
hO 10)00 ~ 0 00
~
4 bOO 40-j 0
~k~! !
hO )-) -~
P'P:-~~° P
I-' 000010- 0
~
10) 00010)00 00
~
.4 C) ~ 00.4 0
0OCOOC1~
00000) ~ 0
~
;~~::;; ;
Q b~4~OO00 Q
I-' 0-'-0 00
C~)~4i.3P~CP
00 000) -4 -~4 00
4~
COO Co 00 COO o~
~
00 004 Co 00 00
COO hO-i
00 10 COO 0)10 10)
0 ~ COO 410 COO
~
00 0000 C) .4
~
1'.) 1.310)
P ~~-` P
COO ~ C) COO
~
Co 1010C)C-~ CO
~C)CO~~
0 -4 hO 00 hO 10
~C)CO~~
10 Cl ~ Co0)~ 00
~ PP~ ~
~
001.410000-1 IQ
toj
CD
CD
0
CD
0
B
-4
0
CO
0
0)
-4
0
-4
ci
B~-~ B
0)
0 I0)C)O~o' 00
0~ 10)-4~0 00
)~ b°C)00C) 00
00 00000400 00
Co 0000-10 00
00 C)I-~10OO 00
ho 4C)C)o- 00
hO 00-) 00
!~PPP P
00 40000.00 00
~ ~OP~ ~
b-' -4000000 00
10 00000OO 00
~ hOC)00~ ~
00
0011 ---100
00 COO4000 C)
go 000)0000 00
ci
-4
C)
04
0)
C)
-4
0
0
B
-4
10
00
10
bOO
10
10
C)
10)
go
w
F1
00
C~
0(0
~Co
00).
b-I
CD
CD
0
CI)
`-3
CI)
CD
0
B
-4
CO
0)
-4
0
-4
C)
hOCOO~C~ ~
00 I0)C)OO~ C
hO 0000
P pOt0-.i-)~.3 ~OO
0 0000(1010 00
COOCO~ ~
.4 4Coho10 COO
COOCO~ ~
;0~1O;;-.~o ;-`
COO OO~0OOO-~10 C)
COO (410
10) COOC0040) 10
C C)-ICOOC) 00
~ PP~ ~
10) C)COOC)C Co
0 I0OOC)4~ COO
CO 1000(000 Co
~ ~ro90~ ~
Co 0000400 Co
10
00 ~Qo(o-4 )b-
ci
B.
-4
E
C)
(0
04
C)
-4
0
0
B
00
10)
-4
10)
10
C
10
PAGENO="0037"
PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES
29
100.0
108. 2
122.
3 134. 7
133. 1
139. 9
134. 9
138. 8
145. 5
136.3
139.0
140. 1
72.6
14. 5
3.4
9. 5
72. 6
21. 2
3.5
10. 9
72.
33.
3.
12.
7 73. 1
4 44. 5
7 3.5
5 13. 6
85.4
31.0
3.8
12. 9
91.4
30. 1
4.0
14. 4
90. 5
27. 5
4.2
12. 7
92. 2
25.8
5.7
15. 1
87. 3
37. 0
5.4
15. 8
93. 7
20. 1
6.7
15.8
92. 9
24. 3
7.1
14. 7
98. 7
16. 3
8.6
16. 5
17. 9
24.7
37.
1 48.0
34.8
34. 1
31.7
31. 5
42. 4
26.8
31. 4
24. 9
Component co
sts as
percent
of uni
t prices
100.0
100. 0
100.
0 100.0
100.0
100. 0
100.0
100.0
100.01
100.0
100.0
100.0
72. 7
14. 5
3.4
9. 5
67. 1
19. 6
3.2
10. 1
59.
27.
3.
10.
5 54.3
3 33. 0
0 2.6
2 10. 1
64. 2
23.3
2.8
9. 7
65.3
21. 5
2.9
10. 3
67. 1
20. 4
3.1
9. 4
66. 4
18. 6
4.1
10. 9
60.0
25. 4
3.7
10. 9
68. 7
14.8
4.9
11. 6
66.8
17. 5
5.1
10. 6
70. 5
11. 6
6.1
11.8
17. 9 22.8 30. 3 35. 6 26. 1 24. 4 23. 5 22. 7 29. 1 19.7 22.6 17.7
With this broad picture of the postwar behavior of costs in manu-
facturing industries in mind, let us now attempt .to determine the
why of this behavior. The mere possession of historical price and cost
data does not, in itself, furnish us with any answers to the question of
why prices and costs behaved the way they did. The simple fact that
costs rose in industry after industry gives us no warrant to assert
that prices rose solely because costs rose. And even if we knew that
the rise in prices stemmed, in a causal sense, from the rise in costs, the
more relevant question-why did costs rise-would still remain un-
answered. We are, however, not restricted to the examination of
cost and price data alone. By combining our data on prices and costs
with our measures of output and expenditures we can begin to draw
some tentative conclusions about the relationship of price and cost
changes to changes in demands and technology. In particular we
can investigate the relative magnitude of changes in prices and in
price-cost relationships among various industries and examine how
these relative magnitudes compare with the relative size of expenditure
and output changes in the same industries. We can construct hypoth-
eses about the behavior of prices and costs in relationship to output
and productivity and test them against our data.
One of the major questions to which we will address ourselves is
how to explain the behavior of relative prices among the 19 manu-
facturing industries. This explanation of the behavior of relative
prices can be divided into two parts. First, given the behavior of
relative costs and demands, did relative prices behave as economic
theory would have predicted. Second, what explanation can be given
for the behavior of relative costs. We will examine each of these
questions in turn.
To this point we have defined total unit costs to include labor costs,
indirect taxes, and gross business income. In the following analysis,
however, gross business income will be treated as the residual or
balancing element between prices and costs. Thus, unless otherwise
`rABLE 5.-Cost indexes for manufacturisg industries-Continued
TRANSPORTATION EQUIPMENT
1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958
Unit price index and points of cost components
Unit price index
Compensation
Net business income
Capital consumption~ -
Indirect taxes
Gross business income - -
Unit price
Compensation
Net business income
Capital consumption~ - --
Indirect taxei
Gross business income -
PAGENO="0038"
30 PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES
noted, the word cost will refer to the combination of labor cost and
indirect taxes and will not include gross business income. Using the
word cost in this sense, we may say that prices are determined by the
interaction of demand and cost, with gross business income being the
residual.° Given demand and cost behavior, we will consider whether
this balancing item, gross business income, has behaved as expected.
More specifically, we will assume the goal of profit maximization,
formulate hypotheses about the behavior of prices under various
conditions of costs and demands, and examine the data to see if they
are consistent with the behavior predicted by the hypothesis. In
order to formulate specific hypothesis, capable of being tested by the
data available, we will be forced to make certain simplifying assump-
tions, and in some cases to employ rough and ready techniques for
evaluating the data where more precise measurements are impossible.
Wherever possible, we will discuss, qualitatively at least, the implica-
tions of our departure from the theoretically desirable refinements
and measurements.
Regarding costs, we assume initially, that in each industry the
direction of relative changes in costs is given by the direction of rela-
tive changes in unit labor costs. This assumption will be relaxed at
a later point insofar as indirect taxes are concerned.
Changes in demand as has been noted above, are assumed to be
given. There is. the problem, however, of measuring changes in
demand. The term demand is employed here in the sense common to
economic usage, i. e., the complete schedule of amounts that buyers
are willing to purchase at all possible prices, and not merely the
amount exchanged at the going market prices. Thus an increase in
demand refers to a shift of the entire schedule, and means, in general,
that buyers are willing to purchase more at all possible prices than
they were before the shift. We have no precise measures of demand in
this sense. Nevertheless, we can classify most industries on the basis
of whether their demand rose by more or less than the average for all
industries. If, for example, both the price and the output of a par-
ticular industry rose by more than average, there is good reason to
believe (although there is no certainty) that demand rose by more
than average. Similarly, a less than average rise in both price and
output indicates a less than average rise in demand. Where less than
average increases in output are accompanied by more than average
increases in price, or vice versa, it is more difficult to classify the
the increase in demand. In general, however, an inspection of the
relative magnitudes involved will allow us to classify a demand change
as greater or less than average.
There is an assumption in this procedure which should be made
explicit. The price which is relevant for investigating changes in
demand is the market price, whereas we are using the price of value
added in each industry. The two prices wifi differ when there is a
divergence between the movement of raw materials prices and that of
value added prices. Since we are mainly interested in relative price
and cost movements, our analysis is weakened to the extent that the
relative movements of prices of raw materials among industries differs
significantly from the relative movement of value added prices. A
This should not be taken to deny that in the long run at least, some part of gross business income becomes
a cost.
PAGENO="0039"
PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES 31
section, however, has been incorporated, which indicates, very
roughly, the influence of relative changes in the prices of raw materials.
Table 6 summarizes the changes in output, prices, and the major
components of unit costs in the 1948-56 period. On the basis of this
table, each industry may be classified according to the changes in its
relative unit labor cost, the changes in the relative demand for its
products (as reflected in the price and output changes), and the changes
in its gross margin (i.e. the percent of value added represented by gross
business incorne)~. Table 7 shows the 19 manufacturing industries
classified by this three-way classification method. Before examining
table 7, however, let us consider exactly what behavior of gross mar-
gins our assumptions would lead us to expect.
PAGENO="0040"
32 PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTtJRING INDUSTRIES
C~3
PAGENO="0041"
PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES 33
If during a particular period demands in all industries were to rise
by the same amount, then, granted the assumptions made above, in
industries with greater than average increases in unit labor costs,
gross business incomes per unit should rise by a smaller amount than
unit costs; more simply, gross profit margins as a percent of value
added should fall.'0 The opposite results would be expected to emerge
in those industries whose advance in unit labor costs was less than
average. These expectations, in turn, would be modified by two
other considerations. If the demand for the products of an industry
increased at a sufficiently greater than average rate, then gross margins
might increase, even though the rise in unit labor costs were greater
than average. Further, when we modify our assumption that a rel-
ative increase in unit labor costs implies a relative increase in total
costs (excluding gross margins), we must modify our conclusions.
In particular, if indirect taxes form a significant proportion of total
costs, then the relationship between prices, demands, and unit labor
costs could be altered by a change in indirect taxes which differed
sharply from the average. The same is true of capital consumption
allowances. We have data for these two nonlabor costs, and can
include their influence in the analysis. As was indicated earlier,
however, relative shifts in the unit cost of raw materials cannot be
formally incorporated into the data. We will attempt a qualitative
evaluation of~such costs at a later point.
It may be worth the risk of excessive repetition to recast the fore-
going analysis in somewhat simpler terms. We are stating that the
profit maximization hypothesis implies the following:
1. When relative costs increase and relative demands are unchanged,
gross "profit" margins will be narrowed, i.e., gross business income
per unit of output will rise by less than costs per unit, and will thus
decline as a percent of value added. The opposite holds true for
decreases in relative Oosts.
2. When relative demands increase and relative costs are unchanged,
gross profit margins will be widened, and vice versa for relative
decreases in demand.
3. The actual behavior of gross margins, therefore, will depend
largely on the combined influence of relative changes in demand
and costs.
4. Relative changes in unit labor costs, the largest single element
of costs, are taken as indicative of relative changes in total costs.
The analysis will be explicitly modified to take into account the effects
of significant changes in indirect taxes and capital consumption allow-
ances. The analysis is seriously weakened, however, by its failure
to include more specifically changes in relative costs of raw materials,
although we shall attempt to indicate in a general way the influence
of such costs.
Table 7 presents a three-way cross-classification of manufacturing
industries; each industry is classified according to the direction of
change in its relative unit labor costs, its relative demand, and its
gross margin.
10 This is not exactly accurate. It is possible that a change in average unit costs may alter both average
cost curves and marginal cost curves in such a fashion that profit maximization would lead to behavior
different from that suggested in the text. However, for purposes of building our hypothesis, we will assume
that any change in average cost curves results in a change in marginal cost curves which maintains the
same relative relationship between the two. Similarly, changes in the relative elasticities of demand would
change relative prices; we have, therefore, assumed constancy of relative elasticities of demand. These
relationships may also~be~affected by the degree of competitiveness and by deviation from simple profit
maxlmizingbehavior.
PAGENO="0042"
34 PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES
TABLE 7.-Relationship o.f changes in demands, unit labor costs and gross margins,1
1948-56
[Number of industriesi
Gross margins
decreased, demand
rise relative
to average
Gross margins
approximately un-
changed, demand
rise relative
to average
Gross margins
increased, demand
rise relative
to average
Greater
Same
Less
Greater
Same
Less
Greater
Same
Less
Unit labor cost increase greater than
average
Unit labor cost increase about the same
asaverage
Unit labor cost increase less than aver-
age
2
0
0
1
0
0
0
1
5
0
0
2
0
0
0
0
0
0
3
1
1
1
0
0
1
0
1
1 Gross margins are the percent of value added going to gross business incomes.
Industries are first classified according to whether their unit labor
costs, during the 1948-56 period, rose more, about the same, or less
than the average for all industries. Within each of these groups,
industries are further classified according to whether gross business
incomes rose or fell as a percent of value added. In each of these sub-
groups a further classification is provided according to the relative
magnitude of demand increases. Each cell in the table can be labeled
according to whether its characteristics are consistent, inconsistent,
or are uncertain, with respect to expected behavior. For example,
in an industry whose unit labor cost rose by less than average, while
the demand for its products rose by more than average, we should
expect to find that gross business income rose as a percent of value
added. Industries which exhibited these three characteristics, we
label as consistent with expectations. This does not necessarily im-
ply that profit maximization was the sole guide to price-cost relation-
ships. It merely indicates that the actual behavior of prices relative
to costs did not contradict what would be expected from a profit maxi-
mization hypothesis, over a period of intermediate length. An in-
dustry which possessed the first two characteristics (labor costs rising
less than average, demands more than average) but whose gross busi-
ness income fell relative to value added, would exhibit behavior in-
consistent with expectations. There are a number of situations,
however, which preliminarily we should have to label "uncertain."
If one characteristic, e~g., a less-than-average rise in unit labor costs,
leads us to expect an increase in gross business income relative to
value added, while the other characteristic, a less-than-average rise
in demand, leads us to expect the opposite, then without information
about the magnitude of the forces involved we must label the results
as uncertain. While we do not have a precise measurement of the
extent to which the rise in demand was greater or less than average,
we can resolve a number of uncertain cases where it is obvious that
increases in demands were substantially greater or less than average.
A preliminary count of the characteristics of the 20 industries
yields 4 cases in which actual behavior is consistent with expectations,
4 cases of inconsistency, and 11 uncertain cases. An investigation
of the relative magnitudes involved, however, allows us to correct our
findings to 13 cases of agreement, 3 disagreement, and 3 uncertain.
PAGENO="0043"
PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES 35
TABLE 8.-Consistency of actual behavior with expectations, 19 manufacturing
industries, 1948-56
~Number of industries]
Consistent
Inconsistent Uncertain
Preliminary classification
4
4
11
Corrected classification
13
4
2
Five of the eleven "uncertain" cases were industries in which unit
labor costs rose by less than average, demands rose by less than aver-
age, and gross business incomes rose by less than unit labor costs.
These industries were: lumber, textiles, apparel, leather, and miscel-
laneous manufacturing. The first characteristic, a less-than-average
rise in unit labor costs, would lead us to expect an increase in gross
margins. The second characteristic, a less-than-average rise in de-
mand, would lead us to expect a decrease in gross margins. In all
five industries gross business income did actually fall as a percent of
value added. Since the rise in demand in all of these industries ap-
peared to be substantially less than the rise in demand for other in-
dustries, the behavior of gross business income per unit may be judged
to be consistent with expectations. In the "corrected" classification
we have transferred these industries to the column denoting consis-
tency with expectations.
In two of the "uncertain" industries, fabricated metal products
and transportation equipment, unit labor costs rose more than average
(expectation: a decrease in the gross margin) and demand rose more
than average (expectation: an increase in the gross margin). In
both of these industries gross margins fell. In the case of fabricated
metal products the rise in demand appeared to be only slightly greater
than average, while the rise in unit labor costs was substantially
greater than average. Hence the actual results appear to confirm
expectations and the industry was transferred to the "consistent"
column. In the case of transportation equipment, however, the rise
in demand was substantially greater than average while the rise in
unit labor costs was only moderately greater than average. The
actual behavior of gross margins was, therefore, inconsistent with
expectations. There are two very important subindustries within
this industry group-aircraft and automobiles. Responding to the
huge increase in Government aircraft procurement, the aircraft in-
dustry has grown more rapidly than the automobile industry. Since
a very large proportion of plant and equipment in the aircraft industry
is Government owned, a satisfactory rate of return on private invest-
ment can be earned with a very small margin on sales. Thus, as the
proportion of total output in the industry accounted for by aircraft
rises, the total industry figure for gross business income per unit
tends to be depressed. This may account for the apparent disagree-
ment between expectations and actual results for this industry.
Without a further breakdown of the data, it is impossible to test this
hypothesis, however, and we have left the industry in the "uncertain"
column.
There were three "uncertain" industries, primary metals, non-
electrical machinery, and instruments, in which unit labor costs
rose more than average (expectation: a decrease in gross margins)
PAGENO="0044"
36 PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES
while demand also rose more rapidly than average (expectation:
an increase in gross margins). Gross margins in these three industries
actually rose. In two of the industries-nonelectrical machinery and
instruments-the rise in demands appeared to be greater than average,
while the rise in unit labor costs was only slightly to moderately
greater than average. Hence, expectations and results coincided, and
the industries were transferred to the "consistent" column. In the
case of primary metals, however, demand appeared to have risen
only moderately more than average, while unit labor costs increased
by very much more than the average for other industries. Yet the
share of gross business incomes increased. Further, the increase in
capital consumption allowances per unit in the primary metal indus-
tries exceeded by far that in any other industry. Despite the large
rise in both labor costs and capital consumption allowances relative
to average, the share taken by net business income rose substantially.
The increase in demand does not appear to have been sufficiently
greater than average to explain this behavior. Indeed, if we take
into account the fact that the demand for primary metals is probably
less elastic than in most other industries, the combined output and
price changes in the industry may indicate an increase in demand
little if any larger than the all-industry average.'1 For all of these
reasons we have reclassified the primary metals industry as one of
those which are inconsistent with expectations.
The furniture industry was classified as an uncertain case. Unit
labor costs rose by less than average, but demand also rose by less
than average. Gross business income per unit rose by more than unit
labor costs. The relative decline in unit labor costs was significant;
the relative decline in demand appeared to be quite moderate. Hence
we might be justified in placing the industry in the "consistent"
column. However, the various relative changes were not so large as
to make this conclusion obvious, and we have left the industry as
"uncertain."
The tObacco industry was one of those originally placed in the "in-
consistent" column. In this industry unit labor costs rose more than
average, demand rose less than average, yet gross business income
obtained an increasing share of value added. Unlike the situation in
most industries, however, indirect business taxes form a very large
part of total costs in the tobacco industry. In 1948 such taxes ac-
counted for about 75 percent of total costs. Between 1948 and 1956
indirect taxes per unit rose by oniy 14 percent. Relative to the rise
in other costs, this was quite small. Even though the increase in
demand for the products of the tobacco industry was smaller than
average, the relatively modest rise in the chief element of its cost
structure made possible an increase in gross business income per unit
relative to value added. We have reclassified this industry from the
"inconsistent" to the "consistent" column.
On the basis of the given data one would have to classify paper
and allied products as an industry in which price-cost relationships
liWe have used the magnitude of relative output and price changes as a rough measure of changes in rela-
tive demand. Without a measurement of demand elasticities in the various industries, however, our
criteria are very rough approximations. In general. the lower the demand elasticity the greater the change
in relative price consistent with an unchanging relative demand. In the case of primary metals, output
rose by 26 percent compared to an average rise of 40 percent for all industries. Prices on the other hand
rose by 57 percent compared to an average rise of 23 percent. We have preliminarily considered these
magnitudes to indicate a rise in relative demand. If. however, the overall elasticity of demand for pri-
mary metals is substantially lower than that which characterizes most other industries, the relative price
and output behavior of the industry might be consistent with a rise in demand no greater than average.
PAGENO="0045"
PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES 37
were inconsistent with expectation. This industry has been retained
in this classification. However, it should be noted that unit labor
costs rose by less than average, demand increased by more than aver-
age, yet the percentage of value added going to gross business income
remained about the same in 1956 as in 1948. Further, the relative
decline in unit labor costs was quite modest-a 20-percent increase as
against the 24-percent average increase for all industries; similarly,
the apparent increase in relative demand was not large. The "meas-
ured" deviation of price-cost behavior from expectations was, there-
fore, a minor one.
Those industries in which the relative behavior of costs and demands
was clearly inconsistent with expected behavior were rubber and
chemicals. These two industries illustrate the opposite extremes of
disagreement with expectations. In the rubber industry, unit labor
costs rose by more than average. Even though the increase in de-
mand in the industryappeared to be about average, both gross and
net business income per unit increased by far more than unit labor
costs. In the chemical industry on the other hand, unit labor costs in-
creased very much less than average. Demand on the other hand rose
by more than average. Both of these factors would lead us to expect
an increase in gross business income per unit larger than the increase
in unit labor costs. In actuality, however, the opposite occurred.
Indeed, net business income per unit declined.
The reader will recall that we added to the four industries whose
relative demand and cost behavior was originally classified as in-
consistent with expectations, one other industry: primary metals.
We also eliminated the tobacco industry from this classification, since
its apparent deviation from expectations could be explained by the
behavior of indirect taxes. We are thus left with 13 industries in
which the relationship of unit labor costs and gross business incomes
per unit appear to be explainable by the relative changes in demands
and unit labor costs, 4 industries in which the unit labor cost-gross
business income relationship seems to deviate from what would be
expected on the basis of relative cost and demand changes, and 2
industries which cannot be easily classified.
The analysis has to this point been carried out in terms of value
added prices and unit costs. It has thus ignored the impact of relative
changes in raw materials prices. There are two major ways in which
certain types of relative changes in raw materials costs incurred by
different industries could seriously affect our analysis. First, we
have classified the relative change in demand among the different
industries on the basis of relative changes in output and value added
prices. However, the appropriate criterion is changes in market
prices. For example, an industry exhibiting a significant relative
increase in its value added price might not have experienced a rise in
its relative market price if the relative cost of its raw materials de-
clined substantially. A second problem introduced by the lack of
data on raw materials prices is that it weakens the validity of our
assumption that a relative increase in unit labor costs indicates a
relative increase in total unit costs, excluding gross business incomes.
A greater than average rise in unit labor costs may not connote a
greater than average rise in total unit costs if the relative cost of raw
materials to the industry has declined.
PAGENO="0046"
38 PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES
We have no precise data on the movement of the raw materials
costs incurred by each industry. However, from the Bureau of Labor
Statistics wholesale price indexes we can arrive at some general con-
clusions about the relative char~ge in the prices of important raw
materials consumed by different industries.
The major conclusion yielded by an examination of BLS price
indexes is that prices of materials consumed by the durable goods
industries, particularly the metal fabricating industries, have risen
substantially more rapidly than prices of materials used in nondurable
manufacturing. The BLS index of "intermediate materials, supplies,
and components," rose by 17 percent between 1948 and 1956. In-
termediate materials used in the nondurable goods industries, except
food processing, declined by 1 percent and materials consumed by the
food-processing industry fell 8 percent. On the other hand, prices of
materials used in durable goods manufacturing rose 44 percent and
prices of components increased 40 percent. Steel mill product prices
rose 61 percent. A similar divergence in the movement of the prices
of durable and nondurable crude materials is apparent in the BLS
data. With the aid of these indexes, supplemented by individual
price indexes for such raw materials as crude rubber, hides and skins,
woodpulp, and others, we can classify most of the 19 manufacturing
industries according to whether the increase in their raw material
prices appeared to be larger or smaller than the average increase for
all industries.
Examining all of the cases for which the probable direction of relative
changes in raw materials costs could be ascertained we find only two
situations in which our classification of demand changes might require
alteration. These two were furniture and rubber. In neither case,
however, is the relative change in raw materials prices so different from
the relative change in value added prices that a significant alteration
in our conclusions about these industries seems called for.
A similar examination of each industry reveals only one case,
electrical machinery, in which a relative change in unit labor costs
in one direction was accompanied by a relative shift in raw materials
costs in the opposite direction. In the electrical machinery industry
we found that unit labor costs rose less than average, and demand
more than average; consequently, the rise in gross margins was quite
in accordance with expectations. The fact that a relative decline in
unit labor costs was at least partly offset by a relative increase in raw
materials costs does not, however, invalidate this conclusion. The
relative decline in unit labor costs was substantial; so also was the
relative increase in demands. Hence, it is doubtful if the relative rise
in raw material costs would destroy our finding that the price-cost-de-
mand relationships in this industry were in accord with expectations.
The absence of more specific information on raw materials costs
admittedly weakens our conclusions with respect to price, cost, and
demand relationships. Nevertheless, a brief examination of changes
in relative raw materials prices does not bring to light any major
situations in which our specific conclusions appear to be substantially
in error.
The tests we have applied in this section of the study relate only
to the direction of changes in relative costs, demands, and prices.
Thus, our statement that the change in the share of gross business
income was consistent with expectations in 13 of the 19 industries,
PAGENO="0047"
PRICES AND COSTS IN MANtTFACTIJRING INDUSTRIES 39
means only that margins changed in the expected direction. It does
not tell us whether the magnitude of the change in the share going to
gross business incomes can be explained by the magnitude of shifts in
relative demands and unit labor costs.
The general hypothesis tested in this section was that the behavior
of relative prices of the products of manufacturing industries may be
explained by two major factors: (1) the relative behavior of unit
labor costs, assumed to be given, and (2) the relative behavior of
demands. It was found that in a large number of industries the
degree of change in relative prices could be explained by relative shifts
in demands and unit labor costs, at least to the extent of explaining
whether or not gross business incomes rose or fell as a percent of value
added. However, the investigation revealed some exceptions to this
general pattern. Of the 19 industries examined, 13 were consistent
with expectations, 4 were not, and in the case of 2 other industries,
it proved impossible to determine whether or not price behavior was
consistent with expectations.
The hypothesis tested was constructed on the assumption that
producers set prices with profit maximization as their goal. It should
be remembered, however, that the analysis covered a change in relative
costs, demands, and prices over an 8-year span. Even though the
data for a majority of industries suggested behavior not in contra-
diction to the profit maximization hypothesis, the analysis by no
means implies profit maximization for very short-run periods. And
even for the longer period of 8 years, the analysis simply indicates that
the direction, not necessarily the magnitude, of margin changes was
consistent with profit maximization. Indeed, cost-price behavior
during the three short postwar recessions indicates that in such
periods of absolute demand declines, prices in many industries do not
move relative to costs as might be expected from a pure short-run
profit maximization hypothesis.
UNIT LABOR COSTS, AVERAGE EARNINGS, AND DEMANDS
A simple hypothesis about unit labor costs would be that they are
largely determined by the demand for labor. As shown below, how-
ever, the effect of changes in the demand for labor on unit labor costs
appears to be very greatly modified by other factors. In fact, there
appears to be very little relationship between the relative magnitudes
of changes in unit labor costs and the demand for labor.
Over the entire period from 1948 to 1957, there was a very wide
range of experience among the various industries in terms of the
changes in their unit labor costs. The changes ranged from a decrease
of 3 percent in the textile industry to an increase of 57 percent in the
primary metals industry. The average rise in unit labor costs in the
five industries with the largest increase was 46 percent; the average
rise in the industries with the lowest increase was only 11 percent.
An examination of increases in wage rates compared to the increase
in employment indicates that the two magnitudes had little if any re-
lationship to each other. In table 9 we compare changes in average
hourly earnings of production workers to changes in employment for
the 20 manufacturing industries. Between 1948 and 1957 the average
increase in wage rates for those industries whose employment was ex-
panding most rapidly was insignificantly larger than the increase in
PAGENO="0048"
40 ~rc~s ~ cosTs fl~ M ACTU~ING I~mvsmr~s
those industries with the largest decline in employment.'2 Between
1955 and 1957 wage rate increases in those industries with the least
expansion in employment were the same, on the average, as those in
industries with the most rapid expansion in employment. If the
mobility of the labor force were very high, these results would call for
little comment. There is, however, far from perfect mobility in the
labor force, particularly in the short run, and there are substantial
differences in wage rate increases among various industries. The
central fact is that these differences are not at all closely related with
the magnitude of increases in the employment of production workers.
TABLE 9.-Relationship of change in employment to change in average hourly
earnings of production workers
Percent change in
production worker
employment
Percent change in
average hourly
earnings
1948-57 1955-57
1948-57 1955-57
53 9
Upper quartile I
All industry average
Lowerquartile'
21 2
1 -3
-20 -10
51 10
50 9
1 Quartiles selected on basis of employment changes only.
Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics.
If, however, we compare changes in wage rates, not to changes in
employment, but to changes in production, there does appear to be
some relationship between the two, particularly in the longer period,
1948 to 1957. The changes in wage rates appear therefore to be more
closely related to changes in the demand for output rather than to the
changes in the demand for labor.
TABLE 10.-Relationship of changes in output to changes in average hourly earnings
of production workers
[Percent changel
Output
Average hourly
earnings
1948-57 1955-57
1948-57 1955-57
Upper quartile 1
All industry average
Lower quartile I -
84 9
39 3
10 5
57 11
51 10
40 9
1 Quartiles selected on basis of output change only.
Sources: Average hourly earnings; BLS. Output; FRB indexes of manufacturing production used in
this study.
From 1948 to 1957 the average increase in hourly earnings in the
five most rapidly expanding industries was 57 percent; in the five
most slowly expanding industries the increase was 40 percent. From
1955 to 1957 the differences were relatively smaller; the rate of in-
crease in wages in the most rapidly expanding industries was about 22
percent higher than in the slowly expanding industries (i.e. 11 percent
12 The coefficient of rank correlation between increases In man-hours of production worker employmnet
and increases in wage rates during the 1948-57 period was only 0.14.
PAGENO="0049"
PRICES AND COSTS IN MANuFACTURING INDUSTRIES 41
versus 9 percent) ; the difference in wage rate increases between the
two groups of industries over the whole 9 year period was 43 percent
(i.e. 57 percent versus 40 percent).
If we examine the particular industries which make up the upper
and lower quartiles when ranked according to employment expansion,
and compare them with industries comprising the upper and lower
quartiles when ranked according to output expansion, we can gain
some better understanding of the relationships between the variables.
Among the industries which had the lowest increase in employment
between 1948 and 1957 are the petroleum and the food and beverage
industries. Both of these industries experienced significant pro-
ductivity gains. Despite a decline in production man-hours in these
industries, they had larger than average wage increases. Hence
their inclusion in the lower quartile increases the average wage rise
for the group. When industries are ranked by output increases
instead of employment increases, these two industries are replaced
in the lower quartile by the apparel and the leather industries, both
of which had less than average productivity gains and wage increases,
As a consequence, the average wage increase for the quartile is reduced.
Conversely, one of the most rapidly expanding industries in terms of
output increases was the chemicals industry. It experienced very
sizable increases in productivity and one of the highest wage rate
increases. This tended to increase the average wage rate gain in the
upper quartile of industries when ranked by the size of output gains.
`When the ranking is made in terms of employment increases, the
chemical industry, on account of its very large productivity gain, is
replaced by the printing and publishing industry, with a lower than
average productivity gain and a lower than average wage rate gain.
This reduces the average wage gain in the upper quartile, when the
ranking is done by the size of employment gain.
So far we have considered changes in wages of production workers
only. However, unit labor costs include both wages and salaries.
Because of the very rapid substitution of salaried workers for wage
workers during the postwar period, the increase in salary costs per
unit of output has been substantially larger than the increase in wage
costs per unit of output. Consequently an investigation of the behav-
ior of unit labor costs must take into account changes in salary rates
as well as changes in wage rates. We have no reliable figures on the
change in salary rates per man-hour of salaried employees for each of
the 20 manufacturing industries. However we can obtain data on
average annual earnings per employee. Compensation per employee
includes both wages and salaries. The difference between the behavior
of average hourly earnings of production workers and average compen-
sation per employee, however, will be affected not only by the fact
that the former excludes, and the latter includes, changes in salary
rates, but also by the fact that the annual earnings data include the
effect of changes in the number of hours worked per year.13 Even if
wage and salary rates increased by the same amount, in industries
characterized by changing hours of work during the period in question
average annual earnings would increase by a different percentage than
average hourly earnings. Further, a change in the proportion of
13 There are also some relatively modest discrepancies of a purely statistical nature, resulting from the
fact that the two series are prepared by different agencies,and include some adjustment factors not common
to both series.
PAGENO="0050"
42 PRICES ~&~D COSTS IN MANIJFACTURING INDUSTRIES
salaried workers to total workers will tend to raise the percentage
change in average annual earnings relative to the change in average
hourly earnings of production workers, since the level of salary rates
tends to be higher than the level of wage rates.
TABLE 11.-Relationship of changes in employment to change in average annual
earnings (wage and salary workers)
[Percent change]
Employment
Average annual earnings
1948-57 1955-57
1948-57 1955-57
Upper quartile I
All industry average
Lower quartile 1
32 6
8 5
-16 -5
60 20
53 17
48 14
1 Quartiles selected on basis of employment only.
Source: Average full-time equivalent employees, and average annual earnings of full-time equivalent
employees; ILS. Department of Commerce.
If we rank the 20 manufacturing industries by size of employment
increases and compare the increase in average annual earnings of
both wage and salary workers in the upper and lower quartiles, we
find this time a difference between the average earnings gain in the
two quartiles.
In view of the substantial differences in changes in employment,
differences in average annual wage rate increases were not striking.'4
If we rank industries according to output increases and compare
the increase in average annual earnings in the upper and lower quar-
tiles, we arrive at the same results found in the comparison of wage
rates and output-there does appear to be a noticeable difference in
the increase in average annual earnings in the two quartiles. The
difference between the quartiles is somewhat larger during the 1955-57
period, when the comparison is made on the basis of average annual
earnings than when it is made on the basis of average hourly earnings.
In general we have found that there appears to be only a modest
association between relative changes in wage and salary rates and rela-
tive changes in employment. Between 1948 and 1957 there did appear
to be some relationship between the relative magnitude of wage and
salary increases and the relative size of output increases. In the
shorter period from 1955 to 1957, the relationship between wage and
salary changes on the one hand and output changes on the other was
much weaker, and may have been so small as to be insignificant.
WAGES, PRODUCTIvITY, AND UNIT LABOR COSTS
Changes in unit labor costs may be separated into two distinct
components: changes in the cost of labor inputs and changes in labor
productivity. To the extent that increases in compensation per
employee exceed increases in output per employee, unit labor costs
14 A further test can be performed by constructing rough estimates of average wage and salary compensa-
tion by man-hour, and comparing changes in such average compensation with changes in man-hours of
employment. The coefficient of rank correlation between the two sets of Increases was only 0.36. The
estimates of average compensation per man-hour of both wage and salaried employees was constructed
by dividing Department of Commerce estimatgs of total employee compensation by estimates of total
man-hours of employment including nonproduction workers. In making this calculation, nonproduction
workers were assumed to work an average of 40 hours per week in all years.
PAGENO="0051"
PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES 43
will rise. Table 12 gives a summary comparison of changes in com-
pensation per employee, changes in output per employee man-hour,
and the resultant change in unit labor costs for the period 1948-56.
TABLE 12.-Percent changes in compensation per employee, output per man-hour,
and unit labor costs, manufacturing industries, 1948-56
Percent change
Percent change
Percent change
in compensa-
tion per
in output per
man-hour 2
in unit labor
costs
employee 1
All manufacturing
Primary metals
Fabricated metal products
Nonelectrical machinery
Electrical machinery
56
26
24
70
61
53
50
18
15
17
36
44
40
31
10
Transportation equipment
Stone, clay, and glass
Lumber and products
Furniture and fixtures
65
59
50
46
28
27
28
29
29
25
17
13
Miscellaneous
49
32
13
Instruments
s6
31
27
Textiles..
29
36
-5
Apparel
28
14
12
Rubber
39
21
31
Leather
19
6
12
Paper
54
28
20
Printing
47
15
28
Chemicals
65
57
Petroleum and coal products
Food and kindred products
Tobacco
60
53
86
32
23
26
21
24
48
1 Estimated by dividing total employee compensation (De-artment of Commerce) by total man-hours of
employment assuming average hours of work by nonproduction workers to be 40 hours per week.
2 Man-hours derived as explained in footnote 1.
Sources: BLS, U.S. Department of Commerce, and table 5.
As we noted earlier, there is substantial variation among the
different industries in the percentage rise in unit labor costs. An
analysis of the data indicates that, with several important exceptions,
differences in productivity behavior were more important than differ-
ences in wage and salary changes in producing this variation in unit
labor cost changes. If we rank industries by the magnitude of their
wage and salary increase over the period, we notice two industries-
tobacco and primary metals-with very large wage and salary in-
creases, 86 and 70 percent, respectively, and three industries-textiles,
apparel, and leather-with very small increases, 29, 28, and 19
percent, respectively. The other 20 industries form a middle group
with wages and salary increases ranging from 46 to 66 percent.
Among the middle group of industries, differences in the magnitude
of productivity gains accounted for the largest part of the variation
in unit labor costs. If we rank this middle group of industries by the
size of their increases in unit labor costs, we find that the five indus-
tries with the largest unit labor cost increases had productivity gains
averaging only 20 percent. industries with the lowest increase iii
unit labor costs, on the other hand, had productivity gains averaging
36 percent. The differences in wage rate increases between these two
groups of industries was much smaller, 52 percent versus 57 percent.
In other words among the 15 industries, those with the lowest iii-
creases in unit labor costs had wage increases almost as large as those
industries with the smallest increase in unit labor costs.
PAGENO="0052"
44 PRICES AND COSTS IN MAN1JFACTURING INDUSTRIES
TABLE 13.-Comparison of unit labor cost, average compensation, and productivity,
15 manufacturing industries,' 1948-56
[Percent change]
Unit
labor
costs
Compen-
sation
per em-
ployee
Output
per
man-
hour
5 industries with highest increase in unit labor cost
5 industries with lowest increase in unit labor cost
32
12
57
52
20
36
1 All industries except tobacco, primary metals, textiles, apparel, and leather.
These conclusions are confirmed when we rank the 15 industries by
their increase in productivity instead of their increase in unit labor
costs (table 14). The five industries with the largest gains in pro-
ductivity (averaging 37 percent) experienced wage increases no larger
than the industries with the smallest gains in productivity (averaging
only 18 percent). As a consequence unit labor costs rose by a sub-
stantially larger amount in the industries which experienced the
smallest productivity gains.
TABLE 14.-comparison of productivity, average compensation, and unit labor costs,
15 manufacturing industries,1 1948-56
[Percent change]
Produc-
tivity
Compen-
sation
per em-
ployee
Unit
labor
costs
5 industries with highest increase in productivity
5 industries with lowest increase in productivity
37
18
54
55
8
31
1 All industries except tobacco, primary metals, textiles, apparel, and leather.
l3ecause there appeared to be little if any correlation between ad-
vances in productivity and advances in wage and salary rates, those
industries with the largest productivity gains had the smallest in-
creases in unit labor costs. And because the variation in wage and
salary increases was substantially less than the variation in produc-
tivity gains among these 15 industries, most of the differences in unit
labor cost performance were due to the difference in productivity
behavior.'5
In the other five industries exceptionally large or exceptionally
small changes in wage and salary rates were the dominant factor in
explaining the relative behavior of unit labor costs. In the tobacco
industry average wage and salary rates increased by 86 percent, while
the rise in productivity was 26 percent, about the same as the average
for all industries. The increase in average wage and salary rates in
primary metals was 70 percent, and the increase in productivity only
18 percent. At the other end of the scale, increases in average wage
and salary rates in leather and apparel were so far below average that,
despite below average productivity performance, unit labor costs
rose less than the average for all industries. In textiles, below aver-
age wage and salary increases were coupled with above average pro-
"For all 20 industries the coefficient of rank correlation between changes in output per man-hour and
changes in average wage and salary rates (1948-56) was only 0.21.
PAGENO="0053"
PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES 45
ductivity gains, with the result that unit labor costs actually fell
during the period. This was the oniy industry in which the absolute
level of unit labor costs decreased.16
In summary, we have found that the direction of relative price
movements in most industries can be explained by the relative magm.-
tude of changes in demand and the relative size of increases in unit
labor costs. In a large majority of industries the magnitude of price
increases relative to unit labor cost increases, as measured by the
movement of gross business incomes per unit, can also be explained
by changes in relative demands and the relative magnitude of unit
labor cost increases. There is, however, a small minority of important
industries in which the behavior of gross business incomes relative
to unit labor costs does not conform to the predictions of orthodox
price theory.
The behavior of unit labor costs themselves is much more difficult
to explain. The relative magnitude of increases in wages and salaries
does not appear to be related to the relative magnitude of increases
in employment. There does appear to be a weak relationship between
the magnitude of increases in output and increases in wage and salary
rates over longer periods; but this relationship was not in evidence
during the 1955-57 period of rising prices. For most industries
differences in the magnitude of productivity gains rather than differ-
ences in wage and salary increases explain most of the relative varia-
tion in the size of unit labor cost increases. There were, however,
five industries in which extremely high or extremely low increases in
wage and salary gains provided the major explanation of relative
changes in unit labor costs.
UNIT LABOR COSTS AND "PRODUCT MIX"
In estimating changes in unit labor costs for manufacturing in-
dustry as a whole, two basic methods of measurement are possible.
One may sum the total wage and salary bill for all industries and divide
the total by a measure of manufacturing output. Indexes of output
are normally derived by weighting quantities produced with price
weights. An index of unit labor costs derived by dividing the total
wage and salary bill by an index of total output will change if the
composition of output shifts toward industries in which labor costs
are a larger percentage of price than the average for all industries.
Such a unit labor cost index will reflect, therefore, not oniy changes in
unit labor costs in each industry, but also shifts in output from
industries with low unit labor costs (as a percent of price) to industries
with high unit labor costs, or vice versa. On the other hand, an
index of unit labor costs constructed by weighting individual industry
cost indexes with constant weights, will reflect only the changes in
unit labor costs in individual industries, and will exclude the effects of
a shifting composition of output.
We have constructed such a "constant weight" unit labor cost
index, using 1947 output to weight the indexes of unit labor cost in
each industry. Table 15 compares the change in manufacturing unit
16 The behavior of relative wages In the five Industries named is consistent with the findings on relative
wages reported in ch. 5, "Staff Report, Joint Economic Committee, Study of Employment, Growth, and
Output." Investigations by Conrad and Levinson showed relative wages to be positively correlated with
industry concentration ratios and with profits. The two industries with very high wage increases-
primary metals and tobacco-are industries with relatively high concentration ratios. These Industries
also had very large increases In gross margins over the period In question. Precisely the opposite charac-
teristics are associated with the three industries in which relative wages fell sharply-textiles, apparel, and
leather.
PAGENO="0054"
46 PRICES AND COSTS IN MANTJFACTURING INDUSTRIES
labor costs as shown by the constant weighted index with the change
shown by the aggregate index (i.e., aggregate wage and salary bill
divided by aggregate output). The difference between the two
indexes shows the influence of shifts between low and high unit labor
cost industries.'7 Over the period 1947-57 the two indexes rose by
almost the same percentage. Practically all of the rise in unit labor
costs shown by the "aggregate" index was due to changes in unit labor
costs in each industry; very little was due to shifts in the composition
of output.
TABLE 15.-Comparison of 2 indexes of unit labor costs, all manufacturing industries
[Percent change}
1947-57
1948-49
1953-54
1957-58
`Aggregate" index
"Constant weight" index
36. 5
37. 7
0. 9
2. 2
1.3
2. 6
2. 2
4. 1
On the other hand, in each recession of the postwar period, the
increase in unit labor costs shown by the aggregate index was sub-
stantially less than the increase shown by the constant weighted
index. In other words, the rise in unit labor costs in each industry
was partly offset by a decline in the relative importance of high labor
cost industries. Both indexes show that the rise in unit labor costs
during the 1957-58 recession was somewhat larger than the rise during
earlier recessions. `While we have not fully investigated the factors
which might have been responsible for this greater increase in unit
labor costs during the recent recession, two factors suggest themselves
immediately; first, the decline in output was larger during the 1957-58
recession than during the prior ones; and secondly the proportion of
total labor costs represented by the relatively fixed salary component
was larger in 1957 and 1958 than in earlier years.
PRICES AND COSTS IN RECESSION AND RECOVERY
In this section we will examine the behavior of the prices of the
products of manufacturing industries in the course of recessions and
recoveries. Concerning their behavior during recessions, a very inter-
esting comparison may be made between the behavior of these prices
and other prices in the economy. The price indexes which have been
constructed in this study are, it will be remembered, indexes of the
price of gross product originating in each industry. The price of gross
product originating in any industry is conceptually equivalent to the
price of the product minus the unit cost of materials and supplies
purchased from other firms. For the manufacturing industry as a
whole, the price of gross product originating is equal to the price of
products sold minus the unit cost of materials and supplies purchased
from nonmanufacturing industries.
If we examine the behavior of market prices of manufactured goods
during postwar recessions, we find that in the 1949 recession prices
declined, in the 1954 recession they rose slightly, and in the 1958
recession they rose somewhat more. A similar pattern was exhibited
by the wholesale and consumer price indexes. These changing pat-
`7 More correctly, we can Isolate the effect of shifts In the composition of output among our 20 Industries.
Shifts In the composition of output within each industry are still reflected in our individual Industry
Indexes.
PAGENO="0055"
PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES 47
terns of price behavior have led many Observers to believe that prices
are becoming increasingly likely to rise during recessions. However,
an examination of table 16 shows that at least for the prices of the
product which originates within manufacturing industries, i.e. our
"value added" prices, such does not appear to be the case. In this
table published Bureau of Labor Statistics indexes for manufactured
goods and for raw materials are compared with the indexes of value
added (gross product originating) prices constructed for this study.
The three sets of indexes are not so constructed that they are com-
pletely consistent with each other. Nevertheless, changes in the
prices of manufactured goods, as shown by the BLS indexes, will be
approximately determined by the combined influence of changes in
raw materials prices and changes in prices of value added.
TABLE 16.-Changes in various prices in postwar recessions
[Percent change]
1948-49
1953-54
1957-58
Total manufacturing: 1
Product prices
Raw materials prices -
Price of value added
-3.4
-10. 2
3.9
2.9
-19.6
7.3
-8. 2
-9.6
-1.2
.8
-1.8
1.4
1. 2
-8.8
3.0
.3
-1.4
-1.3
1. 1
2.7
1.8
1.4
-11.4
3.0
. 7
3. 6
-.4
Durable manufacturing:
Product prices
Raw materials prices .
Price of value added
Nondurable manufacturing: 1
Product prices
Raw materials prices
Price of value added
Consumer price index
Food
-1.0
-3.9
-1.4
4.7
.3
-.2
-1.3
2. 7
.7
4.2
1.0
3.8
Other commodities .
Services
Wholesale price index
Farm
Food
Industrial
-5.0
-13.5
-9.8
-2, 0
.2
-1.4
.7
.4
1.4
4.4
8.0
.3
1 Excludes petroleum and coal products industry.
NoTE-The indexes of product prices, value added prices, and raw materials prices, from which the
changes shown in the table were derived, are not completely consistent with each other In terms of weighting
and coverage. As a consequence, the changein product prices, in some instances, may not be fully explained
by the change in the indexes of value added prices and raw materials prices.
It is clear from the table that the major changes in the behavior
of product market prices in the various recessions are traceable not
to changes in the behavior of the prices of product originating within
manufacturing (that is, the prices of value added), but rather to
changes in the behavior of raw materials prices. It~ is true that the
price of value added within manufacturing increased in all three reces-
sions. However, the percent increase in this price of value added was
greatest in 1948-49, and was substantially smaller in the two succeed-
ing recessions. We may conclude then that the changed behavior
of the market prices of manufactured products did not occur because
manufacturers added a larger overall markup to raw materials costs
in succeeding recessions. Rather the explanation lies in the fact that
raw materials prices declined sharply in 1948-49, declined moderately
in 1953-54, and increased moderately in 1957-58. Thus the change
in the pattern of behavior of the market prices of manufactured goods
is largely attributable to the change in the pattern of raw materials
prices.
In assessing the importance of the change in the pattern of behavior
of raw materials prices, it should be kept in mind that the behavior of
PAGENO="0056"
48 PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES
the overall index of raw materials prices is dominated by movements
of farm prices. In the durable goods industries, raw materials pur-
chased from nonmanufacturing firms play a very small role. In part
this is a statistical phenomenon. Most important raw materials (iron
ore, bauxite, copper ore, etc.) are produced by establishments owned
by manufacturing firms. The first time the product appears on the
market it has already been fabricated to some extent (steel ingot,
steel shapes, aluminum ingot, refined copper). The amount of pure
raw material changing hands on the market is quite limited. Rightly
then, the BLS price index of raw materials gives very small weight
to the prices of such materials. These prices are often mere accounting
prices established in the transfer of materials between mining and
manufacturing establishments owned by the same firm. On the other
hand, the major group of raw materials used in the nondurable indus-
tries, farm commodities, does pass through the marketplace. As a
consequence, the overall index of raw materials prices is dominated by
the behavior of farm prices.
During the 1949 recession farm prices fell substantially; during the
1954 recession farm prices declined very moderately, having by 1953
already fallen sharply from peaks reached in 1951. In 1958, on the
other hand, farm prices rose. The different behavior of farm prices
during the various recessions is mainly attributable not to a signifi-
cant difference in the pattern of demand but rather to a difference in
the behavior of output. The rise in farm prices in 1958 can be traced
in large part to reduced supplies, particularly supplies of livestock.
The impact of farm prices on the consumer price index is somewhat
greater than its significance for manufactured prices. Food prices
account for almost one-third of the total weight in the consumer price
index. The direct influence of farm prices, as raw materials costs, on
the prices of manufactured goods is substantially smaller. As a con-
sequence the differential behavior of farm prices in the three recessions
is more strikingly evident in the consumer price index than in the
index of manufactured goods prices.
For manufacturing as a whole, the price of value added had its
greatest rise in 1948-49, with smaller rises in the two succeeding reces-
sions. The most significant change in the behavior of manufacturing
value added prices took place in the durable goods industries, where the
price of value added rose by a very sizable 7.3 percent in 1948-49, but
by only 3 percent in both the 1954 and 1958 recessions. In the non-
durable goods industries, there were relatively small declines in the
price of value added in each recession, the changes being -1.2 percent
in 1948-49, -1.3 percent in 1953-54, and -0.9 percent in 1957-58.
Table 17 summarizes the changes in prices and their component costs
in each industry during the three recessions. From this table it is
possible to pinpoint the cost components which were responsible for
the change in behavior of the price of value added. The cost whose
behavior changed most radically was unit gross business income, and
the major share of this change was contributed by the durable goods
industries. The table shows that gross business incomes per unit in
durable goods industries shifted from a very large increase of 23 per-
cent in 1949 to a negligible increase of 0.5 percent in 1954, to a sizable
decline of -8.7 percent in 1958. The major industries contributing
to the overall increase in 1949 were the primary metals, the machinery,
and the transportation equipment industries. One of the major rea-
sons for the rise in durable goods margins during the 1949 recession
PAGENO="0057"
PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING flThUSTRIES 49
was the fact that throughout the recession purchases of automobiles,
consumer appliances, and new houses continued to rise. There was,
in other words, no recession for these industries and some of their
chief suppliers. Moreover, gross margins, even by 1948, had not
recovered to "normal" levels after the price controls and low unit
margins of World War II. In the nondurable goods industries, how-
ever, the postwar reconversion of production and the recovery of
margins had been much quicker. Indeed margins in many~nondurab1e
goods industries were quite large in 1948, and were vulnerable to the
effects of the 1949 recession.
TABLE 17.-Changes in prices and unit costs in postwar recessions, manufacturing
industries 1
[Percentchange]
1948-49
1953-54
1957-58
Price
ULC'
Gill'
Price
ULC2
GBI3
Price
ULO2
GBI3
Total manufacturing
3. 9
1.6
9.4
1.4
2.4
-1.9
1.8
4.4
-7. 0
Durables
7.3
2. 1
22. 5
3.0
3. 2
. 5
3. 0
6.3
-8. 7
Primary metals
13. 0
6.4
32.3
4.3
7.8
-4.3
4. 6
11. 3
-13. 1
Fabricated metal products
1. 6
3. 1
-3.9
4.8
4. 1
5. 9
2. 3
4. 6
-6. 3
Nonelectrical machinery
7.3
2.4
21.9
6.5
6. 5
6. 4
2.7
4. 7
-4. 5
Electrical machinery
2.6
-2.4
26.8
-1.4
. 5
-7. 2
10.3
11. 5
4. 2
Transportation equipment
Stone, clay, and glass
Lumber and products
13.0
5. 9
-4.0
. 1
2. 9
0
50.2
12.9
-14.0
2. 9
4. 5
-3.0
1. 9
2. 2
-2. 5
-.6
8. 7
-6. 3
.8
3. 1
-3.4
6. 2
4.8
-3. 4
-20. 7
-. 8
-4.3
Furniture and fixtures
5. 6
3.3
14.9
-7. 4
-8. 6
-3.3
-2.3
2. 1
-24. 7
Miscellaneous manufacturing
Instruments
-.7
10.4
. 1
7. 2
-4.3
21.0
0
3.0
1.0
1.4
-3.8
8. 1
-.3
4.2
1.9
2. 6
-9.4
8.2
Nondurables 1
-1. 2
. 7
-7.0
-1.3
.6
-6. 1
-.4
.4
-3.8
Textiles
-11. 2
-2. 1
-32. 2
-6. 5
-3.6
-21. 1
-.9
-2. 5
4.8
Apparel
-3. 7
-2.3
-11. 7
-. 6
. 6
-11. 1
-1.0
-1.2
-3. 1
Rubber
-.4
1. 2
-15. 8
-11. 1
-2. 7
-45.3
2.3
1. 6
0
Leather
-6.4
1. 1
-38. 6
-.7
-2. 6
11. 5
-3.6
. 1
-32.9
Paper and allied products
-2. 7
2. 0
-11. 7
.8
1. 7
-2.0
-1.8
7
-7.6
Printing and publishing
Chemicals and allied
3. 1
3.9
3. 5
2.0
. 9
5. 7
-1.2
3.3
. 5
4.3
-7. 9
1. 5
1.8
-1.2
.
4. 6
9
-9. 1
-4.9
Food and beverage
-2. 1
.4
-10. 0
-2. 6
. 5
-8. 4
0
-1.0
1. 2
Tobacco
4. 8
5.6
27. 9
.9
8. 7
-3. 1
-1.3
-4. 9
-3. i
1 Excludes petroleum and coal products industry.
2 ULC=Tjnit labor costs.
~GBI= Gross business income per unit.
In each recession since 1949, unit labor costs in the durable
goods industries rose by larger amounts. Conversely gross business
incomes per unit declined by larger amounts. The increasing magni-
tude of the rise in unit labor costs, and its converse-the fall in gross
margins-stemmed only in part from the fact that the rise in wage
and salary rates was larger in the later recessions. In large part
this phenomenon was due to the fact that salaried costs-which are a
relatively fixed item of expense-rose as a proportion of total labor
costs throughout the postwar period. The relatively sharp cuftacks
in durable goods production which characterized even the mild re-
cessions of the postwar period, thus generated increasingly sizable
advances in average imit labor costs. During the 1958 recession out-
put fell by more than during the prior two recessions, tending to raise
unit labor costs and depress gross business incomes more substantially.
In the nondurable goods industries, changes in prices, unit labor
costs, and gross business incomes per unit were quite small during the
recessions of 1954 and 1958. Prices and gross margins (equals gross
business incomes per unit) did decline more substantially in the 1949
recession. The major reason for the relatively small changes in
PAGENO="0058"
50 PRICES AND COSTS IN MAN1JFACTURING INDUSTRIES
nondurable prices and costs during the 1954 and 1958 recessions was
the fact that demand and output fell very slightly. In 1949, on the
other hand, output of nondurables fell by a somewhat larger amount.
Perhaps the most; significant feature of the behavior of prices
and costs in manufacturing during recessions is the fact that increases
in unit labor costs are not fully absorbed in gross margins. Particu-
larly in the durable goods industries, the increases in unit labor
costs-associated in part with the reductions in output-are partially
reflected in higher value added prices, despite the rather sharp cutbacks
in the demand for durable products. Moreover the rise in durable
goods unit labor costs during recessions is largely attributable to
increases in "overhead" labor costs. With a growing proportion of
total labor costs accounted for by salaried labor, a given cutback in
production tends to increase labor costs by a larger amount. The fact
that such increases in fixed unit costs are even partially passed on in
higher prices in the face of declining demand for output, strengthens
the evidence that pricing policies are strongly cost-oriented during
periods of demand decreases. Markups are clearly not rigid; gross
margins do decline. Nevertheless, in most industries prices are
raised in the face of declining demands if costs increase, even when
those cost increases are largely attributable to the decline in output
itself.
Table 17 has already presented the behavior of prices and the
various unit cost components during three postwar recessions. As
we noted, unit labor costs tend to rise in recessions, largely because a
substantial part of unit labor costs represent a relatively fixed cost.
If this explanation is correct, we should expect to find that a period
when unit labor costs had risen during a recession would be followed
by a period when unit labor costs would fall during the recovery.
Table 18 classifies each industry according to whether or not its com-
pensation per unit of output followed this pattern during the two
completed cycles in the postwar period. In the 1949-50 cycle, 11
industries conformed to the pattern and 4 did not; another 4 had no
dedine in output and hence could not be put in either group. In the
1953-55 cycle 10 conformed, 4 did not, and 5 could not be classified
because output did not fall. It is of some interest to compare these
results with a similar classification of industries according to the be-
havior of capital consumption allowances. Since depreciation, the
principal element of capital consumption allowances, is in the short
run largely a function of the lapse of time rather than of output,
capital consumption per unit of output should rise when output falls
and fall when output recovers. Table 18 shows that in 1949-50 13
of the 15 industries having output dips showed this pattern and 2 did
not. In 1953-55, however, only 4 of the 14 with output dips showed
this pattern while 10 did not. Why did so many industries appear
to contradict the expected pattern in 1953-55? For 4 of the 10 whose
capital consumption allowance rose continuously over the period,
heavy plant and equipment expenditures were bunched in 1954 and
1955. This increase in plant and equipment led to an immediate
jump in depreciation. Probably more important, the rapid amortiza-
tion of defense facilities and the changes in the tax laws in 1954 which
permitted faster depreciation generally, also helped to explain the
failure of capital consumption per unit to fall with the recovery in
the 1953-55 cycle.
PAGENO="0059"
TABLE 18.-Behavior of labor cost and capital consumption per unit during declines and recoveries in output
5
Unit labor cost rose and fell with decline and recovery in
output
Capital consumption per unit rose and fell with decline and
recovery in output
1949-50
1953-55
1949-50
I 1953-55
Con-
formed
Did not
conform
No out-
put dip
Con-
formed
Did not
conform
No out-
put dip
Con-
formed
Did not
conform
No out-
put dip
Con-
formed
Did not
conform
No out-
put dip
Primary metals
Fabricated metals ordnance
Nonelectrical macisinery
Electrical machinery
Transportation equipment
Stone, clay, glass
Lumber and products
V
V
V
V
V
V
V
V
V
V V
V
V
V
V V
V
V V
v
V V
v
v
V
- V V
V
- V V
- - V V
4 4 10 4 5
V
V
V
V
V
v
V
V
V
V
V ----
V
v
v
V
V
V
V
V
13 2 4
v
V
V
V
V
V
V
V
V
- V
V
v
- v
V
V
V
V
V
4 10
Furniture and fixtures
Miscellaneous manufacturing
Instruments
Textiles
Apparel
Rubber
Leather
Paper and allied products
Printing and publishing
Chemicals and allied products
Food and kindred products
Tobacco
Total
v
*--------
V
V
V
*----
V
11
0
Cl)
0
0
Cl)
Cl)
I-
PAGENO="0060"
52 PRICES. AND COSTS IN MANTIFACTURING INDUSTRIES
The general impression gained from table 18 is that at least where
short run dips in production are concerned, it is very likely that labor
cost per unit will behave more like an overhead cost rather than a
variable one.
SUMMARY OF CONCLUSIONS
The behavior of output in the manufacturing industries examined
was quite diverse over the period 1948-56. A significant part of the
diversity can be explained by the increase and subsequent cutback
in the demand for military hard goods, and the continuation of the
long run trend toward greater fabrication per unit of materials input.
Turning to prices and costs, we found that unit prices of gross prod-
uct originating within manufacturing had risen 23 percent over 1948-
56. Labor cost per unit contributed by far the greatest part of this
increase; however, the contribution of labor cost to the increase was
only about its proportionate share of total costs. Capital consump-
tion per unit was the one cost per unit which contributed more than
its proportionate share to the rise in total costs per unit, while net
business income per unit contributed less than its share to the rise.
The combination of these two costs, gross business income per unit,
contributed just about its proportionate share to the price rise. As in
output, the behavior of prices or unit costs for different industries was
quite diverse.
The direction of changes in relative prices and ui gross margins in
most manufacturing industries appeared to conform to what would
have been expected on the basis of given changes in unit labor costs
and demands. There were some exceptions to this conformity, how-
ever. Behavior of labor cost per unit was far from uniform for all
industries, ranging from large relative declines to large relative in-
creases. The diversity of experience in the behavior of unit labor
costs for most industries appeared to be best explained by variation
in productivity gains rather than variation in wage rate increases.
In industries where productivity increased most rapidly, labor costs
per unit of output rose more slowly than in industries where produc-
tivity rose at a slower rate. There were, however, five significant
exceptions-tobacco, primary metals, textiles, apparel, and leather-
in which the variation in wage rate increases rather than productivity
gains played the larger role in explaining the relative behavior of unit
labor costs. Another factor which influenced the behavior of unit
labor costs was the substitution of salaried employees for wage em-
ployees.
Increases in the unit labor cost for the manufacturing industry as
a whole may come about because of increases in unit labor costs within
individual industries or because of a shift in the composition of output
from industries with low labor cost per unit to industries with high
labor cost per unit. It is clear that the increase in labor cost per unit
for all manufacturing is almost entirely due to actual changes in unit
labor costs within individual two-digit industries and not to shifts in
the composition of manufacturing output among these industries.
A. commonly advanced hypothesis is that prices have become more
likely to increase during recessions than in the past. This pattern is
exhibited in both the consumer price index and the wholesale pnce
index. For the product originating within manufacturing it is true
that prices have risen in each postwar recession, but in this respect,
PAGENO="0061"
PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES 53
these prices have tended to rise less in the two more recent recessions.
The changes in the behavior of the wholesale and consumers price
indexes are therefore largely due to changes in the behavior of raw
materials prices, not prices of the value added within manufacturing
industries.
Over the complete business cycle, it is apparent that labor cost per
unit behaves more like a fixed cost than a variable one. Iii fact, in
this regard, it conforms to the expected behavior of a fixed cost more
consistently than capital consumption per unit. Part of the explana-
tion for this characteristic of labor cost behavior is the increasing pro-
portion of compensation per unit going to salaried employees instead
of wage employees.
In closing, it should be noted that the data presented in this study
have by no means been fully exploited. There are many problems
for which they might be used which have not been considered in this
paper. For example, nothing is presented regarding the timing of
changes in one type of cost relative to changes in other costs. It is
hoped that the presentation here of the detailed cost data will permit
further research to be carried on by others interested in price and cost
behavior.
PAGENO="0062"
APPENDIXES
APPENDIX A
SOURCES OF DATA AND DERIVATION OF BASIC SERIES FOR COST INDEXES
This appendix describes the sources and treatment of data used to obtain the
basic annual series for the cost indexes presented in this study. Appendix B
describes how these series were adjusted for the fact that three of them are based
on data which is reported on a company basis rather than an establishment basis.
The necessary series for each industry are (1) wages and salaries, (2) net busi-.
ness income, (3) capital consumption allowances, (4) indirect business taxes, and
(5) an index of physical output. Each of the first four must be industry totals
on an annual basis and in current dollar values. The output index must be
consistent with the other four and is used with them to obtain the cost indexes
as described in the text of the study.
The basic data source for this study was "U.S. Income and Output," published
by the Department of Commerce, November 1958. For the year 1958, the con-
tinuation of tables found in "Income and Output" in the Survey of Current
Business, July 1959, was used.
WAGES AND SALARIES
Wages and salaries are reported by industry in table VI-2, "Income and Out-
put." The only problem in this series arises from a change in the industrial
classification made in 1948. This reclassification affected lumber and wood
products, furniture and fixtures, chemicals, petroleum and coal products, primary
metals, fabricated metals and ordnance, instruments, miscellaneous manufac-
turing, nonelectrical machinery, and electrical machinery. Estimates for the
affected industries were published for 1948 under the old classification as well
as the new. The percent changes in the data on the old classification, from 1947
to 1948, were applied to the 1948 data on the new classification to get estimates
for 1947 on the new basis. These estimates were then adjusted to conform to
certain given totals. It was apparent that some error existed in the final esti-
mates. Therefore 1947 estimates for the affected industries are not as accurate
as those for subsequent years.
Wages and salaries are reported on an establishment basis and therefore need
no further adjustment before being used to obtain the cost indexes.
NET BUSINESS INCOME
Net business income was obtained by indirect methods. Table 1-10, "Income
and Output," provides estimates of national income originating in each industry.
The national income originating in an industry is the sum of net incomes originat-
ing within the industry. For manufacturing industries, the incomes originating
within an industry are wages and salaries, corporate profits, income of unincor-
porated business, and interest. We have combined the last three and called
them net business income. Therefore to obtain net business income, wages, and
salaries were simply subtracted from the reported national income.
The same reclassification problem exists in 1947 for national income as for
wages and salaries. The method used to obtain 1947 estimates was the same as
that described in the section above on wages and salaries.
Since profits and interest are reported on a company basis, rather than on an
establishment basis, the series obtained by subtracting wages and salaries from
national income must be adjusted before it can be used in the construction of the
cost indexes. Appendix B describes this adjustment.
54
PAGENO="0063"
PRICES AND COSTS IN MANuFACTURING INDUSTRIES 55
CAPITAL CONSUMPTION ALLOWANCES
Capital consumption allowances are made up of three parts: depreciation,
accidental damage, and capital outlays charged to current expense. Data on
these three items are not very reliable, and the final series on capital consump-
tion allowances must therefore be considered to be the least reliable of the four
basic components of gross product originating in each industry.
Corporate depreciation figures are published in table VI-18, "Income and
Output," but they were available only through 1956. Figures for. 1957 and
1958 were obtained by extrapolating the 1956 figures by the relative movements
of depreciation figures published in the Quarterly Financial Report of the Federal
Trade Commission and the Securities and Exchange Commission. The esti-
mates were then adjusted to conform to the totals for all manufacturing given
in "Income and Output." Noncorporate depreciation for each industry was
estimated by multiplying corporate depreciation by the ratio of noncorporate
sales to corporate sales; these estimates were then adjusted to conform with
published totals on noncorporate depreciation for all manufacturing.
Depreciation series were affected by the industry reclassification in 1948, and
the 1947 estimates were obtained as described in the section on wages and salaries
above.
Accidental damage to fixed capital is reported for all business in table V-i,
"Income and Output." These figures were in turn obtained for all manufac-
turing by Schultze for the study, "Prices, Costs and Output in the Postwar Period"
(Committee for Economic Development, Washington, D.C., 1960). The totals
for all manufacturing were distributed to individual manufacturing industries by
the percentage of net depreciable assets which each manufacturing industry had
of the total net depreciable assets of all manufacturing. The figures for net
depreciable assets were calculated from annual issues of the Statistics of Income,
U.S. Treasury Department. Since the Statistics of Income were available only
to 1956, and further, before 1954 depreciable assets were lumped with depletable
assets, the figures on depreciable assets were not very reliable. The use of depre-
ciable assets to determine the share of accidental damage is at best a very rough
estimating method. These shortcomings suggest that the final accidental damage
figures are not reliable. Fortunately, they are not a significantly large share
of costs.
Capital outlays charged to current expense are also given in table V-i, "Income
and Output," but only for all business. The totals for all manufacturing were
obtained by Schultze for his broader study (see above), and these totals were
distributed within manufacturing by using the percentage for each industry of
total annual expenditures on new plant and equipment within manufacturing.
The plant and equipment expenditures were provided by the Department of
Commerce. The use of these percentages was a purely arbitrary way of distribut-
ing a total figure. The basic series published in "Income and Output" is known
to be relatively poor. Hence the figures for the capital outlays charged to current
expense were probably the least reliable data used in this study. The saving
grace, however, is their small size and relative unimportance.
The sum of depreciation, accidental damage, and capital outlays charged to
current expense is the capital consumption allowance. Since all the data involved
in the estimates of these figures are reported on a company basis, the final series
must be adjusted to put the figures on an establishment reporting basis. See
appendix B for this step.
INDIRECT BUSINESS TAXES
* Indirect business taxes levied within manufacturing consist of certain Federal
excises, property taxes, and some other State and local taxes.
The Federal excises may be identified according to the type of product on which
they are levied and the level at which they are levied. The source of information
on these taxes was the Annual Report of the Secretary of the Treasury, 1958.
Some excises such as liquor and tobacco, pose no problems and are assigned to
the appropriate industry quite easily. Others such as excises on electric, gas, and
oil appliances, must be distributed between industries, and to a large extent this
was done on a personal judgment basis. Fiscal year data were shifted to calendar
years by averaging 2 fiscal years. The later year was weighted three-fourths
and the earlier year one-fourth because collections are reported with a lag of
about one quarter after they are actually made.
Property tax totals are reported for all business in table 111-2, "Income and
Output." These totals were broken down for all manufacturing by Schultze for
his broader study (see above). The distribution of the total for manufacturing
PAGENO="0064"
~6 PRICES AND COSTS ]~ MANtJFACTETRING INDUSTRIES
between manufacturing industries was made by using the percentage which each
industry owned of the total of certain types of assets for all manufacturing. The
assets used for this purpose were the sum of net depreciable assets, net depletable
assets, land, and one-half of total inventories. Inventories were included at only
half value because a few States do not tax inventories at all and in several others
inventories are taxed less heavily than other types of property. The asset figures
were taken from Statistics of Income, with 1957 and 1958 figures obtained by
graphic extrapolation.
The major part of other indirect taxes levied on manufacturing industries are
general business taxes. A total series of these taxes for manufacturing was
obtained by Schultze for his broader study (see above). Since many of these
taxes are levied on the basis of gross income, the totals for manufacturing were
distributed within manufacturing by using the percentage each industry had of
total manufacturing sales. Sales data for this purpose came from table VI-17,
"Income and Output," and from unpublished information provided by the De-
partment of Commerce.
Since Federal excises apply to commodities rather than companies, no adjust-
ment need be made for the reporting basis of the excises. Property taxes and
other general taxes, however, will need to be adjusted to put them on an estab-
lishment reporting basis. See appendix B for this step.
INDEX OF PHYSICAL OUTPUT
The basic output data required are output series indexes for each industry.
The four current dollar value series, when adjusted, will be data aggregated on an
establishment basis, classified according to the 1954 Standard Industrial Classi-
fication Manual, and will represent value added within each industry. The
output index must therefore be constructed on the basis of establishments classi-
fied according to the 1954 SIC, and each establishment's output should be weighted
according to its value added. Appropriate output indexes have been made
available by the Federal Reserve Board. Since they were constructed on a
different basis from the Board's regularly published series, they were made
available for calculation purposes, but not for subsequent publishing.
APPENDIX B
THE ADJUSTMENT OF AGGREGATES To CONVERT FROM A COMPANY REPORTING
BASIS TO AN ESTABLISHMENT REPORTING BASIS
In appendix A the sources and methods for obtaining the five basic series
needed for the construction of the cost indexes were described. The data for two
of these series and a component of a third are reported on a company basis while
the remainder are based on establishment data. In order for the five series to
be consistent with each other, an adjustment must be made in one group or the
other. Conceptually establishment data are more desirable than company data
because industry aggregates based on establishment data are closer to industries
defined according to the production of a given set of commodities than are aggre-
gates based on company data. Therefore the adjustments were made to shift
the series ba.sed on company data to an establishment basis rather than vice
versa.
Data reported on a company basis are all included in the industry to which the
largest share of the company's output belongs. Thus data for establishments
which should be classified in other industries will be included in the one industry
to which the company is assigned. The problem, then, is to identify what part
of a given industry aggregate belongs to establishments which should be classified
in other industries, and to which industries this share should be transferred. The
three series which need this correction are capital consumption allowances; net
business income, and the property and general State and local tax component of
indirect business taxes. Unfortunately, no information is, available for any, of
these series on an establishment basis. Therefore some other variable which is
correlated with these series and which is available on both an establishment and
company basis must be used to correct the series to an establishment basis. The
one set of data available for this purpose is employment. The U.S. Bureau of the
Census published this type of employment data in U.S. Censuses of Business,
Manufactures, and Mineral Industries: 1954, Bulletin CS-i, "Company Statis-
tics," (Washington, D.C., 1958). Table 3 of this bulletin provides employment
PAGENO="0065"
PRICES AND COSTS IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES 57
data cross-classified by industry of establishments a~d industry of companies for
the year 1954. With this table it is possible, for the year 1954, to determine
how many employees reported in an industry on a company basis should he trans-
ferred to other industries to arrive at totals based on an establishment classifica-
tion system.
The use of the census employment data to adjust for the company reporting
problem involves two assumptions which should be made explicit at the outset.
The first is that for any given industry, the net business income per employee,
capital consumption allowance per employee, and indirect business taxes per
employee are the same for all employees who are classified in the industry on an
establishment basis. If this is true, and if the three items per employee can be
estimated, the total amounts of each to be added or subtracted from the series
for a given industry will simply be the appropriate ratio times the number of
employees transferred into or out of the industry. The method for estimating
the necessary per employee ratios is explained below. The second assumption is
that the proportion of employees to be reclassified from one industry to another
was constant over the entire period under study. The validity of these two as-
sumptions is certainly open to question. It was felt, however, that corrections
made on the basis of these assumptions were far better than none at all. Such
corrections will indeed be rough, but they should be in the right direction and of
the correct magnitude.
The steps by which the corrections were made are as follows:
1. The ratios of net business income per employee, capital consumption per
employee, and the appropriate indirect business taxes per employee were esti-
mated by dividing each of the unadjusted series for an industry by the total
employment in the industry on an establishment basis. (Logically these ratios
should be estimated on the basis of the adjusted series. However, since the ad-
justed series are not available at the start, the unadjusted ones must be used as
the best possible approximation.) This procedure provides an estimate of the
per employee figures for each year for each series.
2. The numbers of employees to be transferred from each industry to each
other industry were calculated from table 3 of Bulletin CS-i. (Some figures
were omitted from the published table in order to avoid disclosure of individual
firm data. The Bureau of the Census kindly furnished the necessary figures in
such a way as to prevent disclosure but still be satisfactory for the adjusting
method used here.)
3. The number of employees to be transferred into a given industry was multi-
plied by the estimated per employee figures of capital consumption, etc. These
amounts were then added to the gaining industry and subtracted from the losing
industry. The resulting series were the adjusted capital consumption allowance,
net business income, and indirect business tax series.
The steps outlined above indicate the general procedure used. The corrections
were usually not applied, however, where the employment to be transferred was
less than one-half of 1 percent of the employment in the receiving industry.
There were also some corrections made by a different method in the primary
metals industry for the mining properties owned by companies classified in this
industry. Mining properties provide depletion allowances which cannot be cor-
rected for by the employment figures. The petroleum and coal products industry
data are particularly affected by mining property owned by companies classified
in the industry. There are practically no large petroleum refining companies
which do not own extensive crude oil-producing properties. It proved to be im-
possible to eliminate the effects of this type of property from the industry, and
is was therefore dropped from the cost behavior analysis.
Table B-i indicates the extent that adjustments were made in each industry.
This table shows the sum of the subtractions from each industry expressed as a
percent of the unadjusted gross product originating in the industry, and the
additions as a percent of gross product originating, both for the year 1954. Rubber
products required the greatest adjustment with a subtraction of 8.7 percent. This
industry has an important volume of business in the chemical, transportation
equipment, and retailing industries. Other industries requiring extensive adjust-
ments were chemicals and allied products, primary metals, instruments, and
electrical machinery. Manufacturing as a whole (excluding petroleum and coal
products) had a net subtraction of 0.42 percent. The bulk of the establishments
involved in this net subtraction were in wholesale trade, retail trade, mining.
and railroads.
PAGENO="0066"
58 PRICES AND COSTS IN MANETPACTUEING INDUSTRIES
TABLE B-1.-Percent of gross product originating subtracted from and added to
each industry to shift the basic series from company reporting basis to establishment
reporting basis, 1954
Industry
Percent
of imad-
justed
1954
gross
product
origin-
ating
sub-
,;racted
from-
Percent
of imad-
justed
1954
gross
product
origin-
ating
added
to-
Industry
Percent
of unad-
justed
1954
gross
product
origin-
ating
sub-
tracted
from-
Percent
of unad-
justed
1954
gross
product
origin-
ating
added
to-
Food and kindred products~~
Tobacco
Textile mill products
Apparel
Lumber and wood products
Furniture and fixtures
Paper and allied products
Chemicals and allied products
Rubber products
Leather and leather product&
Printing and publishing
0.67
.89
~
0.35
.19
.24
.67
1.26
2.50
Stone, clay, and glass prod-
ucts
Primary metals
Fabricated metals, ordnance....
Instruments
Miscellaneous manufacturing
Nonelectrical machinery
Electrical machinery
Transportation equipmenL
All manufacturing 1~....
.
0.78
1.50
2.21
3.08
2.65
1.93
.67
.29
99
2.04
.64
2.87
.
.75
2. 10
8.68
1.45
.21
4.20
2.31
1.41
1 Excludes petroleum and coal products.
0