PAGENO="0001"
87th Congress } JOINT COMMITTEE PRINT
~L ~L,f~r
10 ~L ~]1ttL ~1i~i-z~ ~t
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY
AND PRACTICE
SUBCOMMITTEE ON FOREIGN ECONOMIC POLICY
OF THE
JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE
CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES
Printed for the use of the Joint Economic Committee
U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE
76697 WASHINGTON: 1961
For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office
Washington 25, D.C. - Price 30 cents
(~ b~
PAGENO="0002"
JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE
(Created pursuant to sec. 5(a) of Public Law 304, 79th Cong.)
WRIGHT PATMAN, Texas, Chairman
PAUL H. DOUGLAS, Illinois, Vice Chairman
HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES SENATE
RICHARD BOLLING, Missouri JOHN SPARKMAN, Alabama
HALE BOGGS, Louisiana J. W. FULBRIGHT, Arkansas
HENRY S. REUSS, Wisconsin WILLIAM PROXMIRE, Wisconsin
MARTHA W. GRIFFITHS, Michigan CLAIBORNE PELL, Rhode Island
THOMAS B. CURTIS, Missouri PRESCOTT BUSH, Connecticut
CLARENCE E. KILBURN, New York JOHN MARSHALL BUTLER, Maryland
WILLIAM B. WIDNALL, New Jersey JACOB K. JAVITS, New York
War. SUMMERS Jom~soN, Executive Director
JOHN W. LEHMAN, Deputy Executive Director
RICHARD J. B~BER, Clerk
SUBCOMMITTEE ON FOREIGN ECONOMIC Poiic~
REPRESENTATIVE HALE Bo~os, Louisiana, Chairman
REPRESENTATIVE HENRY S. Rxuss, Wisconsin REPRESENTATIVE THOMAS B. CuRTIs, Missouri
SENATOR JOHN SPARKMAN, Alabama SENATOR PRESCOTT BUSH, Connecticut
SENATOR 1. W. FULBRIGHT, Arkansas SENATOR JACOB K. JAVITS, New York
SENATOR CLAIBORNE PELL, Rhode Island
II
~ *-~-4 ~
~
PAGENO="0003"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
By
Orro R. REISOHER
III
PAGENO="0004"
PAGENO="0005"
LETTERS OF TRANSMITTAL
NovEi~n~ER 21, 1961.
To the Members of the Joint Economic Comírn,ittee:
Tra.nsinittcd herewith for use of the Joint Economic Committee,
other Members of the Congress and the general public, is a study
paper titled "Trade Adjustment in Theory and Practice," by Dr.
Otto It Reischer.
It is believed that this paper will be especially useful to the mem-
bers of the Subcommittee on Foreign Economic Policy, and to the
witnesses who will be testifying before the subcommittee later this
year.
WRIGHT PATMAN,
Chairman, Joint Economic Committee.
NOVEMBER 21, 1961.
Hon. WRIGHT PATMAN,
Chairman, Joint Economic Committee,
U.S. Congress, Washington, D.C.
D~R Mit. CHAIRMAN: Transmitted herewith is a study pa~per titled
"Trade Adjustment in Theory and Practice" which has been pre-
pared by Otto B. Reischer, and submitted for the use of the Subcom-
mittee on Foreign Economic Policy, in connection with its present
review of our foreign economic policy.
Dr. Reischer is a consulting economist, practicing in Washington,
D.C. He has taught economics at Rutgers University, the University
of British Columbia, Michigan State University and the University
of Virginia, arid has served as a consultant to the Pan American
Union.
I believe that the present study paper provides valuable inforina-
tion which will be useful to other Members of Congress and to the
general public.
Sincerely,
HALE BOGOS,
Chairman, Subcommittee on Foreign Economic Policy.
V
PAGENO="0006"
PAGENO="0007"
CON TENTS
Chapter
I. Introduction: The significance of adjusting to increased competitive Ps~s
imports 1
II. Economic and public policy aspects of trade adjustment 3
Unassisted versus assisted readjustment 3
Economic aspects of trade adjustment 5
The public policy aspects of trade adjustment 6
The gain from trade adjustment 7
The probable dimension of trade adjustment 9
III. Foreign examples of readaptation 13
Readaptation in Benelux 13
The European Coal and Steel Community and readaptation..~ 14
Readaptation and European Common Market 15
Evaluation is
IV. Previous contributions to the discussion of trade adjustment 19
Staley and the problem of compensation 19
The Bell report 21
David J. McDonald and the Randall report 22
Congressional proposals for trade adjustment 23
Summary and evaluation 25
V. Organizational and administrative aspects of a trade adjustment
program 27
Criteria for application 27
Freer trade as cause of injury 27
Extent of injury and appropriate assistance 29
Administrative considerations 29
The case for a program centered on the individual firm.. - - 29
Financing the program 30
Proposed sources and methods 30
Readjustment equalization fund 30
Earmarking customs revenue 31
Accelerated amortization 31
Loans by the Small Business Administration 31
Outline of a trade adjustment program 35
Functions of cooperating agencies 36
How the program would operate 38
VT. Trade adjustment in manufacturing: The glove industry in Fulton
County, N.Y 41
The leather glove industry in Fulton County 41
The domestic leather glove industry 42
The cut and sewn fabric glove industry 44
The seamless knit glove industry 44
Domestic consumption 45
Import competition 45
Alternatives for Fulton County 47
Unassisted adjustment measures 48
An illustrative trade adjustment program 50
Comparative cost of trade adjustment 53
VII. Trade adjustment in agriculture: Woolgrowing 57
Imports versus domestic wool production 57
The U.S. woolgrowing industry 58
Competition from manmade fibers 60
Domestic wool programs since World War IT 60
The tariff on wool 63
The National Wool Acts of 1954 and 1958 65
The Wool Act and tariff protection 67
"Defense essentiality" of woolgrowing versus stockpiling 68
Readjustment in woolgrowing 70
A program of assisted readjustment 71
The cost of trade adjustment 73
VII
PAGENO="0008"
~rm Co rs
Chapter Page
VIII. Trade adjustment in mining: The lead-zinc mining industry 77
The industry's need for readju~tn~ent~~;_ 77
Structure of industry..~~'~ - -~ -~-~ 78
Prices, reserves, and substitutes 79
Labor cost and employmèñt sensitivity 80
Imports and consumption 82
The escape elause investigations 83
Features of a trade adjustment program 86
Another proposal 88
Readjustment of miners 89
Conclusion 90
Appendix: Proposed remedies other than trade restrictions____ 91
The premium-price plan 91
Stockpiling 91
International buffer stocks 92
Bibliography
PAGENO="0009"
TRAI)E ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
CHAPTER I
INTRODUCTION: THE SIGNIFICANCE OF READJUSTING
TO INCREASED COMPETITIVE IMPORTS
This study examines various methods designed to minimize eco-
nomic dislocations caused by increased competitive imports; the desir-
ability of greater freedom of trade is taken for granted.
Withdrawal of tariff protection from an industry often entails
severe losses to groups or individuals. Such losses are open to ob-
jection on social grounds, even though they result from a decision of
the Government taken in the national interest. But these losses may
also give rise to political opposition which can prevent or delay trade
liberalization. Much could be gained, therefore, if it were possible
to remove these objections to a policy shift from protection to adapta-
tion by providing adjustment assistance to producers who, despite
efficient operations, have suffered, or are being threatened with, seri-
ous injury from competitive imports.
Attrition of an industry due to general technological progress is
not the same as damage inflicted on that industry by intensified im-
port competition resulting from lowered trade barriers. In the
latter case the damage results from a policy decision of the Govern-
ment taken in the national interest-national in the sense that matters
of trade and tariff policy are of a nationwide rather than regional,
sectional, or local character. In following through this policy deci-
sion, the Federal Government may be expected to assume responsibility
for mitigating some of these immediately adverse consequences of
freer trade.
In the domestic economy of a free society like our own, where
market forces are given reasonable play, technical progress tends to
be equated with the "law of the market"-the operation of impersonal
economic forces to which producers have to submit or perish. The
Government is charged with keeping these forces operating at home
and fosters them through antitrust and antimonopoly legislation and
controls. The Government also is obliged to desist from directly in-
fluencing technical progress except in an upward direction. It assists
such progress by issuing patents and undertaking research activities,
public works and other forms of assistance.
In the area of foreign trade, however, the "law of the market" only
rarely has been given free rein. Here market forces still are hemmed
in by many restrictive devices dating back to a period when such
restrictions were in fact beneficial on a nationwide basis, and when
stable markets had to be secured for many of this country's infant
1
PAGENO="0010"
2 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
industries. Behind the shield of tariffs, industries have grown up
over the years, investments have been sunk in plant and equipment,
and prosperous businesses have been built up.1
Though firms within an industry differ in their ability to cope with
new developments and new types of competition, domestic competi-
tion has had to be accepted as the law of the land, with a tradition
going back many generations. But foreign competition has not had
to be accepted, at least not until fairly recently. Foreign manufac-
turers are not covered by our legislation on labor standards and re-
straint of trade. Against their competition the tariff and other trade
restrictions have been an effective shelter, not available against an
industry's domestic competitors.2
Economic progress in a free society cannot be dissociated from com-
petition, and no cushioning is needed or desirable. In the foreign
trade field, however, equity requires that the impact of a Government
policy decision leading to increased import competition be accom-
panied by a policy to facilitate adjustments and minimize injury suf-
fered by industries deprived of their accustomed shield against com-
petitive imports.
The Government's objective in safeguarding competition on the
domestic scene is to increase the general welfare; the same objective
underlies the decision to increase competition in foreign trade. The
objective would be realized in the long run (total adaptation) through
the benefits from specialization according to the doctrine of compara-
tive advantage. In the short run (partial adaptation) it would be
achieved as a result of the stimulus of competition and of concessions
obtained from our trading partners. In both instances, it may be
noted, American exports are increased.
Withdrawal of protection from an industry accustomed to rely on
it may contribute to the demise of a certain number of firms in that
industry. Their number will vary in proportion to the measures they
themselves take' and the opportunity the Government gives them to
make a satisfactory adjustment to the new competitive situation.3
No firm or industry is entitled to a blanket dispensation from hav-
ing to adjust its operations to changes in its economic environment.
But the Government, by removing safeguards against injury from
foreign competition which it had provided initially, incurs, as a matter
of equity, an obligation to provide some form of assistance to these
firms and industries now unable to make a satisfactory adaptation on
their own. Increased competition from abroad is a relatively small
matter compared with disturbances in the home market due to tech-
nological and other changes. The `burden of that new obligation
should therefore be rather small.4
1 As Don D. Humphrey has said, "A case for assistance to those who are seriously
injured by imports can be made on economic grounds alone; the injury results from a
basic change in America's historic policy of protectionism." American Imports, New
York, 1955, p. 482.
2 See also Bidwell, Percy W., "What the Tariff Means to `American Industries," New
York 19~6, p. 264.
8 If the Government were to relay, or abolish provisions of its antitrust and anti-
monopoly structure on the domestic side, it would similarly have to assume responsibility
for helping smaller business units to survive by other means, either by finding ways of
supporting them directly, or by making It possible for them to merge Into larger and more
viable units.
For a fuller discussion of this point see Salant, Walter S., and vaccara, Beatrice N.,
"Import Liberalization and Employment: The Effects of Unilateral Reductions in United
States Import Barriers." Washington, D.C., 1961.
PAGENO="0011"
CHAPTER II
ECONOMIC AND PUBLIC POLICY ASPECTS OF TRADE
ADJUSTMENT
Economic dislocations as a rule have more than one cause. If an
industry is suffering in some degree from foreign competition, it is
also suffering from a much larger array of ailments. Changed con-
ditions of domestic demand or new sources of domestic supply often
create the basic problem. But the processes of adjustment are similar,
regardless of whethei~ the dislocation stems from domestic or foreign
causes.
UNASSISTED VERSUS ASSISTED READJUSTMENT
Two general types of readaptation can be distinguished: unassisted
readaptation, and readaptation aided by government.
Unassisted readaptation may entail cost reduction, diversification
of production, market research, and importing. In industries pro-
ducing standardized commodities for a wide market, such as electrical
manufacturing, chemicals, and iron and steel, opportunities for cost
reduction are easily found.1 But even in small-scale manufacturing,
cost reductions are found possible, through time and motion studies,
for example. In general, however, import-sensitive industries may
find more help in competing with foreign firms by analyzing consum-
er demand more carefully, and determining the changed character-
istics of the market. Developing of new designs has been helpful,
too.
Diversification has been another way firms have taken in adapting
themselves to changed competitive situations. In the present context,
this has meant branching out into lines not subject to import com-
petition. But successful selection of new products requires detailed
studies of market possibilities and production techniques, and not all
firms suffering from import competition command the necessary
financial resources and managerial skills to undertake the studies and
apply the findings.
For producers of labor-intensive commodities unable to reduce costs
to the level of competitors in low-wage countries making identical
goods, the only solution has been in offering something distinctive,
which usually has meant something more expensive.2
There are many interesting examples of successful adaptation to
rising foreign competition in the wake of tariff concessions. Manu-
facturers of bicycles turned to competitive models. They also use
their facilities in the off-season for making other products-lawn-
1 See Bidweil, Percy W., "What the Tariff Means to American Industries," New York,
1956, p. 265.
2 Steuben Glass, for example, has become relatively immune to foreign competition be-
cause of concentrating on glass products of the highest quality. Lenox China Is In a
similar position. See Bidwell, op. cit., p. 266.
3
PAGENO="0012"
4 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRA(~'rIcE
mowers, air-conditioning apparatus, equipment for gas stations and
so on. Some woolen and worsted mills make automobile fabrics as
well as apparel cloth; others are producing synthetic and blended
fabrics. Manufacturers of hand-fashioned glass have begun to turn
out Fiberglas. Manufacturers of fine household china also make hotel
ware. And watch companies in addition to defense items are making
watch cases and bracelets, men's jewelry, and electronic apparatus.
Producers of import-sensitive goods often have taken to selling
imported goods to improve their position. Some watch manufac-
turers also are importers of Swiss watch movements, which they case
and sell under their own or another trade name. Several bicycle
manufacturers have made arrangements with foreign firms to mar-
ket their products in the United States. American producers of dye-
stuffs also are engaged in importing. For, while the manufacturer is
mainly interested in turning out the goods himself, importing as a
sideline provides him with a more complete line of products, includ-
ing items which can be procured more cheaply abroad than produced
at home.
But unassisted readaptation may not always be enough for coping
with a changed competitive situation. When, for example, an im-
port-sensitive industry has been the sole or predominant source of em-
ployment in a community, a tariff reduction may push an already
weak producer to the brink of disaster. This may not be a tariff
problem pure and simple, for overspecialization too would have made
the community vulnerable to any sudden change, whether of domestic
or foreign origin. Whatever the cause, the remedy in these cases
would be to broaden the industrial base and thereby create new op-
portunities for employment.
From the point of view of the workers, even a successful diversifi-
cation program may involve considerable hardship.3 Labor is
far from being perfectly mobile. Older workers in particular lack
the inclination and the ability to find employment in other industries.
Workers who do not move suffer losses in earnings because of down-
grading in skill classification. And many a new job may be less
satisfactory than the old.
To cope with such difficulties is in the first instance the respon-
sibihty of both management and labor in the affected industry, and
of State and local authorities. But since such efforts often are in-
adequate, the Federal Government tends to assume responsibifity
for providing help, and has done so in the past. In fact, our Federal
social security and unemployment assistance programs are reflections
of that tendency, as is the recently adopted depressed area program.
The thesis of this study is that more should be done.
Advocates of freer trade deny that the higher American wage scale
makes this country more vulnerable to import competition originating
in low-wage countries, since higher wages in our industries reflect
higher productivity, and are therefore no indication of higher unit
costs. However, this superiority holds true chiefly for standardized
commodities which are turned out in quantity by mass production
methods.'
$ See, e.g., National Planning Association, "Depressed Induetrial Areas-A National
Problem," Planning Pamphlet N~o. 98, WashIngton, D.C.. January l9~7, p.7.
`See also Bidwell, op. cit., pp. 283-284.
PAGENO="0013"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 5
In producing such commodities, heavy investment of capital makes
possible much larger output per worker per hour than in foreign
plants not so well equipped.5 But relatively high wages in this coun-
try tend to be a serious handicap to low-capital producers in import-
sensitive industries. The basic difficulty of these industries, however,
is not the low wages paid abroad. Rather, it is the high competing
wages paid by other American industries, based on the high level of
productivity in American industry. The goods we export are pro-
duced by our most productive highest wage industries.°
No industry stands by itself in competition with foreign suppliers.
Its changing cost structure vis-a-vis the cost structures of foreign
competitors is to a major extent a reflection, indeed a function, of the
changing cost patterns of the national economy in which it operates.
Adaptation to increased imports is not an isolated phenomenon but a
facet of the general process of economic adaptation and growth. One
significant feature of this type of adjustment is that it represents a
point of convergence of domestic and foreign economic policy. This
brings us to the public policy aspects of assisted readjustment which
will be discussed after a brief review of its economic aspects.
ECONOMIC ASPECTS OP TRADE ADJUSTMENT
The economic objective of assisted readjustment is to soften or
spread out the impact on domestic producers of an increase in competi-
tive imports resulting from freer trade. A major prerequisite of a
workable adjustment program will be to convince these producers of
the usefulness of making an adjustment. This prerequisite would be
met by offering those American businessmen who bear the brunt of
intensified import competition a program consistent with the free-
enterprise system and which allows them to continue to exercise their
managerial prerogatives. Such a program would include financial
assistance and technical advice, but no detailed guidelines or prescrip-
tions. Moreover, the program should be optional, and offered as an
alternative to methods currently used for relieving injury resulting
from freer trade, with appropriate administrative safeguards. Var-
ious types of assistance thus made available to businesses as and
where needed would help them to carry the burden of the required
adaptation.
Assistance in adjustment to economic change is intended to increase
flexibility and mobility, not as compensation for injury. Greater flex-
ibility and mobility are desirable in themselves, quite apart from any
reductions in trade barriers with which adjustment assistance may be
associated. Adjustment assistance also can be made preventive rather
than remedial. It can be made available to those who merely expect
to be (or face a threat of being) injured so that they may act before
injury occurs.7
5American electrical manufacturers and chemical producers, for example, are not
troubled by foreign competition with respect to the bulk of their products. They are
sensitive to competitive imports only in a few specialties-such as heavy hydroelectric
equipment and batch-process dyes. For technical reasons these and other items cannot be
mass-produced and consequently require a large input of highly paid labor.
0 has been shown that American export industries tend to pay higher wages than
import-competing industries; in fact, they have done so for over half a century. See
Kravis, Irving B~, "Wages and Foreign Trade," Review of Economics and Statistics, vol.
XXXVIII, No. 1 (February 195~e), p. 14.
See also statement by Walter S. Salant, ~rook1ngs Instiutlon, in "Foreign Trade
Policy," Hearings before the Subcommittee on Foreign Trade Policy of the Committee on
Ways and Means, House of Representatives, 85th Cong., 1st sess., pursuant to H. Res. 104
(Washington 1058), pp 577.-~78.
PAGENO="0014"
6 TRADE ADJTTSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
From the viewpoint of the economy as a whole it seems best to
focus such a program on the individual business firm immediately
affected by increased imports. Workers and communities are affected
by such imports less directly; their injury is a function of the extent
to which the business firms employing the workers, or situated in the
communities, fail to make the necessary adaptation.
Trade liberalization generally is more likely to take place when
there is little resistance to moves of that sort, e.g., in times of com-
parative prosperity, when workers can shift without too much dull-
culty to jobs similar to those they had been doing before being dis-
located. If necessary7 workers can be given preference in existing
public welfare and assistance facilities. Larger enterprises in general
can be counted on to make necessary adjustments in operations with-
out assistance. There would remain only the smaller business units
to be looked after. A comprehensive adjustment program could
then be devised for every type of industry.
The true test of a readjustment program would be the real economic
gain it could produce through a shift of resources to more profitable
employment. That gain is difficult to measure. Parts of it are quan-
tifiable in money terms. Other parts defy that kind of measurement,
being widely diffused through the economy.
THE PUBLIC POLICY ASPECT OF TRADE ADJTTST}[ENT
Public policy enters into a program of assisted readjustment by
virtue of the fact that through such a program the Government could
insulate problems of foreign economic policy, of which tariff and
trade policy is one variety, from dome$tic economic policy problems
created by trade liberalization. Separating the effects of govern-
mental action in the two areas would allow greater freedom of move-
ment as well as greater precision in achieving the respective policy
objectives.
At home, the major policy problem is to keep competition at least
workable by preventing undue increases in concentration of economic
power. Small units have to be kept from being pushed to the wall,
and economic self-reliance among entrepreneurs is to be fostered.
In the domestic policy area also, the Government has to face a
problem pertaining to the national security. It has to decide which
industries and what portion of the labor force are important enough
from a defense standpoint to be kept at their current tasks despite
relatively and often uneconomically high costs.
The problem of national security also arises in the field of foreign
economic policy, where we strive to maintain mutually beneficial eco-
nomic relations with allied nations. To maintain these relations
requires eventual achievement of relatively unrestricted trade. As a
condition for fulfilling this requirement, this country will have to
accept a sizable increase in the volume of imports. Since existing
trade barriers in general are still too high to permit such an increase
the Government is endeavoring to lower barriers accordingly. As a
result, certain domestic industries are already suffering injury from
increased import competition despite existing safeguards, and more
industries are likely to do so before this particular policy objective is
attained. The industries injured are mostly those who in some way had
PAGENO="0015"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 7
geared their operations to the existence of certain types of protection-
to sustaining intervention by Government.
Continuance of such protection would mean, of course, that these
industries would go on receiving indirect Government subsidies. The
number of producers of those industries' products would be limited
by virtue of a partial or total exclusion of foreign goods. And the
price of the goods produced domestically would be kept substantially
higher than if producers were subjected to competitive pressure from
more freely admitted foreign goods.
The Government faces a dilemma in having to deal simultaneously
with relatively inadequate competition at home (in the absence of
advantageously priced imports), and excessive competition from
abroad (from the viewpoint of national interest, that is). The
dilemma cannot be resolved so long as the Government has to rely
on trade restrictions, or sustaining intervention, as the only technique
available for ordering these two conflicting tendencies. Whenever
it now wishes to stop excessive foreign competition, the Government
is forced, as it were, to pour out the baby with the bathwater: it
can indeed curtail foreign competition, ~et at the same time domestic
competition is also weakened. If the Government adopted the tech-
nique of adaptive intervention, in conjunction with a tariff reduction,
the baby would be lifted out of the bath before the tub is emptied,
and the result would be greater precision in policy implementation:
policy makers could then achieve the objectives of liberal trade policy
without any paralyzing concern for protected home industries.
Obliged for once to make adjustments to freer trade and increased
competitive imports, these industries could then be granted assistance
on a temporary basis during a transition period.
A trade adjustment program thus provides the Government with a
tool for separating decisionmaking in the domestic economic sphere
from decisionmaking in the foreign economic sphere. Once the con-
cept of readjustment assistance is accepted, the Government can deal
with requirements of protection for domestic industries in isolation
from requirements of foreign economic policy. And consideration of
the one need not be distorted by consideration of the other, and vice
versa.
A Federal program of assisted adaptation would also have consid-
erable political usefulness. If the appropriate legislation were passed,
it would be easier for many Congressmen who, although convinced
that freer trade is in the national interest, nevertheless have protected
industries in their districts, to vote for tariff reduction. They would
then better be able to face their protection-minded constituents by
pointing to the existence of and the advantages offered by the trade
adjustment programs.
THE GAIN FROM TRADE ADJUSTMENT
Increased adaptabiZity
Assisted readjustment to increased competitive imports basically
aims at increasing the adaptability of this country's industrial struc-
ture to changed world trade conditions.
implicit in greater adaptability is a better aflocM ion of domestic
resources. Spurred by a lowering of trade barriers, the domestic
PAGENO="0016"
8 TRADE AThTUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
economy would gain in strength as marginal producers in import-
sensitive industries are impelled to switch to other and more profitable
pursuits. As imports rise, and assuming that other countries also
lower trade restrictions, there would appear a tendency for exports to
increase in payment for imports This increase in exports would be
a reflection of stronger foreign demand for specific American goods,
such as products of the automotive and engineering industries, for
example This increased foreign demand will cause more resources
to be attracted into existing and into new export industries, the latter
springing up as new needs and opportunities are discovered in foreign
markets Foreign mvestment opportunities also would multiply, and
domestic resources, especially capital goods, will be absorbed by such
investments With progressive easing of multilateral trading re-
strictions, the effect of freer trade will also be felt in the less specialized
export industries, those which hitherto may have produced almost
exclusively for the home market With the increase in opporthmties
created by these developments, marginal producers initially displaced
by greater import competition should find adaptation not beyond their
reach, especially if appropriate assistance is made available
With obstacles to freer trade being removed gradually and in con-
)unctlon with appropriate programs of assisted adaptation-other
things remaining equal-a process of economic expansion will get
underway at home and abroad As expansion of production and trade
continues over time, it may be possible for the Government to reduce
its expenditures for various types of foreign economic assistance in-
cluding military aid.
Foreign economic aid-in the absence of any significant freeing of
trade that would' allow an increase in the volume of goods exchanged
between the United States and aid-recipient countries-may be con-
sidered as a concealed subsidy to certain groups of domestic pro-
ducers. This subsidy serves to support those marginal elements of
American industry that would stand to suffer from increased foreign
competition. Such support is granted at the taxpayers' expense. If
these marginal producers could adapt themselves to a new competi-
tive situation involving the freer admittance of foreign goods, with
or without assistance from the Government, certain industries in
the aid-recipient countries could increase their exports to the United
States. To the extent that these foreign producers would be able to
take advantage of relaxed American protection, they could contri-
bute to the prosperity of their own countries, with the result that the
need for further substantial foreign aid may be lessened, with cor-
responding reductions in U.S. outlays.
A good deal of U.S. foreign aid has taken the form of orders
placed with a foreign country's capital goods industries for produc-
tion of weapons and materiel. Various national engineering and
related industries have been strengthened in that way. When at some
future point in time the present danger should subside, these national
industries may be expected to continue producing durable goods, but
of a nonmilitary character. If the respective internal market should
prove too small for keeping these industries busy, they will seek out-
lets for their products in world markets. These efforts in the first
instance will generate sustained pressure for freer trade on a global
basis. With greater productive capacity all around, the need for
PAGENO="0017"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 9
greater international specialization and division of labor will increase
in proportion. If by the time this need becomes urgent Americn
trade policy should prove not flexible enough to cope with it (in part
for the reason of not having adopted a policy of assisted adaptation of
marginal segments of import-sensitive industries) another foreign-
aid program, but of vastly greater dimensions, may have to be devised.
A seemingly unending vicious spiral threatens to emerge as seen
from the simplified sequence of measures and conceivable counter-
measures which follows: The military buildup in countries friendly
to the United States continues for a time, with assistance from this
country. A detente with the Soviet bloc is then assumed to set in.
Armament industries in countries friendly to the United States then
revamp operations and exert pressure for more exports. American
trade policy, however, continues unchanged in a moderately restric-
tive vein (without a policy of assisted adaptation). The friendly
countries thereupon retaliate by discriminating against American
exports. At the same time they begin suffering from unemployment
in their overgrown durable goods industries. One unfavorable de-
velopment brings forth another. The economies of these countries
become unstable, and one* more economic aid from the the United
States becomes indispensable.8 The next move would be up to the
Soviet bloc. With a renewed tightening of the international situa-
tion, the spiral goes into another turn, and U.S. economic aid once
more is supplemented or transformed into military aid and "defense
support."9 With successful and rapid adaptation to economic change
this repetitive succession of events might be prevented.
THE PROBABLE DIMENSION OF TRADE ADJUSTMENT
Available evidence suggests that the extent of the readjustment
problem will be much smaller than commonly expected. One reason
for this is that the aggregate area of displacement of domestic pro-
duction by imports is likely to be quite small in comparison with the
national economy as a whole.'°
Shifts in production and marketing practices take time.'1 Foreign
products not only must compete pricewise with domestic products
after paying freight and other charges, but must also conform to
established tastes, and appropriate channels of distribution must be
developed for them. Owing to these requirements, whatever read-
justments by domestic producers must be executed can be made gradu-
ally, even if rates of duties were reduced more rapidly than, for ex-
ample, at a rate of 5 percent per year.
Given unimpeded economic progress at home and abroad, there
need be no fear lest resources freed by marginal enterprises not be
taken up by others, such as business firms benefiting from an expan-
sion in production for exports.'2
8 Changes can be rung on this sequence of developments by varying the assumed rela-
tive position of the aid-recipient country vis-a-vis the United States.
~ existence of thermonuclear imbalances and of "missile gaps" adds to the grimeness
of the prospect.
10 See Salant, Walter S., and Vaccara, Beatrice N., "Import Liberalization and Em-
ployment: The Effects of Unilateral Reductions in United States Import Barriers,"
Washington, D.C., 19~1.
"In this connection, see the discussion pertaining to Western European integration
In Hulley, John, "Protect or CompensateS" World Politics, April 1958, especially pp. 320
See in this connection, Hinrichs, A. Ford, "Iowa and World Trade: An Economic
Analysis of the First Congressional District of Iowa." Washington, D.C., 1054.
76697-61---2
PAGENO="0018"
10 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
In a recent investigation concerning the qualitative effect of a con-
ceivable tariff reduction in eight American industries,13 on the as-
sumption that the reduction would be gradual and would not be
undertaken in a period of general unemployment and falling national
income, it was found that lower import duties would affect large-scale
manufacturers only peripherally. Certain small-scale industries,
though, with a high ratio of labor costs to total manufacturing costs,
in some cases aggravated by declining markets, appear to be marginal
from the standpoint of the American industry as a whole. Within
these marginal industries, increased imports would hit marginal firms
hardest. But tariff changes in general do not determine whether or
not an entire industry will survive or disintegrate; they determine
oniy the dimensions of the industry. And any lowering of tariff
duties on commodities which are sensitive to import competition is a
selective process in which only the fringes of an industry-the mar-
ginal firms-are cut off.
The small dimension of readaptation is matched by its probable
low cost in real terms. The real cost of using resources in any given
line of production is the return foregone by what these resources
would yield in other lines. The real cost to the economy of not shift-
ing resources from marginal firms in import-sensitive industries ap-
pears to be substantial. Conversely, the real cost of a readjustment
program in terms of production sacrificed because of a reallocation
of resources would be comparatively small. Besides, this small cost
will be offset and exceeded, after a reasonable period of time, by the
multiplier effect inherent in successful readaptation.14
To sum up, the case for adjustment assistance in instances of disloca-
tion by increased competitive imports may be restated briefly. Read-
justment assistance can be advocated on two grounds: it benefits the
economy through freer trade and better allocation of resources, and
it solves the short-term problems that such shifts entail. The fact that
freer trade benefits the economy is generally accepted. Since read-
justment assistance would facilitate acceptance of imports, it would
tend to promote removal of trade restrictions. And since assisted re-
adaptation in the face of increased import competition may be ex-
pected to reduce opposition to a further lowering of trade barriers,
a readjustment program becomes that much more desirable.
Past opposition to assisted readjustment has concentrated on two
points: the administrative complications of the program, and its re-
dundancy in the presence of a gradual lowering of tariff duties. It
has been held that a readjustment assistance program could not possi-
bly be instituted without very great difficulties of implementation.
To this objection it may be replied that a simple program can be de-
vised that would be no more cumbersome than current measures of
protection, and possibly much less so.15
~ BIdwell, Percy W., "What the Tariff Means to American Industries," New York,
1956, pp. 280-288.
14 On the working of this multiplier, see, for example, Hildebrand, George H., and
Mace, Arthur, Jr~ "The Employment Multiplier in an Expanding Industrial Market: Los
Angeles County,, 1940-47," `Review of Economics and Statistics," vol. XXXII, No. 3
(August 1950), pp. 241r-249; Federal Reserve Bank, Kansas City, "The Employment Mul-
tiplier in Wichita," its Monthly Review, Sept. 30, 1952, pp. 1-7; and Federal Reserve Bank.
Boston, "What Happens When a Community Gains Manufacturing Jobs," its Monthly
Review, March 1955, pp. 1-6.
15 See below; and also Clubb, Bruce E., and Reischer, Otto R., "The Trade Adjustment
Bills: Their Purpose and Efficacy," Columbia Law RevIew, March 1961, pp. 490-503.
PAGENO="0019"
TRADE ADJIJSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 11
It has also been asserted that with a gradual lowering of tariff
rates there would be no need to bother with governmental aid in
adaptation, since under such circumstances the necessary changes in
the industrial structure would take place anyway. The answer to this
objection is, that even in a situation like the preseiit, when there exists
legislation providing for a gradual decrease of tariff duties over a
number of years, there is still a great deal of opposition to a freeing of
trade, to judge from testimony before congressional committees study-
ing our trade policy, and from the number of applications for relief
from competitive imports processed by the Tariff Commission. There-
fore, even with a gradual reduction of tariff duties, a comparatively
simple trade adjustment program, that cuts down resistance to
increased imports, would enhance the boon to economic progress.16
`~ Attitudes of prospective beneficiaries from the program admittedly will vary. But it
seems likely that a successful assistance program would fare like other innovations:
accepted only by a few at first, it would later be taken for granted by the community at
large.
PAGENO="0020"
PAGENO="0021"
CHAPTER III
FOREIGN EXAMPLES OF READAPTATION
Readaptation to economic change is not a new phenomenon, nor is
the idea peculiarly suited to the United States alone. In Europe, in
the course of steps being taken toward economic integration, readapta-
tion has been adopted as an essential corollary to the program of
changing national market and industrial structures of the participants
in the Benelux Economic Union, the European Coal and Steel Coin-
munity, and the European Common Market. This chapter gives a
quick survey of some of the relevant provisions and a short evalua-
tion of the program's operation.
READAPTATION IN BENELUX
Benelux was formally started in the fall of 1944 with the signing
of a customs convention between Holland and the Belgium-Luxem-
bourg Economic Union. But not for almost a decade was it felt
necessary to assist firms which had to carry the main burden of ad-
justing to changes in the policy of protection against foreign compe-
tition.' In 1953 agreement was reached on setting up a joint readapta-
tion fund designed to provide temporary financial help to such firms
with a view to raising their productivity.2 A capital fund was set
up, subscribed in equal halves by the Netherlands Government, and
by the Governments of Belgium and Luxembourg. It provided loans
to the affected industries to help them make the necessary adjust-
ments. It was also agreed that the proceeds from any special charges
levied on the trade among the three Benelux countries as a means for
temporary protection (other than on agricultural products) should be
paid into the Benelux Fund for Readaptation. The functions of the
Fund, as prescribed by article 2 of the agreement, must not include
direct subsidies to the enterprises eligible for assistance, but rather
special readaptation credits, at low rates of interest. The Fund is
also empowered to finance studies and research tending toward an
amalgamation of certain of the affected enterprises with a view to in-
creasing their productivity.3
The agreement on the Readaptation Fund was preceded by an
agreement signed at The Hague on July 24, 1953, which among other
matters dealt with the problem of granting special temporary as-
sistance to particular branches of industry which might be badly hit by
the processes of adjustment required from time to time by the main-
`Robertson, W., "Benelux and Problems of Economic Integration," Oxford Economic
Papers, N.S., vol. 8, No. 1 (February 1956), p. 50.
2The agreement was signed in Brussels on Nov. 16, 1953, but not ratified for another 3
years. For the text of the agreement, see "Moniteur Belge," Aug. 12, 1956, pp. 5416-5418.
See also Meade, James E., "Negotiations for Benelux: An Annotated Chronicle, 1943-SO"
Princeton Studies in International Finance, No. 6, 1957, p. 66.
8 "Moniteur Belge," bc. cit.
13
PAGENO="0022"
14 TRADE ADJTISTMENT IN THEORY AND PRAC'l'IcE
tenance of overall domestic and external balance. This protocol in-
cludes specific criteria governing the granting of aid.4
In order to be eligible, the firm's production must have been reduced
by a given amount in any 6-month period relative to its level in the
corresponding period of the previous 2 years, as a result of increased
imports from one of the partner countries; or the imports of the com-
peting product from one of the partner countries must have increased
in any 6-month period by a given amount relative to their imports in
the corresponding period of the previous 2 years. Provision is also
made in the protocol to give on the one hand some temporary protec-
tion in special circiunstances to an industry which does not meet these
criteria, and on the other hand to withhold such protection, though
warranted by the criteria, if granting it would impose too severe a
burden on the export industry of the partner country. Any measures
of protection are to be temporary, and their permitted duration is to
be announced at the time the measures are instituted. Every 6 months
an examination is made to see whether the continuation of protective
measures is still necessary. Cases of dispute are subjected to com-
pulsory arbitration.5
THE EUROPEAN COAL AND STEEL COMMUNITY AND READAPTAPION
Section 23 of the Convention on Transitional Provisions applicable
to the treaty setting up the European Coal and Steel Community°
allows the High Authority to place funds at the disposal of govern-
ments and firms to deal with unemployment and to organize readap-
tation of laid-off workers, and also to help financing of government-
approved conversion programs to rehire such workers. Intervention
is limited to firms that have been put out of business or compelled to
change their activities as a result of the establishment of the. Common
Market for Coal and Steel.7 This power was granted for the first 5
years of the Common Market only, although it can be extended for
another 2 years by decision of the High Authority, with approval of
the Council of Ministers.8
Article 56 of the treaty grants similar power of intervention for
the duration of the treaty. These powers may be exercised by the High
Authority whenever the introduction of technical processes or new
equipment leads to an exceptionally large reduction in labor require-
ments in the coal and steel industries of the member countries, and
which would make it difficult for certain areas to reemploy the work-
ers displaced by these developments. The powers under this clause
appear to give the High Authority considerable latitude, but they
have not been implemented during the transition period.9
~ Meade, op. cit., p. 65.
`Robertson, bc. cit., p. 34.
0 See ECSC Information Bulletin, July-August 1956, p. 9.
The transition period of the Common Market for Coal and Steel was set from Feb. 10,
1953, to Feb. 1.0, 1958.
S For actions taken under this provision, particularly with regard to the marginal Belgian
coal mines of the Borinage, and the Sulcis mines on Sardinia, Bee, for example, "Fifth
General Report on the Activities of the Community" (Luxembourg, Apr. 13. 1957), pp.
168-177; for other measures of readaptation, ibid., pp. 210-216.
`The High Authority has also sponsored a series of studies of problems encountered in
the process of readaptation. See "Obstacles ~ la Mobilité des Travailleurs et Problémes
Sociaux de Rdadaptation," Luxembourg, 1956. For Belgium, the Institut de Sociologie de
Ia Facultd de Droit de Liege has prepared a study commissioned by the ECSC. "Migrations
Provoqudes et Problémes Soclaux de Mobilité Onvrière" (Liege, 1956). SImilar studies
have been prepared by groups in the other countries.
PAGENO="0023"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 15
READAPTATION AND E7JROPEAN COMMON MARKET
The so-called Spaak report,'° which forms the basis for the treaty
for the European Common Market, signed in Rome on March 25,
1957, provided for a retraining fund or social fund. According to
the report, the purpose of retraining workers is to facilitate conver-
sion of industry made necessary by economic progress. Retraining
would afford them protection against the risks accompanying con-
version, and would reconcile necessary mobility with stable employ-
ment. Due provisions must also be made for the inevitable change
entailed by the conversion from a Common Market limited to coal
and steel to a general Common Market. Grants for unempioywent
relief in the various countries must be harmonized, taking into ac-
count the principle of retraining.
The retraining fund is to be financed by contributions from mem-
ber states. Contributions are to be based on the total amount of
wages and social security benefits paid in each country. Payments
from the fund would not require proof that unemployment was due
to the settin~ up of a Common Market. It would be assumed that
the Community as a whole, as well as each state, would be interested
in progressive structural changes in industry, in rationalization of
enterprises, and in a better use of manpower for the purpose of in-
creasing productivity and raising the standard of living. This in-
terest would justify sharing in the expenditure necessary to protect
workers against risks connected with the conversion.
During the transition period, the fund would meet up to 50 percent
of the expenditure incurred in connection with cases and objectives
agreed on in advance. Contributions would be made available for
retraining workers for resettlement of workers, and for payments
to workers temporarily unemployed or on short time due to conver-
sion of a plant to other production. The length of the transition
period is to be broken down into three stages of 4 years each, extend-
able within a 15-year overall maximum. Detailed provision for
administering the transition period are spelled out in the treaty.'1
The provision for assisting labor and industry to adapt to the new
situation created by the elimination of trade barriers-
is not the traditional American concept of a free market, but rather than of a
"supervised" market with central institutions to insure fair play and to pro-
mote common policies, and endowed with funds to assist the transitional proc-
ess and to alleviate hardship * * *~12
EVALUATION
Without going into detail on the efficacy of readjustment measures
in Europe, it must be noted that application of readaptation measures
in some instances have been less than effective because some of the
national governments as well as industrial interests involved in the
European Coal and Steel Community, for example, have, in effect,
10 "Report Prepared by the Heads of Delegations of the Intergovernmental Committee
Set up by the Messina Conference to the Ministries of Foreign Affairs," OEEC Document
C(56) 215, Aug. 28, 1956 (mimeographed), pp. 64-67.
~` For a summary of these provisions, see Camps, Miriam, "The European Common
Market and American Policy,' memorandum No. 11, Center of International Studies,
Princeton University, Nov. 28, 1956, pp. XVII-XIX.
12 Camps, bc. cit., p. 8.
PAGENO="0024"
16 TRADE AD.TUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
sabotaged directives of the High Authority.13 The European ex-
perience, at least up to now, would not seem to be a good basis for
)udgrng the efficacy of a trade adjustment program in the United
States.
A case in point is the example of the Belgian mines.14 Accord-
ing to one recent analysis-
The [coal] mines in southern Belgium still could stand on their own feet in
the Common Market at the end of the transition period [1958]; their situation
has, If anything, deteriorated.
The measures to make the southern mines viable were taken too late and
applied without sufficient vigor; the results were therefore disappointing. Costs
of production were still too high, and the typical firm was still too small to put
up or to obtain the funds required for reorganization. Though the subsidy
might have been used to help the firms to compete in the Common Market, It en-
couraged them, with the help of the business boom, to avoid the problem
instead.15
The mines in southern Belgium encountered the same problem in 1958, when
the ending of the transitional period coincided with a business recession, as in
1953, another year of recession, as though nothing had been done to change their
situation: stocks of coal at the mines grew and prices were too high. A serious
strike broke out in the Borinage early in 1959 when the operators announced
that several mines would be closed. As a result of the strike the Government
requested permission from the High Authority to pay a further subsidy. The
life of the high-cost mines was prolonged for a short period and the High
Authority agreed to extend readaptation payments to the miners, but made any
further subsidies conditional on the preparation by the Government and
operators of a long-term reorganization and modernization plan.1'
The fact that European adjustment programs have met with diffi-
culties does in no way detract from the importance of these programs.
They are bound to gain in importance as economic integration pro-
gresses. On the whole there simply has not elapsed enough time to
make a balanced evaluation of the efficacy of measures put in effect
in various sectors of the several countries~ Nor does it appear that
sufficiently detailed investigations have been made as yet. Among the
more remarkable positive developments in the realm of trade adjust-
ment reported so far is the case of the Norwegian textile industry.'7
As Edwm L. Dale, Jr., points out:
Industries are likely to adapt remarkably quickly to lower tariffs on com-
petitive imports on one condition: There must be absolute certainty that the
tariffs will decline and eventually disappear-certainly written into laws and
treaties * * * Vulnerable industries will make the necessary changes only
when there is no longer any hope of avoiding tariff cuts.18
18See, for example, Diebold, William, Jr. "The Schuman Plan, a Study in Economic
Cooperation, 1950-59," New York, 1959,pp. 4~5-426.
~ Lister,, Louis, "Europe's Coal and Steel Community, an Experiment In Economic
Unions," New York, 1960, p. 116.
15Lister, op. cit., p. 120.
16Lister, op. cit.,. p. 121. The submarginal Belgian coal mines therefore may be said to
have developed into a depressed area problem as the result o~ nonfunctioning of the orig-
inal readaptatlon program. For a useful recent overview of European assistance programs
for area development, see "Economic Programs for Labor Surplus Areas In Selected
Countries of Western Europe," materials prepared fior the Joint Economic Committee,
Congress of the United States, Washington, 1960. The survey given there Includes pro-
grams in Belgium, Denmark, Federal Republic of Germany, France, Great Britain, Italy.
Northern Ireland, and Sweden.
IT "Western European Industries Adapt Quickly to Tariff Cuts," by Edward L. Dale, Jr.,
the New York Times, May 15, 1961, p. 43.
18 Ibid. ~Dale goes on to say: "This sort of adaptation Is made easier, of course, when
business conditions generally are good as they have been in Europe. Furthermore, the
basic principle does not necessarily apply to that handful of items including textiles,
where the threat comes not from other "advanced" countries but from "low wage" coun-
tries, * * *. But for "fair" competition, the experience with the free-trade experiment
in Europe leaves little doubt that industries can and do adapt."
PAGENO="0025"
TRADE ADJuSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 17
For 6 years (the Norwegian textile) industry was in the forefront of those
forces in Norway that successfully blocked the establishment of a Scandinavian
common market, on the ground that it could not compete with Denmark and
Sweden.
Then the rush of events, started by the formation of the Common Market
on the Continent, suddenly forced Norway almost overnight into the European
Free Trade Association. There was to be tariff-free competition not only from
Sweden and Denmark, but from Britain, Switzerland, Portugal, and Austria
as well.
`With remarkable speed, the Norwegian textile industry faced up to the new
situation. Some product lines were dropped, with concentration on a smaller
number of items that could be competitively produced. And already, with the
tariff cutting only beginning, the industry-no doubt to its own surprise-is not
only surviving, but has become an important exporter.
PAGENO="0026"
PAGENO="0027"
CHAPTER IV
PREVIOUS CONTRIBUTIONS TO THE DISCUSSION OF
TRADE ADJUSTMENT
This chapter will review a number of ~proposals advanced in the
last 10 or 15 years on how to expedite readaptation to increased com-
petitive imports resulting from freer trade. No attempt will be made
to evaluate these proposals systematically except for a brief summary
which also introduces the more detailed discussion. of organizational
and administrative aspects of a Federal trade adjustment program
in chapter V.1
STALEY AND THE PROBLEM OF COMPENSATION
Staley's discussion of the problem of industrial adaptation,2 al-
though set in the broad framework of general economic development
rather than that of impact of increased imports on one country,
touches many points useful to our discussion. According to Staley,
the problem of assisted readaptation is to protect people, not. indus-
tries, as such. When economic change takes place, it may, therefore
be desirable to liquidate a particular industry in a particular locality.
Transfers into other industries must then be made easier and the
burden of transition not be allowed to fall unfairly upon particular
groups.
The first adaptive possibility would lie in the industry's own tech-
nical and managerial efficiency. New methods and improvement in
management may be all it takes to put the industry on its feet. But
changes in demand and supply may make it advisable to curtail, if
not completely abandon, a particular line of production or, alterna-
tively, to increase productive capacity of the more efficient plants in
the industry. To link vocational retraining with the existing system
of unemployment benefits would then become an important step in the
direction of assisted adaptation.
Unwillingness by management to write off obsolete equipment
sometimes makes for hesitancy in the face of technological advance.
Staley suggests exploration of the feasibility of encouraging adapta-
tion by allowing shorter terms of amortization for tax purposes in
certain industries, on condition that funds accumulated in this way
be put periodically into complete plant modernization or into launch-
ing new products.3 He also suggests that the Government make an-
nual surveys of all industries receiving either direct subsidies from
the Government or import protection which enables them to keep
1 For further details on some aspects of the programs here discussed see Clubb, B. E.,
and Relscher, 0. R.~, "The Trade Adjustment Bills: Their Purpose and Efficacy," Columbia
Law Review, March 1961, pp. 4911-503.
2 See Staley, Eugene, "World Ecoaomic Development," Montreal, 1945, ch. 9.
8 Staley, op. cit., p. 205. The problem of accelerated amortization Is discussed more
fully In ch. v, below.
19
PAGENO="0028"
20 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
prices for their products up by a certain minimum percentage higher
than consumers would have to pay in the absence of such protection.
These surveys would report, first, measures taken in that year by each
industry to improve its productive efficiency and, second, the amount
spent in each industry on research for new products and new methods
of production, and how effective this research and development effort
has been.4
Staley aiso observes that the gains from successful adaptation are
often more widely shared than the costs involved, which may be con-
centrated on relatively few people. In many instances, particularly
in a situation involvrng removal of trade restrictions, an adaptive
change in a country's industrial structure would bring a substantial
permanent net gain to the economy as a whole, but at the risk of large,
albeit temporary, losses to particular individuals and groups. In
cases of this sortr-
* * * it might be equitable and useful to compensate private interests for tren-
sitlon costs made necessary by industrial adjustment In the general social In-
terest. If the people of the United States, for example, could * * * somehow
arrange to "buy out" the beet-sugar interests at a price not exceeding, say,
two or three times the annual amount which consumers would save by free
Imports of sugar, the bargain would be a good one. The "buying out" might con-
sist partly of compensation In money and partly in free vocational retraining
subsidization of developmental projects, and research directed to the discovery
of new products which would lead to Industrial expansion In the regions
affected.5
A similar proposal was advanced some years later in the United
States, in connection with the so-called Gray report.6 The Gray
report strongly emphasized the need of this country's accepting more
imports, and of adopting measures to bring this about:
There Is a need to reduce Import barriers not only to augment our already
strained sources of supply, but [also] to limit Western European countries'
requirements for economic assistance from the United States * * ~. Present
circumstances offer the possibility of moving toward reduction of import
barriers with minimum disturbance and distress to American agriculture, bust-
nessandlabor. * * ~7
The Gray report, in its published version, did not deal specifically
with ways in which domestic industry could adapt itself to expanded
imports. The reason for that omission may have been that it was
feared that objections, primarily on grounds of alleged difficulty of
administration to any plan of adjustment assistance following a tariff
reduction would be as strong as "against reduction of the tariff if no
compensation were proposed."8
45taley, op. cit., p. 210.
SOp. cit., p. 196.
~ "Report to the President on Foreign Economic Policies," Washington, D.C., Nov. 10,
1950.
`Loc. cit., p. 78.
~ See Wilcox, Clair, "Relief for Victims of Tariff Cuts," American Economic Review, vol.
Xi, No. 5, pt. 1 (December 1950), p. 889. While Wilcox ruled out compensation, be saw
no objection to a "policy of providing public assistance to facilitate conversion to more
promising activities." This would include loans to enterprises, and temporary support
and retraining for workers. Insofar as existing services of this nature were Inadequate,
they could be strengthened and amplified. ~[n later discussions, the suggestion of granting
"compensation for tariff Injury" has been virtually eschewed. Compensation for tariff
injury and compensation for eminent domain, when private property Is taken for public
use, have nothing in common, according to the Bell report (p. (17). Zn a free-enterprise
economy,. business Is always confronted with risks, and the Government Is not obliged to
Insure any enterprise against the risks of business. "Tariff rates have been raised and
lowered in the United States for 150 years without the Government compensating any
business, export or import-competing, for the effects of a tariff change. No compensation
was undertaken at the time of passage of iir1~é dontr&l & ills prohIbition MW." ~ss
Lindeman, John and Salant, Walter S., "Assistance for Adjustment to Tariff Reductions,"
in Studies in Unemployment, prepared for the special Committee on Unemployment Prob-
lems, U.S. Senate, pursuant to S. Res. 196, 86th Cong. (Washington, 1960), p. 271.
PAGENO="0029"
TEADE ADJTISTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 21
THE BELL REPORT9
Regarding assisted readjustment to increased imports, the Bell
report made a distinction between injury to the national economy and
injury to particular industries. Injury to a particular industry may
occur when certain imports are accepted. But the national economy
would be injured if increased imports were not accepted. The escape
clause procedure, as provided by section 7 of the Trade Agreements
Extension Act, is concerned solely with the avoidance of serious injury
to domestic producers from import competition. Consumer prefer-
ences receive no consideration under the law. Nor are domestic pro-
ducers protected from foreign restrictions on exports as a result of U.S.
restrictions on imports. Injury to the national economy should there-
fore be prevented by accepting imports and by providing adjustment
assistance to those domestic industries for whom an increase in im-
ports would bring competition that might be hard to meet.
The problems of adjustment in import-competing industries would
be relatively simple, if these industries were located in great industrial
centers where alternative job opportunities are available. Here the
normal growth of the economy would provide adequate jobs for those
displaced in import-competing industries. But some of the industries
that would be most affected by imports are located in communities
where other types of industrial employment are not easily available.10
Measures must be devised to facilitate adjustment in these com-
munities.
Although there is no basis for compensating them, the Bell report
continues, there is good reason for helping industries faced with
keener import competition to adjust their production to a more diver-
sified line of products which they can produce profitably in the face of
declining tariffs. Aside from granting some form of tax relief, the
Federal Government could give special consideration to the conver-
sion problems of such industries by loaning part or all of the new
capital requirements in cases where the loan would be a good business
risk.
The central readjustment problem, next to the difficulties faced by
communities overly dependent upon one or a limited number of plants,
was seen by the Bell Committee as finding new jobs for workers dis-
located by import competition. While workers often can and do find
jobs in the same community or in nearby communities, for a small
number, those with less mobility, especially women and older workers,
there may nevertheless ensue a longer waiting period before a new
job is found. Such workers could be given unemployment insurance
for a longer than ordinary period, the report suggests, the added
cost to be borne by the Federal Government. Retraining programs
and helping to meet the cost of moving to job opportunities in other
communities would also be included in the program.
In dealing with the vulnerability of one-industry communities to
increased import competition, the Bell Committee report concludes
that it is a consequence of inadequate diversification. Often the corn-
~` Its full title is: "A Trade and Tariff Policy in the National Interest: A Report to the
President by the Public Advisory Board for Mutual Security" (Washington. D.C., February
1953). Trade adjustment is discussed in ch. IV of the report.
10 See, for example, the case of the leather glove industry in Fulton County, N.Y~, treated
more fully in ch. VI, below.
PAGENO="0030"
22 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN ThEORY AND PRACTICE
munity's distress is rooted in more fundamental economic causes than
competition from imports, such as plants shut down because of in-
efficient management, a shift of plants to other localities, a change
in demand for certain goods. For these communities, the only remedy
would be attracting new enterprises.11
DAVID J. M'DONALD AND THE RANDALL REPORT
The most widely publicized proposal dealing with trade adjustment
was that submitted in early 1954, by Commissioner David J. Mc-
Donald, United Steel Workers of America-ClO, for consideration
by the Randall Commission.12 The Commission's majority did not
accept the proposal, but ordered it published in the body of the report,
with appended dissents?3
Substantively there was little new in McDonald's proposal. He
proposed that when the administration finds it in the national interest
to lower a tariff below the "peril point," or to maintain a tariff con-
cession despite a Tariff Commission finding of injury to an industry
in an escape-clause action, the affected companies, their employees
and the communities in which they are located should become eligible
for aid under an adjustment assistance program. Companies and
communities should have access to technical assistance, comprising
such financial aid as may be necessary to carry out their adjustment
program, including accelerated amortization, and receive special con-
sideration in the award of Government contracts. Employees of
these firms should also be eligible for adjustment assistance if they
are not able to find new jobs promptly. A special unemployment pro-
gram administered through existing Federal-State machinery, but
financed by Federal funds would serve that purpose. Such a program
would also include intensive counselling and placement work, special
training allowances, special moving allowances, and advance eligi-
bility for retirement benefits for unemployable older workers.
The immediate reaction to the McDonald proposal outside the
Randall Commission was not unfavorable.14 It was felt, for example,
that if adopted, the program would make tariff reform easier by
diminishing opposition to it and also by making it easier to argue the
free-trade position. At the same time it was pointed out that the
policy of helping communities ought to be a general one, and should
not be limited to damage from tariff reductions. But in all instances
of economic dislocation, emphasis should be placed on marginal as-
sistance for adaptation, with the initiative coming from local areas,
and Federal aid only as a supplement to local initiative.15
~ In passing, the report observes that, "the national interest [from a defense viewpoint]
in industrial dispersion is the counterpart of the local interest in industrial diversification
* * ~" (bc. cit., p. 67).
~ See Commission on Foreign Economic Policy, "Report to the President and the Con-
gress," (Washington, D.C., January 1954), pp. 54-61. See also the separate volume of
"Staff Papers Presented to the Commission on Foreign Economic Policy" (Washington,
D.C., February 1954). Ch. 7 deals with the problems of adjustment to imports.
13 colleagues did not endorse his readjustment proposal because they viewed
the problem of workers and businesses suffering from declining markets owing to tariff
reductions as part of the broader problem of general economic change.
`~ See Knerr, Klaus and Patterson, Gardner, eds., "A Critique of the Randall Commission
Report on United States Foreign Economic Policy," Princeton, 1954. (A digest and sum-
mary of a conference of 17 economists held at Princeton in February 1954.)
~5 Princeton critique pointed out an important omission of the McDonald program in
that it did not concern itself in a balanced way with the problems of agricultural or mining
areas which might wither as a result of increased import competition. Adjustment there
would entail transferring people and the still usable capital resources to other locations.
(For a discussion of problems likely to be encountered in trade adjustment programs In
these fields, see chs. VII and VIII, below.)
PAGENO="0031"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 23
CONGRESSIONAL PROPOSALS FOR TRADE ADJUSTMENT'6
In June 1954 several bills were introduced in the 83d Congress with
the purpose of providing assistance to those individuals, companies,
and communities suffering serious injury or threatened with serious
injury due to increased imports resulting from a national trade policy.
The prototype of these bills were identical measures introduced in
the Senate by the then Senator John F. Kennedy (S. 3650), and in
the House by Congressman (now Senator) Harrison A. Williams Jr.
(H.R. 9652). In the 1st session of the 84th Congress, Senator Hubert
H. Humphrey introduced a similar bill (5. 751), and Congressman
Williams reintroduced his bill without substantial alterations (H.R.
229). Companion bills were offered by several other Congressmen,
including Frank E. Smith of Mississippi (H.R. 4277) and Henry S.
Reuss (H.R. 2992). In the 1st session of the 85th Congress, Senator
Kennedy once more introduced his bill with only minor changes
(S. 2907) as the Trade Adjustment Act of 1957. In the House sim-
iliar bills were introduced or reintroduced as the Federal Tariff Re-
duction Adjustment Assistance Act by Smith of Mississippi (H.R.
457), Donohue (H.R. 1105), and Eberharter (H.R. 9505).
This section will outline the basic provisions of the several bills,
and emphasize the points of difference both in approach and in specific
provisions.
Title
The original Kennedy-Williams bill had the title "Trade Adjust-
ment Act of 1954." The bill was reintroduced essentially without
change in 1955 and 1957. The bill introduced by Congressman Smith
in 1955 bore the title, "Federal Tariff Reduction Adjustment Act,"
amplified upon its being reintroduced in 1957 to "Federal Tariff Re-
duction Adjustment Assistance Act." The bill introduced by Con-
gressman Reuss in 1955 was entitled, "Reciprocal Trade Casualties
Act of 1955."
Purpose of pro posed legislation
The purpose of the Kennedy-Williams bill, shared by all other
proposals, except the Reuss bill, was to resolve the problem of serious
adverse effects caused particular sectors of the economy by a reduction
of trade barriers. It would do so by helping particular communities,
industries, enterprises, and individuals avoid or ameliorate any injury
they may suffer in the adjustment of their productive activities made
necessary by such a reduction. The Reuss bill proposed to concentrate
such assistance on enterprises only.
Administration
The Kennedy-Williams bill called for the creation of a five-member
Trade Adjustment Board, appointed by the President, one member
to be designated as Chairman. The Smith bill called for a three-
member Board. Under the Reuss bill, no board at all was proposed;
the administrative machinery to be used would have been provided
solely by the Tariff Commission.
~ The proposals considered here are limited to draft legislation introduced prior to 1958.
A number of additional suggestions have been included in proposals introduced into the
Congress since then. These are more fully considered in Clubb and Reischer, "The Trade
Adjustment Bills: Their Purpose and Efficacy," Columbia Law Review, March 1961, pp.
490-508.
PAGENO="0032"
24
TRADE ADJtJ~STMENT fl~ ~HE~RY AND PRACrPICE
The Board would have acted after nOtification by the President,
under the escape clause of the Trade Agreements Extension Act of
1951, that a reduction in the rate of duty or other import restriction
had been found to threaten or cause serious injury to a domestic
industry
Criteria for eligibility
Under th~ Kennedy-Williams bill, any business enterprise engaged
in the production of an article identical to or directly competitive
with the article in question would have been eligible for adjustment
assistance. Eligibility would also have extended to any unemployed
individual whose last regular employment had been in a business
enterprise eligible for the benefits provided, and any community with
a substantial number of residents individually eligible for assistance,
as well as any industrial development corporation organized for the
purpose of aiding the development of a more balanced and diversified
economy, or the diversification of production in a community eligible
for assistance. In determining whether a particular business enter-
prise is eligible for these benefits, the Board would have cOnsidered
first, what portion of the total production of sueh enterprise consists
of the production of an article identical to or directly competitive
with the article declared to have been the cause of injury or threatened
injury, and, second, whether such enterprise had developed satisfac-
tory proposals for programs of economic adjustment consonant with
the purpose of the proposed legislation. The last provision also would
have been applicable to communities and industrial development cor-
porations.
The Reuss bill would have made assistance applicable to producers
only, but particularly those well equipped to bid on Government con-
tracts.
Information and advice
Under the Kennedy-Wiffiams bill, any business enterprise found
eligible would apply to appropriate departments and agencies of the
Government for technical information, market research, or any other
form of information and advice which might be of assistance in the
development of more efficient methods and of new lines of production.
Similarly, eligible communities and industrial development corpora-
tions could obtain information and advice to enable them to develop
a more balanced and diversified economy.
According to the Smith bill, the Adjustment Board was to establish
a central clearinghouse of information to facilitate the work of the
various State economic development commissions and similar agen-
cies by providing a source of statistics and other information regard-
ing the mdustrial advantages offered by various distressed communi-
ties, and by providing State and local agencies with information re-
garding the success of various techniques for achieving diversification
and otherwise avoiding the injurious effects of tariff reductions.
U8e of loan8 and grant8
The Kennedy-Williams bill would have provided for Federal finan-
cial assistance in the form of loans to business enterprises and commu-
nities eligible for assistance either directly or through industrial devel-
opment corporations, from the Small Business Corporation, subject
to the same safeguards as applicable under the Small Business Act.
PAGENO="0033"
TRADE ADJuSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
25
Tinder the Smith bill, the Federal Government would have paid
grants to State governments who in turn would draw up appropriate
adjustment plans, in the implementation of which these grants would
be utilized. These programs would have included benefits to all par-
ties involved in the adjustment process.
Unem~pioyiment compensation
The Kennedy-Williams bill provided for supplementary unemploy-
ment benefits to be paid by the individual States to unemployed indi-
viduals, for which the States would be reimbursed by the Federal
Government. The supplementary payments would have been such
as to make the total payment to the individual equal to two-thirds of
his average weekly earning for 52 weeks.
Training and transportation
Suitable vocational rehabilitation was to be given unemployed indi-
viduals, as provided by the Kennedy-Williams bill, utilizing existing
Federal facilities, and/or training facilities provided by public and
private institutions as necessary. Tinder certain circumstances,
assistance was also to be granted to transportation of an unemployed
individual, his dependents and household effects to a job opportunity
in a new location. The 1957 version of the bill provided for a $150
limitation in such assistance.
Retirement
Older workers certified to be unemployed as a result of interna-
tional trade policy, were to be allowed under the Kennedy-Williams
bill, to retire at the age of 60 rather than 65, and the Social Security
Act was to be amended to that effect.
Accelerated amortisation
The Kennedy-Williams bill, as well as the Smith bill, provided that
business enterprises would be allowed to take advantage of the accel-
erated amortization provision of the Internal Revenue Code.
Preference in defense contracts
The Reuss bill provided that any domestic producer found by the
Tariff Commission to be in danger of foreign imports, would receive a
certificate entitling him to a percentage advantage-up to 25 percent-
in his bids on Government contracts. This would have allowed the
company to keep busy while casting about for new products to sus-
tain it in the long run. The certificate was to have been good for a
limited period only.
SUMMARY AND EVALUATION
The preceding proposals incorporate a number of ideas that could
be usefully applied to solving the problem of assisting in adaptation
to dislocations caused by intensified import competition. Each type
of measure appears to be useful on the face of it and deserving of
further consideration. Taken together, however, the typical set of
adjustment measures as presented, for example, by the McDonald
program actually trespasses onto the field of redevelopment of de-
pressed areas and communities for which comprehensive remedial
measures were enacted in 1961.
76C97-61---8
PAGENO="0034"
26 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
The problems encountered in area redevelopment in some instances
do overlap with dislocations caused by a rise in competitive imports
following a lowering of trade barriers. But these problems for the
most part affect a far larger portion of the county's labor force and
productive capacity. Appropriate measures for area development,
moreover, are being carried out irrespective of what steps are taken
to cope with the problems of trade adjustment. Therefore, it appears
advisable to concentrate a program of assistance in trade adjustment
on the individual business firm, in the manner exemplified by the Reuss
bill, rather than specifically to include in trade adjustment legislation
measures designed for djrect relief of committees and workers. The
program, even though of a narrower scope, should have a wider cov-
erage than the Reuss bill, and assistance under it should certainly not
be limited to preferential treatment in Government procurement.
In the next chapter, the component elements of a trade adjustment
program focused on the individual firm will be discussed in greater
detail.
PAGENO="0035"
CHAPTER V
ORGANIZATIONAL AND ADMINISTRATIVE ASPECTS OF
A TRADE ADJUSTMENT PROGRAM
CRITERIA FOR APPLICATION
Freer trade as cause 0/injury
The first step in setting up an adjustment assistance program would
be to define limits within which a finding could be made to the effect
that an industry or enterprise has suffered injury from increased
imports. In actual practice, this first step will already have been
taken by the Tariff Commission. The Commission, in the course of
an escape clause or peril point investigation, makes a determination
of whether or not injury has been suffered or is being threatened.1
The business firm involved would have to show a persistent decline
in earnings beginning with the lifting of the trade restriction or
shortly thereafter. Domestic competition would have to be ruled
out as a primary, though not as a contributory cause of the firm's
difficulty.
The Commission in the process of determining injury will also have
performed the task of singling out the commodity that allegedly
caused the injury; more precisely, the Commission will have agreed
with the applicant's identification of the particular article, the in-
creased import of which is hurting his business.
The definition of injury as used by the Tariff Commission should
be carefully drawn so as to avoid possible pitfalls. Too broad a defi-
nition would encourage so many applications under the provisions of
the escape clause and the peril point amendment that a program of
adjustment assistance, offered as an alternative measure of relief,
would become impossible to administer. An excessively narrow defi-
nition of injury would hinder an equitable determination of losses
sustained because it would deprive the authority administering the
program of the latitude and flexibility in making awards. Tinder
a narrow definition it might be hard to find even one commodity
among allegedly directly competing imports which could be identified
as the cause of injury inflicted on the applicant.
Determination of injury would be preceded by an examination of
potential causes for injury other than increased imports, such as
changes in demand, increased competitive pressure from domestic
substitutes, higher costs of production and distribution in the indus-
try, and more vigorous domestic competition in general.
The increased inflow of imports may also not have been due solely
to a lowering of trade barriers. There may have been an increase
in the total domestic demand for the article in question, large enough
1 Sees. 7 and 3-4 of the Trade Agreements Extension Act. The program described here
Is of relatively narrow scope because it eventuates from the escape clause mechanI~a.
27
PAGENO="0036"
28 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
to attract and include the foreign product alongside with the domesti-
cally produced item. The domestic industry may not have been able
to expand rapidly enough to ifil all needs, and consumers' tastes may
have been influenced in favor of the import. And foreign producers
may well have i' iproved their competitive position in the American
market prior to the lowering of trade barriers, for price is only one
dimension of competition.
The Tariff Commission, as a result of its escape clause decisions2
and other investigations, has in effect built up a set of precedents
which can provide guidelines in deciding new cases of injury inflicted
or threatened.
The major problem in making determinations in the past has cen-
tered on the question of whether a domestic industry "producing like
or directly competitive products" was being, or was about to be, seri-
ously injured. In the 1951 Trade Agreement Extension Act serious
injury could be found, when, among other things, there was `~ * * a
decline in the proportion of the domestic market supplied by domestic
producers." Prior to the passage of the 1955 Trade Agreement Ex-
tension Act, a minority of the Tariff Commission had tended to assign
heavy weight to this criterion, particularly in cases where a decline
in the share of domestic producers in the home market was accompa-
nied by other unfavorable developments in the domestic industry. This
so-called share doctrine was made explicitly part of the law in the
1955 act.3
In general, trend of production and level of profits have served as
the key criteria for determining serious injury. But a low, consoli-
dated net-profits-to-sales ratio for all firms in the industry, compared
to that of similar industries, or of manufacturing as a whole, has been
deemed, however strangely, more significant than a low ratio of profits
to capital or a declining trend of profits. Yet a wide diversity in the
profit experience of individual firms has been regarded by the Com-
mission as evidence that the industry as a whole was not being seriously
injured by imports. Increased imports have been considered as the
cause of serious injury only when they have contributed "significantly"
to a further deterioration of the industry's position.4
The question of whether, in examining profits, production, etc., the
domestic industry should be defined as including all the operations
of the constituent firms, or only those operations relating directly to
the production of the article under investgiation, has also given rise
to difficulty. Prior to the 1955 act, the Commission generally tended
to find injury in terms of the industry's overall operations. No in-
jury was found, if owing to profits earned in the production of other
goods, the industry continued to be profitable despite a decline in the
production of the product under investigation and an increase in un-
ports of that product.
2Sec. 7 of the Trade Agreements Extension Act of 1951, as amended. See the most
recent version, act of August 20, 1958, 72 Stat. 673.
~ Increased imports, whether actual or relative, are now to be considered as the cause
of threat of injury if they have contributed substantially toward causing or threating
injury to an industry or segment thereof. Thus, If an industry has not succeeded In main.
taming its proportional share of the domestic market-regardless of whether that market
has been shrinking or'expanding-the industry may still cite this relative loss as evidence
of ~i~ss act substituted the word "substantially" for "significantly." An earlier
ver of thG act had called for Industry only to proté that It WAi Beffif "mtt~rIRlly"
PAGENO="0037"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 29
Extent of injury and appropriate assistance
Firms that are being. or are about to be, injured by increased im-
ports may be assumed to need financial assistance in making necessary
adjustments to escape injury. The determination of amount and type
of assistance will depend on the extent of the loss, as well as on the
program of readaptation suitable for the given firm.
The absolute decline in the firm's domestic sales during a given
period, and the extent to which this decline was accompanied by an
increase in imports after trade barriers had been lowered, may serve
as measurement of loss incurred. For 1 year, factors which bear on
the firm's operations other than competitive imports could be assumed
as unchanging. More realistically, however, the firm's loss is likely to
be incurred in a transition period in which it would adjust operations
so as to gain at least partial immunity to adverse effects of increased
import competition. The initial estimate of the firm's loss may there~
fore prove to exceed the one actually incurred.
Since the size of the loss sustained would depend on how success-
fully the enterprise reacted to the change in its competitive situation,
assistance must be provided in a manner not to blunt managerial
initiative.
Administrative considerations
Suitable administrative safeguards must insure that readjustment
assistance not degenerate into a series of economically unjustifiable
handouts. At least three requirements are essential.
In contrast to an "infant industry," a "senescent industry," one that
has no place in a growing economy and that ekes out a meager return
even with benefit of tariff protection, must not be rejuvenated at pub-
lic expense without giving certain guarantees that it will modernize
operations or diversify production.
The program would have to be designed so as to forestall legal or
constitutional difficulties that might arise in its operation. What has
to be avoided, for instance, is a situation where the administering au-
thority would be open to charges of setting conditions in any particu-
lar readjustment project that would conflict with existing obligations
of enterprises participating in the program.5
Finally, business enterprises must have firm advance assurance of
prompt benefits from an adjustment program in the event that the
damages they fear would result from a lowering of trade barriers
do in fact occur. In the absence of such assurance, business' un-
willingness to accept the idea of trade adjustment would be difficult to
overcome.
The case for a program centered on the individual firm~
The central figure in the readjustment picture is the producer him-
self. If the individual enterprise can adjust, and if adjustment assist-
ance to freer trade can be given at the enterprise level, no new ma-
chinery other than existing Federal and State facilities will be needed
to help workers and communities bear the burden of increased competi-
tive imports. Successful readjustment of business enterprises would
6 Some time ago, the Small Rusiness Administration was accused of having offered a
loan to a New York leather goods concern on condition that the plant be removed to
another State. The company, however, was bound by a "no removal" clause in its con-
tract with the union. (See New York Times, Oct. 31, 1955.)
PAGENO="0038"
30 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRA~flCE
tend to take care of the immediate economic difficulties, workers, and
communities, too.6 The individual company could be given added fl.
nancial assistance which would enable it to carry its workers on the
payroll during all or most of the transition period.7 If an enterpre-
neur affected by increased competitive imports were relieved of respon-
sibility for his workers, he might decide to close down his shop al-
together. Readjustment for workers and for the community affected
would then become even more onerous.
Readjustment and the responsibility for its being carried out would
best be fixed in one focal point-the entrepreneur. The more closely
a readjustment assistance program is focused on the individual firm,
the less costly it is likely to be in money terms and the easier it could
be administered. With the enterprise at the center of the pro-
gram, assistance to workers and communities because of injury by
imports has lost much of its erstwhile urgency particularly in view
of the depressed area legislation already passed by Congress.
In providing means for helping the industry, and the businessman
and entrepreneur intent upon readjusting activities to increased im-
ports, and to induce them to make necessary changes with due haste,
no one formula defining an optimal rate of speed for readaptation can
be prescribed.
FINANCING THE PROGRAM
Proposed sources and methods
The amount of Federal contributions to the program will be gov-
erned by the degree to which the Federal Government would partici-
pate directly in the program, and also on the program's coverage.
In the case of a comprehensive adjustment program covering work-
ers and communities as well as business firms, it might be useful to es-
tablish one major source of financing. A readjustment "equalization
fund" has been suggested, fed by allocations from various sources in
stich a manner as supposedly to equalize burdens and benefits de-
rived from greater import competition among industries or segments
of industries. Earmarking of customs revenue either directly or as
contribution to such a fund has also been proposed.8
Another set of proposals concerns assistance in the form of low-
interest loans granted by a Government agency like the Small Busi-
ness Administration, with or without private participation, and in-
cluding a system of loan guarantees.
A third form of financial assistance suggested is that of accelerated
depreciation writeoffs. Liberal amortization allowances would be
provided to induce enterprises to discontinue a given line of produc-
tion, for example, which has ceased to be profitable because of in-
creased import competition. This would permit the company to scrap
equipment more quickly, in the absence of alternative uses.
A readjv~tment equalisation fund
One of the suggestions for financing a program of assistance in
adjustment to increased competitive imports has been that of set-
~ In this respect, most earlier congressional proposals have erred on the side of all-
inclusiveness. This fact raises doubts as to their practicability.
~Th1s would be in line with the closer cooperation between management and Government
which has been developing as a result of the increasingly numerous "guaranteed annual
wage" or "supplemental unemployment benefits" agreements. Most of the agreements
concluded are in export industries, however.
8Eurden equalization must not be made dependent on the method of financing, however.
PAGENO="0039"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
31
ting up a readjustment assistance fund. The fund would aim at
equalizing the burden imposed by readjustment. The Federal con-
tribution to such a fund might be provided out of increased customs
revenue. In the course of a program of trade liberalization more
duties will be collected, for where nontariff restrictions such as quotas
and "Buy American" preferences are reduced and tariff rates remain
unchanged, customs revenues must go up. Customs revenues will also
rise when tariff duties are reduced while the market for the imported
product increases to a greater degree. Other factors, such as the
growth of dutiable imports, which tends to accompany the normal
growth of the economy, likewise enhance the possibility of greater
customs receipts.
If such a fund were established, the amount set aside for it by the
Federal Government might be matched by contributions by State and
local governments within whose reach the companies participating in
the readjustment program are located. This would be one way in
which gains from freer trade that permeate the economy, including
anticipated savings on expenditures out of tax receipts, could be set off
against losses from dislocation. No excessive burden would be placed
on any one sector of the economy in order to help finance benefits
to be reaped from freer international trade by other sectors.
A major drawback of such a fund would be, however, that what it
might acid in equity would be lost in the administrative complications
it would create. No useful purpose would be achieved if such a for-
midable piece of financial machinery were to service a relatively small
program of assistance disbursements.
Earmarking eustonw revenue
As a simpler device, a portion of increased total customs revenue
that would result from a larger volume of imports following a grad-
ual lowering of trade barriers would be set aside to defray expenses
arising in connection with the readjustment program, such as the
periodic payments to affected enterprises to help expand research
and development activities.
There are precedents for this procedure. One is the provision,
under section 32 of the Agricultural Adjustment Act of 1935,~ estab-
lishing a special fund equal to 30 percent of the gross receipts of tariff
duties to be spent for encouragement of export and domestic con-
sumption of agricultural products. Tinder the Agricultural Act of
1949, this fund is allowed to accumulate until it reaches $300 million.'0
Another more recent precedent is Public Law 466, 83d Congress,
2d session, which sets aside a portion of the gross receipts from cus-
toms duties collected to be used in promoting the sale of domestic
fishery products.'1
Earmarking of revenues for specific purposes is open to grave ob-
jections, however, because preferred budgetary positions are being
949 Stat. 774; 7 U.S.C. 612c.
10 U.S. Department of Agriculture, Production and Marketing Administration, "Section
32 Handbook," Washington, D.C., 1953, passim. A certain amount of this fund is set
aside annually for the use of fisheries (sec. 2(a), act of Aug. 11, 1939, 53 Stat. 1411; 12
U.S. 713 C-2).
11 This legislation coincided with a Tariff Commission recommendation for an increase
on imported groundfish fillets and an Import quota for 1 year. See "Groundfish Fillets,
Report to the President on Escape Clause Investigation No. 25," etc., Washington, D.C.,
1954. The Commission's recommendation was rejected by the President on the grounds
that a reduction in imports would not help to expand the industry's market and increase
fish consumption.
PAGENO="0040"
32 TRADE ADJ1JSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
created 12 which obstruct the formulation of a well-balanced program
within the limitations imposed by the whole budget.'3 The particu-
lar program can no longer be considered in relation to other agricul-
tural programs, for example, because its size wifi already have been
determined by basic legislation. Thus support for current production
may be receiving greater emphasis than long-run improvements in
productivity.'4
Earmarking of taxes also introduces rigidities into the financial
structure that may lead to a situation where the tax system would be
rendered less flexible and where it would be more difficult to obtain an
optimum combination of taxes.
Accelerated amortization
The suggestion has often been made to provide liberal amortization
allowances designed to facilitate a firm's exit from a particular indus-
try; or to allow the firm to discontinue a particular line of operations
rendered unprofitable by increased import competition; or to encour-
age the firm to expand production of products other than those affected
by the tariff reduction.'5 Proponents of this idea have argued that the
program would fall into two parts: One would concentrate on scrap-
ping a portion of the firm's existing plant and equipment; the other
half of the program would be concerned with providing aid to acquire
and install new plant and equipment to produce products not sensi-
tive to import competition. The procedure would parallel that used
by the Office of Civil Defense and Mobilization in inducing firms to
expand existing production facilities for defense production.
With regard to the first part of the program, it may be pointed out
immediately that accelerated amortization for junking equipment in
the transition period would not be practicable. In fact, the incentive
to change would be stronger if after a certain point no depreciation
at all were allowed a firm unwilling to make necessary adjustments
along these lines. The extra weight of tax burden thus imposed on
the firm would serve as a negative incentive to producers of import-
sensitive articles not to stay in the same line of business.
But the fundamental difference between the problem dealt with by
the Office of Civil Defense and Mobilization, for example, and an
organization supervising a program of assisted readaptation to in-
creased imports is this: In the case of defense production, relatively
quick installation of an asset is required; the asset may lose its value
once the need for the particular product has lessened. After its in-
stallation, therefore, the asset is supposed to depreciate rather quickly,
and accelerated amortization is designed to take this fact into account
in lowering the firm's tax liability.
~ In connection with the passage of Public Law 466, the Bureau of the Budget did
point out that an annual appropriation for the conduct of research would thereby be
established regardless of need, and that the procedure placed a priority on certain types
of research which, as time went on, might be relatively low in priority to other research
activities. See U.S. Senate Committee on Interstate and Foreign Commerce, "Report on
Encouragement of Distribution of Fishery Products," Washington, D.C., Apr. 14, 1954.
18See in this connection, Smithies, Arthur, "The Budgetary Process In the United
States." New York, 1955, p. 8~2.
14The same criticism is applicable to other agricultural programs, such as price sup-
ports, sugar subsidies, surplus removal, and conservation payments, and the see. 32
program, Smithies, op. cit., p. 386.
1~ 1954 Internal Revenue Code, par. 1J68.
PAGENO="0041"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 33
In a program of readaptation to increased imports, however, a
firm installing new equipment should not have to anticipate that
equipment to depreciate in value as rapidly as a piece of specialized
defense production equipment; indeed, a gradual increase in profita-
bility of the asset is far more likely to occur. Without expectation
of an increased return from the new installation or the new line of
production, readaptation would not make sense. Inducement to
install new equipment would in fact be superfluous since such an in-
vestment would be in the firm's own best interest, and the firm would
not be undertaking it for reasons of national security. The difficulty,
if any, would arise in connection with financing new capital acquisi-
tions and with tiding the firm over the transition period.
Assuming the new investment to contribute to the enterprise's
eventual and continued profitability, it would actually be illogical
to make accelerated amortization part of a readjustment program, to
say nothing of the difficulties the technique has given rise to in other
uses.16 The fast writeoff as used for defense production purposes is
too powerful and too wasteful an instrument for an adjustment as-
sistance program. The best form of assistance in form of tax relief
would be a special tax carryover appropriate for new enterprises.17
A carryover would be more effective in accomplishing the objectives
desired under readaptation: giving the enterprises a good start in
its new pursuit by keeping burdens down at the outset, but letting
the enterprise revert to a less favored position at the end of the transi-
tion period when the enterprise is again able to hold its own against
competing producers at home and abroad.
Because the amounts involved are likely to be quite small com-
pared to the total capital investment in the Nation, the problem of
aggravating erosion of the tax base by this type of assistance is prob-
ably insignificant. This would be true particularly in view of the
savings that will accrue to taxpayers and to the community as a
whole as a result of the availability of a larger volume of imported
goods at lower prices.
One version of proposed trade adjustment legislation provides for
accelerated amortization of facilities used in the old line of produc-
tion as well as the new facilities.'8 This provision is designed to al-
low the displaced firm to recover the cost of its old equipment during
its last years in the protected industry. But the firms that will change
to a new line of production will be those unable to make a reasonable
profit in their old line of production. Thus, during the last years
in the old line of production, the displaced firm will probably not
have sufficient profits to offset the large deduction for amortization.
The effect of accelerated amortization of the old equipment will be
to create a loss which the firm could carry forward if it stayed in the
16 See for example, U.S. Congress,, Joint Committee on the Economic Report, "Implica-
tions o1~ Recent Expansion of Special Amortization Program," staff memorandum, Wash-
ington, D.C. May 29, 1~956 (mimeographed), passim; and the same committee's "Federal
Tax Policy ~or Economic Growth and Stability," (S. Rept. No. 13~iO, 84th Cong., 2d sess.),
Washington, D.C., 1956, p. 8.
`~ New enterprises encounter a period of losses during their developmental phase. A
liberal carry-forward provision insures that such development losses can eventually be
offset if the enterprise proves successful, and thus encourages investment in new ventures.
A carryback, suitable for enterprises nearing or in the process of liquidation, would be
inappropriate for firms hurt by import competition. It would not hasten their exit from
the industry; on the contrary, it would give them an inducement to prolong their existence.
~ See Clubb and Reischer, "The Trade Adjustment Bills: Their Purpose and Efficacy,"
Columbia Law Review, March 1i~61, pp. 4fl0-50&
PAGENO="0042"
TRADE ADJITSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRA~~TICE
same line production (1954 Tnt. Rev. Code, par. 1212). There is a
question, however, whether and under what circumstances the firm
can carry its loss over to offset profits made in the new line of pro-
duction.19 In order to encourage firms to get into other lines of pro-
duction, a trade adjustment program should include tax legislation
permitting a firm injured by trade concession to carry forward losses
sustained while in the protected industry, in addition to the provision
for new equipment discussed earlier in this section.
Loand by the Small Business Adlminidtration
Small business-type loans as a method of financing readjustment
have been an often mentioned device.20
The Small Business Administration was set up in 1953, partly to
take the place of the Small Defense Plant Administration, and partly
to assume certain programs of the Reconstruction Finance Corpo-
ration.2' According to section 202 of Public Law 163 of July 30,
1953-
* * * the Government should aid, counsel, assist, and protect * * * the inter-
ests of small business concerns In order to preserve free competition enterprise,
to insure that a fair proportion of the total purchases and contracts for supplies
and services for the Government be placed with small-business enterprises, and
to maintain and strengthen the overall economy of the Nation.
Lending is only one of the major activities of SBA. Two other
important programs are procurement assistance to small businesses
to obtain a fair share of orders for goods and services by both public
and private buyers, and management and technical assistance with
a view toward making small business take advantage of improved
business or production methods.~
Participation of SBA in a readjustment assistance program would
call for supplementary legislation which may not be germane to the
purpose for which SBA was originally set up, for it is not always the
small concern that can claim injury or threat of injury from a low-
ering of tariffs. Furthermore, the use of SBA in a program of re-
adaptation to increased imports would increase the volume of small
business loans. But this type of assisted readjustment is not aimed
primarily at making small business thrive for the sake of counter-
acting monopolistic tendencies in the economy. Rather, it aims to
eliminate marginal producers in a given industry or industries who
are retarding the economy's progress toward the more efficient utili-
zation of the country's resources, that would be attainable with a
higher degree of international specialization resulting from freer
trade. This objective transcends the accustomed purview of the SBA.
Still another reason against SBA becoming involved in financing
the import readjustment program is the agency's apparent orientation
toward promoting the growth of small enterprises over periods as
10 This problem Is particularly serious for the corporation which attempts to get into a
new line of production by consolidating with another corporation. 1954 Internal Revenue
Code, pars. 381, 382.
2015 U.S.C.A., par. 681, sg.
21 See Commission on Organization of the Executive Branch (Hoover Commission),
"Task Force Report on Lending Agencies" (Washington, D.C., 191i5), pp. 70-76, and
221-23.5. See also, Hoover Commission, "Lending Agencies, A Report to Congress"
(Washington, D.C., 1~5), pp. 89-92.
22 "srpall business" eligible for SBA is defined by law only as an enterprise Inde-
pendently owned and operated and not dominating in its own field. In defining "small,"
SEA is authorized to use such standards as number of employees and dollar volume of
business. It draws no rigid line on these points, since a 1,000-employee company may
be big in golf carts but small In steel. The bulk of its loans, however, has been awarded
to firms employing less than 100 workers.
PAGENO="0043"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 35
long as 10 years, or even longer if required. But an adjustment as-
sistance program, to be effective, must emphasize rapid readaptation
The length of the adjustment or transition period in which assistance
will be needed, will, of course, depend on the rate at which Federal
foreign trade policy will allow imports to increase over time. How-
ever, business firms should not be allowed to set their own pace in
readapting, and not take advantage of public assistance longer than
conditions call for.
There exists, however, another area in a readjustment program to
increased imports where the Small Business Administration could
step in without going counter to its general orientation. That part
of the program includes cases where outright liquidation rather than
adaptation of an enterprise would be advisable in the national in-
terest This contingency may arise for units in certain handicraft or
exceedingly labor-intensive industries. In a healthy economy ex-
posed to a gradual trade liberalization the number of concerns that
would fall into this category would be fairly small. With a view to
preserving at least a semblance of financial respectability, it would not
be advisable, in a statutory readjustment program, to authorize out-
right grants or indemnities for nonproductive purposes. Therefore,
liquidation loans on exceptionally easy terms, patterned upon the flood
and disaster loan provisions of the Small Business Act,23 would~ con-
stitute a valuable adjunct to an import adjustment program.
The theoretical objections to using the Small Business Administra-
tion as an instrument in a readjustment program other than for
handling liquidation loans have been stated. Before considering
practical objections, it would be normally expected that alternative
arrangements be explored. In this particular case, however, this
exploration will prove to be short and unsuccessful for this reason.
In theory a number of important considerations can be brought
forward in favor of making the Export-Import Bank the agent for
readaptation assistance loans.24 In practical terms, however, the
weight of informed opinion appears to lean heavily against placing the
primarily domestic function of governmental assistance to increased
competitive imports with an agency exclusively concerned with over-
seas operations. The Small Business Administration, therefore, would
appear to be best suited for administering loans under an adjustment
assistance program.
OUTLINE OF A TRADE ADJUSTMENT PROGRAM
Federal aid to overcome the effects of increased import competition
would best be focused on the individual business enterprise, the eco-
nomic unit most exposed to any adverse effect from increased com-
petition. For broader types of assistance the Federal Government
can be relied on to backstop State and local adjustment measures in
the course of performing its ordinary functions designed to further
the public welfare.25
~ 1~5 U.S.C,A., par. 63t6(b). See also Hoover Commission, "Task Force Report on Lend.
ing Agencies," pp. 233-2~4.
~ See my "Lower Tariffs Without Pain," Michigan State Business Topics, May 1956,
p. 19.
~ Area Redevelopment Act of 19:61, Public Law 87-27 (May 1. 1961).
PAGENO="0044"
36 ThADE ADJ1JSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
A prime advantage of concentrating such assistance on individual
business enterprises would be that it would make it easier to part sheep
from goats. In the course of conducting escape clause and other
types of investigations, the Tariff Commission has acquired a sub-
stantial body of experience and of precedents for attributing injury
to increased competitive imports. By not including communities as
direct aid recipients under the program, its administration will be
materially simplified: For even in a depressed one-industry town there
will invariably be numerous lines of causation leading to what eco-
nomic dislocation there may be present, and many of these would not
be even remotely connected with increased import competition. If,
therefore, no new Federal aid were programed for communities as
such, other than what would be made available to local business firms
eligible for trade adjustment aid, there would be no need, in the proc-
ess of determining eligibility for assistance, for going into and sepa-
rating out causes underlying such economic distress as may be found
in the community, and thereby complicate the administration of the
program.
F~unctions of cooperating agencies
The philosophy behind Federal aid in trade adjustment is that it
would be used as an inducement to adapt more rapidly operations of
individual business enterprises to changed competitive conditions
brought on by increased imports. In order to have an effective pro-
gram, that philosophy must be adhered to throughout the adjustment
program's operations.
As the individual enterprise will be assumed to be the focal point of
assisted readjustment, it does not seem advisable to set up a special ad-
justment assistance board or other separate administrative body. At
the center of the program would be the U.S. Tariff Commission. A
finding of injury or threat of injury by the Commission would trig-
ger the adjustment assistance apparatus. The Commission would be
empowered to recommend such a program for an industry or portion
of industry, as an alternative to the restoration of withholding of
tariff concessions under an escape-clause or peril-point investigation.26
Putting such additional responsibility on the Tariff Commission
might require that the Commission be provided with additional staff.
Such additional staff could be placed into a trade adjustment division
to be newly created. The staff of this new division, in the performance
of its task, could then draw upon the services of the other divisions
of the Commission, as well as on those of the appropriate departments
and agencies of the executive branch.
Another function of this new division of the Tariff Commission
would be to conduct or to supervise the efficiency investigations of
firms applying for adjustment assistance. This requirement may
well raise a number of complications. Nevertheless, in the interest of
fairness and efficacy, such a determination cannot be shirked, for
gross inefficiency may be an important contributory element to injury
suffered.
~ In order to permit certain types of readaptations that would require time for becoming
effective, the Commission's finding might be in some cases accompanied by a restoration of
the concession for stated limited time only, and on a downward sliding scale. (See Randall
Commission, "Staff Papers," p. 387, and quotation at the end of this chapter, below.)
PAGENO="0045"
TRADE ADJuSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
37
An efficiency investigation is called for in cases handled by the
Tariff Commission under section 337 of the Tariff Act of 1930, as
amended, the section dealing with "unfair competition" from im-
ports. (In recent practice this section has been used mainly for
investigations of alleged patent infringements by foreign producers.)
In investigations under section 7 of the Trade Agreements Extension
Act, as amended, the so-called escape clause, no formal efficiency in-
vestigation of applicant firms is called for. It is known, however,
that the Commission for internal use has not infrequently collected
information on the quality of managerial practices inside the firms
under consideration, as well as on methods of marketing and other
matters pertaining to efficiency of operation. Such information is
almost never made public.27
Recommendations of the Tariff Commission concerning readjust-
ment assistance to be made available would be directed to a Standing
Committee on Trade Adjustment. On this Standing Committee
would be represented, in addition to the Commission, one of whose
representatives could act as Chairman, other agencies of the Federal
Government as necessary.
Four elements of primary responsibility would be involved in the
operation of this Standing Committee. These would be divided
among various Federal departments and agencies as follows:
1. Determination of need for assistance, and referral: Tariff
Commission.
2. Decision on amount of assistance needed: Standing Com-
mittee.
3. Rendering of technical assistance: Departments of Comrn
merce and Labor.
4. Financing of services and loans: Treasury Department and
Small Business Administration.
Agencies of secondary responsibility in the trade adjustment appa-
ratus, and thus represented on the Standing Committee, would be the
State Department, the Administration for International Develop-
ment (on account of matters of foreign trade, foreign aid, and foreign
economic policy involved in the program); the Departments of De-
fense, Agriculture, and Interior (as being familiar and concerned
with the problems of particular industries that might be involved
in the program) ; 28 the Department of Health, Education, and Wel-
fare, and the Executive Office of the President.
Within the Standing Committee, a steering group consistino' of
representatives of the Tariff Commission, the Department of
merce, and the Small Business Administration would be established
to expedite proceedings of the full Committee. The steering group
would have powers to coordinate agency functions and force necessary
action to be taken.
`~ The one apparent exception to this rule in recent years is found in U.S. Tariff
Commission, "Motorcycles and Parts," Report on the Escape Clause Investigation (Rept.
No. 180, second series), Washington, D.C., 1953. (The report was first released in June
1952.) On pages 7 and 8 of this report the majority of the Commission ascribes the
decline in the profits of the principal domestic manufacturer in part to "substantially
increased overhead expense resulting from the major expansion of the company's production
facilities" undertaken at a time when demand for motorcycles had sharply decreased, and
resulting in a large volume of unutilized capacity at a time when the company could ill
afford the "increase in the costs of depreciation and maintenance of expanded plant and
facilities that have not been fully utilized."
`~ The Departments of Commerce and Labor, already represented on the Committee,
would share in this secondary responsibility.
PAGENO="0046"
38 TRADE ADJ1JSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRA~PICE
For several of the agencies involved in administering the proposed
program, some modification in normal function would be necessary.
The agencies concerned are: the Tariff Commission, whose activities
would be widened in a manner already indicated; and the Small Busi-
ness Administration, whose functions would be widened to include the
granting of trade adjustment loans.29 Otherwise the readjust-
ment assistance mechanism here outlined essentially utilizes existing
facilities within the executive branch of the Government.
In granting loans to individual business enterprises, the criterion
used' should be a "reasonable assurance of repayment" of the loan.
This' test, currently used, for example, by the Export-Import Bank in
granting loans under its charter, should be sufficiently flexible so as
not to bring the Government lending agency cooperating in the pro-
gram in competition with private capital and lending institutions.
It should be noted also that the grouping of cooperating agencies
would keep responsibility for dislocations caused by the Federal Gov-
ernment's trade policy essentially within the jurisdiction of the Fed-
eral agencies concerned with foreign trade. A clearer picture of the
administrative accomplishments of the program and of its effects on
the economy would thus be obtained than if a more complex adxninis-
trative arrangement were instituted.
Once assistance has been granted, it would probably be appropriate
to require participating enterprises to submit to annual reviews
throughout their transition periods. The newly to be established
Readjustment Division of the Tariff Commission would be an appro-
priate instrument for conducting these reviews, reporting to the
Standing Committee.3°
How the progratim woi~ld operate
Under the proposed trade adjustment program devoted primarily
to relieving the individual business enterprise of distress caused by
increased imports, assistance granted would be chiefly in the form
of loans, from the Small Business Administration. The Department
of Commerce would have opportunity of providing technical services,
in conjunction with the Department of Labor. Such services are
unlikely to require expansion of current staffs and facilities.
The procedure would start with announced tariff reduction. There
actually would have to be a certain lapse of time after the tariff reduc-
tion went into effect so as to be sure that imports would in fact
increase.31 When imports have in effect increased, the Tariff Com-
mission would have to determine injury or threat of injury. Transi-
tional readjustment periods set for every industry or commodity group
affected by probable increases in imports. The length of the transi-
~ In the case of assistance granted to marginal producers, assistance to workers employed
by them also will often be necessary. The Department of Labor in addition to its con-
sultatory functions in the entire program area, and the Department of Health, Education,
and Welfare, would be specifically responsible for making effective aid available to such
workers. Workers would receive priority treatment under existing social security and
unemployment benefit regulations. No additional administrative machinery would be
required.
~0 procedure would be patterned on the annual reviews now conducted by the Tariff
Commission on commodities for which relief has been granted under the escape-clause
provision of the Trade Agreement Extension Act, under Executive Order 10401.
~ Many rates of duties have been lowered In the past and Imports have decreased.
PAGENO="0047"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 39
tion period would reflect the best available judgment on the time it
would take to carry out necessary adjustments in each case.32
The Standing Committee administering the program would then
call for applications from firms desiring assistance in making certain
needed changes in operations. Petitioners would have to show proof
of being entitled to assistance. A finding of entitlement for assistance
would probably have to be based on grounds of reasonable presump-
tion of injury suffered or threatened. Without such latitude adminis-
tration of assistance in readapting to increased imports would become
too rigid and hence less useful.
One additional point worthy of mention concerns interphasing of
adjustment assistance and temporary protection until the adjustment
program has had its desired effect. The report of the special staff of
the study of U.S. foreign commerce of the Senate Committee on Inter-
state and Foreign Commerce makes the following suggestion:
Even after the Government has had an opportunity to extend approprIate
assistance in cases of incipient or serious injury resulting from imports, com-
plaints of serious injury or the threat of serious injury may still persist. In
this event, it is possible that some form of temporary trade restriction may be
necessary-a limitation of exports by the exporting country or of imports b37
the United States. Such action may be necessary to provide time for the adjust-
ment remedies to take effect. Action of this kind would exceed the authority of
the proposed agency administering the program.
In what form such an auxiliary program should be written into
law is a question that could not be dealt with in the present study.
~ The length of the transition period would interact with, or reciprocally determine
the amount of assistance to be provided: the longer the period, the better the chance for
the dust to settle, and the smaller the amount of assistance required. The question to be
posed in each case would be: What is the economically most feasible way of correcting
the inflicted or threatened dislocation? Once determination is made, performance must not
be modified.
~ "The United States and World Trade: Challenges and Opportunities," Washington,
D.C., 1961, p. 158. A similar idea appeared in Randall Commission "Staff Papers," p. 387.
PAGENO="0048"
PAGENO="0049"
CHAPTER VI
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN MANUFACTURING: THE
LEATHER GLOVE INDUSTRY IN FULTON COUNTY,
N.Y.
In the next three chapters appear three illustrative case studies
of hypothetical adjustment programs as applied to three industries.
These industries either suffer, among other things, from increased
competitive imports, or they are likely to be subjected to dislocation in
the event of a trade liberalization. These case studies are designed
to present some of the problems involved in applying a readjustment
program to a specific industry. Brief background statements on each
individual industry serve to set the stage for discussing the problem of
trade adjustment in manufacturing, in agriculture, and in mining.
THE LEATHER GLOVE INDUSTRY IN FULTON COUNTY
A "one-industry community" provides the first illustrative applica-
tion. The leather and fabric gloves industries located in Gloversville,
N.Y., have been injured by imports 1 and other circumstances. They
have not succeeded in making a constructive readaptation to the situa-
tion on their own, despite energetic efforts at both the local and State
level to assist them with readjustment.
In a one-industry community, alternative employment and invest-
ment opportunities are scarce. Competition from imports, added
to other detrimental influences, generally is aggravating an already
critical employment situation. As a result, business enterprises in
the community and the workers employed by them at least in theory
ought to be willing to respond with alacrity to outside assistance o~-
fered with a view to putting an end to the dislocation. The fact that
the response so far has been anything but favorable adds to the com-
plexity of the problem.2
Piquet ~ has estimated that leather gloves are the third largest
group of commodities the imports of which would at least double, if
not multiply threefold or fourfold, were a suspension of tariffs to be
instituted. Moreover, because the domestic market for gloves is stag-
Though not seriously enough to warrant relief under sec. 7 of the Trade Agreements
Extension Act, the escape clause. See note 2.
2 The following account is based chiefly on secondary sources. A brief sketch of possible
readjustments in the leather glove industry was given in the present writer's "Adjust-
ment to Imports and the National Interest," Chicago ~ournal of Business, October 1953.
Much descriptive material Is found in National Planning Association, "Local Impact of
Foreign Trade," Washington,, D.C., 19~O, Technical Supplement A. "Report on Fulton
County. N.L," by Betti Goidwasser and Gizella Huber, For more recent information
on women's and children's leather gloves, see U.S. Tariff Commission, "Women's and
Children's Leather Gloves," report on escape-clause investigation No, 7-82 under see. 7
of the Trade Agreements Extension Act of 1951. as amended, Washington, March 1960.
8 See his "Aid, Trade and the Tariff," pp. 25 and 47.
76697-~61---~--4 41
PAGENO="0050"
42 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
nant, producers of leather gloves are quite vulnerable to an eventual
lowering of tariffs.4 The increase in wool gloves imports-cut and
sewn fabric gloves, as well as seamless knit gloves-would probably
be "moderate." ~
The bulk of the American leather glove industry is concentrated
in one upstate New York area, Fulton County.6 For some years
(Marth 1952 to September 1955) this area was classified as one of
substantial labor surplus.7
Gloversville and Johnstown are twin cities which contain the bulk
of Fultoñ County's population (53,000 in 1954) and industry. The
economy of the two towns and of the county revolves around gloves.
The leather industry (glovemaking and leather tanning) accounts
for about two-thirds of the manufacturing employment of about 10,000
people in Fulton County. Altogether, nearly 90 percent of the area's
factory workers are closely allied with the glove industry, including
the production of knit gloves, glove linings, knit fabric production,
and cut and sewn fabric gloves from knit fabric.
Glovemaking entails seasonal employment. But glove firms make
it a practice to recall workers for orders coming in, and then laying
them off when orders are completed. This practice affords a consid-
erable volume of partial work. The staggering of work (or stagger
week) is undertaken in agreement with the unions. Most wage earners
earn some money during half of the week, and draw unemployment
compensation for the remainder of the week. Unemployment bene-
fits are less quickly exhausted, and workers can meet the minimum re-
quirement of 20 weeks employment and of earning at least $300 in any
given year in order to be eligible for unemployment benefits.8
Because of these arrangements the Gloversville area has been able
to get along through years of successive crises. Another, and perhaps
even more important reason is that in many families both husband
and wife work in the glove factories: Even when they are both job-
less, they can subsist on unemployment insurance and other social
benefits.
A third saving feature until recently has been the proximity of
Schenectady with its strong demand for labor. In late 1953, for
example, some 2,500 Fulton County residents worked for General
Electric or Alco Products there, or at the Naval Ordnance Depot at
Scotia. An additional 500 or 600 were employed by the carpet mills
at Amsterdam.
THE DOMESTIC LEATHER GLOVE INDUSTRY
Early tariff protection of glovemaking in the United States9 en-
couraged an industry which has become essentially uneconomic on
~ See also Humphrey~ Don D., "American Imports" (New York 1955) p. 401.
6 Piquet, op. cit., p. 89.
~ Nearly two-thirds of all leather-glove producing plants are located in New York State.
A smaller concentration of plants exists in Wisconsin and illinois.
See also Randall Commlission, "Staff Papers," pp. 401-406.
~ Unemployment insurance and related payments constitute a subsidy to the community.
In view of the stable character of the arrangements in Fulton County, these payments
have constituted a sustaining, not an adaptive, intervention on the part of the Government.
9 development of the domestic industry was fostered by a protective tariff in 1862.
In 1872 the tariff on imported skins was removed, paving the way for the manufacture of
fine gloves. See Goldwasser and Huber. bc. cit., p. 36.
PAGENO="0051"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 43
the American scene because it does not readily lend itself to mechaniza-
tion.1° Individual producers are unwilling to consolidate operations,
partly because of their traditional independence, partly also because
they are unwilling to give up entrepreneurial status, no matter how
large the gain in income. Another obstacle is the continued emphasis
on high quality production: both manufacturers and workers are un-
willing to shift, for example, to producing leather work gloves, or
to the less expensive varieties of dress gloves. Because of these atti-
tudes, Fulton County glovemakers have failed to take advantage of
opportunities which might have provided them with steadier employ-
ment and income.
A further contributory factor to the local industry's weakness is
the fact that Fulton County concentrates on women's leather gloves
rather than on men's leather gloves. Because competition from
imports in women's leather gloves is stronger, the industry is to that
extent more vulnerable.1'
The leather glove industry consists in the main of small family-
type enterprises. In 1954, 54 of the 143 establishments reporting to
the census employed 1 to 4 employees, with an average of 2.4; only
2 establishments had over 250 employees, and only 1 of them over
500.
In 1939, New York State accounted for 66 percent of the total of
233 leather dress glove factories in the country, 62 percent of the total
wage earners, and 60 percent of the total value of product. In 1947,
the corresponding figures were 83 percent of 252 establishments, 73
percent of wage earners, and 77 percent of total value of product. In
1954, the percentages were 78 (143 establishments only), 73, and 74.
Practically all of these establishments are in Fulton County.
Glovemaking is a labor-intensive industry. In 1954, 56 percent of
value added by manufacture was made up of production workers
wages, as compared with 40.1 percent for manufacturing as a whole.
The manufacture of leather dress gloves is essentially a handicraft
industry, the only machines used being a sewing machine for machine-
sewn gloves, and a diecutting device for the cheaper grades. Cutting
of gloves determines their quality and price. High-quality table-cut
gloves use only the very best skins. Lower quality skins are used for
pattern and clicker-cutting. Cutters are always men and are the most
skilled and highly paid workers.'2
The sewing machine operators, chiefly women, usually specialize in
one type of stitching, but not in any particular operation. After hav-
ing been sewn, the gloves are dampened and fitted on heated hand-
shaped forms of proper size to be pressed (laid off). Men perform this
operation. Finally, the gloves are brushed, provided with buttons or
snaps, inspected, and prepared for shipment.
~° In this respect, the situation facing the leather glove industry is the reverse of that
In which the glass and china industries find themselves.
]1 In men's leather gloves, Fulton County competes with the Midwest. Rather than on
style, as in women's gloves, competition In men's gloves is based on efficiency of production
and variety of price line.
2 Sewing of gloves Is done by machine in the United States, because handsewing is too
expensive at domestic wage rates. ~abor costs have in many instances been reduced by
shipping glove tranks to the Philippines for sewing by hand, or to Puerto Rico where they
are either hand or machine-sewn.
PAGENO="0052"
44 TRADE ADJuSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRA(~I'ICE
THE CUT AND SEWN FABRIC GLOVE INDUSTRY
Fulton County accounts for less than 5 percent of domestic
production of these gloves; they have gained in importance in re-
cent years. Fabric glove production has served to even out seasonal
fluctuations in employment in leather glovemaking. Fabric gloves can
be cut by machine, and a dozen or more pairs can be handled at one
time. Sewing is similar to the sewing of leather gloves. Rates are
generally lower because the materials are easier to handle than leather.
Production of fabric gloves may either be carried on separately, or in
conjunction with leather gloves production. But in Fulton County
fabric glove plants are more highly mechanized than leather glove
plants. Batches of fabric gloves processed are also much larger than
in leather glove plants, and various laborsaving devices, including
assembly line methods, are used.
The fabric gloves industry shows less of a geographic concentration
than leather gloves. In part this is due to a desire for integration
with the manufacture of fabrics, an industry in which wages are lower
than in the leather glove industry. But in part the manufacturers
prefer not to deal with independent unions such as those in Fulton
County.
THE SEAMLESS KNIT GLOVE INDUSTRY
As of early 1956, out of 17 primary producers of knit dress gloves,
5 were in Fulton County. Knit glove plants are small, and located in
old buildings several stories high, as are leather glove plants. Ma-
chinery, more specialized than leather gloves machinery, is kept up to
date; knit glove plants have their own machine shops to improve pat-
terns and adjust for new types of stitches.13 Routing inside the plant
also is more efficient than in leather glove factories.
The production process of knit gloves is similar for both men and
women's gloves.14 The cuff is knitted on a machine in a long tube,
with individual cuff lengths linked by separating tiireads, later re-
moved by hand. The cuff is then slipped on a machine which knits on
hands, with separating threads for thumb openings and fingers. At
this stage patterns may be introduced. One worker, usually a man,
can handle from six to eight knitting machines, set for a variety of
stitches and color combinations. The machines are large and costly,
and are usually installed in a plant. The hands and attached cuffs are
then passed to a fingering machine operator-usually a woman-who
picks up stitches with a small hook and slips them on a small knitting
machine, which knits a tube somewhat longer than a thumb. The same
procedure is followed for each finger.15 The tops of fingers and thumbs
are then closed and fastened by hand with a straight needle. The
final operations consist of fulling, brushing, and shaping, done in a
factory, usually by men.
18 seamless knit gloves until recently were manufactured of wool, and style was
not a major element, of late string knit gloves, and embroidered and decorated wool knit
gloves have become not only a larger part of total consumption but also subject to style
competition.
14 The same processes are used for seamless knit linings as for leather gloves.
15 machines are small enough to have this operation carried out on a putting-
out basis.
PAGENO="0053"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 45
DOMESTIC CONSUMPTION
Per capita civilian consumption of dress gloves despite increased
real income, has not changed substantially over prewar level. Popu-
lation trends seem to be adequate to account for the long-range trend.
If the population is assumed to be constant, total expenditure for
gloves may be considered as varying with income. According to
surveys by the Bureau of Labor Statistics,'6 glove expenditures in
two periods-1935--36 and 1950-though varying directly with in-
come in both periods, were lower for all income groups in the later
period, despite a much increased average income. In both periods,
geography and climate had an important influence on demand for
gloves; thus persons in the same income level spent less on gloves in
the South than in the North.
Consumer tastes show two long-range shifts in preferences for ap-
parel, both away from gloves. One is a trend toward lighter clothing
accounted for by better heated automobiles, and better heating in
homes and offices. The other trend is a shift toward less formal
attire.
Among short-term influences on demand for gloves, the two most
important are the weather and style changes. The role of price in the
shift from leather to fabric gloves is not clear-cut because of price
overlaps. A highly styled and embroidered fabric glove may be sub-
stantially more expensive than a plain leather glove, even of good
quality, but in general more women's fabric gloves are being bought
because they cost less than leather gloves.
Income changes also have an important short-term influence on
demand for gloves. The purchase of gloves is a postponable item and
expenditures on gloves are more subject to fluctuation than personal
expenditures of higher priority.
IMPORT COMPETITION
The domestic glove industry for some years has been denouncing
foreign imports and has been arguing for higher tariffs. The impact
of import competition varies for different types of gloves.
Leather gloves
Leather glove manufacturers are concerned with various types of
foreign competition. In women's gloves, chiefly from France and
Italy, competition of imported gloves is mainly in terms of styles and
prestige rather than in terms of price, although there is some price-
competition in the lower brackets.'7 In men's leather gloves, however,
domestic producers are able to compete successfully in the lower
brackets even on a price basis. But the lower price of the cheapest
foreign women's leather gloves has forced domestic producers to
maintain an unprofitable low-priced line in order to compete with im-
ports and to offer a full range to retailers. As far as Fulton County
is concerned, the appearance of injury is greatest in women's gloves
and in men's table-cut-highest quality-gloves, for which Fulton
`~ Cited by Goldwasser and Huber, op.. cit.
17 See also U.S. Tariff Commission, "Women's and Children's Leather Gloves," above.
The Commission refused to make a finding of injury in this particular investigation.
PAGENO="0054"
46 TRADE AD,TUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
County is the major source in this country. Because of emphasis on
women's gloves, imports also appear to affect Fulton County more
than midwestern glove centers.
There seems to be no technical or economic reason why Fulton
County producers could not broaden their operation into fields of
glove production where domestic producers can meet foreign competi-
tion at existing wage rates, utilizing mass production methods or
more highly mechanized operations. Domestic producers of men's
leather gloves can compete successfully with imports because men's
gloves are more standardized than women's gloves. Domestic pro-
ducers also compete successfully in block-and-pattern cut gloves,
which are lower priced and produced with less hand labor than table-
cut gloves.
Imports in men's gloves come traditionally in the high-quality
and high-price brackets, leaving lower price ranges for domestic
gloves. There have been no changes in tariff rates on men's leather
gloves since 1948.18
Competition is substantially greater in women's leather gloves, as
noted. Duties on these have not been raised either since 1948, except
for an adjustment in the rate schedule for Unlined gloves at Torquay
in 1950.19
Cut and sewn fabric gloves
Germany was the main source of imports of cotton fabric gloves be-
fore 1933. Thereafter imports decreased, and domestic production
began to rise, chiefly of fabric knitted on thread machines.20 There
was an insufficient number of socalled Simplex machines in this
country to manufacture a fabric that can be treated on both sides
so as to look like suede, and which accounted for most of the imports.
Gradually more Simplex machines were introduced in this coun-
try, and after the war the domestic industry appeared to be in a
comparatively favorable position. But West Germany regained its
position as major foreign supplier, and Italian and British im-
porters likewise were coming up. By 1954 imports of cut and sewn
fabric gloves had surpassed the 1939 level.
The domestic industry has endeavored to counter this competition by
introducing nylon and "stretch" gloves. But these were rapidly
copied abroad and are now being imported into this country. Japan
has shown signs of being able to step up its exports markedly during
the past several years by introducing a cheap fabric glove which retails
here at a substantially lower price than domestic gloves. As the qual-
ity of the Japanese product improves, difficulties are expected to be
created for the domestic industry, paralleling developments in the
seamless glove industry (see below). Japan has been the major for-
~ign supplier since 1950, with about half its imports coming in in the
cheaper price brackets.
Seam2ess knit gloves
Consumption of `wool gloves in this country showed a steady in-
crease in 1933. Imports from various sources began to increase also,
`8Tbe most recent reductions were made in 1945 and 1948.
`~ See 13.5. Tariff Commission, op. cit.
~ U.S. Tariff Commission, "Summaries of Tariff Information" (Washington, D.C., 1948),
vol. 9, p. 151.
PAGENO="0055"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 47
with Germany and Czechoslovakia accounting for most of the im-
ports, mainly unembroidered. In the later thirties, Japan became
the major source of imports, and embroidered gloves also became more
important.22
During World War II, domestic production of seamless knit gloves
increased appreciably. A large part of the gloves then produced
had leather palms, required by the armed services. But since these
gloves were too expensive for general civilian needs after the war,
the industry probably would have found it difficult to maintain a
market for them, even without increased imports.
Before 1949, when Japan reentered the market, knit gloves valued
at more than $3.50 per dozen pairs were the major category. The
duties on these had been lowered in 1939 in the trade agreement with
the United Kingdom, and rates were further reduced at Geneva in
1948. The following year, the Japanese industry had completed its
recovery and could take advantage of these lower rates so that already
in 1949 imports amounted to about one-third of U.S. domestic pro-
duction; by 1950 they constituted two-thirds.
The Korean war caused another expansion in domestic production,
but by 1958, the industry was back to pre-World War II levels.
In 1954, the industry applied for relief under the escape clause on
wool knit gloves and mittens valued at over $1.75 per dozen pairs.
The Tariff Commission refused to recommend withdrawal of conces-
sions granted on import duties because of the "lighter weight" of
~Japanese gloves which are not competitive with the domestic article
and because unusually high inventories carried over from 1953, as
well as the mild fall weather had made for lower imports in 1954
than would have been the case otherwise. The Commission implied
that after inventories were used up, the domestic industry would
get more orders, or at least an increased share of the total.22
ALTERNATIVES FOR FULTON COUNTY
In the absence of a Federal trade adjustment program, Fulton
County glove producers appear to have several ways of getting them-
selves out of their difficulties: Continue to press for higher tariffs to
protect themselves against competitive imports; 23 undertake a nation-
wide advertising campaign to improve their sales; 24 or take part in a
program of industrial diversification.
Attempts to secure new industries, while less expensive than an
adequate advertising campaign, are complicated by the fact that glove
manufacturers and glove workers do not wish to let glovemaking
become second to another industry. This basic attitude toward
change notwithstanding, some elements in the community have taken
steps to become more adaptable to the new competitive situation.
These adjustment measures will be briefly reviewed before the illus-
trative trade adjustment program is presented.
~ U.S. Tariff Commission, "Summaries of Tariff Information" (Washington, D.C., 1948),
vol. 2, pt. ~ p. 74.
~ U.S. Tariff Commission, "Wool Gloves and Mittens, and Gloves and Mitten Linings of
Wool," report on escape-clause Investigation No. 35, under sec. 7 of the Trade Agreements
Extension Act of 1951 (Washington, D.C., December 1954).
~ Little success has met these efforts thus far.
24 This is considered to be too expenslve~. See Goidwasser and Huber, op. cit.
PAGENO="0056"
48 TRADE ADJ1JSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
UNASSISTED READJUSTMENT MEASURES
Bji manu/actw~ers
Readjustment can be thought of as falling into two categories. The
first is automatic readjustment. This comprises steps taken in re-
sponse to pressures of the moment, without awareness of their ulti-
mate impact. This category meludes persistence in the status quo,
tightening of belts, muddling along and vegetating, in a manner of
speaking. The other category includes action consciously directed to-
ward terminating a particular situation, based on willingness to cope
~with new developments, and acceptance of disruptive consequences
of a relatively bold course of action. Fulton County in the main has
only made the first type of adjustment
Leather glove manufacturers have had to adjust to competition
from domestically produced fabric gloves and leather glove imports.
Some of the larger firms have added fabric gloves to their operation,
others are producing fabric gloves exclusively, and some have added
certain knit specialty items. Until recently, little research and de-
velopment has been undertaken by the leather glove industry to fin-
prove their product, although substitution of fabric gloves for leather
gloves has had an increasing adverse influence on the industry.25
The problem of switching from leather to fabric is not a recent
one, however. During the 1930's, management in the leather glove
industry became aware of the trend toward fabric gloves but con-
sidered it a temporary style-vogue, and made no attempt to adjust
its operations to it. The war years, because of Government contracts,
proved to be sufficiently profitable without such a changeover. What-
ever output could be made available~ for the civilian market, was
readily sold. After the war, the industry finally began to face up to
the threat of fabric gloves, and proposals were presented to the local
labor unions involving a switch in production to nonleather gloves
and in wage rate schedules. But unemployment among glove work-
ers was already mounting. And workers' resistance to a changeover
was increased not only because of a threatened displacement of male
glove cutters,2° but also because the industry's proposal was viewed
as the first sign of decomposition which eventually could affect rate
schedules for leather gloves as well. Labor therefore continued to
insist on piece-work rates for fabric gloves identical with leather
glove piece rates. A number of Gloversville firms are producing fab-
ric gloves, but about four-fifths of the operations are farmed out to
various plants in adjoining areas, because of labor resistance to a
rate schedule revision.
Managerial inefficiency also accounts for the leather glove indus-
try's difficulties. Between 1940 and 1950, only one leather glove
firm in the Gloversville area constructed new plant facilities. The
remainder of the industry continued to own plants fully depreciated
~ A new tanning process, which permits leather gloves to be washed more easily, may
improve the latter s competitive position somewhat.
~` A majority of workers in all glove establishments are women. In leather glove
plants, the ratio is 8 female workers to 1 table cutter (for the highest quality gloves),
and 5 to 6 female workers to 1 block cutter (the less expensive variety). The ratio for
cut and sewn fabric gloves Is similar, if not greater, for out and sewn fabric gloves.
PAGENO="0057"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 49
decades ago. Inability to cut costs in the past, and ever-increasing
reluctance to take risks currently, have encouraged operations with
obsolescent plant and inadequate capital investment.2~
By labor
Trade unions in the leather glove industry have always insisted on
"equal distribution of work." This insistence has resulted in shorter
hours, shorter workweek, and skip-week employment, instead of
steady work for one part of the labor force and extended layoffs for
the other. The impact of seasonal operations on the glove workers'
families has thereby been reduced. Those who worked only every
other week, or every third week, could draw unemployment benefits
for intervening idle periods. Those who worked 3 days a week or
tess could draw partial benefits.
Many more families in Fulton County than elsewhere have two or
more wage earners. The 1950 census (although taken in April, an
off-season month in glovemaking), showed 41 percent women in
Fulton County's labor force, compared with a New York State aver-
age of 32 percent.28
Another circumstance tending to weaken workers' willingness to
readapt has been that the unions representing the majority of local
leather glove workers have no affiliation with other labor organiza-
tions for glove workers. Of limited outlook, their activities have
tended to be concerned solely with local problems and have shown an
almost medieval rigidity. Glove cutters, for example, have not per-
mitted a tablecutter to do block or pattern cutting and the other way
round. For many years also the cutters union has restricted ap-
prenticeship, allowing only sons of members to serve the 3 years' ap-
prenticeship required for table cutters.29
The postwar shift to employment outside Fulton County has been
brought about as much by the attraction of high wage rates in defense
work as by the lack of local opportunities. But even though it is an
hour's drive from Gloversville to Schenectady, practically nobody
appears to have moved closer to their work. Scarcity of housing and
preference for local amenities may explain this immobility.
Another factor making for immobility has been homeownership
in the Gloversville area.8° According to the 1950 Census of Popula~.
tion, about one-fourth of the houses in Fulton County are owned
mortgage-free-a higher ratio than for New York State as a whole
(22 percent). This high percentage of homeownership means that
more cash is available for other living expenses, since there are no rent
payments, and repairs and maintenance can be postponed. As a re-
sult, the possibility of higher income elsewhere becomes less attractive.
Being relatively comfortably situated, the older people tend to
remain in the community. The old homes have a comparatively small
resale value, and there is a little opportunity to sell. The presence of
so many older people means that the local labor force is of higher than
average age. In late 1954, the average glove cutters' age was reported
`~ With the sewing machine essentially the most important piece of equipment in a
leather glove plant, modernization would have to be chiefly environmental.
28This appears to be a carryover from the days when homework was prevalent in the
industry. In New York State, homework has been outlawed since May 1942.
~ After World War II, the union admitted 82 apprentices under the "01 bIll." How-
ever, by the end of 1954, all but three of these newcomers had left the industry, mostly
for better paying or more steady employment elsewhere.
80 Goidwasser and Huber, op. cit.
PAGENO="0058"
50 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
to be about 60; a large proportion of the men working in the indus-
tries were in their sixties and seventies. But with shrinking employ-
ment dpportunities in the area, there has come a reduction of the
skilled labor force. The Consolidated Cutters and Shavers Union of
Fulton County (now part of the Amalgamated Clothing Workers)
dropped in membership from 2,000 before the war to 850 in late 1953.
This decrease was in part due to the fact that members that died or
retired were not replaced.
By the comm'unity aind local authorities
*Gloversville faces considerable handicaps in attracting new indus-
tries. There is no suitable factory space to move into. The vacant
glove factories are usually several stories high, with small rooms,
and of unsound construction. The buildings would be suitable for
the apparel industry, but local interests are opposed to this type of
industry because of the high turnover of the firms in it, and also be-
cause the apparel season coincides too closely with the glove season.
Gloversville also lacks railroad facilities. There is no rail passenger
service, and only a single track spur for freight.
Late in 1953 a group of Gloversville residents began to make a
study of the community's social and economic problems, and investi-
gate possible solutions. Their efforts resulted in a mimeographed
"Report on Gloversville" in early 1954, dealing with all problem
areas, but offering no remedial proposal other than greater commu-
nity cooperation in general.
About the same time the Gloversville Development Corporation,
more recently merged with a similar Johnstown organization to form
the Fulton County Development Corporation, began its efforts to
attract new industry.31 The first major newcomer was a record manu-
facturing company (Decca-Brunswick), which established a plant in
Gloversville, employing 300 workers in early 1954. The development
corporation raised $30,000 by selling stock to local businessmen at
$10 a share. Two-thirds of the proceeds were spent in buying the
lease on an abandoned plant, and paying transitional operating ex-
penses, while negotiations were in progress. The New York State
Department of Commerce assisted the development corporation
through the negotiations, and the New York State Employment Serv-
ice helped in screening applicants for the new plant. The develop-
ment corporation since then has encouraged other small industries to
locate in the county, and has helped at least one local industry to
expand.32
AN ILLUSTRATIVE TRADE ADJUSTMENT PROGRAM
Introductory note
A detailed program of industrial diversification would have to be
preceded by a survey of all opportunities for establishing new indus-
tries in the area. Not only would these industries have to be screened
for the size of their employment multiplier, but also for impervious-
~` Also formed was the Joint Industrial Development Committee of the Gloversvllle
and Johnstown Chambers of Commerce.
~` A New York Business Development Corporation was set up in February 1955 (Laws
of New York, ch. 868 of the Laws of 1955, art v-A of the Banking Law) which finances
small businesses in ned of medium term credit.
PAGENO="0059"
TRADE ADJ1JSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 51
ness to economic fluctuations. Community efforts of the type exem-
plified by the "Report on Gloversville" will be of help in this task,
provided they can be kept up to date.
The resources of the Federal Government also could be put at the
disposal of the community and of the State with a view to getting
such a survey underway. The survey also would present the prob-
lems involved in establishing new industries in the area to private
interests and provide an incentive for them to take advantage of
business opportunities hitherto not recognized.33
Through the survey, acceptable industrial projects would be iden-
tified which would promise to expand and stabilize employment in
the area. It is fairly evident that any new industries brought into
Fulton County would have to operate on a relatively small scale in
view of the lack of transportation and industrial raw materials. The
manufacture of parts for electronic equipment, of plastics, or of work
gloves, for example, would conform to these environmental circum-
stances.34
Tariff Commission's finding
The program of assisted readjustment would start to operate with
the industry or the firm making application to the Tariff Com-
mission for relief from injury suffered or threatened by increased
competitive imports under the provisions of section 7 of the Trade
Agreement Extension Act (the escape clause) ~ In contrast to cur-
rent practice, the Commission would be authorized to recommend
assisted readjustment of the firms being parties to the investigation,~
as an alternative to higher rates of duty or other forms of traditic~na1
relief involving import restrictions.36 The Commission then would
instruct the Readjustment Division (newly to be established) to pre-
pare a preliminary report on the situation, with appropriate sub-
stantive recommendations for adjustment relief. Report and rec-
ommendations then would be transmitted to the Interagency Standing
Committee.37
The Interagency Standing Committee
After appropriate study of the report presented by the Tariff Com-
mission, the Standing Committee would decide that, whereas the glove
industry in general has been faced with a difficult problem because
of suddenly increased imports (due to lowered trade restrictions), the
firms needing relief most urgently were those in the Fuiton County
area. The Committee thereupon would instruct a marketing and
~ The technical details of such survey, including criteria for the establishment of new
industries, cannot be gone into here.
~ No attempt will be made here to deal with these potential new industries in greater
detail.
~ The fact that as recently as March 1960 the U.S. Tariff Commission felt impelled to
deny an application for relief brought before it by the women's and children's leather glove
industry would seem to make institution of an alternative method of relief that much more
desirable.
~ The existence of adjustment assistance provisions would have to loosen criteria used
by the Tariff Commission under sec. 7. This' point needs further Investigation. A tempo-
rary raising of rates of duties, interphasing with the adjustment program, need not be
ruled out. See last paragraph of chapter v, above.
~ This first step could actually be simplified in this manner: The Tariff Commission
even under present procedure has to undertake a considerable amount of economic analysis
for each of its investigations under the escape clause. The Commission at present does
not publish ` this analysis. By "declassifying" the substance of such material, the Com-
mission could use it as a basis for informal recommendations appended to its escape-clause
report, without encumbering the docket with additional, very probably repetitive, docu-
mentatiou.
PAGENO="0060"
52 TRADE ADJuSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
engineering survey to be made, in cooperation with the field and re-
gional offices of the TJ.S. Department of Commerce and U.S. Depart-
ment of Labor, and of the New York State Department of Labor
and Commerce.
Result of survey
The survey is carried out with assistance from the local chambers
of comm~rce and the Industrial Development Corp. On the basis
of information developed through the survey, the Commerce De-
partment recommends that one fabric and five leather glove plants
undertake conversion to other types of production-with assistance,
as necessary, and that three small leather glove producers be assisted
in liquidating operations in an orderly manner. The six firms in-
volved in the recommended conversion employ more than 50 workers,
the fabric glove concern more than 100.
The cost of the survey amounts to $20,000. This cost is absorbed
by the agencies cooperating, acting "in line of duty."
Recommendation is made that the five leather glove firms be given
assistance so as to enable them to undertake production of electronic
component parts. The facilities of the fabric glove firm are found
suitable for producing work gloves as a sideline, after procurement
of additional equipment for chemical treatment and dipping.38
Review and financing of program
The Standing Committee approves the recommendations, and in-
structs the financial agencies cooperating in the program (the Small
Business Administration, at the Federal level, and the New York State
Business Development Corp. at the State level) to proceed with ar-
ranging the actual financing of the program.
For the three small leather glove producers, liquidation loans are
arranged for by the Small Business Administration, at a total cost
of $45,000. The fabric glove concern undertaking to produce work
gloves is assisted in obtaining a $350,000 3-year loan with a private
financial institution, with guarantee for the loan provided by the
Small Business Administration. Of the five former leather glove
firms, three decide on merging. This leaves three units to be serviced
by adjustment assistance facilities: Two 5-year loans of $250,000 each
are provided for the two larger plants, both guaranteed by the State
Business Development Corp., in cooperation with the Small Business
Administration. The third concern is eligible for a 5-year, $150,000
loan from the Small Business Administration.
Resumption of production
After a minimum delay occasioned by negotiations of the financial
provisions of the program and implementhtion of required engineer-
ing measures, operations are resumed. The total cost of the program
amounts to $1 million. Spread over 3 years, the annual cost of the
program would be in the neighborhood of $300,000. Actual nonreim-
bursable outlays by Federal and State agencies involved, including
the cost of survey, may be assumed at less than 15 percent of the total
annual cost.39
~ No specific provision is made for retraining workers outside the plants. It is assumed
that they are kept on the payroll and acquire neceesary knowledge of the new processes
as they go along.
80The discussion In the text does not include the possibility of temporary tariff relief,
to be withdrawn after successful adjustment, although a combination of temporary tariff
relief and adjustment assistance deserves further examination. See last paragraph of
Chapter V. above.
PAGENO="0061"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
53
COMPARATIVE COST OF TRADE ADJTJSTMENT
In order to ascertain the gain to be derived from the proposed pro-
gram, its estimated cost may best be compared with the cost of benefits
being made available by units of Government to those affected by
dislocation in Fulton County industry, in the form of unemployment
benefits, social security benefits, and public assistance benefits.
In New York State, maximum weekly unemployment insurance
benefits in 1957 were $36. These benefits are contributory, with em-
ployers paying varying percentages of the first $3,000 of wages paid
each employee. The percentage depends on the employer's record of
stability. The State collects the money, and pays out benefits as and
when needed. No Federal funds are involved, except that administra-
tive costs may be provided from Federal funds, if the U.S. Depart-
ment of Labor deems it necessary.
Social security benefits also are contributory, both by employer and
employee. Payments go into a trust fund, and no further appropria-
tions of Federal funds are necessary. Benefits include retirement and
disability insurance payments, as well as survivor insurance payments
to widows, children, and parents.4°
Public assistance, the third type of benefit to be used in this com-
parison, includes old-age assistance, aid to dependent children, to the
blind, and permanently and totally disabled. Expenditures are split
between the Federal Government and the States, on a pro rata basis.
Funds in this program are channeled through the Federal budget, in
the form of an open-ended appropriation, with deficits made good by
supplemental appropriations at the end of the fiscal year.
In New York State, Federal grants for these several benefits were
disbursed on a per capita basis as follows (for the fiscal year 1952/3) ,41
Employment security, $2; old-age assistance, $3.21; aid to permanently
and totally disabled, $1; aid to dependent children, $2.52. For Fulton
County, the aggregate amounts of these grants can be estimated as
follows: With a 1950 population of 50,021, the Federal contribution
for employment security would have been about $100,000; for old-age
assistance, $161,000; for aid to disabled, $50,000; and for aid to de-
pendent children, $126,000. The total, in round figures, would be
$400,000 per year. But since old-age benefits are not dependent on
the recipient being jobless, they need not be included. The total, then,
reduces to $260,000.
Though not necessarily related to the level of employment in the
county, these expenditures are not productive in the sense that they
cannot be expected to generate income, but merely keep recipients
from becoming destitute. Two-thirds of this money niay be presumed
to be paid out irrespective of the level of prosperity in the county.
A possible saving ot one-third of these outlays, or roughly $150,000,
could be regarded as a gain due to successful readjustment programs.~
State payments in unemployment insurance benefits amount to $36
per claimant per week. For a maximum period of 26 weeks a year,
4° On social security payments as a source of Income, see for example, Schaller, Howard
0., "Social Security Transfer Payments and Differences in State Per Capita Incomes,
1929, 1939 and 1949," Review or Economics and Eftatistics, voL XXXVII, No. 1 (February
1955), pp. 83-89.
°~ "Report of Commission on Intergovernmental Relations," Washington, D.C., June
1955, appendix tables 4 and 5.
4°The amount saved by the State in matching contributions would be considerable, but
of an Indeterminate amount.
PAGENO="0062"
54 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
this would come to a total of $936 (or $950, if rounded) per person per
year.
Just as a two-wage-earner family provides a better living during
periods of employment, so double unemployment benefits make ad-
justment to periods of unemployment less difficult. For Fulton
County, unemployment compensation has in effect become an impor-
tant part of the community's adjustment to economic difficulties.43
The use of the stagger system of spreading employment in the glove
industry results in a maximum number of claimants for unemploy-
ment compensation at any given moment. Glove workers, moreover,
have been habitually reluctant to return to work before their benefits
are exhausted. A household dependent on only one person's benefit
payment could hardly afford to postpone working for so long. But
with two or three payments per household, the pressure to seek other
employment is appreciably reduced.
Old-age and survivors insurance payments also have been carefully
calculated by older workers in setting their employment patterns for
the year. Many workers past the age of 65 continue in the glove in-
dustry. If their earnings do not exceed $1,200 during the year, these
workers remain eligible for old-age insurance benefits. And combined
old-age insurance, unemployment compensation, and wage payments
have provided a fairly comfortable income for husband and wife, even
when employment possibilities were poor.
While unemployment compensation benefits constitute a subsidy
attenuating the effect of economic dislocation, such payments do not
contribute to a cure nor help in the transition toward a cure except
insofar as they aid in maintaining consumer demand in general. In
the long run, expenditures of like amounts by Federal and State
Governments to help establish new industries would probably be of
greater assistance to Fulton County than any form of sustaining
intervention.
Piquet has estimated44 that under a temporary tariff suspension,
imports of leather gloves would increase between 100 and 300 percent,
and would result in imports supplying 23 percent of total domestic
consumption.45 In terms of effect on employment, a 300-percent in-
crease of leather glove imports from the 1953 level, assuming that
the same volume of domestic production is displaced, would mean
imports of 4,792 dozen pairs, and a decrease in domestic production
of 28.9 percent.46 The corresponding loss in employment in Fulton
County's leather glove industry would be about 1,600 workers.
For knit gloves, the tariff has been no barrier to Japanese imports.47
A suspension would increase imports of relatively expensive gloves
from Europe, without, however, causing any further unemployment
in Fulton County.
48 See also Goidwasser and Huber, op. cit.
~ "Aid, Trade, and the Tariff," pp. 25., 74 and passim.
~ In 1953, for example, imports of leather gloves provided only 8.8 percent of total
domestic consumption.
46 See also Goldwasser and Huber, op. cit.
47 Office of Civil and Defense Mobilization on Nov. 20, 1960, ruled that Imports of
wool knit gloves were not threatening the national security, and declined Import restric-
tions to be imposed under see. 8 of the Trade Agreements Extension Act, as amended
(iournal of Commerce, Nov. 21, 1960).
PAGENO="0063"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 55
For cut and sewn fabric gloves, if a tariff suspension resulted in a
10-percent increase in imports, there would be a net displacement of
4,380 dozen pairs of domestic output.48 This would mean about 56
more unemployed workers in Fulton County.
Maximum displacement of workers in Fulton County as a result
of increased imports thus would be about 1,660 workers, or slightly
more than half the average number of unemployment insurance
claimants in 1954. The annual maximum cost to the State in terms
of unemployment insurance payments would be in excess of $1.5 mil-
lion, in the absence of mitigating factors that would tend to reduce
this figure. Since a total suspension of tariffs is unlikely, half the
maximum payment's figure, or $750,000, may be taken as basis for
comparing the cost of coping with the assumed dislocation by means
of sustaining measures, as opposed to a program of constructive
adaptation. This would be the costs borne by the State.
Assuming that applicable Federal expenditures would also increase
by 50 percent, this would represent an annual increase in recurrent
expenditures of $150,000-the potential "savings" noted earlier which
now are not being saved, plus $75,000-the assumed 50-percent in-
crease, giving a total of $225,000 of Federal expenditures per year.
Adding to this `the $750,000 expenditure by the State results in an
annual total of $975,000 per year for an indefinite period. This then
would be the cost of keeping the community going at its traditional
and relatively low level of activity.
The cost of the illustrative readjustment assistance program, in
comparison, could be recapitulated as follows: Technical services for
each of six plants, financed from Federal funds, at $20,000 each,
amounting to $120,000, nonrepayable; plus loans to be gran'ted in a
total amount of $1 million; resulting in annual aid to be granted over
a 5-year period in the amount of approximately $300,000, including
nonrepayable expenditures of $45,000.
The net expenditure involved in an efficiently administered trade
adjustment program would thus be considerably lower than the cur-
rent rate of sustaining expenditures. The probable gain in income
generated by the newly established industries has not been taken into
account in the foregoing rough calculation, but it is evident that that
factor would tip the scales even lower in favor of assisted readaptation.
~ Piquet's analysis applies only to imported commodities that would snpply from 10 to
90 percent of domestic consumption after the tariff suspension. `Cut and sewn gloves are
not included.
PAGENO="0064"
PAGENO="0065"
CHAPTER VII
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN AGRICULTURE:
WOOLGRO WING
We now turn to the agricultural sector. Here the woolgrowing
industry has been chosen to illustrate the problems likely to be en-
countered in applying an adjustment assistance program. This in-
dustry, because of the political power of its members, also typifies
one obstacle to trade liberalization if this kind of program is not put
into practice.
IMPORTS VERSUS DOMESTIC WOOL PRODUCTION
Domestic wool production normally is not adequate to supply do-
mestic needs, and in time of war has fallen far below requirements.
A]though a large portion of wool consumed in the United States has
to be imported, domestic woolgrowers have placed heavy emphasis
on tariffs as a way of supporting wool prices and encouraging produc-
tion. Because of these large imports the domestic wool industry is
heavily dependent on price movements in the international wool mar-
ket. But changes in domestic demand and the nature of the woolen
textile industry have an even greater effect on wool prices.1
In a period of depression, the demand for new clothino~ and for
other products made from wool can drop off very sharply. Zs a result
the demand for raw wool is less continuous and stable than the demand
for other farm products such as foodstuffs. Moreover, the nature
of the woolen textile industry is such that sizable stocks of raw wool
are normally in hands of the mills, importers, speculators, and others.
Stocks of finished woolen goods are held by garment makers and
wholesale and retail handlers. If consumer demand falls off suddenly,
these inventories allow mills and other sectors of the wool trade to
discontinue buying of raw wool for a time while stocks are disposed of.
Severe declines in demand thus are characteristic of the industry.
But wool prices also have a tendency to recover more rapidly than
those of other farm commodities. Price stability, rather than pro-
duction control or tariff protection, is therefore of primary impor-
tance for woolgrowers.
Wool production does not, nor can it be made to, vary greatly from
year to year. The principal method of adjusting supply to increased
or decreased demand has been through variation in imports. During
the 1930's, for example, despite greatly reduced demand, domestic wool
production continued at a high level, but imports fell off sharply.2 In
1 Benedict, M. R., and Stine, 0., "The Agricultural Commodity Programs," (New York,
195:a), p. 3:30.
2 U.s. Agricultural Marketing Service, "Wool Statistics and Related Data" (Stat.
Ruil. 1,42, September 1954), pp. 38 and 80.
76~l97-61---5 57
PAGENO="0066"
58 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
the late twenties imports had been 100 million pounds per year. By
1932 they were down to about 17 million, and they remained fairly
low until 1939. The outbreak of World War II brought a demand
for wool that was far in excess of the amounts the domestic sheep
industry could supply. Between 1942 and 1946, wool imports were
at unprecedented levels, and substantially in excess of the amounts
producted domestically.3 Even in the postwar years, imports were
larger than the amounts produced in the United States. The level of
domestic production continued to be below the amounts required for
domestic consumption into the 1950's.
THE U.S. WOOLOROWING INDUSTRY
Sheep are grown in all of the States, but the large-scale, range-
type sheep production in the West is the principal source of the do-
mestic wool supply.4 In large sections of the West, the rangeland
is marginal for any use except for grazing sheep. The lamb and
wool marketed from the Western States thus form an important share
of the "harvest" from the vast acreage of grazing land. Many farm
areas also carry sheep to utilize feed resources more efficiently. In
irrigated areas, sheep offer a useful means of harvesting legwnes
planted to build up soil fertility, for example.
There is, however, general agreement that it would not be economi-
cally feasible for this country to become self-sufficient in wool pro-
duction; nor does it appear practical to increase domestic wool pro-
duction sufficiently to meet any emergency defense requirements that
might arise. The desirable level of domestic sheep and wool pro-
duction depends upon efficient utilization of domestic production re-
sources, and upon the efficiencies reached in production, marketing,
and processing, and distribution of domestic wool and its products.
One analysis of domestic sources of supply indicates that the graz-
ing and feed resources of the United States would be sufficient for
about 37 million head of stock sheep.6 Annual wool production from
that number of sheep would be about 290 million pounds of shorn wool
and 45 million pounds of pulled wool, the equivalent of about 160
million pounds scoured.7
Numbers of sheep have gone through several cycles since 1884, in
response to price and feed conditions. The most drastic decline, how-
ever, took place between 1942 and 1950, when numbers of sheep and
lambs fell from a near all-time high of over 49 million head to an all-
time low of 26 million. The number of sheep has not appreciably
increased since then.
8 Agricultural Statistics, 1953, p. 378. U.S. Agricultural Marketing Service, supplement
for 1955 to "Wool Statistics and Related Data" (November 1955), p. 10.
4 "Range-sheep States" Include the 11 Western States, Texas and South Dakota. "Na-
tive-sheep States" are all other States where sheep are produced mainly under farm
conditions, usually incidental or supplemental to other enterprises. These States produce
only slightly more than one-fourth of U.S. wool.
"Wool Study Group Report" (1953), p. 43.
6 U.S. Department of Agriculture, "Domestic Wool Requirements and Sources of Supply"
(Washington, D.C., June 1950), p. 62.
`According to a later analysis, using a different set of cost-price relationships, a
balanced livestock population would include about 31 million head of stock sheep, with
an annual production of about 260 million pounds of shorn wool, and about 40 million
pounds of pulled wool, the equivalent of about 144 minion pounds of scoured wool
U.S. Department of Agriculture, "Agriculture's Capacity To Produce" (Washington, D.C.,
June 1952). [Cited In "Wool Study Group Report," p. 43.] Maximum U.S. production
capacity may thus be considered to lie between 260 and 290 million pounds per year, given
a continuation of the price supports and other types of subsidies In force at the time the
estimates were made.
PAGENO="0067"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 59
The decline in sheep numbers during the 1940's resulted primarily
from farmers and ranchers getting out of the sheep business, rather
than merely reducing the size of their flocks. The liquidation of sheep
enterprises was greatest on farms with small flocks, most of which
were in the native States.8
In the early days sheep were raised primarily for their wool. Prior
to 1920, the sale of shorn wool provided some 40 to 50 percent of farm-
ers and ranchers gross income from sheep. But in recent years less
than 30 percent of their gross income has been from the sale of shorn
wool. And even in the Western States where wool is more impor-
tant than in the native States, about 70 percent of family operated
sheep rancher's total cash receipts from their sheep enterprises' is pro-
vided by lamb and sheep sales. However, the price of wool remains
a significant factor in determining the profitableness and hence the
level of sheep and wool production.
For the domestic-sheep industry, the most significant consequence of
World War II was a scarcity and a rise in cost of competent labor. In
the Western States, even family operated sheep ranches were depend-
ent on hired labor for half of their total labor force. Skilled herders
became almost nonexistent. Wage rates for available less-skilled la-
bor increased. The Armed Forces and defense industries cut into
the supply of family labor. Sheep operators who were in a position to
do so began to liquidate their flocks while prices were still relatively
favorable and shifted to cattle raising, which depended less upon hired
labor.
In the native-sheep States the same factors were at work, though
their impact was different. Most flocks were smaller than a hundred
head, being minor farm enterprises designed to utilize unpaid family
labor, feed resources not used by other livestock, and were intended
to augment the relatively low farm incomes of the 1930's. Shortage
and high cost of labor, increased losses caused by dogs and other
predators, and increased incomes received from the major farm enter-
prises caused many farmers to liquidate their sheep enterprises at the
relatively favorable prices which still prevailed in 1942. In the fol-
lowing years the low returns from sheep as compared to returns from
cattle explain the continuing decline in sheep mentioned earlier.
The low incomes of sheep operators were due to a variety of factors:
wool prices remained relatively stable while cattle prices were increas-
ing rapidly; higher production costs were not offset by increases in
efficiency; and competition from synthetic and other fibers was in-
creasing. Uncertainties as to probable impact of foreign and do-
mestic stocks of wool, and of tariff reductions such as those of 1948
also contributed to sheep operators' decision to shift to cattle, or to
get out of the ranching business.°
The hired labor bill on 1,000 ewe sheep ranches in the intermoun-
tam region increased from about $1,700 in 1942 to nearly $5,500 in
1952. During the same period the labor bill of small cattle ranches
only increased from slightly over $100 to about $500.'°
~ Between 1940 and 1950, the number of sheep on farms and ranches declined 42
percent, that of farmers and ranchers reporting sheep, 46 percent.
See "Domestic Wool Requirements and Sources of Supply," p. 52 et seq., for summary
of reasons given by farmers and ranchers for reducing sheep numbers.
10 A less marked disparity has prevailed on family operated sheep and cattle ranches in
the northern Great Plains where many of the sheep are under fence and ranchers depend
less on hired labor. There the net returns on family operated sheep ranches generally
have exceeded that of family operated cattle ranches, but the sheep rancher's investments
~ave been substantially lerger.
PAGENO="0068"
60 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
Efficiency of production is low, and does not counteract high labor
costs: many sheep ranchers are still operating at about the level of
efficiency of 1930-33. Technological advances of crop farmers and
livestock farmers have not been paralleled in the semiarid range areas
of the West.
COMPETITION FROM MANMADE FIBERS
Competition from manmade fibers has had a considerable impact
on the wool industry. Beginning in the prewar period, its rise dur-
ing the postwar period has been striking. Rayon and acetate fibers
we~re the only manmade fibers entering into the wool manufacturing
field before World War II. These have been supplemented by a va-
riety of new fibers, some of which are especially well adapted for use
either in wool mixtures or for making nonwool fabrics serving the
same uses as wool. There has not been an absolute decline in the
total consumption of apparel wool in the United States; in fact, wool
consumption by 1955 was still substantially above the prewar level,
although far below the high levels of the war and postwar years.
But the per capita mill consumption of apparel wool, notwithstand-
ing a large increase in consumer purchasing power, was only about
what it was prior to the war-2.21 pounds in 1952, as compared with
an average of 2.15 pounds for 1935-39. Per capita consumption of
manmade fibers, on the other hand, increased from an average of 0.34
pound in 1935-39 to about 3.05 pounds in 1954.
Wool has failed to retain its position in the textile field largely due
to the growing competition from manmade fibers, although influences
like the trend toward lighter weight clothing were partly responsible
too. Wool's future place in the textile field depends in part upon
its price relative to the price of manmade fibers. This relationship
has tended increasingly to favor the manmade fibers. The price index
for fine wool, taking the average price for the period of 1935-39 as
base, stood at 189 in 1952, for medium grade at 167. For viscose
rayon, using the same base, the index in 1952 was 140, and for acetate
81. The spread has widened since then.
Synthetic fibers made considerable inroads in the men's clothing
field in the early fifties. Since 1954, their importance has receded,
however, and wool has regained some ground. Only in lightweight
suits remain synthetics an important factor.
DOMESTIC WOOL PROGRAMS DURING AND AFTER WORLD WAR 11
Domestic wool, after reaching about 40 cents in 1942-about 55
percent higher than average 1939 prices-saw its demand fall off in
1943. Military requirements were declining, and mill operators
showed a marked preference for foreign wools because of their rela-
tive cheapness and because they required less labor on account of
having been better prepared for the market before shipment.
To overcome the uncertainty with regard to outlets for domestic
wool, the Secretary of Agriculture directed the Commodity Credit
Corporation to purchase the entire domestic clip in 1943 at ceiling
prices, and required that all domestic wool, with minor exceptions, be
sold to the CCC. This procedure was extended year by year until
April 1947.11 The support prices thus maintained were favorable as
~ Benedict and Stifle, op. cit., p. 341.
PAGENO="0069"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 61
compared with prices of wool prevailing in preceding years, but
growers were running into high costs and were especially handicapped
by the shortage of skilled help.
The Government purchase price in 1943 was 41.7 cents per pound,
or 141 percent of parity. It remained at approximately the same
level thro'ugh 1949. However, the prices of most other farm products
rose rapidly from 1945 on, so that the price of wool, though relatively
favorable at the outset, became less and less favorable. By 1949, meat
animals were 183 percent above their 1939 level, and farm products
as a whole were up 160 percent; wool prices, however, had increased
only 120 percent.
High costs, labor shortages, and relatively low prices made for re-
duced production of shorn wool from 1942 on.12 In that year, 388
million pounds were produced. By 1949, output was down to 213
million pounds. Although wool did not share in the rapid price
advance of those years, lambs, another product of the same flocks,
rose practically in the same proportion as other meat products.13
Commodity Credit Corporation stocks of wool had increased toward
the end of the war, as mills turned to the production of civilian goods
and the use of domestic wool dropped off sharply, because the CCC
selling price was higher than the prices of comparable imported
wools.14 In November 1945, the CCC announced that it would sell
domestic wools at the price of duty-paid foreign wools. But since
most mills preferred the better prepared foreign wools to those grown
in the United States, if the former could be obtained at a comparable
price, the CCC concession had little effect. The price was further
reduced in February 1946. CCC sales of domestic fine-combing terri-
tory wool for the first half of 1946 were about 19 cents-clean basis-
below the purchase price. The loss was absorbed by the CCC. Only
then did domestic wools begin to move more freely, and the market
for them improved.
From 1947 on, the world wool market also continued strong with
generally rising prices, and consumption was running substantially
above production. When the greatly increased demand after the out-
break of the Korean war in 1950 was superimposed on a market with-
out any large carryovers, wool prices to farmers rose nearly 100 per-
cent between June 1950 and June 1951. The rise, however, was largely
speculative. U.S. mill consumption rose about 30 percent in 1950,
but fell back to near the 1949 level by 1952.
The wartime wool program expired on April 14, 1947. It was re-
sumed on August 14, 1947, through an act which directed the CCC
to support the price of wool until December 1948 at the same rate as
in 1946.15 The most important feature of this act was an authoriza-
tion for CCC to sell its stock on a competitive basis with foreign
wools.'6 This plus the active demand of the postwar period led to a
12 Shorn wool production has tended to vary with numbers of sheep on farms and
ranches, whereas pulled wool production has varied with changes in the slaughter of
sheep and lambs. Since about fourth-fifths of domestic wool is produced as shorn wool,
total wool production has varied with numbers of sheep.
13 The income from wool is estimated to be only about 40 percent of the total income
from sheep, lambs, and wool. The percentage varies from region to region: In the
Middle West, more of the total comes from meat, whereas in the specialized wool-
producing areas of the Plains and Mountain States, more comes from wool.
14 The ccc held 327 million pounds grease raw wool on July 1, 1945. By July 1, 1946,
holdings had increased to 499 million pounds, or more than the equivalent of an entire
year's domestic wool production.
`5 Public Law 360, Aug. 5, 1947.
`° CCC holdings of both domestic and foreign wools bad reached a peak of 540 million
pounds (grease basis) in October 1946. Benedict and Staine, op. cit.~ p. 347.
PAGENO="0070"
62 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
gradual reduction of COO holdings. By April 1, 1949, they were
down to 67 million pounds-scoured basis, and to 17 million by April
1950.
Under the August 1947 act, wool prices to growers were supported
at an average level of 42.3 cents. While relatively favorable in terms
of percentage of parity in the war years, this advantage rapidly dis-
appeared as prices of things bought by farmers rose. The parity
percentage, 101 percent in 1947, dropped to 94 percent in 1948 and
1949.1T
The Agricultural Act of 1949 (sec. 201)18 made it mandatory for the
Secretary of Agriculture to support the price of wool at such levels
between 60 and 90 percent of parity as the Secretary determined
necessary, to encourage an annual production of approximately 360
million pounds of shorn wool.'9 Wool thus became, and still is, the
only agricultural commodity for which Congress has set a specific
quantitative production objective. Since domestic production was
tar short of the legislative goal, the price support level was set at
90 percent of parity as of April 1, 1950, in an effort to encourage
producers to raise production toward the legislative goal.2°
Price-support operations under the 1949 act were being carried out
by means of a nonrecourse loan program for producers of shorn wool,
and through a purchase program for pulled wool. Domestic pro-
ducers were supposed to be given an opportunity to market their
wool in an orderly manner, through normal trade channels, and at
prices not lower than 90 percent of parity. The nonrecourse loan
program was designed to enable the producer by redeeming the loan
to take advantage of any increase in market price to above the loan
level plus carrying charges. But in the event the market price
dropped below the loan level, the producer did not assume any
liability. As long as market prices were below the support level,
domestic wool thus was held off the market. In the meantime, how-
ever, domestic mills continued to meet their needs from foreign
markets and domestic wool piled up in the hands of the Commodity
Credit Corporation.21 In September 1953, CCC had acquired title to
about 100 million pounds of wool (grease), and 40 percent of all the
domestic wool produced in 1952.
Price support arrangements on the 1953 clip were substantially the
same as those for 1952, and prices to farmers likewise. While duty-
paid prices on some grades of imported wools remained below do-
mestic support prices, it was evident that a large volume of imported
wools would continue to move to the mills, whereas domestic wool
tended to go into stocks. These stocks not only were difficult to dis-
pose of, but they also had a depressing effect on the market.
"The parity price for wool is a national average of prices, on a grease basis, received
by all farmers on first sales of growers' hands.
1~ "Wool Study Group Report," p. 38. See also Benedict, M. IL, "Farm Policies of
the United States 1790-1950," (New York 1953), p. 478.
19 appropriateness of setting a goal at the level is discussed below.
20 1949 act also renewed the authorization for CCC sales at less than cost of
purchase. This left the way open for continuing purchase of domestic wool at premium
prices without building up excessive stocks in hands of the CCC. But if wool prices
had fallen below the foreign price plus tariff, a continuous subsidy would have been
provided.
21 Between July 1, 1943, and June 30, 1952, the CCC lost $92.2 mfflion on its various
wool programs. Of this, approximately $26 million consisted of carrying charges, includ-
ing storage costs, transportation, grading, etc. The balance of the loss resulted from the
necessity of reducing selling prices below purchase prices In order to dispose of the wool,
- and was the largest loss incurred on any storable agricultural commodity In that period.
PAGENO="0071"
TRADE ADJuSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 63
Early in 1954, the administration proposed a new approach to the
wool problem. Direct payments were to be made to growers at the
end of season, in amounts sufficient to make up the difference between
the average prices received by growers and the incentive prices speci-
fled. The payments were to be made from the general revenues of the
Government, but could not exceed the unobligated tariff receipts from
imports of wool and wool products.22
This plan eventually was incorporated in the National Wool Act of
1954 (see below). One feature of this act was an attempt on the part
of the Congress to provide an ostensible solution of the wool problem
without raising taFiffs and thereby leaving international trade rela-
tions undisturbed. Before examining the act in greater detail, and
appraising the usefulness as a point of departure for a readjustment
assistance program for the domestic wool industry, a brief survey of
the wool tariff is in order.
THE TARIFF ON WOOL
The domestic woolgrowing industry has become established with
tariff protection which has continued for a long period. Price sup-
port by means of tariffs also has long been the procedure most favored
by woolgrowers. But wool prices and the level of tariffs have not
always been closely related. The drastic decline of wool prices in
1921, for example, may have been affected to some extent by the gre-
ceding period in which wool was on the free list, but only in a limited
way.23
Wool had been placed on the free list by the Underwood Simmons
tariff (approved October 3, 1913). This constituted a very large re-
duction since previous to that, wool had borne an ad valorem equiva-
lent of 44 percent. During World War I, however, wool prices stood
high, despite heavy imports. After the war, there was a decrease in
demand, severely affecting wool prices.24 The Emergency Tariff Act
of 1921 thereupon provided for a sharp increase in wool duties, and
further increases were provided in the Fordney-McCumber Tariff Act
of 1923.25 The Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act of 1930 established rates
for raw wool which in general were the highest in the history of the
wool tariff since 1816. But wool prices in 1932 were even lower than
in 1921.26
In the beginning of a depression the tariff cannot have much effect
on wool prices. Mills with access to their own stocks and to stocks
readily available through trade channels can carry on without import-
ing much foreign wool or even buying in the domestic market. Wool
prices thus can go very low without causing much increase in the
amounts of wool purchased by the mills. But once readily available
stocks are used up, the mills turn to imported wools. These must
come in over the tariff and are therefore more highly priced. In this
situation the price of domestic wool tends to improve rather quickly,
unlike the prices of other farm products of which there is a surplus.
22 Similar supports were proposed for pulled wool and mohair, with appropriate rate
differentials.
~ Benedict, "Farm Policies of the United States," p. 143.
~ Benedict, op. cit., p. 170.
~ Benedict, op. cit., pp. 202 and 204. See also Taussig, F. w., "The Tariff History of
the United States," 8th edition (New York 1931), p. 460. sq.
~° Benedict, op. cit., p. 251.
PAGENO="0072"
64 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
In such periods of incipient prosperity the wool tariff has been most
effective as a means of price support.
Some of the high duties on wool under the 1930 Tariff Act were sub-
sequently reduced by bilateral agreements with Argentina, Uruguay,
and the United Kingdom. Under the Trade Agreements Act of 1934
these concessions were granted to all other countries. The General
Agreement on Tariffs and Trade of 1948 reduced rates on wool in
general by 25 percent. This was the last overall reduction. The cur-
rent (1957) duty on grease wool finer than 44's is 251/2 cents per clean
pound.
The tariff is generally more effective in supporting wool prices to
domestic producers when prices are low than when they are high.
With duties on raw wool at a fixed rate per pound, less protection is
~afrorded domestic producers as wool prices increase. Similarly, pro-
tection in terms of growers' purchasing power becomes relatively less
as the level of prices of things growers must buy rises.
Although the tariff on wool has tended to maintain prices of do-
mestic wool higher than world market level, imported wools generally
command a premium over domestic woo]s of same grade because of
uniformity and better preparation, which in turn lowers processing
costs for woolen manufacturers.27 Greater processing costs because
of sorting before use constitutes the most important single price dis-
advaiitage of domestic wool vis-a-vis foreign wools. This dis-
advantage neither tariff nor price support programs have been able to
eliminate.
There still remains to be mentioned the relation of tariffs and other
import restrictions to the various price support programs for wools.
A price support program, particularly one that involves Govern-
ment purchase at a price higher than the prevailing world market
price, cannot operate successfully unless the influx of foreign goods is
controlled in some way so as not to swamp the domestic market. This
purpose is served by the mechanism established under section 22 of
the Agricultural Adjustment Act.28
With regard to wool, the Department of Agriculture in recent years
recommended on two occasions that import quotas or higher tariffs be
imposed under section 22.29 On the second investigation the Tariff
Commission ~° recommended imposition of an import fee of 10 cents
per pound of clean content, but not more than 50 percent ad valorem
on imports of the specified wool, and imposition of an 111/4 cents fee
on imports of carboned wool and wool tops-both fees in addition to
the duties levied under the 1930 Tariff Act. The recommendation was
based on a finding by the Commission's majority that increased im-
ports of wool constituted material interference with the wool price
support program in general, and specifically with the program as it
27 Most imported wools are skirted, classed and packed for shipment In compressed bales.
Domestic wools, however, are packed in bags as they are shorn, and are sold with little or
no further preparation.
28 First enac~ted 1935 (49 Stat. 773) ; reenacted 1937 (50 Stat. 246).
~ On the first Investigation, begun by the U.S. Tariff Commission in September 19~2, no
recommendation was made because the price-support program for wool in effect when the
investigation was ordered, had ended in April 1953.
80 Tariff Commission, "Report to the President: Wool, Wool Tops, and Carbonized
Wool," Investigation No. 8 under sec. 22 of the Agricultural Adjustment Act, amended,
Washington, D.C., February 1954 (processed). The President's letter Is dated Mar. 4,
1954.
PAGENO="0073"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 65
was administered under the Agricultural Adjustment Act of 1949,
the controlling legislation in force at the time.3'
The President did not approve the proposed increase, but indicated
that on the basis of a study prepared by the Secretary of Agriculture 32
he had determined that domestic woolgrowers required continued
price or income assistance in a more effective form than that provided
under the 1949 act, without added limitations to the imports of wool.
For this reason the administration accepted the principal recommen-
dations made by the Secretary of Agriculture with respect to such a
program, and submitted them to Congress.33
THE NATIONAL WOOL ACTS OF 1954 AND 1958 ~
According to section 702 of the 1954 act-
* * * wool is an essential and strategic commodity which is not produced in
quantities and grades in the United States to meet the domestic needs * * * the
desired domestic production of wool is impaired by the depressing effects of wide
fluctuations in the price of wool in the world markets.
It is hereby declared to be the policy of Congress * * * to encourage the annual
domestic production of approximately 300 million pounds of shorn wool, grease
basis, at prices fair to both producers and consumers in a manner which will have
the least adverse effects upon foreign trade.
Support for wool is provided by forward pricing rather than by
price supports in the traditional manner. Whereas the fixed per-
centage of parity support price looks to past price relationships with-
out immediate regard to the resulting output, forward or incentive
prices seek to guide production in desired directions. Thus they may
imply differential downward adjustments in price supports as well
as differential upward revisions. Support for wool provided by in-
centive pricing may not exceed 110 percent of parity. If the support
price is put at 90 percent of parity or below, it must be at such a level
as to encourage production of 300 million pounds of shorn wool.35
Between 60 and 90 percent of parity, the Commodity Credit Corpora-
tion is entitled to use any method of support (loans, purchase, pay-
ments, etc.) it deems advisable for carrying the intention of the act,
but above 90 percent of parity, no support other than through pay-
ments may be provided. The total amount of such payments may not
exceed 70 percent of the accumulated totals of specific duties on wool
and wool products collected after January 1, 1953, under schedule 11
n The minority (Commissioners Ryder and Edminister) felt that the Commission had
not been able to show that increased imports of wool had led to, or were threatening to
create losses for the Commodity Credit Corporation in operations with respect to the
domestic wool crop great enough to be regarded as excessive from the standpoint of overall
administration of the price support program, and therefore as interfering with the program
or rendering it worthless. See "Wool-Wool Tops," etc., pp. 64 et seq.
32 "The Wool Study Group Report."
83 Most of these recommendations were included in the National Wool Act of 1954,
see below.
84 Act of Aug. 28, 1954, ch. 1041, tItle vii, sees. 701-708, 68 Stat. 910. The act was
extended by the National Wool Act of 1958 (act of Aug. 28, 1958, Public Law 85-835~,
title iv, sees. 401-403, 72 Stat. 994), The major difference between the two acts is that
whereas under the 1954 act payments were being made from a fund established from
customs revenues on raw wool imports only, the 1958 act set-aside provisions included
custom revenues from all wool imports, including woolens. The 1958 act expires in 1962.
~ Pulled wool and mohair are to be supported at such levels as will maintain "normal
trading practices."
PAGENO="0074"
66 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
of the Tariff Act of 1930, as amended. Payments may be made
through the marketmg agencies to whom, or through whom, the
grower sells his wool.36
Wool prices are now allowed to find their own level in a free market,
except for the price-supporting effect of the tariff. Supplementary
payments on the wool sold in a given year are made in the summer of
the year following. At that time a determination is made of the
average price received by growers, and of the percentage by which this
must be increased to yield an average national return equivalent to the
announced support price, such as, for example, 62 cents per pound for
the 1955 clip.37 Each grower, either directly or through his marketing
agency, must file a claim supported by appropriate documents at his
local county agricultural stabilization and conservation office, giving
date of sale, net price received, and other pertinent information. The
national average percentage, by which the announced support price
exceeds the average return to growers by way of the market is applied
to each grower's net sales proceeds to determine the amount of supple-
mentary payments due him.38 Similar arrangements are provided
for making supplementary payments on pulled wool.
While this program avoids accumulation of stocks in CCC ware-
houses, it involves more detailed and more extensive administrative
arrangements in the field. Each and every grower account must now
be handled separately, whereas, under the plan in effect from 19~0 to
~954, only those growers whoobtained loans, had to be dealt with indi-
vidually. Under the CCC purchase plan used during the 1940's, even
that amount of direct contact with the individual grower could be dis-
pensed with.89
Woolgrowers thus sell their products at the market price, and then
have their income brought up to an agreed level by a subsidy from the
Government. For the 1955 wool year which ended in March 1956 the
Secretary of Agriculture fixed 62 cents a pound as the average price
to which growers were entitled for raw grease wool. The average
price woolgrowers actually received in the market was 42.8 cents a
pound. Therefore the average subsidy to which growers were entitled
was 19.2 cents a pound. But the Department of Agriculture, instead
of simply paying this amount to growers for each pound of wool
they had marketed during the year, calculates the subsidy on a per-
centage basis: 19.2 cents being 44.9 percent of 42.8 cents (the actual
average market price), the Department made payments on the basis
of 44.9 percent of each growers actual market receipts for his wool.
The effect of this method of calculation and payment is to give
greater reward to the man who originally received a higher price for
~ The 70-percent limitation, it may be noted in passing, may prove to be the source
of some complication, should the tariff on wool be lowered. However, removal of wool
duties would logically require the elimination of the compensating element for raw wool
in the duty on woolens and worsted fabrics. Otherwise, free raw wool would give the
manufacturers substantially increased protection. See Bidwell, op. cit., p. 144.
"This was 106 percent of parity as of Sept. 15, 1954. It was 8.8 cents per pound or
16.5 percent above the national average loan rate for 1954, and 15 percent above the
national average received by growers in 1954. The support levels for 1950 through 1954
bad been at 90 percent of parity.
`~ The plan is somewhat similar to the one used in making payments to domestic sugar
producers. ~But whereas the sugar program looks specifically to the stabilization of prices
and production, and includes import quota provisions, the wool program, following the
precedent established In the 1949 act, aims to encourage U.S. growers to produce more
wool. Also, the wool program is tied to customs collected on wool and its products,
whereas the sugar program includes a domestic excise tax. See Benedict and Stine, op.
cit., pp. 291-328 for a description of the sugar program.
`° Benedict and Stine, op. cit., p. 35~.
PAGENO="0075"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 67
his wool. The grower who, for example, sells his wool for only 40
cents a pound is given an additional 17 cents in subsidy, or 57 cents in
all (instead of 62 cents, the average fixed price), whereas the grower
who is able to sell his wool for 50 cents in the market is paid an addi-
tional 22,45 cents, with the result that his total comes to 75.45 cents
per pound. In that way the farmers who grew and marketed better
than average wool are being rewarded.4°
The new plan provided a substantially higher price to woolgrowers
than that authorized under the 1949 act, but the price to consumers
was expected to be no higher than under the earlier plans, when the
Commodity Credit Corporation was allowed to sell its wool acquisi-
tions at prices competitive with those of foreign wools. As a result,
prices paid by consumers were at or near free-market levels, except for
differentials resulting from the tariff. Such influence as tariff rates
may have had on domestic wool prices remain in effect under the 1954
program. But because of the larger subsidy thus granted woolgrow-
ers, the total cost of the program to the TJ.S. Treasury will be higher.
In consequence, the public as a whole will indirectly pay a higher price
for wool than under the plans previously in effect, regardless of
whether or not that cost is considered as a reduction in net returns to
the Treasury from wool duties.4'
THE NATIONAL WOOL ACT AND TARIFF PROTECTION
Under the policy established under the 1954 act, the importance of
tariffs for wool producers may be expected to decline. In theory, the
level of the tariff would be immaterial, if the Government were willing
to support wool prices on an incentive basis, and as long as 70 percent
of the amount of the duty collected is adequate to carry out the
program.42
The incentive program in effect under the 1954 act, however, actually
provides more protection for the domestic wool growing industry than
a tariff ever could provide: With a 1955 average market price of about
$1.10 a pound, clean basis, a tariff increase providing the same incre-
mental return for growers as the incentive program would have to
increase the average price by 40 percent (that is to say, by 44 cents, on
$1.10) ~ Under the incentive program, a 44-cents-a-pound subsidy
was afforded domestic wool growers, "with least adverse effect upon
foreign trade," as provided by the 1954 act. IE[ad equivalent protection
40 At the outset, however, "the growers were all so confused by this recondite method
of calculation and so busy trying to figure out what they were going to receive that they
do not seem to have had time to plan to increase or to improve their flocks." See
"Brannan In Sheep's Clothing," The Economist, Jan. 5, 1957, p. 34.
~` The loss to the Government in the period 1950-1954 was relatively small, comprising
only the amount resulting from resale of lower prices of wool acquired under the non-
recourse loans programs of 1953 and 1954. (See "CCC Report of Financial Conditions
and Operations," Dec. 31, 1952, p. 23, and ibld, Apr. 30, 1955, p. 24)~. In fiscal 1951,
CCC realized a gain of $124,596 on Its wool operations; a loss of $86,610 was incurred
in fiscal 1952, and losses of $15,290 and $452,501 for fiscal 1953 and 1954 respectively.
Consumers have, of course, paid an additional Indirect subsidy to domestic growers as a
result of the tariffs on Imported wool.
42 If the cost of the program were higher, woolgrowers presumably would have a strong
incentive for advocating Increased duties on imported wool, under existing arrangements
for financing the Incentive payments.
~ The level of the incentive price program was 62 cents per pound, grease basis. rrhe
price received by growers under the program in effect in 1955 was 42.8 cents, also on a
grease basis. This meant that the Incentive program resulted in a subsidy of 19.2 cents
on a pound of shorn wool, grease basis. Expressed in terms of clean wool, this subsidy
would have been equivalent to approximately 44 cents. Accordingly, the equivalent pro-
tection to growers by the 1955 incentive program was 44 cents a pound of clean wool,
without affecting the domestic price of wool.
PAGENO="0076"
68 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
been provided by an effective tariff, the situation for 1955 would have
been as follows: Mill consumption was 286 million pounds, clean basis,
whereas domestic consumption was 134 million pounds, with imports
of 152 million pounds. A 40-percent duty increase, if allowed to raise
the domestic price of wool accordingly, would have brought con-
sumption close to the amount of domestic production by helping wool
prices itself out of the market. This would have meant that even with
a small volume of imports the new higher wool tariff could not have
increased returns to domestic producers any further, had sales fallen
off for other reasons, such as competition from synthetic fibers, for
e~ample.44
While the incentive program for wool thus not only provides better
protection for wool than a tariff, wool growers under the forward pric-
ing arangement also are assured of more stable prices than would
prevail if the traditional principal reliance on the level of tariffs has
been continued, because growers can adjust their production to the
prices as set.
The forward pricing element of the Wool Act appears to be the
only useful item for a readjustment program for wool which aimed
at encouraging a shrinkage in the domestic wool growing industry2 with
transitional assistance. The major obstacle to such a program is the
production target in the present act which is set uneconomically high.
Evaluation of this target involves first a consideration of the defense
essentiality of the domestic wool industry.45
DEFENSE ESSENTIALITY OF WOOL GROWING VERSUS STOCKPILING
The goal of 300 million pounds of shorn wool established by Con-
gress in the National Wool Act of 1954 is slightly below the level of
domestic produciton in the years before World War JJ46 Excluding
pulled wool, it would represent about 132 million pounds of scoured
wool, or about 30 percent of domestic consumption of wool during
1950-53.
Does this 300 million pounds production goal make sense economi-
cally? There is no clear basis for deciding how much wool should
be produced at home. Production levels under both the 1949 and
the 1954 acts (360 million and 300 million pounds) were selected arbi-
trarily, although some attention was paid to past performance. But
at no reasonable level of prices can domestic wool production be
increased sufficiently to supply U.S. needs in wartime or in periods
of high domestic demand, such as during 1945-55. This country
must, therefore, count on heavy supplies from abroad at all times,
except possibly in periods of very low business activity.
To increase domestic wool production to a level of self-sufficiency,
even if achievable, would result in enormous oversupplies and price
"The realization of this advantage, although never hinted at in public debate, may
have been one of the reasons why the congressional delegations from practically all the
wool-growing States with the sole exception of Idaho, were solidly behind the wool In-
centive program when it was being debated in the spring of 1954. In the fall of 1956.
woolgrowers tried to persuade the Secretary of Agriculture to have the incentive level
raised from 62 cents to 67.5 cents, but did not succeed in doing so.
`~ The goal has not been altered in the 1958 act.
`~ Shorn wool production was approximately 800 million pounds per year in 1909-li,
but was beginning to fall off just prior to World War I. It passed the 800 million pound
mark in 1928, and moved up fairly steadily to 388 million pounds in 1942. DurIng most
of thie period, except in the years 1930-32, wool prices were more favorable than those
of most other farm products.
PAGENO="0077"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 69
gluts even in ordinary times. The wool industry can be more stable-
and stability, rather than higher production, would seem to he the most
desirable objective of wool legislation-if fluctuation of demand and
production can be absorbed by the very extensive world market, rather
than artificially confining them to the domestic market. Except for a
minimum supply, Government and domestic consumers of wool can
be supplied more economically by the low-cost producers of Australia,
New Zealand, and other supplying countries, than by our own wool
growers.
The Joint Economic Committee a few years ago attempted to estab-
lish a set of criteria for the treatment of industries requesting special
treatment in the name of national defense needs.47 It was found that
only in a very limited number of cases would the balanced assessment
of all factors reveal need of special treatment of a few industries for
the sake of defense. And if these were industries whose manipulation
would have international repercussions, the alternative means to aid
these industries should be weighed carefully in each individual case.
The committee ruled out tariff and quota increases and suggested
assistance in the form of stockpiling of durable items not subject to
obsolescence,48 as well as subsidies, and expanded research and develop-
ment.
For wool, in order to achieve the protection afforded by the legis-
lative production goal of 300 million (in the face of the stated inteñ-
tion of the 1954 Wool Act, that the method of support adopted
there "have the least adverse effects upon foreign trade"), opponents of
the measure had to argue that wool was a strategi.c material,~~ that re-
quir~ments for it rose sharply in wartime, and that then the supply of
imported wool, most of which must come by sea over long distances,
could be cut off.
These arguments are not supported by this country's war experi-
ence.5° Very large military requirements were met without serious
difficulty, from current imports, and only moderate and perhaps un-
necessary restrictions were imposed on civilian uses of wool. In fact,
a large part of the domestic clips accumulated in the hands of the
Commodity Credit Corporation between 1943 and 1947 when it pur-
chased domestic wools at OPA ceiling prices, well above the prices for
comparable imported wools. It was on the postwar sale of these
stocks, mostly for export, that most of the loss sustained by CCC on
wool operations was incurred."
Moreover, in recent years, new types of man-made fibers suitable for
blending with wool, have been developed. High prices for wool, par-
ticularly in the United States, have stimulated this development.
Since the output of such fibers can be readily increased, the risk of
severe shortage in wool has been reduced.
It is true, however, that large armed forces require huge amounts
of more or less specialized woolen goods. And it is also true that mili-
tary requirements may rise sharply on short notice after the outbreak
~` "Defense Essentiality and Foreign Economic Policy" (S. Rept. No. 2629, 84th Cong.,
2d sess., Washington, D.C., 1956), p. 11. The report was an outgrowth of a series of
hearings by a subcommittee Investigating the defense-essentiality of the jewel watch
industry.
"Loc. cit., pp. 29-SO.
"See, e.g., Randall Commission, "Staff Papers" (1954), pp. 184-5.
~ Benedict and Stine, op. cit., p. 888 et seq.
51 See above.
PAGENO="0078"
70 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
of a war. The remedy for that is stockpiling. The Defense Depart-
ment Appropriation Act for fiscal 1951 for that reason authorized the
Department to build up a war reserve of fabrics and "end items," in-
volving 100 million pounds of wool, clean basis.52
Experience during and after World War II thus indicates that
stockpiling of wool is feasible. Deterioration in storage, for several
years, is inconsequential under proper management. The cost of stock-
piling, though by no means negligible, is not prohibitive.53 The cost
of storing fabric includes mothproofing, rolling into bolts and fire pro-
tection, plus the general rates for warehousing-which on a percent-
age basis are relatively low as compared to storing raw wool.
In short, the defense argument provides little or no justification for
a program of price support for domestic wool, particularly with a
production goal out of line in terms of purely economic considerations.
The national interest would therefore be served better by a further re-
distribution of resources from sheep raising to other farming pursuits.
If farm policy were revised accordingly, the problem then would be
how best to provide assistance for the readjustment of woolgrowers.
READJUSTMENT IN WOOL GROWING
Domestic wool production in no event will supply as large a part
of domestic consumption as it did in earlier times when land was
much more plentiful and the country's population much smaller.
There remain, indeed, very large areas in the `United States that are
probably best used for sheep production. Where these are also suited
for beef cattle, they probably should be shifted to that type of use.
The country~s population is rising rapidly, and the need for larger
quantities of beef would assure maximum use of that type of land
resource.54
There appears to be a continuing long-term trend toward a dimin
ishing relative importance of sheep and wool in the national economy.
But even if there were no tariff on wool and no other mode of price
or income support for wool growers, sheep raising and wool produc-
tion in the `United States would surely not disappear. Some further
shrinkage might occur, although swings in sheep numbers and pro-
duction are certainly to be expected. Such shrinkage would mean a
further change in the proportion of the growers' income received from
lamb and wool, respectively, with lambs accounting for a stifi larger
portion of the total than they do now.55 At the same time, increased
~ Raw wool has not been seriously considered for stockpiling. Already In September
1952, it was removed from group I of the list of strategic and critical materials for stock-
piling. The 100 million pound fabric stockpile Is still In operation. The raw wool stock-
pile had been liquidated by late 1957.
~ In the stockpile for strategic purposes It has been found preferable to store cloth,
finished or unfinished, despite obvious limitations of color and weave, because the amount
of time It would take to get raw wool out of storage and channeling it Into production.
For purposes of calculation, it may be assumed that the cost of a unit of fabric Is three
times the cost of a unit of clean raw wool.
64 Encouragement of sheep production can, however, be defended on other grounds:
Much of the Plains area are and have recently been converted to wheat production, a crop
In which there exists a substantial surplus. As part of the wool adjustment program,
livestock production can be made relatively more attractive and crop production relatively
less attractive. Considerable areas In the Plains, especially those subject to frequent
droughts, could probably be used to better national advantage in the production of livestock,
Including sheep, than In grain production. See Benedict and Stifle, op. cit., p. 358.
~ See above.
PAGENO="0079"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 71.
consumption of wool, resulting from reduction in the price of foreign
wool to mills in the absence of a tariff, would tend to set a limit to any
price reduction in domestic wool.56
The income support program under the Wool Act fulfills the stated
intention of Congress in the foreign economic sphere only to the ex-
tent that it has stabilized the tariff situation existing at the time of its
passage, comparatively favorable to the domestic wool industry.~~
However, by virtue of setting up an uneconomically high production
goal and granting growers correspondingly high incentive payments,
the act in effect provides better protection to domestic growers, but
its provisions are not really designed to attain freer trade. The Wool
Act, nevertheless, does contain certain elements that would be use-
ful in connection with a program of assisted readjustment of the wool
growing industry in the event of a lowering of trade barriers, particu-
larly after the defense-essential production goal had been cut down
or eliminated.
A PROGRAM OF ASSISTED READJUSTMENT
The first step in a program of assisted readjustment for the wool
growing industry would have to be a substantial downward revision
if not elimination of the production goal as specified in the Wool Act.
It is an established fact that wool can and actually is being stock-
piled. With an active stockpiling program, greater latitude is gained
for determining the optimal capacity of a given defense-essential in-
dustry. In the case of woolgrowing, this circumstance provides the
possibility of reducing the present production objective considerably.
For purposes of this discussion, it will be assumed that the production
goal is cut in half, to 150 million pounds shorn wool.58
With a lowered production objective, woolgrowers should be able
to quit the industiy in an orderly manner, as and when competitive
iml?orts increase as a result of a trade liberalization. Even without
assistance, such an exodus would not necessarily create undue hard-
ships for all growers. As has been noted earlier, many growers have
set a precedent to this movement out of wool, especially during the
war years, when a shift to cattle raising became profitable. In the
Eastern (or native) States, moreover, sheep raising has always been
only one facet of the diversified agriculture practiced there, and
operators consider sheep raising not as a major enterprise. This situa-
tion leaves the Federal Government, in administering the readjustment
assistance program, with the problem of devising and putting into
operation methods and means to help increase the efficiency of grow-
ers who cannot readily shift to other pursuits, or are located in areas
where other types of land utilization would be uneconomical,
~° The effect of the present tariff is to make wool more costly to manufacturers (though
not necessarily by the full amount of the duty) and to make apparel and other woolen
goods still more costly to consumers, as well as to the Government on purchases for mili-
tary requirements. The president of the Boston Wool Trade Association in 153 estimated
the yearly cost of the tariff to consumers of woolen goods, taking 1948-52~ as an average,
at $240 million, as compared with customs revenues of $100 million per year, and gains
for domestic wool growers, resulting from protection afforded them, at $30 million annually.
(See New York Times, Nov. 18, 1953.) If the indirect subsidy to synthetic fabric pro-
ducers had been included in this figure, its cost would be even higher.
~7 The stated objective of the act, to cause the "least adverse effect upon foreign trade"
thus becomes illusory, and ancillary to the production objective.
~ This reduction admittedly Is a matter of judgment, though it appears to be plausible
in view of the industry's past history.
PAGENO="0080"
72 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
Agricultural producers in general, when threatened by increased
competitive imports, enjoy less flexibility than producers and work-
ers in manufacturing industries. For this they are being compen-
sated, at least to some extent, by the farfiung system of agricultural
support. In the case of woolgrowing, the program in recent years
has consisted of incentive payments to growers. With the lowered
production objective, which would decrease the cost of supplementary
income payments, there would seem to be no objection to continuing
moderate price supports, satisfactory from a technical standpoint,
while the readjustment assistance program is in operation.59
The purpose of the readjustment program would be to help liqui-
date unwanted flocks, to provide loans for operators wishing to switch
to other agricultural or nonagricultural pursuits, and to furnish them
with competent tecimical assistance in speeding them on their way.
Assistance for adjustment to increased import competition differs
basically from compensation for injury.60 Adjustment assistance is
intended to increase flexibility and mobility, not as a reparation
tribute. Greater flexibility and mobility are desirable in themselves,
entirely apart from reductions in import barriers with which the
assistance proffered happens to be associated.
Adjustment assistance also can be made preventive rather than
merely remedial. It can be made available to those who merely are
threatened with injury so that they may act before injury occurs.
This line of reasoning would suggest that adjustment assistance for
woolgrowers be provided on an optional basis, alongside a moderate
price support program. But while the industry and operators ini-
tially can choose to adopt the program, once they have elected to
take advantage of readjustment assistance, they must not be per-
mitted to revert to their old practices.
Wool is not a surplus commodity. However, any increase in the
price of wool, whatever its cause and irrespective of any tariff change,
is limited by the availability of substitutes in the form of synthetic
fibers, in pure form or in various admixtures and combinations. On
the other hand, pure wool is preferred in many uses, when there is
no significant price difference between wool and its substitutes. Gen-
erally speaking, the prices of the substitutes appear to be relatively
stable, with a slight downward tendency as the efficiency in their
production increases. The major problem in wool, though, is that
of price instability, caused by a variety of factors, foreign and do-
mestic. A moderate support program would appear to be necessary
to protect the growers electing to stay in wool from being penalized
as the result of their choice, but not make it excessively attractive
for marginal producers lest they refuse to participate in the adjust-
ment program. With fairly stable prices, competitive with prices for
substitutes, and with the industry cut down to reasonable size, un-
hampered by mistaken considerations of defense essentiality, a fair
return to woolgrowers would be assured.
~° A conflict could arise here between the two types of governmental intervention,
adaptive-the readjustment program, and sustaining-the traditional price or Income
support programs. Abolition of the latter in the case of wool is clearly out of the
question without also radically altering the support programs in force for other crops.
The scope of the present study did not provide opportunity for further examining this
problem.
~° See statement by Walter S. Salant, Brooking Institution, in "Foreign Trade Policy,"
hearings before the Subcommittee on Foreign Trade Policy of the Committee on Ways
and Means, House of Representatives, 85th Cong., 1st sess. (Washington, D.C., 1958),
pp. 577-578.
PAGENO="0081"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 73
In carrying out such a support program (of a temporary nature)
it would be preferable to retain the system of supplemental payments
in force now. Under this system the Government exerts no direct
control over prices, as it does under a loan program, where schedules
of prices have to be set. Government purchase under a loan program
also means Government appraisal. Under a payment program, no
appraisal of stocks is necessary: the Government merely accepts the
grower's valid invoice of his sales as basis for computing the pay-
ments required under the program.
With a lower production goal the adjustment assistance then would
be by supplementary income payments over a transition period. In
setting the level for these supplementary payments (assuming a
moderate support price program to be continuing), the administering
authority would have to be concerned with the relative prices of sub-
stitutes and potential substitutes for wool, as well as with world
prices.6' The support program could and probably would be elimi-
nated, once adjustment of the industry to a greater volume of imports
has been accomplished-that is to say, after 3 to 5 years following the
inception of the program.62
Additional assistance measures would include research to increase
the efficiency of the sheep industry itself.63 A number of fields of re-
search which offer promise as ways of increasing the efficiency and
profitableness of the sheep industry has been described by the Inter-
agency Wool Study Group.64 These include more effective control of
parasites and infectious diseases, nutritional problems, improved
breeding, range improvement, control of predators and so on. The
wool study group also outlined a number of promising fields of study
in the marketing and processing phases of the wool industry, includ-
ing those which would make wool fabrics more attractive to consumers
and thereby check the shift to substituted fibers suited for simi]ar
purposes.65
THE COST OF TRADE ADJUSTMENT
The cost of an adjustment assistance program for wool must be
considered in conjunction with the moderate price support program
which is bound to accompany it, plus the cost of maintaining the
wool or woolen stockpile required by the lowered production objective.
The support program alone would be considerably less than what
it has been in the past several years, even if income payments as pro-
61 The world market for wool would make it necessary to retain some form of import
restriction as long as a support program continues in operation, even of moderate pro-
portions. This would not be the case, however, with an income-payments program that
does not jack up prices. Otherwise the American taxpayer would have to foot the bill
for coping with market difficulties faced by other woolproducing areas.
62 To assume immediate or even gradual elimination of price supports for wool would
complicate matters at this stage of presentation and distract from the main object of the
present inquiry.
~ At the end of a 20-year period ending in 1953, the sheep industry among other
agricultural pursuits, stood at the bottom of the list in terms of improvements in pro-
duction per unit of input: Output per unit of input on sheep ranches in the Northern
Plains area in 1953, 5 percent lower than in 1930-33, in comparison, e.g., with small-
grain and livestock farms in the same area which showed 69 percent increase. See "U.S.
Agriculture: Perspectives and Prospects," a report prepared for the American Assembly,
Graduate School of Business, Columbia University, 1955 (cited by Benedict and Stine,
op. cit., p. 358).
84 See its report, pp. 44-53.
~ The study group's proposal for an expanded and improved program of public re~
lations and promotion was incorporated in the 1954 act, and funds were specifically set
aside for that purpose.
76697-61-- 6
PAGENO="0082"
74 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
vided under the 1954 Wool Act were maintained.66 The cost of main-
taining a wool or woolen stockpile, though not known outside the
agencies concerned with its administration, actually may be treated
as a defense item. For the time being, consumers are providing an
annual subsidy of about $50 million to the domestic woolgrowing
industry.6'7 That cost has had to be weighed against the importance
to the United States of maintaining domestic wool production at
the levels set up as goals in existing legislation-actually a defense
expenditure, to be taken care of by the stockpiling program; the cost
also had to be weighed against equitable treatment for woolgrowers
who have made large investments under protective policies of the
past.68 The cost of the subsidy finally must be measured against such
encouragement as may be desirable for converting cropland now
used in growing wheat and other surplus crops to other uses and
maintaining prosperity in communities built up in areas heavily
dependent on sheep production.
With a reduced production objective of 150 million pounds, the
present subsidy would certainly be lowered. However, while exit
from the industry would be encouraged, particularly for some grow-
ers in the native States, the reduced production objective would still
permit intramarginal wool growers in the Western States to continue
operations under a moderate price support program.
A stabilization program of the kind run by the Commodity Credit
Corporation would remain desirable even under an adjustment pro-
gram such as described in this chapter. As an acquisition and holding
operation-.-separate and distinct from the stockpiling program-it
would reduce Government losses from a temporary glut in the wool
market, which otherwise might result in very low prices and cor-
respondingly high Government support payments.69 Since the
market for raw wool may be severely depressed from time to time
by a sharp falling off of demand, there is continuing need for standby
arrangements whereby domestically grown wool can be acquired and
held until mill demand picks up. For this task an organization like
the CCC is well suited. Even large wool stocks can be liquidated
in an orderly way, if the holding agency has sufficient time and
financial resources.
~° The program would probably be even less costly if handled in the form of purchase-
and-loan operations. Keeping the income-payment approach, however, would not inter-
fere with the objectives of the adjustment program, and would probably ease the way
to its adoption.
~` For the year 1955, for example, the cost of the wool program under the 1954 Wool
Act was $57,585,166, including $49,989,467 for shorn wool incentive payments, and
$7.6 million for lamb (meat price support) payments. From these payments deductions
of $3.1 million were made for the wool and lamb promotion program provided for in the
act (IJSDA press release 1949-57, June 21, 1957). The cost of the 1956 program
appears to have been about 90 percent of the 1955 program-or roughly $45 mifflon for
shorn wool. For 1957, the incentive price, 62 cents, was left unchanged, and the cost
of the program remained about the same.
~ The high level of support for wool provided by the 1954 act rested on the assumption
that it would affect the amount of wool produced and could, therefore, be justified in
terms of equity. However, the problem of equitable returns to sheepgrowers Is com-
plicated by the fact that wool producers have income from lambs and mutton as well.
See Benedict and Stine, op. cit., p. 360.
°~ Current activities of the Commodity Credit Corporation are essentially concerned
with operations at the support price level, which is lower than the present incentive
price level. But with a reduced production objective, the two prices may well coincide.
In recent years, the CCC has had no problem selling wool at supporting price and
has been able to hold down its inventory of raw wool to manageable proportions. In
the event of a reversal of market trends the stabilization function of the CCC evidently
would assume much greater importance.
PAGENO="0083"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 75
Because of the tendency for wool prices to recover as soon as pipe-
line stocks have been used up, stabilizing purchases may not involve
much loss, provided they are handled so as to ease the impact of large
but temporary fluctuations in demand rather than as a method of
keeping prices continually above their open-market levels.70 But be-
cause of the predominant influence of change in demand in the wool
market, some standby arrangements for the absorption and holding
of temporarily redundant supplies would be important, especially
when wool price supports were being lowered, as they would be in
an adjustment program.7'
But the cost reported by the CCC does not reflect the full cost to
the public of contributions made to wool producers under the support
program prior to 1955, and by way of the trade restrictions prior to
1948. It has been estimated 72 that wool producers through tariffs
alone in ordinary times were getting an annual subsidy of about $25
million-or 20 cents per pound on 130 million pounds, clean basis.
As a result of a trade liberalization in conjunction with an assistance
program, this subsidy would be correspondingly lowered. The
reduction would constitute a further gain to the consumer, and a
further benefit to be derived from the adjustment.7'
7° Wools acquired in that way must usually be held for more than a year and worked
off gradually. Consequently this type of operation would be difficult to handle under the
financing arrangements customarily used by cooperative and other selling agencies,
whose primary interest lies In carrying out orderly marketing within the production year.
For a brief survey of CCC operations In wool, see Benedict and Stine, op. cit., pp. 364-366.
~` The overall cost of wool operations as reported by the CCC for the period Oct. 17, 1933
to Dec. 81, 1957, was $113,829,214, an average of about $4.8 million per year. (See Com-
modity Credit Corporation "Report of Financial Conditions and Operations," Dec. 31, 1957,
p. 31.) It should be noted, however, that not all years had a support program, and except
for the higher tariffs before 1948, the level of support for wool was lower than it has
been in recent years.
"Benedict and Stine, op. cit., p. 30.
~` In view of the illustrative nature of the discussion, no attempt has been made to
estimate the actual cost of adaptive intervention in wool growing. Further investigation
into this question would be very desirable.
PAGENO="0084"
PAGENO="0085"
CHAPTER VIII
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN MINING: THE LEAD-ZINC
MINING INDUSTRY
THE INDUSTRY'S NEED FOR READJUSTMENT
This chapter will try to show how a readjustment assistance pro-
gram might be applied to the lead and zinc mining industry. A
segment of the industry has been injured by increased imports in part
due to lowered trade restrictions. Also, the industry has exerted
great pressure for increased protection on the executive and legislative
branches of the Government.' Such pressure may increase if an
adjustment program is not instituted.2
The industry consists of two major segments: Mining and milling,
and smelting and refining. Competition from imports is different
for these two. Imports in the form of ores and concentrates, usu-
ally of much higher metal content than domestic supplies, or of metal,
tend to reduce the demand for domestically produced ores, thus also
reducing the operations of mines and mills. But domestic lead and
zinc smelters and refineries also process imported ores and concen-
trates. For them imports provide an additional source of income and
supplement their supply of raw materials. In fact, a substantial
part of the zinc metal produced in this country, as well as a smaller
proportion of domestic lead metal production comes from imported
ores.3 The availability of imported ores and concentrates to the
domestic lead and zinc smelters and refineries using such materials
has made it possible for them substantially to increase, or at least to
maintain the level of their activity.
1 The industry's efforts In that direction have not been in vain. After investigation
by the Tariff CommIssion under sec. 7 of the Trade Agreements Extension Act of 1951 as
amended (U.S. Tariff Commission, "Lead and zinc: Report to the President on Escape
Clause Investigation No. 05" under the provisions of sec. 7 of the Trade Agreements Ex-
tension Act of 1951, as amended, Washington, April 1958), the President, effective Oct.
1, 19fi8, modified the concessions on unmanufactured lead and zinc granted in the
General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade and imposed absolute quotas on imports of the
two metals (Proclamation No. 3257 of Sept. 22, 1958; 3 CFR, 158 Supp., p. 39). The
annual quotas are to equal 80 percent of the average commercial imports during the
5-year period 1953-57. Import duties remained unchanged-1~ a pound on lead, and
,~, a pound on zinc. In its first report under Executive Order 10401 of Oct. 14,
1952 (3 CFR, 1949-53 Comp., p. 901), which calls for the periodic review of a tariff
modification resulting from an escape clause action, the Tariff Commission found that
developments in the trade of lead and zinc did not justify restoration of the concession
without causing or threatening serious injury to industry (U.S. Tariff Commission, "Lead
and Zinc: Report to the President" (1960) under Executive Order 10401, Washington,
October 1960). For a more detailed survey of developments in lead and zinc since 1952,
see U.S. Tariff Commission, "Lead and Zinc: Report to the Congress on Investigation No.
332-326 (Supplemental) Under Section 332 of the Tariff Act of 1930" made pursuant to
S. Res. h02, 80th Cong., adopted Aug. 21, 1959 (Washington, March 1960.)
2 On Sept. 23, i9~1, the Senate completed action on HR. 84, providing tapering-off
subsidies for small lead and zinc mines. The President signed the bill on Oct. 4, 1961.
No trade liberalization is tied to this legislation, however.
U~S. Tariff Commission, "Lead and Zinc Industries," report on investigation con-
ducted under sec. 332 of the Tariff Act of 1930 pursuant to a resolution by the Corn-
mittee on Finance of the U.S. Senate dated July 27, 1953, and a resolution by the Com-
mittee on Ways and Means of the U.S. House of Representatives dated July 29, 1953
(rept. No. 192, second series, Washington, 1954), p. 87.
77
PAGENO="0086"
78 TRADE ADJ1JSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
The mining and milling end of the industry includes numerous
enterprises. In 1952, for example, lead and zinc ores were mined at
about 900 mines distributed over 25 States and Alaska. The number
of lead and zinc smelters and refineries is relatively small, about 40 in
allas of late 1956.
There exists a conflict with regard to competitive imports between
the small mine operators and the integrated big companies. The big
companies are able to keep going even in the depths of a price drop,
because a number of them, in addition to doing their own smelting
and refining, also produce gold, silver, and other metals aside
from lead and zinc. The other source of interest-conflict lies
in the fact that the big integrated companies often own mining
properties abroad.4 As small operators have been growing weaker
in recent years, bigger producers in effect appear to have been growing
stronger, not the least because of smelting high metal content ores
from low-cost foreign mines.5 In the Coeur d'Alene district of Idaho,
for example, site of considerable mine unemployment, smelters of
Bunker Hill Co. at Kellogg were getting half of their raw materials in
lead and zinc ores through purchase outside the company's mines, from
Australia and South America. And while smaller mine operators
were drastically reducing production.6 Bunker Hill's electrolytic zinc
plant near Kellogg was undergoing a substantial expansion.
The conflict between smelters and miners can also be illustrated by
the case of American Metal Co., Ltd., which owns and operates a large
zinc smelter at Blackwell, Okla., in addition to mining, smelting, and
refining operations in Mexico and Canada.7 The Blackwell smelter
was designed to work concentrates from the nearby tristate area
(Oklahoma, Kansas, and southwest Missouri) and to take advantage
of cheap and abundant natural gas. As local mine output declined,
and no other adequate domestic source of concentrates became avail-
able, Blackwell began to rely on imported concentrates. In recent
years about 85 percent of concentrates smelted at Blackwell have come
from Mexico.
STRUCTURE OF INDUSTRY
Lead or zinc metal produced from ore is known as primary metal.
Secondary metal is produced from scrap. Production of primary lead
or zinc metal involves mining crude ore, milling to produce concen-
trates, and smelting and refining to produce refined metaL
The number of mines engaged in producing crude ores is relatively
large. The number of mills, located near the mines, that concentrate
the ores, is smaller and the number of primary smelters or refineries is
still smaller. The number of both lead and zinc mines in 1956 was 413,
of which 194 were mining chiefly lead, and 219 chiefly zinc.8 The num-
~ Approximately one-third of lead and zinc imports to this country are said to be
brought in by American operators. See "Trade Agreements Extension," hearings before
the Senate Finance Committee on H.R. 1, 84th Cong., 1st sess. (Washington, D.C., 1955),
pt. 3 p. 1379.
~ ~ee "Mine Lament: Lead-Zinc Downturn Blights Mining Areas," by Ray J. Schrick,
Wall Street Journal July 5, 1957.
6The curtailment of production by small operators has led to a growing concentra-
tion of operations. Whereas in Idaho in 1952, for example, 25 mines produced some 90
percent of that year's production of lead; in 1955, only 13 mines produced 95 percent of
all the lead produced in the State. Zinc production has seen a similar concentration.
`See "Trade Agreements Extension," hearings before the House Ways and Means
Committee on HR. 1, 84th Cong., 1st sess., (Washington, D.C., 1955), pt. 2, pp. 2573-2577.
U.S. Tariff Commission, "Lead and Zinc," report to the President on escape clause
investigation No. 65 under the provisions of sec. 7 of the Trade Agreements Extension
Act of 1951 as amended (Washington, D.C., April 1958), statistIcal apuendix, table 36.
PAGENO="0087"
TRADE ADJuSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 79
ber of mills in production in 1956 was 109, with 43 working chiefly
lead, and 66 milling and producing chiefly zinc concentrates. The
number of primary lead smelters and refineries in operation as of the
end of 1956 was 13, and the number of primary zinc smelters, 18.~
Of the 696 lead mines and zinc mines in operation during 1956, 557
mines, or 80 percent, accounted for only 3 percent of the annual pro-
duction of the two metals (895,166 short tons). Each of these mines
produced less than 499 tons of either metal during the year. Only 37
mines reported a production of recoverable metal in excess of 5,000
short tons during the year; but these mines alone accounted for 73.4
percent of total domestic production.1° The number of the larger
mines remains relatively constant from year to year, whereas the num-
ber of smaller mines fluctuates widely, depending on the prevailing
prices of the metal.
The five largest domestic producers of lead normally supply over
half of the total output on a mine basis.11 Some of these companies
also have substantial lead-mining interests in foreign countries, In
the case of zinc, the six largest companies supply less than half the
total.'2 Nearly 60 percent of domestic lead mine production and
about 67 percent of domestic zinc-mine production normally comes
from the Western States.
PRICES~ RESERVES, AND SUBSTITUTES
Production of the two metals is governed by prices. An outstand-
ing feature of lead and zinc market prices is their relative instability.
This in turn results in fluctuating incomes for the industry, especially
for the mining and milling segment. Here one finds many concerns
with limited financial resources, unable to endure a period of very
low prices. Price fluctuations also lead to instability in the cost of raw
materials for industries manufacturing lead and zinc products. The
uncertainty thus created tends to narrow the competitive advantage of
lead and zinc over substitute raw materials, such as aluminum, which
enjoy relative price stability.'3
Until the early 1920's, the market price of zinc generally exceeded
the market price of lead. Since then, the relationship has been re-
versed, except in times of war; zinc enters into military products
(brass shell cases, for example), in greater volume than lead.'4
Prices also have a bearing on deposits and reserves. Estimates of
lead and zinc in ores only represent the reserves shown by develop-
ment work. Because of the expense involved, mining companies usu-
ally do not develop ore bodies for more than 4 or 5 years ahead of
mining. The reserves, moreover, are those regarded as profitably
exploitable at metal prices and production costs prevailing at the
time the estimates are made. The estimates in turn depend upon
° Ibid., tables 43 and 44.
`° Ibid., table 32.
~` See Bishop, 0. M., and Mentch, R. L., "Lead" in Mineral Facts and Problems, USBM
Bulletin No. 556 (WashIngton, D.C., 1956), pp. 418-443.
12 See Bishop, 0. M., and Mentcb, R. L., "zinc" in Mineral Facts and Problems, USBM
Bulletin No. 556 (Washington, D.C., 1956), pp. 977-1002.
13 U.S. Tariff Commission, "Lead and Zinc Industries" (1954), pp. 65-66.
14 The development of selective flotation, allowing recovery of most of the zinc con-
tent in the more abundant lead-zinc, or zinc-lead ores (as opposed to pure lead ores) Is
believed to have had a bearing on that secular change In relative prices. Also, ores con-
taining both metals are found to be richer In zinc than In lead as mining operations pene-
trate to deeper levels.
PAGENO="0088"
80 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
the state of development work and the economic conditions prevail-
ing at the time. Existing estimates of domestic lead and zinc reserves
thus underestimate the resource base. If the price-cost ratio of the
metals increases, domestic production and discovery of domestic re-
serves will be stimulated. New sources of ore supply would be de-
veloped as mining of lower grade ore becomes profitable. It is not
known, however, to what extent such developments would augment
present domestic production.'5
A growing share of the domestic supply of lead and, to a lesser
extent, of zinc, is obtained from scrap. Lead production from scrap
in recent years has exceeded mine production. With a steady growth
in the stock of lead- or zinc-containing articles from which these
metals can be salvaged after use, the increase in secondary production
of lead is expected to continue. Recovery of zinc from scrap also may
increase.
Another source for lead and zinc is material rejected during the
milling or concentration of crude ores, called tailings. The amount
of metal thus lost in former years constituted a relatively considerable
portion of overall production. Milling methods have improved, how-
ever, and less metal is lost in milling than before. Some of the older
mining districts, notably the tristate area and the southeast Missouri
district, have accumulated large piles of tailings. Their metal content
can be extracted with improved methods when prices are favorable.
Lead and zinc are normally the lowest priced nonferrous metals.
Lead is strongly entrenched in most of its major uses because of its
high suitability to these particular applications. But even lead en-
counters competition from other materials, and is subject to the influ-
ence of technological changes that could make the use of lead less
necessary than it now is. Plastics, aluminum, and combinations of
the two in certain types of cable sheathing, and nickel and cadmium in
storage batteries are among the materials currently being substituted
for two important uses of lead.'°
The most important material competing with zinc is aluminum.
That competition is significant with regard to the two largest uses of
zinc: Products of aluminum sheet may be substituted for galvanized
products. Aluminum is also highly competitive with zinc in die-
casting. Another possible substitute is titanium, which competes with
zinc in pigments, and there is a trend toward increased substitution
of magnesium for rolled zinc, in dry-cell batteries and engraving
plates. _______
LABOR COSTS AND EMPLOYMENT SENSrPIVITY
The most important single operating expense in lead and zinc
mining and milling is labor cost. The cost of labor per ton of ore
~ Between 1950 and 1952, under the stimulus of high lead and zinc prices and Govern-
ment encouragement, numerous exploration projects were undertaken both in the United
States and In foreign countries. A certain amount of such development work is continueth
even when prices are temporarily unfavorable.
~ Tetraethyl lead, the most widely used antiknock additive gasoline, has become the
second largest use of lead, after storage batteries. No substitutes seem to be in the
offing, and the upward trend in use of lead is expected to continue. Titanium and other
pigments, however, are replacing lead in paints; plastics and other materials are replac-
ing It in construction, and new packaging methods and aluminum foil have restricted
lead foil to specialized purposes. Lead also is being displaced in Insecticides. Concrete
and high-density tungsten-copper alloys are used as protective shields against radiation
from radioactive substances at the expense of lead, though the alloys are much more
costly.
PAGENO="0089"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 81
mined is determined by wage rates and by the unit of labor required
per ton of ore mined and milled. For 1952, for example, wages and
salaries represented 44.2 percent of the mine value of all lead and zinc
products; supplies and materials accounted for 20.7 percent, fuel for
0.5 percent, and purchased electric energy for 3.4 percent.'7 And
whereas the combined price of lead and zinc per pound has fallen from
32.7 cents in 1952 to 26.1 cents in 1957, average hourly wages paid to
production and related workers have increased from $1.95 to $2.27 in
theseS years.'8
Low prices and high labor costs have had an adverse effect on em-
ployment. Employment in lead and zinc mining and milling has de-
creased substantially in recent years. In 1952, the mining and milling
segment of the industry employed on the average 24,279 workers,'0
divided roughly in a 1-to-2 proportion between lead and zinc. That
average dropped to 19,771 for the first 10 months of 1953, to 17,016 for
1954, 16,845 for 1956, and to 15,563 for the first 10 months of 1957.20
Between 1952 and 1953, the drop in employment was greater at
operations producing principally zinc than at those producing princi-
pally lead. The latter decreased by 37.6 percent, as against a decrease
of only 21.5 percent for zinc.2'
Employment declined most sharply in the Western States. The
decline for the nine Western States averaged 38 percent, and ranged
from 26 percent for Idaho to 88 percent for New Mexico. In the
West Central States, the decline was about 28 percent; in the predomi-
nantly zinc-producing tristate district, 64 percent; in the predomi-
nantly lead-producing southeast Missouri district, however, it was
only 5 percent.
Many of the lead and zinc mines, particularly in the western
States, are located in areas where other means of livelihood are limited
or nonexistent. Mine or mill shutdowns in such areas present a dif-
ficult problem both to the worker and his family, and to the supporting
service industries. In some areas, the situation, if long continued,
gives rise to so-called ghost towns, with a consequent severe deprecia-
tion or total loss of realty holdings, in addition to the loss of income
to the workers. The mine operator, on the other hand, loses skilled
workmen who may not be easily replaced, should economic conditions
permit resumptions of operations at a later time.
The cessation of production at lead and zinc mines, however, does
not eliminate the cost of maintenance and upkeep. Large expendi-
tures for pumping, retimbering, and other maintenance are needed
to prevent excessive damage to mine equipment and installations and
underground workings from flooding and cave-ins. These mainte-
nance costs are frequently the only alternative to permanent closure
of the mines and the loss of ore reserves, because of the high costs that
would otherwise be involved in restoring the mines to production.
Virtually all the decline in total employment in the lead and zinc
industries between 1952 and 1953, as well as in subsequent years was
17 U.S. Tariff Commission, "Lead and zinc Industries" (1954), p. 49.
18 U.S. Tariff Commission, "Lead and Zinc" (1958), statIstical appendix, table 23.
19 U.S. Tariff Commission, "Lead and Zinc Industries," (1954), p. 31. MInes and mills
producing predominantly and chiefly lead accounted for 8,373; those producing pre-
dominantly and chiefly zinc, 15,906.
~° U.S. Tariff Commission, "Lead and Zinc," (1958), statistical appendix, table 35. De-
taIled figures equIvalent to those for 1952 are not available for later years.
21 TI S. Tariff Commission, "Lead and Zinc Industries," (1954), p. 36.
PAGENO="0090"
82 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRA(Yi'ICE
confined to mines and mills. Employment at smelters and refineries
was maintained at a relatively stable level throughout the period: The
1952 average of 17,889 compares favorably with an average of 17,111
for the first 10 months of 1957.22
IMPORTS AND CONSUMPTION
Since the end of World War II, the position of the United States
has changed from one of relatively minor importance in the interna-
tional movement of lead and zinc to one of major importance. This
country's consumption of both lead and zinc has greatly expanded and
become much larger than domestic production. There has been a
general upward trend of foreign primary lead and zinc production,
accompanied by a substantially decreased U.S. primary lead produc-
tion and an only moderately decreased production of primary zinc.23
In consequence, imports of unmanufactured lead and zinc have been
very much larger than imports at any earlier period. Outside the
United States the demand for primary lead has decreased substanti-
ally and the demand for zinc has increased only slightly. Thus a
large part of the exportable surplus of foreign producing countries
has moved to the United States.
The high level of domestic consumption of the two metals compared
with prewar years is attributable only in part to defense needs. Over
the past decade and a half, the growth in population has augmented
the demand for lead and zinc in a wide variety of producers' and
consumers' goods. The consumption of lead, particularly in storage
batteries and as a gasoline additive, has expanded greatly, as has the
consumption of zinc in galvanizing and diecasting.
The extent to which future domestic requirements for lead and
zinc can be met from domestic sources will depend on the production
of newly mined ores as well as on the recovery of these metals from
secondary sources. But as consumption is expected to increase, while
domestic mine production remains relatively constant, future domes-
tic supply will be derived increasingly from imports and secondary
sources. According to Bureau of Mines projections, based on pat-
terns of current use, including increased demand for automobile bat-
teries, building construction and tetraethyl lead with normal pop-
ulation growth, and assuming a high level of industrial growth,
total lead demand in the United States is expected to be ap-
proximately 1.45 million tons by 1970. (In 1955, total demand
was about 1.2 million tons.) But during the 4 years ended in 1953
mine production of lead was only 28 percent of domestic supply, while
imports and secondary lead each furnished 36 percent.~ During
1952-53, if stock accumulation and exports had been eliminated, actual
consumption would have required about 257,000 tons of imported
lead annually, rather than the 368,000 tons actually imported. Thus
the United States does not depend on foreign sources of supply to the
degree the imports suggest.25
`~ U.S. Tariff Commission, "Lead and Zinc" (1958), statIstical appendix, table 35.
~ U.S. Tariff Commision, "Lead and Zinc" (1958), statistical appendix, tables 5 and 6.
~` See Bishop and Mentch, "Lead," bc. cit., p. 443.
~ Total imports from Canada and Mexico alone during 1950-53 averaged almost 250,000
tons.
PAGENO="0091"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 83
For zinc, in the 4 years ended 1953, domestic production met only
44 percent of the total supply, imports 34 percent, and secondary
recovery 22 percent. Discounting stock accumulation and exports,
U.S. imports requirements in the period 1940-53 averaged about
238,000 tons annually to meet industrial needs. This compares with
actual imports (metal equivalent) of about 388,000 tons a year during
that period, or on the average 150,000 tons over consumption. Dur-
ing 1950-53, imports of recoverable metal totaled 1,180,000 tons, or
444,000 tons over the quantity needed to balance supply and require-
ments excluding exports. According to the Bureau of Mines, how-
ever, imports of about 230,000 tons a year would have been ample to
fulfill domestic needs which could not have been met from domestic
sources.2°
THE ESCAPE CLAUSE INVESTIGATIONS
Even though the United States has greatly expanded its overall
requirements for lead and zinc, it has not been able to keep up with
the high production of foreign suppliers. This situation has caused
a general and sustained fall in prices for the two metals. In the
domestic industry, although prices declined, costs (wage rates and
prices of machinery and supplies) did not decline. Imports in the
meantime stayed high. With ample supplies of metals available,
domestic mine production decreased, mines were closed, and employ-
ment declined. In July 1953, the Senate Finance Committee and the
House Ways and Means Committee directed the Tariff Commission to
make a thorough study of all factors of the domestic lead and zinc
situation.27 In September 1953 the Tariff Commission instituted an
escape clause investigation under section 7 of the Trade Agreements
Extension Act of 1951.28 The report of the industry investigation
was factual and contained no recommendation. It showed that the
existing tariff structure restricted imports of lead and zinc but
slightly, and that during the preceding decade a substantial part of
all imports was exempt from duty, and that rates of duty in effect
were only having a slight effect upon the competitive position of the
industry.29
Commissioners Edminster and Ryder, however, felt compelled to
make more comprehensive statements with regard to policy decisions
(ibid., pp. 91 and 95). Edminster pointed out that increased duties
would not help the domestic industries. In the first place, the do-
mesti.c price structure of the metals was tied to world prices. Im-
position of import restrictions, diverting from the U.S. market the
considerable and increasing portions of exportable surpluses of for-
eign countries of these metals would tend to depress their world
prices. This in turn would tend to limit the effectiveness of the im-
port restrictions in raising domestic metal prices. Edminster also
mentioned the possibility of market conditions offering strong in-
centives for use of substitutes for both metals when prices were
relatively high, and the fact that under such conditions there was
added incentive to reclaim secondary lead and zinc. Both tendencies
~ Bishop and Mentch, "Zinc," bc. cit., p. 1000.
~ See U.S. Tariff Commission, "Lead and Zinc Industries" (1954).
~ See U.S. Tariff Commission, "Lead and Zinc" (1954). [Escape clause investigation
No. 27.] Another investigation was completed in 1958. (See below.)
20 "Lead and Zinc IndustrIes" (1954)', p. 89.
PAGENO="0092"
84 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
would offset any protective effect an increase in import; restrictions
would have. Edminster finally mentioned the fact that additional
restrictions on imports would tend to encourage the expansion of
domestic operations and the working of ores the exploitation of
which would not otherwise be economically feasible. This would con-
tribute to bringing about a situation where new marginal mines would
have difficulties in maintaining operations even at the higher prices
resulting from the increased restrictions.
Commissioner Ryder set forth the general outlines of a policy deal-
ing with import competition in extractive industries which should
attempt to reconcile, as far as possible, the divergent interests of pro-
ducers and consumers, and to integrate these private interests with
the overriding national interest. Action on the one hand would he
directed toward maintaining substantial lead- and zinc-mining indus-
tries in the United States, and affording them such assistance (in the
form of import restriction or subsidization) as may be required to
maintain production at levels generally prevailing in post-World War
II years. On the other hand, action would also be directed to the
maintenance of adequate imports of lead and zinc, and any stringent
restriction of imports would be avoided. Such a program would not
tend to increase prices to such a degree as materially to discourage
domestic lead and zinc production. Existing industries and the com-
munities dependent on them would be protected to the extent neces-
sary to prevent serious injury which might occur if domestic pro-
ducers were required to submit to the impact of unrestricted imports
without any form of governmental assistance. At the same time,
Government policy would not give rise to a rapid expansion of lead
and zinc mining irrespective of costs. And while such a program
would enable the United States to maintain its lead and zinc indus-
tries, it would permit the United States to maintain good relations
with other lead- and zinc-mining countries, especially Canada and
Mexico, and encourage the maintenance of well-developed lead and
zinc industries in those countries. This would be especially important
since in the event of a serious national emergency this country would
be largely dependent upon them to supply its increased requirements
for lead and ~
The report on the first escape clause investigation (in 1954) recom-
mended that import duties on most lead and zinc materials be in-
creased 50 percent.3' The administration, however, did not accept the
Commission's recommendation, and instead instituted an expanded
stockpiling program with a view to assisting the domestic lead and
zinc industry.32
Beginning August 1954, Government purchases of newly mined
domestic lead and zinc for the strategic stockpile were greatly ac-
celerated in relation to the rate of acquisition of these metals in im-
mediately preceding years. Prices of the metals increased, lead from
14 to 16.5 cents by January 1956, and zinc from 11 to 13.5 cents.33
3°Ibid., p. 97.
31 Tariff duties in effect in early 1958 were about 60 percent lower for zinc and 50
percent lower for lead than the statutory rates in the Tariff Act of 1930. The decrease
in ad valorem equivalents of current rates of duty compared with ad valorein equivalents
of prewar years is considerably larger than the reduction In specific duties because prices
of the two metals have increased considerably.
3° See appendix 2 of this chapter for a discussion of stockpfflng.
3° See U.S. Tariff Commission, "Lead and Zinc" (1958), Escape Clause Investigation
No. 65, pp. 34-35.
PAGENO="0093"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 85
Beginning June 1956, lead and zinc of foreign origin was purchased
by the Government in exchange for perishable surplus agricultural
commodities under the so-called "barter program." ~ This program
was in operation until June 1957, when it was suspended.
In 1957, consumption in the United States of both lead and zinc
was somewhat lower because the decline of business activity, and mine
production likewise was somewhat lower. But im~orts of lead were
575,000 tons-18 percent higher than in 1956. Supplies exceeded
consumption and export by a wide margin, which was not absorbed
by Government purchases. Zinc imports (951,000 tons) rose even
higher, 30 percent above the 1956 level of imports, which was higher
than imports in any previous year. Even excluding imports under
the barter program, total zinc imports amounted to 757,000 tons in
1957. Government purchases also were insufficient to absorb excess
supplies.
Market prices for both metals declined sharply. As of April 1958,
lead was at 12 cents, and zinc had dropped to 10 cents. These prices
were 2 cents and one-f ourth cent respectively below the prices that
prevailed in May 1954 when the Tariff Commission sent its first
escape clause report to the President.
The second escape clause investigation was begun in October 1957,
on application by the Emergency Lead-Zinc Committee, representing
domestic lead and zinc mining interests. The investigation resulted
in a unanimous finding of serious injury. However, the Commission
split on recommended remedial action. Whereas three Commissioners
recommended reimposition of the rates originally imposed by the
Tariff Act of 1930, the maximum rates permissible through escape-
clause action, the other three recommended such duties to be supple-
mented by absolute import quotas.35
According to the Tariff Commission, the biggest factors in the de-
cline of market prices were overexpanded world production, with-
drawal of U.S. Government support through the barter program, and
a moderate decline in consumption.36 There was a worldwide ex-
cess of supplies, Govermnent stockpiling purchases were coming to
an end, as stockpile goals were being reached, and industrial con-
sumption was shrinking because of generally reduced industrial
activity.
Mining and milling companies, especially those without their own
smelting facilities, bear the brunt of the impact of market price cuts,
in the face of increased costs of labor, supplies and materials, mining
equipment, freight rates, and other expense.37 As a result, mine
output for many areas in the United States was substantially lower
in 1957 than in 1954. Employment was cut correspondingly, and
mines were closed down. Closures were not limited to the small- and
medium-size mines; operations were also completely suspended at 5
of the 34 largest lead and zinc mines in 1956.38 The Commission, as
indicated, unanimously concluded that the domestic lead and zinc
~ Under the Agricultural Trade Development and Assistance Act of i954 (Public Law
480, 83d Cong.) and related legislation.
°~ Reimposition of 19S0 act rates would have meant an increase of current rates of duty
by 140 percent for unmanufactured lead and 200 percent for unmanufactured zinc. See
"Lead and Zinc" (1958), statIstical appendix, table 3.
se "Lead and Zinc" (1958), p. 41.
`~ Ibid., pp. 45-47.
"Ibid., p. 53.
PAGENO="0094"
86 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
industries were being seriously injured by increased imports. In
the absence of alternative remedies, they unanimously recommended
increases in duty, and divided on imposition of absolute quotas.39
FEATURES OF A TRADE ADJUSTMENT PROGRAM
Despite a finding of serious injury by the Commission, it was
pointed out that conditions in the industry were spotty. While cut-
backs and reduced employment have been severe in the tristate area
and Montana, for example, they were much less so in southeastern
Missouri, in States east of the Mississippi, and in Arizona, Colorado,
Idaho, and Washington. And employment at mines and mills in
New York, New Jersey, Pennsylvania, Tennessee, and Virginia was
generally higher in 1957 than in 1956.~° In general, the overall de-
cline in production and employment resemble that which prevailed
on past occasions when these industries-subject to periodical
fluctuations that reflect changes in world supply, demand, and
prices-were in the trough of a cycle. The better situated and
stronger companies also appear to be fully able to "ride out" the
trough. This leaves high-cost domestic mines that operate at little
or no profit even in good times to be taken care of. In helping them,
care must be taken not to inflict losses, in terms of jobs and profits,
on other segments of the industries.
One solution to the world problem of oversupply is increased con-
sumption, with careful market research guiding any future produc-
tion expansion programs. Since consumption is stimulated by low
metal prices, efforts to improve extractive techniques and to lower
costs per unit of output would help to overcome that difficulty.
But costs of some domestic mining enterprises are bound to be
too high for profitable operations. The problem of providing relief
without restricting trade thus becomes one of deciding at what point
of the range high-cost producers would be cut off. Various considera-
tions enter into such a decision. Humphrey has observed that-
the case for protection [of mining industriesj derives its strength from the insta-
bility of prices.
But he also points out that-
once mines are abandoned, flooding and caving in * * * make the cost of re-
opening shafts and tunnels prohibitive. If mines are not in continuous opera-
tion, * * * they will deteriorate so badly that they cannot be reopened. This
leads to the paradoxical argument the production from low-grade reserves
should be subsidized by tariff protection in the interest of conserving natural
resources.~
Support of uneconomic but essential high-cost mines on a realistic
basis could be provided by some form of payment. This method would
very likely cost less than imposition of a higher tariff on the metals,
for domestic mines output is a relatively small part of total supply,
and an increase in the cost of imports would tend to raise overall
costs to consumers of lead and zinc. But such an increase in tariffs
would still not assure a market for domestic primary production since
domestic production alone is basically inadequate for domestic re-
89 IbId., p. 73 and p. 85. For subseonent actions by the administration, see footnotes
1 and 2 to this chapter, above.
`°U.S. Tariff Commission, "Lead and 7tnc" (1958), pp. 1O4~-1O7, and stati~t1~al appsndlz,
~ab1e 37.
~ Humphrey, Don D., "American Imports" (New York, 1953), p. 178.
PAGENO="0095"
TRADE ADJuSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 87
quirements at a reasonable price. Any increase in the domestic metal
price sufficient to keep a major portion of high-cost mines in operation
would tend to call forth greater utilization of substitutes on the one
hand and greater production of metal from scrap and from tailings.
The latter two moves would evidently have a depressing effect on
primary metal prices.42
However, in order to administer "phasing-out" payments, an in-
crease in bureaucratic controls would be necessary. Readjustment
assistance must be limited: it must constitute only temporary support,
offered with a view to achieving structural changes wherever
possible. Once the desired structural change is achieved, the assist-
ance must be terminated. In the case of lead and zinc mining, this
would mean that high-cost operators would have to go and quit min-
ing. These operators would be the ones required to make the adapta-
tions necessary for the structural change in the industry.
The determination of the cutoff point for high-cost producers
would raise considerable problems, however. The point would vary
according to the prevailing metal prices, and would also be subject
to engineering advice. In view of the fact that there are no security
considerations present in the case of lead and zinc, with the TJ.S.
mobilization base including Mexican as well as Canadian suppliers of
the metal, no difficulty about easing marginal domestic producers out
of the industry would arise on that score. Political obstacles are a
horse of a different color, and ways would have to be found to cope
with them.
Currently the problem of the lead and zinc mining industry is one
of oversupply. Unless a readjustment assistance program is limited
to helping domestic mines go out of production, the oversupply prob-
lem will not even come near to being solved. A scheme such as the
"premium price plan" (see app. 1 of this chapter) would obviously
not fill the bill since it would only bring new producers into the field-
indeed a case of carrying quicksilver to Almaden.
Another difficulty such an assistance program would encounter
would be foreign producers increasing their production even at exist-
ing low prices.4~ This last point, however, might be less troublesome if
a trade adjustment program, such as the one outlined below, were
adopted.
The trade adjustment program would be confined to small inde-
pendent mine operators. This limitation suggests itself on the
theory that larger mining companies either are sufficiently inte-
grated-owning smelting and refining facilities-so as to be able to
rely on processing imported ores when operations of their domestic
mining properties run into difficulties pricewise; or that these com-
panies have at their disposal a large enough number of other mining
properties allowing them to shift miners from high-cost to lower cost
~ At the same time, producers in Canada and Mexico, part of this country's mobilization
base, would be injured. Although this point is not often publicly mentioned, President
Eisenhower in a letter to Representative Jere Cooper of the House Ways and Means
Committee, of Aug. 23, 1957 (mimeographed White House release), declined to utilize the
national security amendment of the Trade Agreements Extension Act to afford relief to the
lead and zinc industries-an indirect public admission of this country's dependence on
Canadian and Mexican lead and zinc in an emergency situation.
~ Peru, for example, was reported to have suspeded its export tax rn lead and zinc
during 1957 in order to facilitate shipments to the United States at prevailing low prices.
PAGENO="0096"
88 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
operations,~~ while putting the former on a standby basis. The ra-
tionale of the program would be "least cost to the economy," as op-
posed to affording relief to the mining operators by an indirect sub-
sidy in the form of an increase in tariff duties.
The ~program would be aimed toward closing certain lead and
zinc mines. Mine closures cause difficulties in terms of upkeep, as
noted earlier. Moreover, some of the high-cost mines, particularly
those producing lead and zinc ores with silver content, will wish
to remain in production or in a standby condition.
The program also would have to have a "birth control" clause so as
to avoid the bringing in of new mines, possibly of a marginal char-
acter, that would add to existing supply difficulties.
An important cost item in a readjustment assistance program in a
mineral industry may be the "mothballing" of mines so as to keep
them in standby condition for eventual reopening. The cost of such
"mothballing" varies widely, from anywhere near 2 percent to 10 per-
cent of the annual operating costs of the given mine. The major
variables affecting the costs of standby arrangements are the wetness
of the mine, and required pumping connected with it; and the hard-
ness of the ground, which determines the cost of supports.
In the case of lead and zinc2 such "mothballing" would certainly be
more expensive than stockpiling: in a lead-zinc stockpile, the metals
can be dumped at the appropriate location without cover-custodial
services and financial expenses on initial outlay constituting the only
costs in addition to the amount required for acquisition. Stockpiling,
however, offers no solution for readjustment. If "mothballing" is
indicated, and a decision to that effect cannot be taken on economic
grounds alone, the mine should not be included in a trade adjustment
program. Government assistance in "mothballing" can only be justi-
fied in terms of national security, and would thus fall outside the pur-
view of trade adjustment.
It would seem, therefore, that temporary assistance for readapta-
tion, either in the form of tapering off grants or of loans from the
Small Business Administration, would be the most economical way
of solving the problem posed for the small lead and zinc mine opera-
tor by increased imports.
ANOTHER PROPOSAL
A variant of this proposal could take the following form: ~ It
would entail purchase of mineral and surface rights from marginal
mineowner-operators in return for their going out of production and
having the mines withdrawn, while they undertake to seek other more
profitable pursuits (possibly with temporary import controls). Such
a program could be so designed that a computer could provide con-
tinuous performance check on the basis of available information. A
separate agreement would be made with each mine to be withdrawn,
~` This method reportedly has been employed by captive fluorspar mining operations.
Also, in the case of fluorspar mining in the Illinois-Kentucky district, small companies or
ipdividuals with limited capital have been working side by side with larger producers. As
cost of production has increased in recent years, there has been a trend toward acquisition
of many of the individual properties by a few financially strong concerns. (See U.S. Tariff
Commission, "Fluorspar," investig~tion under sec. 332 pursuant to resolution by Senate
Finance Committee, Washington, D.C., June 1955, pp. 51-52.) No tendency toward such
a concentration of ownership has been reported in lead and zinc mining.
44a ~ am endebted to Edward B. Hincks for calling attention to this procedure.
PAGENO="0097"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 89
setting forth, among other items, the schedule of assistance payments;
production ceilings for successive periods, if desirable, but phasing
production out to zero by the end of the adjustment period; and an
outline of readaptation avenues the owner will undertake or ex-
plore during the transition period. The payments for the mineral
rights will be so scheduled as to terminate at the end of the transition
period.
In order to have meaningful performance control by an informa-
tion system the following objectives will have to be defined and pro-
gramed, utilizing the information given further on: (1) "Micro ob-
jective": Closing of marginal mines after acquisition of mineral rights
by adjustment authority, and former owner-operator having success-
fully settled in another line of production. (2) "Macro objective":
All other lead and zinc mines remaining in production in the United
States are economically viable, contribute to overall economic growth
of this country, and require no tariff or quota protection against com-
petitive imports.
The achievement of the "micro objective" would be measured against
the target number of mines to be retired from production, and the
target number of former owner-operators and miners formerly em-
ployed by the closed mines who must find new occupations. This in-
formation is essentially a summation of the individual targets con-
tained in the individual agreements signed between owner-operator
and administering authority-the achievement of the "macro objec-
tive" would be measured against current data on mine production
collected and published by the Bureau of Mines, as well as prices, im-
ports, and exports of the two metals, and projected future resource
requirement balances, and by cessation of Federal appropriation.
READJUSTMENT OF MINERS
Finally, something should be said about readjustment for workers
in marginal lead-zinc mines. Their problem appears to be relatively
minor. For one thing, most small-scale mining operations employ
very few workers. If Government assistance is provided for the
owner, his labor force presumably can be included in the readjust-
ment without too much difficulty.45
Miners in general are, in a highly skilled occupation and, other
things being equal, face less difficulty in retraining for or
finding other types of skilled employment.~~ For those workers who
own homes in communities which they may be obliged to leave as a
result of mine closures, direct financial assistance may indeed be re-
quired. However, it stands to reason that even such help would be
extremely moderate in comparison with the costs imposed on the econ-
omy, through an increase in rates of duty on lead and zinc, or the
imposition of quantitative restrictions.
~ Some of the smaller mines, except those in the Western States, have been known to go
in and out of production over the years, depending on cyclical conditions, and part-time
mining has prevailed. Readjustment assistance for these mines would be directed to
strengthen nonmining part-time employment.
~ The risk of casual employment in hardrock mining also is generally discounte4 for by
the relatively higher wages for miners than those prevailing in other lines of work.
,76697-61-------7
PAGENO="0098"
90 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
CONCLUSION
The purpose of the last three chapters has been to describe and
evaluate a set of methods designed to solve the problem of how con-
sumers may be allowed to benefit from freer international trade with-
out at the same time injuring certain segments of domestic industry
by the resulting increase in competitive imports. The suggested solu-
tion in essence consists of a series of federally sponsored programs of
orderly readjustment to economic change. Trade adjustment would
have to be applied in different form in the various sectors of the econ-
omy. The three chapters have shown hypothetical applications of such
program' in manufacturing, agriculture, and mining. One finding is
abundantly clear: No matter where they are put into effect, the trade
adjustment programs would be less costly to the American taxpayer
than a retention of existing tariff barriers.
Furthermore, a policy of trade adjustment would allow separating
domestic economic problems from objectives pursued by this country
in its foreign economic policy. Now the two areas of decisionmaking
are rigidly linked via the tariff issue: virtually any constructive move
on the foreign plane, in terms of this country accepting a larger vc~lume
of imports, leads to severe injury for some home industry. A readap-
tation program might be likened to a set of surgical hemostats clamped
to blood vessels severed by the blow. The hemostats stop further loss
of blood and allow sutures to be taken. In that way they expedite the
healing process that sets in after the operation has been successfully
performed.47 But in order to successfully implement a policy of Fed-
eral trade adjustment, a good deal of further research is needed for the
difficulties and possibilities of readaptation vary greatly among differ-
ent industries. Even the three hypothetical applications described in
some detail in this study constitute little more than scratches on the
surface of this vital but extremely complex subject.
471n the metaphor the managers of the enterprises doing the readapting obviously would
be the surgeons.
PAGENO="0099"
APPENDIX TO CHAPTER VIII
PROPOSED REMEDIES FOR LEAD AND ZINC MINING
OTHER THAN TRADE RESTRICTIONS
TIlE PREMIIJM PRICE PLAN
During World War II, while ceiling prices were being maintained
on lead and zinc (as well as other metals) various measures had to
be taken to increase domestic mine production. The most important
of these was the "premium price plan." 1 This plan, instituted in 1941,
entailed the payment of a comparatively high price for high-cost
marginal mine output, in excess of the prevailing ceiling price for
the metals. These higher prices were applicable to production in
excess of officially set quotas. As costs increased during the war,
quotas were decreased, and premiums were paid on progressively
larger amounts of total production. The plan in effect tended to be-
come a method of helping companies achieve a reasonable return on
investments.
Oversupply, coupled with price instability, rather than inadequate
supply, characterize the lead-zinc mining industry now. The pre-
mium price scheme therefore would not be applicable to the present
situation.2
STOCKPILING
A method frequently advocated and used for affording relief to lead
and zinc mining has been Government purchases for stockpiling.3
There now exist three stockpiles in this country: the strategic stock-
pile, established in 1946; the long-term stockpile for minerals and
metals, established in 1954; and the supplemental stockpile for non-
perishable strategic materials having low storage costs, also estab-
lished in 1954.
Two objectives of stockpiles may be distinguished: security, and
price support. In general, if the given materials can be stored, and
if there are no difficult marketing problems, stockpiling may be more
economical, from the standpoint of security, than expanding produc-
tion. The cost of taking the material for future use out of current
markets and holding them is likely to be lower than the cost of getting
1 See O'akes, Eugene E., "Incentives for Minerals Industries," the President's Materials
Policy Commission, Resources for Freedom (Washington, 1952). vol. V, selected reports to
the Commission, No. 3, p. 23,
The scheme was abandoned on ~une 30, 1947, as the result of President Truman's
vetoing Its continuation for another 2 years. The administration pointed out at the time
that with the high prices for the metals then current, the plan would not have produced a
substantial Increase in production; the cost of the plan was excessive; and the plan
had adverse "conversion effects" In that It tended to encourage premature production,
especially from dumps and tailings. See Oakes, bc. cit.
`For a general discussion, see Mendershausen, Iiorst, "Stockpiling Materials for Se-
curity," Resources for Freedom, vol. V, Selected Reports to the Commission, No. 17,
pp. 137-149.
91
PAGENO="0100"
92 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
them from marginal sources. Conversely, maintaining marginal pro-
ductioti facilities over a period of years is likely to be more costly
in terms of subsidies required than keeping a stockpile.
There is, however, an inverse relation between Government buy-
ing for stockpiling and governmental support of mineral prices.
Development stockpile purchases add to the demand for the mineral;
they tend to sustain production, and/or create an incentive to expan-
sion. Thus stockpiling tends to be a costly way of price support, par-
ticularly if not coupled with appropriate import restrictions.
Metal stockpiling beyond the goal required by purely military needs
is not an alternative to a readjustment assistance program to relieve
injury resulting from increased imports. The lead and zinc stock-
piling program, as carried on in the United States since 1954,~ with
relatively unrestricted imports, has meant that the United States has
been sucking in excess production of these metals of practically the
entire world. Since it has not dealt with excess production in the
United States alone, the program was bound to be more expensive
than a support program with import restrictions, such as that in
effect under section 22 of the Agricultural Adjustment Act. In the
absence of such restrictions, the program covered a much wider field
than would be contemplated by a readjustment assistance program
for lead and zinc mines. However, stockpiling with import restric-
tions renders pointless any comparison with an adjustment assistance
program, designed to bring about freer trade.5
INTERNATIONAL BUFFER STOCKS
In order to alleviate necessary readjustments by domestic lead and
zinc producers that would appear to be necessary in the absence of
curtailed imports, it has been variously suggested that a "buffer"
stockpile be established, both nationally and internationally, so as to
allow any readjustments in the industries to be shared by domestic
and foreign producers. On the domestic side, this would mean estab-
lishing a Metals Credit Corporation (analogous to the Conmiodity
Credit Corporation) with authority to purchase metals and minerals
to be stored in the buffer stockpile. This arrangement would be ac-
companied by a system of production quotas agreed to by foreign
and domestic producers.
Although international buffer stocks have often been urged as a
stabilizing device for metal prices, there has been no experience with
them except for their limited use under international tin control
schemes.6
Office of Defense Mobilization, "Stockpile Report to the Congress," January-June
1955 (Washington, D.C., 1955), p. 6. On effect of stockpiling in lieu of tariff relief,
see Tariff Commission memorandum on S. 2376 (Sliding-scale tariff on lead and zinc),
In "Import Tax on Lead and Zinc," hearings before Senate Finance Committee on S. 2376,
86th Cong., let sess. (Washington, D.C., 1957). p. 10.
The U.S. Bureau of Mines estimates that the average price of lead and zinc would
have been 11/2 cents lower without the barter stockpile (Government metal purchases in
exchange for surplus agricultural commodities) in operation between 1954 and 1957, and
1 cent lower without the Government stockpile program initiated in 1954. (Communi-
cation from Office of Chief Economist, U.S. Bureau of Mines.)
C See, for example, Randall Commission, "Staff Papers," p. 192. For general die.-
cussion of buffer stocks, see Davies, Joseph S., "International Commodity Agreements,"
Committee on International Economic Policy, Carnegie Endowment for International
Peace (NeW York, 1947), pp. 26-36; and Mason, Edward S., "Controlling World Trade:
Cartels and Commodity Agreements," CED research study (New York, 1946), pp. 167 sq.
PAGENO="0101"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 93
The application of buffer stock arrangements to lead and zinc is
complicated by the existence of national stockpiles of these products,
possibly exceeding the levels of proposed buffer stocks. There is also
is a strong tendency on the part of producers to interpret stabiliz-
ing as "boosting," with resistance directed primarily against falling
rather than against rising prices. Moreover, the problem of fore-
casting demand-supply relations even for limited periods gives rise
to extraordinary difficulties.
On an international basis, a buffer-stock arrangement not only
would involve enormous investment in the two metals but also a cor-
responding concentration of power. This would make it politically
impracticable. Political difficulties also would arise in operations.
Producers of the metals are numerous and well organized. National
pressures brought to bear on the management of the buffer would
be so strong as to defeat its fundamental purpose.
Lead and zinc are now in surplus in the sense that portions of the
industry receive "persistently" low returns in relation to the resources
they employ. The economic problem in buffer-stock management
would be to differentiate between long-run price changes due to
changes in consumer preferences or in costs of production, and those
which would sooner or later be corrected by the opposite action of mar-
ket forces. The buffer's function would be to straighten out the short-
period price fluctuation sooner rather than later.
A workable production quota scheme would be necessary to set up
quotas adequate to insure the consistent maintenance of a level or
trend of prices which would enable the buffer to control price changes
which the market would in time reverse. If the buffer stock is of suf-
ficient size, these price variations can be compensated for without quota
changes. But the control authority may wish to counteract price
variations by changes in the quota, while holding the buffer to small
dimensions. A change in quota is of little use in protecting prices
against short-run variations; it must be effective for a considerable
period of time, and even then it may overshoot its mark.r
In the case of lead and zinc there has been persistent overproduc-
tion in recent years. Under such conditions, a buffer stock can func-
tion only in conjunction with a quota scheme. But with many
producers-and there are many more lead and zinc producers than
producers of tin, for example-agreement on quotas would be difficult
to achieve. A quota scheme for zinc would moreover be impracti-
cable because it would be difficult to administer in view of the great
number of individual commodities involved and the variation in metal
content.8 A base period would also have to be chosen which would
be bound to discriminate against foreign producers of recent vintage
who were still bringing in new mines and had not yet attained peak
level of production. A buffer stock program for lead would be easier
to handle, for lead is being mined in relatively fewer areas than zinc.
However, there is also less reason for supporting lead than there is
for supporting zinc, particularly as long as automobile batteries make
up two-thirds of lead's uses.
In a buffer stock without a production quota scheme, the management not only has
no control over supply in response to the level or structure of prices, but pressure from
producers for higher prices would directly affect buffer-stock operations instead of in-
directly, via the adjustment of quotas.
On reasons against metals and concentrates quotas, see 115. Tariff Commission,
"Lead and Zinc," report on escape clause investigation No. 65 (Washington, D.C., April
1958), pp. 94-100.
PAGENO="0102"
PAGENO="0103"
BIBLIOGRAPHY
BOOKS AND REPORTS
American Leather Glove Industry, Statement by the Employees and Management
to Committee on Reciprocity Information, Gloversville, New York, 1950.
Benedict, M.R., Farm Policies of the United States, 1790-1950, New York,
1953.
Benedict, M. R. and Stine 0., The Agricultural Commodity Programs, New York,
1956.
Bidwell, Percy W., What the Tariff Means to American Industries, New York,
1956.
Camps, Miriam, The European Common Market and American Policy, Memoran-
dum No. 11, Center of International Studies, Princeton University, 1956.
Commission on Organization of the Executive Branch, Task Force Report on
Lending Agencies, Washington, D.C., 1955.
Commission on Organization of the Executive Branch, Lending Agencies, A
Report to Congress, Washington, D.C., 1955.
Committee on Economic Development, United States Tariff Policy, New York,
1954.
Commodity Credit Corporation, Reports on Financial Conditions and Operations
(annual).
Davies, Joseph S., International Commodity Agreements, New York, 1947.
Diebold, William, Jr., The Schuman Plan, A Study in Economic Cooperation,
1950-1959, New York, 1959.
Fisher, A. G. B., Economic Progress and Social Security, London, 1946.
Gloversville, Report on, (Workshop on Commodity Study), Gloversville, New
York, 1954.
Hinrichs, A. Ford, Iowa and World Trade, An Economic Analysis of the First
Congressional District of Iowa, Washington, D.C., 1954.
Humphrey, Don D., American Imports, Twentieth Century Fund, New York,
1955.
Joint Committee on the Economic Report, The Need for Industrial Dispersal,
Washington, D.C., 1951.
Lister, Louis, Europe's Coal and Steel Community, An E~cperiment in Economic
Union, New York, 1960.
Marshall, Alfred, Principles of Economics, 8th ed., London, 1920.
Mason, Edward S., Controlling World Trade, Cartels and Commodity Agree-
ments, New York, 1946.
Miernyk, William H., Inter-Industry Labor Mobility: The Case of the Displaced
Tea~tile Worker, Boston, 1955.
Myrdal, Gunnar, An International Economy, New York, 1956.
National Planning Association, Depressed Industrial Areas-A National Prob-
1cm, Planning Pamphlet No. 98, Washington, D.C., 1957.
National Planning Association, Local Impact on Foreign Trade, Washington,
1960.
New York State, Department of Commerce, New York State Business Facts,
1954 Supplement, Mohawk Valley, Albany, New York, 1954.
New York State, Department of Labor, Division of Employment, Labor Market
Reports, Gloversville Labor Market Area, October, 1954.
New York State, Joint Legislative Committee on Commerce and Economic De-
velopment, Reports for 1954 and 1955, Albany, New York, 1954 and 1955.
Office of Defense Mobilization, Stockpile Reports to the Congress (semi-annual).
Piquet, Howard S., Aid Trcufe and the Tariff, Including a Handbook of Major
Dutiable United States Imports, New York, 1953.
S President's Materials Policy Commission, Resources for Freedom (Paley Re-
port), Washington, 1952.
95
PAGENO="0104"
96 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
Princeton University, International Finance Section and Center of International
Studies, A Critique o/the Randall Commission Report on United State8 For-
eign Economic Policy, Princeton, New Jersey, 1954.
Public Advisory Board for Mutual Security, A Trade and Tariff Policy in the
National Interest, A Report to the President, Washington, D.C., 1953. (Bell
Report.)
Randall, Clarence B., A Foreign Economic Policy for the United States, (Wal-
green Foundation Lectures), Chicago, Ill., 1954.
Salant, W. S. & Vaccara, B., Import Liberalization and Employment, Wash-
ington, D.C., 1961.
Small Business Administration, Public Statement of Loan Policy, Washington,
D.C., 1954.
Smithies, Arthur, The Budgetary Process in the United States, New York, 1955.
Staley, Eugene, World Economic Development, Effect on Advaneed Industrial
Countries, end ed., Montreal, 1945.
Steinberg, David J., A Time for Decision in U.S. Foreign Trade Policy (mirneo-
graphed) Washington, D.C., 19d1.
Taussig, F. W., The Tariff History of the United States, 8th ed., New York,
1931.
Thorp, Willard L., Trade, Aid or What?, Baltimore, Md., 1954.
U.S. Agricultural Marketing Service, Wool Statistics and Related Data, Sept.,
1954.
U.S. Bureau of Mines, Mineral Facts and Problems (Bulletin No. 556), Wash-
Ington, D.C., 1956.
U.S. Commission on Foreign Economic Policy, Report to the President and
Congress, Washington, D.C., 1954. (Randall Report.)
U.S. Commission on Foreign Economic Policy, Staff Papers Presented to the
Commission, Washington, D.C., 1954.
U.S. Commission on Intergovernmental Relations, A Report to the President for
Transmittal to Congress, Washington, D.C., 1955.
U.S. Commission on Organization of the Executive Branch, Lending Agencies, A
Report to Congress, Washington, D.C., 1955. (Hoover Commission.)
U.S. Commission on Organization of the Executive Branch, Task Force Report
on Lending Agencies, Washington D.C., 1955.
U.S. Congress, Joint Committee on the Economic Report, Federal Taw Policy
for Economic Growth and Stability, Washington, D.C., 1956.
U.S. Congress, Joint Economic Committee, Defense Essentiality and Foreign
Economic Policy, Washington, D.C., 1956.
U.S. Department of Agriculture, Development of Agriculture's Human Resource~s,
A Report on Problems of Low-Income Farmers, Washington, D.C., 1955.
U.S. Department of Agriculture, Domestic Wool Requirements and Sources of
Supply, Washington, D.C., 1950.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Area Development Division, Available Federal
Assistance for Community Development, Washington, D.C., 1955.
11.5, Department of Labor, Bureau of Employment Security, Bimonthly Sum-
mary of Labor Market Developments in Major Areas, March, 1952.
U.S. Department of Labor, Division of Interindustry Economics, Industrial Em-
ployment in the United States as Related to Ecoports in 1947, Washington, D.C.,
1952.
U.S. House of Representatives, Committee on Ways and Means, 84th CongresS,
1st Session, Trade Agreements Ea,tension, Hearings, 2 Parts, Washington, D.C.,
1955.
U.S. House of Representatives, Committee on Ways and Means, Subcommittee
on Foreign Trade, Hearings, Foreign Trade Policy, 85th Congress, 1st Session,
pursuant to H. Res. 104, Washington, 1958.
U.S. Joint Committee on Defense Production, 4th Annual Report of the Activities
of the, Washington, D.C., 1955.
U.S. Joint Committee on the Economic Report, Hearings Before the Subcom-
mittee on Foreign Economic Policy, Washington, D.C., 1955.
U.S. Office of Defense Mobilization, Defense Manpower Policy No. 4, (Revised),
Washington, DC., 1953.
U.S. Office of Defense Mobilization, Memorandum on Amortization to Defense
Facility E~vpansiOns Located in Areas of Substantial Labor Surplus, Wash-
ington, D.C., 1954.
U.S. Security and Exchange Commission, Cost of Flotation, 1945-1949, Wash-
ington, D.C., 1951.
PAGENO="0105"
TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE 97
U.S. Senate, Committee on Finance, Import Tax~ on Lead and Zinc, Hearings on
S. 2376, 85th Congress, 1st Session, Washington, D.C., 1957.
U.S. Senate, 84th Congress, 1st Session, Committee on Finance, Trade Agree~
ments Ecotension, Hearings, 4 Parts, Washington, D.C., 1955.
U.S. Senate, Committee on Interstate and Foreign Commerce, Encouragement of
Distribution of Fishery Products, Washington, D.C., 1954.
U.S. Senate, Committee on Interstate and Foreign Commerce, The United States
and World Trade. Challenges and Opportunities. (By Special Sta~ on
Study of U.S. Foreign Commerce), Washington, D.C., 1961.
U.S. Senate Special Committee on Unemployed Problems, Report, Pursuant
to S. Res. 196, 85th Congress, Washington, D.C., 1960.
U.S. Small Business Administration, Development Credit Corporations, Wash~
ington, D.C., 1954.
U.S. Tariff Commission, Fluorspar, Investigation under Section 332 Pursuant to
Resolution of Senate Finance Committee, Washington, June, 1955.
U.S. Tariff Commission, Groundflsh Fillets (1954), Report to the President
on Escape Clause Investigation No. 25, Under the Provisions of Section 7 of
the Trade Agreements Act of 1951, Washington, D.C., 1954.
U.S. Tariff Commission, Lead and Zinc, Report to the Congress on~ Investigation
No. 332-26 (Supplemental) Under Section 332 of the Tariff Act of 1930
Made Pursuant to Senate Resolution 162, 86th Congress, Adopted August 21,
1959, Washington, March, 1960.
U.S. Tariff Commission, Lead and Zinc Industries, Report on Investigation Con-
ducted Under Section 332 of the Tariff Act of 1930, etc. (Report No. 192,
Washington, D.C., 1954).
IJ.S. Tariff Commission, Lead and Zinc, Report to the President on Escape Clause
Investigation No. 65 Under Provisions of Section 7 of the Trade Agreements
Extension Act of 1951, as Amended, Washington, D.C., April, 1958.
U.S. Tariff Commission, Lead and Zinc, Report to the President (1960) Under
Executive Order 10401, Washington, October, 1960.
U.S. Tariff Commission, Summaries of Tariff Information, Washington, D~C.,
1948.
U.S. Tariff Commission, Women's and Children's Leather Gloves, Report on
Escape Clause Investigation No. 7-82, under Section 7 of the Trade Agree-
ments Extension Act of 1951, as Amended, Washington, D.C., 1960.
U.S. Tariff Commission, Wool Gloves and Mittens and Glove and Mitten Linings
of Wool, Report on Escape Clause Investigation No. 35 Under Section 7 of the
Trade Agreements Extension Act of 1951, Washington, D.C., 1954.
U.S. Tariff Commission, Wool Knit Gloves and Mittens, Report to the President,
etc., Section 336 of Title III of the Tariff Act of 1930, Report No. 108, Second
Series, Washington, D.C., 1936.
U.S. Tariff Commission, Wool, Wool Tops and Carbonized Wool, Report to the
President, Investigation No. 8 under Section 22 of the Agricultural Adjustment
Act, Amended, Washington, D.C., February, 1954.
Wiles, P. J. D., Price, Cost and Output, Oxford, 1956.
Wool Study Group Report (U.S.D.A.), Washington, 1953.
ARTIcLjcs
Bourque, Philip J., The Domestic Importance of Foreign Trade of the United
States by Producing Regions, Manufacturing Sectors, 1947, Review of Eco-
nomics and Statistics, November 1954, p. 401.
Clubb, Bruce E., and Reischer, 0. R., The Trade Adjustment Bills, Their Purpose
and Efficacy, Columbia Law Review, March 1961, pp. 490-503.
Federal Reserve Bank, Boston, What Happens When a Community Gains Manu-
facturing Jobs? Monthly Review, March 1955, p. 1.
Federal Reserve Bank, Kansas City, The Employment Multiplier in Wichita,
Monthly Review, September 30, 1952, p. 1.
Goode, Richard, Accelerated Depreciation Allowances: as a Stimulus to In-
vestment, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 69, No. 2, May 1955.
Hildebrand, George H. and Mace, Arthur Jr., The Employment Multiplier in an
Expanding Industrial Market: Los Angeles County, 1940-47, Review of Eco-
nomics and Statistics, August 1950, p. 241.
Hulley, John, Protect or Compensate? World Politics, April, 1953, p. 313.
Humphrey, Don D., Forces of Disequilibrium and World Order, American Eco-
nomic Review, May, 1954, p. 552.
PAGENO="0106"
98 TRADE ADJUSTMENT IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
Eravis, Irving B., The Growth Criterion as a Guide for Reciprocal Trade Policy,
Quarterly Journal of Economics, May, 1952, p. 273.
The Trade Agreements Escape Clause, American Economic Review, June,
1954, p. 319.
-, Wages and Foreign Trade, Review of Economics and Statistics, VoL 38,
No.1 (February 1956), p. 14.
Lindeman, John and Salant, W. S., Assistance for Readjustment to Tariff Reduc-
tions, Studies in Unemployment, Prepared for the Special Committee on Un-
employment Problems, U.S. Senate, 86th Congress, 2nd Session, Washington,
D.C., 1960, pp. 251-281.
Meade, James B., Negotiations for Benelux: An Annotated Chronicle, 1943-1956,
Princeton Studies in International Finance, No. 6, 1957.
Miller, John Perry, The Pricing Effect of Accelerated Amortization, Review of
Economics c~ Statistics, Vol 34, No. 1, February 1952, p. 17.
Piquet, Howard S., Tariff Reductions and United States Imports, Compendium
of Papers on United States Foreign Trade Policy, House Subcommittee on
Foreign Trade Policy, Washington, D.C., 1958, p. -.
Would Tariff Suspension Hurt U.S. Business? Harvard Business Review,
November-December, 1953, p. 95.
Reischer, Otto R., Adjustment to Imports and the National Interest, Journal of
Business of the University of Chicago, October 1953, p. 254.
Assistance in Adjusting to a Tariff Reduction, Journal of Business of the
University of Chicago, April 1953, p. 103.
-~, Lower Tariffs Without Pain, Michigan State Business Topics, Vol. 3, No.
6 (May1956), 13-22.
The "Defense Essentiality" of Readjustment Assistance, Hearings be-
fore the Subcommittee on Foreign Trade Policy, Committee on Ways and Means,
U.S. House of Represenatives, 85th Congress, 1st Session, Washington, D.C.,
1958, pp. 816-822.
,Statement on S. 1609, "Assistance to Small Business to Facilitate Adjust-
ment Made Necessary by Foreign Trade," in Small Business Adjustments
1959, Hearings before Small Business Subcommittee, U.S. Senate Committee
on Banking and Currency, 86th Congress, 1st Session, Washington, D.C., 1959.
Robertson, W., Benelux and Problems of Economic Integration, Ow ford Economic
Papers, N.S. Vol. 8, No. 1 (February 1956), p. 50.
Salant, W.S., Employment Effects of United States Import Liberalization, Amer-
ican Economic Review, Vol. L, No. 2 (May 1960), pp. 419-432.
-, The Short-Term Domestic Economic Effects of Reducing Import Barriers,
Compendium of Papers on United States Foreign Trade Policy, House Sub-
committee on Foreign Trade Policy, Washington, D.C., 1958.
Schaller, Howard G., Social Security Transfer Payments and Differences in
State Per Capita Incomes, 1929, 1939, and 1949, Review of Economics t~ Sta-
tistics, February, 1955, pp. 83-89.
PERIODICALS
Barron's Financial Weekly. The Journal of Commerce.
Congressional Record. New York Times.
The Economist (London). Survey of Current Business.
Fortune Magazine. The Wall Street Journal.
0