PAGENO="0001"
90th Congress ~ JOINT COMMITTEE PRINT
1st Session
ISSUES ~ U.S. FOREIGN
TRADE POLICY
A COMPENDUM OF STATEMENTS
SUBMITTED TO THE
SUBCOMMITTEE ON FOREIGN ECONOMIC POLICY
OF THE
JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE
CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES
~pNr~f i~EPOSiTORY
PROP~Ri~Y Q~ ~T~5~S TUE STATE UUWERSITY
COLLEGE G~ SOUTH JERSEY LIBRARY.
CAMDEN, N. J.
246
SEPTEMBER 1967
Printed for the use of the Joint Economic Committee
U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE
WASHINGTON : 1967
For snie by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office
Washington, D.C., 20402 - Price 65 cents
~i~r `j~
PAGENO="0002"
SENATE
JOHN SPARKMAN, Alabama
J. W. FULBRIGHT, Arkansas
HERMAN E. TALMADGE, Georgia
STUART SYMINGTON, Missouri
ABRAHAM RIBICOFF, Connecticut
JACOB K. JAVITS, New York
JACK MILLER, Iowa
LEN B. JORDAN, Idaho
CHARLES H. PERCY, Illinois
HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES
RICHARD BOLLING, Missouri
HALE BOGGS, Louisiana
HENRY S. REUSS, Wisconsin
MARTHA W. GRIFFITHS, Michigan
WILLIAM S. MOORHEAD, Pennsylvania
THOMAS B. CURTIS, Missouri
WILLIAM B. WIDNALL, New Jersey
DONALD RUMSFELD, Illinois
W. B. BROCK 3D, Tennessee
WILLIAM H. MOORE JOHN B. HENDERSON
DONALD A. WEBSTER (Minority)
GEORGE R. IDEN
SUBCOMMITTEE ON FOREIGN ECONOMIC POLICY
HALE BOGGS, Louisiana, Chairman
HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES SENATE
HENRY S. REUSS, Wisconsin JOHN SPARKMAN, Alabama
WILLIAM S. MOORHEAD, Pennsylvania J. W. FULBItIGHT, Arkansas
WILLIAM B. WIDNALL, New Jersey HERMAN E. TALMADGE, Georgia
DONALD RUMSFELD, Illinois STUART SYMINGTON, Missouri
W. E. BROCK 3D, Tennessee ABRAHAM RIBICOFF, Connecticut
JACOB K. JAVITS, New York
JACK MILLER, Iowa
JOHN B. HENDERSON, Economi8t
JOINT ECONOMIC OOMMITTEi~
[Created pursuant to sec. 5(a) of Public Law 304, 79th Cong.]
WILLIAM PROXMIRE, Wisconsin, Chairman
WRIGHT PATMAN, Texas, Vice Chairman
JOHN R. STARK, Ewecutive Director
JAMES W. KNowLEs, Director of Research
ECONOMISTS
II
PAGENO="0003"
LETTERS OF TRANSMITTAL
SEPTEMBER 22, 1967.
To THE MEMBERS OF THE JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE: Transmitted
herewith for the use of the members of the Joint Economic Committee
is a compendium of statements prepared for the Subcommitee on For-
eign Economic Policy on "Issues and Objectives of U.S. Foreign Trade
Policy." The 12 statements included in the compendium were pre-
sented by distinguished international economists from the universities,
from professional associations, and from the business world in re-
sponse to a request from Representative Hale Boggs, chairman of the
subcommittee. The contributors were invited to give their assessment
of certain important aspects of U.S. foreign trade policy and to indi-
cate how they thought policy should be directed in the light of the
recently compl~ted Kennedy Round of trade negotiations.
These statements do not necessarily reflect the views of the commit-
tee or any of its members.
WILLIAM PROXMIRE,
Chairman, Joint Economic Commitee.
SEPTEMBER 21, 1967.
Hon. WILLIAM PROXMIRE,
Chairman, Joint Economic Con-tmiittee,
U.S. Congress, Washington, D.C.
DEAR MR. CHAIRMAN: Transmitted herewith is a compendium of
statements on "Issues and Objectives of U.S. Foreign Trade Policy."
The contributors, who are distinguished international economists in
academic life, in research institutes, and in professional and business
circles, were invited to write on subjects which were of particular con-
cern to the subcommittee as it approached its brief initial set of hear-
ings. It was the intention of the subcommittee both to provide itself
with expert opinion and to achieve a wider range of opinion than the
hearings alone would be able to provide. Some of the papers are exten-
sions of or extracts from the current professional work of the authors.
In view of the comparatively short time available for the preparation
of this compendium, the subcommittee did not aim at a complete
survey.
The professional experts who contributed to this compendium have
been most generous in giving their time and energy to meet the sub-
committee's request. The subcommittee, therefore, wishes to express
its gratitude and appreciation to them and to their organizations.
The staff of the Joint Economic Committe undertook responsibility
for coordinating the papers in the compendium in accordance with
III
PAGENO="0004"
IV LETTERS OF TRANSMITTAL
plans developed by the subcommittee. Miss Carol Kern was the edi-
torial assistant in preparing the manuscript for publication.
As is evident from `the diversity of subject matter and viewpoint,
the opinions expressed in these papers are those of the individual con-
tributors. They do not necessarily represent the positions of the Joint
Economic Committee or of individual members or of the committee
staff.
HALE BOGGS,
Chairman, Subcommittee on Foreign Economic Policy.
PAGENO="0005"
PREFACE.
In planning a short set of hearings for July 1967 on the sub~ject of
the future of U.S. foreign trade policy, the Subcommittee on Foreign
Economic Policy took account of severa.l special factors that appeared
likely to affect the usefulness of the hearings.
First, there had been a gap in the public discussion of where the na-
tional interest of the United States lay, in regard to the next steps
in trade policy. Congressional con'imentary during the last 6 months
of the Kennedy Round negotiation had been for the most part re-
served and particular. As the terminal date of the Kennedy Round,
the last day of June 1967, approached, the tension and uncertainty of
the negotiations engaged public attention.
Secondly, the subcommittee was quite aware of the shift in the rela~-
tive importance of different subjects of trade policy, for example, the
growing significance of nontariff barriers; the undefined problem, for
national trade policy, of the development of multinational corpora-
tions; the acute difficulty of beginning negotiations on agricultural
commodities; the possibility that the special situation of the trade of
less developed countries would receive less than due attention, and
many similar issues.
Thirdly, it was not expected that either the subcommittee or any
external observer would be able to supply a prompt and complete
evaluation of the outcome of the negotiations. Yet, in order to give
substance and balance to its deliberations it was necessary to have up~
to-date and expert commentary on the status of U.S. trade policy.
For these reasons, in the main, the subcommittee sketched out some
of the issues and objectives of trade policy and considered some of the
recent expert writing on these subjects. Members of the staff inquired
whether the authors were willing to contribute their most recent work
for the information of the subcommittee or were able to adapt its
scope to meet the subcommittee's intentions.
Happily the authors concerned, and in some cases the organizations
or businesses with which they were associated, gave the most ample
and generous support to these requests, and the subcommittee grate-
fully recognizes their valuable contributions.
The subcommittee accepted in every case the authors' own ap-
proved statement. Apart from earlier editorial reductions of the scope
of the papers, the staff contribution was that of coordination. The sub-
committee therefore stresses that the views presented are those of the
authors and not those of the subcommittee or any of its members.
At the hearing of July 19, 1967, on "The Future of U.S. Foreign
Trade Policy" before the Subcommittee on Foreign Economic Policy,
the papers presented by Mr. William Diebold, Jr., of the Council on
Foreign Relations, Prof. Robert E. Baldwin of the University of
Wisconsin, Dr. John Pincus of the RAND Corp., and Prof. Lawrence
IV. Witt of Michigan State University were the basis of their testi-
mony before the subcommittee.
V
PAGENO="0006"
PAGENO="0007"
CONTENTS
Page
Letters of transmittal III
Preface v
Section I. THE BASIS OF NEGOTIATION
Diebold, William, Jr.: Future Negotiating Issues and Policies in Foreign
Trade 3
Baldwin, Robert: Toward the Seventh Round of GATT Trade Negotia-
tions 21
Junz, Helen B.: The Border Tax Issue Defined 31
Section II. INSTITUTIONAL ASPECTS
Geiger, Theodore, and Lea, Sperry: The Free Trade Area Concept as
Applied to the United States 43
Schwenger, Robert B.: The Restructuring of Foreign Trade Policy 65
Section III. TRADE AND THE ADYUSTMENT PROCESS
Piquet, Howard: Foreign Trade Policy in the Framework of the Balance
of International Payments 99
Polk, Judd: U.S. Exports in Relation to U.S. Production Abroad 109
Lloyd, Lewis E.: The Economics of International Trade 117
Section IV. SPECIFIC ISSUES
Witt, Lawrence, and Sorenson, Vernon: Problems of Agricultural Products
in World Trade 145
Pincus, John: United States Trade With Less Developed Countries_. 189
Lary, Hal B.: Imports of Manufactures From Less Developed Countries 216
Hansen, Kenneth R. East-West Trade: Dilemma or Delusion? 245
VII
PAGENO="0008"
PAGENO="0009"
Section I
THE BASIS OF NEGOTIATION
1
PAGENO="0010"
PAGENO="0011"
FUTURE NEGOTIATING ISSUES AND POLICIES IN
FOREIGN TRADE
BY WILrirAi~I DIEBOLD, Jr.*
The Trade Expansion Act made major innovations in U.S. foreign
trade policy. The Kennedy Round introduced some unprecedented fea-
tures into international negotiations. Neither worked quite as it was
expected `to but both achieved important successes. Neither can be
adopted unchanged as a model for dealing with the next set of prob-
lems we face.
Analyzing what has just been done can help us to decide what new
steps ought to be taken. For `that we need to call on the experience of
those who went `through the negotiations and also statistical work coin-
paring tariff cuts, or the lack of them, to patterns of world `trade. Lack-
ing both these sources, this paper is an outsider's attempt to say some-
thing about the decisions that will confront the United States in the
next 5 to 10 years based on a look at the unfinished business of the
Kennedy Round.
Though I have not had a chance to read the fine print, I think that
what was done and not done in the Kennedy Round can be fairly safely
summarized in a few propositions.
On a wide range of manufactured goods tariffs have been cut to
lower levels than at any* time since the early 1930's, but significant tar-
iff protection remains on a nunTher of important products.
Nontariff barriers, not new in international trade negotiations, have
had their importance highlighted by the Kennedy Round, both for the
future and as a means of making final some of its conditional arrange-
ments.
In agriculture, the Kennedy Round made a number of useful tariff
cuts and made some progress in linking transatlantic grain trade with
world food problems. No dent was made in the barriers put up by the
European Economic Community's common agricultural policy, but the
discussions may have given an impetus to a new kind of international
negotiation about agriculture.
While a number of the things done in the Kennedy Round will be of
benefit to the less-developed countries, they were relatively silent part-
ners; their main trade problems have yet to be dealt with.
East-West trade, too, will be affected only in a modest degree by the
Kennedy Round.
eMr. Diebold is senior research fellow at the Council on Foreign Relations,
Inc., New York. The council is a private nonprofit organization. It takes no stand
on questions of national policy. The views expressed in this statement are the
author's oniy. Most of the points made in this paper will be dealt with more
fully in a book on U.S. foreign economic policy that Mr. Diebold is preparing for
the council.
3
PAGENO="0012"
4 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
If this summary is reasonably accurate, it gives us the outlines and
some of the dimensions of the issues we need to consider in looking at
future U.S. trade policy.
In what follows I have assumed that the United States will continue
to press for the removal of barriers to international trade, whether they
are imposed by itself or by others. The case for such a policy is, in my
opinion, clear-but I do not argue it here. If the assumption were to be
regarded as false, readers could dispense with the pages that follow ex-
cept to the extent that they might be thought helpful as a partial list
of the kinds of barriers to American exports that might well increase
in the absence of an effective effort to lower them and as some indica-
tion of the forms in which American consumers might have to make
the payments exacted from them by restrictions on imports.
This paper emphasizes broad issues and general directions. It says
little about timing, tactics, or the specifics of legislation. It leaves out
a number of questions of trade policy, including the important matter
of adjustment assistance, one of the most notable instances of the
TEA's not working out as expected. Even with these limits the paper
covers so wide a range of issues that it is full of unqualified and per-
haps even dogmatic statements. Part of the excuse for that is that the
aim of the paper is to raise questions; not answer them. It does not
prescribe what U.S. trade policy should be in the years ahead, but tries
to state some of the issues about which decisions will have to be made
in shaping that policy.
THE REMAINING TARIFFS
Much of the impact of the Kennedy Round will be on that large
segment of world trade made up of the exchange of manufactured
goods among industrialized countries. From now on we can think of
the remaining tariffs on this trade as falling into three categories:
(1) those that were reduced by the full 50 percent or some-
thing approaching it, or that are quite low even if the cuts were
smaller;
(2) those that were reduced by little or nothing because deeper
cuts were regarded as economically or politically unacceptable
to major trading countries;
(3) those that a country would have been willing to reduce
but withdrew from the bargaining because other countries were
not willing to make adequate concessions.
There are no hard and fast lines between these categories, but it is
clear that they present rather different kinds of problems for the fu-
ture. There is little to say about the third except that it provides an
area of maneuver in future tariff bargaining. The second includes the
hard cases-whether for a number of countries or just one or two key
ones-which will probably require special efforts and very likely more
than tariff bargaining if they are to be dealt with at all. More will
be said about these later.
As to the first category, two questions suggest themselves: How re-
strictive are these duties? If they could be cut as much as they have
already been cut, should one expect to be able to reduce them still more
in the not too distant future, say when the Kennedy Round reductions
are fully in effect?
PAGENO="0013"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 5
Merely because a duty is below 10 percent it cannot be called unim-
portant or unprotective. A 9-percent aluminum duty that the Euro-
pean Community refused to touch was one of the sore points of the
Kennedy Round. Businessmen and consumers are not indifferent as to
whether a tax is 3 or 8 percent. Valuable recent work distinguishing
"effective" from "nominal" tariff rates has emphasized an old but
often forgotten point that if raw materials and other inputs are tariff
free, the protection offered the manufacturing process may be much
higher than the apparent duty rate on the finished product. Neverthe-
less, when a large number of duties get down to what by the standards
of the last 50 years are fairly low levels, many of them begin to look
rather dispensable. Certainly the idea that they spell the life or death
of great industries looks less plausible than ever. It is no accident,
after all, that in the TEA Congress gave the President the power to
remove duties of less than 5 percent. It would seem modest enough,
then, to suggest that one aim of future trade policy would be for the
United States and other industrialized countries to eliminate "nui-
sance tariffs." The question would be only where the line should be
drawn-at 5 percent or above.
To pursue this aim the power the President now has could be ex-
tended. But broader approaches ought to be considered. After all, the
lesson of the trade policy the United States has followed since 1934
is that tariffs can be very substantially reduced without great damage
to domestic interests and with probable benefit to the national econ-
omy. This conclusion is certainly supported by the European exper-
ience in the Common Market and EFTA. The Kennedy Round has
shown the willingness of a number of governments to take another big
dose of the same tonic. Would it not be realistic to think of one more
step that would eliminate (or at least drastically reduce) most of the
tariffs remaining on trade in manufactured goods among industrial-
ized countries? Of course there would be exceptions, including prob-
ably the hard cases of category 2 above which have to be approached
in a different manner. But much more would be included than the
"nuisance tariffs," those of 5 percent or less. Many of the duties that
will be 10 or 12 percent after the Kennedy Round cuts are fully in
effect were several times as high 15 or 30 years ago. Sometimes the
last quarter of a tariff may seem more valuable to those it protects
than the first three-quarters, but it is hard to dismiss the impression
that if such cuts could be made in 20 or 30 years, the remnants could
be disposed of in another 10. The argument would not be that the re-
maining duties were meaningless or negligible but that in the light of
what has already been done, and on the basis of giving and gaining
that is the core of tariff policy, a general agreement to eliminate over
a period of time a large number of tariffs on trade in manufactured
goods among the industrialized countries would be a desirable and not
unimaginable goal.
Another Kennedy Round with linear cuts would be one way of going
at this possibility (though I doubt that there would be much en-
thusiasm for that idea now). Perhaps a more clear-cut approach
would be to think of a formula under which countries would move
more or less automatically toward the agreed-on goal. While a num-
ber of formulas could be devised-and the possibilities multiplied by
combining them in various ways-the alternatives that follow give a
reasonable idea of the main hues of approach.
PAGENO="0014"
6 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
(1) Duties could be reduced according to a uniform schedule that
would bring all of them to zero in a short time.
(2) Some duties might be reduced faster than others, perhaps be-
cause they were higher to start with, or more slowly because some
countries needed longer to adjust to free trade than others, but all
would be completely removed by a scheduled time (presumably but
not necessarily the same time).
(3) A country's obligation might be to reduce the average of its
tariffs (or the average in each of several categories of tariffs) by a cer-
tain amount each year. This formula would permit each country some
flexibility-going slow on some duties if it went faster on others-
while assuring the same results in the end.
(4) If the elimination of tariffs were unacceptable the same for-
mulas could be used to proceed to a more modest goal.
One possible goal which might be pursued with or without a
formula is tariff "harmonization." This loose term means to some
people that different countries should apply the same tariff rate to the
same products (or depart from the pattern only for special reasons).
The European Community's proposals for dealing with ~crêtrnent and
tariff discrepancies in the Kennedy Round were in a sense versions of
this form of harmonization. Another way of using the word is to de-
scribe a goal in which most tariffs on trade in manufactured goods
among industrial nations-with the inevitable exceptions-would fall
into an agreed-on range-say 8 to 10 percent. As in the third of the
formulas outlined above, flexibility could be introduced by applying
the rule to averages. The economic advantages of harmonizing tariffs
are less obvious than of reducing them, but there is a kind of ele-
mentary equity about the idea which might make tariff reduction more
acceptable than some other kind of arrangement.
Formulas have the advantage of seeming to simplify matters, but
that will not be enough to persuade governments to submit their hard-
est cases to them. The future will, therefore, include some of the same
kind of tariff bargaining as the past. Perhaps, though, the chances of
success can be increased by some new approaches. Eric Wyndham
White, Director-General of GATT, has suggested that in some major
industries "characterized by modern equipment, high technology and
large-scale production, and by the international character of their
operations and markets" negotiations might lead to free trade "within
a defined period." 1 To some degree industry by industry negotiations
were begun in the Kennedy Round, partly it would seem to deal with
some of the "hard cases." The idea of advancing from exceptions lists
to possible free trade is an attractive one. Chemicals and steel are in-
dustries in which a number of leading countries have both protected
and exporting sectors; in aluminum there are only a few big producers
and a very international market. One advantage of this approach is
that other trade barriers could be looked at along with tariffs. Another
is that the relative importance or unimportance of trade barriers
would be made much clearer than is usual when a negotiation is only
about trade barriers and everything else that affects the industry is
regarded as falling outside the discussion. The result, Wyndham
White believes, could be a series of agreements moving toward free
trade industry by industry.
1 Speech to the Deutsche Gesellschaft für Auswhrtige Politik, Oct. 27, 1966.
PAGENO="0015"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 7
The approach prompts questions about the government-business re-
lationships needed for this kind of negotiation. Another set of doubts
may focus on the tacit or explicit understandings that might be en-
couraged between private businessmen in several countries. It is also
important, as Representative Thomas Curtis pointed out in his testi-
mony to this subcommittee on July 12, 1967, to avoid accepting past
shares in the market as a fixed pattern for future trade. Nevertheless,
the idea has enough merit in it to deserve serious exploration and per-
haps some experimentation.
Industry by industry negotiation may not lead to separate industry
agreements. While in some complex industries it may be possible to
balance the advantages and concessions of a number of countries, in
others the discrepancy will be too great or one of the parties will want
to bargain its acceptance of an industry arrangement for another
country's acceptance of a different industry agreement. The experience
is common enough in normal tariff negotiations; it is said to have
taken a Common Market concession on paper to get the Scandinavians
to reduce automobile duties in the Kennedy Round. This is not a fatal
weakness of the industry-by-industry approach but a warning that its
adoption may not go quite as far as its name suggests to divide trade
negotiations into a series of discrete transactions. By the same token
an agreement on nuisance tariffs and another on reduction by formula
might well be linked with one another, and industry agreements to
them.
In analyzing trade problems of the post-Kennedy Round period we
tend to distinguish among them and naturally look for solutions suited
to the problems, not universal solvents. This suggests a certain break-
ing up of the pattern of negotiations and the analysis of nontariff bar-
riers points strongly in the same direction, as we shall see. Perhaps
we should get in the habit of thinking about trade negotiations as a
continuing process proceeding at different paces on different matters,
rather than as a process with periodic clirnacterics such as the main
rounds of tariff negotiations under GATT have been. But it may be
a mistake to think that things can be broken apart in this way, given
the discrepancy between the aims of one country and another and the
natural tendency of bargainers to use all the counters at their com-
mand. It does not follow that an all-in new Kennedy Round is the only
alternative but it seems likely that separate pieces of negotiation will
not be truly independent of one another.
NONTARIFF BARRIERS
Some of the first American businessmen to complain about the re-
suits of the Kennedy Round charged that not enough had been done
to reduce Europe's nontariff barriers on American exports. That is
a healthy emphasis that can lead to more good than the more familiar
complaint of the past that American industry could not survive with-
out tariff protection.
Nontariff barriers are nothing new. Getting rid of quotas was one
of the great aims of American trade policy in the first postwar decade.
As the dollar shortage gave way to general convertibility, quotas were
largely peeled away and tariffs once again resumed their importance.
Now major reductions ill tariffs are making other nontariff barriers
PAGENO="0016"
8 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
more prominent. Maintaining an attack on them should be a major
feature of the next phase of American foreign trade policy. It will
not be a simple matter. The wide variety of nontariff barriers is the
beginning of the difficulties-but only the beginning.
The Kennedy Round has made people familiar with American Sell-
~ng Price and European taxes on automobiles which discriminate
against large cars. Buy American rules in this country and comparable
government procurement practices in Europe are well known to bus-
inessmen. Marking and labelling regulations, laws about trademarks
and patents, packing regulations, rules about health and safety are
all examples of things that can be barriers to trade. Some of these non-
tariff devices, like ASP, work by enhancing the effect of tariffs or
making it difficult and costly for goods to pass through customs. Trade
by government agencies can be conducted so as to bar as well as to pro-
mote transactions, and to protect domestic production or discriminate
between one foreign supplier and another. Any number of taxes and
other kinds of charges may in one way or another impede trade, in-
cluding perhaps some which for generations economists said were
neutral in their impact.
It is not only variety but motive that makes the analysis of nontariff
barriers difficult. Some are used overtly to restrain imports. Others are
used only covertly, under the guise of performing some other function,
once perhaps their real purpose. In still other cases, the impediment
to trade results from the legitimate pursuit of some honest public pur-
pose.2 Gray areas abound and the categories overlap. Where barriers
are overt, the questions are about the will and means to negotiate. in
the second category, more demonstration is necessary though the lie-
gotiating problem is similar. In the third case, however-the barriers
that are incidental to something else-matters are more complicated.
One has first to find the cases, then judge how much damage is really
being done to foreign trade, and where. Then comes a process of find-
ing ways to reduce the damage to trade without seriously interfering
with the pursuit of the legitimate aims of the policy. That being done,
there comes a weighing of the inescapable damage to trade against
what is needed to pursue the purpose for which the regulations were
imposed, a choice in which domestic and foreign interests may well
conflict.
Taxes may be found in any of these categories. Those that are
plainly subterfuges for tariffs will of course not pass muster under
GATT or any other sensible international agreement about trade bar-
riers. But as tariffs fall, many kinds of once-innocent taxes begin to
look suspicious, especially for the discrimination they may hide. In
recent years, long-established principles about the effect of "indirect"
taxes on international trade have been called into question. Economists
are questioning the facts and theories on which the rules about taxes
in GATT and in other agreements are based. Their doubts coincide
to a considerable degree with the businessman's conimonsensical and
untutored reaction that if his goods have to pay a tax on entry into
a country while his competitor's goods are exempted from the same
tax when they are exported, he is at a disadvantage. After years of
work, the six countries of the European Community have decided to
2 ~ notice that officials of the U.S. Government have recently been in Paris discussing the
new automobile safety regulations with their European counterparts who, In turn, have to
enforce national safety and other regulations which are Incompatible with one another
PAGENO="0017"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 9
harmonize at least the systems of their turnover taxes-and an
aligning of the rates will probably follow. In England and the United
States questions are being asked as to whether it would not be helpful
to the international competitive positions of those countries if part
of the corporation income taxes were turned into this kind of trans-
action tax which would be forgiven on exports and levied on imports.
The border tax issue may well be the most important of the nontariff
barriers to be fought over in the next few years. (And if it is not, it
will be important to be sure why.) The issues are not simple; in some
countries domestic considerations will outweigh foreign trade aspects.
And if certain taxes are altered to improve the Nation's foreign trade
position, what questions may not eventually be raised about the rest
of the tax burden?
The pursuit of nontariff barriers leads far and into many corners.
It does not stop with government action. Private business practices
can be serious trade barriers. Of course what governments do or do
not do to regulate businessmen is part of the problem. The laws vary
greatly from country to country and enforcement is another question
again; it may be legal to treat the foreigner as you may not treat your
compatriot. Several postwar efforts to get international agreement on
the regulation of restrictive private business practices have come to
nothing. The process continues in a low key and no very important
breakthroughs have been heralded, but if we are to look more inten-
sively at nontariff barriers these old subjects will have to rise in im~
portance on the international agenda.
As my examples may have suggested, the long-run problems of
nontariff barriers concern not only their range and variety but the un-
certainty of what is a barrier a.nd who is hurt by it. In the short run,
though, while these questions are being studied, governmental action
can focus on discernible barriers. Here the question is: How to deal
with them?
Sometimes existing rules apply. That is the case with quotas on
manufactured goods applied by industrialized countries in balance-
of-payments difficulties. To the extent that such controls are not re-
moved when the difficulties are over, the remedy is to press harder.
Agriculture is something else again, to be discussed later, while the
heavy incidence of controls on coal and oil suggests that the emergence
of energy policy as a focus of governmental attention in Europe,
North America and Japan may put yet another set of trade barriers
in a special category.
The commonly heard statement that the remaining quotas on trade
in manufactured products are of minor importance needs three quali-
fications. First, it does not apply to cotton textiles. Second, many
European countries still apply quotas to a wide range of imports from
low wage countries. Third, the rather good formal record of North
American and European countries conceals a reliance on commitments
by Japan (and to a degree other countries) to limit export.s of certain
products. It is hard to believe that a general attack on nontariff bar-
riers-which are apparently quite important in limiting imports into
Japan-could carry much conviction if it did not take account of
voluntary export quotas like these.
When the question is not one of enforcement but of making new
rules, the heterogeneity of nontariff barriers poses problems. Some
could be flatly banned but for most it would be a matter of making
PAGENO="0018"
10 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
rules about their use and abuse. General rules covering a range of
practices could be devised or codes of behavior drawn up. But would
not a code that was general enough to apply to all nontariff barrlers
be so general as to be meaningless? We shall, then, probably end up
with a number of different agreements of rather different sorts. An
agreement to prevent the misuse of antidumping procedures has come
out of the Kennedy Round. There has been talk of a code covering
government purchasing. Europeans believe it would help matters if
the United States accepted the Brussels customs nomenclature and
the practices common in other countries.
Something more is probably needed, some kind of consultation pro-
cedure. This would help to reveal which things are important and to
whom. It would explore the possibility of adjustments that would
make it unnecessary to go through the elaborate process of devising
and negotiating an international code capable of regulating very dif-
ferent national situations. While bilateral adjustments may prove ex-
pedient, the most sensible approach to the most prevalent barriers
would be to provide a place in one of the multilateral agencies to
which countries could go with their complaints at the same time that
they raised the issue with the offender. Out of the accumulation of case
material might come a more objective study and appraisal than would
otherwise be possible and some guidance as to relevant and enforce-
able rules. An agreement setting up this kind of procedure might also
incorporate some broad principles about nontariff barriers, but.
whether much would be gained by this step is hard to judge until we
find whether major trading nations are ready to go beyond the broad-
est statements of principle.
The heterogeneity of nontariff barriers makes for separate treat-
ment. This will undoubtedly sometimes be the best way, as in the case
of the antidumping code. But the separation of issues may make it
impossible to agree on some of them. Countries are not equally inter-
ested in the removal of each type of barrier. For example, if negotia-
tions had been over road taxes alone, what could the United States
have offered the Europeans to persuade them to end their discrimina-
tory practices? Formally or not, therefore, it may be necessary to link
specific nontariff barriers of quite disparate types. For the same rea-
son, it seems unlikely that arrangements on nontariff barriers can be
totally separated from tariff bargaining.
How we negotiate about nontariff barriers is related to where we do
it. GATT and OECD both have claims. There seems no reason to
choose one as the exclusive arena. Purely pragmatically one might pur-
sue an issue in one place at one time, in another at another time, and
sometimes in both. So far as logic goes, nontariff barriers related to
tariffs are certainly best discussed in GATT; some of those linked to
invisible transactions and primarily of interest to industralized coun-
tries might well be brought into the discussions of the OECD's code
of liberalization. In between are a large number of issues that might
reasonably be looked at in either place as opportunity offers.
The examples of nontariff barriers already cited show how far afield
from traditional trade negotiations we are likely to move in the next
decade. All kinds of. issues usually thought of as "domestic" may be-
come the subject matter of international negotiations-either because
the United States asks it of others or they do of us. This may not
PAGENO="0019"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 11
happen quickly but in the long run it seems inevitable. This will in
many ways be awkward. But little will be gained by trying to shy away
from it. Indeed, if the United States wants to take a new initiative in
international trade, as it has several times in the last generation, this
might be the best to pick. In our present state of knowledge it is im-
possible to say whose trade is hardest hit by the sum total of non-
tariff barriers, but there is at least an even chance that the United
States has more to gain in this field than others and there can be no
doubt that the world economy would benefit from the same degree of
progress in removing nontariff barriers in the next 30 years as has been
achieved in reducing tariffs and removing quotas in the last 30-thanks
largely to American initiatives.
If we are to do this, though, another problem arises, different from
the others and also difficult: How can the United States most effec-
tively negotiate about nontariff barriers? The formula delegating
powers to the President that has been used successfully in the Trade
Agreements Act for over 30 years does not fit. It is not easy to see
a clearly analogous definition of the power and its limits considering
the variety of the issues and the extent to which domestic legislation
is involved in them. But can there be effective negotiations if each
agreement depends on positive congressional action?
AGRICULTURE
The new issues in trade policy discussed so far arise largely because
of the progress made in the last 20 years in lowering tariffs and elimi-
nating quotas on manufactured goods. The same cannot be said of
trade in farm products; there the same old problems persist and trade
barriers have probably been increased more than removed. For a long
time many people have felt hopeless about the possibility of liberaliz-
ing agricultural trade. The Kemiedy Round has not brought a funda-
mental change but it has pointed to some possibilities.
Although the negotiators failed to work out a long-run agreement
assuring outsiders of continuing access to the European Community's
market for products covered by the common agricultural policy, they
were on the right track. No doubt it was reasonable of the United
States to turn down as insufficient the Community's offer limiting the
degree of self-sufficiency that it would strive for in grains. However,
the fact that this was the kind of issue discussed is a hopeful one,
for it has become increasingly clear that, over a large segment of
agricultural trade, negotiations can have a major effect only if basic
policies are discussed. Negotiations confined to trade barriers will
almost surely run into the same blocks as in the past. It is from domes-
tic policies that the trade barriers are to a great degree derived. We are
not used to discussing internationally such traditionally domestic mat-
ters as farm production goals, prices, land use, and surpluses. That
course is difficult for any democratic country and it may be that the
United States or others may not in the end be willing to go through
with it. But `there is a strong case for trying since the alternative seems
to be to perpetuate an impasse of the sort we have known in the last
20 years.
This hard choice does not confront us for every farm product. There
are quite a few on which conventional tariff reductions (or sometimes
PAGENO="0020"
12 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
quota enlargements) are meaningful and satisfactory. We ought to
try to keep as many products in that category as possible.
The grains agreement that has come out of the Kennedy Round
demonstrates one more dimension of future agricultural trade negotia-
tions among industrialized nations: they will be directly affected by
the world food situation. Probably that will more often than not make
agreement easier (because it will tend to increase demand and raise
prices), but it will also extend the range of issues from trade barriers
and domestic policies to aid, export subsidies and prices and the status
of commercial shipments to poor countries.
LESS DEVELOPED COUNTRIES
Instead of trying to deal comprehensively with what is now coming
to be called North-South trade, I shall make only a few general re-
marks, trying to give a perspective.
"Trade not aid" has always had a healthy sound to Americans.
More trade would certainly be good for the less developed countries;
they earn far more foreign exchange from exports than they get in
aid. But there are probably not many underdeveloped countries for
which the alternatives aremutually exclusive. In most places adequate
development will probaby require both aid and increased opportuni-
ties to trade; often, the basic question will be what proportions should
be maintained between these two things. And that in turn will depend
to an important degree on how much the United States and other
industrialized countries will do to open their domestic markets fur-
ther to competing goods.
There is no doubt that many less developed countries ~could gain
substantially if barriers to their sales of agricultural products and
minerals were reduced. The protection the Uinted States and Western
European countries give their domestic producers often hits the less
developed countries. What is more the tariff structures of the industrial
countries discourage the growth of processing industries in the less.
developed countries. This results from having duties which are reJa~-
tively low on raw materials and mount as the degree of processing
increases. Canada has complained of this aspect of the American
tariff for years and for the less developed countries the effect can be
serious. The processing of local raw materials is apt to be one of the
sounder bases for industrialization, so the elimination of barriers that
discourage it would seem to have an added attraction, in addition to
improving the export position of the less developed countries.
it is unfortunate, in my opinion, that so much of the recent discus-
sion about exports of manufactured goods from the less developed
countries has been about giving them tariff preferences so that they
would be subject to lower duties than products coming from rich
countries. The real issue is freer access to the markets of the developed
countries. Whether preferences would be a good way of getting that
access, or enhancing it, is a subsequent question. I fear that working
on plans for future preferences has kept governments in less developed
countries from pressing Europe and North America as hard as they
might to remove present barriers. To a degree the ar~uinents over
preferences have served as `an excuse for some industrialized countries
to sit tight with their existing limited preferences while the pressure
grows on the United States to do something to compensate Latin
PAGENO="0021"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 13
America for being left out of the British and European preferential
arrangements. There is certainly a case for lowering barriers to im-
ports from Latin America, but what good would it do the United
States to do that at the expense of Asian or African countries? One
of the hard problems of the near future will be to decide how far the
United States should go in acting alone if it cannot work out satis-
factory arrangements with the Common Market, Britain and perhaps
Japan about preferences.
If, for whatever reasons, the United States goes along with the idea
of granting preferences t.o the manufactured goods of the less de-
veloped countries, it should try to insure that they satisfy three
criteria.
They should not discriminate among LDC's; they should be limited
in time (by reducing the general rate, not raising the preferential
one); and they should not be allowed to hold up the removal of duties
on imports from advanced countries. There is a good case for giving
the full Kennedy Round concessions to the LDC's right away, but it is
doubtful how much they could benefit from such a step.
The real question is access, not whether access comes in a preferen-
tial form. Unless the governments of developed countries are willing
to confront that fact and accept the idea of taking more competing im-
ports, it will do little good to talk about preferences. Some who advo-
cate preferences do so because they fear that Europe and North
America will not alter their agricultural protectionism and therefore
should give the LDC's at least something that they want. If that advice
is followed-more for diplomatic than economic reasons, it would
seem-the question will be how generous an offer will be made and
how many exceptions the United States or other advanced countries
will insist on making. How much economic advantage will the LDC's
get from a preferential system in which the goods they can most suc-
cessfully export in quantity are limited by quotas?
Unfortunately, there are good grounds for fearing that any system
of enlarged preferences likely to be put forward in the next few years
will be limited in scope, ringed around with qualifications, and riddled
with exceptions. The rather attractive idea of avoiding rigid rules and
permitting each industrialized country to be somewhat restrictive
where its own domestic sensitivities are greatest is only too likely, in
my opinion, not only to fail to encourage generosity on other products
but to lead to the less developed countries' being given what they can
least use and being denied freer access to markets in which they could
really make progress. How much diplomatic or political advantage
will the United States, or the other developed countries, get from such
a development?
Inevitably the Long-term C~tton Textile Arrangement comes to
mind. It is a document that looks two ways, professing to provide an
orderly expansion of markets for the exports of less developed coun-
tries while permitting importing countries to make or keep arrange-
ments that in themselves are restrictive. The results may be ambigious:
because of shifts in trade among the 64 categories established in the
agreement it is hard to judge the full meaning of figures showing size-
able increases in imports. Who has benefitted, at whose expense and in
what degree is hard to tell. Rut this kind of reality cannot be left out. of
account when general declarations are made about the importance of
helping the less developed countries expand their exports.
PAGENO="0022"
14 ISSUES AN]) OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
While cotton textiles are by far the most important manufactured
goods exported by the less developed countries, there are others and, if
development is to proceed, the list will have to grow. In spite of the
rich man's label that has been put on the Kennedy Round, it includes
a large number of tariff concessions from which less developed coun-
tries can benefit, provided they produce and export these products
cheaply enough and market them effectively. If they can take advan-
tage of this access that has been given them, and even more if the
access can be improved by future trade barrier reductions, they can
make important gains. By accepting increased import competition
from the less developed countries, in agriculture, mining, processing,
and manufacturing, the rich countries open new possibilities for the
effective use of aid and investment as levers of development.
EAST-WEST TRADE
As 1 see it, there are four main questions to be considered.
First, should we relax export controls on sales to the Eastern
countries? These are matters which are to a considerable degree with-
in the discretion of the President but it is understandable that he
should want an indication of congressional support for expanding
trade before using what was originally restrictive legislation in this
way. So far as practical effects go, there appear to be relatively few
c'ises in which the American restrictions present maj or difficulties foi
the U S S R or Eac~t European countries, except peihaps in the
short run for certain str'~tegic items or advanced technologies An
other question that then arises is how Fir we should go in gr'tnting
credit
The second question is whether the President should be given power
to grant most-favored-nation treatment to the Communist countries
if he feels he has carried on satisfactory negotiations with them. Here
the considerations are quite different in dealing with the U.S.S.R.
and with the smaller East European countries. For the latter, it is a
question whether we can improve their freedom of choice in the world
by giving them etsier access to this maiket For the formei, it is
primarily a question of whether we would like to add trade to the list
of issues on which Moscow and Washington can effectively negotiate
as part of their continuing dialog. The potential economic gains to
the United States from such steps are, in my opinion, quite secondary
to these broader considerations. It seems foolish to impose rigidities
on ourselves without gaining any obvious economic and political
advantages.
The third question is what to ask for in return for most-favored-
nation treatment. Under systems of state trading, a reciprocal promise
of eoual tre'ttment h'is little value The refoirns being intro3ucec1 in
most of the Communist countries may make that pledge somewhat
rnoie meaningful in the future and we should ceit~irnlv insist on hay
ing it just in case that turns out to be true. A range of things affecting
trade c'tn suit'ibly be incorpor'ited in agieeTnents with the Communist
countries to reciprocate for the American grant of most-favored-
nation. No one of them is guaranteed to work. Few have the simplicity
of rules about tariffs and quotas that we are used to. We must, there-
fore, h'ive an expeumental appio~ch in what ~ e do Th~tt is one re'ison
PAGENO="0023"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 15
that it will be wise to make agreements that are subject to review or
renegotiation after a few years.
The fourth decision concerns bringing the Communist countries
into GATT. Here we face the same kind of problem we do in bilateral
relations. GATT rules have little to say about the conduct of state
trading countries and, consequently, offer less assurance to other sig-
natories of the agreement. Special arrangements, such as those that
have been worked out with Poland, have a certain value, though again
they set up trading arrangements that are not wholly satisfactory.
There is value, though, in bringing the Communist countries into
GATT on some basis as a way of providing for the discussion of com-
mon problems. The thing to understand is that their membership does
not solve these problems but only opens up opportunities to work
effectively on them and to experiment as long as both sides are willing.
Safeguards against risk of serious loss should not be too hard to
devise.
SOME OTHER DIMENSIONS
In this sketch of some of the main elements on the agenda of U.S.
foreign trade. policy in the post-Kennedy-Round period I have made
the tacit assumption that the way to remove trade barriers in the
future is the way it has been done in the past, by bargaining with other
countries. We remove our barriers, they remove theirs. We are, after
all, not talking about something the United States can do all by it-
self, nor have we very good means of persuading other countries to
remove barriers except by offering them something. It is true that
this view runs full in the face of much economic logic which shows
that since it is the American economy that suffers from putting im-
pediments in the way of its imports, unilateral action to remove them
would be a good turn to ourselves. Nevertheless, the advantage of
bargaining as a way of dealing with the rest of the world (which is
not likely to respond simply to high-minded example) is to me com-
pelling.
A word of caution is in order about how we think of reciprocity.
The balancing of statistics showing how much trade is affected by
what each country has done has never been entirely satisfactory. The
real national interest lies in the consequences of trade barrier reduc-
tion, not in its anterior circumstances. As an increasing number of
domestic activities are drawn into the trade negotiations in the man-
ner described above, it will become increasingly meaningless to try
to find a common measure for judging the exact value of what each
country has done. A broader view of what constitutes satisfactory
performance seems needed. That conclusion is suggested, too, by the
widespread acceptance of the idea that it is impossible to ask less
developed countries for reciprocal reduction of trade barriers. It does
not follow that nothing should be asked of them, since their ability to
take advantage of trade concessions made to them will depend to an
important degree on their own policies. This broadening of the ap-
proach to trade may also lead us to conclude that sometimes unilateral
action may be the best course even if, under the old vocabulary, the
United States seemed to be giving something away.
Great as the postwar expansion of international trade has been, the
increase in American direct investment abroad has been greater. An
PAGENO="0024"
16 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
important part of the total is made up of investment in manufacturing
industry in Canada, Britain, Western Europe, and, to a degree, Japan,
our major trade partners. How should we think about the very sub-
stantial sales by American-owned manufacturing companies abroad
which in 1965 were double our exports of manufactured goods? Are
they additions to our exports, displacements of them, or a partial re-
placement of them, or a partial replacement of exports that would
have been wholly lost to foreign suppliers if there had not been
American-owned companies abroad? Subsidiaries, either by their own
purchases from the United States or by the stimuli that they give to
American sales abroad through their dealings with foreign buyers,
influence American exports. How do the amounts compare to the
drain on the U~S. balance of payments represented by the movement
of capital abroad? Clearly, the scope of what we have to think about
when we speak of "the foreign trade of the United States" has
broadened even beyond the range suggested by the discussion of non-
tariff barriers.
The growth of overseas investment is stimulating interest in the
development of truly multinational corporations. For them interna-
tional trade is an intracorporate transaction. What do tariffs and
other trade barriers mean to them? Are changes in these barriers
likely to have important effects on the corporation's behavior? We
know very little of these matters, but it seems to me certain that the
more they are examined, the greater the increase in the number of
issues that will have to be taken into account when we talk about trade
policy. The same is almost certain to be true of the investigation into
the way technological change and innovation affect international
trade. The consequence will be a further widening of the range of
government policies that will have to be thought of as affecting for-
eign trade.
Quite a different kind of alteration of established attitudes toward
traditional trade barriers results from the growth of economic re-
gionalism as an important factor in world trade. The common external
tariff of the European Community is not just an economic instru-
ment; it is also part of the institutional cement that holds the group
together. How long this will be true is hard to say, but it is in the
American interest, and I believe in the interest of true integrationin
Europe too, to press the view that other ties than commercial discrimi-
nation must become strong enough to justify the great effort that has
been made to change the historical face of that continent. Meanwhile,
though, there is not only a political but a functional difference be-
tween the common tariff and national tariffs. What is behind the com-
mon tariff is not a single economic and political entity so the process
of decidino what the Community's tariff should be is complicated both
procedurally and substantively by national differences.
As regionalism grows in the rest of the world, the question is more
frequently asked whether the United States should not be finding
partners with whom to form ~orne kind of common market or other
preferential t.radin~ area. Politically there are all sorts of difficulties
about this approach, most of them going back to the simple fact that
while such a grouping removes barriers to trade among the members
it sharpens the distinction between members and nonmembers. Whom
would the United States like to exclude? Economically, too, it is hard
PAGENO="0025"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 17
to put together a grouping that promises the United States substan-
tially greater advantages than might be obtained from a global reduc-
tion of trade barriers on a nondiscriminatory basis
A possible exception to th~ generally negative conclusion to which
these two arguments point is the idea of some closer association be-
tween the United States and Canada. The two economies are already
extraordinarily intertwined and a surprising amount of their trade is
free of barriers.~ The idea of completely eliminating tariffs between
them is an old one on which Canadians have blown hot and cold and
in the end always rejected. Now there are again stirrings on this sub-
ject north of the border but what will come of them is not clear. Since
both the greatest gains and the greatest disturbances of any major
step toward trade integration between the two countries would be
Canadian, I suggest that the proper posture for Americans is to wait
and see and be prepared to talk about ways and means and goals if the
Canadians should make up their minds that closer trade integration
with the United States is something they want.
The growth of regionalism and foreign preferential groupings has
made some Americans wonder if the United States should abandon the
principle of equal treatment which has been a basic element of our
trade policy. Exceptions, waivers, and violations of the most-favored-
nation clause have been cited to strengthen the case. Perhaps the great-
est stimulus of all to such thinking was the fear that the Kennedy
Round would be spoiled by the refusal of one major partner. to agree
to terms acceptable to all the others. Although that hazard has been
passed, it remains true that the most-favored-nation principle can
sometimes slow progress in liberalization to the speed acceptable to a
single major trading nation. Nevertheless, in spite of all these con-
siderations it would be unwise to deprecate or depreciate the principle
of equal treatment, much less to jettison it. What substitute is there for
it in the rational ordering of world trade? Economists can show that
some mixture of discriminatory arrangements can maximize welfare
in certain circumstances, but can they turn their analysis into effective
policies? Discrimination may benefit any given number of countries at
one time or another, but to give nations freedom to discriminate is un-
likely to produce the greatest benefit for all. Since a guiding principle
is necessary to shape a world trading system it is hard to see what rule
can apply generally except that of equality.
Even massive departures from a rule need not destroy it if they have
an orderly basis. One proof of GATT's worth was its flexibility in
permitting European discrimination against American goods when
dollars were short and pressing them to restore equality when their
currencies became convertible. The less-developed countries are now
being permitted many departures from the rules that are being applied
to other countries, and with good reason, but it is equally sensible to
work out a way for them to come back to normal standards as their
situations improve. One of the aims of liberalizing East-West trade is
to bring at least some of these countries into an easier relation with
others in the world trading system. Replacing the bilateralism now
prevalent in East-West exchanges with some kind of miltilateralism
would benefit Eastern and Western countries alike. As an organizing
principle for world trade equal treatment remains of fundamental im-
portance. In its practical effects it is an important-if imperfect-
safeguard against discrimination directed against the United States.
PAGENO="0026"
18 ISSUES ~&~D OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
Unless this country is clear about equal treatment and vigorous in
furthering it, the erosion of recent years is likely to grow, to the detri-
ment of the United States and the decrease in the chances for making
the world trading system more rational.;
Breaking down problems as I have done in the foregoing sketch
may suggest that the United States should have not one trade policy
but at least three-for industrial countries, less-developed countries,
and Communist countries-or perhaps even four if we count agricul-
ture separately. In a sense this is correct but it is also misleading. The
policies, differ because they cope with different problems and exploit
different ranges of possibility. The aims they serve, while not identical,
must, in a high degree, overlap. Serving the interests of one country,
these separate policies cannot make sense if they conflict with one
another persistently or to an important degree-though some incon-
sistency is natural in a pluralistic society. The separation that is need-
ed to pursue some ends effectively has to be accompanied by a common
view of the whole, as to both ends and means.
Another factor that might make for fragmentation is the parceling
out of trade tasks among a number of international agencies, notably
GATT, OECD, UNCTAD, and, in a more limited way, ECE and
the agencies for hemispheric cooperation in which U.S. relations with
Latin American common markets and free trade areas are discussed.
All this is in addition to direct negotiations with other governments
and the European Economic Community, and in such bilateral bodies
as the joint meetings of Cabinet members we have with Canada and
Japan. No doubt there is some confusion, some overlap, some duplica-
tion; to an outsider it does not yet seem to have reached an alarming
level, but that is the sort of thing on which the testimony of those
closer to the events is more valuable. There is certainly a potential
problem for the future. It is complicated by the fact that the criterion
cannot be just neatness and order; we must ask, too, where action
will be most effective and how American policy can best be furthered.
The answer may differ at different times and vary according to issues
What is more it may not always be apparent and there m'~y be need
for probing or experimentation that will entail duplication and some
waste
Unfortunately, the ramification of trade policy described earlier in
this paper is going to make the choice, of forums more difficult, just
as it will make the process of negotiation more complicated. The draw-
ing into trade negotiations of many matters not formerly thought of
as being part of trade policy is bound to have that effect. To the extent
that any given issue can be separately pursued, one forum or an-
other-including some not generally thought of as the loci of trade
negotiations-may appear suitable, but such partial solutions will still
leave the problem of the interrelatedness of all issues for bargaining
purposes' which has been mentioned several times `above. It is prob-
ably not wise to try to lay down a rigid formula to~cover all cases,
but unless one has some principles in mind and some rough guidelines
for practice there is a risk, not only of confusion, but of a failure' of
policy. This is true because the long-run aims of American trade
policy must include the building and maintenance of a world trading
economy and that goal i~ affected not only by the `competence `of or-
ganizations but by the rules that surround them.
PAGENO="0027"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 19
The three organizations most involved-GATT, the OECD, and
TJNCTAD-have sufficiently distinctive characteristics to suggest a
rough division of labor, though the difficult problems may lie in the
refinements. TJNCTAD, the newest of the three, is an invaluable prod
forcing the United States and other developed countries to give more
attention to the problems of the less-developed countries than they
would otherwise. For this reason we should welcome TJNCTAD and
help to make its examination of problems penetrating as well as
vigorous. It does not follow that the action which governments take
in response to UNCTAD discussions need always be taken in
UNCTAD. No doubt there will be some matters on which special
UNCTAD-sponsored agreements will be in order, but UNCTAD's
essential function is to insure that the needs of development are never
absent from the consideration of trade policies. It can do that no mat-
ter what form an agreement finally takes, or even if key countries
take national action without formal agreement. In dealing with trade
barriers it seems likely that some of UNCTAD's most important re-
suits might manifest themselves in the removal of quotas and the re-
duction of duties through GATT procedures, since it is not wise to
treat the trade of the less-developed countries as if it were separate
from the body of world trade as a whole.
The OECD, the middle-aged member of this trio, has already
been the scene of a number of trade discussions and has under its
aegis a code of liberalization of invisible transactions that has a
certain relation to some kinds of nontariff barriers. On the face of it,
OECD is preeminently suited to deal with questions that are of
primary interest to the industrialized countries; but it is not always
crystal clear which those questions are, especially as the economies of
the most developed of the less-developed countries become more
complex. It can, of course, be made possible for a few nonmember
countries with special interest to take part in OECD deliberations.
Another function frequently recommended for OECD is as an "ante-
chamber to GATT" (or UNCTAD), a place where the industrialized
countries try to achieve some degree of harmonization among their own
policies before engaging in negotiations with others. Up to a point
this, too, seems plausible, but there are two caveats. First, the indus-
trialized countries have not shown themselves very proficient at
coordinating their trade policies, whether on preferences for less-
developed countries or East-West trade-but that is not the organiza-
tion's fault. Second, if they were to be successful in finding common
fronts, delicate questions would arise about how far they could wisely
go in reaching understandings before negotiating with outsiders. If,
for example, a cotton textile agreement had been drafted in OECD
and then submitted to nonmembers it is unlikely that some of the
exporting countries would have accepted terms that they finally
agreed to in the arrangement negotiated under the sponsorship of
GATT. Of courses the agreement might not have been the same.
GATT, once thought of as a temporary agreement and technically
not an organization at all, not only has shown great survival value
but has something both UNCTAD and OECD lack, a comprehensive
body of rules about international trade. And that is crucial-far more
important than organizational strengths or weaknesses. No doubt the
rules have weaknesses, and changes will be needed to deal with some
of the trade problems of the next decade. No doubt procedures and
PAGENO="0028"
20 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
organizational arrangements can be improved. But one need only con-
sider the achievement of the Kennedy Round to realize not oniy the
importance of GATT but the extraordinary labor (and risks of
failure) that would be involved in trying to build a new code of
trade policy on a different foundation. The separation of issues will
no doubt sometimes make it sensible to deal with certain kinds of
problems outside GATT, though the need to match concessions on
otherwise unrelated matters in order to strike bargains may tend to
pull issues toward GATT. It would probably not be wise to try to
find a place for every trade issue in a revised G-ATT structure, but
a good general guide might be the ntiaxim suggested by my colleague,
Helena Stalson: Do it in GATT unless it can clearly be done better
somewhere else. And in making that judgment the prime consideration
4s not just whether* it is easier to get agreement in one place rather
than another, but what the effect of the agreement is likely to be on
the structure of world trade. In facing the issues outlined in this
paper, the United `States will fiuid that its interest in coherence and
order' in: the system of world trade, will usually be best served `by
strengthening the position of GATT and the principle of equal
treatment it `embodies.
PAGENO="0029"
TOWARD THE SEVENTH ROUND OF GATT TRADE
NEGOTIATIONS
BY PROFESSOR ROBERT E. BALDWIN*
It is well to begin a discussion of future trade legislation by recall-
ingthat the official name of the recently concluded Kennedy Round is
the sixth round of GATT trade negotiations. In other words, unique
though these negotiations have been in several respects, they represent
but one of a series of trade liberalization efforts that originated 20
years ago. Indeed one must go back a third of a century to the Trade
Agreements Act of 1934 in order to put the Kennedy Round in proper
perspective. At that time, as a result of the Tariff Acts of 1921 and
1922 and then the Smoot-Hawley Act of 1930, tariffs were at their
highest levels in the Nation's history. However, since the first Trade
Agreements Act, the United States has become the leader in a signifi-
cant worldwide reduction in duty levels. Although simple averages
are notoriously poor indicators of the restrictive effects of tariffs, a
rough notion of the extent of these liberalization efforts can be ob-
tained by pointing out that the average (weighted by trade volume)
duty level in 1934 was 48 percent whereas it will be around 8 percent
after the Kennedy Round reductions.
The purpose of this paper is to review briefly the history of the
negotiations that have brought about this liberalization and then to
focus upon certain problems these negotiations have failed to solve
adequately. It will be argued that further significant progress in re-
ducing protectionist levels is dependent upon a more successful
handling of these problems.
AN OUTLINE OF PREVIOUS NEGOTIATIONS
The Period 1934-1945. The period between 1934 and 1967 can be
divided conveniently into three subperiods as far as the history of
U.S. commercial policy is concerned. The first extends from 1934 to
1945; the second from 1946 to 1961; and the third from 1962 to the
present. In 1934 the President was given the power to undertake trade
negotiations with other countries for the purpose of securing recipro-
cal tariff reductions that, on our part, could go as far as cutting then
existing duties in half. Prior to the original Trade Agreements Act,
efforts to secure reciprocal tariff reductions had not met with much
success. The executive branch had sought to conclude formal treaties
with various countries on several occasions but only three ever were
ratified by both parties-the last being with Cuba in 1902. Obtaining
the necessary two-thirds majority vote of the U.S. Senate in most
cases proved to be an impossible task, since it was necessary to specify
* University of Wisconsin
21
PAGENO="0030"
22 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
the particular items proposed for duty reduction in each case. This
difficulty was avoided under the 1934 legislation by giving the Presi-
dent considerable power to undertake reciprocal reductions covering a
broad range of items. Since 1930 the Congress has not passed a tariff
act, but instead granted the President the authority on successive oc-
casions to continue to reduce (and to raise) the general level of duties.
The trade agreements concluded between 1934 and 1945 were bi-
lateral in nature. Thirty-one agreements were negotiated between these
years. The technique employed was that the two parties concentrated
upon reducing duties on those items for which each tended to be the
principal supplier for the other. The mutual tariff reductions agreed
upon were then generalized to all traders with both parties. This ap-
proach had both advantages and disadvantages. The main drawback
was that, by extending the duty cuts to all countries, nonparticipants
were able to increase their exports to the two countries without also
opening up their economies to greater imports. In view of the exist-
ence of widespread unemployment in most countries during this period
coupled with the notion of reciprocal concessions contained in the leg-
islation, efforts to avoid this "free ride" aspect of bilateral negotia-
tions were made by confining the cuts between two countries to a small
number of items in which each was the other's main supplier. Items
for which there was no single overwhelming supplier or countries who
were not major suppliers of any item tended to be neglected. Even be-
tween two countries, where the principal-supplier trade was highly
unbalanced, it was impossible to reduce one party's tariffs the same
percentage as the other's and still achieve an acceptable balance of con-
cessions for each. On the other hand, the bilateral technique with its
concentration upon principal supplier items permitted a movement to-
ward freer trade without requiring the consent of all major trading
nations. Clearly during the thirties it would have been impossible to
proceed on any other than the step-by-step basis actually adopted.
The Period 1945-1961. At the end of World War II there was a
widespread desire to deal on a cooperative, multilateral basis with eco-
nomic problems that had important international repercussions. Con-
sequently, the opportunity arose for undertaking tariff negotiations
not on a country-by-country basis over time but on a multilateral basis
at a given time. The arrangement in which this opportunity. was seized
and made workable was the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade.
In 1947, 22 nations completed a multilateral tariff cutting exercise that
resulted in concessions on nearly two-thirds of total world trade. The
United States negotiated under the additional 50 percent cutting
power that Ccmgress had granted the President in 1945.
Besides establishing an organization through which periodic multi-
lateral tariff negotiations designed to reduce duty levels could be un-
dertaken, the GATT set forth a code of commercial policy. The most-
favored~-nations principle is the cornerstone of the GATT. The first
article of the Agreement specifies in detail that each nation shall grant
nondiscriminatory treatment to the products of all other contracting
nations with regard to import and export duties and subsidiary
charges, rules, and formalities in connection with importation and
exportation, and internal taxes and other internal regulations. A sec-
ond basic principle is the general prohibition of quantitative restric-
tions as a protective device. Except under special circumstances, only
customs duties can be used for this purpose.
PAGENO="0031"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 23
The United States participated in two additional rounds of tariff
negotiations within the GATT framework under the 50 percent cut-
ting authority granted in 1945. One was held at Annecy, France, in
1949 at which 10 more countries became contracting parties to the
General Agreement and another at Torquay, England, in 1950-51. In
1955 the Congress again gave the President additional tariff cutting
authority but considerably less than it gave in 1934 and 1945. The new
authority permitted him to reduce duties by an additional 15 percent
over a 3-year period. With these powers the United States participated
in the fourth round of GATT negotiations in 1956. This session at
Geneva dealt with the accession of Japan to the GATT.
The negotiating session prior to the recent Kennedy round was
the so-called Dillon round (named after the then Secretary of the
Treasury) in 1960-61. This was the first negotiation held after the
formation of the European Economic Community. The objective of
the United States was to obtain a reduction in the common external
tariff of the EEC in order to offset at least partially the trade diver-
sion caused by reducing duties within the EEC toward zero. Conse-
quently, in 1958 Congress gave the President the authority to reduce
duties by another 20 percent.
The five rounds of negotiations under the GATT between 1947 and
1960-61 represent an outstandingly successful example of productive
international cooperation. Not only were tariffs among the industrial
nations reduced significantly but the highly restrictive structure of
quantitative controls erected for balance-of-payments purposes at the
end of the war were gradually dismantled.
The Period 1962-1967. After the disappointing Dillon round,
however, a view began to develop to the effect that the traditional
technique of bargaining was inadequate for achieving further signifi-
cant liberalization of world trade. The technique employed within the
GATT was item-by-item bargaining in an essentially bilateral series
of simultaneous negotiations. It was argued that this negotiating
method tended to limit both the scope and depth of tariff reductions.
Domestic pressures within each country were, it was claimed, more
successful in excluding many items on the basis of particular reasons
than would be the case if an across-the-board tariff-cutting approach
were used. In addition, it was noted that, when one country exclnded
important items in a particular industry, other participants tended to
exclude for bargaining purposes their important import items in the
same industry. The outcome tended to be a negotiation confined to
items in which no severe import competition problem existed in any
country and therefore in which no one was particularly interested.
Participants also adopted the restrictive bargaining attitude of giv-
ing up as little as possible in return for as much as possible.
Given these apparent drawbacks of the item-by-item approach
coupled with the growing diversionary effects of the EEC on outside
trade as internal duties were decreased, the Kennedy administration
sought the power to undertake a sweeping negotiation, especially
with the EEC, that would bring about a significant cut in duty levels
among the industrial nations. The outcome of these efforts was the
Trade Expansion Act of 1962 followed by the Kennedy, or sixth,
round of GATT negotiations. The essential authority granted under
the Trade Expansion Act was the power to reduce duties by 50 percent
over a 5-year period. A unique feature was the authority to cut duties
PAGENO="0032"
24 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
to zero on items for which the EEC and the United States accounted
for at least 80 percent of world trade. The act also contained language
permitting the President to negotiate on nontariff barriers.
The history of the 4 years of negotiations in the Kennedy Round is
too well known to require more than a few sentences. In terms of what
the United States hoped to accomplish, the results cannot be regarded
as other than disappointing. The average cut is more like one-third
than one-half. Since Britain was not admitted to the Common Market
the 80-percent provision pertaining to United States-EEC trade be-
came irrelevant. No significant progress was made in beginning to
dismantle the complex set of controls that protect important sectors
of agriculture in most industrial countries. The nontari if-barrier field
also received little attention. However, despite the length of the negoti-
ations and the wide gap between expectations and accomplishment,
the Kennedy Round will be regarded in the future as a considerable.
success. For, compared with previous GATT tariff-cutting exercises,
this round stands out as the one involving the deepest average tariff
reduction.
PROBLEMS FOR FUTURE NEGOTIATIONS
The last two rounds of GATT negotiations have, however, made it
increasingly clear that certain key problems must be dealt with more
adequately if further liberalization efforts are to be successful. In
a real sense, these problems have arisen because of the very success
of previous liberalization efforts. These efforts have eliminated the
protection that was largely superfluous and increasingly cut into
those areas where significant resource reallocation effects are pro-
duced by the reductions. We must deal with the hard core of pro-
tection from now on, if further expansion of world trade is to be
encouraged. In doing so, several difficult problems must be met. Three
of the more important ones are as follows: (1) Achieving a better
balance between consumer and producer interests in economically
vulnerable industries; (2) Mitigating the restrictive effects of non-
tariff barriers; (3) Making the negotiating process more effective
in achieving its goal of trade liberalization.
(1) Achieving a better balance between consumer and producer in-
terests in econornicall~j vulnerable industries
This is the key domestic problem in any tariff-cutting exercise.
Yet it is one that has not been adequately handled since the first
Trade Agreements Act of 1-34. The issue can be simply stated. Since
thetime of Adam Smith, economists have been able to show that-set-
ting aside infant-industry and term-of-trade effects-it is possible
ror a country to raise its real income level under free trade com-
pared to a system of tariff protection. However, although the gain
to consumers in the form of lower prices is more than enough to
compensate the producers of protected products from any loss they
suffer, in practice such compensation is not made. In industries where
workers and employers can readily find alternative employment the
adverse effects of tariff cuts are minor. But in industries where em-
ployment and profits are alre~dy declining bec'tuse of increased im
ports or competition from some other domestic or foreign industries;
where the workers are older, less skilled, and less educated than most
workers; and where the areas in which the industries are located are
PAGENO="0033"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF TJ.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 25
depressed generally, then the costs of greater import competition can
be high for a small group. It is true that even under these condi-
tions there is usually a net gain in the sense that the gainers from
lower prices could conceivably compensate those losing their em-
ployment. However, in the actual situation where compensation is
not made, it is understandable for members of both the legislative
and executive branches of the Government to give greater wei~'ht to
the large loss suffered by a few people than the more than offsetting
gain distributed very thinly over many people. Obviously the typical
legislator knows that he is likely to lose votes on balance if he sacri-
fices the losses of the few for the greater, but thinly spread, gain to
the many. But, instead of this representing a regrettable fact of
politics-as some seem to suggest-I suspect it reflects the actual value
judgments of the people in general. In other words, the general public
does regard a larger gain spread over many people as inferior to
a smaller total loss that falls on a relatively few. However, they would
prefer even more a situation where those who were severely hurt eco-
nomically were given the resources needed for their successful ad-
justment and where there still remained a consumer gain.
In the past this problem has been handled mainly by refraining
from cutting duties on those industries that might suffer a severe loss
or by refraining from cutting to the level where such losses would be
incurred. President Roosevelt and Secretary of State Cordell Hull
pledged themselves not to cut in industries where substantial injury
would be caused. In postwar trade legislation the notions of the peril
point, that is, the duty level below which substantial injury would be
caused, and of the escape clause, that is, a modification of a previously
granted tariff concession due to injury-causing increased imports,
were introduced to handle the problem. Finally, in the 1962 act pro-
visions for adjustment assistance in the form of extended unemploy-
ment payments, retraining and relocation allowances, low-interest-
rate loans, technical advisory services, and so forth, were introduced
in order to meet the problems connected with a SO-percent, across-the-
board cut.
This trade adjustment assistance portion of the Trade Expansion
Act represents a major innovation in dealing with the balance problem
between consumer and producer interests. However, the provision is
phrased in such narrow terms that in practice it seems unlikely to be
an important source of adjustment assistance. The assistance provided
is also on a meager scale. What is needed to deal with the tariff-cutting
problem as well as-even more importantly-with the broad problem
of adjusting to technological progress within the domestic economy
is a general adjustment assistance act. Otherwise, we shall soon arrive
at that level of tariffs where substantial potential overall gains remain
but where, because of the hardships imposed upon some in obtaining
these gains, they are not tapped.
(2) Mitigating the restrictive effects of nontariff barriers
Besides having to deal with the hard core of tariff protection, we are
increasingly becoming aware of the restrictive nature of nontariff
obstacles to trade. Nontariff barriers that were superfluous in their
restrictive impact when `duty levels were high have become effective
deterrents to increase trade as these duties have declined. An added
reason why these barriers are likely to become more significant is the
82-246-67----3
PAGENO="0034"
26 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
probably tendency for countries to introduce new nontariff devices
and to enforce old ones more vigorously in order to offset the internal
adjustment burdens of tariff restrictions under the Kennedy Round.
An elaboration of the many nontariff barriers that are important in
world trade today would require a lengthy paper in itself. The typical
classification divides them into the following groups: (1) Quantitative
controls and State trading; (2) government procurement policy; (3)
customs valuation and practices; (4) antidumping legislation and
practices; (5) border tax adjustments. Actually this list covers only
a portion of the laws, rules, practices (public and private) distorting
trade in a manner that discriminates between domestic and foreign
producers. All of the above measures distort trade in a direct and
obvious manner. But businessmen have become increasingly concerned
with trade distortions brought about indirectly by laws, practices,
taxes, and subsidies aimed at domestic activities. These include: (6)
Domestic subsidies, for example, maritime and other transportation
subsidies, agricultural subsidies, research and development subsidies,
and special tax benefits; (7) domestic taxes and regulations; and (8)
monopolistic practices in private product and factor markets.
Although it is easy to recognize the trade-restricting effects of non-
tariff barriers, it is a much harder task to suggest how best to reduce
these effects on a worldwide basis. The Kennedy Round has not pro-
duced much progress along these lines. The tariff-reducing aspects of
the negotiations were so difficult and time consuming that it was not
possible to launch a major effort to reduce nontariff barriers. However,
enough was learned to realize that these are much more difficult to
deal with than duties. A major reason for this is because import pro-
tection or export promotion is not the main purpose of many of these
trade-distorting measures. For example, in parts of agriculture, the
coal industry, and the textiles field, nontariff barriers are often only
an incidental part of a set of measures designed to ease the adjust-
ment of sectors that are depressed for reasons quite unreleated to im-
port competition. In other cases, the trade distortions are byproducts
of measures designed to meet goals that may conflict with economic
efficiency in a narrowly defined sense. The various nontariff measures
designed to promote national defense fit this category. Similarly, poli-
cies whose objectives are to redistribute income, for example, mini-
mum wage legislation, or to increase national prestige, for example,
the space program, fall into this grouping.
Clearly, one cannot expect nations to abandon these goals simply
for a more rational distribution of world resources devoted to foreign
trade. There may be opportunities to modify some of these goals over
a long-run period of time, but short-run policy usually must take them
as "given." The best that can be done under these circumstances is to
try to eliminate needless conflicts among policy measures. For exam-
ple, the approach followed by most countries in meeting the agricul-
tural problem needlessly sacrifices the benefits of economic efficiency.
Temporary income-support payments coupled with measures to
attract excess resources out of agriculture are much preferable on
efficiency grounds and yet also can prevent undue distributive hard-
ships. The same points apply in such industries as coal and textiles.
Maintenance of adequate defense capacity in certain industries also
PAGENO="0035"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 27
can often be achieved in a manner that does not sacrifice the gains from
international trade.
The changes required to obtain these trade benefits are primarily
modifications in domestic policies. Easing trade restrictions will only
be a byproduct of these domestic changes. This means, of course, that
negotiations with the purpose of modifying simultaneously both in-
ternal and external policies are necessary. As the Kennedy Round dis~
cussions of the world agricultural problem have indicated, successful
negotiations of this type are, however, most difficult to achieve. Thus,
we face a formidable task in any further efforts to expand signifi-
cantly the benefits of trade. Some of the most serious distortions in
world trade are the indirect consequence of domestic policies, yet these
are the kinds of measures that are the most difficult to modify. Only
if there is a general desire among the major trading nations at the
highest political level to modify these policies will such negotiations
succeed. Furthermore, it may be that the main push of any efforts to
change these domestic measures must be directed initially more at
harmonization than at significant liberalization. Suggestions to stand-
ardize and harmonize various trade restricting measures on a sector
approach have met with some success in the present negotiations and
may be a useful approach for future negotiations. Then, as harmoniza-
tion is achieved, it may be easier to reduce the trade-restrictive impact
of domestic policies.
(3) Making the negotiating process more effective
(a) The level of economic analysis supporting the negotiators.
Despite some important progress made in the Kennedy Round, the
level of economic analysis involved in trade negotiations must be re-
garded as inadequate. Billions of dollars of sales and thousands of
jobs are affected by any extensive tariff cutting operations yet our
negotiators have only the roughest of ideas as to the effects of these
cuts on import levels, employment, profits, and so forth.
On paper the steps outlined in the Trade Expansion Act for secur-
ing this information look impressive. The President is directed to
furnish the Tariff Commission with a list of items that may be con-
sidered for duty reduction and the Commission must within 6 months
"advise the President with respect to each article of its judgment as
to the probable economic effects of modifications of duties or other
import restrictions on industries producing like or directly competi-
tive articles." In preparing its advice the Commission is directed to
take into account numerous economic factors affecting each article.
Furthermore, the Tariff Commission must hold public hearings as part
of the process of arriving at its advice. The President also seeks in-
formation and advice directly from the various departments of the
Government and even holds public hearings of his own on items that
might be affected by duty cuts.
For the Tariff Commission to hold public hearings and prepare a
detailed, sophisticated analysis in 6 months of the probable economic
effects of duty reductions on each of some 4,000 items, in addition to
carrying out its other duties, is an impossible assignment. The same
holds true with respect to the advice from most other departments.
Neither the Tariff Commission nor the various departments possesses
a staff that is adequate in size for the job outlined in the Trade Expan-
sion Act. But the problem is more than one of size. Except for a few
PAGENO="0036"
28 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
dedicated people in the Tariff Commission and the various other
departments, the personnel is simply not trained to undertake the kind
of economic analysis needed for the job. The people involved are
highly competent in carrying out their regular work, but they gen-
erally are not well-suited for carrying out the economic analysis out-
lined in the act.
The public hearings held both by the Tariff Commission and under
the President's direction also are not very useful in ascertaining the
economic consequences of tariff reductions. Very few of the presenta-
tions give the kind of economic facts needed to obtain more than a
casual impression of what a duty reduction will do.
The result is that the vital decisions concerning the impact of duty
cuts on domestic producers as well as what we might gain in terms of
greater exports are only imperfectly understood. The final decision
as to the list of offers seems to be reached by a complicated haggling
process in which economic and political pressures are the dominant
determining factors. Obviously these are highly relevant factors for
reaching final decisions. But when they operate in an environment of
comparative economic ignorance as to the relationships on which these
economic and political pressures supposedly are based then the out-
come cannot be other than highly imperfect.
Fortunately, in the Kennedy Round a small group of exceptionally
hard-working and dedicated individuals from various parts of the
Government has helped pull together information from a variety of
sources and provide reasonably satisfactory economic backstopping
operations for the U.S. negotiators. But much more is needed. If we
are to obtain the benefits from expanding trade yet avoid unreason-
ably severe adjustment burdens to particular sectors, we must greatly
improve our economic-support efforts.
One way this can be done is for Congress to provide a small amount
of funds annually for the purpose of undertaking economic studies
designed to determine the ability of workers and employers in various
industries to adjust to increased import competition. In addition, stu-
dies should be made as to our export potential in various fields. These
studies could be undertaken by economists both within and, in partic-
ular, outside of the Government. The essential point, however, is that
they be done by individuals who can combine a sound analytical back-
ground with modern techniques of statistical and economic analysis.
They can provide the answer as to what would be required in terms
of adjustment assistance in order to obtain the benefits of trade with-
out undue hardships to particular groups.
The Kennedy Round also offers a unique opportunity to obtain by
direct observation data concerning the economic effects of U.S. tariff
cuts on U.S. industry as well as of foreign tariff cuts on U.S. exports.
But, to take advantage of this opportunity and obtain the greatest
possible knowledge from this experience, a carefully formulated eco-
nomic study must be developed and put into operation sOon. Too often
we simply predict what will happen without ever improving our sub-
sequent predictions by checking out carefully what actually did occur.
Here is a unique opportunity for such a check.
(b) The reciprocity problem.-As John Evans has pointed out so
well in his book for the Council on Foreign Relations, "U.S. Trade
Policy-New Legislation for the Next Round," Harper & Row, 1967,
PAGENO="0037"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF 15.5. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 29
the notion of reciprocity as interpreted in the actual negotiations has
hampered the move toward trade liberalization. In these negotiations
each party tends to regard any tariff cut by himself as bad and any
cut by other parties as good. Consequently, unless each party is con-
vinced that its exports will increase as much as its imports, it pulls
back some of its offers to achieve this objective. This in turn sets off
a chain of further withdrawals producing the end result that the
country with the smallest offer tends to set the standard cut. The prin-
cipal supplier technique helps to avoid this in part but the general
tendency is clear.
Countries with initially low average duties are put in an especially
difficult position. They may be prepared to cut completely to zero,
but they know that higher duty countries will consider reciprocity to
be achieved before they themselves reach a zero level. Thus, the for-
mer countries could be left with zero duties of their own and no bar-
gaining power to use in order to obtain further tariff reductions from
other countries.
It probably must be taken as a given constraint of any tariff-cutting
exercise that the cuts should not result in any significant increase in a
country's balance-of-trade deficit. Moreover, given the unwillingness
to use other policies for bala.nce-of -payments adjustment purposes, this
means that the direct and indirect effects of the multilateral tariff cuts
by themselves must not cause a significant export-import imbalance.
However, this general constraint still leaves considerable latitude to
the negotiators. Moreover, studies made thus far seem to indicate that
as far as the United States is concerned rather significant changes in
U.S. versus foreign offers produce only a small net effect on the U.S.
balance of trade. The feedback effects are very strong. Yet negotiators
easily become caught up in the give-and-take spirit of bargaining
sessions and tend to forget the larger purpose of the whole exercise.
The result is that some of the benefits to all countries from trade-
expansion tend to be sacrificed.
(c) Ta~ff -cutting techniques. The interesting aspect of this problem
is that the negotiators are not under any legislative directive to adopt
this narrow view of reciprocity but have tended to establish it them-
selves. This perhaps means that the nature of the negotiations should
be changed. Indeed this was one of the initial objectives of the Ken-
nedy Round. Instead of item-by-item bargaining, an across-the-board
cutting procedure was to be followed. Implicit in this was the notion
that approximately equal percentage cuts (weighted by trade vol-
umes) would achieve reciprocity. We have learned in the Kennedy
Round, however, that such a simple technique cannot stand up to the
economic and political realities of any negotation.
In the future we should try to follow simple tariff-cutting tech-
niques that minimize the negativeness of item-by-item bargaiiiing, but
we must also be highly flexible with regard to alternative techniques.
The objective is to reduce duties without causing undue hardships
domestically. With a vigorous adjustment assistance program coupled
with the notion of achieving a general balance of concessions, we can
best implement this goal by using a variety of techniques. This might
involve some general percentage formula for most items, sector-by-
sector negotiations in certain areas, and item-by-item in others. This
is the. procedure eventually followed in the Kennedy Round. FTacl it
PAGENO="0038"
30 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
been followed from the beginning, the negotiations might long ago
have been completed. In short, we need a balance between simple tariff-
cutting procedures and direct negotiations in sensitive areas. In the
Kennedy Round we initially were too rigid on a particular simple tariff-
cutting formula; namely, the linear-cut concept. A greater willingness
to consider sympathetically other types of cutting formulas might
have accelerated the negotiations and deepened the average cut. Yet,
all items cannot be covered by simple rules. Negotiations on particular
sectors still will be needed. However, if one starts out by trying to
negotiate all cuts on an item-by-item basis, this, too, will lessen the
average tariff reduction.
CONCLUSIONS
A number of highly competent observers interpret our recent tarifF-
cutting experience as requiring radical changes in our approach to
worldwide trade liberalization. Some of them suggest the formation
of free trade blocs between the United States and various other indus-
trial nations. Others propose the abandonment of the most-favored-
nations principle in our tariff-cutting policies. While these various
proposals have points in their favor, the merits of proceeding along
the same general lines as in the last six GATT negotiations to me
seem greater, especially if the goal is the economic one of lowering
artificial impediments to world trade.
There is still much to be done in reducing the trade-inhibiting effects
of nontariff barriers. This will be a very difficult task but there is
some evidence to suggest that at least the major industrial countries
are willing to proceed toward a harmonization and reduction of some
of these barriers. With an effective adjustment assistance program
together with an adequate `background of economic analysis, a less
rigid view of the reciprocity concept, and a more flexible negotiating
approach there is also still much that can be accomplished in the
tariff field. We will be hampered by the unwillingness of some coun-
tries t.o reduce their barriers as far as we are prepared to do. But
what can be accomplished by a flexible approach to tariff cutting
seems significantly preferable to the longrun economic and political
risk involved in regionalization and tariff discrimination. Thus, it is
not too early to begin to plan for a seventh round of GATT negotia-
tions aimed primarily at the nontariff barrier problem and at expand-
ing trade between developed and less-developed countries, but also
designed to achieve further moderate cuts in duties among industrial
countries.
PAGENO="0039"
TI-IE BORDER TAX ISSUE DEFINED
BY HELEN B. JUNZ*
With the disappearance in the postwar period of a large number of
quantitative restrictions on international trade and the progressive
dismantling of tariff barriers, nonquantitative and nontariff barriers
to international trade have become relatively more important. Major
among these barriers are differences in the relative ease and cost with
which imported goods enter countries and a main element in these
differences is the tax treatment accorded to goods crossing interna-
tional borders.
Under present international rules, countries are permitted to levy
charges on imports and allow rebates on exports up to the amount of
indirect taxes levied on like products consumed or produced domes-
tically.1 The question at issue is whether or not this system of so-
called border tax adjustments for differences in national systems of
indirect taxation has a trade-diverting effect. This paper attempts to
set out the rationale behind the current practice of border tax adjust-
ments and to assess it against the body of discussion that has arisen
since its inception. The conclusion is that the current system of
border tax adjustments, under less-than-perfect market conditions,
which is characteristic of the world we live in, tends to give a com-
petitive advantage to countries which employ them vis-a-vis those
that do not.
THE BORDER TAX SYSTEM
Under the rules laid down in the original GATT and in the 1955
revision, border tax adjustments may be made only for indirect taxes,
such as excise, turnover, and value-added taxes. Thus, countries hav-
ing such taxes normally will levy an import charge-or import
equalization tax-designed to impose the same amount of indirect tax
on the imported product as is embodied in the price of the like home-
produced product. Conversely, exporters receive a rebate-or tax
exemption-equal to the amount of indirect tax embodied in the price
of an exported good. The intent of the adjustment system is to free
world market prices completely from indirect taxation so that prices of
imported goods reflect only indirect taxes levied in the country of
consumption.
* Economist, Europe and British Commonwealth Section, Division of Interna-
tional Finance, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. This paper
reflects the personal opinion of the author and must not be interpreted as
representing the opinion of the Board of Governors.
1 See appendix I (this paper) for the relevant provisions as laid down In the General
Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) and the treaty establishing the European Eco-
nomic Community.
31
PAGENO="0040"
32 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
Direct taxes, on the other hand, are specifically excluded from the
border tax system and any border adjustment for such taxes would
be viewed as an export subsidy or an import charge contravening
GATT.2 The logic behind this different treatment of the various taxes
lies in the premise that taxes borne by the factors of production should
reside in the country of origin and that taxes borne by the ultimate
consumer should reside in the country of destination. Therefore, the
entire border adjustment system is based upon the assumption that
direct taxes are always fully shifted backward to the factors of pro-
duction and that indirect taxes are always fully shifted forward into
the final price of a good.
EXAMINATION OF EcoNoMIC LOGIC OF BORDER TAX SYSTEM
Under the above assumption of tax shifting, imported goods, with-
out tax equalization charges, would be at a price advantage vis-a-vis
home-produced goods to the extent that the exporting country had a
lesser rate of indirect taxation. Conversely, without tax rebates a coun-
try with a relatively high rate of indirect taxation would be at a com-
petitive disadvantage in world markets relative to countries with a
lower rate of indirect taxation.
Second, without border adjustments goods moving in international
trade would be taxed doubly: once in the country of origin and once in
the country of destination, both tax levies being paid by the consumer
in the country of destination. Thus, the foreign consumer would make
a contribution to the exchequer of the country of origin. Furthermore,
world market prices would be raised by the amount of the tax and t.he
volume of trade would be likely to shrink.
Thus, if the assumption of full reflection in final prices of indirect
taxes and zero reflection in prices of direct taxes holds true, the current
system of border tax adjustments indeed serves to neutralize the trade
effects of different national tax systems. However, the current system
is open to two basic and related questions:
1. Is the current practice of classifying certain taxes as "direct"
and others as "indirect" a correct reflection of actual conditions?
and
2. Given such classification, are shifting assumptions correct?
DIs2'INc~oN BETWEEN DIRECT AND INDIRECT TAXES
Indirect taxes are generally defined as taxes on consumption, while
direct taxes are defined as those levied on income. However the distinc-
tion on the basis of these definitions has become more and more cloudy
over time. The only area where there seems to be clear agreement is
with regard to personal income taxes, which are classified as "direct"
2 The distinction between "direct" and "indirect" taxes is, in fact, not made explicit In
the GATT regulations, but flows from interpretation of and amendments to the relevant
provisions.
PAGENO="0041"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 33
and retail sales taxes, which are classified as "indirect" taxes; beyond
this the classification becomes a morass.3
Thus, it could be argued that the distinction made in international
practice between direct and indirect taxes may essentially be arbitrary
and seems to be based more on prevailing practice than on theoretical
reasoning. For example, it is not at all clear whether employer con-
tributions to social security fall into the indirect or the direct tax
category, although GATT practice specifically places them with direct
taxes. `Conversely, value added taxes, according to GATT classification,
are considered to be indirect taxes. However, value added taxes fall
on both costs and profits of the producer (value added being defined
as the difference between the value of a firm's purchases and sales) and
to the extent that they fall on profits are not always clearly distin-
guishable from a profits tax in their effect. Nevertheless, corporate
profits taxes are classified as "direct" and value added taxes as "indi-
rect" taxes.
Tml Qtn~sTIoN OF TAX SHIFTING
Given the murkiness of the borderline between "direct" and "indi-
rect" taxes, it is not surprising that the premise of full forward shift-
ing into price of direct and full backward shifting to the factors of
production of indirect taxes has given rise to even greater uncertainties.
The shifting argument is based upon Marshallian price theory which
holds that, under pure competition, profits taxes will not affect prices
because prices are determined by marginal producers and marginal
producers have no net profits. Modern theory of shifting and incidence
of taxation has moved a long way from so clear cut a statement. For
example, statistical studies can be found which support either the full
backward shifting or the full forward shifting theory for some direct
taxes.4 Basically most experts today would argue that shifting of
either type of tax can an~ does occur in both directions and that the
degree of shifting will vary with different circumstances, such as
variations in demand and supply elasticities, in degree of market con-
trol and in government policies. The current border tax adjustment
system, however, is solely predicated upon a general full shifting
assumption and, therefore, cannot be conditional upon the structure of
market forces or upon certain government actions, such as a permissive
monetary or fiscal policy.
Richard A. Musgrave and P. B. Richman, "The Allocation Aspects of Direct vs. Indirect
Taxation," Brookings conference on the role of direct and Indirect taxes In the Federal
revenue system.
Full forward shifting Into price of corporate profit taxes Is suggested by Marlan
Krzyzaniak and R. A. Musgrave, "The Incidence of the Corporation Income Tax," Johns
Hopkins Press, 1963; full backward shifting by Challis Hall, "The Incidence of the Cor-
poration Income Tax," American Economic Review, May 1963.
PAGENO="0042"
34 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
TABLE l.-Balance of trade effects of general taxes assuming fixed exchange rates
and unchanged real demand for domestic output 1
Balance of trade effect
.
With border adjustment
Without border adjustment
1.
Raise indirect taxes:
II.
a. Product prices rise.
b. Factor prices falL -
Raise social welfare
NEUTRAL
Favorable
~
Unfavorable.
Neutral.
III.
charges:
a. Product prices rise
b. Factor prices falL -
Raise corporate profits
taxes:
Neutral
Favorable
~
Unfavorable.
NEUTRAL.
a. Product prices rise
b. Profits fall
~
Neutral
Favorable
Unfavorable.
NEUTRAL.
Balance of trade effect
Indirect tax with
All taxes with
No border
IV.
Substitute indirect tax for
border adjustment,
others without
border adjustment
adjustment
~
social welfare charges:
a. Under Ia and IIa
Favorable - - -
Neutral
Neutral.
b. Under Ia and IIb~
NEUTRAL~.
Unfavorable -
Unfavorable.
c. Under lb and IIb~
Favorable- - - -
Neutral
Neutral.
V.
Substitute indirect tax for
corporate profit tax:
a. Under Ta and IIIa
Favora.ble~~
Neutral
Neutral.
b. Under Ta and TIIb.
NEUTRAL
Unfavorable~ -
Unfavorable.
c. Under lb and IIIb
Favorahle - - -
Neutral
Neutral.
I This table is adapted from an unpublished submission by Richard N. Cooper and Richard A. Muegrave
to the Symposium of Experts on Border Tax Adjustments held by the OECD in Paris, September 1964.
Effects in capital letters reflect GATT reasoning.
Insofar as the actual extent of forward, or backward, shifting of
relevant taxes cannot be determined clearly, the extent of tax neutral-
1~y brought about in inteination'tl ti~de by the curient bordei t~ix
adjustment system is also unclear. Table 1 sets out a number of exam-
ples of possible effects on trade balances of various tax changes under
different shifting assumptions. Thus an increase in indirect taxes, with
full border adjustments, would not affect the balance of trade only if
product prices rose to the full extent of the tax (case Ta), which is
the case assumed by the GATT convention; if, on the other hand,
factor prices were to fall, the trade effect would be clearly favorable.
Thus substitution of, for example, an indirect tax, which is not fully
reflected in product prices, but which is rebated in full, for a corporate
profits tax, which was not reflected in prices and which was not rebat-
able, would have a favorable trade effect (case Va); the trade effect
would be doubly favorable if the corporate profits tax was partially
reflected in prices (case Vb).
Since there is a substantial body of theoretical and empirical evi-
dence which tends to contradict the view that certain taxes are always
fully shifted into price, while others are always fully absorbed by the
factors of production, it is most likely that the true state of affairs
PAGENO="0043"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 35
encompasses all and several combinations of the possibilities shown in
table 1. Consequently, in modern economies the instances of trade
neutrality consistent with GATT assumptions constitute only a special
rather than the general case.
PRACTICAL IssuEs
If the current system of border adjustments neutralizes tax effects
on international trade in special cases only, how serious are trade di-
verting effects in the remaining instances?
Trade distorting effects of existing border adjustments probably
have been largely compensated by past changes in relative rates of
exchange, tariffs or price levels. But, under present conditions, ex-
change rate or tariff changes no longer are flexible instruments of
adjustment to changes in competitive position among industrial coun-
tries. Consequently, possible trade distorting effects of new border
adjustments now are of much greater concern than they were in the
past, although even past changes-with the greater adjustment possi-
bilities then available-probably have produced a world trade pattern
rather different from that which would have come about under sys-
tems which truly neutralized the international trade effects of differen-
tial national tax systems.
To remedy the situation one could, first, consider fundamental
changes in the basic system of border adjustments. These might range
from elimination of the entire practice to a broadening of the practice
to include various taxes now considered ineligible for adjustment.
Complete elimination of current practices clearly is not a practical
possibility, partly because adjustments to earlier trade distorting ef-
fects-such as may have occurred in relative rates of exchange for
example-would need to be unwound. But more importantly, in the
absence of border tax adjustments, countries with a high degree of
trade involvement and a close tie to world prices would find forward
shifting of indirect taxes (i.e., full reflection of the tax in export
prices) virtually impossible. Thus their basic tax structure might have
to be modified to the extent that it relied heavily on indirect taxation.
Inclusion of a broader range of taxes, such as the corporate profits
tax and social security charges, would meet with considerable admin-
istrative problems. Even if the degree of shifting, which to complicate
matters may actually vary from product to product and from country
to country as well as over time, could be accurately determined, it
would be virtually impossible to determine the precise amount of tax
embodied in the price of a specific product. This problem is analogous
to that encountered in rebating cumulative turnover-or so-called
cascade-taxes, where "average" rates are being rebated, which leads
to over- or under-rebating in individual instances and to distortions
of the competitive position among individual firms. The elimination
of this problem is one of the advantages cited in favor of the value-
added tax system which is to replace the cascade type systems in Ger-
many, Italy and the Benelux countries by 1970.
In any event, as shown in table 2, extension of border tax adjust-
ments to virtually all types of taxes, except the personal income tax,
would not redress the balance of competitive advantage in favor of
countries, such as the United States, now having no or few border
PAGENO="0044"
36 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
adjustments. This is so because the tax burden, relative to GNP, is
higher in most continental European countries than it is in the United
States or the United Kingdom. In this respect a truly "ideal" system
of border adjustments designed to produce tax neutrality in interna-
tional trade should probably take account of government expenditures
also. For instance, where tax revenues are employed to reduce produc-
tion costs, countries rebating indirect taxes may actually reap a dou-
ble competitive advantage. For example, if an excise tax is levied in
order to fully finance a national transportation system, domestic pro-
ducers would in effect have zero transportation costs on their exports,
since the excise tax would be rebated at the border. If in addition, the
tax is not fully reflected in final prices, a full rebate would give the
exporter a second trade advantage over outside suppliers.
TABLE 2.-Selected countries: General Government revenues and expenditures as
percent of gross domestic product, 1965
United
States
United
Kingdom
France
Ger-
many
Italy
Nether-
lands
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
Indirect taxes
Personal income taxes
Contributions to social
security
Total, 2 plus 3~.
Corporation tax
Empi. contributions to
to social security_ - - - -
Total, 5 plus 6__
Direct taxes, 4 plus 7~_
Other
Total current revenues
9
14
18
14
12
10
9
2
9
3
4
4
7
5
(1)
(1)
10
~
11
12
8
12
(1)
13
5
2
2
2
2
10
3
5
(~)
(`)
7
18
4
16
2
12
20
1
8
20
2
(1)
17
3
11
24
3
27
32
39
36
32
37
Not available.
Source: "National Accounts Statistics, 1956-65," Organization for Economic Cooperation and Develop-
ment, Paris, 1966.
On the whole, it is fairly clear that it is currently not practicable
to construct an "ideal" system of border adjustments. However, this
does not mean that nothing can or should be done to remedy clear exist-
ing and future inequities arising from the current border tax treat-
ment.
Impending or recent changes in taxation with definite favorable
trade effects for the countries which impose them include:
1. Change from a system of cumulative turnover taxes to one
of value added taxes, where tax burdens are now generally not
fully compensated under the cascade system (such a change is
now pending in Germany and the Benelux countries);
2. Change from a system of retail sales taxes or cumulative
turnover taxes including investment goods and fuels (which cur-
rently are not rebatable) to a value added system which excludes
these items and imposes a higher rate on consumption goods.
3
8
PAGENO="0045"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 37
3. A shift from direct taxation or social security charges (which
are not rebatable) to indirect taxation (which is) to the extent
that the former taxes were shifted into final prices or the latter
are not so shifted (such a change was effected in Italy);
4. Upward changes in adjustments for so-called "taxes
occultes" (indirect taxes charged on certain inputs, such as fuel,
at some earlier stage of production) or for cascade type taxes be-
cause of earlier under-rebating (such changes were effected in the
United Kingdom and Germany).
The greatest promise for ironing out inequities arising from trade-
favorable effects of border tax adjustments lies perhaps in treating
them in a manner similar to that now applying to changes in tariffs.
The recent discussions within the Organization for Economic Coopera-
tion and Development, which aimed at a standstill on border taxes
with possible countervailing concessions for changes with definite
trade effects-such as those cited above-point in this direction. Such
a system of countervailing concessions, broadened to not only achieve
a standstill in, but perhaps also a rollback of, border tax adjustments,
would solve the problem of distorting effects on the trade patterns
between two countries with different tax systems. However, beyond
this there still remains the problem of trade effects in third markets,
which may require further accommodation, such as possible selective
waivers of GATT rules currently prohibiting export subsidies.
PAGENO="0046"
38 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
APPENDIX I. GATT AND TREATY OF ROME PROvIsIoNs RELATING TO
TRADE ASPECTS OF NATIONAL TAXATION
1. GATT PROVISIONS ON BORDER TAXES AND EXPORT SUBSIDIES
a. Import equalization charge for "product" (interpreted to read
"indirect") taxes as set forth in article 111:2:
The products of the territory of any contracting party im-
ported into the territory of any other contracting party shall not
be subject, directly or indirectly, to internal taxes or other in-
ternal charges of any kind in excess of those applied, directly or
indirectly, to like domestic products. Moreover, no contracting
party shall otherwise apply internal taxes or other internal
charges to imported or domestic products in a manner contrary to
the principles set forth in paragraph 1.
Article II prohibits import charges above rates agreed upon and
bound in tariff negotiations, but a specific exception is made with re-
spect to indirect taxes: article II :2 (a)
Nothing in this article shall prevent any contracting party from
imposing at any time on the importation of any product:
A charge equivalent to an internal tax imposed consistently with
the provisions of paragraph 2 of article III in respect of the like
domestic products or in respect of an article from which the im-
ported product has been manufactured or produced in whole or
in ~part.
A similar exception is made in article VI which defines and pro-
hibits dumping practices: article VI :1:
Due allowance shall be made in each case for differences in con-
ditions and terms of sale, for differences in taxation, and for other
differences affecting price comparability.
and article VI :4:
No product of the territory of any contracting party imported
into the territory of any other contracting party shall be subject
to antidumping or countervailing duty by reason of the exemp-
tion of such product from duties or taxes borne by the like prod-
uct when destined for consumption in the country or origin or
exportation, or by reason of the refund of such duties or taxes.
b. Export tax rebates and subsidies. The GATT is generally op-
posed to export subsidies as stated in article XVI :2:
The contracting parties recognize that the granting by a con-
tracting party of a subsidy on the export of any product may have
harmful effects for other contracting parties, both importing and
exporting, may cause undue disturbance of their normal commer-
cial interests, and many hinder the achievement of the obj ectives
of this agreement.
But there is no outright prohibition of export subsidies. Their ex-
istence for exports of primary products is explicitly recognized and
condoned in article XVI :3 which, however, deplores the practice and
states that it should not be used to obtain "more than an equitable share
of world trade in that product." For other than primary products
article XVI :4 holds that: .
Further * * * contracting parties shall cease to grant either di-
rectly or indirectly any form of subsidy on the export of any
product other thaii a primary product which subsidy results in
PAGENO="0047"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 39
the sale of such product for export at a price lower than the com-
parable price charged for the like product to buyers in the do-
mestic market.
Rebates of indirect taxes on exports do not constitute subsidies ac-
cording to a note in annex I to article XVI:
The exemption of an exported product from duties or taxes
borne by the like product when destined for domestic consump-
tion, or the remission of such duties or taxes in amounts not in ex-
cess of those which have accrued, shall not be deemed to be a
subsidy.
But remission of direct taxes or social welfare charges was defined
to contravene article XVI :4 at the 17th session of the contracting
parties as was overcompensation for indirect tax burdens:
(d) The exemption, in respect of exported goods, of charges or
taxes, other than charges in connection with importation or in-
direct taxes levied at one or several stages on the same goods if sold
in internal consumption; or the payment, in respect of exported
goods, of amounts exceeding those effectively levied at one or sev-
eral stages on these goods in the form of indirect taxes or of
charges in connection with importation or in both forms.
Under article XVI :1, countries are required to notify each other of
any practice considered as subsidies and to enter into discussions with
countries feeling themselves injured by such practices. Article VI :3
permits countries injured by subsidies involving direct tax credits to
impose countervailing duties.
2. TREATY OF ROME PROVISIONS RELATING TO BORDER TAXES
The rules governing the treatment of export tax rebates and import
equalization charges among Common Market countries appear to be
patterned fairly closely after GATT regulations. But they specify
somewhat more clearly than does the GATT that by "~ * * charges
* * * applied * * to like domestic products" only indirect taxes are
meant. The relevant provisions are laid down in article 95:
A member state shall not impose, directly or indirectly, on the
products of other member states any internal charges of any kind
in excess of those applied directly or indirectly to like domestic
products.
Article 96:
Products exported to the territory of any member state may not
benefit from any drawback of internal charges in excess of those
charges imposed directly or indirectly on them.
Article 9?:
Any member states which levy a turnover tax calculated by a
cumulative multistage system may, in the case of internal charges
imposed by them on imported products or of drawbacks granted
by them on exported products, establish average rates for specific
products or groups of products, provided that such states do not
infringe the principles laid down in Articles 95 and 96.
Where the average rates established by a member state do not
conform with the above-mentioned principles, the Commission
shall issue to the state concerned appropriate directives or
decisions.
PAGENO="0048"
40 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
Article 98:
With regard to charges other than turnover taxes, excise duties
and other forms of indirect taxation, exemptions and drawbacks
in respect of exports to other member states may not be effected
and compensatory charges in respect of imports coming from
member states may not be imposed, save to the extent that the
measures contemplated have been previously approved for a
limited period by the Council acting by means of a qualified
majority vote on a proposal of the Commission.
Source: `Sidney Weintraub, "Border Tax Adjustments and the GATT," The Tax Execu-
tive, July 1965, PP. 317-320; Treaty Establishing the European Economic Community.
PAGENO="0049"
Section II
INSTITUTIONAL ASPECTS
41
82-246---67------4
PAGENO="0050"
PAGENO="0051"
THE FREE TRADE AREA CONCEPT AS APPLIED TO THE
UNITED STATES
BY THEODORE GEIGER and SPERRY LEA *
CONTENTS
Page.
1. The new setting for U.S. foreign trade policy 43
II. Two paths to free trade 47
The multilateral approach 47
The free trade arrangement approach 48
Possible characteristics of a free trade area including the United
States 50
III. The two approaches compared: A preliminary evaluation 53
Some basic considerations 53
Considerations related to the EEC and the United Kingdom.~_.. 54
Considerations regarding the feasibility of the multilateral ap-
proach 56
Tactical considerations 57
IV. Conclusions 57
Annex A: The GATT provisions for free-trade arrangements 61
Annex B: Major questions involved in considering the possible character-
istics of a free trade arrangement involving the United States 63
I. THE NEW SETTING FOR U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
This paper explores in broad outline the relevance of the free-trade-
area concept for the United States. Until recently, such an inquiry
would have been largely of academic interest. However desirable free
trade has been in economic theory, it was generally recognized that,
in practice, it was not an attainable objective for U.S. policy. The
commitment to some significant degree of protection was so strong
among influential sections of American industry and labor and the
extent of dependence on foreign trade of the American economy was
so minor that the national interest considerations favoring free trade
were insufficient to offset these negative factors. In the circumstances,
the goal of U.S. policy was trade liberalization; that is, freer trade, and
not the complete removal of all barriers to the flow of imports and
exports. Indeed, at times during the postwar period, resurgent pro-
tectionism was strong enough to force significant-though temporary
-retreats from even this limited objective.
Moreover, because the national and group interests favoring freer
trade were comparatively weak, this goal of U.S. policy was pursued
as much for political as for economic reasons. In essence, the political
rationale was that the security of the United States rested in part
upon the stability and progress of the international system, many of
* Theodore Geiger is chief of international studies of the National Planning
Association, and Sperry Lea is the American director of research, Canadian-
American Committee of the National Planning Association, Washington, D.C.
The views expressed in this paper are the authors' only.
43
PAGENO="0052"
44 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
whose member countries were substantially dependent for their own
domestic stability and welfare upon the gains from foreign trade.
By promoting the growth of world trade, the general reduction of
barriers fostered the prosperity of many nations and, therefore, great-
er willingness and ability on their part to behave responsibly and co-
peratively in their relations with one another.
In the early 1960's, however, these political considerations were
reinforced by certain economic developments with the result of
strengthening the U.S. commitment to freer trade.
The progress of the European Economic Community (EEC) to-
ward internal freedom of trade and a common external tariff con-
fronted the United States with both a danger and an opportunity.
The danger was that the closer the EEC came to the completion of
its customs union, the larger would be the degree of its discrimination
against U.S. products. The opportunity was that of persuading the
EEC to open its rapidly growing common market more widely to
U.S. exports in return for reciprocal tariff reductions in U.S. import
barriers.
Politically, the early 1960's marked the culmination of the U.S.
effort to realize its "grand design"-the formation of an equal partner-
ship between the United States and a unified Western Europe willing
and able to share the responsibilities of protecting world peace and
fostering world progress. These economic and political possibilities
were dramatically underscored in 1961 by the application for member-
ship in the EEC of the United Kingdom and other European coun-
tries, which brought within sight the achievement of the European
union that was the precondition for Atlantic partnership.
The U.S. response was the Trade Expansion Act of 1962, in which
the Congress granted to the President unprecedented authority to re-
duce virtually all U.S. tariffs by 50 percent in return for reciprocal
across-the-board reductions by other countries and, in the "dominant
supplier" provision, to abolish tariffs on products for which the ex-
ports of the United States and those of an enlarged EEC represented
"80 percent or more of aggregated world export value." This bold
trade liberalizing initiative was supported by American congressional
and public opinion as much to hasten the realization of the "grand
design" for an Atlantic partnership as to counter the possible threat
of increased discrimination by an enlarged EEC.
The subsequent Kennedy Bound of tariff negotiations proved to be
very much longer and more difficult than originally anticipated, and
for most of their 4-year course seemed unlikely to re~sult in substan-
tial reductions in trade barriers. Moreover, early in the negotiations,
President de Gaulle vetoed the British application for membership
in the EEC and the prospect of imminent enlargement of the Common
Market vanished-and, along with it, the usefulness of the U.S.
"dominant supplier" authority. Nevertheless, at the 11th hour, agree-
ment was reached on surprisingly large reductions in tariffs over a
broad range of commodities. While interpretations of the details are
not yet complete and, in any event, the quantitative significance of
tariff reductions varies according to the method used to calculate it,
the Kennedy Round has clearly resulted in the largest advance in trade
liberalization yet made under the GATT. Indeed, with the exception
of certain admittedly important commodities, it is not an exaggera-
PAGENO="0053"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 45
tion to say that, insofar as tariff barriers are concerned, the limited
goal of trade liberalization has now been achieved.
Once again today, as in the early 1960's, the United States is con-
fronted with an opportunity and a challenge. The opportunity is
made possible by the unexpected success of the Kennedy Round. If
freer trade-the objective of U.S. policy for more than three decades-
has been substantially accomplished, then it is no longer of purely
academic interest to investigate the possibilities of free trade-that is,
the abolition of tariffs and other restrictions to trade-as a relevant
and practicable goal of U.S. policy and the methods by which it could
be realized. In other words, owing to the six postwar GATT rounds
of tariff reductions, the remaining duties on a very broad range of
products are now low enough to envisage abolishing tariffs completely
on most or all of these commodities in the next negotiation. True,
there are certain industries, such as textiles, shoes, and other con-
sumer goods, as well as agriculture, which continue to enjoy a high
degree of protection and where the prospects for free trade are still
remote. But, a large enough proportion of internationally significant
commodities are already free of tariffs or within striking distance of
that situation to make free trade a relevant goal of U.S. policy for
the decade or so that lies ahead.
This possibility is strengthened by the challenge of the new period
in world politics that began during the mid-1960's.1 The two preced-
ing postwar decades were an era of major structural changes in the
international system made necessary and possible by the deep disloca-
tions caused by World War II. Chief among these postwar changes
were the great decolonization movement that brought into existence
60-odd new nations, the clear-cut global United States-Soviet con-
frontation of the cold war, and the rise of Communist China. In turn,
World War II and these and other subsequent developments provided
both the incentive and the opportunity for such unprecedented acts
of creative restructuring as the establishment of the United Nations
and many other international political and economic organizations, the
Marshall plan and the process of European unification, NATO and
other mutual defense pacts, and the large-scale programs of financial
and technical assistance to Asian, African, and Latin American coun-
tries. If it had produced an effectively integrated Atlantic Community
willing and able to protect and help its allies and friends in all parts
of the world, the "grand design" for an Atlantic partnership would
have been the culmination of the postwar process of international
restructuring.
However, in the course of the 1960's, it gradually became evident
that the intensity and clear-cut global dichotomy of the cold war was
being diffused and confused by fundamental changes on both sides:
the growing rivalry between the Soviet Union and China, the gradual
loosening of Soviet control over the East European countries and their
increasing independence in both domestic and foreign policy, the wan-
ing revolutionary fervor of Soviet communism and its concomitant
waxing concern with fostering Russian prosperity; and, on the West-
ern side, the parallel decline in U.S. influence over its NATO allies,
the new "isolationism" in West European attitudes, and the marked
1 For a fuller analysis of the characteristics of the new period and their Implications for
u.S. policy, see Theodore Geiger, "The Ending of an Era In Atlantic Policy," in the Atlantic
Community Quarterly, vol. 5, No. 1, spring 1967, pp. 87-98.
PAGENO="0054"
.46 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
slowing down of the movement toward European economic and politi-
cal union. During these years, it also became evident that recurrent
crises would be occurring in Asia, Africa, and Latin Americ'i in which
the United States would feel impelled to become actively involved
without the support-and sometimes despite the disapproval-of its
now-isolationist NATO allies.
Thus, the new period in world politics is much more complex, am-
biguous, and intractable than that of the immediate postwar decades,
and the possibilities for grand designs and other major world political
`md economic restructuring become correspondingly more remote An
Atlantic partnership effectively organized and willing tO play an active
role in protecting the security and fostering the progress of Asia,
Africa, and Latin America is no longer a realistic goal of U.S. policy.
In the long term, there may well be other compelling reasons for
Atlantic unification than the now waning external menace of revolu-
tionary communism-although there could perhaps be a revival of the
latter's worldwide messianism How ever, it is hkely that efforts to press
toward this hitherto pivotal objective of U S postwar policy will be
futile duiing the medium term and, indeed, coald well result in further
weakening of NATO `mnd gie'tter European dis'mffection fiom U S
leadership in the shorter term.
In place of an Atlantic partnership serving as the organizing and
supporting nucleus of an international system, less focused, less inte-
grated and less institutionalized developments alone appear to be feasi-
ble in the period ahead. In place of great new structural political
creations, more modest functional economic arrangements may be all
that lie within the limits of the possible These c'tnnot now be premised
upon and aimed at completing a grind At1'mntic design While `ms a
practical matter, they may begin with some or all of the m'tjor West
em nations, there no longer are pohtlc'Ll ieasons for giving them an
exclusively regional Atlantic focus Indeed, to `itternpt to do so would
arouse suspicions not only in Asi'm, Afr'c'm, `md Latin America but also
in continental Western Europe, and thereby make their realization
impossible.
Thus, today, when free trade has for the first time become a realistic
eventual goal of U.S. policy, it can-and must-now be pursued in a
more flexible manner and in a less explicitly j?olitic'ml context th'mn w'ms
characteristic of the past. The basic and generalized political reason
for U.S. national interest in free trade, as previously in freer trade, still
holds: its contribution to world stability and progress and hence to
the security and welfare of the United States. But, in considering how
to reach this goal, it is no longer necessary-indeed, it would probably
be counterproductive-to place much emphasis on an Atlantic com-
munity rationale. Formally organized arrangements-for example, a
free-trade area-may well be needed, if not to achieve free trade, then
to preserve it, as we shall explain below. i~ so, however, their justifica-
tion is largely economic in nature and their chances of being accepted
by most other countries-including perhaps even the United Kingdom
and Japan and certainly the main continental West European na-
tions-are likely to be enhanced to the. extent to which they are con-
ceived `mnd presented in economic terms
In this new setting for U.S. foreign trade~ policy, we believe that
the achievement of free trade by the end of the next decade or so has
PAGENO="0055"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 47
now become a relevant and realistic goal for U.S. policy. On this
assumption, the remainder of this paper considers and compares the
two ways open to GATT members to reach an ultimate goal of free
trade-the traditional approach of multilateral bargaining in suc-
cessive GATT rounds, and the establishment of an appropriate form
of free-trade arrangement. In assessing their relative merits, two kinds
of considerations need to be taken into account. The first are quali-
tative and analytical, involving comparison of the characteristics of
the two approaches and of how they have affected the efforts so far
made to implement them. The second set of considerations are quánti-
tative `and empirical, consisting of `attempts to measure the probable
effects of the two methods on the volume and composition of imports
and exports'; on particular industries, regions and types of enter-
prises and workers in the countries concerned; and on the general
conditions of internal and external equilibrium of these nations.
In this paper, we have scope only for a preliminary assessment of
the first kind of considerations, and they would certainly have to be
analyzed much more thoroughly than we are able to do here before
definitive conclusions about them could be reached. Quantitative esti-
mates of the comparative costs and benefits of the two approaches
are equally important but neither the time and personnel nor the
empirical data required for such an evaluation have been available.
This underscores the preliminary character of the analysis and con-
clusions in the remaining sections of the paper.
II. Two PATHS TO FREE TRADE
THE MULTILATERAL APPROACH
Since World War II, the multilateral approach has dominated U.S.
participation in negotiations to liberalize trade. These have taken
place in six rounds held under GATT auspices, the last and most active
being the Kennedy Round. The essence of these multilateral negotia-
tions is universality and nondiscrimination. All GATT members par-
ticipate in exchanging concessions and do so according to uncondi-
tional use of the most-favored-nation (MFN) principle-described in
annex A-which dictates that concessions granted to one country are
automatically extended to all.
The six GATT rounds have made substantial progress toward fiee
trade, both in the depth of tariff cuts and in the range of products
affected. But, unlike a formal free-trade arrangement, the multilateral
approach has not committed participants to a defined goal and a fixed
program for reaching it. The extent of tariff cuts and other conces-
sions, the breadth of commodity coverage, and how often to stage
the periodic rounds-these questions have been settled ad hoc by the
participating countries and, indeed, the `two former have been key
elements in the negotiations themselves.
The outcome of the multilateral approach has, therefore, been un-
predictable. It has been animated by initiatives from the most eager
countries and from the GATT secretariat. But, in the last analysis,
the pace setters have been those major trading nations least willing
or able to offer meaningful concessions. The unconditional applica-
tion of the MFN principle has committed the multilateral approach
PAGENO="0056"
48 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
to proceed, like a wartime convoy, at the speed of its least active par-
ticipant. Otherwise such a country would have been given, through
the operation of the MFN principle, a "free ride." 2
The successful conclusion of the Kennedy Round has largely dis-
pelled the feeling, nurtured during its early years of frustration, that
the multilateral approach was no longer workable, owing to the pres-
ence of laggards among the major trading countries. But the question
remains whether or not the "convoy effect" will prevent adequate prog-
ress in the future. With tariffs lowered substantially, the next range
of tasks makes for a challenging agenda with emphasis on such stub-
born nontariff barriers as border taxation and government procure-
ment, and such "hard-core" sectors as agriculture and textiles. For the
multilateral approach to function effectively on these issues, the will-
ingness of all major GATT members will be required to break difficult
new ground.
These past limitations and continuing uncertainties for the multi-
lateral approach make it desirable to look much more seriously than
hitherto at the alternative free-trade arrangement approach now that
free trade appears to be a realistic longer range goal of U.S. policy.
THE FREE-TRADE ARRANGEMENT APPROACH
In the multilateral approach, all trading partners move as far and
as fast as they can together. A formal free-trade arrangement involves
a more limited group-at least initially-of countries sprinting ahead
to reach a state of completely free trade for virtually all products.
Since it is the assigned subject of this paper, we need to go into more
detail in introducing and defining the free-trade area concept as appli-
cable to the United States.
To date, the official U.S. view has been that regional free-trade
arrangements are desirable to support economic growth and political
integration in Europe and economic development in Asia, Africa and
Latin America but that they have not been relevant to the United
States itself nor preferable as a tactical means to the multilateral ap-
proach when the `United States was involved. Private individuals and
groups in the United States have, however, proposed from time to
time that the United States consider participating with other coun-
tries in some kind of free-trade arrangement.3 To some extent, these
views were born of frustrations during earlier stages of the Kennedy
Round, especially during the latter half of 1965 when the French
For years, a limiting factor has been the U.S. negotiating authority, which only twice
(1934 and 1945) permitted the President to negotiate for tariff cuts exceeding 20 percent
and was generally hedged by peril points and escape clauses. During the agonizing course
of the Kennedy Round, it appeared that it was the EEC that was holding down the pace
of negotiations, at one point stopping them entirely. The conclusion of the Kennedy Round
has dispelled this contention. All of the major trading countries-including the United
States-proved to have their areas of reluctance or inability to negotiate.
8 Published proposals for considering one or another type of free-trade arrangement as
an appropriate approach for U.S. trade policy include: "After the Kennedy Round, What?"
a speech by Howard S. Piquet, senior economist, Library of Congress, January 1965; "The
United States Should Adopt a Free Trade Strategy," a private paper issued in July 1965
by David J. Steinberg, chief economist of the Committee for a National Trade Policy; "The
TIS. Role in Britain's Economic Crisis," a speech by Senator Jacob K. Javits at the Savoy
Hotel, London, November 1965; "A New Trade Strategy for Canada and the United
States," a Policy Statement by the Canadian-American Committee of the National Planning
Association (U.S.A.) and the Private Planning Association of Canada (Washington and
Montreal: May 1966) : "A Reassessment of Trade Policies," one of the recommendations
in the "United States Balance of Payments: An Appraisal of U.S. Economic Strategy" by
the Economic Policy Association (Washington, DC.: 1966) pp. 146-1~1; Ralph I. Strauss,
"A Proposal for New Initiative in U.S. Foreign Trade Policy," Orbis, vol. XI, No. 1 (spring
1967).
PAGENO="0057"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 49
boycott of the EEC's operations paralyzed negotiations. More recently,
private interest in free-trade arrangements and critical response to this
approach4 no longer view it as an alternative to an unpromising Ken-
nedy Round, but rather as the next logical step for U.S. trade policy
regardless of the outcome at Geneva.5
Almost without exception, these proposals for free-trade arrange-
ments have been unconcerned, or at least unclear, about the nature
of the basic agreement. Therefore, it would be useful to describe the
general outlines of the kind of free-trade arrangement that would be
appropriate for U.S. participation.
The starting point is the GATT rule permitting a group of mem-
bers to form a new free-trade arrangement that discriminates against
other GATT members in violation of its basic principle of nondis-
crimination. Annex A describes in greater detail how the GATT
reconciles this apparent conflict. Suffice it to say here, the GATT does
sanction discriminatory arrangements but only if they meet strict
requirements aimed at preventing them from becoming loose pref-
erence systems or protectionist trade blocs. Specifically, it allows its
members to form either a free trade area or a customs union that meets
four standards:
Complete, not partial, elimination of "duties and other restric-
tive regulations" among its members.
Commodity coverage accounting for "substantially all the
trade" among participants.
No increase in restrictiveness of trade barriers against non-
members; and
Full development "within a reasonable length of time."
As defined by the GATT, a free trade area is formed when two or
more countries agree to abolish tariffs and other barriers to trade
among themselves. Unlike the alternative customs union (a tradi-
tional arrangement with a long history in Europe), the free trade
area does not require its participants to form a common external tariff
affecting imports from nonmember countries.
This simple distinction between the two types of free-trade arrange-
ment permitted by the GATT holds important implications for their
applicability to the United States. Members of a customs union must,
and members of a free trade area need not, develop a common com-
mercial policy toward nonmembers.6 In the context of possible U.S.
participatioii, the need for concerting commercial policy appears to
preclude the customs union, for this requirement would clearly pre-
For recent assessments of the free-trade arrangement as a policy option for the United
States that do not find it preferable to a continuation of multilateral approaches see:
John Evans, "U.S. Trade Policy: New Legislation for the Next Round" (New York: Harper
& Row for the Council on Foreign Relations, 1967) especially ch. VIII, "Atlantic Partner-
ship and Free Trade Areas"; Bela Balassa, "Trade Liberalization Among Industrialized
countries: Objectives and Alternatives" (New York: McGraw-Hill Book Co. for the
Council on Foreign RelatIons, 1967) especially ch. VII, "A Trade Policy for the Atlantic
Area."
It Is worth noting the rise of private interest In Canada, and later in the United
Kingdom, in some form of free-trade area which would encompass them and the United
States as a nucleus. As we shall discuss in greater detail below, the U.S. view as to the
eventual scope of such an arrangement is wider than the Atlantic free trade area that
Canadian and British supporters usually have in mind.
° A subsidiary technical implication of retaining individual tariffs toward non-members
Is the need for a free trade area to prevent goods from outside the area entering a high-
tariff country via diversion through a lower-tariff member. This "origin problem" has
apparently been solved by the European Free Trade Association.
PAGENO="0058"
50 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
ernpt congressional prerogatives to set U.S. trade policy. A free trade
area, however, would permit U.S. trade policy toward nonmembers to
be determined as it now is. In addition, the absence of a common ex-
ternal tariff and a common commercial policy makes it possible to
have an arrangement with a minimum need for policy integration
among the members and with less extensive adjustment problems than
in a customs union. Between the two forms of free-trade arrangement
permitted by the GATT, therefore, the free trade area appears to be
the only practicable choice for the United States.
Experience to date among industrialized countries shows that
achieving a stable free-trade situation that provides fair competition
requires more than n'ierely abolishing tariffs and quotas. Participants
must also take steps to control the discriminatory effects of nontrade
regulations and practices affecting freely traded products. In addition,
they may wish-as does the EEC-to coordinate certain of their na-
tional economic policies that significantly affect comparative produc-
tion costs, for example, taxation and social welfare, energy and trans-
portation, etc. A group of countries desiring to reach full economic
integration and eventual political unification, as did the EEC, will aim
to go even further in developing joint policies and arrangements, such
as a c mmon currency, a single capital market, etc. But, it is realistic
to assume that even the simplest free trade area-one leaning over
backwards to limit economic integration-will, as did the EFTA, find
it necessary to set some "rules of competition" to prevent frustration
of the benefits expected of free trade.7 Such a relatively nonintegrated
free trade area would probably also have to develop mechanisms for
harmonizing members' domestic economic conditions so as to enable
participants to avoid or, if not possible, to deal jointly with, severe
problems of internal and external imbalance by meaiis other than the
reimposition of restrictions on imports and exports.
Taking together the distinction between the two forms of free-trade
arrangement permitted by the GATT, the GATT rules and the prac-
tical requirements governing them, and assuming that the United
States will continue to adhere to the GATT and that the Congress will
maintain its role in determining U.S. trade policy, we conclude that:
A free-trade arrangement invola'ing the United States would have to
take the form of a free-trade area in which participating countries
would, over a specified time period, completely abolish barriers affect-
ing virtually all mutually traded products, and set other rules to co-
ordinate policies as may be found necessary to provide fair competi-
tion for the commodities being freely traded and to preserve free trade
despite the changing internal and external conditions of its members.
POSSIBLE CHARACTERISTICS OF A FIiEE-TRADE AREA INCLUDING THE
UNITED STATES
This basic definition notes only the most general features of a free-
trade arrangement involving the United States. There still remains a
wide scope for choice as to its specific ch~tr'icteristics An i1lustmtr~ e
For an account of how EFTA approached these questions, see "Building EFTA, A Free
Trade Area In Europe," prepared by the EFTA Secretariat (Geneva: December 1966) pp.
100-120; and J. S. Lambrinidis, "The Structure, Function, and Law of a Free Trade Area:
The European Free Trade Association," (New York: Praeger, 1911o) ~l. i17-155. A@
applicable in a hypothetical free trade area Involving the United States, the whole range
of ancillary commitments to tariff elimination are discussed In "A Possible Plan for a
Canada-U.S. Free Trade Area," op. cit., PP. 33-41.
PAGENO="0059"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 51
checklist of questions, grouped by areas of decision, is given in annex
B. How these questions would be decided could only be known at the
conclusion of negotiations. On the basis of previous inquiry by the
authors into the possible characteristics of a Canada-U.S. arrange-
ment, however, it is reasonable to assume the following broad outline 8:
For reasons given above, the free trade area appears clearly
preferable to the customs union as the basic form of the arrange-
ment. Rules of origin would probably be patterned after those
used successfully by EFTA.
The important question of membership, that is, the geographi-
cal scope of the free trade area, will be discussed at greater length
below.
Following the precedents of Benelux, the EEC, and the EFTA,
commodity coverage would probably include all industrial prod-
ucts and raw materials. As an indispensable adjunct to free trade,
especially with blanket coverage, the arrangement would be ex-
pected to provide variousmeasures (such as adjustment assistance
and prolonged timing) to help particular industries and pro-
ducers meet the threats and realize the opportunities of a wider
and more competitive market. TJnless the participants were pre-
pared to harmonize their agricultural policies, however, they
would exclude this sector, at least at the outset, as did the EFTA.
The arrangement would probably shun explicit steps toward
closer economic integration; but, as discussed above, it would
include certain measures considered indispensable to insure that
the benefits expected from free trade would not be counteracted
by national policies, especially those with preferential effects.
These steps might include certain rules of competition and, where
necessary, facilities to insure that internal and external im-
balances would not be remedied by abrogating free trade.
The common institutions (council, secretariat, etc.) would, like
those of the EFTA rather than the EEC, be as simple as possible
and would not have scope to act supranationally.
The timing arrangements incorporated in the treaty would need
to include a transitional period as short as possible, but long
enough to enable reinvestment and restructuring of affected indus-
tries and flexible enough to recognize special adjustment problems
in certain industries and countries.
The question of membership requires fuller discussion, although
the complexities involved and the contingent perplexities that could
develop preclude our giving as clear an answer as for some of the
other characteristics of a free trade area. In the event that the
United States were to opt for the free trade area approach-the
circumstances of which are discussed later-the most likely initial
group of full members would consist of the United States, Canada,
the United Kingdom and some other EFTA countries if they had not
entered the EEC by then.9 Others interested in full membership
B See two publications of the Canadian-American Committee of the National Plannlng
Association (U.S.A.) and the Private Planning Association of Canada: Sperry Lea, "A
Canada-U.S. Free Trade Arrangement: Survey of Possible Characterlstlcs," and "A Pos-
sible Plan for a Canada-U.S. Free Trade Area," a staff study (19C3 and i9~5 respectively).
The characteristics broadly outlined here reffect to some extent those developed in ch. II,
`Choices Among Options," of the latter publication.
A bilateral nucleus Of the United States and Canada is theoretically possible, and such
a North American free trade area has sometimes been suggested as an end in itself. But,
for somewhat dIfferent reasons, Canadians and Americans interested in mutual free trade
appear to prefer a wider arrangement.
PAGENO="0060"
52 ISSTJES AND OBJECTIVES OF IJ.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
initially might be the EEC, Japan, Australia, and New Zealand,
and perhaps a few Asian, African, and Latin American nations, as
discussed below. In line with the global purposes of the arrangement,
reflecting considerations mentioned earlier, the other economically
developed countries would be invited to participate at the outset but,
for various reasons, some or all of them may be unable or unwilling
to become founding members. Therefore, the charter members would
want to design their free trade area to facilitate subsequent entry
of the other developed nations that did not opt for initial accession.
The two major uncertainties are the EEC and the less developed
countries of Asia, Africa, and Latin America. The question of EEC
membership is so closely related to the considerations that the United
States would face in choosing between the two approaches to free
trade that it can best be discussed in that context later in this paper.
Here, we can briefly consider the problems involved in participation
by the less developed nations.
In keeping with the nonregional, nonpolitical character of an
arrangement relevant to the new period in world politics, participa-
tion in .a free trade area would be open to Asian, African, and Latin
American countries. But, it would be neither realistic nor even desir-
able to expect them to meet the same schedule of tariff cuts as the*
economically developed nations of North America, Western Europe,
and the Pacific. A possible way to overcome this difficulty would be
to permit the less developed countries to abolish their tariffs over a
long period, say 25 to 30 years-as the EEC did in extending asso-
ciate membership to Greece and Turkey-and, conversely, to grant
free entry for their exports to the industrialized members in half the
time, or even less, that the latter envisaged for themselves. In this way,
the nonindustrialized countries would have an incentive to develop
their export capabilities; they would have the advantage of temporary
preferential access to the free trade area since they would not have to
meet the export competition of the industrialized members for the first
5 years or so; and their own home markets could be protected for a
long enough period from the competing exports of the latter.
Two difficulties can be forseen in such an arrangement. The first
relates to the fact that a handful of Asian, African, and Latin Amer-
ican countries are markedly more developed than the great majority
and could, in consequence, be expected to preempt most, if not all, of
the benefits of early free access for industrial products to the markets
of the developed countries. The second is the fact that their manu-
factured exports would consist in large part of precisely those goods
(textiles, clothing, etc.) that would create the most sticky adjustment
problems for the United States and the other developed members.
Hence, it would probably be politically necessary to distinguish
between the more and the less advanced among the developing coun-
tries, with the former receiving the benefits of participation in the
free trade area later than and not as fully as, and meeting the recip-
rocal obligations of full membership much earlier than, the latter.
Indeed, a valid argument could be made for expecting them to con-
form to the same transitional schedule for opening their own markets
that the developed members would be following. If they were to do
so, they would, of course, qualify for full membership along with
the ini~tial nucleus of founding countries. The really less developed
PAGENO="0061"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 53
nations enjoying the benefits of participation would be associate mem-
bers until they, too, were able and willing to open their own economies
freely to the exports of the other members.
III. THE Two APPROACHES COMPARED: A PRELIMINARY EVALUATION
Our original question remains of how relevant such an arrangement
would be to the future needs of U.S. trade policy; specifically,
whether, and if so at what point, it would be desirable to shift from
the multilateral approach to the free trade area approach. It is quite
beyond the scope of this paper adequately to analyze all of the factors
involved in this question. But without presuming to reach definitive
conclusions, we shall briefly discuss certain key issues on which the
free trade area option is likely to be tested.
First, let us clarify what is to be compared. If, as in the past,
Americans clearly distinguish between free trade and merely freer
trade as ultimate objectives-and generally continue to prefer the
latter-then the free trade area concept is irrelevant as a means of
policy, and has to be evaluated as an alternative goal. We have as-
sumed in this paper that Americans will now increasingly recognize
the relevance of the proposition that free-not just freer-trade is a
realistic objective. Thus, we are comparing multilateral bargaining
with the free trade area solely on their merits as means to a free trade
goal.
It should also be recognized that we are comparing two approaches
whose differences, while now considerable, would in all probability
gradually disappear. After another successful round of multilateral
negotiations, freedom of trade among the participants would be so
close that the question "Where do we go from here?" would inevitably
assert itself. Many GATT countries would be likely to feel the need
to set some specific target date for achieving free trade and a time-
table for reaching it. Moreover-and, as already indicated, probably
more important-the closer the GATT countries approach to free
trade, the stronger their desire to iDsure that freedom of trade would
be irreversible and that it would be conducted under conditions of fair
competition. Thus, we could expect them to undertake a variety of
commitments-mentioned above-that would duplicate most of the
characteristics of a formally organized free trade area. The partici-
pants in future successful multilateral negotiations might, therefore,
come in time to form a free trade area through a process of adaptive
mutation without having initially launched it, fully rigged, according
to the rules and rites of the GATT.
For these reasons, we assume in the following comparison that the
free trade area approach is to be tested against the traditional U.S.
multilateral approach on the basis of whether it would be a better way
to proceed-not whether it would be a better place to end up-when
conditions are propitious for a new trade policy initiative within the
next few years.
SOME BASIC CONSIDERATIONS
An essential question is how each approach handles those tasks
which assure the meaningfulness of free trade. One such task is to
stimulate more efficient use of resources-the major economic raison
d'etre of the free trade objective because of its enduring benefits to
PAGENO="0062"
54 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
producers, consumers, and the economy as a whole. The weakness in
this respect of multilateral negotiations, at least~as practiced thus far,
has been to permit participants to protect many less efficient sectors
indefinitely. A free trade area, assuming that it would not allow sig-
nificant exemptions among nonagricultural products, offers from the
outset the prospect of shifting resources from virtually all of the less
to the more efficient sectors. The inefficient industries would either be
forced to modernize or their resources would be transferred to activi-
ties in which they could be used competitively. In either case, ad-
justment assistance of various kinds would, of course, have to be made
available to both management and labor.
A second important consideration is the degree of certainty on the
part of producers that the new market situation, with its greater
growth opportunities as well as competitive threats, would be here to
stay. Without such assurance, the investments required to increase
efficiency would not be made, or at least not made extensively enough.
On this question, too, a free trade area appears to be superior in terms
of its psychological and economic effects, for it would offer compre-
hensive treaty commitments considered firmer than the limited "bind-
ings to zero" reached by the multilateral approach as hitherto
practiced.1°
The third criterion of~ an effective approach-one now recognized as
of greatly enhanced importance-is the ability to deal with nontariff
barriers. Here, the free trade area appears to have several advantages.
By abolishing tariffs, it automatically eliminates tariff-related prob-
lems; e.g., the methods of valuing and classifying imports for the pur-
pose of setting duties, etc. For other nontariff barriers, such as border
taxation, official prOcurement policies, indirect governmental aids to
production and exports, etc., the institutional mechanisms of a for-
mally organized free trade area seem to offer better means for formu-
lating and implementing the necessary accommodations than the in-
termittent and ad hoc procedures hitherto characteristic of the multi-
lateral approach. A clearer understanding of this difference would be
gained by evaluating the performance to date of the EFTA with re-
spect to nontariff barriers.
CONSIDERATIONS RELATED TO THE EEC AND THE UNITED KINGDOM
The United States cannot decide upon its method of approaching
free trade or, indeed, whether this would be a desirable objective with-
out considering the probable reactions of its principal trading part-
ners. Its largest trading partner is Canada, whose approach would
probably continue to be similar to that of the United States. The
major uncertainty would be the reaction of the EEC and the United
Kingdom.
Prior to the question of the comparative willingness-or reluc-
tance-of the EEC and the United Kingdom to participate in either
of the two approaches to free trade is the basic issue of whether either
or both of them are now, or will be in the next few years, disposed to
contemplate eventual free trade with the United States. Indications
are that strong resistance may be expected, particularly among Euro-
10 Canadians, whose main concern in any free trade situation is assured access to the
ITS. market. often stress these advantages of a formal free trade arrangement over free
entry as bound by the conventional GATT agreement.
PAGENO="0063"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 55
pean businessmen, to making free trade with non-European nations-
especially the United States-a goal of European trade policy. it
should be remembered, however, that many European businessmen
were also opposed to the formation of the EEC, but their governments
were nevertheless able to move ahead to establish a common market.
European governments could do the same with respect to free trade
with North America provided they were convinced that, in the sense
defined at the beginning of this paper, the free trade objective is today
as relevant for Western Europe as for the United States. Hence, it is
legitimate to assume that the Europeans may also ~come, Sooner or
later, to see free trade as not only a realistic but also a desirable
eventual goal.
With respect to the existing six-member EEC, whether and when it
may be prepared to contemplate free trade with North America are
questions closely related to the future role of its common external tar-
iff. whose functions are in turn determined by the EEC's own long-
term goal. in addition to its conventional protective function, the
common external tariff has been serving the broader purposes of
helping to maintain the identify of the EEC during the period of its
evolution into a full economic and political union and of providing an
inducement for the participating countries to remain members of it.
Prior to the achievement of a European union, abolition of the com-
mon external tariff, particularly in order to participate in a wider
free trade area, would probably result in dissolution of the EEC
unless other binding and benefit-conferring relationships had by then
developed; for example, a common currency, integrated tax systems,
common policies in the major economic sectors, increased suprana-
tional authority for the European Commission, etc. Conversely; un-
less the EEC remains committed to, and continues to make some sig-
nificant progress toward, a European economic and political union,
some or all of the six might prefer to participate in a much wider and,
therefore, potentially more beneficial free trade area than to continue
as members of a customs union that would be little more than a pro-
tectionist bloc. The marked slowing down in the course of the 1960's of
the movement toward European union raises this possibility.
in view of these questions, the next 3 or 4 years are likely to. he
a critical period for the future of the EEC. One event that would
force its members to make decisions on these questions would be an
explicit commitment by the United States to an eventual free trade
goal. Should the EEC decide to resume the advance toward full union,
then the other binding relationships, noted above, would rapidly de-
velop to fulfill the noneconomic functions hitherto performed solely
by its common external tariff, and it could still participate in a wider
nonpolitical free trade area without loss of identity and cohesion.
Conversely, should the Europeans decide not to move toward union,
the EEC's Customs Union might well prove to have been no more than
a transitmonal arrangement that prepared its six members to partici-
pate more effectively in a broader free trade area including North
America.
if the United Kingdom succeeded in joining the EEC in the next
few years, the critical decisioii period would undoubtedly be pro-
longed. But, the basic issues outlined above would remain, except that
PAGENO="0064"
56 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLiCY
United Kingdom membership would probably be one of the factors
working against resumption of the movement toward full union.
Should the United Kingdom fail to join the EEC, the British may be
expected to investigate other kinds of free trade arrangements in
which they could participate, especially with North America. Indeed,
several private groups and individuals in England are already explor-
ing an open-ended free trade area for the United Kingdom."
A definitive judgment about the implications of these complex and
ambiguous considerations for the U.S. choice between the two ap-
proaches to free trade cannot be reached at this time. On the one
hand, if the U.S. decision has to be made in conditions of continued
uncertainty about whether the United Kingdom could join the EEC
and about resumption of the latter's movement toward European
union, another round of the multilateral approach would probably
be indicated. On the other hand, the failure of one or both of these
possibilities in the next few years would argue for resolving the am-
biguity in favor of a free trade area approach by the United States.
CONSIDERATIONS REGARDING THE FEASIBILITY OF THE MULTILATERAL
APPROACH
Regardless of the foregoing considerations, the United States could
well decide to stay with the much more familiar multilateral approach.
In that event, it would direct its initiative to shaping and animating
a new GATT round to deal with the new agenda of tasks. But, as
noted above, multilateral negotiations have in the past been paced,
through the "convoy effect," to the speed of the least willing major
participant. If this limitation could not be obviated through advance
agreement, it might be that one or more of the main participants
would prove unwilling or unable to reciprocate for concessions offered
by the others. This situation would confront the willing countries with
the choices of (1) giving the reluctant nation a "free ride," (2) seek-
ing progress in areas not involving the latter, which might amount to
becoming reconciled to accomplishing little, or (3) proceeding them-
selves to form a free trade arrangement under the GATT rules.12
For the United States to consider seriously the latter course would
require weighing several crucial questions:
Would the loss of momentum in failing to move ahead provide
an opportunity for the resurgence of protectionist forces ~
11 Such an arrangement Is viewed In England both as an alternative should the United
Kingdom fail to join the EEC and as a future development of Atlantic policy if the IlK.
application for EEC membership succeeds. These Britons conceive the initial scope of such
an arrangement as comprising the United States, Canada, and the EFTA countries, with
Australia, New Zeland. and possibly Japan also Included. There seems to be less interest
in Japanese participation In the United Kingdom than In the United States. The Britons
interested in this possibility believe that the EEC would prefer to abstain from partici-
pation until the process of Internal unification progresses much further. Such a free trade
area possibility and its implications are being clarified by the Atlantic Trade Study, a
corporate group recently formed to sponsor a series of research projects outlined In foot-
note 14. At first sight there appear to be some differences between their concept and the
free trade area we have described above, but they could well be only matters of emphasis
and semantics deriving from the nature of Britain's current "great debate" about Its role
in the world. The British almost always talk of an "Atlantic free trade area" or a "North
Atlantic free trade area." The word "Atlantic" is shunned, however, in the discussion, as
well as In the titles, of the two most fully articulated American proposals to date ("A
New Trade Strategy for Canada and the United States," op. cit.; and R. Straus, op. cit'
Yet the British studies are explicitly based on the first of these publications.
12 We reject the feasibility of changing the U.S. MFN commitment to a conditional basis
In dealing with other major trading countries for the reasons given In "The Most Favored
Nation Principle: An Appraisal of Its Current validity In World Trade" (Washington,
D.C.: Chamber of Commerce of the United States of America, February 1966).
PAGENO="0065"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 57
What reaction might be expected from the reluctant country or
group of countries if the United States and other important trad-
ing nations were to decide to form a free trade area without them?
What would be the reactions of other countries willing to move
ahead in multilateral negotiations but which would not be in a
position to participate in a free trade area from the outset?
At that time, an evaluation of the two latter points would be par-
ticularly important. While, in the event of the failure of a new multi-
lateral round, the United States might decide to take the initiative
toward forming a free trade area, it would clearly wish to encourage
all GATT countries to participate eventually, if not initially. Hence,
it would be necessary to weigh carefully the possibility that major
trading nations not part of the nucleus group might be alienated in-
definitely from the free trade arrangement. Considerations of this
kind, particularly as related to the EEC, could only be settled in the
context of the situation existing at the time.
TACTICAL CONSIDERATIONS
A final set of considerations relates to the private reactions to the
two approaches. Essentially, the question turns on whether or not it
would be good tactics to make the free trade goal explicit. Some people
claim that the best way to gain support and neutralize opposition for
a process leading to free trade would be to present a fully articulated
plan with its ultimate end clearly proclaimed. This view would favor
use of the free trade area concept from the start. However, it could
well be that it would be better tactics not to publicize the free trade
objective and a timetable for achieving it until one or more successful
multilateral rounds reached the stage, described above, where the par-
ticipants felt impelled to adopt many of the attributes of a formally
organized free trade area.
Only an empirical investigation of potential support for the goal of
free trade-not only in the United States but also in the other major
trading nations-could settle this question. However, one bit of evi-
dence relevant to such an inquiry is the reaction of the U.S. business
community and trade unions to the unexpectedly large tariff reduc-
tions made by the Kennedy Round. While the response has not been
as enthusiastic as could be wished, it has also not been as hostile as was
anticipated. U.S. business and labor generally seem resigned to coping
with the more competitive situation that will develop as the Kennedy
Round cuts go into effect, and their neutral reaction would augur well
Tfor the free trade area approach.
IV. Co~cr~rsio~
Before summarizing our conclusions, we wish to reiterate the point
made at the beginning of the paper relating not to the means we have
compared but to the end they would serve. The fact that it has become
relevant and realistic for the United States to commit itself to reaching
the goal of free trade by the end of the next decade or so is of over-
Tiding significance compared with the choice between the two possible
ways to achieve it. In the next few years the primary need is for de-
cisionmakers and opinion leaders in the United States to become ac-
customed to think about U.S. trade policy in these new terms, viz, as
S2--246----67-------5
PAGENO="0066"
58 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
aimed at free trade and no longer at freer trade. Once this way of
thinking becomes sufficiently widespread-as happened two decades
ago with the idea of trade liberalization-then the question of whether
to continue to follow the traditional U.S. method of multilateral nego-
tiations or to shift, sooner or later, to a free trade area approach be-
comes largely a technical question of choosing the most effective means
to an accepted end.
Assuming that Americans can think in these new terms about where
U.S. trade policy should end up, then the free trade method has to
be regarded as~ a major practicable technique for getting there. Our
preliminary evaluation indicates that the free trade area concept is
relevant to the long-range perspective of U.S. trade policy almost re-
gardless of what happens. Our reason is that, sooner or later, the
United States appears likely to find either that its next logical step
would be to participate in establishing a free trade area or that it
would be moving gradually into relationships that would amount to
much the same thing. These possible outcomes could be reached in
three ways:
1. The earliest, that a decision about U.S. trade policy is likely
tO be taken would be after the presidential election of 1968, most
probably not until the spring of 1969. If the United States con-
tinues to think in terms of the multilateral appi o'ic1i, an evalua
tion at that time of the prospects for another round of negoti't
tions might indicate slight ch'tnce for success owing to lack of
`tgreement as to objectives or agenda or to the unwillingness or
in'ibility of one or more maior trading nat ons to m'ike their
share of cOncessions (the. "convoy effect"). In that event, the
United States might conclude that it would be appropriate to
maintain momentum toward eventual free trade by the only al-
ternative approach available under GATT rules-a formally or-
ganized free trade arrangement consisting of those countries in a
position to move ahead. As outlined above, such an arrangement
would probably be a free trade area that would eliminate tariffs
and other barriers to mutual trade in all nonagricultural prod-
ucts; being functional in purpose, it would limit steps toward
economic integration to those that proved indispensable to insure
the benefits of free trade; it would have simple institutions and
flexible timing arrangements to deal with problems in certain
products in certain countries. It would aim to be ultimately
global in scope, welcoming all industrialized countries as mem-
bers and providing for special arrangements for less-developed
countries. Such a free trade area, unlike all other postwar free
trade arrangements, would not be regional. To be sure, it would
probably start among Atlantic countries, but it would strive to
expand beyond that beachhead to include within the area of free
trade as many other nations as possible.
2. A more likely prospect would be for the United States to
enter into multilateral negotiations, focusing its efforts on sue-
cessfiiliy coping not only with further tariff reductions but also
with the challenging new problems of nontariff barriers. This
development would probably not mean, as might appear, perma-
nent U.S. rejection of the free trade area approach; it could
PAGENO="0067"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 59
mean quite the opposite. If the next round of multilateral nego-
tiations, despite early promise, gets stalled for the reasons men-
tioned, then it is quite possible that the United States would
decide to shift to the alternative approach of a global nonpolitical
free trade area, as outlined above. A U.S. decision to make this
change could be accelerated by the EEC's definitive rejection of
United Kingdom entry, if the British were then to take a serious
official interest in a free trade area including the United States
and others.
3. If, however, the next round of multilateral negotiations
turns out to be successful, the major trading nations would then
be so close to free trade that they could be expected to commit
themselves to this objective by a fixed future date, and to create-
if and when required-institutions to develop, concert and im-
plement the policies needed to preserve free trade, once attained.
In this case, the distinctive characteristics of a free trade area
would evolve gradually and tacitly rather than be established cx-
plicity in a formal treaty.
We must also admit the possibility that none of these three develop-
ments would occur owing to the unwillingness of a number of impor-
tant trading nations to reach free trade with the United States. In
this case, the chances are that GATT countries would inch ahead
together in future rounds, gradually evolving a world trading system
that, for want of a better name, might be called a "freer trading
area" with significant economic sectors still protected but perhaps
with some progress made in reducing nontariff barriers. Even so,
the free-trade area concept would still be relevant to describing the
ultimate situation that would be approached, although not reached.
Because the free-trade area concept appears in greater or lesser
degree relevant to almost every foreseeable development affecting
11.5. policy-excepting Only prolonged complete blockage of forward
movement-it is important for Americans to use the present pause
before a new trade policy initiative to acquaint themselves better
with its nature, applicability to future tasks, and probable impact
on the United States. Specifically, we recommend:
A. An evaluation of the practical experience of the postwar free-
trade arrangements among developed countries, especially the EFTA
which most closely reflects the spirit and purposes that would animate
a scheme involving the United States. Particular attention should
be given to four aspects: (i) The difficulties actually encountered
within EFTA-compared to those anticipated-from completely elim-
inating tariffs affecting all nonagricultural products; (ii) the adjust-
ment policies that proved to be most effective; (iii) the ancillary com-
mitments found necessary to assure fair competition; and (iv) how
EFTA has dealt with, or has considered dealing with, nontariff bar-
riers and the eventual inclusion of agriculture. The problem of non-
tariff restrictions promises to figure prominently on the agenda of
any future trade negotiations whether for further multilateral tariff
reductions or to form a free trade area.
B. Quantitative empirical studies directed to determining the prob-
able impact of a free trade area on a range of aspects affecting the
United States. Research programs currently being completed in
PAGENO="0068"
60 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
Canada 13 and launched in the United Kingdom ~ would be useful
guides, but clearly a U.S. effort would in addition cover such particu-
lar concerns as balance-of-payments effects.
In summary, the United States might opt for establishing a formal
free trade area if the traditional multilateral approach appeared,
before or after a new round of negotiations, to have no prospect for
success. This decision might be influenced by official British support
for a free trade area in the event that the EEC rejected the United
Kingdom's application for membership. Conversely, a successful mul-
tilateral round could lead GATT countries to creating gradually
arrangements to ensure fair competition and to handle problems of
internal and external imbalance that would amount to a free trade
area. For these reasons, the free-trade approach is already a relevant,
and could soon be an applied, means of U.S. policy. Americans need,
in consequence, to explore its potentialities and limitations and its
benefits and costs much more seriously and thoroughly than they
have hitherto done.
13The Private Planning Association of Canada is completing the Atlantic economic
studies program, a 3-year project to assess the implications for that country of freer or free
trade among Atlantic nations. Nearing publication are over 20 studies grouped under the
following subjects: discussions of policy options; economic impact studies (covering agri-
culture, a number of specific industries and geographical regions, and capital movements)
analyses of appropriate harmonization policies and of transitional arrangements; ap-
praisais of the long-term prospects of the Canadian economy under freer and free trade;
and the implications of closer Atlantic trading relations for Canad~s's trade with other
areas.
14 The recently initiated Atlantic Trade Study, whose objectives are noted in footnote
No. ii, is reported to comprise at least seven studies covering the following aspects of a
"North Atlantic free trade area" from the British viewpoint: trade policy alternatives,
monethry problems, political aspects, U.S. investment in Britain, problems of harmoniza-
tion, agriculture, and relations with the less developed countries.
PAGENO="0069"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF TJ.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 61
ANNEX A
THE GATT PRovisioNs FOR FREE TRADE ARRANGEMENTS
The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) was formed
in 1948 at the intersection of two conflicting impulses in international
commercial relations. One was the determination to reestablish the
principle of nondiscrimination, which had badly eroded before World
War II. The GATT thus selected `as its cornerstone the unconditional
most-favored-nation (MFN) principle; its very first sentence states:
"With respect to custom duties [and other charges on imports and
exports] any advantage, favor, privilege or immunity granted by any
contracting party to any product originating in or destined for any
other country shall be accorded immediately `and unconditionally to
the like products originating in or destined for the territories of all
other contracting parties." ~
Thus, GATT countries would treat the products of all other mem-
bers on an equal basis, concessions that were negotiated would be
passed on to all, and any new preferences were to be prohibited.' (But
members might retain previously established preferences such as those
among commonwealth countries, or then in effect between the United
States and Cuba and the United States and the Philippines.)
At the same time, the GATT had to accommodate a new and ir-
repressible movement-at first confined to Europe-toward regional
free trade through `arrangements in which participants shared this
privilege among themselves alone. Indeed9 on the same day that GATT
was born in Geneva to encourage multilateralism, the Belgium-
Netherlands-Luxembourg Economic Union (Benelux) was launched
in Brussels to initiate the postwar movement toward regional free
trade.
The delicate task of reconciling these trends fell to Article XXI V.2
The first relevant paragraph recognized that regional free trade might
be so oriented and organized to serve its participants without frustrat-
ing the basic goals of the GATT, and to this end permitted members
to form new free-trade arrangements, either as customs unions or free
trade areas.
"The contracting parties recogniz'e the desirability of increasing
freedom of trade by the development, through voluntary agreements,
of closer integration between the economies of the countries party to
such agreements. They also recognize that the purpose of a customs
union or of a free-trade area should be to facilitate trade between
the constituent territories and not to raise barriers to the trade of other
contracting parties with such territories."3
The remaining six paragraphs of article XXIV then went on to
provide rules designed to prevent the new project from violating the
spirit of the above paragraph by imitating the commonwealth prefer-
`ence system or becoming an inward-looking protectionist trade bloc.
1 From paragraph 1 of article I, entitled "General Most Favoured Nation Treatment."
The relevant text of article XXIV of the GATT, setting forth the conditions for new
free-trade arrangements, is presented verbatim and accompanied with a brief commentary in
Lea, op. cit., pp. 99-107. A more extensive discussion is to be found iii James Jay Allen,
"The European Common Market and the GATT" (Washington, D.C.: The University Press
of Washington for the Institute for International and Foreign Trade Law, Georgetown
University Law Center), 1960; and Lambrinidis, op. cit., chapter XII, "Compatibility of
the EF'TA Convention with GATT."
Article XXIV, par. 4.
PAGENO="0070"
62 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
Specifically, article XXIV stipulated that, in forming customs unions
or free trade areas (or interim arrangements leading to either), mem-
bers must meet certain substantive and procedural provisions.
SUBSTANTIVE STANDARDS
Complete, not partial, elimination of "duties and other restrictive
regulations of commerce" applied to products originating in members'
territories.
Commodity coverage accounting for "substantially all the trade"
among participants.4
No increase in restrictiveness of trade barriers against nonmembers;
and
Development "within a reasonable length of time."
PROcEDURAL REQUIREMENTS
Article XXIV requires also that GATT members submit their pro-
posed project to the GATT for sustained examination, with approval
deferred until its real characteristics are revealed in operation. Where
a free trade project clearly fails to meet the substantive standards, a
waiver must be granted by two-thirds of its membership under article
XXV. Such a waiver was granted in 1952 for the European Coal and
Steel Community, and in December 1965, for the Canadian-American
automotive agreement, both of which violated the MFN clause of the
GATT without amounting to a free trade area or customs union as
defined by the GATT.
4 The precise meaning of "substantially all the trade" has never been given, but
precedents for about 80 percent of total trade appear to have been set. The question of
whether this rule would have to be waived to permit the exclusion of agricultural products
might raise itself more seriously in a free trade area Involving the United States, Canada
and Australia than it did in the case of EFTA.
PAGENO="0071"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 63
ANNEX B
MAJOR QuesTIoNs INVOLVED IN CONSIDERING THE POSSIBLE CHARAC-
TERISTICS* OF A FREE TRADE ARRANGEMENT INVOLVING THE UNITED
STATES
DECISION AREA AND MAJOR QUESTIONS
1. Basic Jiorm.
a. Choice between customs union or free trade area as each is
defined in the GATT.
b. If customs union, method of determining the common ex-
ternal tariff.
c. If free trade area, method of handling the "origin problem."
2. Geographic scope.
a. Composition of the initial membership.
b. Provisions for the accession of additional new members.
c. Treatment of territories or countries having special trading
relationships with member countries, (such as the Common-
wealth countries have with the United Kingdom).
d. Whether or not the arrangement should be open-ended to
potentially fully participating members, or to linking with estab-
lished free trade arrangements.
e. Whether the arrangement should accept associate members
(such as Greece and Turkey with the EEC) with special long-
term transitional provisions.
f. Whether and how the arrangement might extend free trade
on a one-way basis to developing countries.
3. Comíimodity coverage.
a. Extent of coverage among nonagricultural products (manu-
factures and industrial raw materials). This could be all inclusive
(EEC and EFTA) or under a doctrine of "maximum possible
coverage," permitting exemptions (Australia-New Zealand free
trade area).
b. Extent of coverage among agricultural products and close
derivatives. If covered, guidelines for common agricultural
policies.
c. Handling of nonagricultural products with special situations
(most naturally, petroleum).
d. Various forms of adjustment assistance, seen as an alterna-
tive to exemption from commodity coverage of products with
acute problems.
4. Economic integration.
a. Purpose: Limited to providing meaningful free trade
(EFTA), or undertaken for its own sake, or even to lead to po-
litical integration (original EEC purpose, apparently opposed
by Dc Gaulle).
b. Approach to "rules of competition":
Handling of government aids to exports, production,
* transport, procurement, etc.
Restrictive business practices.
*These decision areas are explored in detail In Lea, op. cit. and "A Possible Plan for a
Canada-United States Free Trade Area," op. cit. Choices for some of these questions are
given under "Possible Characteristics" In sec. II of this paper.
PAGENO="0072"
64 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
c. Approach to policy coordination:
That concerned with growth and stability (monetary
policy, responses to balance-of-payments problems, etc.).
That related to redefinition of "domestic producer,"
"export market," etc., in laws affecting dumping, anti-
trust, and pooled export legislation.
5. Comimon ~titution~.
a. Basic purpose: Limited to serving free trade arrangement
(EFTA), or as means to "institutional integration" with political
overtones (most especially ECSC, but also EEC).
b. Approach to institution building: Fully defined in basic
treaty (EEC), or left to be created by the central organ as it deems
necessary (EFTA).
c. Extent of powers: Voting formulas, possibility of supra-
national elements.
d. Distribution of powers: Single central body (EFTA Coun-
cil), or in different bodies holding balance of powers (EEC).
e. Techniques for settling disputes.
f. Location of common institutions.
6. Ti9ming arrangements.
a. Timetable for abolishing trade barriers, between the member
countries, including possibility of recognizing special adjustment
problems by prolonged or staggered transitional periods.
b. In a customs union only: Timetable for forming the com-
mon external tariff.
c. Timing the entry into force of other aspects of the agreement.
d. Provisions for accelerating or delaying the basic timing
arrangements.
e. The duration of the free trade agreement: A definite expira-
tion or renewal date (NATO) , or indeterminate.
Glossary:
ECSC-European Coal and Steel Community.
EEC-European Economic Community.
EFTA-European Free Trade Association.
NATO-North Atlantic Treaty Organization.
PAGENO="0073"
THE RESTRTJCTTJRING OF FOREIGN TRADE
NEGOTIATIONS
BY ROBERT B. ,SCHWENGER*
CONTENTS
Page
Introduction and summary 65
Argument 68
An integrating production process 70
Intergovernmental coordination 73
Telling good barriers from bad 75
Bargaining favors bad barriers 78
An international trade policy mechanism 84
Public process for the public interest 91
Economic unity, and political fragmentation 95
INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY
A NEW APPROACH BASED ON UNDERLYING IMPERATIVES
This paper presents and explains a new approach to international
trade discussion. Its principal conclusion is that future foreign trade
policy should be conducted on different' principles. This is not a crit-
ici'sm of what has been done in the past. In fact, the five principles
presented here were derived in very large part by observation of cer-
tain present trends in intergovernmental discussion. The U.S. foreign
trade program should be modified and adapted to the changed en-
vironment which imposed these trends.
To bring out their relevance for the next stage of policymaking,
after the expiration of the powers granted under the Trade Expan-
sion Act of 1962, the principles are incorporated in a specific proposal
for restructuring future trade negotiations. To emphasize, the prin-
ciples do not supply immediate solutions to present problems; they are
elements for a policy framework-a modified approach-within which
such problems may prove more readily solvable. In particular, they
were not developed for application to the Kennedy Round of GA'TT
trade negotiations, now successfully ended as a worthy sixth episode
in that remarkable series of negotiations that began in Geneva in
1947. They enyisage, as a sequel to the GATT negotiation series, cer-
tain new and con'tinuing discussions `along a somewhat different track.
*Lately Foreign Economic Policy Adviser to the Assistant `Secretary of `Labor
for International Affairs.
This paper presents the central thesis of the manuscript, "Rethinking Foreign
Trade Policy," Washington, February 1966. That manuscript was a product of a
sabbatical year spent at Gunnar Myrdal's Institute for International Economic
Studies, University `of Stockholm, reviewing 30 years of personal experience in
the trade agreements program and comparing notes with others in the field.
65
PAGENO="0074"
66 ISSUES ~D OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
These discussions would, in effect, institutionalize the revolutionary
acceptance among governments and people in the great trading coun-
tries, brought about largely through the GATT experience, of the
obligation to discuss acts distorting trade with a view to avoiding in-
jury to one another as far as practicable. It is proposed to dispense
with the ideas of reciprocity and "balance" in negotiations, over which
the GATT countries have publicly bickered and inveighed in recent
years, often with little meaning and even less useful effect. The new
discussions would move a step farther toward international princij~le
and law, and a step away from national economic power, in determin-
ing trade questions. They would be based on lessons learned in the
past three decades as to how, and how not, in the changing circum-
stances of our times, to bring trade discussion to constructive agree-
ment. They would look to a dynamic competitive process in a world
mixed economy-not to a world free trade area. They would put tar-
iffs and quotas on the same footing as government subsidy: justify or
eliminate! They would emphasize the positive contribution trade pol-
icy can make, not only to harmonious coexistence among the private
ownership developed count~ ies, but also to resolving differences with
the less developed and with the government ownership countries
They aie thought to responc1 to undcrlymg impeiati~ es ~nd, thereiore,
to open the w'ly to more ripid progrecs toward such ide'tl objectives of
U.S. foreign trade policy as peace, freedom, efficiency, and growth.
EFFORTS AT "TRADE BARRIER~~ REDUCTION THROUGH BARGAINING ARE
BECOMING LESS EFFECTIVE
A review of the trade agreements program reveals two intertwined
tendencies:
(a) To bargain away government action affecting trade; and
(b) To reach intergovernmental understanding regarding con-
tinuing government action affecting trade.
In recent years, the former, which is the declared purpose of U.S.
policy, has slowed down. Governments are reaching more and more
"resistance points" beyond which they will not reduce their trade-
affecting actions. More and more the bargaining is becoming an effort
to escape the pressures inherent in the present negotiating process; one
invents new measuring devices or new terminology intended to put
one's op:ponents on the spot, to reduce their intervention and, at the
same time, to justify one's own intervention; one finds new forms pf
intervention which maintain the effects of the old forms one turns to
subterfuge or str'uned interpret'ition Thus, the dynamic, productive
world economy-particularly th'tt maior portion of it in the private
ownership industrial countries-is governed unpredictably by groups
who differ over trade intervention theories. The confrontations be-
come frankly protectionist.
A MECHANISM FOR REACHING UNDERSTANDING: ELIMINATE UNNEEDED
INTERVENTION AND COORDINATE THE REST
Meanwhile, the second tendency noted-the growing tendency to
reach understanding about intervention-has frequently succeeded in
limiting intervention to that which serves necessary ends and in reduc-
PAGENO="0075"
ISSIJES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 67
ing its adverse effects; moreover, the effort to understand one another's
acts provides a basis for meaningful trade conversation with countries
which will not accept the reduction of government intervention as an
ideal objective. The proposals may be characterized as a shift of em-
phasis in U.S. foreign trade policy toward this process of seeking
understanding. The five principles may be crudely summarized as
follows:
1. Governments should collaborate in administering their trade
barriers.
2. Collaborating governments require a means for distinguish-
ing trade barriers which serve the public interest from those which
do not.
3. Barriers which do not serve the public interest should be
scheduled for elimination.
4. The public purpose behind a given trade barrier should be
served in the most efficient way and with the least harmful side
effects.
5. The conduct of foreign trade policy-in its details-should
be open to informed public surveillance.
The essence of the proposed mechanism is:
(a) A continuing (rather than sporadic). multilateral trade
barrier forum, for discussion of the trade effects of specific gov-
ernment actions, including actions taken to meet the domestic
problems of individual nations;
(b) All procedures of the organization to be public rather than
behind closed doors, with machinery for getting alT relevant facts
meaningfully considered;
(c) Individual governments to publicly reconsider their ac-
tions, through their own constitutional processes, in the light
of the public purpose of the action and of the findings of fact at
the multilateral examination; and
(d) Individual governments to consider cooperating to help in
the achievement, most efficiently and with minimum adverse side
effects, of the public purposes of actions examined intergovern-
mentally and maintained after public national reconsideration.
A SHIFT OF HYPOTHESES FROM BARGAINING TO DELIBERATING
Adoption of such a program calls for a shift of emphasis in the
official view as to the actions which will accomplish our objectives in
the foreign trade field. Since the end of the great depression, we have
been committed to the hypothesis that "trade barriers" prevent desir-
able economic activity and cause conflict with foreicn governments;
therefore, reducing them makes for prosperity and peace: eventually,
they should be eliminated (free trade) - One reduces them progres-
sively by bargaining between governments.
Underneath this hypothesis, however, there has developed a tacit,
qualifying counterhypothesi s: Certain "harriers"--ol d and new-ours
and other countries'-are exceptions to the rule; they are necessary
to maintain or bring about desirable national economic ohiectives; re-
ducing them would he disruptive or otherwise undesirable: hut the gov-
ernment imposing them cannot refuse to discuss them with other gov-
ernments adversely affected by them; these "barriers" must be
PAGENO="0076"
68 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
administered so asto hurt one's trading partners no more than is es-
:sential to accomplishment of the public purpose for which they are
needed. The proposal in this paper involves recognition of the exist-
ence of these exceptions and adoption of a method for including them
in intergovernmental deliberation.
ARGUMENT
Many barriers ar~ responsible government actions even though they
hurt trade.
U.S. foreign trade legislation and policy should contemplate con-
tinuing active collaboration with other governments in dealing with
mutual trade. This basic principle is imposed by growing economic
interdependence. It is not enough to seek agreement on the reciprocal
reduction (or even elimination) of trade barriers-and let market
forces do the rest. The very word, trade barrier, hides some of the
problem. It is "loaded" with laissez-faire assumptions regarding the
domestic economies of nations. A barrier may, as the word suggests,
be an obstacle imposed at the nation's border to prevent desirable for-
eign competition, but it may be a byproduct of the fact that a govern-
ment is involved in supporting its agriculture, rebuilding a depressed
area, defending its currency, checking an antisocial business activity,
or acting toward some other phase of its national economy in a way
that affects trade-and, therefore, other countries' interests. And
other countries may similarly maintain trade barriers that reflect their
involvement in their own economies. The effect of these various actions
on foreign trade varies considerably with changes in the domestic
problems to which they are principally directed. It is not useful to
attack these measures as "barriers" to he "reduced" by reciprocal bar-
gaining. They are responsible government actions; their trade impacts
must be coordinated on the basis of mutual understanding.
MUCH US. LEGISLATION PROVIDES FOR INTERGOVERNMENTAL COLLABORA-
TION-BUT THE TEA THRUST IS TO LET MARKET FORCES DETERMINE TRADE
Some U.S. legislation relevant to foreign trade provides for coordi-
nation of action with other governments. Some awareness of the need
for such coordination can even be read into parts of the Trade Expan-
sion Act of 1962 (TEA), although the thrust of that act is to get rid of
government action affecting trade on the hypothesis that this will
cause U.S. exports to expand `and will thus stimulate the TI. S. econ-
omy. The Congress was, of course, aware that much intergovernmen-
tal coordination of trade intervention was already going on in the
trade program and in other programs affecting trade. The language of
the act is broad enough not to prevent such coordination and, in fact,
multilateral agreement is specifically contemplated in some cases. Other
legislation, designed for particularly difficult trade problems, contem-
plates even more specifically that there is to be policy coordination.
Thus, the legislation authorizing participation in certain international
commodity agreements provides for continuous coordination-with in-
ternational councils and secretariats to institutionalize it. The famous
Public Law 480, for providing surplus food to less developed countrics
PAGENO="0077"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 69
on special terms, contemplates various steps for coordination `of policy
both with the recipient countries and with other countries exporting
`the kinds `of commodities involved. Section 204 of the Agricultural Act
of 1956 contemplates that the export controls and import controls of
foreign countries and the United States, respectively, shall be coordi-
nated to carry out an intergovernmental agreement; the present long-
term cotton textile arrangement was concluded under this authority as
amended. But when it comes to basic trade policy as such, legislation
and announced program alike largely ignore the need `for collabora-
tion. T'hey look the other way. They count on the freeing of world
market forces to achieve U.S. trade objectives.
THE UNGOVERNED MARKET PLACE CANNOT DO ALL OF THE JOB
But the free flow of trade among national economies can do only
part of the job. Alone, it is not adequate, in the modern industrial
world, for pursuing even the economic objective of maximizing the
community's total income by allocating productive resources to the
most efficient use. The're would also have to be enough free competition
within the several national economies to bring about a strong tendency
toward general economic equibrium. Such equilibrating domestic
competition is part of the model from which economists reasoned out
the neoclassical theory of international trade, including the doctrine
of comparative advantage which is so frequently mentioned as a guide
in the conduct of United State's trade policy. `The theory has advanced
greatly in sophistication over the years, but the main policy conclu-
sions drawn from it have not yet been demonstrated to be valid except
for a relatively simple, static model where competition free of govern-
ment intervention does the economic determining within the individual
countries.
The theory conveyed highly relevant and practical insight for mem-
bers of the vigorous, competitive commercial-financial community of
early 19th-century England with its small, technologically relatively
simple industries, its mercantilist-protectionist foreign trade barriers,
and its unchallenged economic nationalism. The theory again gave
valuable insight for the industrial world in the throwback of the inter-
war depression with disintegration of internal economic organization
and suicidal, isolationist trade intervention by every government. At
that time, the genius of the trade agreements program-for the re-
ciprocal reduction of trade barriers-lay in its blending of this theory-
of-international-trade approach with an international peace objective.
As a result, many leaders of opinion came to associate the freeing of
trade with emergence from the traumatic experience of the depres-
sion; this association, taken together with the traditional success of
free trade during the rise of Victorian England to wealth and power,
has surrounded free-trade theory with an aura of proven validity and
even, for some, of moral imperative.
Meanwhile, the economic world has changed and the theory has
become archaic. The model whose main elements were selected for rele-
vance to the intuitively perceived need of early 19th-century England
yields many conclusions and insights that are irrelevant and backward
looking in today's industrial world.
PAGENO="0078"
70 ISSTJES AND OBJECTIVES OF u.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
AN INTEGRATING PRODUCTION PROCESS
WITHIN EACH COUNTRY THERE IS A DYNAMIC COMPETITIVE PROCESS-
A MIXED ECONOMY-IN WHICH INTERVENTION IS A NECESSARY PART
Competition within `t modem mndustiial coui try vhiie a di lying
force, does not do all aspects of the job it is traditionally supposed to;
it is not relied on as a general equilibrating mechanism for the na-
tional economy as a whole. It is supplemented by direct government
action in many sectors of the market economy such as those deter-
mining farm prices, oligopoly prices, investment, savings and wages.
The theory of international trade has not found a way to live with
this fact.
However, effective competition persists in the form that John Mau-
rice Ch'i ~ descubes a~ a dynarn'c pi3cess Soiv'ething l~ a it piei ails
i~ ithin iuiOsf of the private o~~nei chip industrial coi n~i es It n~y
peih~ps be thought of `ts the enoilomic ~spect of t1ie ~ ~ of living
together being evolved through uhe centuries by our expanding society
There is freedom for initiative and innovation. There is a tendency
to try to better, or to join, one's competitors. Individuals operating in
groups often have an advantage, and most advances in technology
seem to increase this advantage and to make the optimum group size
larger. However, limits are imposed on excessive economic power-seek-
lug in conformity with basic social and moral concepts-e.g., busi-
ness methods must be socially acceptable, they must not unduly restrict
community progress and the benefit pattern must not outrage egalitar-
ian ideals. As necessary, government intervenes in response to political
pressures-Some (often secret) from special interests-some from in-
formed public opinion.
The economic process comes to be carried on by a dynamic combina-
tion of heterogeneous units-individuals, firms, associations, combina-
tions, public corporations, labor unions, community action groups,
clubs, societies, and all the complex and conflicting units of govern-
ment. All of these, in a sense, compete for the custom and support of
the paying and voting public. Any of them may influence the market
or check and balance the influence of the others. The sum of all this-
and more-is the dynamic mixed economy.1
It has been a dramatically successful combination thus far. How-
ever, eternal vigilance seems necessary to keep it in dynamic balance.
It must grow and change to meet its challenges. Not the least difficult
of those challenges come from economic relations among the different
mixed-economy countries.
THESE COUNTRIES ARE INTERDEPENDENT PARTS OF A~ WORLD ECONOMIC
MECHANISM
The major economic forces in these dynamically growing national
mixed economies are not prevented by trade barriers from crossing
1 This is not to detract from the significance of the frequent contention in trade dis-
cussions that the United States is a great "free-trade area" and that this has been cart of
the secret of its economic growth. However, a free-trade area n~eans an area throughout
m~h the ( cc co aicots in g ogi ip ic ines `icios which th~ movement 01 goo is
oh t n T i ~ci rn in-c -ilso c r othei lm'llicatiors e g tics the gos ci n nec or the
entcre area 15 to some degree centralized and that there is a common currency. However,
it can not meaningfully imply the assumption that there is no government interference
with tice operation of market forceeon trade within the area.
PAGENO="0079"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 71
national boundaries (although their interplay is affected and the
growth of the world economy may be slowed). Not only is there a
good deal of trade but also a movement of production methods, distri-
bution systems, skills, capital, and all of the things and ideas that
each economy develops tO enrich the consumption pattern of its people.
The various national economies, particularly in the industrial coun-
tries, have become inextricably intertwined; they are parts of a single,
production-consumption process. One national part of the whole can-
not be governed without regard to what is done in governing the other
national parts. Moreover, the mechanism is growing dynamically, so
that a national gain contrived by the government of one of the coun-
tries at the expense of others tends to be short lived; the adverse
repercussions on the overall growth can more than wipe out the gains.
In this mechanism, what we call internatiOnal trade is not a natural
component entity. It is an arbitrary aggregate. The figures for total
exports and imports represent a sort of partial "clearinghouse record"
with significance only for national payments accounts; beyond that,
they suffer from all of the whimsy and heterogeneity that characterize
any system of accounts drawn on an arbitrary basis of ownership or
location. Focusing of attention on them can become a distraction that
inhibits rational analysis and policy. The dimensions of trade are not
established primarily at the national boundaries where trade is per-
ceived. They are established within worldwide product economies-
wheat, steel, chemicals, etc.-and their worldwide subeconomies, whose
interrelationships are determined in the complicated arrangements of
the mixed economy. Therefore, to understand the effects of govern-
ment action, one must examine the whole product economy of which
a trade flow is a part. Where intervention is required, it cannot be
carried out efficiently by one government without the cooperation of
others having jurisdiction over related parts of the product economy.
This last point epitomizes the interdependence problem as it is often
seen in practice from the perspective of our present U.S. foreign trade
posture. If our Government actions affecting foreign trade are to
achieve their public purposes, other governments must be persuaded
to reinforce, and not counter, them. If we are to raise our domestic
cotton prices, holding down the level of our production in an effort
to give our farmers acceptable incomes (when technological ferment
would otherwise impoverish them in the free market), other govern-
ments must also limit cotton production and certainly must not en-
courage its expansion. If we set certain health or quality standards
for a perishable product, other governments must not let lower grade
products spoil the market. If we give surplus wheat to an exchange-
short government for its poor people, that government must not let
the wheat be used in place of our normal commercial exports. If we
raise tariffs against imports or subsidize our exports to compensate for
costs we consider special to us, foreign governments must not pay
subsidies to offset our action. If we limit the rate of expansion of a
certain import trade in order to avoid market disruption, foreign
governments must help by limiting their exports. How are we to
persuade. them to cooperate adequately in these efforts, inconsistent
with our declared trade policy, to use the power of government to
serve our idea of the public interest?
PAGENO="0080"
72 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
ELEMENTS OF A WORLD MIXED-ECONOMY STRUCTURE ARE IMPROVISED TO
MEET THE NEEDS OF THE MECHANISM
But there is another way of looking at it-a larger one-which can
serve as a better intuitive guide in serving our national purposes. The
growth and integration of the world's production mechanism is mak-
ing an economic community of its beneficiaries. They have a common
interest in the dynamic operation of the world mechanism, whatever
their country.
Now, as has been pointed out, the social-political structure evolved
for operating such a production mechanism within an industrial coun-
try is the mixed economy; it is an underlying free market system con-
strained by a variety of individual and organizational forms of
"intervention," of which government action is probably the most im-
portant component, to operate within the bounds of the public interest
of the national community. A modern production system, when asso-
ciated with this kind of a social-political structure, comes to give to a
greater and greater proportion of the people of the community sub-
stantial economic benefit in the form of increased income and welfare;
moreover, the more the system extends benefits to new groups of par-
ticipants, the more it increases those of the old.
A comparable structure is needed for the evolving world industrial
community; there, too, such a mixed economy offers promise of trans-
cending national bickering and beggaring over undesirable alterna-
tives. It should express in action the essential unity of economic
interest among the different countries just as the mixed-economy struc-
ture within, a country reflects in action the essential unity of interest
of labor and management, farm and city, rich and poor.2
The need for such a structure is slowly, unevenly, but increasingly
being met. Not only is cooperation developing among firms such as
shipowners, traders, and underwriters, whose operations are naturally
international, but more and more originally domestic firms are extend-
ing their operations over a number of countries. Ties and affiliations
are being developed among labor unions, trade associations, chambers
of coimnerce, and all sorts of groups whose roles in the national econo-
mies must be played in the larger economic community too.
In a world of sovereign democratic nation-states, however, operating
across national boundaries creates difficulty beyond the obvious tech-
nical and physical problems There is public distrust of the untried,
the unfamiliar, the foreign. Many individuals and groups oppose a
wider area of both competition and cooperation. They may fear it will
imperil the balance achieved, not without difficulty, on the more
limited national scale-the balance which made possible the dynamic
national mixed economy. There is more than the usual difficulty `of
`reaching agreement as to where national interest lies.
`The difficulty is greatest where cooperation among governments is
concerned. `Their electorates are accustomed to look to them more for~
national unity in an emergency than for steps toward the human unity
essential for economic peace and survival. Yet, governments must
improvise at least quasi-world measures to meet pressing world trade
problems if they are not to stand marked as failures. They must ana-
lyze the substance behind the conflicting drives for their intervention,
2 For the insights out of which this and related paragraphs were written, a particular
debt is due to Prof. Gunnar Myrdal. (See especially his "Beyond the Welfare State," Yale
University Press, 1960.)
PAGENO="0081"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 73.
distinguishing and acting upon only the necessary cases. They must
see and make prevail the point that the national interest is sometimes
the world interest rather than the local interest, or they will frequently
cut off bits of the national nose to spite some foreign face.
INTERGOVERNMENTAL C001IDINAD:oN
EXTENSIVE EFFORTS AT GOVERNMENT ECONOMIC COLLABORATION
Governments are responding to the imperatives of this situation
surprising well. Intergovernmental collaboration is being found, or
at least sought actively, in a number of fields affecting trade.3 There
is, of course, the general world forum for economic discussion-the
Economic and Social Council of the United Nations. But there are
also many specific arrangements, some of them providing quite active
trade-influencing collaboration.
Some of the more dramatic examples are:
(a) The International Monetary Fund's efforts to remedy the
inadequacies of the means of payment available to finance inter-
national trade;
(b) The OECD Economic Policy Committee's discussions of
the maintenance of the levels of economic activity and employment
on which expanded international trade depends;
(c) The FAO (and the world food program) efforts to bring
together those unhappy twin offspring of the technological revo-
lution-surplus in the rich countries and underconsumption in the
poor;
(d) The International Wheat Council's and other agricultural
and mineral commodity bodies' efforts to achieve adequate supply
to importers at prices fair to exporters;
(e) The UNCTAD efforts toward trade and financial coopera-
tion to speed economic development in the poorer countries;
(f) The International Labor Organization's efforts to prevent
labor exploitation as a basis of trade; and
(g) The GATT procedures dealing with intergovernmental
trade problems.
Although governments have no fully agreed rationale in the matter,
most significant government actions affecting trade are discussed in-
tergovernmentally; a few are discontinued; many are agreed to (some-
times tacitly) in modified form; some are maintained by concerted
action.
OTHER COORifiNATION DEVELOPING';' MUCH LONG ESTABLISHED IN LESS.
DRAMATIC FIELDS
In addition to established arrangements for active multilateral inter-
governmental collaboration affecting trade, there are a number of
areas where less formal consultation takes place. Examples are trans-
portation rates and subsidies and international corporations and busi-
ness combinations. Mention should also be made of the many fields in
which coordination has long proceeded without `much public debate.
3 It will be noted, however-and this reflects the conceptual problem in the foreign trade
policy field-that most of them either are fields generally considered not to be part of trade
policy or are thought of as requiring action only temporarily and exceptionally, until for-
eign trade. policy shall have succeeded sufficiently in its goal of discontinuing government
actions affecting foreign trade.
82-246-67--------6
PAGENO="0082"
74
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN `TRADE POLICY
Thus, thei~e are health andsanitary regulations (which sometimes burst
out in controversy when abuse is suspected but, for the most part, go
forward from day to day without difficulty), standardization of tech-
nical specifications oi qualities, overl'tpping taxation, patent regula
tions, postal service, telecommunications, insurance rates, traffic laws,
etc. There is a continual exchange of information and visits by officials
concerned with hundreds of fields of government activity which can
affect trade. Intergovernmental consultation and coordination is a per-
vasive fact in international trade.
A NUMBER OF IDEAL OBJECTIVES ARF SEPVED BY SUCH COORDINATION
Thus far, the argument that U.S. foreign trade policy must contem-
plate some continuing coordination of intervention in trade relations
among national mixed economies has been made largely on the basis
of the traditional economic ideal objective of. maximum efficiency-
production of the greatest possible income from available resources
It is evident, however, thatintergovernmental coordination of trade
intervention is also necessary (and undertaken)' to serve other ideal
objectives significant in prevailing U.S. opinion and relevant for trade
policy. Some of these objectives are even more important than maxi-
mum production. Thus,' under' usual circumstances in our affluent so-
ciety, minimizing intergovernmental economic conflict and maximiz-
ing individual freedom in trading are both probably held to be of
greater importance in foreign trade policy decisions th'in is maximum
productiOn. In addition, a good deal of importance as an. ideal objec-
tive is given to the maintenance of economic growth and full employ-
merit-and even to providing a certain minimum of basic food for
people (including foreigners) who are in absolute want. None of these
objectives, nor an acceptable balance `among them, can be properly
served by the Government of the United States acting alone within
its area of jurisdiction. All of them require intergovernmental coordi-
nation and, as necessary, collaboration.
BUT FOREIGN TRADE THEORY AND POLICY HAVE BEEN HOSTILE TO
COORDINATION ` `
Yet when discussion turns to foreign trade as such, U.S. policy
statements tend to revert to the old language, "disencumber trade
from government barriers," which sterns from the archaic model of
separate, laissez-faire national economies whose governments prevent
trade and do not talk to one `another on economic matters. To the ex-
tent that Cordell Hull's emphasis on the peace objective is, considered,
it is indnect or neg'itive-the maintenance of pe'~ce by not lettm~ the
governments deal with the contested trade questions. In the resultant
confusion, the officials focusing on the trade program are often pitted
~mst those working on some of the cooidiwttion progr'trns men
`tioned above. By a mysterious process that at times seems compounded
more of faith and fear than of reasoning from facts, the trade officials
take the general position that freeing trade tends toward that efficient
distribution of resources dictated by the doctrine of comparative ad-
vantage and that, therefore, acts of government affecting trade result
ipso f~tcto in `i decre~~e ifl n'i±ion'il incove In t1nat ic1eologv, thei~ is
PAGENO="0083"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 75
little logical basis for selecting among different government acts. At
various times over the past 30 years, the writer has seen this thesis
used to oppose intergovernmental action directed to such varied pur-
poses (with such varied, merit) as maintaining surplus farm product
prices above "natural" world market levels, regulating primary com-
modity trade, rehabilitating the European economies after the war,
preventing the wealthy classes in less developed countries from im-
porting luxuries, transferring food surpluses to hungry people, limit-
ing the rapidity of. trade increases under especially disrupting cir-
*curnstances, and many others. From this trade freeing point of view,
the conflict among. acts of intervention by different countries is some-
times thought of as one of the weapons for use in getting rid of the
intervention; coordination is opposed because it tends to continue
the intervention by making it intergovernment.aily acceptable.
In any case, since all intervention is considered bad intervention
"theoretically," there is no underlying ethical or moral or public
policy basis except expediency-measuring the power of the persons
`and interests exerting political pressure-for deciding which inter-
vention to tolerate. The fragmented and sometimes internally incon-
sistent pattern of current intergovernmental steps (some firm, some
~alt.ering) to impose a representative surveillance on the emerging
industrial world production mechanism is considered a generally un-
fortunate drift with the stream of history. As a result, if the various
trade affecting elements in U.S. policy at times add up to a coherent
expression of public purpose, it is more a matter of administrative
genius than the result of an announced overall policy.4
TELLING GOOD BARRIERS FROM B~
`TO BECOME PART OF A COHERENT FOREIGN ECONOMIC POLICY, TRADE POLICY
MUST DISTINGUISH INTERVENTION THAT MUST BE MAINTAINED IN THE
PUBLIC INTEREST FROM INTERVENTION REQUIRING REDUCTION
Here then is another key to change, a second major principle. For
`U.S. foreign trade policy to contemplate collaboration with other
governments in needed actions which affect trade, it must also con-
template a method of distinguishing, other than by naked power or
static economic theory, between desirable trade intervention and un-
desirable trade intervention. We have seen that the process of dynamic
competition in a modern nation requires some government interven-
tion in economic matters to assure service of the public interest. We
have seen that the economy of the industrial world is becoming a
single production mechanism, so that intervention by one government
must be coordinated with related intervention by other governments.
There are doubtless other elements to explain the hostility of trade officials toward
intergovernmental collaboration in actions affecting trade. One, for the United States at
least, is the historical nntigovernment attitude expressed in the famous line, `That govern-
meat Ic best which governs least a basic distrust of government. w~Lh its inefficiency,
Tack of imagination, and proneness to corruption, becomes a supporting argument for
laissez-faire even in cases where it may not serve social purposes. Anotimer element may be
the separation of powers ; the laying of duties and regulating of commerce is a c~ngres-
sional power under the U.S. Constitution while the conduct of foreign relationc is an execu-
tive one. The consequent cumbersomeness of onr own Government may suotly slant our
thmnkmrg ~ns a~ f cm the seened coorden ion (1 s a tim o i oc c i Ii
conmiection. it is Interesting to watch the consequences of the ~eveiopment even greeter
cunibersomeuess of the same general kind in the new- e~:onomic qunsi-acc-erning unit, the
I F~ 11 ( tebl 1 cC o c's r the m tes 1 `s~'i x ti c `~ ti ci ucn
ems the United States.
PAGENO="0084"
76 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
We have seen that this proposition is given de facto recognition ~fl
much of our foreign economic policy but that our foreign trade pro-
gram and legislation are basically inconsistent with it; they treat all
intervention affecting trade as being, in the last analysis, contrary
to the public interest because it interferes with the results of competi-
tion in the marketplace. If we are to have a coherent foreign economic'
policy, this public posture must be changed. U.S. foreign trade policy
must explicitly embrace the understanding that, in international as in
domestic affairs, government does not abridge dynamic competition,.
but preserves it by making it socially acceptable, when it intervenes
in the marketplace to the extent required by a public interest which
would not otherwise be served adequately.
HOW TO DISTINGUISH INTERVENTION IN THE PUBLIC INTEREST FROM
OTHER INTERVENTION
But how is one to determine in practice which trade intervention~
is in the public interest? Within the national mixed economy, govern-
ment does this job with the aid of the complicated representative'
structure already mentioned. Individuals, firms and the other entities
of the mixed economy carry on their economic functions and exercise
their economic strength in the marketplace and, when they do not
accept the resulting "arbitraments," express their objections and try'
to get government to help them or stop helping others against them.
If government decides to intervene, its act becomes the expression
of the public interest at that moment of decision. But the process is
dynamic. Continual challenge and reconsideration are necessary to
keep government action responsive to public interest as it changes
with changes in the economic environment. This is the democratic'
process. Extending it to the international level-to serve the larger
community created by the world industrial production mechanism--
is, in a sense, our fundamental foreign trade policy problem.
ONE CANNOT DISTINGUISH BY CATEGORIES
An effort to preserve at least part of the automatic character of'
the intervention-withdrawal policy, by getting intergovernmental
agreement on the acceptability or unacceptability of different cate-
gories of trade affecting action, has. not worked. A government can
bring about a particular trade effect through different categories of
intervention. Such things a.s public purchase and sale, taxation, sub-
sidy, tariffs, interest rates, government-controlled freight rates,.
patriotic exhortation, fiat, and the like, can often be used either alter-
natively or in combination with one another. This is widely recognized
and is evidenced by the many kinds of government action complained
of as trade damaging in GATT discussions; no government can con-
tract and "pay" for the reduction of a particular trade barrier by
another government unless it is assured against possible substitute
actions by the barrier reducing government. In discussions of prin-
ciple centered around the GATT, certain categories (e.g., quotas) have-
been censured at one time or a.nother as being particularly difficult.
to discontinue when not needed (and, therefore, opposed to the public
interest in trade barrier reduetloll) other c~tt@gol1i@~ (e.g., c8rtarn
kinds of subsidies), have been branded as particularly susceptible of
PAGENO="0085"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 77
abuse on behalf of special interests. Still others (e.g., direct payments
to producers) have been recommended as being easily susceptible of
public surveillance. Most judgments as to the merits of alternative
categories of action have been found to have numerous exceptions,
and some of the judgments have been at least tacitly reversed. A more
relevant kind of distinction among categories is based on adverse
"side effects"-consequences not sought by the government acting.
Thus, trade barriers incident to agricultural income supports are
judged partly according to whether they discourage consumption by
raising market prices. These and other similar considerations can be
valuable in reaching intergovernmental agreement on the appropriate
kind of intervention for a purpose considered necessary in the public
interest, but they offer no guide to a satisfactory formula or auto-
matic technique for deciding whether or not a given act of trade
*intervention is in the public interest. There probably is no such tech-
nique to be found. Extending the economic governing process inter-
nationally must be done by people who govern-not by rule and
doctrine.
GROPING FOR CATEGORIES, GOVERNMENTS HAVE FOUND THE ELEMENTS OF
A MECHANISM FOR DISTINGUISHING
However, whether or not the motive was escape, the effort to namQ
good and bad categories made a very constructive contribution. It
pioneered ways of working together toward agreement on specific
trade affecting actions which had to be maintained. Thus, discussing
whether particular quotas were bad per so led to discussion of their
purpose, how small they had to be, and whether other measures might
substitute for them eventually. From the traditional viewpoint of our
:announced trade barrier reduction policy, these actions are referred
to as "exceptions" and are generally deplored. It is sometimes said
that the GATT rules (meaning the formal rule's of the GAT'T text
`into which we wrote our long-run free trade principles-and aspira-
`tions) have so many exceptions that they are practically meaningless.
There shall be no quotas, except; export subsidies must be avoided,
except; there shall be no preferences, except; etc. There are exceptions
for the protectionist use of internal taxes and regulations, for dis-
crimination in applying quotas, and for all sorts of other proscribed
categories of action. Then there are certain general exceptions to all
rules-a whole list of them in a separate GATT article. And then
there is provision for waiving any obligation of the GATT "in
exceptional circumstances not elsewhere provided for." It is true that
almost all of the exceptions provisions have some temporary, `self-
terminating quality written into them; the idea was thus to force
gradual change so that, in the end, there would be no need to use the
exceptions. But, on the whole, it has not worked out that way. In
fact, there is little protest nowadays when an official says, whether in
disgust or in an effort to persuade, "You can do anything you want
to under the G-ATT!" But, with equal validity (a.nd perhaps more
significance for the future) one can say the opposite-"You can't
get away with `anything important without its coming up in the
G-ATT !" Most of the exceptions are made on condition that the
governments acting under them report what they do and why. More-
over, there is a general requirement that governments shall consult
PAGENO="0086"
78 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
with a government which challenges their actions as being against
its trade interest. There are many such challenges and even more such
reports. There is an almost continuous discussion of them, not only
in the G-A'TT but also in other intergovernmental forums.
THE PUBLIC INTEREST IS ~~DEFINED~~ BY CURRENT AGREEMENT AMONG
GOVERNMENTS
In these discussions, what is sought is agreement-not adherence to
rules. The GATT exemption (from any of its rules) for actions taken
under an international commodity agreement openly arrived at has,
in practice, been extended to any action which no substantially inter-
ested government complains of. Thus, agreement satisfies the rules
even if it is no more than "negative" agreement-i.~., failure to object.
Seeking agreement, or averting complaint, sets up a wide compass of
discussion at many levels which prefigures the international extension
of the mixed-economy process. Each government, in its actions affect-
ing trade, finds itself forced to consider in some measure the public
interest as it is seen by the governments of the other mixed economies
involved, and ~ll of the interested governments togethei are con-
strained to persuade one another in the perspective of the whole dy-
namic economic process-the "bigger pie "The result is a beginnmg of
a mechanism for focusing the, expression of world public interest in
trade matters. It is proposed that such a mechanism now be consciously
employed so that its functioning can be widely understood and con-
tinuously improved. It is proposed that the intergovernmental forums
originally dedicated to the reduction of intervention be now rededicat-
ed to distinguishing between needed intervention and unneeded inter-
vention.
BARGAINING FAVORS BAD BARRIERS
INTERVENTION NOT NECESSARY IN THE PUBLIC INTEREST SHOULD BE
SCHEDULED FOR ELIMINATION
Thus far in this paper, the argument for an agreed intergovern-
mental process to make the distinction between needed and unneeded
intervention has been presented largely on the basis of the imperatives
for trade intervention that (even when yielded to) are not formally
accepted as part of ourtrade policy. We have seen that unilateral gov-
ernment responses to those imperatives must he coordinated if they are
to accomplish their objectives. Let us now' turn to the other side of the
coin-intervention which is avoidable because it is not needed in the
public interest. This includes the barriers most commonly in mind
when discussing present trade policy. It is almost tautological at this
point to state as our third principle that such barriers should be dis-
continued-i.e., not reduced but eliminated.5 This can be accomplished
more effectively through a nonadversary `intergovernmental examina-
tion of the barriers than by bargaining.
It will be recognized that a reduced barrier-whether a very low tariff, a large quota
under which licenses to import are granted freely to all applicants, or other measure
modified so as to approach freedom of trade-Is substantially more restrictive than no
barrier at all. The administrative processes involved and the psychological situation faced
by the trader are themselves barriers.
PAGENO="0087"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 79
THE HISTORIC MERITS OF BARGAINING
Let US consider the merits and weaknesses of the trade bargaining
technique-and where it is leading us.
Bargaining made possible great achievements, it was a natural
bridge across which opinion in the great trading countries moved
away from the concept of a tariff or other trade. barrier as a domestic
instrument for the expansion of the national economy or protection
from unfair foreign competition toward the concept of a reciprocal
interest in reducing barriers to trade. It institutionalized the lesson-
so disastrously learned in the fruitless national efforts of these trading
countries to protect themselves out of industrial depression-that a
unilateral act affecting trade can be completely frustrated by a foreign
counteract. it became the basis for the concept of the GATT as a con-
tract, giving each participant a sense of the value of the GATT as an
instrument for obtaining some degree of fair treatment of its export
trade from other countries as a matter of right. The bargaining tech-
nique has been the strength of the GATT and has often frustrated
efforts .to "unravel" the G-ATT. Why, then, shift emphasis to a differ-
ent process?
BARGAINING DOES NOT BRING THE PUBLIC INTEREST TO BEAR ON SPECIAL-
INTEREST QUESTIONS
In answer, let us examine some of the weaknesses of the bargaining
technique in present circumstances. The logic of the bargaining tech-
nique does not run to the public interest; therefore, bargaining is not
very effective in reducing an unneeded t.rade barrier if there is vigor-
ous protest from a domestic interest involved. The rationale of the
bargaining program is that. the barrier must be reduced for the good
of a foreign country; the foreign government will, in return, reduce
one or more of its barriers in order to try t.o help U.S. exporters. The
bargaining format dramatizes a distorted and oversimplified conflict
of interest: On the one side, domestic producers keenly conscious of
current foreign con'ipetition; on the other, a loose alliance of foreign
sellers, international traders, and domestic producers vaguely hopeful
of expanding foreign markets.
Other considerations, the consumer interest, alternative profitable
use of the domestic producing resources, expected market expansion to
offset the alleged injury, the effect of the barrier on dynamic competi-
tion and growth in the national economy, even the facts proving the
alleged danger from foreign competition tend to be neglected in the
emotions generated in the ba.rgaining conflict. In the moment of nego-
tiation decision, a government will rarely decide to risk injuring the
going concern, however undesirably protected. Due deliberation of the
general national public interest in the matter, not to mention the world
public interest, is hardly to be expected.
THE BARGAINING TECHNIQUE IS SUFFERING FROM AGE: RIGIDITIES OF BAR-
RIER MEASUREMENT, ACCOMPLISHMENT OF PART OF PURPOSE, AND RESIG-
NATION TO FAILURE FOR THE REST
This does not leave much for the bargaining technique to achieve.
Current imperatives transfer most needed intervention from the bar-
gaining process to intergovernmental discussion. Much unneeded in-
tervention is able to resist the process; that which cannot resist is
PAGENO="0088"
SO ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
usually of lesser trade importance. In this situation, the technique is be-
ginning to show the weaknesses of age.
One weakness showing up in the bargaining process is a loss of
flexibility. Many of the ploys, developed by negotiators trying to per-
suade or otherwise overcome their opposite numbers from other gov-
ernments, have become formalized over the years and thereby given
the status of limiting concepts and even principles. Thus, the idea of
reciprocity in negotiations was originally a general one. In the first
G-ATT negotiations in 1947, each country was to lower all of the ob-
structions to each other country's trade that it could, using as a guide
regarding nontariff barriers the rules of good trade conduct in what
then became the general provisions of the GATT. Our negotiating
arguments ran primarily to whether all participants had satisfied that
requirement on a reciprocal basis-had shown fairness to one another
in judging what they could and could not do. To that end, the prob-
able effects of individual concessions were debated in as realistic a
way as possible, However, in the efforts at persuasion, there came to
be brought in various aggregative measures by which to compare
tcriff concessions: The average percentage reduction of tariffs offered,
the amounts of trade in a base year covered by the offers, the weighted
average percentages of reduction, and so forth. Eventually there de-
vedoped a sort of pseudomathematical game in which reciprocity came
to mean a balance between figures representing the offers made by the
two countries in a negotiation; much negotiating effort went into dis-
putes as to which figures were meaningful; the arguments became
public and there was resort to new terms (~cr~tement, disparity, etc.)
with abstruse statistical meanings but little if any known meaning
in terms of the probable effects of concessions. These developments
tended to limit the effectiveness of the bargaining technique in reduc-
ing barriers, since the negotiators with most to offer had to hold some
of it back in order to report that they had obtained "reciprocity."
Another weakness, to which tariff bargaining, as opposed to negotia-
tion of nontariff trade barriers, is particularly vulnerable, is loss of
power. We have seen that the process was strongest during the pros-
perous postwar years when the excesses of the war and depression
could be bargained away. Now, however, the tariffs that we are able
to lower, have been taken down to relatively low levels. When the
Kennedy Round reductions take effect, most of these tariffs will have
been reduced by a total of over 85 percent.
A third weakness arises from the practice of evasion. As tariffs be-
came more or less frozen by the bargains made under the program,
Government concern with foreign competition led to a search for other
methods of trade control, some of which were more effective than
tariffs. These nontariff barriers, of ever-increasing variety, are clif-
ficult to tre~i.t in a bargaining process directed to firm agreement to
reduce specified trade barriers. They are often directed to some domes-
tic intervention purpose with which they vary, regardless of the effect
on trade. Agreements to reduce them or bind them, though they can
be formulated and sometimes are made, tend to become unstuck.
A final weakness in this list is the tendency to he resigned to nernia.-
nent compromise on the objective of getting rid of trade harriers en-
tirely. Perhaps it is partly a result of the mathematical-balancing
game. There comes to be a measure of agreement, a~ a byproduct of
PAGENO="0089"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 81
the bargaining process, that a certain level of tariff-perhaps about
5 percent-is "reasonable" and even desirable. A certain amount of
"fairness" comes to be attributed to the increase of tariffs which are
below that level.
THE ACROSS-THE-BOARD APPROACH CALLED ATTENTION TO THE PROBLEM
BUT DID LITTLE TOWARD REMEDYING IT
The "across-the-board" or "linear" approach was put* forward by
the U.S. Government in an effort to get around some of these weak-
nesses. It was apparently inspired, on the constructive side, by analogy
with the European Common Market which was planning to eliminate,
or coordinate, all of its internal trade barriers-reducing tariffs to
zero by a series of across-the-board percentage cuts and "harmonizing"
other actions affecting trade. This dramatized for the public the weak-
nesses we have been discussing. But for those who saw the need of
specific types of intervention, whether for the public interest or for
themselves, it created a strong desire to keep those specific "barriers"
from the negotiating process. It gradually became evident that the
across-the-board approach was not applicable among governments not
otherwise integrating their economic governance. The public-not to
mention the negotiators-had difficulty understanding what across-
the-board could mean for quotas, price supports and various other non-
tariff trade barriers.
It is reported that the approach resulted in much deeper and more
extensive tariff reductions in the Kennedy Round than would otherwise
have obtained because there was a presumption for reduction of each
tariff.
However, even for tariff barriers, the use of the bargaining technique
as the vehicle of negotiation meant that, after across-the-board offers
and their exceptions, adjustments had to be made so that the final bar-
gains were reciprocally equitable. The principal virtue of across the
board was then gone.
THE BARGAINING FORMAT IS PROTECTIONIST
The bargaining format, in its basic concept and operation, is eco-
nomic nationalist and protectionist-that is, barrier raising. Bargain-
ing governments, in order to sell reduction of their trade barriers
dearly, must argue that all of them are in their own national public'
interest and are harmful to foreign countries. Thus public support is
enlisted-as, in the United States, for "shrewd Yankee trading" by
the negotiators. There is little said of barrier reduction to benefit all
countries. The harm being done to one's exports by foreign countries is
bitterly exaggerated. To the extent that the merits are discussed, every-
thing possible is done to emphasize the static, short-term validity of
the protectionist case. Buying from foreigners is treated as a sub-
stitute for producing at home. Trade barriers are thought to "beggar
thy neighbor"-thus increasing national product.
The original concept of a high-trade area to be created through re-
ducing barriers reciprocally has been transformed by the bargaining
process into one where each government tries to use its bargaining
power to beggar without being beggared.
PAGENO="0090"
82 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
The bargaining process has come to embody the worst of both
worlds. It is negative toward the idea that a particular trade inter-
vention might be necessary in order that the market process may best
serve the public interest, but it accepts with little question the necessity
for increasing a particular barrier (regardless of the domestic public
interest) in order to hurt a foreign country which will not reduce one
of its barriers to which we object. If the Kennedy Round had difficult
going from time to time, criticism of supposedly wrong action by this
or that government or official usually missed the point. The whole pub-
lic posture of the negotiations was one of protectionism.
GOVERNMENTS REMAIN "POISED" TO REINTERVENE
It is not surprising, therefore, that one result of the bargaining
process is a good deal of direct discouragement of trade expansion.
There is a public fear that reducing a barrier will hurt. Thus, the es-
cape clause of U.S. legislation and article XIX of the GATT provide
for restoring a barrier if it results in increased imports which hurt.
The great new adjustment assistance approach has not yet altered this
basic problem. The government is considered responsible for increases
in foreign competition caused by technological or other change. Gov-
ernments seem to remain poised to pounce with additional restrictions
of one sort or another whenever a trade item shows signs of expanding
substantially. This not only keeps down expansion in items regularly
traded but also discourages the expansion of trade where special effort
is required-as for products of relatively small producers without
elaborate marketing organizations and not able to afford campaigns
to open foreign markets. Trade under a reduced barrier is thus not
freer at all. It may be less costly, but the barrier to expansion usually
remains. In fact, in the discussion of injury from trade-barrier con-
cessions, it is almost as though governments felt that the reduction of
a duty was in itself the concession and that the expansion of the trade
was something of an abuse.
IN THE TRADE EXPANSION ACT, CONGRESS CONTEMPLATED ELIMINATION OF
SOME TARIFFS
All in all, therefore, the bargaining technique is a poor instrument
for further progress toward eliminating unnecessary trade barriers.
To use it for baruers other t1v~n tariffs, meanings must be so twisted
that the process comes into public ideological conflict with itself. If,
as here proposed, there were a shift to the technique of identifying
barriers (or portions of barriers) which were not needed in the public
interest, and then eliminating them-not as a matter of bargaining
away imagined advantages but through jointly and publicly applying
criteria, rules, and principles to get rid of what is disadvantageous, it
is to be anticipated that the adversary attitudes of the protectionist
barga.ining process might recede and there would be set up an attitude
tolerant of dynamic competition and trade expansion.
It seems, significant that, in the Trade Expansion Act of 1962, the
Congress expressed its intention to proceed toward the elimination of
a mimber of tauffs-those on m~nuf'~ctured producLs wheie there is
PAGENO="0091"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 83
Ilittle competition from low-wage areas, those already below the 5
percent level, and a few less important classes. As it has worked out,
the oniy one with some potential importance is section 202 permitting
complete elimination of any tariff which is now assessed at a level less
than 5 percent of the value of the imports. The provision (section 211)
for eliminating duties on industrial-country manufactured products
was largely tied to United Kingdom admission to the European Eco-
nomic Community (which has not come about) so that it had little
applicability in the Kennedy Round. Some members of Congress
wanted to remove the tie to the EEC, but the Government showed an
interest in its retention. The provisions (sections 212 and 213) for
eliminating the duties on certain agricultural and forestry commodi-
ties, also tied to United Kingdom-EEC merger, are written in such
guarded terms that they apply to only a small and unimportant
amount of trade. The congressional intention in these various provi-
sions was presumably to offer advantages to foreign countries in order
to obtain reciprocal advantages in the bargaining; but the nature of
the selection of items is such as to indicate that there was also the
purpose of eliminating (instead of reducing) those tariffs which, for
one reason or another, are no longer considered entirely necessary for
our own purposes.
FRUSTRATION OF THAT INTENTION SHOULD NOT BE BLAMED ON THE EEC
There is a widespread current view that the tariff-eliminating
purpose of the legislation was largely frustrated by the failure of the
EEC to take in the EFTA countries, particularly the United King-
dom. That view is difficult to justify. It overlooks the formidable
opposition to such elimination in the European countries. One could
argue the opposite: That the inclusion of the United Kingdom in the
EEC would have increased the value of external protection as an aid
in integrating the enlarged economic community. Even with only six
countries to integrate, it was not possible for us to get enough conces-
sions to use the 50 percent reduction authority for many of these
industries. With more countries, could we have used 100 percent at
this time?
Sector discussions running to the nonbargaining question of what
intervention is needed, and in what form, for the major industrial
sectors of the world economy, could contribute ~reatiy to negotiations.
It is through the achievement of understanding on such broad, indus-
try-wide public questions that an intention to eliminate unneeded
tariffs could be carried out to the maximum.
WHERE INTERVENTION IS AGREED TO BE NEEDED, MEET THE NEED IN
THE MOST EFFICIENT WAY
This leads to the fourth and, in a limited sense, completing principle
for future U.S. foreign trade policy (and legislative authority).
Where trade intervention exists (or is sought) to accomplish a pur-
pose agreed to be in the public interest, the intergovernmental effort
should be directed to accomplishing that purpose most efficiently
and with a minimum of harm to other countries. We have noted
PAGENO="0092"
84 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
the interchangeability of many trade-affecting actions. Therefore,
there is room for intergovernmental discussion of the incidental trade
consequences of alternative actions which would accomplish a given
purpose. We have seen that the determinants of a given trade flow
lie in the worldwide product economy of which it is a part. Therefore,
an overview of that product economy must be part of the information
available to governments if they are to find the most effective and
least disturbing way of accomplishing a' purpose involving that
trade.
AN INTERNATIONAL TRADE-POLICY MECHANISM
`THE BASIC PRESCRIPTION (ELIMINATE BARRIERS OR COORDINATE THEM)
WOULD FACILITATE CONSISTENCY THROUGHOUT FOREIGN ECONOMIC
POLICY
Since the proposed trade policy approach does not extend the
traditional free-trade prescription to cases where it is in the~ public
interest to bear the cost of giving help to particular producers, it
can "ride tandem" relatively comfortably with many policy areas
which have come into some conflict with the present program. Since
these areas are being dealt with in other papers prepared for the
committee, I will not elaborate except to note that, in the 30 years
we have come through under the trade agreements program, we have
at various times seen the trade-freeing objective of the program pub-
licly held to be inconsistent with progress toward domestic recovery,
agricultural support, European recovery and rehabilitation, aid to
economic development, monetary stability, and other national ob-
jectives. A way through these apparent dilemmas was improvised
through pragmatic intergovernmental cooperation. The proposal in
this paper derives its inspiration from that experience.
A WAY TO START
How could the proposed approach be launched? There are many
ways. The initiative would not have to be American. Since the pro-
posal is essentially to base future intergovernmental trade cooperation
(especially among the industrial countries) on recognition of the com-
mon interest in the growth and expansion of the international indus-
trial economy, it might be put forward officially by any interested
government or by one or more of such international secretariats as the
&ATT, the TJNCTAD and the UN. And there are doubtless many
kinds of programs that would launch the approach suitably. It could
be put forward as the subject of a new general conference or as a
rationale for continuing the gradual shifting of stance and modifica-
tion of procedures in existing intergovernmental oganizations. There
could be emphasis either on the new-approach aspect, on the consolida-
tion of experience, on a combination or on some specialized `applica-
tion; But in any case, something like the proposed approach must
eventually pervade intergovernmental discussions if the industrial
powers are to live together in peace.6
This sort of approach is necessary, also, if the less-developed countries are to be brought
to a decent economic existence during the present era.. They should be partIes to the entire
process.
PAGENO="0093"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 85
SUMMARY: AN~ INTERGOVERNMENTAL FORUM ON THE EFFECTS OF TRADE-
AFFECTING ACTIONS
One approach, then, would be for governments to join in recognizing
first, that no one government can realize its full national economic
potential except through the maximum growth of the international
economy as a whole. Secondly, they would note that technological
progress-achieved or in early prospect-makes it physically possible,
given the will, to develop the world's productive resources so as to pro-
vide a decent level of living for every human being. The participating
governments would state, therefore, that this minimum production ob-
jective can be realized if there is such specialization of production and
expansion of trade as would result from permitting the several na-
tional economic processes to function as integral parts of a dynamic
international competitive process in which all individuals can benefit
and contribute. Governments would be committed to maintain (in an
appropriate multilateral forum or forums) a continuing public con-
versation regarding such of one another's present (or proposed) ac-
tions affecting international trade as have (or would have) significant
repercussions outside national jurisdictions.
Each government would be committed to limit its action to the
level (and the duration) which it publicly declared to be necessary for
the purpose of the action, and to carry out that action in the form
which it publicly decided to be least disturbing (or most helpful) to
the interests of other countries and to the international economic proc-
ess. A government might seek cooperation from other interested gov-
ernments in order to find or to carry out the particular mix of actions
that would serve an accepted public purpose in the most efficient way
with a minimum of undesirable side effects; and all governments
would be committed to give public consideration to thus cooperating
in an action affirmed after public reconsideration in an intergovern-
mental examination. Finally, governments would establish and main-
tain a special official structure, independent of the rest of the trade-
policy and trade-program structure, the sole responsibility of which
would be to assure that the facts and analyses for assessing the effects
of trade-affecting actions were fully avail able and were brought to
public attention in all the interested countries.
HOW TO SCHEDULE ACTIONS FOR EXAMINATION
There will be a question as to which actions to examine first and how
*a concerned government or individual can initiate consideration of an
action. A part of the solution might be for governments to agree to
put forward for early consideration the actions of other governments
which seem to them to have particularly important adverse effects.
But, a government-complaint procedure, while probably necessary,
would not be sufficient. Supplementary ways of bringing actions for-
ward for intergovernmental consideration might be (a) to make each
government responsible for presenting a report and analysis of the
economic effects of its own actions; (b) to give the principal officers
of the special information structure, set up to see that all relevant facts
and analyses are available, the right to suggest an action for considera-
tion; or (c) to bring some of the particularly diffi cult commodity prob-
PAGENO="0094"
86 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
lems now being wrestled with in more limited groups such as interna-
tional commodity study groups within the purview of the general
forum and its public process.
In addition, it should probably be open to a government to put for-
ward for consideration an action which it contemplates but has not
yet taken; this technique might appeal in cases where foreign govern-
ment cooperation was particularly valuable for insuring the success
of the action.
RULES AND PROCEDURES
The intergovernmental conversation would deal primarily with the
economic effects of a government action. It would cover all significant
effects-domestic and foreign, direct and indirect, concentrated and
diffused, immediate and longer term, costs and gains. It would run to
specifics. As far as possible, it would be in quantitative terms-esti-
mating or evaluating even when examining doctrinaire allegations of
effect. How much does an action change prices, costs, profits, produc-
tion, consumption? Who is affected adversely, who benefically, when,
and to what degree? What is the effect on the growth of the world
production process-on innovatiOn-on adjustment to current changes
in the economic environment,? The format of discussion of these ques-
tions would net. be one of bargaining between governments. It would
be a~ search for facts on which to base judgments. Conflicts of interest
would, of course, be involved; but a participant government would
not be called on to take a position as between a national (say, produc-
er) interest that might be helped by an action and another national
(say, transportation or consumer) interest that might be injured..
Each would he assessed separately; and, the presentation of this com-
bination of assessments-for all interests, wherever found, which are
signiflc'uitly ~ffected by the `iction-would be the entire obiect of the
examinition Dis'igreements would be reported-and ouantifieel as far
as possible they w ould relate to f'icts, not to iecommend'itions for
action-although perhaps facts about alternative possible actions
might be presented. In form, however, the process would not be of an
adversary nature. Neither would it be reciprocal except in the sense
that all countries would participate-permitting multilateral inter-
governmental exn.mination of their actions which affect trade-and
each would ioin in the discussion of the effects of the actions of the
other countries. The examination would involve no negotiating about
t.he status or appropriateness of the different acts-merely a series of
findings about the separate economic effects of each. The interrela-
tionships would be brought out as revealed through the effects.
The examination would probably take on' some of the constructive
qualities of many current nonadversary intergovernmental economic
discussions, e.g., the GATT consultations on balance-of-payment'
restrictions and development program implications, of some of the'
OECD "confrontations," and commodity study groups, and of many
other current discussions. There would, however, be two main dif-
ferences from most of these intergovernmental discussions, stemming'
from points of emphasis. In the first place, though deriving its
raison d'etre from trade, the examination would not be directly asso-
ciated with a multilaterally accepted code of trade ru1e~c or princip1e~
of fair dealing in trade matters. The only really basic principle of the
PAGENO="0095"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 87
examination would be that governments (on behalf of their own
nationals) accept responsibility for their actions, not only vis-a-vis
one another but toward the economic objectives of the community of
nation-states taken as a whole-toward realization of the abundance
of which the world production process is capable. Discussion, there-
fore, would run exclusively to the complicated real effects of those
actions. While such discussion inevitably would take into account the
area of common understanding reflected in the rules and principles
developed in the GATT, UNCTAD, FAO, UNECOSOC and other
intergovernmental bodies, the whole program would be seriously dis-
served by an intergovernmental effort to agree on a new or consoli-
dated code of rules for trade intervention before starting the examina-
tion of specific effects. The second difference of emphasis concerns
scope. The examination would be held on the basis of a world perspec-
tive and yet it would go deeply into relevant facts. It would be
accepted that one must look at all of the effects of a given action, both
closely and broadly, to judge what purposes it in fact serves. Thus, it
would be a new kind of discussion as far as formal definition is con-
cerned, though something like it frequently takes place in fact (e.g.,
in GATT panels and FAO agricultural policy groups).
ITEM-BY-ITEM CONSIDERATION ESSENTIAL
It is evident that the intergovernmental consideration of trade bar-
riers proposed in this paper would be carried out item-by-item; that
is, one traded product at a time. That method of consideration has
come under widespread public attack in the past 5 years. Therefore,
it seems useful at this point to explain that the item-by-item approach
is proposed not only because formula approaches fail but also because
of its intrinsic usefulness. There is little merit in the often repeated
cOntention that item-by-item procedures slowed earlier trade agree-
ment negotiations and limited their success. This view apparently
originated as a public position during the search for a quick, sweeping
approach after the very long (although reasonably useful) Dillon
Round of negotiations (1960-62). But the length and frustrations of
the Dillon Round can be explained without blaming the item-by-item
procedure of negotiation. In the first place. the United States had
very little to offer (a 20 percent cut of tariffs that had twice before
been subject to 50 percent cuts) ; and no offer was made at all on
sensitive items where this slight cut might have caused imports to
increase significantly. This rules out any dramatic success. In the
second place. much time went into wrangling about the meaning of a
theoretical EEC tariff which had never been in effect. Earlier nego-
tiating rounds bargained almost exclusively from tariff rates in being.
In the third place, the United States made it a condition of comple-
tion of the negotiations that some of the European countries abandon
their traditional technique of supporting farm prices through varia-
ble import charges. The negotiations were held up over this as long as
politically possible; the issue was then settled for a practically mean-
ingless "standstill" undertaking on the main products involved. In
spite of all this, the anti-item-by-item theory in 1962 became a major
public posture in which officials have since felt themselves trapped.
This i~ n~irticu1ariv unfortunate beceuse of the great value of item-
by-item discussion in trade negotiations. In the three great negotiating
PAGENO="0096"
88 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
rounds held at Geneva, Annecy and Torquay between 1947 and 1951,
at which the weighted average level of all U.S. duties was reduced by
over 50 percent, item-by-item discussions frequently served tohold the
conferences together while gOvernments were deadlocked over a few,
unusually difficult concession items. On the other side, of course, one
can argue that cutting all tariffs by the same percentage would pre-
vent protectionist selectivity; theoretically, one can pursue a protec-
tionist goal while lowering many duties and not raising any. Expressed
from the interest-conflict point of view, getting rid of trade barriers
dramatically en bloc would better focus the consumer interest and the
exporter interest in reduced protection and would make it difficult for
powerful producer interests to keep just those tariffs and other barriers
which restrain their foreign competition at the expense of the general
public. Experience suggests, however, that this interest balancing
works out relatively poorly. It is usually the most powerful interests
which find it easiest to have their protective barriers excepted from
sweeping reductions. They can best persuade officials and the public
of the logic of their particular cases for exception from a broad for-
mula. Since no two trade barriers have quantitatively identical effects
according to formula, it is only when all of the effects of government
action in each specific competitive situation are considered, item by
item, that the officials will understand and face the full implications
of a decision. For the same reason, public surveillance of trade barrier
reduction can be focused intelligently only when the specific effects of
each barrier on costs, prices, production, profits, and the like are
brought out in an open discussion process-item by item-as here pro-
posed. And the need for item-by-item consideration is becoming even
greater because general reduction formulas are applicable effectively
oniy to tariffs and certain quotas-not to most other kinds of barriers;
yet the latter are becoming very important. The dream of a policy
which can wipe out most trade intervention in sweeping strokes is not
geared to modern realities.
INSTITUTIONALIZED ACCEPTANCE OF RESPONSIBILITY IN THE TRADE FIELD
The proposed mechanism, therefore, would attack the problem by
shifting trade policy emphasis to the responsibility governments as-
sume in the specific instances when they choose to intervene-not neces-
sarily the responsibility they intend to assume but that which, because
of the real effects of their intervention, they cannot in the end evade.
Under present U.S. foreign trade policy, as represented in legislation
and program, emphasis is on the portion of the tariff or other barrier
which it is proposed to get rid of. The portion maintained (and the
present program calls for some substantial portion to be maintained
in almost every case) is presumably left to unilateral manipulation
without direct formal concern for the interests of other countries (and
often, as these things work out in the United States at least, with rather
less than enough concern for even the domestic general public interest
-as opposed to that of some special interests). Yet it is the interven-
tion maintained in force and effect which affects international trade.
Under the program here proposed, each specific act of trade inter-
vention which a government maintains would be publicly declared to
be carried out for a specified public purpose. In the consultation with
other governments and the reconsideration, discussion would inevitably
PAGENO="0097"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 89
run to facts relevant to that purpose-how to define it in trade terms,
what costs to other objectives must be incurred to satisfy it, what
measures would cost least, etc. Many elements of such a process, includ-
ing the development of criteria, working rules and a tradition of rea-
.sonab}eness, have already emerged in the GATT and in other forums.
With agreement to schedule the elimination of all intervention de-
cided not to be in the net national public interest, the process would
take on a new importance. There would be discussion of the magni-
tudes and duration of the damage to the protected interests and of the
service to the public interest. The exchange of information on this and
other relevant questions, properly conducted, would serve to narrow
differences and even to stimulate action to alleviate unnecessary dam-
age to one another's interests. The more specific the discussion, the
greater the possibility of its having such effects. Agreement would
rarely he complete, but areas of difference would fall within more and
more reasonable "tolerance points." With time and public familiarity,
the process should become increasingly effective in achieving a pattern
of trade freedom, with acceptable and rational modification where de-
sirable for the effectiveness of the world economy or other publicly
decided purposes.
Where reconsideration by one country led to decisions conditional
on actions by other countries, there would tend to emerge multilateral
discussion going beyond the examination of effects and into policy
arrangements-whether to withdraw intervention or to coordinate it.
`These discussions-essentially product discussions-would usually be
carried on in separate forums or subforums-as has already happened
for a number of primary products. But under the proposed mecha-
msm, such discussions would have to be carried on consistently with,
and responsively to, the course of discussion in the principal trade-
intervention forum: They would have to be fully public and would
have to consider and investigate full facts. Where, as in wheat and
Othergrains, the decision of governments to intervene in ways affecting
foreign trade is widespread and economically almost irrevocable, a
continuing forum for intergovernmental program agreement will be
required. However, not very many products will both be character-
ized by market inadequacy and be sufficiently basic' to be handled in
this way. For those which are so handled, there will never (or hardly
`ever) be sufficiently comprehensive agreement for these "commodity"
forums to be complete or adequate-even within their own product
`economies, to say nothing of their interrelationships with other parts
of the world economy. Therefore, even for such permanent interven-
tion cases as wheat, much of the subject matter will be dealt with in the
principal conversations, and this perspective might lead to modified
positions in the commodity discussions.
LOCUS OF THE CONVERSATIONS
The question arises as to the "locus" of the proposed intergovern-
mental conversations in relation to the many organizations and ar-
rangements for* intergovernmental trade discussion already in exist-
ence. No effort is made in this paper to give a preferred answer to
that question. But the proposed review and coordination would be
closely related to a number of fields of foreign economic policy other
~2-246---67---7
PAGENO="0098"
90 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
than trade. It would affect the areas of jurisdiction of almost all inter-
governmental economic organizations. The secretariats of a number of
them would have an important interest in its success. It might be best
to have them somehow operate jointly in servicing the proposed con-
versations. Finally, the proposal would be most constructive if par-
ticipatioñ were made universal in principle. Therefore, the forum
would have to be such as to facilitate the inclusion of any interested
country.
The actions whose effects were examined would be of all kinds. At
one extreme might be a simple trade barrier with comparatively little
to examine beyond the cost, to his compatriots and foreigners, of the
support of an inefficient producer. At the other extreme might be an
interrelated pattern of costly government subsidies and restrictions
such as that designed to govern the world's grain supply and con-
sumption. The institutional framework used should be such as to give
the various related current intergovernmental conversations (which
would presumably remain in the forums where they are now going
on-except as the examination might develop reasons for changing
them) significance in terms of representative surveillance of the
growth of a dynamic world economy. In this way, the modification of
action taken for interests narrowly conceived can be weighted toward
the general interest, even though the narrow interests inevitably are
the more acutely and urgently recognizable in the details of a particu-
lar examination.
RELATION TO PRESENT PROGRAM
The question of whether the proposed policy approach is desirable
has often been obscured by the question of "how to get there from
here"-and by doubt that it could be done. This is in part the mecha-
nism aspect of the uestion, whether governments will reduce inter-
vention if they are not given something in return. The GATT is a
contract-the end product~ of a bargain. The threat of retaliation is
the force which makes governments honor their GATT undertakings;
the protectionist values and objectives in the bargaining concept domi-
nate thinking If agieement was reached on `t new techrnoue (discuss,
reconsider and then either eliminate or coordinate) directed toward a
new value objective (the public interest conceived as being not neces-
sarily national in its extension but often, in economic matters, shared
internationally), would not the GATT fall apart ~ Would not ban iers
rise ~ It n'iust be evident that, if the rethinking of fundamentals that
led to this propos'iJ is correct, then questions of this type must be
taken as mechamcal problems to be worked out-not as arguments for
abandoning the proposal.
On a more deliberate look in a wider perspective, however, they
will be seen to reflect unjustIfied fears. The program here suggested
as one way of carrying out the proposed policy approach should have
a strengthening effect on the GATT. There would probably be no more
"rounds" as such (for which fact alone there might be much quiet
thanksgiving). However, discussions of trade intervention would not
decrease. They would be continuous and much more public. The danger
of "unraveling" the GATT might, therefore, be taken care of more
effectively than it now is Barriers would have to be justified publicly
as good in their own right-not as bargaining power to use in dealing
PAGENO="0099"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 91
with opponents. And, indeed, the present concept of a reciprocal
"balance" of concessions to be restored when a concession is impaired,
has not been very successful in restraining new or increased trade
intervention in recent years. Retaliation by "hurting" the impairing
one has become commoner, the granting of equivalent new concessions
less common. Even in the Trade Expansion Act negotiations, many
countries settled down to sweat out reciprocal "suffering" and resigned
themselves to the economic costs of this limited economic warfare in
the vague hope that it would force their trading allies to agree to an
advantageous "armistice" or trade treaty. Under the proposed ap-
proach, public intergovernmental trade discussion would not empha-
size such adversary alternatives, whether or not there was a contra-
vention of the GATT or some change in its bargained "balance."
They would emphasize the economic pros and cons particular to each
action.
The new examinations of the effects of trade intervention should
probably not-as a formal matter-replace the GATT "bargain," the
underlying obligations of which were the basis for the GATT's
strength as an institution over the years of national efforts to avoid
more thorough or formal coordination. Reciprocity broadly con-
ceived would continue. The mechanism proposed is inspired by suc-
cessful past improvisations for meeting difficulties encountered in
those efforts. If the fundamental approach catches men's imagination,
ways to effect it will be discovered-not invented-in the reports of
Geneva dinner conversations, in the qualifications of economic pro-
nouncements, and in many places and forums. The ideas in this paper,
if they should be noticed, will then be awarded that very high accolade
among officials and professors: "Correct, but not very new or
original !"
PUBLIC PROCESS FOR THE PUBLIC INTEREST
THE KEY ROLE OF INFORMATION
The fifth and final principle is that the conduct of foreign trade
policy-in its details-should be open. The policy approach proposed
in this paper requires that intergovernmental trade conversation and
the effects of trade intervention be subject to informed public surveil-
lance, at least proportional in extent and depth to the surveillance
exercised by the public over Government intervention in domestic
market processes within the United States and the other industrial
countries. The responses of governments, separately or in coordina-
tion, to the need of the world production and distribution mechanism
cannot be representative and, therefore, proportioned to the public
need, unless they are open. It is not enough to debate general principles
and doctrines, but be secretive when considering their application to
cases. There must be informed debate in advance of significant deci-
sions and there must be public scrutiny of subsequent performance.
INTERNATIONALLY, THE EXEOUTIVE HAS DISPROPORTIONATE POWER~ USED
NEGATIVELY AND SECRETLY
A major problem .of governance of the dynamic world-production-
distribution mechanism is that the governing institutions, both gov-
ernment and nongovernment, are less flexible and less representative
than those within the national dynamic competitive economies. At
PAGENO="0100"
92 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLiCY
best, the function of "government" is performed by a concert of dis-
tinct "sovereign" units, responsible to separate electorates. The "sov-
ereigns" are usually at odds over some aspects of that international
trade which evidences the economic cooperation of their electorates.
There is little or no formal institutionalized cooperation on an au-
thoritative basis. The various intergovernmental economic organiza-
tions which have been set up to pioneer ways of improving this
concert of sovereigns are limited because they must depend, or must
appear to depend, entirely on persuasion among their component
governments.
The governments, whether acting separately, in organizations, or in
direct cooperation, are "narrower" and less responsible than they are
in domestic matters. It is almost e~clusively the executive branches of
the various National Governments which participate in the interna-
tional economic governing. Hence, it is extraordinarily difficult, on the
intergovernmental plane, for any economic interests which are not
adequately weighed in executive decisions to find corrective expression
through legislative, judicial, or "commission" processes. The domi-
nance of the executive branch in these matters may be an inescapable
part of our Nation-State system and certainly it is not here proposed
to change it.
However, a trade policy proposal must take account of the fact that
the executive branches have tended to exercise in a negative sense their
power to govern the meshing of their national. economic activity in a
world industri al production mechanism. They have not reached a com-
mon ideological understanding, unless one counts their tongue-in-
cheek GATT cçmmitment to gradually cease using their power to gov-
ern in the trade field. Their concerting of. action is given timid and
apologetic publicity. The trade~barrierreduct10n ideology has been
associated in executive branches-certainlY in the TJ.S. executive-
with a certain fear and distrust of electorates. The opinion is widely
held in governments that all people are protectionist as concerns their
own interests; therefore, as we have seen in analyzing the bargaining
technique, specific trade~barrier-reduction moves are given a protec-
tionist format-and they are then carried out secretly. The great
marshalings of public support have been based on generalites like free-
dom of trade, comparative advantage, or across-the-board reductions.
When it comes to deciding on the use of the power of the executive
to affect specific trade transactions, however, the great bulk of it is
done in clOsed meetings without prior public debate or subsequent de-
tailed discussion of specific anticipated effects.7 In these circumstances,
the executive acts inadequately and often-against their expressed
purpose_protectively. They keep the electorate at arm's length, as it
were, and preserve the trade programs in principle, but do not usethe
programs very much for fear the specific effects would alienate public
support. The opportunity is not often taken to marshal public opinion
behind decisions in favor of the greater, and more public specific
interest-with compensation where justified to the lesser and more
private specific interest.
~ In escape-clause cases, where damage Is alleged to have been done to a domestic interest,
there is an expost facto discussion of effect. This will pregumably be more frequent under
*the adjustment assistance provisions of the Trade Expansion Act.
PAGENO="0101"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 93
NONGOVERNMENT ENTITIES INFLUENCING INTERNATIONAL TRADE ARE ALSO
UNBALANCED-IN FAVOR OF THE MORE POWERFUL INTERESTS
When it comes to nongovernrnent entities of the sort whose partici-
pation in domestic economic governance helps maintain dynamic com-
petition with a minimum of direct government intervention, those that
span the international economy sufficiently to exercise some trade-
governing influence tend to represent the larger and more powerful
economic interests. Smaller producers, who might be able to enter a
domestic market and get effective public support against suppression
of their competition by more powerful or locally entrenched firms, may
find it too difficult or costly to do so in international markets. Con-
sumer and civic groups do not readily discover and express interna-
tionally their common interests with their foreign counterparts in the
maintenance of market dynamism. Community organizations, unions,
and most of the many types of nongovernment entities that can par-
ticipate in domestic market governance do not easily make their influ-
ence felt on an international market scale. The reverse is true, how-
ever, for larger firms of great market power. The number of industries
with large firms operating over more than one national market is in-
creasing rapidly. Large trading organizations are embracing more and
more products. In the management phase, industrial organizations are
expanding to embrace and direct the interdependent world produc-
tion mechanism. Their contribution toward the effectiveness of that
mechanism is very great and they sometimes are channels for dy-
namism and efficiency interchanges which governments might fear to
permit. By the same sign, however, their power is increasing. The
reticence of the executive branches of government about the concerted
public use of trade-governing power gives the large private power
complexes an additional advantage, for they can use their power and
knowledge to influence the intergovernmental trade discussions which
are kept secret from the general public. Hence, the structure of non-
government entities available for participation in the governance of
trade is unbalanced when it comes to representing the full range of
public interests involved.
PUBLIC OPINION IS READY FOR INFORMATION AND WANTS CHANNELS FOR
EXPRESSION
But if the structure of government and nongovernrnent entities for
the governance of international trade among the industrial countries
may be called incomplete and badly balanced for the representation
of the public interest, what can be said of the organs of public infor-
mation and direct expression of opinion, and all the channels for hold-
ing governing powers to public accountability and a sense of social
responsibility? Only rarely does the public get the information and
timely analysis needed to discuss thoroughly the pros and cons of a
specific trade situation requiring governance. When it does, however,
a very important thing is revealed. In spite of the bargaining pos-
tures of governments and of nongovernment powers, and in spite of
that major part of the press and communications media which reports
these postures and supports one of them or another, the public remains
relatively unimpressed. As could be observed in all of the countries
PAGENO="0102"
94 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
supposed to have their interests at stake in the ridiculous "poultry
war" during early Kennedy Round maneuverings, the literate popu-
lations of the industrial countries do not approve of major govern-
ment confrontations over economic trifles-even in the name of policy
or principle. They are concerned at the sufferings of producer groups,
but they want, on the whole, to see the public interest given priority.
They have an emerging concept of a world public interest which is
reflected in their readiness for wider understanding-they seek chan-
nels of specific information and informed expression. In this respect
they are ahead of the public postures of their governments, in trade
matters at least.
SECRET TRADE DISCUSSIONS ARE INADEQUATELY INFORMED
Where the public does not know what is being considered officially,~
official considerations will be inadequate for the public interest. The
most palpable and pervasive reality observed by the writer in 30 years
of association with intergovernmental trade discussions was igno-
rance-a lack of adequate factual information to judge the economic
effects of the government actions discussed. Moreover, there was a
direct correlation with secrecy; the more completely the discussions
were kept from public knowledge, the less adequate the information
and the more suspect the facts relied upon-obtained for the most
part either from powerful parties at interest, uninformed generalists
or subordinate officials vindicating their advice or program perform-
ance. Discussants need to know, in a relevant and reliable form, the
economic and physical facts regarding the commodity involved (costs,
production problems, utility, the availability of substitutes, trade de-
tails, and so forth). Paradoxically, the problem is not primarily a
matter of fact gathering resources. `The U.S. Government has experts
covering almost every angle of information relative to trade-overall
and commodity by commodity. The GATT secretariat and those of
some. of the other intergovernmental organizations, the U.S. Tariff
Commission staff, and the hearings of the Interagency Trade Or-
ganization under the Trade Expansion Act have done notable fact-
finding and fact-correlating work relevant for judging the effects
of trade intervention in specific cases. But, while the accumulation
and publication of facts is valuable, and more may be needed, the real
problem is one of bringing facts and analysis to bear in a timely way~
as regards a specific situation. If the gamesmanship qualities of the
bargaining process or the natural secrecy of governments make the
official participants "hold their cards close to their chests," then the
analysts and statisticians-in government as well as out-cannot help
them with information necessary to discover the public interest (al-
though the more powerful interests can sometimes reach `them).
A SENIOR OFFICER FOR TRADE INFORMATION
What pr'~ctic'tl step can be taI~en to remedy some of the imperfec
tions of communication and information exchange within the existing
system of governing trade-with its concert of overpowerful but un
certain nationil executives, its self confident international private
powei complexes, and its tradition of secret negotiations inhibiting
PAGENO="0103"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF TJ.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 95
the focusing of public knowledge and reason on trade-intervention de-
cisions? What seems to be needed is an independent agent, as nearly
omniscient as possible, with responsibility and authority for maintain-
ing constant pressure on those involved in the governance of inter-
national trade to reveal their actions and show publicly that they have
considered all facts bearing on the public interest in the effects of their
decisions. He needs to have authority to obtain all relevant facts and
to disclose them. He would have no right to guide policy but would
give the public-individually and collectively-a substantial measure
of insurance against hidden maladministration and malfeasance. It
is proposed, therefore, that each country joining in the continuing re-
view of trade intervention appoint an officer for trade information
with the power and status necessary to carry out this function.
In addition, there should be an adequate statistics staff, and a fact-
finding body on trade barriers. On the international level, there should
be a committee of the national officers for trade information, with an
independent secretariat, to carry out the information and public con-
sideration function vis-a-vis the intergovernmental conversations and
collaboration proposed here. They should have the right to receive
reports and complaints from individual traders as well as from gov-
ernments. This arrangement would be an invaluable adjunct to the
search for intergovernmental understanding in trade intervention
matters. Without changing any powers or relationships, these officers
should force emphasis on openness, trust, and reliance on reasoning
where the present arrangements militate toward secrecy, maneuver,
and resort to bargaining power.
ECONOMIC UNITY AND POLITICAL FRAGMENTATION
THE ETHIC OF ECONOMIC AGREEMENT
Much of the international structure for the governance of trade
sketched in this paper is evolving rapidly. Although it does not rec-
ommend itself to trade-policy ideas based on assumptions of a separate
national economy and a separate national public opinion, it has been
evolving through (and, therefore, consistently with) existing political
forms and power structures. It expresses the emerging realization that
nations (especially industrial nations), while remaining formally in-
dependent, are economically interdependent; their governments can-
not afford either the national loss caused by withholding cooperation
in such surveillance as is required by the common international econ-
omy or the strain on political harmony and coexistence caused by try-
ing to dominate that economy at the expense of one another's interests.
Of course, on the international level, each government must remain,
as far as its own acts are concerned, the final judge of the interest of
its own public-its electorate. Hence, there probably would be little
point at this time in seeking further formal agreement on a definition
of the general concept of international public interest in trade mat-
ters. Criteria enough have been elaborated and given intergovern-
mental status in GATT, FAO, TJNCTAIJ, ECOSOC and elsewhere.
Perhaps a restatement of some sort would have to emerge, in connec-
tion with the proposed forum for the examination of acts of interven-
tion in relation to their declared public purposes, but the practical way
to move forward with the proposal is through the intergovernmental
PAGENO="0104"
96 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
consideration of specific actions, guided by fairly general value
premises (peace, efficiency, growth, employment, egalitarianism, etc.),
but guided also by the force of public debate with full disclosure re-
quired. While each government must retain the right to interpret any
agreement (or lack of agreement) as regards its own acts of trade
intervention, this interpretation must be informed by an understand-
ing of the common economic interest. This is an inescapable considera-
tion. Trade conflicts can intensify political bitterness; agreement on.
their solution among governments determined not to escalate the con-
flicts can have the opposite effect.
The fact of common tenure of the industrial economy is making
imperative among nations, and more and more recognized, a point of
view which is the nucleus of an ethic; it might be called the ethic of
economic agreement. Stated simply, it is that intergovernrnent eco-
nomic discussions must, for the common good, be persisted in to the
point of agreement. The hope of the future seems to lie in coordinating
economic activities of governments by agreement-without resorting
to arbitrary political pressure.
The word agreement need not mean a signed and delivered doc-
ument. It can be as little as that negative kind of agreement where
each keeps the others fully informed of its unilateral acts and the
discussion of differences continues in an atmosphere of reciprocal
efforts at persuasion. This is implicit in a society of human beings
sharing a common living space and a common source of wealth.
Perhaps the greatest contribution that the acknowledgment of this
ethic can make, however, is to reinforce the processes by which the
greater and greater unity which characterizes economic reality is'
brought to bear `against political fragmentation.
PAGENO="0105"
Section III
TRADE AND THE ADJUSTMENT PROCESS
97
PAGENO="0106"
PAGENO="0107"
FOREIGN TRADE POLICY IN THE FRAMEWORK OF THE
BALANCE OF INTERNATIONAL PAYMENTS
BY HOWARD S. PIQtm~T*
Expert opinion in the area of international finance ranges from those
who believe there will be an international calamity if the United
States fails to bring its international accounts promptly into balances
all the way to those who think that continuing deficits are a normal
characteristic of the international accounts of a country that has been
selected by other countries to serve as their central banker, and who
have been using its currency for a long time for both monetary re-
serves and to carry on trade.
Notwithstanding this wide iange of opinion, there is general agree
ment that it would be desn able foi the United States to bring its
accounts into closer balance It is agreed, furthermore, that by "bal
ance" is meant, not the achieving of temporary equality between the
inflow and outflow of funds through such restrictive means as curtail
ing merchandise imports and capital exports, but the attaining of
self sustaining equilibrium There is general consensus thaL equilib
rium will be the more likely to prevail `ts countries become willing
to allow their economies to adjust to each other
The effectiveness of capital movements, as an equilibi ating force,
in response to changes in 1 ates of interest, is generally recognized
Wh%t is not `dways recognized is the importance of the free move
ment of goods and services as an instrument for maintaining equthb
rium Although the movement of goods and services is not as sensitive
a force as international short term capital movements, the magrntude
of international trade is much greater than the magnitude of capital
movements and, if not intei fered with by governments, can be a potent
force for adjustment
Merchandise trade is the largest single item in the intei~ational
accounts Although the borrowing and lending of funds and pay
ments for such services as shipping and insurailce are also important,
their magnitude is dwarfed by merchandise exports `tnd imports With
respect to the United States, merchandise exports acOount for close
to three-fourths of all receipts from abroad, while merchandise im-
ports account for more than half of its payments abroad-i eceipts and
payments being on both government and private account.
The United States has had deficits in its international accounts every
year, with only one exception, since 1950. Unlike Western Europe
after World War II and unlike the situatiOn prevaling in the less-
developed countries today, the United States has ample productive
capacity to make up the difference between its expenditures abroad
and its receipts from foreigners. It is: obvious from the magnitudes
.*Senior specialist in international economics, Legislative Reference Service of the Library
of Congress The views expressed herein do not necessarily represent the views of the
Library. ~
99
PAGENO="0108"
100 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
involved (a GNP of over $750 billion, compared with balance-of-
payments deficits of between $1 and $4 billion a year) that the diffi-
culty does not arise from economic weakness. It is, rather, evidence
of inability, or lack of willingness, of countries to allow their econo-
mies to adjust to each other through the free flow of capital and
merchandise trade.
Ordinarily, a country having persistent deficits in its international
accounts must either increase its international receipts, relative to its
payments, or allow the foreign exchange value of its currency to de-
cline. Prior to World War I there was an international monetary
mechanism that kept the values of national currencies in line with
each other, namely, the international free gold standard.
THE Fn~ Goi~ STANDARD
What made the free gold standard system of the 19th century so
effective was the manner in which continuing equilibrium in the inter-
national accounts was maintained There were no persistent deficits,
or persistent surpluses, in the balance of mternational payments of
Great Britain or any other important country So effectively, m fact,
did the Bank of England function as world banker that the system
seemed automatic and natural
In those days most international trade was carried on in terms of
pounds sterling Pounds and gold were freely convertible into each
other, and other currencies were convertible mto pounds or into gold
The international bahncing mechanism seemed to be so close to auto
matic that countries were not even conscious of imbalances between
their international receipts and their international payments
Gold was free to move from country to country, not by virtue of
governmental decisions or licensing but in response to market forces
The freedom of~gold to move internationally2 together with the will-
ingness of most countries to accept the disciphne.of the gold standard,
by allowing bank credit to expand and contract as the supply of gold
expanded and contracted, provided the world with a multilateral pay-
ments system that worked well. International commerce was free, not
in the sense that there were no trade barriers, but in the sense that
tariffs were applicable to all foreigners alike. There was no discrim-
ination against certain suppliers in favor of others through the use of
quantitative import restrictions and other trade controls.
The pound was convertible into gold at a fixed rate and the cur-
rencies of most countries were freely convertible into each other.
Currencies were legally defined in terms of their gold weights. The
dollar was 23.22 grains of fine gold and the British pound sterling
was 113.0016 grains. The ratio of the weights of the two currencies
(4.866-plus to 1) was known as the "par of exchange."
Individuals could convert gold into currency, or currency into gold,
at the legal rate, or convert one currency into another at the prevail-
ing exchange rate. Gold was the standard of value and the system
provided a mechanism for keeping the values of currencies in line with
each other at approximately their gold parities. As a result,. gold
was distributed throughout the world according to need, as deter
mined by changing prices and by changes in foreign exchange rates.
For example, when prices of certain commodities in the United
PAGENO="0109"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 101
States increased, relative to their prices in the United Kingdom, there
was a tendency for Americans to increase their imports of those com-
modities. Unless offset by other price changes in the opposite direc-
tion, the increase in U.S. imports, relative to U.S. exports, caused an
increase in the demand for sterling in terms of dollars, thereby caus-
ing the dollar to weaken relative to the pound sterling. The decline
would not go beyond the "gold export point" (4.886-plus per £1),
however, for at that point it would be more economical to convert
dollars into gold for shipment to the United Kingdom than to pay a
higher price for sterling in the foreign exchange market. Since gold
was directly related to the supply of money and credit, the exporta-
tion of gold would cause price levels in the United States to halt their
rise, ielative to those in the United Kingdom When prices in the two
countries came into line with each other the exchange rate was close to
parity and there was a state of international equilibrium.
Usually, long before the gold shipping point was reached the decline
in the foreign exchange value of the dollar would itself attract short-
term capital (since a given number of pounds would purchase n'iore
dollars than before) thereby tending to bring international payments
and receipts into balance with each other. The system worked well
largely because the British Government pursued liberal trade and
investment policies.
ILLUSTRATION OF ECONOMIC ADJUSTMENT UNDER A FREE GOLD STANDARD
1. An increase of U.S. commodity imports, relative to U.S. com-
modity exports, causes dollars to become more plentiful in the foreign
exchange market, relative to other currencies, so that the value of
the dollar drops from $4.866=~1 (parity) to, say, $4.87 ~
2. Because pounds will now purchase more dollars than before,
it becomes more profitable than before to convert pounds into dollars
for short-term investment in the United States.
3. The ensuing flow of short-term capital into the United States in-
creases the supply of short-term capital, relative to the demand for
it, and causes the short-term interest rate in the United States to
fall, thereby tending to neutralize the effect of the decline in the
foreign exchange rate.
4. Also, while the dollar is cheapening, relative to sterling, it be-
comes more profitable than before for foreigners to buy certain kinds
of merchandise in the United States. Hence, U.S. exports will increase,
relative to imports, tending to correct the previous excess of imports
over exports. The effect will be to raise the value of the dollar back
toward parity.
It is important to observe that these correctives-capital movements
and merchandise trade-are brought about by changes in foreign ex-
change rates, without the international transfer of gold.
5. If, however, this adjustment mechanism fails to work effectively
the foreign exchange value of the dollar will continue to decline until
it reaches $4.886 to £1. This is the "gold export point." Since it costs
(or used to cost) 2 cents to ship a pound sterling's worth of gold be-
tween New York and. London it is more profitable to ship it than to
pay any more than $4.886 (a 2-cent differential) for a pound sterling
in foreign exchange
PAGENO="0110"
102 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
6. The movement of gold from New York to London decreases U.S.
monetary reserves and increases reserves in the United Kingdom,
thereby serving to contract credit in the United States and to expand
it in the United Kingdom.
7. In consequence, certain prices in the United States will fall, rela-
tive to prices in the United Kingdom, thereby making the United
States a better market in which to buy and the United Kingdom a
better market in which to sell. U.S. exports, therefore, will be stim-
ulated while imports will be retarded.
Generalizing the illustration5 a decline in the foreign exchange value
of a currency, by inducing short-term capital inflow, by making it
profitable to export gold, and by changing the relationship of exports
to imports, serves to distribute the world's monetary gold among
countries in accordance with their needs, and prevents prices of inter-
nationally traded goods from getting out of line with each other.
This is what is me'int by "equilibrium under the free gold stand'ird"
The "correctives" under an idealized free gold st~ndard are freely
fluctuating exchange rates, within the gold points, freedom to buy and
sell gold; relatively free international movement of capital and mer-
chandise; and fluidity of prices within and between countries, includ-
ing those of the factors of production (interest rates and wages).
The essence of the. free gold standard was the willingness of coun-
tries to allow their domestic economies to adjust to each other `in re-
spo~se to changes in the eceternal va~ues of their currencies.
Those who favor return to a free gold standard are, in effect, argu-
ing that countries allow wages3 prices, and rates of interest to adjust
to wages, prices, a~d rates of interest in other countries, as well as to
allow gold to move internationally in response to freely fluctuating
exchange rates. Most important of all, the discipline of the free gold
standard requires that bank credit be allowed to expand or contract
as the supply of gold expands or contracts.
It is doubtful whether any country in the world today is willing to
go this far toward fostering a "world economy." Most countries seek
to insulate themselves against infl'Ltioniry and deflation'iry forces in
other countries, and are more interested in domestic prosperity and
economic growth than in a functioning international economy. Full-
employment policies and programs take precedence over almost every-
thing else in the economic sphere largely because of fears of the de
flation which political leaders believe would result from return to a
free gold standard
Because of the unwillingness of countries to allow their domestic
economies to adjust to each other, it is probable that return to a gold
standard would have deflationary effects. However, if the economically
developed countries were willing to make the internal a diustments
necessary to bring about the full utilization of productive resources
everywhere, it is probable that the cost of makmg the necessary eco
nornic acl]u'~tments would be slight
If countries were to allow their economies to adjust freely to each
other, only small quantities of gold would be needed for the purpose
of making international settlements Indeed, if they went the full
way and became a true "world economy," with or without a unified
world currency, there would be no need for gold at all This is the situ
ation that prevails in most large cities where `banks balance their
PAGENO="0111"
ISSIJES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 103
~accounts against each other daily, or even within a national economy
where economic forces are allowed to operate freely. One never hears,
for example, of a balance-of-payments deficit of an individual State
of the United States with respect to other States of the Union. Even
areas within a country that are beset by economic difficulties, such as
parts of the Appalachian region, do not attempt to solve their eco-
nomic problems by insulating themselves against trade with other
areas of the country.
EQUILIBRIUM WITHOUT GOLD
If countries allowed their domestic economies to adjust to each
other by resisting the temptation to interfere with the international
movement of goods and capital and by not using subsidies to interfere
with internal economic adjustments, there would be continuing equi-
librium among them even without the use of any gold.
Countries, however, refuse to allow their economies to adjust to
each other because they have learned how to use domestic monetary
and fiscal policies to stimulate economic growth and domestic employ-
ment. In consequence, with currencies pegged at fixed ratios relative
to each other, and with all sorts of obstacles being placed in the way
of the international movement of goods and capital, it becomes ex-
ceedingly difficult to keep the international accounts of all countries
in balance with each other. Because of this difficulty, and because the
achievement of balance under such circumstances requires consider-
able time, there is strong and continuing demand for "increased
liquidity" on the part of countiies that are in deficit in the form of de
mands for easy access to additional monetary reserves.
The question of adequacy of reserves is intimately related to the
degree to which countries allow their economies to adjust to each other
through changes in capital flows, nierchandise trade, prices, interest
rates, and wages. The greater the resistance to international adjust-
ment, the greater will be the need for monetary reserves. Conversely,
the greater the willingness to allow international adjustment to occur,
the less will be the need for reserves. Indeed, "adequacy of reserves"
may be conceived of as a spectrum, ranging from a need for zero
reserves at one extreme to a need for almost infinite reserves at the
other, the quantity of reserves needed at any time depending upon
the degree to which countries resist international economic adjust-
ments. Attempts to determine the amount of reserves needed, without
ref ërence to international adjustments, are futile.
The problem of monetary reserves is the problem of providing a
deep enough financial cushion to provide time during which national
economies can adjust to each other Monetary reserves are the shock
~bsorbers of international finance, they are not an elixir th~rt can sud
denly bring prosperity to countries that have not yet learned how to
support themselves.
If foreign exchange rates were allowed to fluctuate freely no deficit
in the balance of payments could occur because changes in rates of
exchange would clear the market. Changes in the conditions of demand
and supply in foreign trade would be met by adjustments in capital
flows and in the volume and composition of intern'~tion'il trade Short
term capital moves internationally in response to sm'ill changes in
PAGENO="0112"
104 ISSUES ~D OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
interest rates, and merchandise exports increase, relative to imports,
if the currency of a country cheapens in terms of the currencies of
other countries. Equilibrium is established, it should be noted, not by
the adjustment of average price levels to each other, but by adjust
ment of the prices of individual commodities.
As the value of a country's currency declines, it becomes increasingly
profitable for foreigners to buy in that country. A series of "export
points" for various commodities become operative, such as a cheese
export point, a wheat export point, and so forth, which are similar
to the "gold points" under the free gold standard. Thus, when the
Canadian dollar falls in value to a certain point, relative to the U.S.
dollar, it becomes profitable for Americans to import Cheddar cheese
from Canada. If, on the other hand, the Canadian dollar appreciates
in value, relative to the U S dollar, it becomes profitable for Cana
dians to import Cheddar cheese from the United States Such coin
modity shipping points serve to adjust national economies to each
other through changes in the composition, as well as the volume, of
international trade.
However, since international adjustments sometimes cause sensitive
prices, including certain wages to decline, governments resist. This is
what happened between World War I and World War II. The gold
standard had been abandoned by most countries, and national gov-
ernments vied with each other to protect themselves against exchange
depreciation. They *depreciated their own currencies in frantic at-
tempts to increase exports relative to imports. Quantitative controls
against imports, exchange controls, and a wide variety of other de-
vices were employed to protect themselves against each other's
exports.
The wide variations in foreign exchange rates that accompanied
competitive exchange depreciation made international transactions
hazardous and were a serious deterrent to international trade. Between
1930 and 1932 international trade dwindled to a mere trickle, and the
world became bogged down deeper and deeper in depression, with
millions of people unemployed.
There is nothing economically illogical about freely fluctuating ex-
change rates. The difficulties in adopting them lie in the political
sphere. There is an all-pervasive fear against allowing a national
economy to adjust to other economies or, in popular language, "to im-
port deflation or inflation from abroad." Adoption of either an in-
ternational free gold standard or a system of freely fluctuating foreign
exchange rates would require' that governments allow their economies
to adjust to each other. It would be necessary that they abstain from
interfering with international capital outflows and with merchandise
imports, that they allow prices and wages, to be determined by the
interplay of market forces, and that they not try to prevent the trans-
fer of capital and labor from less efficient to more efficient lines of
production. , ,
THE ADJUSTMENT PROCESS
The international transfers of merchandise that bring about econom
ic adjustment need to be conceived' of in terms of actual commodities,
rather th'tn in terms of statistical aggregates Adjustment occurs, not
only through changes in the total volume of imports relative to the
PAGENO="0113"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 105
total volume of exports, but also in terms of changes in the com-
position of trade.
An increase in the imports of a highly competitive product into a
country where the marginal cost of that product is considerably high-
er than its marginal cost in the country of export will have the effect,
first, of lowering the price of that product in the country of importa-
tion and, secondly, of displacing some of that country's marginal
production. In turn, this is likely to lead to some unemployment and
some impairment of profits in the industry in question. In accordance
with the competitive principle underlying the free enterprise system,
the result will be transfer of some capital and labor away from the
production of the good in question into the production of goods that
have a competitive advantage in a foreign market. These continuous
transfers of labor and capital away from areas of higher-cost produc-
tion to areas of lower-cost production serve to keep the international
economic accounts in equilibrium.
THE "No INJURY" PHILOSOPHY
Not since the United Kingdom abandoned free trade at the turn of
the 20th century has any important trading country been willing to
require that domestic producing interests adjust to highly competitive
imports. Most countries have followed the opposite course of protect-
ing individual firms and groups of workers who are hard pressed by
foreign competition by restricting such imports. The world is still
mercantilistic; governments are much more concerned over the im-
mediate pecuniary welfare of producers than over the long-run wel-
f are of consumers.
Notwithstanding all the fanfare that has accompanied the liberal
trade programs initiated by the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act in
1934, there has been consistent and active concern over the "injury"
that might be caused by the increased competitive imports resulting
from reductions in tariffs and other trade barriers. Ever since 1942
there has been provision, either in the law itself or by administrative
action, authorizing the President to impose barriers against imports
whenever the Tariff Commission finds that imports are causing, or
threatening to cause, "serious injury" to any domestic producing
interest.
Not until the Trade Expansion Act was passed in 1962 was there
even the slightest indication in the law that tariffs and other trade bar-
riers should be reduced even though the increased imports resulting
from such action might threaten injury to some domestic producers.
Title III of the new legislation provided, for the first time, for sub-
sidizing adjustment in those cases where increased imports might in-
jure domestic producers.
As evidence of this change in thinking was a statement of intent
by the Kennedy administration, when the trade expansion bill was in-
troduced in Congress in January 1962, to negotiate for across-the-
board tariff reductions with a minimum of exceptions. Prior to 1962
tariff negotiating was confined to those tariffs, the reduction of which
would not result in increases in imports sufficient to alarm domestic
producers. Under the 1962 legislation, if injury should eventuate it
would be in the discretion of the President either to increase tariffs
82-246-67----8
PAGENO="0114"
106 ISSuES AND OBJECTIVES OF IJ.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
(and impose import quotas) for the purpose of restricting the trouble-
some imports, or to invoke the adjustment assistance provisions, in-
cluding the retraining of workers and the rendering of technical as-
sistance to individual producing firms.
The fact that Congress modified the proposed legislation in such
a way as to make the adjustment assistance provisions almost impos-
sible to administer does not alter the fact that for the first time the
law recognized this fundamental change in trade philosophy.
There has been, and there continues to be, confusion between "in-
jury" and the "inconvenience" of having to adapt to a new and in-
tensified competition. "Iiij ury," resulting from import competition, is
essentially a short-run phenomenon. Under free trade most of the
workers who are displaced by imports soon find new jobs. The problem
of injury is the problem of someone being hurt in the short run.
Injury involves individual workers and the owners of individual
firms. The dictionary meaning of the word is clear-"injury" means
that someone is hurt. It does not mean, and it should not be confused
with "inconvenience."
The inconvenience of shifting from one job to another may be con-
`siderable, but it does not mean that a person is necessarily hurt, or
injured, merely because he is forced to adust to a different line of ac-
tivity. In a free enterprise economy this is done every day in response
to the pressures of domestic competition.
It is the essence of the individual enterprise system that those who
are not suitably adapted to their economic environment should trans-
fer to other lines of work for which they are better adapted. The
underlying principle of the individual enterprise system is that the
utilization of resources is maximized through the pursuit of self-in-
terest. When the government prevents such adjustment efficiency is
minimized.
When injury resulting from import competition is referred to it
should be made clear that the reference is not to the mere inconven-
ience of transferring from one line of work to another. For example,
not very long ago, a number of producers of briar smoking pipes in
New York City were displaced by import competition. They were not
"mjuied," however, because it w~s easy for the woikers ~nd the own
ers of the firms to find new jobs and new profitmaking opportunities
in the highly industrialized and highly diversified city of New York
But, when `~ similar phenomenon occurs in a less-diversified area,
such as parts of West Virginia, where only a limited number of
economic opporturnties exist, the adiustment process-the inconven
ience-can itself constitute injury When a person c~tnnot re'~sonably
locate an alternative job he is "injured". When the same thing happens
to a firm it, too, is hurt. This is what should be meant by "injury".
It is important to recognize that "industries", seldom, if ever, suffer
injury "Industry" is a statistic'il, rather th'ui an economic, concept
Individual workers and owners of capital, not industries, suffer injury
When firms or workers are unable to find alternative opportunities
they are injured, `md the question is "w hat should be done about it ~
Most Americans believe th'~t no individual, or group of individuals
should be called upon to bear the economic cost of foreign pohcj b~
PAGENO="0115"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 107
being deprived of an opportunity to work for a living. This is why
it is so easy to jump to the conclusion that job displacement brought
about by foreign competition should be remedied by restricting
imports.
Although an individual worker, or owner of a firm, should not be
called upon to bear the cost of job displacement resulting from a
liberal foreign trade policy, it is not correct to conclude that people
should be frozen into their jobs by governmental action whenever
there is an intensification of import competition.
Only when the problem of injury is conceived of in terms of indi-
viduals, rather than industries, does the "avoidance of injury" philos-
ophy make sense. When it is tied to the requirement that imports
should be curtailed there is danger of muddy thinking.
Injury to individuals needs to be avoided. Curtailment of imports
under the escape clause, however, is only one type of remedy. The
escape clause means what it says. It is an escape from a commitment
made in good faith between the United States and another country
to reduce trade barriers. It is the adjustment assistance philosophy,
as yet inadequately implemented in the law, that affords the Presi-
dent a choice, either to impose a higher tariff (or an import quota)
after receiving a finding of threat of injury from the Tariff Com-
mission, or to provide for Government assistance to facilitate the
transfer of those individuals who are adversely affected into lines of
activity for which they are better suited. Adjustment assistance
avoids injury to individual workers and firms without restricting
imports. It provides the flexibility and the mobility that are essential
to a world economy based on free enterprise.
THE MAGNITUDE 013' ADJUSTMENT
Although the political resistance would be formidable, the economic
magnitude of the adjustments that would be necessary to implement
a freely functioning world economy would not be very great. They
would be analagous to pruning the trees in a fruit orchard when dead
and dying branches need to be removed if the chemicals in the soil
are to be allowed to nourish the trees as a whole. Unless high-cost
producers at the margin, in various lines of production, are allowed
to be displaced by more efficient low-cost producers, the economic
body, like the fruit trees, will not be sturdy.
It was estimated a little over a decade ago, that if the United States
were to abandon all of its tariffs and import quotas its imports would
increase by somewhere between 10 and 24 percent which, in terms of
1965 imports, would be an increase of between $2.3 billion and $5.2
billion. An increase in imports of this magnitude might necessitate
the adjustment from one occupation to another of between 0.3 percent
and 0.6 percent of the country's total civilian work force-which is
certainly no greater than the percentage normally affected by techno-
logical changes in production.'
1 For estimates of probable imports In the event of suspension of all U.S. tariffs and
import quotas, see Piquet, H. S., "Aid, Trade and the Tariff," 1953. For the meaning of
increased imports in terms of adjustments in employment see Salant, W. 5. and vaccara, B.,
"Import Liberalization and Employment," 1961.
PAGENO="0116"
108 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
SIGNIFICANCE OF THE KENNEDY ROUND
Although the tariff cuts that are to be made as a result of the Ken-
nedy Round are far from negligible, and will assist the international
adjustment process, their importance should not be overestimated.
Although, according to early press releases, the cuts will apply to a
large proportion of all international trade, they do not provide for
free trade. Nor will they accomplish much with respect to import
quotas and other nontariff trade barriers.
In Western Europe and the United States, where industrial tariffs
average between 12 and 14 percent, the overall reduction of approxi-
mately 35 percent provided for by the Kennedy Round will reduce
them only to an average of between 8 and 9 percent. Clearly, much
remains to be accomplished in the way of trade barrier reduction,
notwithstanding the arduous efforts that went into the Kennedy
Bound.
The first need is for recognition by the industrialized countries that
the free international interplay of economic forces would be to their
own advantage, as well as to the advantage of the less-developed
countries. The importance of liberal foreign trade policies to a solution
of the problem of persistent international disequilibrium is not the
superficial one of increasing merchandise exports, relative to merchan-
dise imports, with respect toa particular country, but rather in trying
to secure agreement by all countries to the elimination of obstacles to
the free movement of goods and capital.
If goods and capital were free to move internationally, economies
would adjust to each other and, in accordance with the principle of
comparative advantage, the adjustment would lead not only to self-
sustaining equilibrium in the international accounts, but also to the
maximizing of world production and world consumption.
PAGENO="0117"
U.S. EXPORTS IN RELATION TO U.S.
PRODUCTION ABROAD
BY JUDD POLK*
Traditionally, United States, like other countries, has viewed its
trade with other nations as the main indication of its concrete
economic interest, in the outside world. Trade policy in broad historic
sweep has moved from preoccupation with the problems of defending
particular industries against foreign competition to general acknowl-
edgment of the mutual interest of all nations in freer trade. In this
century the movement toward toward freer trade has just achieved
its most dramatic manifestation in the successful conclusion of the
Kennedy ROund of comprehensive and significant trade concessions
among the major trading nations.
There is a powerful economic rationale for this trend and for its
continuation. But the*~ decisive considerations of policy can no longer
be seen from the vantage point of international trade itself or in terms
of the familiar arguments which since Adam Smith's day have ration~
alized the cause of freer trade as a means of reaping the harvest of
the international division of labor.
The fact is that international trade is now itself incidental to the
broader phenomenon of international production. This term inter-
national production is here used to describe the deliveries ,which one
nation makes in the markets' of another via the direct expedient of
producing there locally, as distinguished from exporting to that
market the product of facilities located at home.
* As `will be shown, the producing stake of United States and other
countries probably now accounts for sales upward' of some $150 billion,
as against U.S. expOrts of about one-fifth as much. As this tremendous
producing establishment has developed, American subsidiaries abroad
have come to occupy a very substantial role among our foreign
customers. And the free movement of goods, in favor of which our
forebears could, argue the relative luxury of the gains available from
specialized trade, is now more in the nature of a structural imperative
of the method of production itself-much in the same way one might
urge the structural importance of the interstate commerce clause in
the U.S. economic constitution. Moreover, when international trade-
especially in the case of the United States-is seen in proper relation
to production abroad, very serious doubt is cast upon the workability
of any trade-policy initiative, such as export expansion, unless taken
in compatible relation to policy initiatives pertaining to the entire
range of our foreign production-here namely the encouragement of
investment in production abroad.
* United States Council of the International Chamber of Commerce, Inc.,
New York, N.Y.
109
PAGENO="0118"
110 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
International investment is transforming the character of the world
economy; for one thing, it is no longer whimsical to speak of a world
economy. The output associated with U.S. production in other nations'
markets is large in relation to the national GNP's of the industrial-
ized world. While the history of international investment goes back
almost as far as the history of international trade, only recently has
it emerged as the most important fact of international economic life.
The implications of this fact are only beginning to be understood.
Here an effort will be made to sketch the basic picture and suggest
some of the implications for questions of trade policy.
THE SCOPE OF TJ.S. DELIVERIES TO FOiui~IGN MARKETS
The most important trade concept, and one that is essentially new
in the structure of world trade, as fundamentally altered by interna-
tional investment, is that of total deliveries to a market, in contrast
to the traditional concept, now secondary in importance, of deliveries
(exports) that happen to cross international borders The aggregate
world GNP, excluding Communist countries, for which compatible
market statistics are not available, is in the order of magnitude of
$1,600 billion, about half accounted for by the United States Of this,
a rapidly growing portion-perhaps $250 billion, but not definitely
estimatable-is product associated with intern'ttionally owned and
operated plants U S statistics on investment abroad and associated
production permit a firmei rough estimate of $150 billion as its share
of this intern'mtional production U S total delivei ies to foi eign mar
kets are some $180 billion Of these, about `t fifth-$30 billion-aie
expoi ts, the rest emanating from TI S production facilities located
abroad
Therapid and steady growth of our foreign investment and produc-
tion is shown on the ~ccomnpanymg gr'mphs (page 111) The calculated
trend rate of growth of the known book value of investment is 10 per-
cent since 1950, and a striking feature of this growth is its regularity
the growth each year has been close to trend
Accompanying growth of exports has been buoyant but somewhat
slower. Shown on the graph is an earlier calculated trend rate of 5.4
percent. In view of the livelier growth in recent years, however, the
average annual rate of growth of 7 percent from 1960 through 1966 ap
pears more representative and this line has been added to the second
graph, where also is shown (1) the inferred volume of U.S. production
abroad and (2) the sum of this plus exports-"Total Foreign Sales"-
representing the value of total U.S. deliveries to foreign markets from
both exports and local (foreign) production.
PRODUCTION. ABROAD AND EXPORTS GROW TOGETHER1
The concept of total foreign sales properly brings together U S de
liveries in response to foreign demands, whether involving product
made here or there. Basically the two sources of. supply are comple-
mentary, and, in fact, they have grown in a parallel and vigorous
manner, as can be seen at a glance from the graphs. The fact of their
`The discussion here of the relationship between exports and production abroad incor-
porates material previously developed for the National Export Expansion Council's Sub-
committee on Less Developed Countries.
PAGENO="0119"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY lii
The positive effect of investment on ex-
ports, which producers abroad commonly re-
port they "see" in thoir own operations, is
strongly suggested in the area growth-rate
profiles:
% Av. Annua] Growth
l9~51Q~J66
Invsnt Exports
Europe 15 8
Canada 10 8
Lat. Ant. 5 3
Other 11 8
Note: Trends shown are least square trends calculated for the
period 1950 - 1964. Investment, exports and inferred
foreign sales data for 1966 have been estimated and added
to the actual performance lines. Similarly, a terminal-
year average rate of growth (7%) has been calculated on
the basis of the 1960 and 1966 figures, and is shown as
be.ng a fuither useful inoication of the prevailing trend
parallel growth, when coupled to the fact of the overriding quantita-
tive importance which the high level of U.S. investment since World
War II has given to production from facilities located abroad, consti-
tutes a fact of utmost importance for United States foreign economic
policy. For example, as against our present tendency to discourage
investment and encourage exports in the thought that this realinement
of delivery methods will have a beneficial effect on our net foreign
exchange position, there stands the powerful inference from export
and production trends that investment is a major stimulant to exports.
Furthermore, detailed work with both national and company statistics
suggests that the defense and extension of a sales position achieved
through exports will require continuing investment.
Balance-of-payments accounting is trade oriented and largely ne-
glects the economic impact of our foreign investment as the major
channel through which U.S. producers operate in foreign markets. The
investment shown in the accompanying graphs is limited to so-called
direct investment; this is investment in which U.S. business has, by
definition, at least a 10-percent equity, and has, in actual fact, outright
CtIio~. at Dolto,s (a)
bOo Oral.
00
to
60
40
Tm U.S. RESPONSE TO FOREIGN MARKET DEMAND
The graph at left generalizes the com-
parison of exports to sales of output from
production abroad, the latter as estimated
above (first graph). In 1950 the estimated
U.S. sales of goods produced locally abroad
wore 2,1 over exports-a difference of $13
billion. After 14 years of vigorous export
c,rcswth, the difference was $64 billion, the
ratio 4:1.
Total
-~ " Exports
(5.4%)
- P,ot.ttod
PAGENO="0120"
112 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
control in the great majority of instances. The growth in investment
includes new dollar capital outflow, which appears in the balance of
payments, and retained earnings-which do not, but which are fol-
lowed and published by the Department of Commerce. In the typical
instance of investment, these two sources of financing are of roughly
equal importance. But more important in evaluating the local impact
of investment is a quantification of the value of product to be associ-
ated with the expanded productive facilities. From data now available
on, for example, the value of sales by U.S. manufacturing subsidiaries
abroad, a reasonable rule of thumb ratio of 2 to 1 can be derived for
output to book value. From this, the implication of these figures is that
gains in 11.5.-initiated output abroad for, say, Europe grew from $6
billion in 1950-against U.S. exports of roughly half that amount-to
some $32 billion in 1966-against exports of $10 billion, or less than a
third. Moreover, at this level of local output from U.S. investment, a
substantial tendency for an increase in local imports-perhaps $11/2
billion-may reasonably be inferred as the import share of the increase
in local income, and supplementary to imports directly associated with
the capital increase, notably capital equipment. In the case of the less-
developed countries this tendency to import more as income rises con-
tributes to the chronic foreign exchange shortages with which most of
them grapple, and is curtailed by familiar import and exchange
restrictions.
The basic income-import relationships have been more fully ex-
plored in the National Industrial Conference Board's report, "U.S.
Production Abroad and the Balance of Payments" (1966). The re-
capitulation here is intended to show the extent to which local produc-
tion abroad has outdistanced exports as a means of delivering goods
to foreign markets, and how the gains in local production, so vital to
the basic process of development, have been compatible with regular
growth in traditional deliveries via exports.
DOES PRODUCTION ABROAD DISPLACE EXPORTS?
The answer to this question appears to be clearly "Yes" for specific
products, but for total exports, clearly "No" and for products in the
same general industrial classification, probably "No." It is a common-
place of policy in less-developed countries to interdict imports in
favor of programs of local production.2 The Mexican industrialization
program is a nearby familiar example. A familiar response of U.S.
~ornpanies to such programs has been to set up local production facili-
ties, where cost-profit-risk factors warrant. In such cases, the alterna-
tive export of equipment, raw materials, and even other related fin-
ished products more than offsets the loss of the original product ex-
port.
In other cases, relative cost considerations lead to production aboard.
in still other cases. and these are the most frequent. the marketing
advanta~es obtainable onlythroii~h the maintenance of a local foreign
establishment prompt the decision. The many motivations of foreion
investment, and the primac~ of marketing consider'itiowi among them,
~Enrope In the days of postwar reconstruction similiarly restricted imports for con-
sumption `md f'mvored imports for production
PAGENO="0121"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 113
have been widely studied elsewhere and need no recital here. it is im-
portant, however, to note emphatically that intensive case study rarely
turns up a situation in which the producer abroad could have con-
tinued to export as an alternative to producing locally abroad.
Moreover, an important fact often forgotten in discussions of what
impels companies to produce abroad as against supplying foreign
markets through exports is that there are no acceptable substitutes
produced in the United States for much of U.S. production abroad.
This is the case even in manufacturing, but is particularly clear in
the case of the extractive industries which establish facilties abroad
so as to gain sources of supply rather than new market, and applies
also to trading ccmpanies, utilities, and other service enterprises that
~ limited to foreign sites by the nature of their operatio~is. These
nonmanufacturing instances have especially close relevance to the
LDC's. Even in consumer goods, versions developed for the U.S.
market are keyed to income levels and social positions more advanced
than those prevailing in the LDC's.
As for new U.S. exports induced by investment abroad, it seems
likely that the relationship between exports and local production is
close, and is probably particularly strong in the case of LDC's. In
1964, for example, the ratio of U.S. exports shipped to Latin Ameri-
can manufacturing affiliates to sales revenues of these affiliates was 11
percent. The comparable ratio for Europe: 6 percent. The difference
is some indication of how much more producers in LDC's n'iust look
abroad for their supplies than is the case for those in more developed
countries. Comparably competitive sources of supplies and equipment
are simply not at hand for the LDC producers, and this relative in-
flexibility in source has a widespread impact.
In the case of capital goods, for example, the technology necessary
to produce the machines for making other machines, as well as ma-
chines for making final product, is not readily available in the LDC's.
Thus in 1964 Latin America imported $126 million of capital equip-
ment from the United States; Europe imported only $65 million,
despite the much more rapid pace of U.S. investment in Europe-six
times the rate in Latin America. Available figures also permit a cor-
roborating examination of capital-equipment sources for foreign
manufacturing subsidiaries. Latin American subsidiaries obtained
half of the materials used in their manufacturing operations from the
United States, European subsidiaries about a tenth.
Investment-induced exports appear generally more impressive than
those hypothetically displaced, although the latter concededly raise
an imponderable question. What might have been the level of U.S.
product exports had there been no production abroad cannot be deter-
mined. But the question is largely idle; producers did not have the
choice in the first place.
The often expressed anxiety that U.S. production abroad displaces
exports on balance is not persuasive. For one thing, U.S. foreign di-
rect investment alone now (mid-1967) totals more than $55 billion,
and accounts for possibly as much as $115 billion in product deliveries.
It is not credible that foreign countries would permit or could finance
these deliveries as supplemental exports from U.S. facilities. More-
over, as noted already, this productive activity within foreign markets
has in fact been accompanied by a vigorous growth of U.S. exports
(7 percent annual average, 1950-66), the more vigorous in areas where
PAGENO="0122"
114 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
investment activity has been more intense. The directness of the rela-
tionship between~ investment activity and export growth is now fur-
ther supported by various statistical and case-study surveys of the
transactions of U.S. affiliates abroad. While so far the United States
imports relatively little from foreign affiliates, its exports to them are
substantial (about one-quarter) and growing-U.S.' own foreign affili-
ates already have emerged as a major customer of the United States
abroad. Less direct but also significant for U.S. exports is the increase
in foreign imports as a result of income gains associated with U.S.
local (foreign) production. The increase in foreign imports (includ-
ing, of course, U.S. exports) from the higher income is now a sub-
stantial figure.
It is perfectly compatible with this interpretation of the favorable
effect of U.S. investment abroad on U.S. exports to acknowledge the
uniqueness of exports as foreign-exchange earners and the importance
of increasing exports, especially in periods like the present when
dollars tend to accumulate in foreign hands, with the all too well-
grounded likelihood that they will be presented for conversion into
gold rather than spent on U.S. exports or invested here.
THE UNITED STATES AS A PEDDLER
The charm of exports from a balance-of-payments point of view is
that they yield foreign exchange to the country equivalent to their
sales value, not just their profit margin. In contrast, production abroad
on the basis of U.S. investment, returns foreign exchange equivalent
only to the remitted portion of the producers' profits-typically now
about 5 percent of the sales revenue (in the case of manufacturing, for
which sufficient figures are available to permit a fair estimate). Thus,
from the narrow and short-run perspective of the transactions enter-
ing balance-of-payments accounting, the proceeds of commercial ex-
ports of goods and services constitute the No. I foreign-exchange earn-
ings of the country. Even were the export transactions conducted at a
commercial loss, there would be a foreign exchange gain.
The fact that U.S.' primary role in the world economy is that of a~n
investor and producer is plainly adventitious for its role as seller of
U.S. products wherever made. In contrast, the point is now frequently
heard that U.S. producers tend to overconcentrate on the investment!
production approach to foreign markets. Those concerned with what-
ever element of truth there is in this contention argue that the sales-
men of our main advanced-country competitors (Europe, Japan-
and possibly Hong Kong?) have not forgotten how to hustle and do
not disdain individually small (but cumulatively large) sales. Nor do
they find that their selling requires a costly investment establishment.
It is not possible to quantify how extensive such presumably
drummed-up sales by others may be-and therefore for a more com-
petitive United States might be. Nor is it possible to quantify for com-
parison and by way of offset the volume of U.S. sales that could
fairly be attributed to the competitively superior marketing position
achieved through the U.S. producing establishment abroad. On the
former-the success of sellers from competitive countries-American
pvodiie~v~ ~brô~d f~equ~riIy i~e~ife ôffh~md in~tanees of the effective-
ness of other industrialized countries' salesmen operating without the
benefit of an entrenched local marketing establishment, but with the
PAGENO="0123"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 115
benefit of readily available help from their governments. There is
also some corroborative evidence of their effectiveness in foreign
balance-of -payments figures of these countries, showing, for example,
European surpluses achieved in third areas, say, Latin America. The
comparability of available figures is open to question; the various
nonuniform balance-of-payments accounts do not yield clear evidence
on the geographic sources of export earnings.
Nonetheless, an arresting case can be made out inferentially that
major U.S. competitors are earning their trade surpluses-and ulti-
mately their net dollars and their gold-not with this country but with
"third countries." No doubt there are real possibilities for improving
our commercial competitive position including increased exports to the
LDC's. But whatever may be the export gains to be achieved tem-
porarily, a real and sustainable improvenient in LDC purchases from
abroad, including the United States, depends on the further develop-
ment of basic LDC income (production), with accompanying growth
of LDC earning capacity (LDC exports).
TRADE POLICY IS PRODUCTION POLICY
The U.S. delivery system to foreign markets-based on advancing
production, marketing, and above all, organization techniques-has
now evolved into an essentially foreign-base plant system of supply.
Although this development has carried exports to an ever rising level
and at a rate of growth (7 percent) about halfway between that of
domestic U.S. production (say 5 percent) and our production abroad
(a steady 10 percent), U.S. companies' total deliveries to foreign
markets are some six times larger than "conventional" exports alone.
This does not mean that United States has a diminishing interest in
good international trade policy. The freer international movement of
goods and money-capital goods and capital funds as well as current
goods and current funds-is now for us internationally as well as na-
tionally an essential condition of production itself, not just of periph-
eral trading benefits. Production since the not entirely fictitious
Robinson Crusoe has meant specialization and money. The effect of
our intensively developed international producing position is a re-
minder that trade is an integral part of production, internationally
as well as nationally. The sweep of international investment since
World War IT has removed any overtone of whimsy from the. concept
of a world economy rather than just an international one. From elabo-
rated interproduction among nations, world production is emerging,
and from international t.rade,world trade.
The policy implications of this shift away from the mere swapping
of national products and toward world production cannot be fully
anticipated. We are at a beginning here, and it is most appropriate, in
my opinion, that we pause at this juncture to study, beginning our
study with the responsible deliberations of this joint congressional
committee.
Some major shortcomings of present policy can be sensed when~
reviewed against any sober effort to assess the irreversible require-
ments of our worldwide producing.position:
1. We should squarely face the possibility that our present general
policy of discouraging the normal growth of our producing estab-
lishment abroad by putting restraints and restrictions on investment
PAGENO="0124"
116 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
is misconceived. This approach adopted as a "temporary" (now in its
fifth year) bit of pragmatism thought to be required by the exigencies
of the balance of payments and thought to be productive of balance-
of-payments relief, is pursued at the direct expense of our economic
position in the world and is likely to have been and to be prejudicial
to our earning position in the world.
2. The current emphasis on encouraging exports, though highly
desirable insofar as it pertains to goods produced at competitive cost,
cannot operate as a substitute for our investment and production
abroad. An effective export effort in our stage of development can, for
the most part, be maintained only on the basis of appropriate invest-
ment backstopping in foreign markets. Consistent with this, however,
is any step that facilitates exports and thereby reduces the time lag
between finanacial commitments we make abroad and the transfer of
real resources (exports) to implement them.
3. Problems of improving the terms of credit available for inter-
national projects frequently arise in the context of specific export
projects, particularly in the capital goods field. Almost certainly the
importance of this range of problems, already high, will grow. The
adequacy of international credit, of international financing institu-
tions, and of foreign governmental policies to accommodate freer move-
ment of capital and current funds is directly and vitally relevant to
the viability of our tremendous position in worldwide production.
4. To a very real extent, international production-unlike national
production-must take place on the basis of a very sketchy "legal
infrastructure." National laws contain many conflicting policies, many
of them simply for lack of occasion or motivation to harmonize them
internationally. Among these are regulations already mentioned af-
fecting the transfer of funds; company laws affecting the initiation
and terms of operation of companies, often to the disadvantage of
international companies; fiscal policies, especially unresolved prob-
lems of tax jurisdiction over international operations; antitrust and
other laws affecting the permissible methods of operation in different
countries.
5. The production context is especially vital to realism in consider-
ing any aspect of commercial policy affecting the less-developed
countries~ By definition, their position of underdevelopment means
"underproduction" and "underinvestment"-investment being liter-
ally and precisely the process of committing resources to production.
The question of their trade is, by the same token, a question of markets
for more effectively organized production. Special measures of en-
couragement and accommodation for their exports may well be in
order, but lacking appropriate investment support are almost certain
to fall short of maintainable gains in production.
The foregoing are only a few general areas of policy requirement
in the new world of international production. They are in a sense the
real "nontariff" barriers that embarrass international economic de-
velopment, and far outweigh the usually specified nontariff barriers
such as awkwardnesses of customs procedure.
The real objective of trade policy today is to facilitate international
production, and the cost of policies not appropriately responsive to
this objective will from now on be measurable in terms of the adequacy
of world economic development.
PAGENO="0125"
THE ECONOMICS OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE
BY Dr. Lewis E. Lloyd*
The subject of foreign trade has a special fascination for most
people. Almost everyone is inclined to take a strong stand for or
against it-often without any study of or even information about
foreign trade.
This is one of those problems that has a built-in emotional response.
It carries with it the lure of strange and distant places. It offers an
element of vicarious adventure. In addition, it appeals to the logic of
"one world" idealism-are we not all passengers on the same space-
ship, earth? And finally, many have been conditioned to believe that
trade and travel advance peace and that trade barriers and restrictions
cause war; and hence, the trade question reflects emotions involved in
the war and peace issue. .
In spite of the fact that foreign trade is much discussed, it is little
understood. In recent decades, writings on the subject in economic
textbooks and current literature have consisted largely of a recounting
of various arguments and slogans for "free trade," or "trade liberal-
ization" as it is more subtly called. Little attention is given to the
fundamental economics of foreign trade and to the accompanying
problems of international finance. Generally, no attempt is made to
examine and evaluate the special business problems and relationships
involved in operating in international markets. Even the history of
foreign trade is neglected.
In short, a simplistic presentation of the free trade theory and a
glowing statement of supposed advantages has more often sufficed
to reveal the emotional commitment of authors than to illuminate the
nature and consequences of foreign trade. In claiming that free trade
will solve most. of our domestic as well as our international problems,
advocates seldom get beyond the point of generalities, cliches, and the
uncritical use of statistics. This is not sufficient. Only by delving into
the basic economics of trade and examining all the ramifications can
adequate judgements be made concerning the best policies to follow
and how best to implement them.
This paper proposes to set forth the basic fundamentals of foreign
trade and to examine them in some depth. It will also give attention
to~ the practical implications that flow from the basic principles. In
this we shall need to extend our attention beyond the subject of trade
and take note of all aspects of the economic relations between nations.
Attention will be focused on the economic aspects of the problem
of world trade. Recognition has to be given, however, to the political
factors and to what extent the economic and political factors are
mutually supportive and to what extent antagonistic.
*Economist, The Dow Chemical Co.
117
PAGENO="0126"
118 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
TRADE HISTORY
From earliest, times, men have sought to increase the variety of
products available to them through trade. As early as 1000 B.C.,
Phoenician ships were bringing back silver from Spain, tin from
Britain, and tropical products from Africa, Asia, and the islands.
Much of the early exploration of the landmasses and later the oceans
of the earth were carried out in attempts to find better trade routes
and new sources of products.
Prior~ to the industrial revolution, even the most advanced civ~hza-
tions were based largely on natural products. Land vehicles, ships,
the timbers and roofs of most buildings, as well as furniture and even
utensils, were. largely made of wood. Special woods-spruce, cedar,
mahogany, teak and ebony-were prized for special applications. Min-
eral ores for lead, tin, iron, copper, and silver were only known in
those regions where the deposits were at or near the surface of the
earth's crust. Many desirable foods, spices, fibers, and medicinals were
available only in particular regions.
Accordingly, for thousands of years the variety of natural resources
which are useful to man were widely scattered and were a constant
incentive to farfiung trade.
In 1776, Adam Smith, a professor of moral philosophy at the Uni-
versity of Glasgow, published his revolutionary book, "Inquiry Into
the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations." Prior to this date,
economic thinking had been dominated by a theory called "mercan-
tilism." its central theme was the notion that a nation is prosperous
in proportion to its supply of the money commodity-gold or silver.
Common belief held that one way to increase the stock of precious
metals was to expand exports and limit imports, and thereby induce
an inflow of gold and silver bullion. This naturally required a host
of regulations and restrictions in the country as well as at the borders,
and with all a swarm of enforcing agents.
Adam Smith, in his "Wealth of Nations," developed a new concept.
He declared that wealth consisted in the quantity of goods and services
produced and freely exchanged. He proposed competition as an effec-
tive regulatory force in a free economic society and saw government
regulations as unnecessary overhead. Complete freedom for trade be-
tween areas and different countries was a natural extension of his
idea of division of labor and competition.
In Adam Smith's day, society was essentially nonindustrialized.
Commerce consisted largely of the exchange of natural products and
the products of handicraft. The world consisted of sovereign nations,
each with a limited variety of resources. Countries that could grow
wheat or corn were not suited for growing cotton. Regions that could
effectively grow sheep and supply wool were not effective producers
of wheat or bananas. As a consequence, individual items of food, fiber,
building materials, or mineral products were shipped from a country
having an abundance, in exchange for other natural items of food,
fiber, and the like.
As the industrial revolution developed and research brought newin-
sights and new competence to society, men have learned to substitute
synthetic produet~ foi ntttur~il ones. At on~ time, hôvn Wã~ the only
plastic material available. Now there are dozens of synthetic plastics
PAGENO="0127"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 119
suitable for a wide variety of end-use needs. At one time, man was
dependent entirely upon natural products for his drugs and medicines.
Today, most of our medicines are synthesized in factories. A century
ago, Goodrich learned to vulcanize rubber from the latex of trees and
make it an important industrial product. Today, we have literally
dozens of synthetic rubbers that for many uses are better than natural
rubber. For thousands of years, man was dependent solely upon animal
and vegetable fibers for clothing. Today, we make nylon superior to
the best silk and a host of other synthetic fibers to meet our needs. In
recent years, we have even begun to supply specialized food supple-
ments from our factories-products such as sulphur-bearing amino
acids and vitamins. Research and technology has greatly extended
man's choices.
As a result of these far-reaching developments, we are no longer
dependent upon specialized regions for many of our wants. It is not
surprising, therefore, that foreign trade has not kept pace with indus-
trial growth. In the United States, for example, the record shows that
our foreign trade has been progressively decreasing as a percent of our
total economy, even though it has increased in actual dollars. In 1800,
our foreign trade represented more than 12 percent of our gross na-
tional product. By 1875, it had decreased to 6 percent and in another
75 years to about 3 percent. Currently, it is in the 2 to 3 percent range.
Figure 1 shows the record of our imports as a percentage of gross
national product.
IMPORTS AS PERCENT OF G~0SS NATIONAL. PRO~J~1
Figure
PAGENO="0128"
120 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
Nor is this trend between internal and external commerce peculiar
to the United States. A look at the world situation indicates that the
experience is general. In all of the industrial countries of the world,
foreign trade has been decreasing in importance as the industrial
economies grew. Figures 2, 3 and 4 show curves for total world pro-
duction and total international trade. These curves only date back
to 1925, but such data as are available show that the divergence car-
ries back much farther.
TOTAL
WORLD PRODUCTION AND INTERNATIONAL TRADE
gOO - - 925-38 AND 1948-51
(I~0~X NUP1E~RS 1929 * 00)
.
150H
H
H
H
- -
PRO
- PIlE
OUCIION
ANATION
AL TFIAO
E (VO
LU~E)
- -
f
E
?
`i
I
j_j_
I
I-
`93.
1925 1929 1932
Figure 2
The bar chart in figure 5 compares more recent periods with 1870
and indicates also a progressively decreasing ratio of external to
internal trade.
Many writers in recent times have proclaimed the necessity of in-
creasing our foreign trade. The idea is presented as though any in-
crease, all possible increases without limit, would necessarily be good.
This is not a valid premise and is not a sound basis from which to build
a trade policy. Moreover, history seems to indicate that the economic
forces are moving in the direction of less reliance on foreign trade,
not more.
For a full understanding of foreign trade, it is necessary to start
with more fundamental questions, namely: Why do nations want
and need foreign trade? What `are the factors that determine the
amount and kind of trade that will be advantageous? What is the
political frame of reference `in which the trade occurs?
-~
~
`U
I
1-
_1_
4--too
PAGENO="0129"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE. POLICY 121
V)
Lu
I-)
z
C!)
0
PRIMARY PRODUCTS
WORU~ PRODUCTION t~ND INTERNATIONAL TRADE
l925-38~ND 948-51
(INDEX NLIM8FRS: `929W 100)
I
200
150
100
P 1001
- I) TER
PCTII
~ATI )NA
. TF
ADE
cvc
1
II L I
II
I
- - -
.- *
-
~
-
**.__*_
,
-
-
~
~.1
`.-~
~UM
~) -
200
I50
100
194$
/
/
50
925
1932
1935 i938
Figure 3
1951
50
Lu
a
z
`U
0
z
a
82-246-67----9
Figure 4
PAGENO="0130"
122 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
When we examine the objectives of trade, foreign or domestic, we
find that individuals trade to increase the range of choices and, hope-
fully,~ to lower the cost of satisfying human wants. How does trade
lower costs ? To answer this question, we shall need to examine some
fundamental economics.
The basic economic problem consists in this: Man has limitless
wants; he seeks to satisfy them with limited resources.
Man, being a rational animal having the power of memory, reason,
and imagination, persists in forever visualizing new wants which he.
would like to have satisfied. The natural resources and the human en-
ergy available to satisfy these wants are limited.
Faced with this basic dilemma, man must make choices. He must
decide howhe will allocate the scarce resources and toward what ends.
He must make decisions on what will be produced, and then other
decisions about how the production will be divided between the mem-
hers of society.
It is true that man has aspirations and objectives that are non-
economic, but most of them have economic consequences. For example,.
if he wishes to take time out to enjoy a beautiful sunset or to vacation
in the mountains, he thust forgo the rewards from productive effort
that he could have had.
THE EXCHANGE EQUATION
"Trade" is the term we use to describe the exchange process; the act
whereby we increase the variety of goods that we may enjoy. It is
an essential part of that production technique called "division of labor"
that permits specialization and large increases in efficiencies.
In a division-of-labor society, some workers produce a given goods.
or service and exchange this with other workers for the products of
1913
Figure 5
OBJECTIVES OF FOREIGN TRADE
PAGENO="0131"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 123
their labor. When a society becomes industrialized, barter is inadequate
to bring about the exchange of goods and services, and so money is
used as a tool to expedite the exchange. We can indicate this process
by the following equation:
GOODS & SERVICES~±MONEY~GOODS & SERVICES
It is important to nOte that the economic exchange process is not
complete with the first step of exchanging goods for money, but only
after the second step of exchanging the money for another economic
good. If one individual or group of individuals exchanges goods or
services for money, and retains or hoards part of this money, failing
to exchange it for other goods and services, then an imbalance results.
It means that others have production for which there is no market.
As we shall see shortly, this basic equation of economic exchange
portrays the economics of trade between nations as fully as within a
country. In the case of nations, however, if the export and import of
goods and services does not balance, then money will flow into or out
of the country and from this there are some important economic
consequences.
From this equation it is obvious that trade in and of itself does not
increase the amount of goods and services available. It merely brings
about redistribution of the goods already produced. If a nation or a
community wants a higher standard of living, it must either produce
more or find a way to get part of somebody else's production.
PRODtTcING A STANDARD OF LIVING
The standard of living of a society consists of the sum of the goods
and services that are produced. We can picture the four factors of
production and their relationship by the following equation:
MMW=NR(HE x T)'
where: MMW= man's material welfare
NR= Natural resources (land)
HE=Human energy (l'abor)
T=Tools (capital)
`= Idea (entrepreneurship)
Analysis indicates that natural resources are a fixed quantity. Man
may conserve them or utilize them more efficiently, but he cannot
"create" them. Human energy increases only slowly and even then is
balanced by an equal increase in consuming units. By contrast, the
use of tools and ideas may increase rapidly and without limit. The
use of tools permits the effective division of labor in a society. This
reaches its ultimate in the modern, automated factory system where
productivity can be very high. It is interesting to note that the factor
"tools," or "capital" as the economist calls it, multiplies human energy.
In the United States, we have substituted mechanical energy to the
point where something over 98 percent of our total energy input is
now mechanical. The ext~nt to which tools are available in a society
is proportional to the savings-stored-up human energy.
PAGENO="0132"
124 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
Equally if not more important is the input of ideas and innovation.
The entrepreneur who conceives an idea for a better product or proc-
ess, organizes the human and natural resources toward this idea, takes
action, and bears the risk for his decisions, is certainly as important,
perhaps even more important, than capital itself. Without new ideas
and innovation, we would merely replicate the present, and such is
the roadto a stagnant society.
It is clear that whenever a nation or a community wants to increase
its standard of living, the way to do it is to produce more. Not much
can be gained by trying to redivide the pie in different ways. It is
much more important to increase the total size of the pie. The in-
dividual has two options: he may produce more, or he may find a
way to get part of another's production. Society, however, has only
one option; it must produce more. Of course, countries as a part of
the total world society may, through gifts and aid programs, through
war reparations, or through unequal trade practices, conceivably bene-
fit at the expense of some other nation or peoples. This, however, is not
an effective way for a permanent improvement in a standard of living.
It is clear, then, that trade in and of itself is not a direct way to
increase living standards. There are, however, some ways in which
foreign trade may affect the factors of production. Examination re-
veals that there are five economic reasons why a nation may benefit
from international trade:
1. If a nation is lacking in certain essential raw materials, it will
need to import them. In fact, if a nation's sources yield essential raw
materials of only low grade, it may import them more cheaply from
nations with sources of high-grade minerals. Some nations are more
favored than others in the abundance of natural resources. Few, if
any, find themselves with adequate quality and quantity of all desired
raw materials. Hence, all nations will probably need foreign trade to
get certain raw materials.
2. A second reason why nations may want foreign trade is to get a
full variety of animal and plant life. Nations with an overabundance
of suitable soil and climate for growing certain products may profit-
ably sell these in world markets. Coffee, bananas, rubber, and spices
are products, for example, that grow readily in tropical areas, while
edible grains and food animals are more efficiently produced in tem-
pered climates.
3. Another reason for foreign trade is to obtain a mass market.
Whenever production can be mechanized, unit costs decrease in pro-
portion to the size of the production unit. Outstanding examples are
large steel mills, petroleum and chemical plants, and the production-
line automobile plants. Large-scale production is not possible, however,
unless there is a mass market. Wherever a country is too small to rep-
resent by itself a mass market, it will need trade with its neighbors
to expand the market and get the advantages of large-scale pro-
duction.
4. Conversely, a nation may profit by foreign trade if its technology,
ingenuity, and inventiveness lag behind. By trading services and craft
products with neighboring nations for mass-produced items, a back-
ward nation can obtain manufactured products not otherwise available
to it. Industrial nations can get new and/or patented products that it
does not yet produce.
PAGENO="0133"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF TJ.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 125
5. Finally, the balance of supply and demand is constantly shifting
in each nation-crop failures, temporary imbalance in new capacity,
et cetera. Foreign trade often is able to bridge the demand/supply
gap in individual countries on a current basis.
FREE TRADE THEORY
The extension of the ideas of division of labor and free markets
to a worldwide basis has been formalized in the free trade theory. This
proposes that in the absence of interferences, division of labor would
take place on a worldwide basis; that, as a consequence, man-hour
productivity would increase everywhere and this would mean higher
standards of living for all. It would result in the use of the best, most
readily available raw materials, the best locations, the most effective
human energy, and the best ideas, coupled with the best tools to bring
about the lowest cost production. The theory proposes that under such
conditions individuals would be employed at their highest skills, the
most readily accessible and highest quality raw materials would be
utilized, and the ultimate in mechanization reached. In other words,
this theory holds that if there is complete freedom for trade through-
out the world, man-hour productivity, per capita income, and living
standards will be maximized. The theory also holds that unilateral
adoption of free trade will benefit any nation that practices it, whether
or not other nations reciprocate, and that any nation that does not
practice free trade cannot obtain the highest standard of living for
its people.
The free trade theory does not even require that each nation be able
to do something better than all other nations, but merely that each
nation be engaged in that production which it can do better than
anything else. Dr. C. E. Griffin, professor emeritus, University of
Michigan, states the principle of comparative advantage as follows:
"If a country is blessed with advantages it always has greater advan-
tages in some lines than in others. It will, therefore, gain most if it
devotes its efforts to the things it can do best and exchanges the
products of these efforts for things in which its advantage is least."'
The advantages proposed for free trade are both desirable and con-
vincing, since man seeks to satisfy his wants with the least possible
effort. The free trade theory is very appealing. In an ideal world, free
trade might be as perfect in practice as in theory, but to fully evaluate
its application, we must examine the premises on which it is based and
see to what extent they are realized in the real world. We shall see
that many conditions must be fulfilled if free trade is to give the re-
sults claimed.
For several decades, the discussions concerning international trade
have focused attention primarily, in fact almost exclusively, on the
question of tariffs. There has been a tacit assumption that the elimina-
tion of tariffs would in and of itself lead to the advantages of free trade.
Careful examination shows that the free trade theory was conceived
as a basic natural law. Its attention is centered on division of labor
based on natural advantage-natural advantage associated with either
1Clare E. Griffin, "A Tariff Policy for Modern Times," Michigan Business Review, vol. V,
No. 5 (September 1953), p. 9.
PAGENO="0134"
126 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
inherent individual skills or advantages in natural resources and cli-
mate. Although the statement of the theory does not say so, it is in-
herent in its major premise that other factors, let us call them un-
natural advantages, are all equal. It means that all the ways other
than tariffs by which governments may interfere with or structure
the international marketplace must be eliminated or equalized. In
other words, it assumes that all of the international economic relations
of the peoples of nations are on a completely free market basis. When
the economic engineer seeks to apply the free trade theory, he finds
that, as a minimum, the following conditions would have to be met in
order for the proposed results to be obtained:
1. No government enterprises.
2. No government subsidies.
3. No major variation in taxes on business.
4. Uniform business laws, uniformly enforced.
~S. No immigration restrictions.
6. Complete free markets in exchange rates and movement of
capital.
7. No overriding defense requirements.
8. No cartels.
When government enters production or engages in state trading,
prices are based on political considerations and not economic costs.
As a consequence, international trade which involves government
enterprise will not generally lead to an international division of
labor based purely on economic efficiency. Trade and economic pro-
grams that are tailored to political objectives have shown a history
of low economic efficiency. This is not surprising because the political
rewards system penalizes mistakes so much more severely than it
rewards success.
In similar manner, international trade based on government sub~
sidies-whether it be tax forgiveness, whether it be government guar-
anties of loans, whether it be sales of subsidized products below home
prices, or by whatever means-all subvert the price mechanism in the
economic allocation process. In fact, the whole object of a subsidy is
to negate the consequences of the decision of the marketplace. Thus,
subsidies thwart the objective of free trade.
If there are major variations between countries in the taxation of
businesses, then government-imposed taxes will be a major factor in
determining the economic division of labor. This will thwart the
allocation based on true economic costs.
In similar manner, laws governing business activity, man-hours,
overtime payments, minimum wage rates, safety standards, and vaca-
tion and holiday practices, influence production costs. However so-
cially valuable such regulations may be, when there are wide differ-
ences between different countries this may influence the allocation of
production more than does true economic efficiency.
Human energy-labor-is one of the key factors of production. If
maximum efficiency is desired, then workers must be free to move so
that the most effective combination of natural resources, workers, capi-
tal, and ideas may be combined.
In a capitalistic, industrialized society, capital is a very important
factor of production. Accordingly, there should be no restrictions on
the movement of capital across national borders nor on the earnings
PAGENO="0135"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 127
from the employment of resources in any given area. In like manner,
there should be a complete free market in exchange rates so that the
exchange rates can adjust between countries and properly relate
changes in productivity and wage rates.
No nation will be willing to truly face the ultimate in international
division of labor unless it feels secure from war and the necessity of
maintaining an adequate national defense. Modern warfare is heavily
based upon technology and the products thereof. The implications for
national defense are clear.
Finally, businessmen are themselves inclined to try to thwart the
verdict of the marketplace. One way is to form cartels. In so doing,
producers either collude in setting prices or on dividing the market by
territory. Cartel practices are outlawed in the United States but have
been a regular part of export practices of the European and Japanese
business communities. A cartel may set export prices at, above, or be-
low domestic prices, depending on the immediate objective. If the ex-
port is primarily to move surplus, then the export price may be set low.
Under other conditions and especially to underdeveloped countries, the
export price is often held above domestic prices.
Basically, cartels are formed to reduce or eliminate competition. In
foreign trade, cartel pricing may be used to drive competition out of
business, or to prevent potential competitors from getting started.
After the competition has been destroyed or blocked, then prices are
raised to higher and lucrative levels.
Individual firms may also treat the foreign market different than
the home market. It is not uncommon for a producer who has some
unused plant capacity to reason that, on an incremental basis, the cost
of producing additional units, up to capacity, would be very low. Fur-
ther, that he could sell the extra production at lower prices in foreign
countries without disturbing his home price, and thus add some incre-
mental profit. This is, in fact, a very common practice. It distorts the
price mechanism, causing it to give a false signal. The undesirability
of this type of short-range, shortsighted practice is indicated by the
`derogatory term, "dumping."
Thus, business practices may also thwart the international market-
place in its allocative function of maximizing efficiency. Within a
country, government regulations may be used to prevent collusion and
reinforce competition. No government, however, can control what the
nationals of a foreign sovereign nation do. The most it can do is to
offset at the border the consequences of restrictive practice by foreign
producers.
When a theory is applied under conditions different than those which
its premises assume, the results are likely to be quite different than
promised. When we look at the real world of commerce, we see that
there are many ways in which governments structure and interfere in
the international marketplace, ways that thwart the ideal division of
labor.
To be realists, we must do one of two things: either we must suc-
ceed in eliminating all interferences in the international marketplace
and accept a large degree of laissez-faire in economic affairs; or we
must recognize that we are not dealing with an ideal situation. It may
be that the structure of tariffs that has been widely used for many de-
PAGENO="0136"
128 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
cades is a practical way of dealing with the imperfections in the inter-
national marketplace when the world is divided into sovereign nations.
It is interesting to note that when six countries of Europe sought to
establish a Common Market, they had to wrestle with these very prob-
lems. As they have eliminated, step by step, the tariffs between each
other, they have had to try to harmonize the other factors that im-
pinge upon economic efficiency. They have permitted the freedom for
workers to move from country to country. They are seeking to har-
monize their fringe benefit programs. They are moving in ihe direc-
tion of harmonizing business laws-antitrust and patent laws, etc.
They are making progress toward harmonization of business taxes,
and they are looking forward to the day of a common currency, which
would eliminate the exchange problems.
This is not surprising, because in the great free~ trade area between
the 50 States of the United States, we have met or approached all of
these requirements in the premises of the free trade theory.
Theoreticians have steadily set their face toward the ideal of free
trade and the maximum division of labor. There is reason to doubt
that a maximum division of labor for maximum efficiency on a world-
wide basis would, in fact, be a desirable situation. Maximum division
of labor would carry with it the risk of maximum instability. Com-
munities, companies, even individuals, find it desirable to spread the
risk-to diversify, to apply the insurance principle. Even the Detroit
auto industry has seen fit to spread its production units into every
corner in the United States and to expand into many other products
in addition to automobile production.
Stability is becoming an increasingly prominent objective of indus-
trial systems. It is doubtful that, given a free choice, workers would
choose the small increments of productivity increase over the risks of
maximum specialization. Countries that are essentially "one industry"
countries-coffee dominance in Brazil, copper in Chile, and tin in
Bolivia-are in frequent trouble due to instability in fluctuating
markets. The ideal would surely be some appropriate accommodation
between diversification and maximum specialization.
In the economic reasons for foreign trade, we noted the need for a
mass market. The economics of total cost, including distribution to
the consumer, indicates that there is a practical limit to the advantages
from specialization as between industrial countries. For example, it
would not be economically desirable to have the United States make
all of the automobiles and Europe make all of the steel. Both Europe
and the United States have ample requirements to permit maximum
savings from large-scale production in both of these products. To
ship half of the cars to Europe and half of the steel to the United
States would add unnecessary shipping costs.
The free trade theory presupposes a world marketplace that is un-
hampered by government restrictions and interferences of any sort. It
assumes a worldwide dissemination of pertinent product information.
It assumes freedom to advertise and transmit knowledge about prod-
ucts. And, in a sense, it also assumes an openmindedness about for-
eigners and foreign products-no nationalistic bias.
To what extent are these conditions met in actual practice? What
are the conditions and special hazards that the businessman meets and
must adjust to in international commerce? To what extent do govern-
ments place special hurdles that impede international trade?
PAGENO="0137"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 129
In actual practice, most countries apply a whole host of proce-
dures, taxes, and restraints on imports. Some countries, like the United
States, rely primarily on duties. Others have, in addition to duties,
extensively utilized direct quantitative restrictions and more subtle
regulatory practices. The United States has been extensively reducing
trade barriers for two decades; by contrast, many other countries
have been increasing restrictions, especially in the area of nontariff
barriers.
The U.S. Department of Commerce, Business and Defense Services
Administration, and the Bureau of International Commerce, have set
forth a definition of "nontariff trade barriers" and listed many prac-
tices which are or can be used to impede imports:
DEFINITION OF "NONTARIFF TRADE BARRIER"
A nontariff trade barrier is defined as any law, regulation, policy,
or practice of a government, other than the import duty proper, which
has a restrictive impact on imports. For purposes of this question-
naire, this definition does not include impediments to trade resulting
from the operation of foreign cartels, private monopolies, or other
nongovernmental business practices.
Some nontariff restrictions may be specially designed to insulate seg-
ments of the domestic economy from the effects of imports from for-
eign competition. There are, however, many other reasons for these
barriers including the conservation of scarce foreign exchange, the
promotion of economic development, the protection of domestic busi-
ness against unfair competition from abroad, the protection of the
public health, safety and morals, the protection of the national secu-
rity, the collection of revenue, and the control of imports of products
for the public account in favor of domestic procurement. Some of
these barriers are recognized as legitimate under international com-
mitments to the extent that they are not abused.
The following is an illustrative list of trade regulations and prac-
tices which may be so drawn or administered as to have a restrictive
effect on the sale of U.S. goods abroad, and should be considered as
nontariff trade barriers.
A. CUSTOMS LAW
(1) Regulations governing the right to import.
(2) Valuation and appraisement of imported goods.
(3) Classification of goods for customs purposes.
(4) Marking, labeling, and packaging requirements.
(5) Documentary requirements (including consular invoices).
(6) Measures to counteract disruptive marketing practices, e.g.,
antidumping and countervailing duties.
(7) Penalties (for examp'e, fees charged for mistakes on docu-
ments).
(8) Fees assessed at customs to cover cost of processing (handling)
goods.
(9) Administrative exemptions (for example, administrative au-
thority to permit duty-free entry of goods for certain purposes).
(10) `Treatment of samples and advertising material.
PAGENO="0138"
130 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
(11) Prohibited and restricted imports.
(12) Administration of customs law provisions (delay in process-
ing goods, inadequate or delayed publication of customs information).
B. OTHER LEGISLATION SPECIFICALLY APPLICABLE TO IMPORTS, UNDER
WHICH RESTRICTIONS ARE APPLIED PRIOR TO ENTRY OF GOODS
(1) Taxes.
(2) Balance-of-payments restrictions (including quantitative im-
port restrictions, licensing fees, prior deposit requirements, import sur-
charges, credit controls on import transactions, multiple exchange
rates).
(3) Restrictions imposed to protect individual industries (includ-
ing measures to protect infant industries).
(4) Taxes applied to imports to compensate for indirect taxes
borne by comparable domestic goods (European turnover taxes).
(5) iRestrictions applied for national security reasons (other than
under customs law).
(6) State trading (or the operation of enterprises granted exclu-
sive or special import privileges).
(7) Sanitary regulations (other than under customs law).
(8) Food, drug, cosmetic, and pharmaceutical regulations.
(9) Patent, trademark, and copyright regulations.
* (10) Shipping and insurance regulations.
C. OTHER LEGISLATIVE AND ADMINISTRATIVE TRADE BARRIERS
* (1) Government purchasing regulations and practices.
(2) Domestic price control regulations.
(3) Restrictions on the internal sale, distribution and use of
products:
(a) Screen quotas and other restrictions affecting motion pic-
ture film and television program material.
(b) Specifications, standards, and safety requirements affect-
ing such products as electrical equipment, machinery and auto-
mobiles.
(c) Internal taxes that bear more heavily on US. goods than
on domestic products (for example, automobile taxes in Europe
based on horsepower rating).
(4) Restrictions on advertising of goods.
(5) Restrictions on display of goods at trade fairs and exhibitions.
It will be useful to single out a few of the more important nontariff
barriers and to examine them specifically:
1. State trading. Obviously, nations such as the U.S.S.R. and
its satellites, which set up a political bureau to plan and handle
all foreign trade, have moved the foreign trade sector of their
economy completely into the political arena. While only a few
nations openly apply state trading, many other nations in apply-
ing licenses, quotas and the like, start by developing a central
plan which includes a specific level of expected exports and
imports.
2. Import licenses are widely used means of controlling im-
ports. Most of the underdeveloped countries use licenses exten-
sively. Many countries, even when not faced with unfavorable
PAGENO="0139"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 131
trade or balance of payments, leave their import license proce-
dures on the books. They merely make licenses easy to get when
imports are desired.
3. Some countries require import deposits, which run from a
modest amount up to as much as 200 percent of the value of the
merchandise. This is, in effect, a forced loan against the foreign
exporter. These deposit systems have been extensively used by
South American countries. Even more important than the interest
cost is the loss in purchasing power through a rapid and continu-
ing price inflation that reduces the purchasing power of the
local currency.
4. Foreign exchange allocations of currency for imports. This
has been extensively used in Japan and in some Latin American
countries.
5. Price controls have been used by India and Belgium to limit
specific imports.
6. Specific requirements such as field testing of pesticides by
West Germany and France, or difficulty in registering pharma-
ceutical products in Spain.
7. Excessive delays in the clearance of import licenses and ex-
cessive paperwork are procedural impediments in a number of
countries, notably in South America.
8. Cartel arrangements which may be used to freeze out other
potential suppliers, as was the case in the EEC for the distribu-
tion of ammonium sulphate fertilizer to preclude U.S. entry into
that market.
9. The use of turnover, value added or cascade consumption
taxes and special surcharges in some EEC countries are another
potent nontariff barrier.
In moving to harmonize the taxes on business within the EEC, sev-
eral countries are adding or adjusting their value added tax. This
becomes, significant because whereas the total tax against business in
Europe does not differ greatly from ours, in most countries half or
more of the corporate tax is in the form of a value added or turnover
tax, whereas most of our corporate tax is profits tax. When we ship
to Germany, we will already have paid income tax on the total income
and will, in `addition, have to pay a border tax equal to the turnover
tax that would have been paid if the product had been made in Ger-
many; so the total tax on exports from the United States to Germany
will be considerably higher than on German production.
By contrast, when a German firm-the same is true for many Euro-
pean countries-ships to the United States, it does not have to pay
the value added tax that it pays on domestic sales. Thus, the tax on
a U.S. export to Germany is about twice as much as the tax that a
German producer pays on exports to the United States. This is one
example whTch shows how taxing differences can affect international
trade.
U.S. TRADE EXPERIENCE
National trade policy, if it is to be successful, must be sound. To
be sound, it must recognize and accommodate to the facts of the real
world: a world composed of sovereign nations and less-than-perfect
men. Men who are often shortsighted and seek short-term gain over
PAGENO="0140"
132 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
longer term benefits. A world in which in proportion as political forces
are injected into the economic process, short-term or irrelevant cri-
teria influence decisions and, as a consequence, basic factors are sub-
merged.
It will be instructive to examine the recent history of U.S. foreign
trade and economic policy as a frame of reference for perfecting the
future. Past policies need to be examined and evaluated in order to
judge what changes are required for the future.
It will probably be adequate to look at our foreign economic his-
tory in the period since World War II. Important changes in foreign
economic policy that represent a break with our total history occurred
in the early postwar years. The practical policy question is whether
these policies should be continued and extended or whether some basic
and important changes are necessary.
One break with the past was our initiating and joining the organiza-
tion known as "General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade" (GATT).
By this step we shifted from bilateral to multilateral trade negotia-
tions and agreements. The Trade Agreements Acts have authorized
the Chief Executive to negotiate reciprocal tariff cuts with other na-
tions. Since 1948, these negotiations have been carried on through the
GATT organization on a multilateral basis.
It is difficult to determine the average level bf tariff rates for any
given nation and, even more difficult, to judge their degree of protec-
tion. It seems clear, however that, on the average, U.S. tariff rates
since 1934 have been reduced by more than 75 percent and that the
recent GATT negotiations will have reduced the remaining tariff level
by an estimated 35 percent. The reason the average is less than 50
percent, authorized by the "Trade Expansion Act of 1962," is that
already many of our tariffs were down to 8 percent or less, and these
low tariffs were reduced only 20 percent instead of the 50 percent on
other products.
The argument for the Trade Agreements Act in 1934 and for its
many extensions since has always been that reciprocal tariff reduc-
tion would increase our exports and thereby improve our economy. We
have already seen that, on the basis of theory, actual trade practices
of other countries, and long-term history, this is a forlorn expecta-
tion. Nevertheless, we should examine the trade data for the past
couple of decades and see what indeed has happened to our foreign
trade.
Figure 6 shows the U.S. imports and exports in the postwar years.
The upper curve shows the exports as reported by the Department
of `Commerce; and the dashed curve, the imports.
A significant part of these exports, however, are goods that we buy
with our own money and ship overseas. Included are sizable quantities
of agricultural products sold under Public Law 480 to the less-
developed nations of the world. These are paid for in the country's
local currency and are `blocked so that they cannot `be converted to
dollars and must be spent in the country. To date, about the only use
we have been able to make of these currencies is to build elaborate
embassies and to finance congressional junkets. So these sales are, in
fact, a gift. Also included as exports are the food supplies that we
ship as relief to famine areas. Included also are sizable shipments to
our military establishments overseas. And finally, included are annil-
PAGENO="0141"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
YEARS
FIGURE 6
133
1970
ally $2 to $3 billion of agricultural products which are subsidized.
The grain and produce that are under our price-support programs are
sold on the world market well below the support price at home. The
difference constitutes a subsidy, which has averaged about 25 percent.
When these exports, which are paid for with American dollars or sub-
sidized, are subtracted from the export data, the so-called trade sur-
plus vanishes.
We follow the practice of tabulating our foreign trade on the basis
of FOB values (for imports this is the price at the foreign factory or
shipping point). Practically all other nations use a CIF basis (cost,
including insurance and ocean freight-that is, landed cost). Prac-
tically all of our imports and most of our exports move on foreign
bottoms. In the case of imports, therefore, we pay out dollars for the
landed cost. The ocean freight, insurance, and other transport costs
have to be added to arrive at a landed cost. Several studies have in-
dicated that this ranges from 10 to 25 percent. One study shows an
average of 17 percent.
In figure 7 the import curve has been converted to a landed cost
basis by adding a modest 15 percent. It is clear from this data that our
commercial exports (those sold in competition in the world market)
and our imports on a CIF basis for which we pay out dollars has not
been in balance in the past two decades, and that we do not have a
favorable trade balance but a net unfavorable trade balance-gifts can
hardly be called trade-and that the dollar value of imports has ac-
tually grown more than commercial exports since the end of the 1940's.
Moreover, even the adjusted exports shown in figure 7 exaggerates
our competitiveness. A significant portion of our exports are from
U.S. firms to their overseas subsidiaries. Department of Commerce
data shows that this has varied from $21/2 to $3 billion in recent years.
0
1945
950 1955 1960 1965
PAGENO="0142"
134 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
0
1945 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970
YEARS
FIGURE 7
In many cases, these exports were not competitive and were justified
solely on the basis of internal corporate accounting.
It is clear that we not only do not have a favorable trade balance
but actually an unfavorable one as far as our competitive commercial
exports are concerned. Instead of our trade data indicating that there
would be a large growth in our exports relative to imports if all tariffs
were lowered or eliminated, it indicates the exact opposite; namely,
that we are not competitive in world markets and that, in the absence
of tariff protection, imports can be expected to climb faster than ex-
ports. Moreover, there are other independent evidences that we are,
on the average, noncoinpetitive with efficient foreign producers.
One such is the changing character of our exports and imports since
the early 1950's. Dating back to early this century, the United States
imported primarily tropical products, raw materials, and products of
low labor content, and exported primarily manufactured goods. In the
past decade and a half, this has been reversed. We now export, on
balance, more agricultural products, raw materials, scrap iron, chem-
ical raw materials, and products of low labor content, than manu-
factured products. More than half of our imports are now manufac-
tured goods of high labor content-cameras, typewriters, automobiles,
motorcycles, TV's, dyes, medicinals, etc. (In chemicals, for example,
U.S. exports of crude coal tar products increased 746 percent from
1951 to 1960. In the same period, our exports of coal tar dyes and
stains decreased by 32 percent, and our imports increased by 51 per-
cent.) This striking change in the character of our trade is a clear-cut
indication that our labor costs are pricing us out of world markets.
A final evidence of our noncompetitiveness is a continuing chronic
negative balance of payments. Our merchandise exports and imports
are, of course, only a part of our economic exchange with other na-
PAGENO="0143"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 135
tions. We have to look at the balance of payments to see the whole
picture. The economist speaks of "goods and services" and our inter-
national economic relations must include the service sector as well as
the goods sector.
The balance of payments is the figure that shows the balance or
imbalance of our total economic exchange with other nations. It in-
cludes the following:
The net of foreign trade.
The net of tourism.
The net of services (shipping, insurance, et cetera).
The net of capital and investment flow.
The net on gifts and loans.
It turns out that our foreign aid policy represents another break
with previous history in our foreign economic relations. The massive
outflow of dollars through foreign aid gifts have had important impli-
cations for our balance of payments. Nevertheless, the most funda-
mental factor relative to a balance of payments is the competitiveness
of a given economy in world markets. If, for example, our competitive
position were favorable enough, all of the foreign aid dollars would
be spent for our products, and thus, the gifts would not have an in-
fluence on the balance of payments.
As shown in figure 8, we have had a negative balance of payments
every year since 1949, except for the year 1957 when the Suez crisis
~LANCEOPAY~~S
B U.. IONS OF OLL
2
0
-I
-2
-.4
~-
~
-
SURPLUS
DEFICIT
~t~WI,
-~
`p
ON CURRENT ~~COUNT
-5
$950 $955 $960 $965 $970
YEARS
FIGURE 8
PAGENO="0144"
136 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
forced Europe to buy quantities of oil from the dollar area. This means
that year after year more dollars have left our shores than have re-
turned. This continuing and growing deficit exists because foreigners
who get dollars from our imports, from tourism, and from gifts can,
on the average, use these dollars to buy elsewhere cheaper than in the
United States.
As a result of the continuing outflow of dollars, foreigners have
built up dollar claims against us, and in addition, have claimed almost
half of the gold that we had at the end of the war. Figure 9 shows
our gold reserve, which was $24.6 billion in 1948 and 1949, has now
been reduced to about $13 billion. Gross foreign dollar claims are now
about $33 billion. The net figure is about $26 billion, after subtracting
our claims against other currencies.
Source: American Institute for Economic Research
FIGURE 9
PAGENO="0145"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 137
Figure 10 shows the amount of gold we would have left if at any
point in the postwar years all of the dollar claims had been cashed for
gold. Also shown is the amount of gold required to meet our bank
reserve requirements. By early 1965 this latter had gotten up to almost
$14 billion. When the gold cover was removed from Federal Reserve
deposits in February 1965, the domestic banking requirement dropped
to a little more than $6 billion, but has since moved back up to $10
billion.
Source: American Institute for Economic Research
It is clear that since 1960 we have not had enough gold to meet
all of our foreign commitments, let alone our domestic banking re-
quirements. It is this shortage of gold backing that has reduced
foreign confidence in the dollar and has toppled it from its former
position as the most sought after currency in the world.
GOLD R~SEAV~ FOR
IEY-CREDIT SYSTEM vs. ACTUAL GOLD
A~TEL~ FOREIGN SHORT-TERM
I I I I I
FIarn~E 10
82-246-67-10
PAGENO="0146"
138 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
CAUSES OF Loss or COMPETITIVE PosmoN
There are two basic causes for our noncompetitive position and its
unfavorable consequences for the balance of payments. One has to do
with the inflation process, and the other with rigidities in the foreign
exchange market. A nation's competitive position is determined by its
wage rate divided by its productivity vis-a-vis other nations. At a
given exchange rate, if the wage rate divided by productivity turns
out to be the same for two nations, then they will on the average be
competitive. If the wage rate in one country is twice that of the other
and its productivity is twice that of the other, they will have the same
average unit cost factor.
But wage rates and productivity factors may change differently for
different countries over time. When this happens in a truly free in-
ternational market, the exchange rate will change to keep the average
unit cost factor the same.
Another important change took place following World War II,
namely, the establishment of the International Monetary Fund and its
control of exchange rates. Exchange rates are now fixed by this in-
ternational bureaucracy and are not subject to fluctuation in a free
market as they were early this century. Here we have a political rigid-
ity which affects one important part of the international market.
The present exchange rates were fixed soon after World War II,
long before anyone could foresee the resurgence of Europe and Japan
and the phenomenal increase that they have made in productivity.
Their productivity has increased about twice as fast as ours, and they
have not matched their rapid productivity gains with equally large
wage rate increases. As a consequence, they have improved their com-
petitive position vis-a-vis the United States.
INFLATION
Another important factor is the inflation which we have sustained
and which has not been matched by any devaluation of the dollar or
exchange rate adjustment.
We noted previously that money is a tool used to assist in the eco-
nomic exchange process. If the amount of money is kept in step with
the amount of goods and services to be exchanged, the exchange proc-
ess can operate smoothly. If, however, hoarding (which draws money
from circulation) or counterfeiting (which adds excess money) dis-
torts the money supply in relation to the economy, the economic ex-
change process is disrupted.
Private counterfeiting, although constantly being tried, has never
become large. The creation of worthless, paper, fiat money by mone-
tization of the Federal debt, however, has reached major proportions.
This type of "printing press" money has an effect on the exchange
process similar to that of private counterfeiting. During World War
II, Korea, and subsequent years, Federal expenditures have often ex-
ceeded income. A substantial portion of the bonds covering this debt
has been placed in the Federal Reserve System as new and additional
money created out of "thin air." In this way, more than $100 billion
of "printing press" money has been injected into the banking system
and this has served as a base for further credit expansion. By this
PAGENO="0147"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 139
process of monetization of the Federal debt, the ratio of money supply
to goods and services to be exchanged has more than doubled. There
are far-reaching consequences from such extensive monetary inflation.
One is the increase in prices. In the postwar years, two dollars (one
good dollar and one "printing press" dollar) have been coming to the
marketplace to bid for a dollar's worth of goods. Since the market
couldn't tell one from the other, prices have been bid up to twice
prewar level. In fact, the price index indicates that the dollar is only
worth 43 cents in terms of 1939 purchasing power. Not only have
prices of products been bid up, but also wages. The price of labor
has gone up along with, in fact a little more than, the price of goods.
This monetary inflation has had important consequences for our
balance of payments. The basic difficulty becomes evident when we
examine the exchange equation:
GOLD
11~
GOODS & SERVICES~DOLLARS~GOODS & SERVICES
Normally, when foreigners sell us goods or services or by whatever
means get dollars, they would spend these dollars for our goods and
services. If this balanced out, there would be no distortion. As a re-
sult, however, of our monetization of Federal debt, the prices of our
goods and services have more than doubled. There is one economic
good however-gold-that still has the same price as was fixed in
1934; namely, $35 an ounce. Thus, gold is the cheapest commodity that
we offer to the world. It is not surprising that foreigners prefer to
trade our dollars for gold or to hold these dollars against the day when
they might wish to trade them for gold. So long as confidence remains,
the advantage of holding dollars in the form of Treasury notes or
bills is that they pay interest. When dollars are cashed in for gold,
not only is there no interest payment, but there is in fact a storage
charge.
The monetary inflation and its consequent higher labor costs and
prices is the basic reason why our products are not more competitive
in world markets. To be sure, the foreign aid dollar outflow has ag-
gravated the problem, but fundamentally our unit costs have advanced
higher than that of our aggressive competitors in the Common Market
and Japan. We cannot hope to get back to a permanent balance in our
foreign accounts until we recover our competitive position. The
straightforward and simple way to do this would be to establish a
free exchange rate or at least widen the limits for fluctuation so that
supply and demand forces can make some real adjustment. In this
way, the relative value of the currencies of different countries would
again truly reflect the average wage level divided by productivity,
and hence, the average price level in each country.
FuTTn~E TRADE PoLIcY
First, in looking at the question of future trade policy, we need to
recognize that trade is not an isolated event but only part of our
total foreign economic relations. We need to develop a policy that
covers and coordinates all of the economic relations between other
PAGENO="0148"
140 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
nations and ourselves-trade, tariffs, quantitative controls, dumping
practices, cartels, patents, exchange rates, capital transfers and re-
patriation, tourism, and aid.
We must also recognize that theories do not operate in a vacuum;
that the real world differs substantially from the idealized conditions
visualized by the free trade theory. It is essential that our policies be
based on the real situation, on reasonable expectations of the behavior
of sovereign nations, and on enlightened self interest:
1. We should recognize that the system of trade controls that
nations have developed through the years has, in fact, been a
system. That tariffs, for example, are only one of the ways of
"handicapping" in the world marketplace. In part, tariffs have
been used to compensate for other restrictive practices. Further,
we should realize that of all the various forms of government
restrictions on trade, tariffs are much less objectionable than are
quotas, licensing, and other quantitative restrictions. We should
be extremely leery of moving in the direction of quotas and li-
censing in areas where tariffs have been reduced or eliminated,
and as a consequence, industry and jobs jeopardized. Quantitative
controls inject government policy decisions deeply into the eco-
nomic process. It becomes difficult, even to the point of impos-
sibility, for government regulations to avoid inequities as be-
tween individual enterprises. If we find that on the products of
some industries our tariff rates have been reduced too much, it
* would be better to increase the tariffs than to get involved with
licensing and quotas.
2. As a first step, we should recognize the basic cause of our
* difficulties and readjust the exchange ratios of the various cur-
rencies to reflect the average unit costs of each country. The sim-
pie way to discover the relative average costs would be to rein-
stitute a free market in foreign exchange. Those who claim that
this would disrupt foreign trade because of uncertainties of for-
eign exchange rates apparently have never heard about "hedging"
by buying exchange futures.
An important side effect of floating exchange rates, or at least
a widening of the margins within which exchange may fluctuate,
is that it would take care of the so-called international liquidity
problem. Experience indicates that when free market forces can
adjust the exchange between currencies, very little of the money
commodity-gold-is required because there are few imbalances
that have to be corrected by the shipment of gold. It is the pres-
ent system of rigid exchange rates which makes almost any level
of gold reserve inadequate to meet all of the imbalances that
tend to pile up.
3. We need to put an end to our Federal deficits and monetary
inflation in the United States in order that we do not further
aggravate the problem of pricing ourselves out of world markets
through the well-known inflation process.
4. We need to substantially revamp and improve our anti-
dumping laws. In a world of sovereign nations, it is inevitable
* that producers with any idle capacity will seek to sell in foreign
markets, at dumping prices if necessary. Such a producer can
always justify his lower foreign price by incremental costing of
PAGENO="0149"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE ~ouc~ 141
his extra production and by reasoning that dumping overseas
doe's not affect his market price `at home. This kind of distress
selling, and even more so, direct predatory pricing with an at-
tempt to drive localized production from the market, is disrup-
tive of ordinary marketing processes. It gives false signals both
to consumers and producers as to the relative value of competing
products. International trade will grow on a sound basis in pro-
portion as dumping practices can be minimized.
The low levels of tariffs to which we are now committed will be an
open invitation to extensive dumping practices; therefore, we need
to prepare the best possible defenses against this type of ma'rket
disruption.
A sound antidumping law would establish dual criteria as a basis
for dumping penalties, (1) that there be, in fact, sales below fair
market value; (2) that there be injury to producers in the country
of import.
The crux of the matter comes in the definition of the terms in these
two criteria.
To arrive at a definition of dumping, a fair market value must be
established. Important criteria for the definition of "fair market
value" are: (1) that it should represent a price at which the product
is freely `offered in the country where produced; (2) in normal whole-
`sale quantities, unless the import is similar to a level of trade in the
product for which there is special pricing and conditions of sale in
the home market-"condition of sale" here referring to end use, type
`of shipment, duration and volume of the commitment, et cetera;
(3) that the price be `taken as f.a.'s. (free alongside ship) or f.'o.b. ship's
rail (depending on whether packaged or bulk cargo) at the time and
place of shipment or at the nearest port; (4) that cnlculations of cur-
rency exchange rates used in any antidu'mping case 1)e the actual in-
volved in trade transactions where there is a difference from official
rates.
It i's important that an injury test be relevant to the actual market
conditions. Any suitable definition should include the following
criteria:
1. An antidumping statute should recognize no injury for prod-
ucts that are noncompetitive. For this, the U.S. criteria~ of "like
and similar" in present legislation in defining competitive prod-
ucts seems to be a good one.
2. There should be a presumption of no injury where import
sales are not below the prevailing price in the country of impor-
tation. There should be no penalty for imports that meet the
going price.
3. There should be a finding of injury if the import is sold
at prices below the prevailing price in the country of importa-
tion and producers have capacity to supply 10 percent or more
of the home market.
4. Each product or product line should be considered an in-
dustry in and of itself. An injury test which looks to the average
profitability of an industry or a company therein is meaning-
less; in fact, there is no economic basis for applying any profita-
bility test in an antidumping law.
PAGENO="0150"
142 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
5. Experience has also shown that~ in a large and diversified
country like the United States, regional considerations may be
important. Even as we recognize regional pricing under the Rob-
inson-Patman Act, we should also recognize regional areas for
antidumping injury cases.
& Special consideration should be given to shipments from a
parent company to a foreign subsidiary. If a product is shipped
to a subsidiary and further upgraded by 25 percent or more, there
should be the presumption of no injury, since the product does
not enter the channels of trade but rather serves as a raw
material.
7. Special consideration should be given to "coproducer" trans-
actions. In many instances, coproducer sales will be made at
special prices. Since the coproducer buyer is not interested in
destroying his own price structure, such a sale, even though
technically "dumping," will not tend to injure the market of the
country of destination.
It is recognized that the rules of procedure and the ways in which
they are applied can greatly influence the effectiveness of any regu-
lation. It would seem that the following principles should be incor-
porated into any antidumping law, (1) a chance for interested parties
to be heard; (2) prompt disposition of cases; (3) safeguards for
confidentiality of data; and (4) a requirement that complainant and
defendant suppiy necessary data promptly.
Failure of the former to comply within a specified time would
dismiss the case, and of the latter would automatically constitute
a finding of dumping.
In the matter of procedures, it is important that the findings be
prompt and not delayed, and that they be as specific as possible with
a mimmum of judgmental leeway. Only if both the regulations and
procedures are specific and clear can either the exporter or domestie
industry judge what is dumping and what is not.
PAGENO="0151"
Section IV
SPECIFIC ISSUES
143
PAGENO="0152"
PAGENO="0153"
PROBLEMS OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS IN
WORLD TRADE
BY LAWRENCE WITT and VERNON SORENSON *
CONTENTS
Page
Summary Propositions 145
I. Introduction 148
II. Present Patterns of Agricultural Trade 149
III. Trade Problems Affecting Both Developed and Developing Nations.. 155
A. Problems stemming from characteristics of demand 156
B. Problems stemming from the growth of synthetics 158
C. Agricultural prices in international markets 160
IV. Trade Problems and Policies Among Advanced Countries 166
A. Commercial markets for U.S. agricultural products 168
B. Implications of the EEC and U.K. policies 172
C. Problems in future policy change 173
V. Trade Problems and Policies of Special Relevance for Developing
Nations 175
A. Agricultural self-sufficiency efforts 176
B. International commodity agreements 176
C. Discrimination against the export of processed agricultural
products 178
D. Internal growth in demand in developing nations 179
E. Production, population and food aid 180
VI. The United States' Interests in Agricultural Trade 183
A. United States' interests 183
SUMMARY PROPOSITIONS
A. Agricultural products constitute about a third of world mer-
chandise exports. For the developing nations their importance is even
greater, constituting over half of the total, or three-fourths if petro.-
leum is excluded. Over 20 percent of U.S. exports are agricultural
products. Primary products have special characteristics; hence several
troublesome problems stem from heavy dependence upon such coin-
modities.
B. The volume of world trade in agricultural products is expanding
in absolute amounts but is declining as a proportion of total trade.
Growth in trade of some products has been affected by competition
from synthetic substitutes. The rate of growth is limited also by the
low income elasticity of demand, that is, with an increase of income
the increase in demand for food rises less than proportionately. Thus,
agriculture does not share equally with other industries in rising levels
of income. This may lead to a relative depression of farm income, an
outmigration of labor from agriculture and the need for changes in
the proportions of productive effort devoted to agriculture, industry,
*Department of Agricultural Economics, Michigan State University.
145
PAGENO="0154"
146 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
and other nonfarm activities. The impact on producers varies, depend-
ing upon the product they sell.
C. Trade expansion is also hampered by policies. The developed
nations have followed a number of policies that lead in the direction
of agricultural self-sufficiency. For reasons associated with internal
political pressures, governments use tariffs to protect internal markets
for farmers, protect consumers from shortages in times of war, et
`cetera. These have the effect of import substitution policies in agricul-
ture, and militate against an expansion of farm-produced exports.
D. In a significant number of countries, including the United States,
areas of specialized production are sufficiently large, or politically
vocal, or important for exchange earnings, to induce in government
serious consideration-and often acceptance-of export subsidies and
`other measures to stimulate exports. Consequently, international ef-
forts to reduce the quantity of artificial stimuli to exports become
intimately involved in domestic agricultural policy. The combination
of restrictive import policies and programs to expand exports has led
to international markets that operate without consistent rules and to
conditions where international commercial conflict is increasingly fo-
cused on agriculture. Progress in resolving theseissues is possible only
if future negotiators are in a position to discuss domestic farm policy
`and trade policy jointly.
E. Developing countries face special problems because of price in-
`stability and advanced country policies. The nature of the demand for
`agricultural products exposes these commodities to fairly wide price
fluctuations, which leads to government intervention to influence the
market, such as minimum export prices, domestic price supports, sub-
`sidies to export, marketing boards, and international commodity agree-
ments. In technical terms, this basic characteristic is a low elasticity
of demand with respect to price; that is, a small increase in volume
brings a larger decrease in the price received. This traditional concept
has been less valid during the past decade, primarily because of the
increased ability of major consuming nations to maintain economic
stability, but still is important. In consequence, the less-developed
countries, as they examine their agricultural trade potentials, hesitate
to expand most farm exports greatly. Although some have done so
successfully, most nations fear that larger volumes of exports will
lead to lower prices and lower foreign exchange earnings. This point
is more telling when the nation provides a significant fraction of the
total world trade in its principal export commodity.
F. Less-developed countries are unable to expand the export of
processed farm products, despite the logic of emphasizing this type of
industrialization, because the tariff structure of most developed nations
is geared to favor raw material imports. The tariff protection to the
developed nation's processing plants often is very substantial. Given
the desire to industrialize, this situation presses most developing
nations into manufacturing for the domestic market, often with special
consideration to import substitution industries.
G. The growth in income and population in the developed countries
of Europe, North America, and the Far East are likely to lead to a
continued expansion in commercial trade in certain farm products.
Red meat and feed grains have favorable prospects. Commercial trade
among developed countries is likely to be static or decrease for certain
other products, such as wheat and poultry, as new or advanced tech-
PAGENO="0155"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 147
iiology becomes more widely distributed. Also, an expansion in the
membership of the EEC may lead to changes in the patterns of com-
modity movement among the countries included and excluded.
Countries like the United States will face both export and import
problems, if such changes in membership occur, as we and other nations
adjust to new market conditions.
H. The rapid growth in population and some increases in income in
the less-developed countries lead to high rates of increase in the
domestic demand for food in the less-developed nations. Despite sub-
stantial increases in agricultural production, many of these countries
have required concessional imports from the United States. The evi-
dence indicates a continued basis for a food aid program for the next
decade, at least. A substantial program of family planning can in-
fluence the need for a food aid program after 1980, but the potential
heavy consumers of concessional food aid during the 1970's are already
born. Without population control, the "need" for food aid will increase
continuously. With U.S. surplus stocks reduced, coupled with the
recent expansion in commercial exports, future commitments for
concessional shipments will need to be considered more carefully in
relation to current production.
I. The relation of trade and domesic interests is becoming ever more
comprehensive and interrelated. The United States has a complex
pattern of interests in agricultural trade. This interest includes but
goes far beyond the economic interest in a large volume of exports. It
includes trade from developing countries as a partial substitute for
foreign aid. It includes the support which growth in trade can make
to improved economic welfare of people around the world. It includes
the economic welfare of U.S. farmers and marketing agencies who
produce and distribute for the export market. It includes the simple
humanitarian interest in making bread, rice, and better nutrition more
possible than before. These and more are elements of the broad U.S.
interest in agricultural trade-
J. These interests continue to present the United States with major
challenges and opportunities for policy leadership. Our efforts should
seek to increase the competitive structure of world markets and at the
same time encourage cooperation among nations in dealing with food
aid and the trading problems of kss developed countries. Exploration
of appropriate policies and possibilities for coordinated international
action needs to continue on such important issues as: (1) Methods of
reducing the conflict between domestic agricultural policy and inter-
national trade policy, (2) provision and financing of all aid including
food aid, (3) preferential trading relations and reduction of barriers
on imports from developing countries, (4) financial arrangements and
marketing aids to permit expanded trade and improved export possi-
bilities for developing countries, and (5) the purpose and role of
international commodity arrangements in future improvement of
international agricultural markets.
The bases for the above statements are elaborated and discussed in
the following report. We deal first with the agricultural trade patterns,
next with certain pervasive problems relevant to agricultural com-
modities, then with trade problems and policies among the developed,
and the less-developed nations. We close with some comments on the
U.S. interests in agricultural trade in the short run and long.
PAGENO="0156"
148 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
I. INTRODUCTION
Agricultural primary products, characteristically, face a number of
special problems in world trade. Among these problems are the slow
growth of demand, price and volume instability, intervention of gov-
ernment in defining the conditions of trade, concentration of exports
in one or a few commodities, trade discrimination, and the deteriorat-
ing balance between the growth of production and the increase in de-
mand. Some of these problems apply to fishery, forest, and mineral
products; and some apply to the processed products of agriculture
and other sectors. Thus, uniqueness or exclusivity is not claimed for
agriculture in this paper; rather the conditions discussed dominate'
the agricultural trade sector, with few exceptions, and call for serious
attention because agricultural products represent about a third of
world trade.
This paper concentrates on the long-run characteristics of interna-
tional agricultural markets, the nature of the problems after the'
Kennedy Round, and the kinds of action that may be feasible in deal-
ing with them. It does not discuss the accomplishments of the Kennedy
trade negotiations, partly because details are not yet available and
partly because the full impact cannot be known for some time. We do
suggest that one of the reasons for substantial difficulty in gaining
agricultural concessions is the close interweaving of domestic agricul-
tural price policy with trade policy for many countries-the United
States included. In consequence, a substantial array of domestic eco-
nomic interests, in many countries, apply political pressure upon a
nation's leadership as they discuss possible trade concessions, which
`equate to a discussion of internal farm price policy. Finally, the Ken-
nedy Round emphasized trade policy among developed nations,
whereas agricultural trade substantially represents exports from de-
veloping to developed nations. The agricultural trade interests of
developing nations will be dramatized in the forthcoming UNCTAD'
Conference in India. The U.S. interests and position vis-a-vis the
developing nations require substantial attention and imaginative
analysis.
In examining trade in agricultural products, it must be conceded at
the outset that no precisely measurable criterion exists for suggest-
ing how much trade should exist, whether in relation to developed or
developing nations. Yet, overall, three things must be kept in mind in
evaluating conditions in international agricultural markets. These
are:
(1) The concept of comparative advantage is meaningful in
application to agriculture, and further movement in specializa-
tion of production toward areas of lowest cost would benefit in-
dividual countri'es and the well-being of the world as n whole.
Impediments to trade hinder this movement. At the same time it
is necessary to recognize the concept of fixed assets, which some-
times builds an economic case for a gradual process. or for ad-
justment payments as p~ rt of a more rapid process. Possible po-
litical pressures are likely to be greater when fixed assets bulk
large in production costs.
(2) Trad'e in agricultural products plays an important role in
the total of international transfers related to the problem of eco-
PAGENO="0157"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 149
nomic growth. Exports of agricultural products from developing
countries as a means of earning foreign exchange are important.
The imports of agricultural products as a vehicle of development
are of consequence, but easily overemphasized by the nation pro-
viding such products on a concessional basis. The importance of
farm products in the export trade of developing nations makes
them the object of significant political and policy discussions.
(3) International transfers of agricultural products have on
various occasions in recent years played a special role in relief and
welfare.
We will discuss these three criteria from at least two points of view
in various parts of this paper. First, empirical data will be presented
to indicate changes in the specific content of these criteria, be they
technological advances, exports and foreign exchange earnings, or
unilateral transfers, such as the food for peace program. Second, sug-
gestions will be made on the values (objectives) implied by these cri-
teria, and the extent to which the U.S. interests coincide with those of
other nations, or of groups within them.
The maj or concern in this paper is agricultural primary products,
`but some of the data presented will include partially processed farm
products. Some attention will be given to the development of synthetic
materials which may substitute for agricultural primary products;
`also, the trade discrimination against processed raw materials will be
discussed. We turn first to a discussion of trade patterns.
II. PRESENT PATTERNS OF AGRICULTURAL TRADE
The value of agricultural primary products constituted 31 percent
of total world trade for 1959_61.1 Processed agricultural products
would add another 1 to 2 percent to this figure. For the developing
`regions the proportions were: Latin America 57 percent, Middle East
22 percent (but 78 percent if oil exports were excluded), Asia and
`the Far East 64 percent, and 58 percent for Africa. For the developed
nations, including those centrally planned, agricultural primary prod-
`ucts represented 25 percent of their total exports (table 1). For the
United States, agricultural exports were 23 percent of total exports
in 1965 and 1966.
Going behind the trade figures, the reliance on agriculture in the
`developing nations is reemphasized. Agriculture typically represents
40-55 percent of the national product, and provides the main source
of livelihood for 50-75 percent of the population. In contrast, in the
developed countries 10-20 percent of the national product is derived
from agriculture, with a similar small percent of the population de-
riving their livelihood therefrom. Despite these small percentages,
`there are regions within the developed countries in which the role of
agriculture is fully as dominant as in typical developing nations.
The expansion of agricultural trade has lagged behind the growth
in total trade, as indicated by the FAO statement:
"During the past decade international trade in agricultural primary
products was characterized by a relatively slow growth of volume,
falling unit values and terms of trade, and consequently a slower
1 FAO Commodity RevIew 1964, special supplement: "Trade in Agricultural Commodities
In the United Nations Development Decade," vol. 1. p. 1-4.
PAGENO="0158"
150 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
growth of agricultural export earnings. Simultaneously, the share'
of the developing countries in the total volume and value of this trade
contracted, and shipments from developed countries on `special' or
concessional terms, mainly to developing regions, assumed growing
importance. Short term fluctuations continued, presenting an addi-
tional problem to developing economies." 2
TABLE 1.-AGRICULTURAL PRIMARY PRODUCTS IN EXPORTS OF DEVELOPING REGIONS, AVERAGE 1959-61
Regions
Exports of
agricultural
products
(millions)
Exports of agricultural products as percentage
Total
exports
Exports
other than
fuel
~
*.
Exports of
primary
products other
than fuel
Latin America
Middle East
Asia and Far East
Africa and developing countries n.e.s
All deveoping regions -
Other regions
World total
$4, 877
1, 105
4,783
3, 429
57
22
64
58
79
78
70
72
91
81
94
96
14, 194
24,908
53
25
74
27
97
91
39, 102
31
35
91
a SITC secs. 0 (food and live animals), 1 (beverages and tobacco), 2 (crude materials, inedible, except fuels), and 4
(animal and vegetable oils and fats), excluding division 28 (metalliferous ores and metal scrap). This classification thus
includes amongagricultural products a number of raw materials of nonagricultural origin, amongthem synthetic rubber and
fibers, crude fertilizers and crude minerals.
Excluding Japan, and Asian centrally planned economies.
Developed and centrally planned regions.
Source: FAO, Trade in Agricultural Commodities in the United Nations Development Decade, vol. 1, pts. I, II, and Ill,
1964. p. l-4.
The conclusion that agricultural trade expands less rapidly than
total trade has been noted in a number of studies made during the past
third of a century. One of the latest comparisons, that of the FAO for
1959-61 compared with 1952-53 indicates that the volume of agricul-
tural exports rose 36 percent while manufactured products rose 65
percent. Because agricultural prices dropped during this period the
value of exports rose only 14 percent for agriculture, compared with
71 percent for manufactured goods.3 Since 1961 the unit value of
agricultural commodities has risen almost at the same rate as manu-
factured products, but growth in agricultural exports continue to lag
behind total exports, albeit by only a few percentage points. The
reasons for such lags will be discussed in chapter III. Table 2 provides
annual data to 1965.
On a comparative basis, the change between 1952-53 and 1959-61
was adverse to the developing nations. A 1964 FAO report4 com-
ments:
"The growth of developing countries' export earnings was even
slower than that of the volume of exports because of the widespread
decline in the average export prices of agricultural products.. For all
products combined, the price fall amounted to 16' percent between
1952-53 and 1959-61. With a simultaneous increase of 4 percent in
the average export prices of manufactured goods the purchasing power
`2 Idern, p. I-TO.
3ldem., p. I-TO.
`Idem., p. 1-14.
PAGENO="0159"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 151
of agricultural exports in terms of manufactures (their "terms of
trade") fell by 19 percent."
The report notes certain differences among commodities:
"Among foodstuffs, there was a sharp contrast between meat and
fruit, the prices of which rose, in some cases by as much as 20-25
percent, and most grains and dairy products, the price of which fell
by more than the average for all agricultural products. The price
decline was somewhat more uniform among beverage crops and agri-
cultural raw materials, except for tea, the price of which was rela--
tively stable, and rubber, the prices of which fluctuated widely."
TABLE 2-INDEXES OF THE VOLUME, UNIT VALUE AND TOTAL VALUE OF WORLD TRADE IN AGRICULTURAL
FISHERY AND FOREST PRODUCTS
[Indexes, 1957-59=1001
Average,
1953-57
1958
1959
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
(prelim-
nary)
Volumeof commercial agricultural exports
Unit value of commercial agricultural exports_~
Total value of agricultural exports
Average export unit value of manufactured
product exports
Total value of world trade (agricultural and
nonagricultural)
92
107
98
96
85
98
99
96
100
97
104
96
99
99
103
109
97
105
101
114
116
93
108
102
120
118
92
109
102
126
124
99
122
103
137
128
102
132
104
154
130~
100
131
107
167
Source: FAO, `The State of Food and Agriculture 1966," table 11-6, p. 35.
The differences in price trends among commodities also had regional
impacts: 6
"Differences in the commodity composition of exports were respon-
sible for considerable differences in the changes of the average unit
values in the various regions. . . . The heavy concentration of Latin
America on coffee combined with price falls for cocoa, grains, and
textile fibers [combined] to reduce the average export unit value of
this region by nearly a quarter. Asia and the Far East suffered a much
smaller reduction, by only 5 percent, thanks in part, to the exceptional
prices of rubber and tea during 1952-53 and 1959-61. Average unit
value of exports from Africa and the Middle East declined by 17
and 14 percent, respectively. There were similar differences in the unit
value of agricultural exports from developed regions."
Since 1961 agricultural prices have moved upward, so that by 1965
the value of agricultural exports had risen 18 percent. However, the
regional picture was highly variable, with a 38 percent increase for~
Western Europe, 24 percent for North America, 22 percent for Latin
America, 18 percent for the Near East, only 8 percent for Africa, and
zero for the Far East ~ (table 3).
The volume of trade in all products is substantially higher for de-
veloped countries than for developing nations. Over 55 percent of
total exports (excluding the centrally planned economies) are from
one developed nation to another, with another 20 percent going to
developing nations. An additional 18 percent of total trade are exports
of the developing to the developed countries. Only 6 percent of total
trade is among the developing nations themselves (table 4).
5Iclem.
o Ideas.
FAO State of Food and Agriculture, op. cit., pp. 233-235.
PAGENO="0160"
Prewar
average
Average,
1948-52
1955
TABLE 3.-WORLD AND REGIONAL INDEXES OF VALUE OF AGRICULTURAL EXPORT PRODUCTS
[Indexes, average 1957-59=1001
Western
North America
Oceania
Latin America
Far East 1
Near East
Africa
World, excluding the centrally planned econ-
omies
Eastern Europe and U.S.S.R
World 1
1956
1957
1958
1959
1960
1961
1962
30
22
29
26
45
28
19
28
63
95
93
92
97
91
72
86
91
102
99
106
102
98
96
100
69
98
89
76
95
103
109
93
95
94
76
93
103
108
111
105
102
110~
98
105
96
104
1963
1964
98
96
85
99
93
92
102
96
88
96
Source: FAO, "The State of Food and Agriculture 1966," table 12A, pp. 233-235.
1 Excluding China (mainland).
99
96
105
96
105
98
99
99
115
100
109
114
102
99
108
104
99
106
113
106
115
123
112
100
100
97
101
108
135
110
138
134
134
113
107
113
111
122
142
123
118
118
113
103
100
101
104
109
139
111
ci
1965
preliminary
158 C12
151 ~
135 ~
122
100 ci
115 J2
109
129 o
z
0
148
158
147
119
108
114
113
132
128
132
PAGENO="0161"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 153
TABLE 4.-PERCENTAGE FLOWS OF TOTAL WORLD TRADE AND TRADE IN AGRICULTURAL PRIMARY PRODUCTS
BETWEEN ECONOMIC REGIONS, AVERAGE 1959-61
Exports-from/to
Total world trade 1
Agricultural trade 2
Developed
Developing
Centrally
planned
Developed
Developing
Centrally
planned
Excluding centrally planned:
Developed
Developing
lnxluding centrally planned:
Developed
Developing
Centrally planned
55
19
47
16
2
20
6
17
5
1
2
1
9
43
40
36
34
3
11
6
10
5
1
2
4
5
`Source: FAO, Trade in Agricultural Commodities in the United Nations Development Decade, vol. II, p1. IV, 1964
table 1.1/Vi, p. 5.
2 Source: Idem, vol. I, pts. I, II, and Ill, 1964, table 1.1/Il, p. 1-5.
For agricultural products, the dominance of the developed nations
is less severe, since developing nations typically export a higher pro-
portion of these products. Even so, 43 percent of the agricultural ex-
ports are among developed nations. But, from another point of view,
the developed nations as customers are more concentrated-for total
trade, developed countries receive 74 percent of the exports while for
agricultural products this proportion is 83 percent.
Significant in terms of future market potential, developing countries
received only 17 percent of the total exports, composed of 11 percent
from developed and only 6 percent from other developing nations.
Table 4 presents these data, along with similar data with centrally
planned economies included.
Following heavy wartime shipments U.S. agricultural exports
dropped to a low of $2.5 billion in 1945. Since then steady increases
have occurred 8 and exports reached nearly $6.9 billion in calendar 1966
(table 5). These increases can be attributed to a number of factors in-
cluding: (1) an aggressive U.S. export program (too aggressive from
some points of view) ; (2) the successful efforts to prevent a serious
postwar depression in the developed world through fiscal and mone-
tary policies which led to increasing purchasing power in North Amer-
ica, Japan, and Western Europe; (3) the successful efforts to restrict,
with a few exceptions, a new series of trade restrictions after the early
1950's; and (4) the creation of the Public Law 480 program to expand
shipments to developing nations, coupled with the increased rate of
population growth.
Concessional grants and sales constitute about a fourth of total
U.S. exports since 1955. The total from all nations, including the world
food program, Canadian, French, and other bilateral arrangements,
range between $1.5 and $2.0 billion annually. U.S. exports, the domi-
nant factor, are shown in table 5.
U.S. grants of food (titles II and III) have ranged from 10 to 20
percent of the noncommercial trade shown in table 5. A clear distinc-
tion between concessional sales, export dumping, and food aid is a
hopeless task. Some food shipments under these programs represent
Grains, fats and oils provide the major Increases. See Robert L. Tontz and Isaac B.
Lenon, "Agricultural Exports are Becoming More Important to U.S. Agriculture," Foreign
Agricultural Trade, ER5-U5DA, February 1967.
82-246--67-----1l
PAGENO="0162"
154 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
true export disposals, while other shipments represent real develop-
ment assets for the receiving nations. Still other shipments, especially
donations, have primarily humanitarian objectives and effects. But the
intent and the results are sometimes consistent and sometimes inverted;
even detailed country studies cannot fully disentangle the conse-
quences.
The largest single recipient has been India, with countries such as
Pakistan, Brazil, Yugoslavia, Turkey, Poland, Spain, Israel, TJnited
Arab Republic, and Korea being important recipients for several years
during this period. Public Law 480 has been revised periodically since
1954, with changing specifications on country eligibility as recipients.
The 1966 revision collapsed the four titles, shown in table 5, into two,
and made grants and local currency sales less significant. The decline
in the CCC-owned stockpile of agricultural commodies, the change in
the law, and tougher eligibility requirements combine to reduce the
size of the U.S. bilateral program. The world food program is increas-
ing modestly; while under the Kennedy Round Agreements, the con-
tributions of other developed nations to such food aid programs is
likely to increase.
Briefly, these food aid (or agricultural surplus disposal programs)
result from (1) a disequilibrium in the domestic agriculture of the ex-
porting developed nations, with excess resources devoted to certain
commodities, and probably to agriculture as a whole, and (2) a dis-
equilibrium in international markets with certain developing countries
unable to earn sufficient foreign exchange to become substantial com-
mercial purchasers of food products. The economic and institutional
barriers to adjustment are deeply rooted and persistent. The developed
nations appear to be somewhat closer to a solution than the recipient
nations. Further policy implications will be postponed to the final
chapter.
TABLE 5.-U.S. EXPORTS UNDER SPECIAL PROGRAMS IN RELATION TO TOTAL AGRICULTURAL EXPORTS
[In millions of U.S. dollarsi
Average, Average, 1965 1966
1955-59 1960-64
Exports under Public Law 480:
Title I 629 1,060 926 820
Title II 80
Title Ill (barter) 223 126 188 260
Title Ill (donations) 164 160 180 131
Title IV 38 143 226
Total 1,063 1,461 1,510 1,517
Agency for International Development (AID) pro-
grams 298 81 26 47
Total, special programs 1,362 1,542 1,536 1,564
Commercial sales 2, 575 3,822 4,693 5,321
Total exports 3,937 5, 364 6, 229 6, 885
Exports under special programs as percentage of total
agricultural exports 35 29 25 23
Sources: Calculated from annual data supplied by ERS, U.S. Department of Agriculture.
PAGENO="0163"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 155
III. TRADE PROBLEMS AFFECTING BOTH DEVELOPED
AND DEVELOPING NATIONS
Any evaluation of agricultural trade problems must recognize the
political and economic setting within which agricultural market~~
operate. From the viewpoint of economic criteria, the level of develop-
ment is important. The simple breakdown into developed and under~
developed countries, however, is hardly sufficient to provide a frame-*
work for agricultural trade analysis. Among the developed economies,~
wide variation exists in the resource base and the conditions surround--
ing agricultural production. On the one hand, countries such ~-s
Australia, New Zealand, Canada, Denmark, the Netherlands, and
increasingly France are primarily agricultural export countries. Agri-
cultural production rests on favorable soil and climatic conditions,
farm units use relatively modern techniques buttressed by adequate
investment in rural infrastructures, and education, all of which has led
to a high level of agricultural productivity. On the other hand, an-
other group of industrial countries, which includes the United King-
dom, Japan, Germany, and to lesser degrees several other European
countries tend to have an inadequate resource base for agriculture,
and in some cases, a poorly structured farm organization. Despite a
highly productive agriculture they remain major importers. The
United States belongs in the first group rather than the second, eve.n
with the preponderance of manufactures in its export pattern.
In all of these countries agriculture has declined relatively through
time and is likely to continue both from the viewpoint of the origin of
national products and the composition of the working population. This
process of contraction, however, is not accompanied by a decline in
agricultural output; hence the agricultural exporting countries tend
to exert a continuous pressure on the world market in products that
they produce while those that are importers are able to rely heavily
on domestic production.
Among the less developed countries, differences exist in the extent
to which agricultural output covers domestic requirements, but where
excess production exists this often tends to be in a specialized product
or group of products such as coffee, bananas, etc. The more important
distinction from the viewpoint of trade problems among the less de-
veloped countries is the extent to which change and dynamic adjust-
ment is occurring, both in agricultural and nonagricultural sectors.
Among the less developed and most static of the low-income countries,
agriculture tends to be of a subsistence type both with respect to pro-
duction and consumption, and the bulk of the labor force is engaged
in agriculture. With many rural households largely self-contained, ~n-
ternal market systems and trading is mainly restricted to the local
level, and these economies have only a limited participation in world
trade, either as exporters or importers.
Another group of basically underdeveloped economies, however, has
an important stake in international trading relationships. While these
economies tend still to be largely agricultural, the process of change
has begun. Improvements are being actively sought in agricultur.
productivity and the expansion of industrial output is underway.
Many participate actively in international markets either as importers
PAGENO="0164"
156 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
or exporters, or in some cases both. Import requirements among these
countries tend to be dictated by a fundamental imbalance between
agricultural output and population levels. Basic natural resources
often are not in plentiful supply and much production is based on
traditional agriculture with low productivity and static methods.
Exporters among this group of countries tend to be centered around
specialized crops whose principal markets are in the developed coun-
tries of the world.
Within this structural framework of world agricultural markets,
the principal flows of trade are: (1) among the developed countries
of the world and involve largely temperate zone agricultural products;
(2) shipments, largely on a concessional basis, of temperate zone agri-
cultural products from the developed to importing underdeveloped
countries; and (`3) exports of tropical and specialty commodities from
the developing to the developed countries (table 4). It is within this
frame of reference and in relation to the question of comparative ad-
vantage, economic efficiency, and the economic growth problems facing
the developing countries that specific international trade problems in
agriculture need to be defined.
PROBLEMS STEMMING FROM CHARACTERISTICS OF DEMAND
The market for agricultural products is inelastic both in respect to
price and in respect to income. This means that a 1-percent increase
in supply at `a point in time results in a greater th'an 1-percent decrease
in price; and, a 1-percent increase in disposable income is matched by
a less than 1-percent increase in sales. These inelasticities of price and
income, as they are called, vary among countries with the level of in-
come and other socioeconomic characteristics, and among commodities.
These fundamental characteristics of demand impose very real limita-
tions on the economic growth potentials and policy alternatives for
the agricultural sector.
In developed nations price elasticities tend to be low, which means
that small changes in Volume are matched by large changes in price.
Experience with these conditions leads many farmers and farmer
representatives to press for public action to limit the price changes
for those important commodities subject to moderate to substantial
changes in production from year to year. Grain, especially wheat,
potatoes, and tobacco are likely to be at the low end of the scale of
elasticities, and therefore more likely to be exposed to such pressures.
Meat, dairy products, and fruits tend to be toward the upper end of
the scale of elasticities (but still less than 1), and therefore somewhat
less likely to become involved in such measures. These low price elas-
ticities lead to price instability in world markets as well as in domestic
markets. A number of crops, particularly tree crops, also are charac-
terized by an inelastic supply, or a supply influenced mainly by
weather. The combination of supply and demand inelasticities can lead
to even wider price fluctuations, but can also be offsetting.
Similarly, income elasticities for farm products in developed coun-
tries tend to be low, with about the same range among commodities,
so that rising levels of national income do not flow equally to the pro-
`ducers of agricultural `and manufactured products. `These characteris-
tics often are exacerbated by the way in which prices are established
in the several markets, since as technology advances, consumers are
PAGENO="0165"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF IJ.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 157
the likely beneficiaries of lower costs from agricultural advance, while
workers, shareholders, and consumers share jointly in technical ad-
vances in industry. Another consequence of the low-income elasticity
is to limit the growth potential for agriculture, both permitting and
requiring a change in the structure of the economy away from agri-
culture. The evils, often exaggerated, of a one-crop economy derive
mainly from these two points.
The instability of raw material prices has been documented by a
series of studies over the past 30 years. A United Nations study in
1952,~ covering the period 1901 to 1950 indicated an average year-to-
year fluctuation in prices of 14 percent. The export volume varied by
nearly 19 percent, while the combination of the two exaggerated
rather than reduced the fluctuations, so that export earnings had a
year-to-year fluctuation of 22.6 percent. This was a period of two
major wars, a major depression, and several more limited cyclical
changes. A more recent study,1° for 1953-61 for a somewhat different
list of commodities shows more modest fluctuations, volume 8.7 per-
cent, unit value 8, while export value averaged 10.5 percent. With the
greatly enhanced ability to deal with cyclical fluctuations during the
past 20 years, the 10 percent of the latter study is far more appropriate
than the 22 percent of the earlier study. An economic study by
MacBean,11 forming entirely on the period after 1947, concludes that
the fluctuations in exchange earnings are no more severe for develop-
ing nations than for developed countries. However, there were in-
dividual countries which, for a variety of domestic and international
reasons, suffered substantial instability in exchange earnings. We sug-
gest that the widely accepted traditional view; namely, that special-
ization on a few export primary products exposes a nation to great
economic instability, is likely to be overstated and overstressed. The
traditional view depends too much on the experiences of 1925-45 and
too little upon the period since 1947 when widespread sophisticated
management and substantial economic stability of the major national
economies has been the rule.
Turning to growth and development problems imposed by the low-
income elasticities, here too the traditional view in the developing
countries is to eschew investments in export agriculture. Only an ex-
ceptional nation, such as Taiwan, has deliberately invested broadly in
agriculture for export. Others, such as Nigeria in oil palms and
Parana State in Brazil in coffee, have invested in certain crops, in a
few cases with deliberation, but in most cases as a consequence of
private farmer decisions. Most nations have sought to save exchange
through import substitution industries, or have sought new exchange
revenues by developing a new export commodity as a means of diver-
sifying their economy. In most cases, these procedures have been con-
trary to the concept of comparative advantage, assuming that added
output of existing raw material exports would depress the price and
therefore exchange earnings. The recent price facts support this view
for certain commodities, such as coffee, rubber, coca, and cotton, and
deny this view for other products such as meat, dairy products and
United Nations Department of Economic Affairs, "Instability in Export Markets of
Under-developed Countries," New York, 1052.
10 FAO, Trade in Agricultural Commodities, op. cit., p. 1-17.
~ Alasdar MacBean, "Export Instability and Economic Development," Harvard Univer-
sity Press, 1966.
PAGENO="0166"
158 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
feed grains. We shall see that factors other than demand have con-
tributed to sluggish prices for some of these products. The point to be
emphasized is that generalizations covering all primary products or
all agricultural commodities need to be elaborated more carefully;
price history of some major commodities confirm the traditional view,
while for others the contrary is true.
PROBLEMS STEMMING FROM THE GROWTH OF SYNTHETICS
Through modern science, a wide range of synthetic substitutes for
agricultural raw materials have been developed. The list includes
rayon, nylon and a host of other fibers, synthetic rubber, atabrine and
others for quinine, synthetic detergents, substitutes for leather,
artificial sweeteners, along with certain more traditional substitutes
such as paper for jute and other fibers. Presumably the general effect
of such developments is to reduce the growth in demand for the
natural materials. To the extent to which these new products derive
from nationally produced raw materials, they also reduce the potential
growth in international trade. However, the actual situation is more
complex.
First, these new synthetics prOvide certain qualities which create
new uses for the end product, carpeting in places not previously car-
peted, a more extensive use of soft drinks, wider use of foam rubber
cushions, pillows, etc. Thus, synthetics displace much less than the
equivalent amounts of the natural commodity.
Second, in some cases, synthetics and natural products are being
combined to create commodities more pleasing to consumers. Such joint
products may enhance the sales opportunities, creating a larger de-
mand for the final product, as has occurred recently for fibers.
Third, the price patterns are modified by the existence of a close
substitute. The I~rice elasticity of demand for the natural product is
increased, thus reducing the probable range of price movements.
A 1964 study by the FAO of "Synthetics and their Effectson Agri-
cultural Trade," 12 states:
"One of the main threats to the exchange earnings of developing
countries in recent years has come from competition of synthetics with
agricultural raw materials, principally cotton, wool, jute and allied
fibers, hard fibers (mainly abaca), and rubber. In the period 1959-61,
world exports of these products were valued at about U.S. $5,600 mil-
lion, equivalent to 24 percent of the total value of world agricultural
trade. Moreover, more than half (55 percent) the total originated in
developing countries, where they accounted for 30 percent of total ex-
ports of agricultural products.
"The overwhelming items in the developed countries' exports of
agricultural raw materials are wool, the hulk of the trade in which
originates from Australia, New Zealand, and South Africa, and United
States cotton, valued at $779 million in the period mentioned. Other-
wise the trade consists essentially of a flow from developing to de-
veloped countries.
"The world output of synthetic materials is heavily concentrated in
developed countries (the United States, Western Europe and Japan)
and centrally planned countries.
12 FAO. "Synthetics and Their Effects on Agricultural Trade," Commodity Bulletin Series
38, FAO, Rome, i964, p. i.
PAGENO="0167"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 159
"The location of synthetic industries in the main agricultural raw
material importing countries is, of course, basically inimical to an
expansion of the trade in the natural products. However, the establish-
ment of such industries is usually inspired by technical, rather than
autarchic, considerations except insofar as the synthetic products are
competing among themselves. It is but one facet of the general process
of technological evolution which is affecting the demand for agri-
cultural raw materials in many different ways."
The origins of the natural materials much exposed to competition
from synthetics are shown in table 6. Later this FAO report points out
some rapid increases in demand:
TABLE 6. DISTRIBUTION OF EXPORTS OF AGRICULTURAL RAW MATERIALS BY ECONOMIC GROUP OF ORIGIN
AND DESTINATION, 1959-61
EIn millions of U.S. dollars, f.o.b.J
Origin
Destination
Developed
regions
Developing
regions
Centrally
planned
countries
World
total
Developed
regions
Developing
regions
Centrally
planned
countries
World
total
Rubber
Cotton
Wool
Jute, allied fibers
Hard fibers
Total
`68
894
1,233
1,392
1,115
249
185
134
302
63
1,460
2,270
1,545
185
134
bl,061
1,363
1,307
145
124
93
325
42
24
4
306
544
196
17
5
1,460
`2,270
1,545
185
134
2, 155
3, 074
365
5, 594
4,001
487
1, 067
5, 594
Reexports.
b Includes imports of rubber subsequently reexported.
Includes unallocable exports valued at $38,000,000.
Source: FAO, Trade in Agricultural Commodities in the United Nations Development Decade. Rome, 1964. FAO, "Syn.
thetics and Their Effects on Agricultural Trade," Commodity Bulletin Series 38, FAO, 1964.
"When assessing the effects of these developments on the demand
for agricultural raw materials it is necessary to keep in mind that the
overall world market for apparel fibers and elastomers has been ex-
panding at a rapid rate throughout the postwar period. Between 1952
and 1962, apparel fiber consumption increased by over 50 percent,
while elastomer consumption nearly doubled. The markets shared by
natural and synthetic products have, in fact, grown faster than those
of some of the important food products."
In the United States, synthetic sweeteners have become of some
importance as a substitute for sugar. A recent study examined five
major food processing industries which normally use 60 percent of
the sweeteners used in the United States; namely the beverage, bak-
ing, confectionary, canning, and dairy industries. After discussing
competition among natural sweeteners in some of these industries,
Hayenga concludes:
"The soft drink industry has exhibited little caloric sweetener sub-
stitutability because of technical requirements for a high sweetness
level per sweetener unit and purity, color, and sediment standards.
Consequently, sucrose has historically supplied between 92 and 96 per-
cent of the caloric sweetener requirements in the beverage industry.
But the beverage industry recently began extensive use of the much
`°Ibid., p. 6.
14 Marvin L. ilayenga, "Sweetener Competition and Sugar Policy," paper to be presented
to the American Farm Economics Association, August 1967.
PAGENO="0168"
160 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
lower cost synthetic sweeteners. Low calorie soft drink sales have
multiplied several times since 1960. In 1964, low calorie products
represented approximately 10 percent of soft drink sales. Some in-
dustry sources believe this percentage may increase to 30 or 50 per-
cent by 1975."
The general price patterns of natural and synethic commodities is
indicated by the data in table 7. The stability in prices of the man-
made materials is clearly evident; certainly they have reduced but not
eliminated the fluctuations in the prices of the natural products. As
to the level of the prices the FAO study 15 concludes:
"Since 1953, when the Korean boom had largely subsided, two
features are immediately apparent: firstly, prices of most of the prod-
ucts were lower in 1962 than in 1953; secondly, reductions in prices
of natural materials were generally greater than those of the syn-
thetic products. The extent to which synthetic composition has con-
tributed to this deterioration in agricultural raw material prices is
indeterminate. If, at any time, the output of all synthetic materials
had ceased, prices of their natural counterparts would certainly have
risen in the short term. However, taking into account longer term
supply responses, there is no similar assurance that prices would have
been higher than they are today if manmade materials had never
come into existence. Prices of some major agricultural products not
subject to competition from manmade materials (e.g., coffee and
cocoa) have declined more rapidly in the last decade than those of
agricultural raw materials."
AGRIC1JLTURAL PRICES IN INTERNATIONAL MARKETS
Much controversy has appeared about the level and the role of prices
in the developing countries. Some of this stems from an argument
about whether Public Law 480 shipments depress farm prices in the
recipient countries. Some stem from the role which prices may play
in stimulating an expansion in production in developing nations, where
traditional agriculture is a dominant force. And, some arguments
develop around the price trends for agricultural staples compared with
manufactured goods, it being alleged that foreign exchange earnings
are depressed by adverse terms of trade for major agricultural exports.
Each of these points has an extensive literature; time and space do not
permit an adequate coverage. We postpone the first issue to the final
chapter when we review the policy implications of food aid. The second
issue more properly belongs in a paper on agricultural development.
The third price issue will be discussed briefly at this point.
Agricultural prices in world markets have lagged behind prices of
other commodities. But the lags are uneven, and some commodities
have price changes that substantially exceed those of manufactured
exports. The prices of meat and dairy products rose 27 and 15 percent,
respectively, for 1965 over the 1957-59 period. Beverages and agricul-
tural raw materials' prices have actually declined during this period
(table 8). Significantly, most of the latter products are mainly the
products of developing countries, wool and cotton being exceptions
in part.
15FA0, "Synthetics and their Effects on Agricultural Trade," op. cit., p. 6.
PAGENO="0169"
U)
U)
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 161
U)
-
E
c_) -
~ ~
~
Q~)~
B' `-~
-
~EE
EY~-~,
U)U)>U)~
<
C-,
U)
B
B
B
=
U)
><
C-,
0~
PAGENO="0170"
162 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
TABLE 8.-INDEXES OF WORLD AVERAGE EXPORT UNIT VALUES OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS, BY MAIN COM-
MODITY GROUPS
[1957-59 = 1001
Average,
1953-57
1958
1959
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965(pre-
liminary)
Agricultural products
Food and feedstuffs
107
104
99
99
96
98
97
97
93
96
92
97
99
108
102
110
100
109
Cereals
Sugar
Oilseeds and vegetable oils
fruit
Meat
Dairy products
Beverages and tobacco
Coffee
Cocoa
112
97
103
95
96
109
111
127
103
100
96
98
105
101
92
105
102
118
98
91
101
89
105
104
92
83
103
98
87
97
90
108
103
89
80
83
97
89
95
93
106
96
83
76
66
103
89
91
93
102
96
81
73
63
103
139
98
100
107
102
84
69
68
106
137
99
94
121
106
92
88
71
104
104
110
97
127
115
91
89
56
Agricultural raw materials
Wool
Cotton
Rubber (natural)
Average export unit value of manufactured
products
111
118
116
97
96
94
89
101
87
100
94
85
88
111
99
103
92
94
125
101
97
90
96
92
102
92
89
92
87
102
96
103
91
83
103
96
113
88
79
104
90
96
89
76
107
Source: FAO, `The State of Food and Agriculture, 1966,' table 11-10, p. 40, Rome, 1966.
These trends have been interpreted as a worsening of the terms of
trade for the developing nations, since they largely export farm prod-
ucts. But this trend also suggests that economic development is pro-
ceeding, that food requires a smaller part of the total family budget
than formerly, leaving purchasing power to support a higher level of
living. About 100 years ago, the typical U.S. family spent about two-
thirds of its income on food and clothing; the decline in this percentage
to a fourth or less is a major component of our economic development.
The decline has been strongly influenced by a significant and con-
tinued increase in agricultural productivity. The fewer farmers of
today are able to produce more food than their predecessors, and this
process continues. True, this change required migration of millions of
people from agriculture to industry and other urban occupations, a
migration with many fits and starts. Farm prices and farm incomes
lagged because of comparative overcommitments of resources in agri-
culture. The adjustment process brought anguish to many unable to
understand and to accept the consequent inequities, and unable, also, to
do much about them.
Is this same process operating in the agriculture of other nations?
In most advanced countries, it is clear that evolving agricultural tech-
nology is leading to greater production per man and per acre, with
substantial outmigration of rural manpower. Technical change also is
affecting the conditions of production of some of the major exports of
developing countries, e.g., coffee, cocoa, and cotton. The challenge is
not to keep agriculture from becoming more productive; rather it is
to devise procedures by which to take advantage of the changes that
are occurring, and to assure that the gains are more equitably dis-
tributed. In the developing nations, rising population and income
pressures lead to much concern that food production will not increase
rapidly enough, despite substantial increases in food production. But,
at present, another issue looms larger in politic-economic discussions
coming from the developing to developed countries.
This is the argument that the longrun relative price movements of
agriculture and manufactured goods-the terms of trade are adverse
to the developing nations and leads to a deterioration of exchange
PAGENO="0171"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 163
earnings. Dr. Raul Prebisch, economist with the Economic Commis-
sion for Latin America, and Hans Singer, economist with the U.N.,
have developed this argument. More recently, as Director General of
the UNCTAD Conference in Geneva, Dr. Prebisch has generalized
these issues to all developing nations vis-a-vis the developed nations.
The issues are sensitive and involve a wide range of economic and
political relations between these two groups.
These views have been discussed by Harry G. Johnson 16 as follows:
"The alleged tendency, however, is not consistent with the empirical
evidence. It is necessary in this connection to distinguish between two
frequently confused but analytically distinct propositions: that there
is a longrun tendency for the terms of trade between manufactures and
primary products to turn against producers of the latter, and that
there is a longrun tendency for the terms of trade between developed
countries to turn against the latter."
Dr. Johnson cites a study by Robert Lipsey as evidence that the first
proposition is not true, and that the second proposition is confirmed by
one set of evidence and denied by two others, thus suggesting that a
particular case but not a general case can be made.
Lipsey examines U.S. data and reviews previous studies,17 con-
cluding:
"Comparisons with exports of U.S. manufactures strongly contra-
dict the belief in declining relative primary product prices; compari-
sons with manufactures imported into the United States mildly
confirm it. On the whole, there seem to be more instances of primary
products relatively gaining in price than losing. The scatter around
these relationships among totals is large, and supports Kindleberger's
view that the primary versus manufactured product distinction is not
a particularly useful one for the analysis of changes in terms of trade."
In testing the second proposition Lipsey examines data for the
United Kingdom (the basis for most of Prebisch's empirical evi-
dence), the United States, and Kindleberger's data on continental in-
dustrial Europe. The proposition is supported by United Kingdom
data but denied by the other two.
Moreover, when price fluctuations exist the selection of the base
period can be crucial to the conclusions reached. Prebisch examines
1950 to 1961 price trends, thus starting with the Korean induced peak
and ending with the post-Suez stump. The choice of 1950 is a U.N~
statistical standard, not a Prebisch selection however.
FAO data, cited earlier, gives some support to the first proposition,
but mainly suggests that the differences among commodities are far
more important than the general trend. The data in Table 8 indicate
a difficult trend situation for a nation exporting coffee or cocoa, but
a favorable trend for nations exporting meat or dairy products.
A recent study by Goolsby in the Economic Research Service,
USDA, examines prices and export earnings for Temperate and
Tropical Zones commodities. This classification is only partially a
developed versus developing nation comparison; cotton, for example,
is excluded from either classification. Goolsby develops price trends
for 11 commodities in each classification with a 10-year (1954-63) and
1~ "Economic Policies Toward Less Developed Countries," the Brookings Institution,
Washington. D.C., 1967 p. 269.
~` Robert E. Lipsey, "Price and Quantity Trends In the Foreign Trade of the United
States," National Bureau of Economic Research, Princeton University Press, 1963, p. 23.
PAGENO="0172"
1164 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
a 17-year (1947-63) trend. The summary is shown in `table 9. Again
individual commodities do better or worse than the trend. He sum-
~marizes as follows: 18
"Over the postwar era from 1947 to 1963, prices of farm exports
from the Temperate Zone dropped an average of 2 percent a year,
while prices of major tropical products as a whole declined 0.2 percent
a year. But the variation in prices of Tropical Zone products was
almost twice as much as the variation in prices of Temperate Zone
products.
"Prices in 1947-54 were particularly unstable. Prices of tropical
products increased aproximately 50 percent from 1947 to 1951. In
1954, they were still over 40 percent higher than their 1947 levels.
Prices of Temperate Zone products fluctuated within a rather wide
range in 1947-54, but in 1954 they were lower than they had been
in 1947.
"From 1954 to 1963, prices of tropical products declined an average
of 2.6 percent per year and those of Temperate Zone products decline~1~
1.5 percent per year.
"Export earnings for both groups of commodities increased
throughout the period studied. For the Tropical Zone commodities,
the increase in earnings was 2.5 percent for the entire postwar period,
but negligible over the last decade studied. Very significant declines
in earnings for coffee and cocoa largely offset the increases for a num-
ber of other Tropical Zone commodities during this decade."
TABLE 9-TRENDS IN PRICES AND EXPORT EARNINGS FOR SELECTED TEMPERATE AND TROPICAL ZONE
COMMODITIES, 1954-63 AND 1947-63
.
Commodity group
Average annual change
in unit value
Average annual change
in expart earnings
1954-63 1947-63
1954-63 1947-63
I Temperate zone commodities
Tropical zone commodities b
-1. 5 -2. 0
-2. 6 -. 2
4. 7 3. 4
. 2 2. 5
a Includes wheat, wheat flour, barley, corn, pork (bacon, ham, salt pork), powdered milk, butter, cheese, shell eggs,
soybeans, and wool.
b Includes milled rice, bananas, copra, shelled peanuts, palm oil, coffee, tea, cocoa, raw sugar, natural rubber, and jute
Source: ERS-USDA, "Agricultura Exports from Temperate and Tropical Zones," "Foreign Agricultural Economic.
Report No. 29," tables 2 and 4, pp. 7 and 14.
Our conclusions are that this is a very complicated matter. It is far
more important to examine individual commodities and the individual
countries degree of reliance on commodities adversely affected, than
it is to make universal generalizations about developing nations, tropi-
cal commodities, or manufactured versus primary commodities. Fluc-
tuations may be more critical than long-term trends for most commod-
ities, though obviously some products are afflicted with surplus pro-
ductive capacity.
The belief that the trends have been adverse, despite limited and
contradictory evidence to support the claim, is a political fact of
some magnitude in the developing-developed nations' relationships.
The cord of truth in the argument is that the economic structure under
which these producth are produced and consumed frequently prevents
10 Halbert Goolsby, "Agricultural Exporte from Temperate and Tropical Zones," ITS.
Department of Agriculture, March 1966.
PAGENO="0173"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 165
them from being used as "engines of growth" and as the sources of
rapidly expanding foreign exchange earnings that developing coun-
tries need if they are to purchase development tools and provide their
people with the commodities needed for an improved level of living.
In both developed and developing nations, groups of producers,
marketing, transportation, and export firms have developed produc-
tion and distribution facilities geared to the continued export of cer-
tain commodities. They compete in world markets with other export-
ers, and in many cases with domestic producers in the importing
nation. They seek policies which will enhance their ability to compete,
and protest against measures which make exportation more difficult.
Very frequently they are fairly specialized producers of the product
or marketing services; alternatives are significantly less remunerative
to the resources involved, and may require substantial costly and time
consuming readjustments. Not infrequently their political influence is
substantially based upon a variety of social, political, and economic
strengths. In many cases a significant concentration occurs in a geo-
graphical area, so that an entire community, perhaps an entire state,
perceives that its welfare is intimately related to a continued export
flow. Thus, both leadership and a significant fraction of an electorate
perceive their economic and political interests in common and seek
to impose certain policies.
At the national level the perception of national problems may take
on similar views, but with differences. Exports earn foreign exchange
which translates to income for the producers and processors, but repre-
sents a source of development tools, imported consumer goods, and a
base for international loans in the view of national policymakers. Or,
expanded farm exports can help redress an adverse balance of pay-
ments and strengthen a nation's international financial position. Few
nations are able to long ignore the problems of its exporters.
Developing nations, as indicated in the previous section, seek meas-
ures which counter instability and raise the level of prices received.
Individually, they adopt devices which artificially enhance their com-
petitive position (or offset discrimination imposed by importers).
These devices include such items as favorable exchange rates for some
or all exports, tied international sales and purchases, and the sale by
semi-official agencies at losses for a period of time. Typically export
taxes are major sources of government revenue; the rate of taxes may
be reduced to stimulate or maintain exports.
Developed countries are subject to similar pressures, although ex-
port trade in farm products are critical to their international well-
being. Internal agricultural policy may provide modern inputs at less
than cost, as in a number of European countries, thus increasing do-
mestic production of many products, some of which may be exported.
More important, these stronger economies have sufficient resources to
subsidize exports, if they deem it in their interest to do so. Although
various arguments have been advanced to defend or condemn such
measures, most nations tend to view them as a form of dumping ad-
verse to the interests of other exporting nations. The United States
engages in this activity, for some 15 commodities in 1965-66 with
expenditures for nearly $600 million (table 10). Some progress has
been made through changes in domestic farm policy in cutting the num-
ber of commodities receiving subsidies and reducing the amount of
payment.
PAGENO="0174"
166 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
These pressures to export are the counterpart to the pressures not
to import, that is, to depend more heavily upon domestic production as
described elsewhere. Both types of measures interfere with the full
functioning of comparative advantage, and often spawn countermeas-
ures in other countries which lead to further interference with trade.
TABLE 10.-ESTIMATED EXPORT PAYMENTS ON U.S. AGRICULTURAL EXPORTS-AVERAGE PER UNIT AND TOTAL
YEAR ENDING JUNE 30, 1966
Commodity
Unit
Average per
unit (dollars)
Total (million
dollars)
Wheat grain Bushel
Wheat flour Hundredweight
Grain sorghums Bushels
Rice, milled Hundredweight
Cotton, upland Bale
Cotton, extra-long staple domestically produced do
Tobacco, unmanufactured Pound
Flaxseed Bushel
Linseed oil Pound
Peanuts do
Milk, nonfat dry do
Butter do
Milkfat (butteroil, anhydrous milkfat, ghce, etc.) do
Cheese do
Chickens, whole do
Total
0. 467
1. 05
. 095
1. 805
28.75
50.00
.05
. 2325
.01585
.07
- 036
. 299
. 368
.087
.056
354. 3
45. 5
23. 0
54. 7
87.9
.4
.3
1. 2
1.3
12.4
9. 8
2. 0
3. 7
.1
.2
596.8
Source: ERS-USDA, "Foreign Agricultural Trade of the United States," Economic Research Service, USDA, June 1967.
IV. TRADE PROBLEMS AND POLICIES AMONG ADVANCED CouNmIEs
The flow of trade in agricultural products that originates in or is
absorbed by advanced countries constitutes approximately 73 percent
of the world total. The dominant component among advanced coun-
tries consists of Temperate Zone agricultural products. The major net
importing areas are West Europe and Japan, while the major net
exporting areas are North America and Oceana. Trade within regions
is important in Europe and in North America. The net recent position
and changes in imports and exports since 1953-54 are indicated in
table 11.
Despite rather substantial increases in the flow of trade among
developed countries, major obstacles still exist; commercial conflict
among developed countries has increasingly focused on agriculture.
Rapidly expanding agricultural production based upon the technologi-
cal revolution in agriculture and the stimulus of national support poli-
cies has led to a situation where the principal problem of exporters is
to find outlets for excess production. Many of the policies that now in-
fluence trading relationships were developed for a purpose quite dif-
ferent from that which they now serve. The main impetus for the
programs now in effect in most countries stems from the need for
rapidly expanding food output during and following World War II.
While the central objective in agricultural policy has shifted to income
protection, other important objectives are sought. With the exception
of a few small countries where agricultural exports represent a sub-
stantial share of gross national product, emphasis is placed on accom-
modation of agricultural policy to internal economic, political, and
social requirements.
PAGENO="0175"
C,,
"C
CD
CD
"C
C,)
F-
CD
C-)
CD
F-
`C-)
C,)
>-
C,)
F-
C-)
CD
CD
CD
1-
CD
CD
F-
E
>
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 167
r -"'cr:- ~ ~"`~- ~
~I II I I I
>-~
CD
C/) C.)
CD
C-)
CD
E
-~ CD
`Do
C-)
`DC,)
PAGENO="0176"
168 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
COMMERCIAL MARKETS FOR U.S. AGRIOIJLTETRAL PRODUCTS
The bulk of U.S. commercial agricultural exports go to Japan,
Canada, and Western Europe. Exports to Canada largely consist of
fruit and vegetable products that cannot be produced for year-round
supply in northern climates. Comparative production advantage and
demand expansion associated with population and income growth in
Canada largely determine this flow of trade. Policy conflicts are minor
and steady, though only gradual increases in exports to Canada can
be anticipated.
Japan presents a unique situation in advanced country agricultural
trade. Because of extremely limited land resources, postwar agricul-
tural policy has been oriented toward expansion of output, first to
provide self-sufficiency in cereal food requirements and, in more recent
years, to provide increased quantities of livestock products, fruits,
and vegetables. Approximate self-sufficiency has been achieved in rice
but considerable quantities of wheat and barley are imported for food.
With increasing incomes consumption of livestock products is expand-
ing rapidly, requiring increasing imports of meat and milk products,
as well as feed grains to support domestic production. These can be
expected to continue despite restrictive import policies and domestic
price programs.
Japanese farms average only about I hectare in size. Commodity
price guarantees are required to maintain farm income and this, in
turn, led to close regulation of competing imports. All cereals are sub-
ject to state trading; quantitative controls are used to regulate imports
of livestock products, some oilseeds and oils, and processed foods. Thus,
while Japan has been expanding imports rapidly, growth has been
closely regulated and subsidiary to domestic agricultural programs.
Clearly the most complex issues surrounding trade relations in agri-
culture are those among individual and groups of European countries
and those between other exporting countries and West Europe. This
follows both from the economic and policy conditions surrounding
European agriculture. Recent changes in food consumption and agri-
cultural production have resulted in increasing pressures on some
markets, yet in other instances output tends to be inadequate. While
surplus stocks have generally not accumulated, increasing problems
in some countries and some commodities have resulted in expansion of
sales and export subsidies on international markets. In other cases,
agricultural product prices have risen rapidly in response to short
supply. In general, increases in both consumption and production have
been rapid.
Recent expansion in consumption has been most marked in live-
stock products other than milk and in fruits, vegetables and sugar, with
increases in the order of 2 to 3 percent per year for most of these
products (table 12).
Consumption levels, however, vary widely within Europe and the
potential for future expansion both in response to income and price
variation differs greatly by regions. In northern Europe, consumption
of some commodities is approaching North American levels and in-
come elasticities of demand are relatively low and declining. In south-
ern Europe considerable potential for expanded consumption with a
strong response to both higher income and lower price appears to
exist.
PAGENO="0177"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 169
TABLE 12.-WESTERN EUROPE: LEVEL AND CHANGE IN PER CAPITA CONSUMPTION AND CHANGE IN OUTPUT
OF SELECTED COMMODITIES
Consumption
Output
item
Quantity
consumed
per capita,
1962-63
(kilograms
per person)
Index 1962-63
(1952-53=100)
Item
Index 1962-63
(1952-53=100)
Bread grain
Rice
Potatoes
Vegetables
Fresh fruit
Total meat
Eggs
Sugar
Fats and oils
Liquid milk
Cheese
Butter -
97. 7
3.4
90.8
85.8
73. 6
50. 0
10.6
32. 2
16.8
98. 5
6. 6
4.9
89
110
88
111
126
135
133
131
121
96
132
126
Wheat
Coarsegrain
Rice
Sugar beet
Meat
Milk
Eggs
Fruit and vegetables
Oilseeds
128
137
92
131
149
121
145
130
136
Source: OECD Agricultural and Food Statistics, 1952-63, Paris, 1965.
Changes in consumption have been accompanied by relatively rapid
rates of expansion in the output for most commodities. The index of
total agricultural output increased during the same period to about
128 or an output expansion of nearly 3 percent per year. Coupled with
the fact that per capita consumption levels are now relatively high
for many food products and rates of increase appear to have declined
somewhat, a question arises as to whether historical rates of output
can be absorbed in the future.
The existing and developing market balance, however, varies con-
siderably between commodities. In wheat, annual increases in output
exceed the rate of increased in utilization. Imports are based pri-
marily on the need for quality wheat with little change in the gen-
eral level of imports since the early 1950's. On the other hand, sub-
sidized exports from western Europe, primarily France, to eastern
Europe and other areas have become an increasingly important safety
valve in providing outlets.
An even more rapid rate of expansion, about 4 percent per year,
has occurred in production of feed grains. However, because of a rapid
expansion in production of livestock, self-sufficiency has declined and
increasing imports have occurred. This can be expected to continue
and represent an expanding market for U.S. products.
With the exception of Mediterranean countries, both the produc-
tion and consumption of dairy products is relatively high and ex-
porters are experiencing increasing difficulty on international trade
flows. Dairy products trade is primarily intra-European with the
United Kingdom, Germany, and Italy as the principal importers and
with excess production in most other countries. Future expansion in
European markets will depend primarily on income growth in coun-
tries with lower income levels and on general population growth.
"Expanded consumption from these two sources, however, is not likely
to keep pace with output. Increasing pressures on dairy markets and
greater problems for exporters can be expected within the European
markets." 19 A number of European countries would like to expand
foreign outlets but short of liberalized trading relationships with
1~ OECD unpublished material.
82-246-67-12
PAGENO="0178"
170 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
North America, there is little prospect for major shipments, except
on concessional terms.
Fruit and vegetable consumption per capita is relatively high
throughout western Europe. The major trade flows are intra-Euro-
pean from the Netherlands and Mediterranean countries to other
European countries. Shipments of canned products from North Amer-
ica are increasing, however. European production has increased at
the relatively rapid rate of 3 percent per year. `With consumption
levels already high, it appears that this rate of expansion cannot be
maintained in the future. `While our exports to west Europe have in-
creased, the expansion has not been rapid and cannot be expected in
the future to represent large quantities.
Trade relations with western Europe are closely tied to agricul-
tural income policy. With the exception of the United Kingdom and
the Netherlands, incomes in agriculture lag, sometimes substantially,
`behind those in other sectors. The central focus of policy to maintain
or increase incomes in agriculture continues to be implemented
through variety of direct price supports and policies that directly in-
terfere with agricultural trade. Further, as economic growth con-
tinues and incomes expand in nonf arm sectors, the scope and corn-
plexity of measures taken tend to increase coverage so that virtually
all commodities receive some form of market protection in most
countries.
Price support and supplementary measures have led to widely dis-
persed price levels and hence in the relationship to world price levels.
These relationships for wheat are shown in table 13. A similar pattern
exists for other grains and dairy products. Adequate data to indicate
the overall effectiveness of support measures with consistent compari-
son between countries and change through time are not easily avail-
able but the general pattern is that prices have increased though some-
times not commensurate with general inflation; hence real prices have
declined somewhat.
TABLE 13.-WHEAT: SELECTED PRICE DATA
Country Price in United States dollars Ratio of support prices to
per bushel, 1963-64 import value 1962
Denmark 1. 58 92
United Kingdom 1. 63 97
ireland 1.83 105
france 1.94 111
Greece 2.01 118
Netherlands 2.09 112
Austria 2. 12 124
Belgium 2.12 123
Italy 2.20 129
Sweden 2.30 129
Spain 2. 30 121
Portugal 2.34 137
Germany 2.38 139
Norway 3.20 187
Switzerland 3. 68 215
Finland 4. 22 204
Source: FAO Developments in Agricultural Price Stabilization and Support Policies, 1959-64, CCP 65/5, Mar. 22, 1965.
PAGENO="0179"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 171
The method of price determination and the political mix in Euro-
pean agriculture assures that price supports will continue to be im-
portant and that price levels will, in general, be maintained.20 The
agricultural population is relatively large in many countries and, un-
like the Uni~d States, the relationship between agricultural interest
groups and government is often relatively close and formalized. Farm
organizations often either participate directly in the year to year price
determination or in the basic formulation of agricultural legislation
and price computation methods. In Sweden long-term contracts are
negotiated directly between the government and the farm organiza-
tion. In other countries, prices are subject to more frequent negotia-
tion and to automatic renegotiation if general price levels change by
more than a specified amount. Where direct negotiation is not re-
quired, government price fixing often occurs in direct consultation
with farm organizations, or within closely specified rules and in some
cases through the direct use of farm cost-return data. These methods
tend to assure price such that relative incomes in agriculture, if not
always prices, will be generally maintained irrespective of market
pressures or general price level changes.
The scope of price supports historically has tended to be limited
largely by export considerations and in less-developed countries by
the sheer weight of agriculture in the total of the economy. Increas-
ing adequacy of supplies and expanded treasury burdens more re-
cently have led to some restriction on price supports in an effort to
reduce the burden of treasury costs. In some cases, this has taken the
form of shifting costs to consumers through higher prices. It has also
taken the form of specific limitations on the proportion of a product
eligible for price support or of declining scales of support with in-
creased output. These limitations, while having some implication for
adjusting production to market demand, have not generally been de-
signed specifically for this purpose. With the exception of a few spe-
cial commodities, direct supply regulation has not developed and
probably cannot be expected.
Thus agricultural protectionism in Europe under national policies,
had become very extensive and covered all major commodities in vir-
tually all countries. The methods and instruments used for implement-
ing policy include internal price support plus a large variety of trade
controls including traditional import restrictions such as customs
duties and quantitive restrictions as well as newer devices such as
minimum prices and variable levies, import calendars, conditional im-
ports and mixing-in regulations, state trading, equalization taxes on
imports and preferential trading systems. Countries with export sur-
pluses have adopted numerous measures to facilitate sales including
direct export subsidies, transport subsidies, special tax exemptions,
price equalization arrangement, and other measures to assist in sales.
The intermix of domestic and trade policies thus is comprehensive
and trade policy discussion becomes a discussion of national agricul-
tural policy.
20 The following several pages are based in part on a previous article: v. Sorenson,
"Trade Policies and Prospects in Western Europe," Journal of Farm Economics, December
1960.
PAGENO="0180"
172 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
IMPLICATIONS OF THE EEC AND UNITED KINGDOM POLICIES
Two major recent developments have occurred that change the set-
ting but not necessarily the focus of European agricultural policy.
These are the formation of the EEC and the EFTA. EEC agricul-
tural policy is based on objectives and attitudes long embedded in
national agricultural policies. Changes are aimed largely at arriving
at a common market organization but not at reducing, or for that
matter greatly increasing, the amount of protection to agriculture. To
this point the EEC has not developed a broadly oriented agricultural
policy. The principal focus has been on domestic price supports, pro-
tection against competitive imports and, where necessary, export sub-
sidies. These policies have recently taken on concrete form and will
apply to 85 percent or more of EEC production. While prices are rela-
tively high as shown in table 14, the overall increase from preexisting
levels does not appear to be great.2' Price guarantees will apply to 85.
percent or more of EEC agricultural output.
TABLE 14.-EEC: COMMON PRICES FOR SELECTED PRODUCTS
Product
Market22 price in
units of account
(1 U.A.=$1 American)
Average U.S.
price in Chicago
markets, 1964
Soft wheat
Barley
Rye
Corn
Cattle (on the hoof)
Calves (on the hoof)
Hogs
Milk
2.90 bu
2.88bu
2.56 bu
2.97 bu
31.11 unite
40. 68 unit c
32.66 unit
4.43 unit
1. 46,
1.01
a 1.03
b 1.26
22. 86
d 20. 99
17. 40
13. 37-5. 35
a U.S. average price received by farmers.
Beef steers, all grades.
Medium quality.
d United States, average cost to slaughter, all grades.
1964-65 marketing year.
1 Low price is U.S. price paid by condenseries; higher is U.S. average dealer price for fluid use. EEC price is for all milk.
22 Market prices, while not precisely comparable, tend to more closely approximate U.S. terminal market prices than farm
prices.
In evaluating EEC policy, the assumption is normally made that if
prices are maintained at high levels this will protect high-cost produc-
tion and import requirements will be lessened. While this may be true,
it falls somewhat short of evaluating the total impact of the EEC.
To the extent that the formation of the EEC increases the rate of the
economic growth, an income demand effect will take place. If this
occurs in the face of prices which are not in excess of the average
that would exist in the absence of the EEC, there is a net stimulation
to food requirements which increases import needs.
On the other hand, as indicated above, the formation of the EEC
may have some stimulating effect on output through providing the
basis for specialization and exchange within the community and thus
reduce import requirements. The effect of EEC price policy on total
production in agriculture, however, can easily be overestimated. With-
in the range of feasible price levels, it is unlikely that the total re-
source commitment to agriculture will shift measurably.
21 For an evaluation of probable changes in prices to farmers due to Implementation of
EEC policy see D. EEP., "The Impact of Agricultural Policies on Regional Grain and
Livestock Prices In the European Economic Community," mimeo, to be published.
PAGENO="0181"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 173
A recent comprehensive study of the grain and livestock economy
of the EEC suggests that overall price developments will likely stimu-
late the consumption of some livestock products and thus potentially
increase feed grain requirements.23 Relative prices between agricul-
tural commodities will change somewhat but not enough to cause
major shifts in the total output of grain or livestock products. Analy-
sis of production conditions in all of the EEC countries indicate that
technology and organization have had a great deal more influence
than price change on the level and composition of output in recent
years.24 This will likely continue to be the case for some time to come.
A second major factor of European agricultural policy, the trade
implications of which are not yet fully clear, are recent developments
in the United Kingdom. Direct agreements regulating imports have
been completed with the major suppliers of several important com-
modities. The trend began in 1962 with essentially unilateral action
by the United Kingdom to place quotas on butter. In 1963, agreements
were concluded with principal suppliers of bacon to regulate import
quantities. Agreements concluded with four principal suppliers of
grain in 1964 to allocate imports between suppliers and establish
minimum import prices. Since 1964, 17 additional countries have
signed similar agreements so that virtually all grain imports by the
United Kingdom come from signatory countries. Import levies can
be applied if a signatory country fails to comply with minimum
prices.
All of these agreements (except butter) were entered into with the
mplicit or explicit understanding that market growth would be
shared between domestic (United Kingdom) producers and exporters.
Whether this will follow isn't yet clear. `While United Kingdom sup-
port policies have been adjusted with a view toward balancing market
requirements, the national economic plan developed in 1965 empha-
sizes the importance of food imports as an element in the balance of
payments. Expansion in livestock output is visualized with increased
teed grain requirements met largely from domestic sources. Market
growth for outside suppliers will cease if this is accomplished.
PROBLEMS IN FUTURE POLICY CHANGE
The solution to problems of international adjustment in agriculture
are complicated by domestic income policy. Income policy, in turn, is
highly dependent on problems of production organization and re-
source use in agriculture. Central to the question of whether trade
relations among advanced countries will improve is the extent to
which production methods and particularly farm organization can
be adapted to modern technological conditions in high cost producing
countries. These changes will not depend solely on conditions and
policies related to agriculture. General economic growth rates will
23 V. Sorenson and D. Hathaway, "Changes in the Grain-Livestock Economy of the EEC
and Their Effects on Foreign Trade Patterns," mimeo, to be published.
24 George E. Rossmiller, "Changes in the Grain and Livestock Economies of west Ger-
many With Projections to 1970 and i~97;5," "Changes in the Grain and Livestock Economies
of the Benelux Countries With Projections to 1970 and i975," mimeos, to be published.
Fred A. Mangum, Jr., "Changes in the Grain and Livestock Economies of Italy With Pro-
jections to 1970 and i97~." mimeo, to be published.
Michel J. Petit and Jean-Baptiste viallon, "French Grain and Livestock Production
Projections to 1970 and 1975," mimeo, to be published.
PAGENO="0182"
174 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
improve the climate for change in agriculture through increased de-
mand, particularly in lower income countries, but more directly and
in all countries through the labor market.
Achieving structural transformation is important for two reasons.
First, short of major structural reorganization in agriculture, the
flexibility to adapt output to market requirements as between com-
modities will be difficult to achieve. Many small farms with excess
family labor, limited capital, and very limited land resources must
employ labor intensive techniques and maximize returns to land. This
resource organization limits flexibility in responding to market and
price conditions and leads to excess output of some products in the'
face of limited or inadequate output of other products. Second, the
small farm is high cost and large numbers of high cost producers'
create conditions where governments have little flexibility in reducing
price support levels and trade barriers.
A significant question is whether policies will be implemented to
effectively support or encourage reorganization. Change could un-
doubtedly be facilitated by market pressures if permitted to operate,
but this is difficult to achieve in the face of political pressures, and it is
likely that achi'eving change will depend heavily on policies that are
aimed directly at changing farm organization rather than through
price pressures. Maintenance of income on small farms will become
more and more difficult as time passes and increasing attention must
be given to direct programs for structural improvement.
Legislation to improve farm organization in both Japan and West-
ern Europe includes efforts to provide specifically for consolidation
and amalgamation of land into larger units as well as broader pro-
grams aimed at promoting rural development and assisting rural peo-
ple to prepare for and accept other employment. With few exceptions,
however, these programs have not progressed far and in large part are
aimed at gradually eliminating land parcelization and achieving a
reduction in the number of very small farms. Programs are not aimed
at encouraging the general `structural reorganization that is required
to provide an efficient commercial agriculture utilizing modern tech-
nology and with `sufficient land and capital resources to provide an.
increasing level of income without relatively high prices and conse-
quent trade restrictions.
Thus, it cannot be assumed that change will take place quickly to'
bring agriculture to a lower cost basis requiring less isolation from
world markets. Political, social, and institutional restraints to change
based on historical factors are numerous. In these areas, the EEC has
taken oniy minor and cautious `steps and there is little evidence that
leadership for this kind of change will develop under the common
agricultural policy. Further, agricultural policies are sometimes
strongly influenced by oth'er factors. In Japan, achieving self-suffi-
ciency in food cereal production has an important bearing on agricul-
tural policy. Sweden and some other European countries, seek to main-
tain a given level of self-sufficiency in food production even at an
economic cost. In most European countries the maintenance of a de-
sirable rural social structure, again at an economic cost, is a strong'
motivating factor in policy development.
While conditions vary among countries both exporters and import-
ers engage in widespread intervention in domestic agricultural mar-
PAGENO="0183"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF TJ.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 175
kets and protectionism in international markets. Subsidies and other
aids serve the same purpose for exporters as trade restrictions for mi-
porters-namely to maintain domestic prices above free market levels.
It is clear, therefore, as recently indicated by the FAO,2' that in inter-
national agricultural markets "palliatives which have no mfiuence on
domestic support policies cannot be expected to effect any significant
improvement to the trade situation for this group of commodities.
However, the social pressures which led to the need for agricultural
support continue to exist. Farm incomes in the developed temperate-
zone countries continue to trail behind those in the rest of the economy,
and as a consequence it will be by no means easy to gain agreement
on the ways in which domestic policies are to be changed."
Change in the concept of income policy for agriculture will be re-
quired. Price supports alone, without supporting programs to adjust
agriculture to modern conditions, will achieve little for many farmers
and will perpetuate the conflict between domestic policy and a more
liberal trading policy. Progress in reducing the level of direct income
supports, especially in high cost countries, can be accelerated through
programs that seek to: (1) create structural reforms through consoli-
dation and amalgamation of holdings, inheritance laws, ecetera; (2)
provide help to the low-income or marginal farmer by creating the
conditions for the transfer of his labor elsewhere in the economy and
by financial aid; by accelerating farm improvement programs; by
creation of supplementary income sources through vocational training;
employment information; decentralization of industry, ecetera; (3)
strengthen the commercial farmer's economic position through agri-
cultural education and advisory services, marketing aid, income as
against price supports, ecetera.
This will entail far-reaching changes in the approach to agricul-
tural income protection. The full recognition in agricultural policy of
what is basically a very simple concept, namely that income is a func-
tion of both price and quantity, and its full incorporation into Gov-
ernment programs, is fundamental to achieving the kind of change in
domestic policy that will ultimately be needed to reduce agricultural
protectionism and achieve improved trading relations.
V. TRADE PROBLEMS AND POLICIES OF SPECIAL RELEVANCE FOR
DEVELOPING NATIONS
The developing nations' contribution to world trade is small in rela-
tion to their population. Among themselves, despite constituting the
majority of the world's population, they contribute only 6 to 7 percent
of the total trade. Most of their international trade is with developed
nations, exporting to them primary products of agriculture, forest,
fishery, or mineral origin, while importing a wide range of commodi-
ties, including food. The priority given to development usually is
high, usually requires substantial imports of capital goods, and ~en-
erally leads to foreign exchange deficits. These deficits in turn limit
the potential exports of the developed nations. Thus, both economic
and humanitarian goals of the United States could be more fully met
if the value of developing countries' exports could be expanded. But
since most developing countries project limited export expansion,
~` FAO, Commodity Policy Studies, No. 2, op. cit.
PAGENO="0184"
176 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
and because certain desired connotations of modernity attach to in-
dustrialization and a declining dependence on agriculture, import
substitution (manufacturing) has become a major element of policy.
Hence, behind the specific problems, discussed below, lie this need to
increase the volume of exchange earnings (the preferred position),
and to use the exchange earned for high priority imports.
AGRICULTURAL SELF-SUFFICIENCY EFFORTS
The agricultural leadership in many developing nations, especially
in Latin America, often have a background of experience with large-
scale agriculture. Their farm management decisions often place sub-
stantial emphasis on holding cash expenditures down, to make the farm
nearly self-sufficient, even when additional purchased inputs would
increase production by several times their costs. The concept of special-
ization and comparative advantage is not applied to individual firms to
the extent that is applicable. Price instability, variation in Government
policy, institutional rigidities, and fear of war or depression induced
input shortages, provide a general economic setting hindering the
full application of comparative advantage among farms. Moreover,
the inflationary pressures common to many developing nations, and
consequent rising costs and uncertain supplies of inputs, also rein-
force the drift into self-sufficiency.
The same approach carries into national policies for agriculture,
reinforced by the desire to save foreign exchange. Thus, import sub-
stitution policies also operate within the agricultural sector. Not in-
frequently, more enthusiasm attaches to production policies and re-
search developments which will make production possible or larger
for a new farm commodity than to programs which increase the pro-
duction and efficiency of a present major export product.
In the short term, foreign exchange may be saved (though usually
less than anticipated), and uationalistic pride is swelled. But, for the
longer run, scarce scientific manpower has been diverted and spread too
thinly, while production efficiency and comparative advantage has
lagaed in the important export products.
These approaches to agricultural policy reduce the degree of special-
ization and extent of comparative advantage. A wider range of
products are produced for domestic use than would be provided with
specialization and exchange. And exports of the product with greatest
advantage often are not pressed as far as recent economic conditions
warrant because secondary products are stimulated in efforts to di-
versify.
INTERNATIONAL COMMODITY AGREEMENTS
The agricultural price experience of many export countries since
1925 has been interpreted as a signal to avoid one crop economies, to
intervene in the international marketplace where nossible in order to
raise prices, and to seek means beyond price of products and volume of
export which assure a stable or preferably a rising volume of foreign
exchange earnings. International Commodity Agreements have been
sought as a commodity-oriented program with beneficial price imports.
The merits of the twin problems of price and earnings instability and
chronic deterioration in the terms of trade were reviewed in chapter
III. But whatever the merits of these debates, producers of certain
PAGENO="0185"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 177
commodities do consider price trends unfavorable and do seek public
and international efforts to counter price adversities.
Despite the many discussions and efforts to formulate programs,
Blau notes: 26
"Yet in the 17 years since the end of the war, international agree-
ments have been concluded for only five commodities-wheat, sugar,
coffee, tin, and olive oil. Of these, the oniy two functioning at present
as agreements which qualify as producer-consumer agreements and
contain some operative provisions designed to influence world trade,
are those for wheat and tin. The total value of world trade in the five
commodities for which agreements have been concluded in one form or
another accounts for about 10 percent of world trade in primary prod-
ucts. The proportion of trade actually covered by agreement provisions
is considerably less.
"In recent years, there has been a growing sense of disappointment,
particularly on the part of the primary producing countries, with the
limited results attained so far. Increasing attention has been paid to
other techniques which could serve either as a substitute for, or as a
complement to, the working of International Commodity Agreements."
Since this was written the series of 1-year arrangements on coffee
have been replaced by a more comprehensive 5-year quota agreement.
Some of the discussions with the EEC, particularly France, have urged
the expanded use of commodity agreements. Conceptually, Interna-
tional Commodity Agreements impose limitations on trade. Though
operating internationally, they are close kin to domestic price supports
and storage operations such as the CCC wheat and cotton programs.
They pose new problems while dealing to some degree with the older
problem of low prices. The lack of control of surplus productive capac-
ity and the handling of the produced excess are crucial limitations; in
fact stable prices, if attained, may actually attract new excess capacity.
Stabilization programs often "stabilize prices upward" and are very
difficult to readjust once established, as indicated by some domestic
U.S. experience with price supported commodities. Quotas imposed
under such programs usually reflect past production history and oper-
ate as if comparative advantage were static and equal for all pro-
ducers. Economic logic would call for a reduction in production for
high cost producers and for those whose comparative advantage was
declining, but little success has been attained, partly because interna-
tional reallocations of quotas are even more difficult to apply than re-
gional allocations within a nation.
Another approach to this same problem of controlling world prices
functions through national marketing boards, as in West Africa for
cocoa and palm oil. Such agencies have attempted to average payments
to farmers over a series of years, while selling in a fluctuating world
market. To some degree their decisions to sell or to hold also influenced
the level of prices. More recently, a priority purpose has become agen-
cies through which to collect the equivalent of an export tax, thus
accumulating funds for development.
Both of these approaches to improving the price situation have a
number of other economic, administrative, and political limitations.
In an effort to deal with the basic development problem-namely, the
~ Gerda Blau. "International Commodity Arrnngement~" reprinted in C. Eicher and
L. Witt, Agriculture in Economic Development, McGraw-HuH, i964, pp. 322-339.
PAGENO="0186"
178 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
instability of export earnings-and to avoid the limitations of a single-
commodity approach, several combinations of measures to guarantee
exporting earnings have been discussed. A report by a U.N. commit-
tee 27 suggests the costs and returns of several levels of guarantees.
More recently the World Bank and International Monetary Fund have
been asked to evaluate alternative approaches.
Each of the approaches discussed so far in this chapter implies a
continued emphasis on agricultural and raw material exports and ways
to make this dependency supportive of stability and development. But
most developing nations place substantial emphasis on industrializa-
tion and measures which increase exchange earnings. For this we turn
to another area.
DISCRIMINATION AGAINST THE EXPORT OF PROCESSED
AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS
Developed nations often have tariffs in the following pattern: Un-
processed raw material, 5 percent of value; partially processed, 10 per-
cent of value; fully processed, 15 percent of value.
A tariff at this level does not appear to be a serious hindrance to
trade. And it is not for the unprocessed raw material. However, the
second and third 5 percents become rather large tariffs in relation to
value added by processing. Assume that processing adds 50 percent to
value, so that the following values apply:
Value
Tariff
rate
(percent)
Tariff
charged
Marginal increment
Raw material (hundredweight)
Partially processed
Fully processed
Raw material to fully processed
10.00
11.50
15. 00
5
10
15
0.50
1.15
2.25
5 percent.
43 percent (0.65÷1.50).
31 percent (1.10÷3.50)
35 percent (1.75÷5.00).
In this example the rate of protection against the raw material is a
low 5 percent, but the rate of protection against processing is 43 and
31 percent. Against such tariff rates the developing nations have no
choice; they export the raw material.
Yet, the natural and logical first steps toward industrializing a de-
veloping country would be factories to process the nation's maj or raw
materials. While the labor costs of processing are likely to be smaller
in a developing country, the capital costs are usually larger, so that
the cost differentials normally would not counterbalance the differ-
ences in tariffs. For a plant to process their own raw materials the
economies of scale are likely to be advantageous compared with a plant
for an important substitution industry, since the size of the plant is
limited only by the volume of raw materials, rather than by the size
of the internal market. This statement is especially relevant for small
economies.
The question now becomes, "How important is this type of discrimi-
nation?" Harry Johnson cites some unpublished computations by
Padma Mallampally, as shown in table 15.
°7 United Nations, "International Compensation for Flucuations in Commodity Trade,"
13/3447, E/CN. 13/40, New York, 1961.
PAGENO="0187"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 179
TABLE 15.-NOMINAL AND EFFECTIVE PROTECTION OF PROCESSING OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS, UNITED
STATES AND EUROPEAN ECONOMIC COMMUNITY
[In percent]
Processing industry
U.S. protection rates
EEC protection rates
Nominal Effective
Nominal Effective
Coconut oil (refined)
Jute fabrics
Cigarettes
Hard fiber manufactures (cordage)
5. 7 57. 5
3. 1 5. 3
47. 2 89. 0
15. 1 38. 0
15. 0 150. 0
23. 0 39.6
(a) (a)
(a) (a)
a Not available.
Source: Unpublished computations by Padma Mallampally from scattered data on processing costs. Harry G. Johnson,
Economic Policies Toward Less Developed Countries, The Brookings Institution, Washington, D.C., page 91.
An aggregative analysis is provided for five developed nations in
a study by Balassa. See table 16. `For both sets of data, clearly the
effective tariff is substantially above the nominal tariff. Note also
that advanced processing enjoys greater tariff protection, for the
U.K. rising from 7.6 to 17.8 percent.
TABLE 16.-AVERAGES OF EFFECTIVE AND NOMINAL RATES OF DUTIES FOR FOUR COMMODITY CATEGORIES,19
[In percent]
Category
United
States
Nom- Effec-
inal tive
United
Kingdom
._
Nom. Effec-
inal tivo
Common
Market
.~
Nom- Effoc-
ioal tive
Sweden
Nom- Effec-
inal tive
Japan
-
Nom- Effec-
inal tive
Intermediate products Ia
Intermediate products lIb
Consumergoods
Investment goods
All commodities
8. 8
15.2
17.5
10.3
11. 6
17.6
28.6
25.9
13.9
20. 0
11. 1
17.2
23.8
17.0
15. 5
23. 1
34.3
40.4
23.0
27. 8
7.6
13.3
17.8
11.7
11. 9
12. 0
28.3
30.9
15.0
18. 6
3.0
8. 5
12.4
8.5
6. 8
5.3
20.8
23.9
12.1
12.5
11.4
16. 6
27.5
17.1
16. 2
23.8
34.5
50.5
22.0
29.5
a Manufactures whose main inputs are natural raw materials.
b Intermediate goods at higher levels of fabrication.
Source: Bela Balassa, `Tariff Protection in Industrial Countrios: An Evolution," Journal of Political Economy, vol. 73
December 1965), p. 591.
The final line of table 16 indicates that for 1962 the nominal U.S.
tariff rate of 11.6 percent becomes an effective tariff rate of 20 percent.
Little information is available to the authors to calculate the rates
application when the Kennedy Round rates go into effect. But it seems
clear from the preliminary information that this problem will con-
tinue to be significant and to represent an important area for future
discussions between the developed and the developing nations.
INTERNAL GROWTH IN DEMAND IN DEVELOPING NATIONS
Exports develop when the volume of production is sufficiently large
to more than satisfy internal demand. If price differentials between
internal and international markets offset the costs of exporting then
the exportable surplus is sold. If price differentials are too small
or nonexistent, then internal prices must decline, production must
shift to other products, or a public agency must intervene to purchase
and hold the commodites pending future world price increases, or to
arrange for exports at a loss.
PAGENO="0188"
180 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
The increases in per capita income, modest though they may be,
graduafly increase the level of domestic demand. In developing na-
tions the income elasticity of demand is higher than in developed na-
tions, 0.5 or 0.6 compared with 0.2 or 0.3; thus, a given increase in in-
come converts to a larger demand than in developed countries. High
rates of population increase, stemming from high birth rates and
sharp decreases in death rates, also add substantially to the increase
in effective demand.
Thus, over time, the internal consumption of agricultural products
increases. A number of developing nations, once exporters of rice or
beef and certain other food products, have become less significant in
world markets or have disappeared entirely. This set of circumstances
ensues when the expansion of production lags behind the dynamics of
income and population. This tendency toward a larger internal con-
sumption pervades all countries. Continued and expanded exports re-
quires a significant internal effor~t to increase production. Thus, a
static or relatively static situation with respect to agriculture will
lead to a gradual reduction in exportable surpluses, a decline in the
volume of exports, and a reduction in exchange earnmgs, unless in-
creases in world prices compensate for the decreases in volume. A pres-
ent concern is that a significant number of developing countries are
becoming less capable of feeding their own population.
PRODUCTION, POPULATION AND FOOD AID
The rate of agricultural expansion in developing nations has been
substantial. "During the period 1948-63, the rate of increase in crop
production . . . exceeded 5 percent a year in seven countries
Israel, Sudan, Mexico, Costa Rica, the Philippines, Tanganyika and
Yugoslavia. It varied from 4 to 5 percent a year in five other coun-
tries . . . Taiwan, Turkey, Venezuela, Thailand and Brazil."28
Food production is expanding in the developing countries of the
world. During this century, at least, the United States only occasion-
ally has attained increases of 3 percent; the usual figure is smaller
and occasionally negative. However, these substantial improvements
in agricultural production are matched with high rates of increase
in population and by increasing per capita incomes, part of which
goes to increase per capita consumption of food products. Nonethe-
less, most of the countries listed above have been able to improve
their consumption export balance. However, among the nations whose
agricultural progress has been less dramatic, many face actual or po-
tential shortages of food at current prices; with possible combina-
tions of alternative consequences of (1) increasing prices to con-
sumers, (2) rationing of existing supplies, (3) increased investment
in agriculture designed to expand domestic production more rapidly,
(4) expanding imports, (5) population control as a long-term
solution.
Popular discussions of world food problems have been confused
by the mixing of two concepts, the need for food and the demand
for food. The need for food derives from estimates of the kinds and
amounts of food required to feed the world's population a nutrition-
2SERS/TJSDA, "Changes in Agriculture in 26 Developing Nations 1948 to 1963" Foreign
Agricultural Economic Report No. 27, November 1965, pp. 6-7.
PAGENO="0189"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 181
ally balanced diet. It begs the questions of: (1) who will pay for this
food? (2) how will those now consuming poor diets be induced to
consume a better diet? and (3) how can the requisite foods be distrib-
uted to those people and geographical areas where deficits exist? The
demand for food, on the other hand, reflects consumers' desire backed
up with money which they are spending. The need for food increases
as population increases. The demand for food increases as incomes
expand. The major interest in these discussions of trade problems is
with the demaiid for food and other agricultural products, the com-
merial trade that caters to this demand, and the international trade
that helps adjust national supply to demand.
However, a substantial portion of the U.S. Public Law 480 exports
fall in between these two concepts. Reviewing past shipments, grants
under former titles II and III (present title II) represent donations
to attend to food needs which otherwise would be met only with great
difficulty. Long-term loans under former title IV (present title I) rep-
resent food sold on a dollar repayment basis, thus bridging a current
foreign exchange gap. Sales for local currency under former title I
(and still possible, though restricted, under present title I) represent
.a combination of grants and sales depending upon the uses to which
the local currency is put in the specific case. The shipments under the
world food program, and certain bilateral programs as for Canada,
fall into a food aid or development aid category; i.e., development
grants for specified purposes. Most sales of wheat by France probably
should be classified as concessional sales or export dumping since the
principal concession is in the price. The new multilateral program
developing out of the Kennedy Round negotiations on grains will
provide a substantial amount of food aid from present importing
countries. Present reports on the agreement do not make clear whether
these shipments should be classified as grants or as concessional sales.
Any discussion of food aid in the future rests heavily upon the likely
trend in world population and the prospects for a great acceleration
in family planning. If current projections are realized, the pressures
for accelerated food aid will be well nigh insatiable, especially if cou-
pled with a growth in commercial trade stemming from larger per
capita incomes in Japan and Western Europe, and from concessions
made in the Kennedy Round negotiations. If family planning is accel-
erating rapidly, as argued by a few population specialists, then modest
and feasible levels of concessional and grant shipments will continue,
with a gradual improvement in the average levels of human nutrition.
To complete this section we turn to a recent research report on
Public Law 480, 29 selecting from the summary chapter. This material
discusses the impact upon development and prices of past Public Law
480 shipments.
"An examination of the program's impact in several countries mdi-
cates that farm products can provide useful economic assistance, but
they do not do so automatically. The internal policies of the recipient
nations can do much to compensate for or override the possible adverse
price effects of additional imports * * * within the framework of
the individual Public Law 480 agreement, a recipient nation may find
~ Witt, Lawrence, and Carl Bicher, "The E~ects of U.S. Agricultural Surplus Disposal
Programs on Recipient Countries," Research Bulletin 2, Agricultural Experiment Station,
Michigan State UnIversity, 1964, pp. 69-72.
PAGENO="0190"
182 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
it possible to reduce commercial imports, thereby reducing the volume
of additional imports and increasing the amount of industrial goods
and non-surplus farm products imported * * *
"The economic events which led the United States to inaugurate
this program in 1954 and to expand it in ensuing years are not neces-
sarily limited to a desire for economic development among the poorer
nations. In fact, the program became one of the ways in which the
structural weakness of the national economy (not of agricultural
policy alone) could be made less onerous. These events are likely to be
repeated in other advanced nations. Several western European coun-
tries, and the European Common Market, look upon overseas disposal
as a convenient tool of policy. Subscriptions to the world food pro-
gram reflect the same forces as those underlying the Public Law 480
program. Advances in agricultural productivity similar to those of
the United States are well underway in the advanced nations-based
upon reduced price uncertainty, improved technology, better manage-
ment, more capital, more nonfarm produced inputs, and farm con-
solidation. These additional supplies move to markets where price and
income elasticities are moderate and declining as economic growth
pushes up individual incomes. The combination of low price elastic-
ities and low downward supply response threaten to provide lower
farm prices and incomes. In many countries of Western Europe there
is good reason to expect a political response which supports and con-
tinues price policies which bring "surpluses" into being; in some
commodities, they already exist."
"These countries too, have economic and humanitarian reasons to
send surpluses overseas, to aid development and improve nutri-
tion***
"The convenient marriage which Public Law 480 represents stems
from the substantial resources which developed countries must corn-
mit in order not to produce certain commodities, while the less-devel-
oped world hesitates to commit substantial resources to expand pro-
duction of the same or similar commodities. If the world is short of
food and prepared to insure that adequate supplies are made evail-
able, then the resource cost of producing additional supplies may well
be less, in the shortrun, if produced in pve~enfly deve1oped nìations
and distributed at low or zero prices where needed.
`~Whatever the merits of a temporary prooTalu, it does h~vo hoth
short-term and long-term difficulties. First. the possibility of Public
Law 480 supplies at low cost may postpone making fund arnen~~l struc-
tural adjustments both in sending and in receiving countries. The
economy of each is less strong than it might be. Second. the commodi-
ties in surplus may not be the commodities most needed for develop-
ment or for better nutrition. Public Law 480 has done little to reduce
the apparent substantial protein deficiencies especially prevalent in
South Asia. Third, for the developed countries at least, the process of
structural adjustment is in operation, and, there is no assurance that
surplus commodities will be available for an indefinite period. Fourth,
with the high rate of population increase in underdeveloped nations,
it seems unlikely that the developed nations alone can continuously ex-
pand food production to feed them. The local country almost certainly
must supply the majority of the necessary increased food needs * * ~
PAGENO="0191"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 183
"Finally, attention must be given to the question of whether Public
Law 480 inhibits development through adverse effects upon agricul-
ture. The evidence here is equivocal. Additional imported farm prod-
ucts have helped prevent consumer protests and permitted an expansion
of industry without necessarily a concomitant, supporting expansion
in internal agriculture and marketed supplies. This is development,
even if it is one-sided, and may contain a fatal weakness. (Develop-
ment theory is not sufficiently advanced to permit a final judgment.)
In some countries agricultural development appears to have been dis-
couraged as a consequence of Public Law 480 imports. In other coun-
tries, Public Law 480 imports have either become an agricultural
development resource, or have been neutralized through internal pol-
icy adjustments-thus encouraging or not discouraging the simultane-
ous development of local agriculture."
VI. THE U.S. INTERESTS IN AGRICULTURAL TRADE
Annual reviews and day-by-day decisiomnaking by Congress and
the executive agencies deal mainly with the immediate and direct in-
terests of the United States. Papers such as these emphasize the long-
term and the broad, sometimes less, direct aspects of U.S. interests
in one or another public issue. Neither approach should ignore the
other; but the pressure of events and administration emphasizes the
short run. The attainment of short-term goals can be a step toward
improved long-term relations, but, not infrequently, the short term
is at least partially in conflict with the long term. With these thoughts
we turn to an examination of U.S. interests in agricultural trade.
U.S. INTERESTS
Agricultural trade relates to a number of economic, social, political,
and humanitarian interests of the United States. Those that seem to
be most important are listed below; it is presumptuous to suggest the
relative importance of each to Members of Congress. In fact, one of
the purposes of this set of hearings, is for your Committee to recom-
mend on the importance of this topic to the United States. We will
try, on the basis of the past, to suggest some of the interests that seem
to be important. Briefly, the United States has the following interest
in agricultural trade:
1. Agricultural exports provide about 20 percent of U.S. export
earnings.
2. The export market represents a large outlet, 35 to 50 percent,
for certain commodities, notably wheat, feed grains, cotton, tobacco,
soy beans, and certain other fats and oils.
3. International agricultural trade brings to U.S. consumers a
wide range of tropical and semitropical products at reasonable cost,
which contributes to a higher level of living.
4. Agricultural product exports make a significant contribution to
the network of world trade, which increases the economic interdepend-
ence between the United States and the major world trading nations.
Such interrelationships have many important, though subtle, influ-
ences toward reducing the likelihood of conflict among these nations.
PAGENO="0192"
184 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
5. Trade, including agricultural trade, provides for specialization
and makes use of comparative advantage, so that the participating
economies become more productive, thus, enabling their citizens to en-
joy higher levels of living.
6. Improved international political relations often are associated
with an expanding volume of trade. It is not always clear which is
the primary cause and which is the effect, but once well started, ex-
panding trade usually improves the general tone of international
relations.
7. Agricultural trade is one means for improving the level of human
nutrition and well-being in nations whose agricultural productivity
and resource base is limited.
8. Concessional or grant exports of farm products help satisfy our
humanitarian concern and sense of responsibility for undernourished
individuals and groups in other parts of the world. Our aspirations
that such assistance will enable these people to become more produc-
tive, have not been realized as fully as desired.
9. Concessional agricultural trade programs can have desirable
political effects. Despite the protests of some Congressmen, we believe
that food exports to Yugoslavia provided that country with an op-
portunity to pursue a more independent course than would otherwise
have been possible, and that this stance contributed, through time, to
U.S. international political interests. The Egyptian experience argues
a contrary view.
10. An increasing volume of agricultural (and other exports) from
developing countries can increase their level of economic activity. As
these nations increase their sense of economic and political well-being,
the number of individuals with goals and values consistent with our
own are likely to increase, with gradual changes in their international
position. While there is no assurance that they will aline themselves
with the United States, it is likely that they will pursue independent
policies with which the United States can live.
11. Moreover, as these nations strengthen their economies they are
more likely to become expanding markets for our commodities, and to
require smaller amounts of foreign aid.
These interests are both conflicting and overlapping. Programs to
serve these interests are not always well designed to attain their objec-
tives, and differ significantly among countries and regions. We turn
first to United States and the developing nations.
One conflict needs to be given special attention here, particularly
since it has arisen and will arise again in UNOTAD and other con-
ferences. The U.S. interest in maintaining or expanding trade in its
own subtropical agricultural products, in certain other raw materials
and in simple manufactures conflicts with the U.S. interests in the de-
veloping nations' expansion of their exports and improvement in their
economies. Many other developed nations face the same conflict. Pro-
tection against the import of such products, so as to maintain domestic
production and processing has the same effect.
Expanding agricultural exports increase foreign exchange earnings
and thereby reduce the U.S. balance-of-payments gap. The increased
outflow of farm products strengthens the internal U.S. market for such
products, provides opportunities to reallocate agricultural resources,
and to utilize a larger proportion of the productive capacity of U.S.
agriculture. The economic welfare of farm people is enhanced. An ex-
PAGENO="0193"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 185
pansion in agricultural trade, like total trade, increases the inter-
dependence of the trading nations, and, as they exploit comparative
advantage more fully, contributes to higher incomes, greater welfare,
a.nd stronger economies.
For the less developed nations trade expansion is even more vital.
An expansion in agricultural and other raw material exports increases
their foreign exchange earnings, and thereby makes it possible for them
to reduce a balance-of-payments gap or to increase their purchases of
tools for development. An increased outflow of farm products also
benefits the level of economic activity within the economy and leads
to a.n increase in aggregate and in per capita income. Moreover, de-
veloping countries depend far more heavily upon raw material ex-
ports as the "engine of growth," typically 70 to 80 percent of their
exports being so derived compared with 5 to 25 percent for most of
the developed nations. The one-sidedness of their economy can rep-
resent a solid exploitation of comparative advantage, but it is also a
source of uncertainty and inflexibility. A recent UNCTAD document
comments on the lack of diversification as follows:
"Many factors have contributed to this situation. Ecology, topog-
raphy, climate and soil often limit the scope for agricultural diversi-
fication. There are also many economic benefits to be derived in some
cases from specialization. These include comparative cost benefits,
economies of scale and of estate cultivation, greater standardization,
etc. 1-lowever, specialized economies are excessively vulnerable to in-
stability in international commodity markets and to the adverse effects
of policies adopted in competing and in importing countries. They are
liable to be faced with difficult adjustments if demand should contract.
Moreover, the long-term growth of demand in international markets
for most agricultural commodities may be too slow to permit the ade-
quate growth of imports required by rapid economic development." 3°
The United States has economic strength to subsidize exports at the
expense of the developing nations, if it so desires, but also has multiple
alternatives for many of its resources, so that it could, at some cost,
eschew such a rise in exports. Such action could strengthen the export
sectors of relevant developing countries and help them attain a rising
level of income and larger foreign exchange earnings. Such develop-
ments would contribute to two other U.S. objectives, the direct interest
in larger exports of industrial goods, and the longer run, less direct
interest in stronger, more self-reliant economies in the developing
world. The choice is a very difficult one to make in the United States
and in other developed countries, mainly because of the adverse in-
ternal income effects on farmers and manufacturers presently pro-
ducing such products and prepared to protest politically. A choice
must be made, if the United States is to deal effectively with the dis-
cussions between developing and developed countries begun at the
first UNCTAD Conference in Geneva and continuing in the forth-
coming second UNCTAD Conference in India.
Thus, one of the important issues is the competition in available
consumer markets between the developed and developing countries
for those commodities exported by the latter.
A second issue is the reduction of trade barriers, perhaps on a dif-
ferential basis, to ease the entry of agricultural imports from devel-
oping areas. The United States does not have high tariffs against most
3° UNCTAD, "Role and Financing of Diversification Programmes," Trade and Develop-
ment Board, Committee on Commodities, TD/B/C.1/36, Jan. 9, 1967, p. 3.
82-246-67-----13
PAGENO="0194"
186 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
of these products-Western Europe is more open to criticism-but for
a few commodities the United States has a combination of quotas and
tariffs that are significant barriers. Sugar, wool, and dairy products
are noteworthy.
The problem of synthetic competition-rubber, fibers, plastics-has
some similarities, but the technological considerations make this more
a question of adapting to dynamic changes in comparative advantage.
Another area of concern to the developing areas is the discrimina-
tion against processing of raw materials in the producing country.
Here the United States and most other developed countries need to
review the situation after the Kennedy Round, and consider possible
actions. Economic logic in comparative advantage and longrun in-
terests in fostering efficient industrialization indicate that additional
tariff and other concessions are appropriate.
We turn now to trade and policy issues among developed countries.
In volume this trade is far larger. Policy issues recently have been
dominated by relations between the United States and the presently
constituted EEC. In the future this may change to an expanded EEC
and include important questions of relationship with non-EEC free
world countries as well as socialist countries. Whatever the specific
composition of issues at any particular point in time, U.S. interests
will simultaneously lie in increasing the competitive structure of world
agricultural markets while at the same time improving cooperation
among advanced countries in dealing with problems of food aid and
policy vis-a-vis developing countries.
In trading relations vis-a-vis advanced countries, U.S. interests lie
primarily in seeking reduced restrictions in importing countries and
expanded sales of U.S. farm products. Obtaining concessions on trade,
however, will depend on the exthnt to which international negotiations
can be instrumental in reorienting domestic agricultural policies to re-
duce the conflict with trade policies. "As long as price supports at
relatively high levels are used as the principal means of protecting
income, these must be accompanied by tariffs or controls of interna-
tional trade." 31 The obligation for leadership in reducing these kinds
of conflicts necessarily lies with any country seeking reduced trade
barriers. Yet, it is fair to say that our use of trade restrictions to facili-
tate domestic support programs has been relatively comprehensive.
Some of these inconsistencies have recently been reduced, especially
for cotton and grains, by changes in domestic price support legislation,
and the trade expansion act has limited the use of the escape clause.
Nonetheless, many recent specific actions have emphasized our sensi-
tivity to protection and expansion of the American market for domes-
tic producer groups. These include the import limitations on dairy
products from Australia, New Zealand, and Ireland in 1963; agree-
ments on the limitation of beef imports; the continuous use of section
22 restrictions to restrict imports of supported commodities. These
specific actions along with such longer term policy positions as that in
sugar and the fact of a two-price system which provide a differential
in returns to producers from the domestic and international market,
create difficulties in bargaining for reduced trade barriers by other
countries. While all of these conditions cannot be eliminated, a wise
policy would attempt to minimize them and they must be subject to
reciprocal international negotiation.
n OECD, "Agriculture and Economic Growth," Paris 1964.
PAGENO="0195"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 187
Second, restraint in pursuing export programs is also needed. Mar-
ket promotion in developed countries if inappropriately handled can
lead to inconsistencies to serious consequences for competing countries
as well in those countries whose market is at stake. Market promotion
further often leads to forceful representation of commodity interests
in international discussions and often does little to sell more farm
products; rather it contributes to tensions which make international
negotiations difficult.
rfhis is not to say that all efforts at expanding foreign outlets should
be avoided, e.g., those that inform and attempt to discover market re-
quirements. Market expansion based on economic forces should be wel-
come as should expansion based on overall and mutually acceptable
reduction in trade barriers both on industrial and agricultural prod-
ucts. Trade expansion through vigorous pressures for reduction of bar-
riers on specific commodities sometimes contrary to the welfare of an
always smaller country or through special commodity arrangements
are more questionable.
The pursuit of reduced interference with trade among advanced
countries must continue to represent an important part of our interna-
tional policy. Meaningful negotiation, however, normally requires that
each country to the negotiation have something to gain from agree-
ment or to lose if it fails to bargain. Meaningful reciprocity therefore
must be sought or by implication some parties to the bargain must be
willing to forego full reciprocity. Given the conditions in agricultural
production, with wide disparities in production costs among countries
plus our own willingness to place commodities on world markets below
production cost it is not surprising that major agricultural price con-
cessions were not achieved in the Kennedy Round.
Progress in the future will depend on the reciprocal willingness of
both exporters and importers to reduce protection of domestic agricul-
ture and this in turn depends on accelerating the process of change
in countries with an inefficient agriculture and in adjusting the level
of total resources in agriculture to fit the needs of domestic and world
markets. While immediate and sharp reductions in agricultural trade
barriers among advanced countries are probably not feasible meaning-
ful improvement should be possible through time. As suggested re-
cently:
"Considerable gains could be achieved by adopting changes in agri-
culture and food policies that over a period of years will permit ex-
pansion to occur most rapidly in areas with the greatest comparative
advantage. Policies should be implemented in such a way that they
encourage desirable international specialization and should not seek
to maintain traditional commodity relations where this interferes with
shifts in line with comparative advantage. With reduction in artificial
stimuli for all high cost production, wherever it exists, the general
balance of international resource use would be gradually improved.
This allocation must be secured within the framework of total resource
commitment that is in line with potential rates of expansion of do-
mestic and world markets and the potential rates of diffusion of eco-
nomic growth among regions and areas." 32
The second major issue among advanced countries is achieving the
basis for cooperation in meeting the trade and aid needs of developing
32 OECD, "Agriculture and Economic Growth," op. cit.
PAGENO="0196"
188 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
countries. Some progress was made in the grains agreement of the
Kennedy Round. This calls for a joint allocation of food aid among
both importing and exporting countries. The issues, however, are
broader than providing coordinated food aid. Developed countries in
exploring the possibilities of coordinated action to improve the trad-
ing relations and to accelerate growth in developing countries should
explore a number of questions. These include:
1. The degree to which international cooperation is useful in
providing and financing aid, including food aid.
2. The extent to which preferential trading relations and re-
duction in barriers on imports from developing countries is feasi-
ble.
3. The extent to which financial arrangement and positive
jriarketing aids to encourage exports from developing countries
can be instituted.
4. The role that international commodity arrangements could
play and the form they should take to be politically acceptable
and economically useful to developed and developing countries.
International commodity agreements, in particular, have been
viewed as one approach to improvement in the trading position of
less-developed countries. Their adoption, however, has been limited.
Some efforts have been instituted by the International Monetary Fund
to provide compensatory financing of export fluctuations that tend to
equalize earnings from export over time. The problem of the extent
of use of commodity and financial measures and possibilities for inter-
national cooperation in developing programs are important issues in
trade policy toward developed countries.
Other measures to guarantee export earnings have recently been dis-
cussed by the U.N. that need to be considered jointly. Over time most
developed countries have instituted a set of nationalistic policies that
pay little regard to its impact on less-developed countries. Import
restrictions on tropical products with differentials related to degree
of processing have already been noted as a case in point. Trade re-
strictions and subsidies on trade in commodites such as oils and oil-
seeds reduce the earning from competing exports in less-developed
countries. Through this process, international prices are driven to un-
realistically low levels with major consequences for competing third
countries. These market disruptions are essentially discriminatory
against developing countries and cannot be reduced without direct
cooperation of all advanced countries.
But, eliminating discrimination against developing countries is not
the end point of needed policy coordination. The call has recently been
sounded for trade preferences on a general basis for developing coun-
tries. Present international arrangements, including the EEC arrange-
ments with overseas territories and the British preferential system in
particular, provide certain trade preferences. On the whole, however,
these arrangements provide preferences for certain countries over
others in the markets in question and do not deal with the question of
preferential trading relations between developed and developing coun-
tries. This more general question cannot be handled short of major
policy coordination among all advanced countries. In the face of pre-
existing biases toward regionalization among continental European
countries and toward more general most-favored-nation treatment in
the United States, this may represent the No. 1 immediate challenge
in international policy confronting the United States.
PAGENO="0197"
UNITED STATES TRADE WITH LESS DEVELOPED
COUNTRIES*.
BY JOHN PINcus
CONTENTS
Page
I. INTRODUCTION 189
Current trends in under-developed countries-trade interests_ 189
Investment interests 191
Dynamic factors in trade and investment 192
Aggregate growth 193
II. PRESENT SITUATION AND PROSPECTS-COMMODITY TRADE 196
Trade liberalization 198
Commodity agreements 198
Price stability 199
Conclusions 200
III. TRADE IN MANUFACTURES 200
Nondiscriminatory reductions of tariffs and other trade barriers - 203
Preferential systems 206
Some proposals for preferential systems 208
The French plan 208
The LDC plan 208
One-way free trade 209
The effects of preference 210
Commonwealth Preference 210
Balance-of-payments effects 212
Predicting the trade effects of general preferences 213
Conclusions 214
I. INTRODUCTION
CURRENT TRENDS IN THE UNDER-DEVELOPED COUNTRIES-TRADE INTERESTS
The discussion of this paper is taken from a recent study ~ on the
economic relations between rich and poor countries. The rich countries
(Western Europe, United States, Canada, Australia, New Zealand,
and Japan) are often referred to herein as "the North." The poor
countries (Latin America, Africa, and the rest of Asia) are often re-
ferred to in the text as "the South."
We can begin the analysis of North-South trade policies by point-
ing out the advantages derived from international trade for all par-
ticipants. There are two aspects to the gains from trade: those
deriving from specialization according to comparative advantage,.
and those deriving from and contributing to the process of economic
development over time. Today, economists discussing development em-
phasize the latter set. They are not necessarily inconsistent with the
former, and modern versions of neoclassical theory emphasize the view
*Reprinted by permission of McGraw-Hill Book Co., from "Trade, Aid and
Development" by John Pincus, RAND Corporation. Copyright 1967 by Council
on Foreign Relations, Inc.
John Pincus, "Trade, Aid, and Development," New York, McGraw-Hill, 1967.
189
PAGENO="0198"
190 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
that specialization according to comparative advantage will he likely
to promote rapid growth.
The principle of comparative advantage states in effect that to max-
imize world output at any point in time, each country should export
those goods it produces relatively cheaply and import those it pro-
duces relatively dearly. The total world output from a fixed quantity
of resources is thereby increased compared with production without
trade.
The static gains from trade are presumably greater as the differ-
ences between trading partners' resource endowments and production
and demand conditions are greater. It is difficult to measure the actual
value of these gains, however; in the absence of data on prices and
costs, we must resort to gross measures. The combined national prod-
ucts of the Northern countries were about $1,165 billion U.S. dollars
at official exchange rates (1964 estimates). Their total exports in 1964
were about $118 billion, of which one-fifth went to underdeveloped
countries. In other words, exports to underdeveloped countries are
equivalent to only 2 percent of Atlantic Community production.
Therefore, gains from trade with the South are less than vital to
Northern prosperity. For the South, trade with rich countries ac-
counts for at least one-tenth of total output. Small wonder, therefore,
that the future of North-South trade is a perpetual concern of devel-
oping countries, while the North tends to look upon such issues as
somewhat secondary. Table 1 shows the relevant trade and income es-
timates for 1964.
Table 1 probably gives a slightly misleading impression of the
North's trade stake in the South. Although North-North trade is
much larger, the gains per dollar of trade are probably greater in
North-South trade. Gains from trade are presumably greater when
countries differ widely in resource endowments and demand patterns.
TABLE 1-FREE WORLD EXPORTS AND PRODUCT, 1964
A. TOTAL TRADE, 1964a
[Dollars in billionsi
Region
1964 combined
GNP
1964 exports
(fob.)
1964 imports
(c.i.f.)
Exports, as
percentofGNP
Industrial countries
Underdeveloped countries
Total
$1, 165
240
$118
35
$125
35
10
b15
1,405
153
160
11
B. NORTH-SOUTH TRADE, 1964
Exports
Amount
Percent of
1964 GNP
From industrial countries to industrial countries
From industrial countries to underdeveloped countries
From underdeveloped countries to industrial countries
From underdeveloped countries to underdeveloped countries
$85
25
25
7
7
2
10
3
a Includes free world imports from and exports to Communist countries; excludes trade between Communist countries.
b The United Nations has estimated LDC exports as amounting to 18 percent of combined domestic product in 1931.
"The Growth of World Industry 1938-61: International Analyses and Tables," New York, 1965, p. 33. The estimate it
the table may therefore be too low.
Source: United Nations, Monthly Bulletin of Statistics, March 1966.
PAGENO="0199"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 191
This conclusion that the North has a relatively minor interest in
trade with the. South applies a fortiori to some of the dynamic aspects
of gains from trade. The transmission of technology and skills through
trade and investment is predominantly from North to South. rllhe ec-
onomic reorganization and market ex~pansion the. South seeks will
utilize the experience, products, and markets of industrial countries.
In general, the. industrial countries' dynamic gains from trade-those
that result in expanding markets and in lowering costs by increasing
scale or output or introducing new techniques, thereby raising pro-
ductivity-stem primarily from trade with each other. However,
their dynamic gains are probably relatively smaller per unit value of
trade anyway, because the state of the arts varies less among them
than between them and LDC's. New technique (more specifically,
embedding technological progress and productivity growth in the
economy) is probably a central element in the dynamic gains from
trade, although it is evidently linked in practice to cost reductions
stemming from economies of scale.
INVESTMENT INTERESTS
Turning from trade to investment, the relative stakes change some-
what. Northern annual net private investment, including portfolio
investment, in underdeveloped countries aveiagecl about $2.5 billion
during the decade ending in 1964, and showed no particular trend.
In 1964, the value of U.S. private capital invested in the South was
estimate.d at about $13 billion. LDC investment in industrial countries
is small, although much of it is presumably unrecorded and no reliable
figures exist. Of course, Northern and Southern stakes in private for-
eign investment are not adequately measured by the value of sunk
capital. In the long run the dominant issue is the potential returns
on investment, both to private individuals and to societ.y a.s a whole.
It is commonly stated that private investment benefits the host
country by providing capital, transferring technology, increasing the
productivity of labor and thereby allowing increases in domestic sav-
ings and investment, further stimulating growth. No a priori judg-
ment is possible, however, as to whether the rich countries or the
poorer ones have a greater economic stake in protecting existing invest-
ments and promoting new ones. As an extreme example, some poor
countries might gain mOre from confiscating existing Northern invest-
ment~s than from encouraging new ones. It is rather difficult to speak
in quantitative terms of Northern or Southern stakes in liberalizing or
restricting investment, because each country is sui generis.
The issue, moreover, is primarily not economic but political. The
economic loss of new investment arising from restrictions is largely
the host country's because the investing country's capital can go else-
where. For existing investment, restriction generally takes the form
of control over repatriation of capital and profits, and of requirements
for domestic participation. The net effect on capital availability de-
pends on whether discouragement of new investment exceeds gains
resulting from controls.
Obviously, the decision to invest or not is ultimately a question of
profit. From the viewpoint of the foreign investor, his return (includ-
ing discounts for unusual risks arising from investment in LDC's) is
PAGENO="0200"
192 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
the primary criterion. In that light, restriction is simply one aspect.
It affects the degree of risk or the expected profit. Profitable foreign
investment in the South has been largely limited to mining and refining,
although in recent years there has been some investment in manufac-
turing.
In any event, looking at both trade and investment from the static
viewpoint, the industrial countries taken together have a rather
modest interest-although there are significant exceptions, such as
Japan, which does half of its export trade with LDC's and could not
readily shift these exports to markets in the North. The specter of
a North deprived of vital raw materials by a hostile South owes more
to imagination than to analysis. At most, if raw materials exporters
insisted for political motives on denying themselves export earnings-
an unlikely event-there would be an increase in raw material costs.
This in turn would presumably be offset, at least in part, by induced
technological changes in industrial countries.
DYNAMIC FACTORS IN TRADE AND INVESTMENT
Similar conclusions apply to the process of economic growth over
time. Some economic theories of trade and development tend to sup-
port the view that trade is an agent of economic growth. Historically
there is no doubt that it has operated to promote the interests of both
advanced and underdeveloped countries. To the extent that trade now
operates as an agent of growth for the Atlantic countries, however,
the developing countries play a minor role in the process. Only one-
fifth of Northern trade is with LDC's, and the proportion to total
trade has been falling in the post-World War II period. It is the intra-
Northern trade that has grown most rapidly among the market econo-
mies, particularly intra-European trade. Again, as in the case of static
gains, there are exceptions. The remarkably rapid post-war growth
of Japan must reflect in part the increased specialization and econo-
mies of scale made possible by the expansion of its exports to the
South, and by the development of new raw material sources in under-
developed countries.
Although the North's interest is less vital than the South's it is far
from negligible. Furthermore, the process of growth in North and
South alike may intensify the Northern interest. Northern growth will
increase the demand for imported raw materials, including some in
which it is now largely self-sufficient. Southern growth will increase
its demand for Northern products. The South's population, even ex-
cluding China, is more than 1.5 billion, 2J/2 times that of the North,
so that the increase in demand could be substantial. At the same time,
cost conditions in the two areas will change, and each may export
goods it now imports. Each can benefit from trade under situations
where comparative costs change. But this is far ahead, because the
South's demand is now sharply constrained by the interacting effects
of low income levels and foreign exchange restrictions. However, as
the next section points out, taking a long view, we can foresee vast
increases in LDC trade and income by the end of this century. In the
past 150 years the United States has risen from an insignificant role
in world trade to a major one. Qver the generations to come, the
underdeveloped regions may also play an increasingly important
part.
PAGENO="0201"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 193
AGGREGATE GROWTH
It is generally believed that economic growth in the underdeveloped
countries has been slower than that in developed countries in recent
years. If we define growth as a percentage of increase in national
product, this belief is not so-the two areas' incomes grew at an
average compound rate of about 4.5 percent annually from 1950 to
1962 with the LDC rate if anything slightly higher than that of the
Atlantic countries. Growth of per capita income, however, has been
faster in the Atlantic countries, the amount of the spread from year
to year being influenced not only by faster population growth in
LDC's, but also by changes in U.S. income growth, because the United
States accounts for more than half of Atlantic income.
If it were not for rapid population growth in the South, economic
growth rates in the two regions would be a.bout the same (other things
being equal). With annual growth in per capita incomes of 3 percent
then entirely feasible, incomes per head would double every 23 years.
It is largely on the basis of this concern for small differences in
growth rates and on the alleged limitations of growth caused by lack
of foreign exchange that underdeveloped countries in economic ra-
tionality can justify their preoccupation with trade and aid conces-
sions from the North. It is possible to argue one or both of two cases
to support the need for faster export growth as a condition of faster
output growth: (1) Foreign exchange limitations create a barrier to
output growth; (2) domestic savings or domestic markets for goods
cannot be increased readily, so that increased imports are the only way
to increase investment; or increased exports the only way to find
markets (because domestic demand is small, or domestic productive
factors are immobile as among industries). Both arguments are made
by underdeveloped countries.
Industrial countries, on the other hand, generally do not argue so
strongly for trade expansion on these grounds. Their case for more
trade is to a greater degree on the comparative cost arguments and,
in the case of smaller countries, the desire to benefit from economies
of scale.
In any event, there is clearly no unique relation between trade and
economic development. The percentage growth of Atlantic Commu-
nity exports was nearly twice as great as its income growth during
the past decade; underdeveloped countries' exports rose a little slower
than income. Yet income in the two areas grew at nearly the same
rate. Table 2 compares industrial and underdeveloped countries' trade
growth from 1950 through 1965.
These data underline the error inherent in equating income growth
and trade growth uniquely for all countries. The industrial countries'
prosperity has been marked by rapid increases in trade, probably re-
flecting: (1) Dismantling of the trade restrictions created during the
depression of the 1930's, and maintained until after World War II-
in effect a sort of catching up to normal trade patterns after a long
period of restriction; (2) increasing specialization in production of
manufactures, made possible by increases in demand, and encouraged
by preferences for widely advertised products; (3) the international-
ization of tastes made possible by modern communications, and en-
couraged by the growth of international corporations, which are also
PAGENO="0202"
194 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
often their own customers in world trade; (4) the marked and con-
tinning decline in transportation costs in this century.
TABLE 2.-GROWTH AND SHARES OF EXPORTS, 1950-65
Average export growth
rates (percent per
year)
Shares of total exporto
(percent)
1950-60 1960-65
1950 1960 1965
Industrial countries
Underdeveloped countries
8.6 8.4
3.6 5.8
66 76 78
34 24 22
Excludes trade between Communist countries; includes tree world exports to Communist countriex.
Source: UNCTAD, Handbook of International Trade Statistics, Doc. E/Conf. 46/12/add. 1, Feb. 28, 1964; United Notions,
Monthly Bulletin of Statistics, May 1966.
Growth of the underdeveloped countries has taken place under a
variety of trade conditions. They have benefited, either as exporters
or importers, from the factors listed above, but the results for trade
have been generally modest. The situation varies greatly among
countries. The basic points accounting for the difference seem to be:
(1) the buoyancy of world demand for manufactures has allowed all
Northern countries to share, albeit unevenly, in the rapid growth of
trade; (2) often lacking that opportunity, some Southern countries,
usually the larger ones, were able to expand rapidly by maintaining
the traditional but slow-growing exports, substituting domestic in-
dustrial production for imports, and using the foreign exchange sax -
ings for importing capital goods; while others grew either by outpac-
ing the average LDO export performance or else failed to grow. The
data of table 2 offer some evidence of changes in this pattern since 1960.
Southern exports have increased faster than in the preceding decade,
and their exports of manufactured products have continued to rise
at a faster rate than all exports combined. It is still too early to say
whether this trend marks a shift in the' forces that propel Southern
economic growth, or portends a rise in aggregate growth rates. It
could be largely the reflection of short-run fluctuations in commodity
price levels.
The TJNCTAD resolutions and the report of its Secretary-General
stressed inadequate command over imports as the major factor in
slow growth. While there is evidence to support this claim, an
examination of all the facts supports a somewhat more complex
interpretation.
First, sustained economic growth is almost always associated with
at least some growth of imports, often financed in part by foreign
capital. There have been a few exceptions in modern times, neces-
sarily associated with major efforts at import substitution. But to
cite the exceptions, such as Brazil, the Soviet Union, and possibly
Australia in recent years, only stresses the special conditions re-
quired-a large domestic market and a varied natural resource base.
Second, the smaller the country, the greater the need for trade
growth as a condition of income growth. Small countries (less than
10 million population) that grow fast always have a rapid growth
of imports.
In most cases, import growth is somewhat faster than income
growth for small countries. The principal exceptions are Venezuela,
PAGENO="0203"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 195
where changes in oil company imports of capital equipment have been
an important source of variation; and Israel, faced with serious trade
deficits and aided by capital inflows and a rapidly growing home
market for import-substituting industry and agriculture.
Third, rapid import growth is not a necessary condition for rapid
income growth, where the market is large enough to allow domestic
industrialization, or substitution of domestic for imported commodi-
ties. Thus, between 1950-52 and 1961-64, Mexico's income grew at
the annual rate of 5.6 percent, while imports increased at the rate of
4.7 percent. For the Philippines the comparable figures are 5.4 per-
cent and 3.8 percent. In Brazil and Burma, imports actually declined
over the period.
In sum, rapid peacetime growth of imports has been a sufficient
condition for the growth of income in the South, but not a necessary
one. The reasons for the association are clear. Steady growth of
imports is financed either by an equivalent export growth or a capital
transfer. In the Tatter case, the recipient benefits from increased in-
vestment without the immediate need for corresponding savings. The
continuation of such a transfer normally means that private or public
investors in the North are conficlei~t of the capital importer's economic
potential.2 If the import increase is largely export financed, as is the
case for most of the fast-growing small countries, then it implies that
the country is able to compete effectively in world markets, and is
presumably in a favorable growth situation.
If. on the other hand, a developing country finds itself unable or
unwilling to finance steady import increases by exports or borrowing,
the record shows that rapid growth may still be possible if the domes-
tic market is large enough and the resources and organization are
present to permit large-scale import substituting investment. In such
cases, the close relationship between trade and growth recently oh-
served in the North no longer holds, and import substitution becomes
the leading sector in growth.
TABLE 2A.-GNP GROWTH AND TRADE GROWTH, FAST-GROWING LDC'S, 1950-52 TO 1961-64
(Annual increases; countries listed in decreasing order of GNP growth)
Country
GNP growth
rate (percent)
Trade growth a (percent)
Imports
Esports
Populations under 10 million:
Israel
Jordan
Iraq
Trinidad
Jamaica
Venezuela
Puerto Rico
Nicaragua
Ghana
Populations over 20 million:
Mexico
Brazil
Thailand
Philippines
Burma
Turkey
10.0
b 9.8
8.4
b 7.6
7.0
6.7
5.6
5.3
5.3
5.6
5.6
5.4
5.4
5.2
4.9
6.0
10.5
9.7
9.2
9.4
1.4
9.1
8.1
7.6
4.7
1.6
12.6
3.8
-1.1
2.9
17.0
13.1
11.7
9.6
12.3
4.2
10.0
7.2
3.0
3.7
-2.1
4.9
3.7
3.5
~6
a Corrected for terms of trade changes, 1962 equal 100.
b 1955-57 to 1961-64.
Source: Computed from U.N. data.
2 Of course, the motive for the transfer may be political. In extreme cases (Vietnam,
Korea), long-term potential is virtually irrelevant.
PAGENO="0204"
196 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
Some economic writing insists that the trade development relation-
ship is essential to growth. In fact, the world allows a variety of sources
of growth; a high and fast growing level of trade is perhaps indis-
pensable only for small nations or those with a particularly uneven
distribution of resources. The combined populations of 70 developing
nations with less than 10 million inhabitants each do not equal half
the population of India, but they exercise together a disproportionate
political weight in international forums. This fact has shaped the
nature of the UNCTAD recommendations, particularly its insistence
on the international element in growth.
II. PRESENT SITUATION AND PROSPECTS-COMMODITY TRADE
About 85 percent of LDC exports are primary commodities-food,
tropical beverages, agricultural raw materials, fuels, and mineral ores,
some domestically refined for further processing after export. Table
3 shows the trends, by category, in recent years.
No matter what the long-range hopes for LDC manufactured ex-
ports may be, most underdeveloped countries today must rely primarily
on commodity trade. Prospects for trade in commodities vary greatly,
both by product and by country.
World demand for LDC commodities in the aggregate rose slowly
during the decade 1952-62. The principal factors were probably slow
growth of demand for food in rich countries; substitution of synthetics
for natural raw materials (rubber, plastics, synthetic fibers, deter-
gents); a tendency for industrial buyers to use smaller amounts of
raw materials per unit of final output; agricultural protectionism in
the Atlantic Community; low elasticity of demand for commodities
in the aggregate with respect to price changes (although the actual
market situation product by product is complex). During the 1950's,
these tendencies were reinforced by the decline in prices, following the
speculative effects of the Korean war.
TABLE 3.-LDC EXPORTS BY CATEGORY, 1956-64
[In billions of dollars]
Year
Food and
beverages
Agricultural
raw materials
and mineral
ores (not
refined)
Petroleum and
other fuels
Manufactures
(including
refined ores) *
Total
1956
1958
1960
1962
1963
1964
8. 0
8. 2
8. 1
8. 5
9.4
10.3
7. 0
6. 2
7. 6
7. 3
7.6
7.7
6. 5
7. 4
7. 7
8. 9
9.6
10.8
3. 3
2. 8
3. 8
4. 2
4.8
5.5
24. 8
24. 6
27. 4
28. 9
31.5
34.4
* In recent years, refined ores have accounted for $1,000,000,000 to $11,700,000,000 of the LDC exports under this
category. The estimated figures for 1960 through 1964 are, in billions of dollars: 1960, $1.4; 1961, $1.4; 1962, $1.4;
1963, $1.5; 1964, $1.7. (Cf. United Nations, Monthly Bulletin of Statistics, May 1966.) Rows may not add to totals shown
because of rounding.
Source: United Nations, Monthly Bulletin of Statistics, March 1962 and March 1966.
There were several factors at work tending to maintain and increase
LDC export supplies despite the slow growth of demand. The princi-
pal ones were immobility of resources in LDC's, leading to continued
production of traditional export crops even when demand was un-
PAGENO="0205"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 197
favorable; high prices during the Korean ~risis bringing expansion of
supply for many products, notably minerals and tree crops; new coun-
tries, seeking additional foreign exchange sources, turning to expanded
commodity production as the easiest way to compete in world markets.
In the past 15 years, regions that previously exported little coffee, tea,
or petroleum have entered the world market as significant producers.
The net effect of LDC export supply growth outpacing demand
growth for their products was a general reduction in commodity ex-
port prices during the period. The UN index of LDC export prices
declined from 113 in the 1951 boom to 100 in 1952, and drifted down to
84 in 1962. Subsequently, agricultural commodity prices rose and LDC
export unit values were about 5 percent above 1962 levels at the end
of 1964. Atlantic Community export prices meanwhile remained rela-
tively stable, so that terms of trade (export price index divided by im-
port price index) of LDC's declined by about 8 percent over the 1952/
53-1962 decade, and by about 5 percent for the period 1952/53-1964.
Although the quantity of LDC exports rose more slowly than the
Atlantic Community's, there was a substantial increase in total LDC
export quantity and value during the decade following the conflict.
LDC commodity export values rose from about $18 billion equivalent
in 1952 to about $28 billion in 1964.' If these figures are corrected for
terms-of-trade declines during the interval, purchasing power of LDC
commodity exports apparently rose by about $7 billion equivalent dur-
ing the 13-year period, or at the compound rate of 23/4 percent annually.
This is much slower than the real growth rate of Atlantic Community
exports or of LDC manufactured exports, but it is by no means
negligible, compared with LDC export growth over the past 50 years.
A continuation of this trend would result in a doubling of 1952 com-
modity export value by 1977.
In discussing the commodity trade situation of some 70 countries,
there is a great deal of variation, perhaps too much to allow any all-
inclusive statement. However, a few points seem clear:
1. Many Latin American and Asian countries will be able to rely
less and less on commodity trade for financing import growth.
2. The Middle East and Africa are better off, thanks largely to
petroleum in the former region and favorable supply conditions for
a number of products in the latter.
3. Two conditions will tend to favor the growth of any country's
commodity export trade:
Low-cost productive potential, even if the particular commod-
ity faces sluggish world demand (as in the postwar expansion
of African tea and sisal exports).
Specialization in products with good demand prospects (as
in Peruvian fishmeal trade, African copper exports, Middle East
oil, or Malayan tin).
4. For most countries, this last condition does not apply. Those
that are semi-industrial (India, Brazil, Argentina, Mexico, Taiwan)
can hope to shift increasingly from commodities to manufactured ex-
ports, although this is no easy task. Those whose industry is not yet
established have even fewer trade alternatives. For them, unless
tourism or other service industries can be developed, the foreign ex-
`UNCTAD, "Handbook of International Trade Statistics" (E/Conf. 46/12 Add. 1), Feb.
28, 1964; "Monthly Bulletin of Statistics," April 1965.
PAGENO="0206"
198 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
change limitation is likely to loom as a major obstacle to desired rates
of growth.
lnternationai action in the sphere of commodity policy has been con-
~cerned with three kinds of measures: (1) trade. liberalization; (2)
transfer of income from commodity importers to exporters; (3) sta-
bilization of commodity prices and export earnings.
TRADE LIBERALIZATION
In theory improved market access is the most efficient way to in-
crease LDC export earnings, because it increases the flow of trade
and raises the earnings of exporters, with no corresponding income
transfer from rich to poor countries. A liberal trade policy benefits
both exporting and importing countries by raising the real incomes
of both, but it may create adjustment problems for high-cost pro-
ducers or revenue problems for governments who benefit from cus-
toms duties and fiscal changes. Because agriculture in the North is
a relatively declining industry, which resists such adjustments, there
is little likelihood that barriers to imports of competing crops (South-
ern commodities that con~pete with domestic ~rocIuction in the North)
will be reduced. Some progress might be made, with relatively limited
effects on trade, for such noncompeting products as tea, coffee, cocoa,
and tropical hardwoods.4 rfliils although LDC exports to the North
might well increase by anywhere from $3 to $5 billion annually as a
result of free trade in commodities, the immediate prospects for change
are slim in the short run. For the time, agricultural protectionism
seems to be on the increase.
COMMODITY AGREEMENTS
If the prospects are modest for increasing world income through
freer trade in commodities, they are perhaps slightly greater for
transferring income from rich to poor countries by commodity price
fixing. The persistent international interest in "stabilization" of com-
modity prices is largely an effort to make importers pay more than
they would in a free market. Discussion of such agreements is usually
confined to noncompeting exports (coffee, tea, cocoa, sugar, bananas,
spices, tin) and price-fixing agreements for these products could be
used to transfer an average of perhaps $1 billion annually from North
to South over the decade 1965-75. If extended to competing products,
as proposed by the French Government, price fixing could result in a
far larger transfer. For example, if price fixing could increase the
south's $17-$18 billion annual revenue from commodity exports to
the North by 20 percent. tiw total annual transfer would he of the or-
der of $3.5 billion initially. However, a generalized price-fixing policy
not only invites substitution of synthetics, but also encourages im-
port substituting domestic production in the North. The common agri-
cultural policy of the EEC is aimed in part at this latter goal. There-
fore, the longrun effects of price fixing for competing products may
be harmful to LDC's, unless import quantities are also guaranteed.
Furthermore, there is no good reason for importers of competing
In fact, the North, through the GATT, has suspended its duties on tea and tropical
hardwoods. This modest accomplishment seems to have been the major result of the GATT
action program in its first 3 years.
PAGENO="0207"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 199
products to accept the principle of such transfers to other rich coun-
tries unless it is simply incidental to a policy of reaching domestic
self-sufficiency, a la EEC.
The commodity approach to capital transfers suffers from many
disadvantages in terms of administrative difficulties, economic ineffi-
ciency, promotion of substitute production, and encouragement of
over-production. Its advantages are (1) it disguises the income trans-
fer, thus apparently easing the recipient's conscience and relieving the
donor of the burden of aid administration, a seemingly inescapable
adjunct of official aid transfers; (2) it seems, within limits, to be more
acceptable to importing countries than free trade in commodities, per-
haps because the system is analogous to domestic commodity support
programs. For these reasons, it seems likely that international discus-
sion of policies for tropical exports will continue to revolve around
price-fixing schemes. However, the increasing interest in supplemen-
tary finance (payments to underdeveloped countries whose export
earnings over a period of time fail to meet reasonable expectations,
because of circumstances beyond their own control-such as a long-
term decline in world commodity prices, for example), arising from
the United Nations experts' report and the UNCTAD resolution on
the subject, may presage a gradual turning away from a single com-
modity approach.
PRICE STABILITY
The issue of price and earnings stabilization has become thoroughly
confused with that of income transfer. Price stability and earnings
stability are not the same for the individual exporter even if aggregate
demand remains constant. If Colombian coffee output rises or falls
20 percent, constant world prices destabilize earnings. Stable earn-
ings are sometimes asserted to be the goal, but it is not worth much
to either importer or exporter simply to reduce short-term fluctuations
around a trend by borrowing now and paying back later. The South
wants to have greater price certainty but is not willing to reduce its
freedom of action substantially in exchange for those benefits. It
seeks much more strenuously to avoid low prices for products in in-
elastic demand, but that is not a question of stability.
If the objective were price stability, it would be possible to do some-
thing toward this goal by better price forecasting, use of buffer stocks,
export controls, or price compensation schemes. The case for price sta-
bility is stronger than that for earnings stability because the prices of
many commodities fluctuate so widely that they offer a poor set of sig-
nals for investment planning. They may also lead buyers to seek sub-
stitutes with more stable price levels. Providing that the system chosen
to stabilize prices is a reasonably good forecaster of the market, it
should help promote more rational investment. The extent to which
this is desirable-and therefore also the price worth paying for it-
depends on relevant opportunity costs. The amount of these costs is
not an appropriate subject for aggregative analysis; and the detailed
research that could offer some guidelines remains, as yet, largely pro-
spective. The inference from existing work is that price stability isn't
worth much as a guide to investment in terms of effects on GNP
growth. However, we are still far from a definitive judgment on this
subject.
PAGENO="0208"
200 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
CONCLUSIONS
The dominant conclusion that emerges from investigating all these
aspects of international commodity trends and policies is that the
South as a. whole must look primarily to Northern prosperity as a
source of export growth, and not to the UNCTAD policies. Should the
effects of these policies be substantial, they are unlikely to be adopted;
measures that are likely to be adopted are also likely to be unimportant
as sources of increased capital or trade. Policies to increase or stabilize
commodity earnings cannot proceed much faster than Northern will-
ingness to act on the broader problem of LDC growth. This forecast
offers scant encouragement to those who seek to promote Southern pros-
perity. But the issue here is prediction, not preference; and I find only
faint grounds for Southern ~ptimism about the course of international
commodity policy in the decade ahead.
III. TRADE IN MANUFACTURES
The predominant economic element in the South's desire to indus-
trialize as a means of becoming prosperous stems from differences in
the income elasticities of demand for manufactures and commodities.
World output of manufactures grew at the rate of 4.2 percent annually
from 1937 to 1957 and at 8 percent annually from 1958 to 19(34. Output
of commodities, including petroleum, grew less than half as fast. The
world economy has changed, therefore, and the South seeks to change
with it. Domestic industrialization normally affects world trade in two
ways: It increases the demand for manufactured imports in the indus-
trializing countries and it leads eventually to the development of
manufactured exports by countries that formerly exported only com-
modities.5
At TJNCTAD, the South produced a formula and a rationale for
increased trade and aid, in which industrialization was perhaps the
most important element. The formula consisted of six principal ele-
ments: (1) higher prices for commodities; (2) greater trade access in
Northern markets; (3) payments by the North to developing countries
whose export earnings are persistently below some reference level;
(4) preferential treatment in Northern markets for southern manufac-
tured products; (5) creation of preferential regional trading systems
in the South; (6) creation of a permanent UNCTAD as the forum for
LDC trade and aid demands. This chapter deals primarily with trade
access and trade preferences for manufactured products.
Both the Secretary-General's report, Towards a New Trade Policy
for Development, and the Final Act of TJNCTAD stressed that in-
dustralization is the key to economic development and that increases
in manufactured exports could act as the catalyst promoting that in-
dustrialization. In the words of the Final Act:
The Conference recognizes the urgent need for the diversification and expan-
sion of the export trade of developing in manufactures and semimanufactures as
a means of accelerating their economic development and raising their standards
of living. It considers that individual and joint action by developed and develop-
ing countries is necessary to enable the latter to obtain increased participation,
5 A. Maizels, "Industrial Growth and World Trade," Cambridge University Press, 1963,
ch. 1.
PAGENO="0209"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 201
commensurate with the needs of their development, in the growth of interna-
tional trade in manufactured and semimanufactured products.6
This view that industry is the key is commonly expressed by LDC
spokesmen. The novelty in the UNCTAD approach lies in the asser-
tion that industrial development can be fostered by export of manu-
factures, before a broad industrial base exists. Normally, the export of
manufactured products on a large scale follows the long-term build-
up of domestic industry.7
The South is making rapid strides in industrial development. From
1950 to 1962, its manufacturing output increased by nearly 8 percent
a year; at the end of the period, volume of industrial production was
120 percent greater than in 1950. During the same period Northern
industrial output grew by 80 percent. The powerful desire to in-
dustrialize quickly stems both from the close relation between indus-
trialization and economic development cited above and from the
foreign exchange problem that dominated discussions at UNCTAD.
During the period 1955-63, value of world exports of manufactures
increased at the rate of 8.1 percent annually, compared with a rate of
3.1 percent for commodities. Countries seeking rapid increases in ex-
port earnings are therefore naturally enticed by the prospects of trade
in manufactured goods. Furthermore, Southern trade in manufactured
products (excluding processed foods and refined metals), although
still very small, grew at the rapid rate of 7.4 percent annually for the
8-year period. The contrast with the relative stagnation in commodity
trade is not lost in the South.
Table 4 gives a regional summary of LDC exports of manufactured
products for the years 1955, 1959, and 1963-64. Asia is by far the most
important exporter, accounting for half of the total, and is also in-
creasing its manufactured exports faster than other areas, thanks
largely to the Hong Kong trade.
TABLE 4.-GROWTH OF WORLD EXPORTS OF MANUFACTURED GOODS, a BY REGION, 1955-64
[Dollar amounts in billionsj
Region
1955
1959
1963
1964
Percent
increase,
1955-64
World
Industrial countries
Eastern Europe
LDC's
Latin America
Middle East
Africa .
Asia
45.5
37.8
4.4
3. 0
0. 7
0.1
0. 8
1.3
61.1
49.9
7.2
3. 2
0.7
0.2
0.9
1.5
86.3
70.2
10.3
4. 8
1. 0
1 8
-
2.4
98.7
80. 8
11.5
5. 5
1. 1
.
2.7
117
114
161
83
57
108
a Includes refined metals.
Source: UNCTAD, Handbook of International Trade Statistics, Doc. E/Conf. 46/12/Add. 1, February 28, 1964; United
Nations, Monthly Bulletin of Statistics, various years.
Several points emerge from the study of the manufactured exports
of LDC's.
6 Final Act, par. 62, reprInted UNCTAD, Proceedings, vol. 1, p. 13. There was also a
special principle favoring trade preference for the South in the draft Final Act, but it was
not voted on.
The exceptions are of two kinds: (a) Materials-oriented industries, of which minerals
refining (Chile, Mexico), pressing vegetable oils (Nigeria, Senegal), and refining sugar
(Taiwan) or petroleum (Iran) are typical ; and (b) Industries that benefit from low-cost
labor, notably textiles and certain other light manufactures (Hong Kong, India, Mexico).
82-246-67----14
PAGENO="0210"
202 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
1. LDC exports of manufactures are small compared with both
total LDC exports (about 10 percent) and with world exports of
manufactures (about 4 percent). On the other hand, the South buys
nearly one-fourth of the manufactured products entering world trade.
2. This Southern export t.rade is very specialized. The handful of
developing countries that export manufactures in quantity have so
far concentrated either on light manufactures with a high labor
content (carpets, textiles, footwear, clothing) or on processing local
raw materials, with a rather small value added by manufacture
(metals, plywood, jute products). The degree of this concentration is
great by country, region, and product: nearly half of LDC mann-
±actured exports come from two countries; one-third of LDC manu-
factured exports are textiles; two-thirds of all LDC manufactured
exports are from Asia.
3. The export concentration is matched by import concentration.
The United States and the United Kingdom account for nearly half
of all Northern imports of manufactured products; both countries
take more than 10 percent of their manufactured imports (including
metals) from the South.
4. The rapid growth of world trade in manufactured products
shows no signs of slowing down; this tends to reinforce the preference
of the foreign exchange-starved South for industrialization as the
high road to development.
This sounds obvious and innocuous enough. But on consideration,
it turns out to imply some intractable problems. The fact that the
South is a large importer and a small exporter of manufactured
products means that it has a comparative disadvantage, or that money
costs do not reflects real costs (as, for example, where industrial wages
are maintained at higher levels than required to call forth a given
labor supply).
Almost all underdeveloped countries will have to change their
economic structures and, often, their economic policies before they
can export these products. The North does tend to erect high tariff
barriers against labor-intensive manufactures as demonstrated below.
The effect is to discriminate somewhat against LDC's. In terms of to-
day's realities, that discrimination is confined to the semiindustrial
countries; and elsewhere, to the rather limited prospects for materials
processing and refining.
Therefore, the UNCTAD contention that preferential access (and
to a lesser extent, nonpreferential reduction of Northern trade bar-
riers) will be the catalyst for industrial development implies one or
more of the following beliefs: (1) Northern protection is so high that
tariff preferences will allow today's inefficient industry to compete;
(2) access to the vast Northern market will encourage new domestic
and foreign investment on a scale that will permit preference-aided
Southern industries to reduce costs through economies of production
by large scale firms; (3) preferences will encourage those more widely
diffused economies, arising from the growth of industries in general,
that ultimately transform economic and social structures; (4) the
preferential system will benefit only the semiindustrial countries di-
rectly, but the repercussions will ultimately influence the most back-
ward countries, by increasing world demand for their commodities, by
concentrating the flow of foreign aid toward them, or by a gradual
PAGENO="0211"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 203
shift of labor-intensive industries toward the countries that are today
least developed.
Each of these pointh can also be used to justify the demand for non-
prefereiltial reduction of Northern trade, barriers, although the acivan-
ages to the South would be diluted. Let us start our discussion of
policy choices by looking at these issues in terms of reductions of trade
barriers and going from there to see how preferential systems might
alter the results.
NONDISCRIMINATORY REDUCTIONS OF TARIFFS AND
OTHER TRADE BARRIERS
Since the end of World War II, reduction of barriers to trade-
tariffs, quantitative restrictions, exchange controls-has been a signifi-
cant causal factor in the rapid growth of Northern trade. As yet, it
has not shown the same catalytic effects on the South, despite the fact
that under the GATT procedures the benefits of reductions have gen-
erally been available to all nations. The major reason is that the South
exports commodities, raw or processed, for which effective trade lib-
eralization has been much more modest. Another reason, of less imme-
diate importance, is that the North has often failed to reduce. its tariff
on the labor-intensive manufactures for which the South presumably
has a longrun comparative advantage.
In the domain of processed products and manufactured goods,
Southern exports have grown more rapidly-at the rate of 5 percent
annually from 1953 to 1963, and at nearly twice that rate in recent
years (1958-64). It is not clear how much of this recent advance is
attributable to cost reduction or to increases in demand induced by
income growth and by tariff reduction abroad and how much to im-
proved statistics; all statistics about underdeveloped countries are
legitimate objects of suspicion. If Prebisch is correct in asserting that
easy lines of import-substitution have been exhausted in many LDC's,
then increases in export supply of these products may be a dominant
reason. The argument for dominance of supply factors is reinforced by
the fact that Northern incomes have not risen faster since 1958 than
they did before, nor have tariff reductions proceeded faster.
The GATT negotiations for general tariff reductions that began in
1963 under the title of the Kennedy Round were aimed partly at coun-
teracting the discrimination against outside suppliers created by the
two European trade blocs, particularly EEC.
However, some Northern governments also claimed that the Ken-
nedy Round, if it achieved its goal of a 50-percent reduction in North-
ern tariffs without requiring reciprocity from the South, would also
greatly benefit Southern exports. Thus, in the words of the LT.S. dele-
gate to TJNCTAD:
The industrial countries have done much in recent years to reduce these
barriers. More can be achieved by deep, across-the-board tariff cuts in the "Ken-
nedy Round"-and we are prepared to have these benefits accorded to the de-
veloping countries without asking reciprocity. Such tariff cuts can be of immedi-
ate help to the developing countries. But even more important they can provide
an environment that will make it possible for them to build productive export
industries. It is at this point that UNCTAD and the GATT Conference, which is
to follow, so strongly complement each other.8
9 UNCTAD, Proceedings, vol. II, p. 396. Statement of George Ball, U.S. delegate.
PAGENO="0212"
204 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
Such viewpoints as this find their rationale in the case for free trade.
The merits of free trade as a vent for surplus, source of new methods,
and incentive to economic efficiency have been Opposed by the protec-
tionist rejoinder, based on infant industry and infant economy argu-
ments, as well as on skepticism about the North's interest in actually
allowing "low wage" manufactures to enter its markets. What are
the facts? Will nondiscriminatory removal of trade restrictions have
a great effect, a small one, or none at all on the growth of Southern
trade and income?
First, what would be the result of northern adoption of "free trade"
removal of all restrictions on trade in manufactured products? There
are two kinds of short-run effects to consider: (1) substitution ef-
fects resulting Tfrom replacement of domestic products by imports, and
(2) income effects resulting from the growth of world income as a
consequence of free trade. The income effects, it can be confidently
predicted, would be negligible.
The substitution effects would be far greater. It is impossible to
estimate anything more than orders of magnitude, because we know
so little about cost levels or about price elasticities of demand and
supply. Johnson has made a valiant effort to estimate the effects, and
emerged with a minimum figure of a 40-percent increase in LDC
manufactured exports, resulting from abolition of Northern duties
on manufactures.9 In 1963, this would have amounted to $800 million
if only manufactured articles are included, or to about $1.3 billion if
other processed products are included.
Johnson's estimate of a 40-percent increase is, as he recognizes, very
conservative. It assumes that imports from LDC's would increase at
the same rate as imports from the world. But both nominal and effec-
tive protection of manufactured products that LDC's are likely to
export is greater than that on manufactured goods in general.
It has been long recognized that effective rates of protection are
often higher than the nominal tariff rates imply. If copper ore, for
example, bears no import duty, and refined copper is dutiable at 10
percent, then the effective protection is much higher than the duty
implies. If ore accounts for 75 percent of the costs of refined copper
production, then a domestic manufacturer of refined copper who
purchases domestic or imported ore benefits from a 10-percent duty
on the full value of output, not just on the 25 percent of its total value
that the manufacturing cost represents. Thus, the height of the tariff
on value added is not 10 percent, but 40 percent (10 percent tariff on
total value, divided by 25 percent value added by manufacture). This
means that the copper exporting nations seeking to build up a refining
industry for export effectively faces a 40 percent tariff barrier in the
importing country. The difference between nominal and effective tariff
rates results from the fact that some goods are imported, not for im-
mediate consumption, but as inputs into production. Normally, calcu-
lations of effective tariffs show that nominal tariff rates understate
the real degree of protection, because tariffs on raw materials are
usually lower than those on finished products.
Industrial countries' effective protection for all goods combined is
roughly double the nominal rate for all products combined. It is gen-
° Harry Johnson, "Economic Policies Toward Less-Developed Countries" Washington
D.C., The Brookings Institution, 1966, ch. 3.
PAGENO="0213"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF TJ.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 205
erally highest on consumer goods, and is significantly higher in J apan
and the United Kingdom than elsewhere in the North.
Effective protection is not only greater than nominal; it is also par-
ticularly high on manufactured products of interest to developing
countries.
The effects of free trade are not only static, as discussed above, but
also dynamic, leading to changes in economic growth and structures.
The dynamic consequences of free trade might include changes in
the location of investment leading to development of new skills and
of product lines that, with the assurance of export markets, can oper-
ate at low unit cost; and the association of this cost-reducing pattern
with growth of supply and demand in the pattern of increasing returns.
These consequences of free access to Northern markets are more im-
portant than static effects, particularly if reciprocal tariff concessions
are not required from the South.
It is impossible to estimate the extent of these dynamic effects, ex-
cept by historical examples; these are always open to the objection
that they reflect special circumstances. In recent years Puerto Rico
and Hong Kong, by selling manufactures largely into zero-tariff or
low-tariff areas, have experienced a vast growth of industrial output
which has fed upon itself, bringing rapid improvement in living
standards, providing capital and skills for new investments, and im-
proving the relative cost position of the economy. In essence these cases
seem to validate the classical economists' case for free trade as an agent
of growth.
But both territories benefited from special circumstances: preferen-
tial access to U.S. markets and tax advantages for foreign investors
in the case of Puerto Rico; and Commonwealth preference, plentiful
local capital, and a huge, low-cost, adaptable labor supply in Hong
Kong. The dynamic gains from free trade are much less striking in
other Southern countries that have benefited from preference-notably
France's former colonies and British Commonwealth members. In the
French case, industrial exports, except for metals, are nil. In the
British Commonwealth, the textile exports of India, Pakistan, and
Honk Kong have been the principal beneficiaries of preferences for
manufactures. As a general proposition, each case is sui generis, so
the conclusions must remain agnostic. Some beneficiaries of Common-
wealth preference seem to have grown no faster than the South as
a whole. Trade liberalization seems to be a necessary condition of in-
dustrialization only for small nations and is never a sufficient condi-
tion of itself.
The GATT aim of reducing tariffs on manufactured goods without
requiring reciprocity from the South, nevertheless, remains a goal
worth striving for, by the criterion of Southern self-interest. Any such
reductions are overwhelmingly likely to benefit the South rather than
hurt it; the only practical qualification arises from the operation of
preferential systems, as discussed below. If tariffs are reduced on
labor-intensive manufactures, LDC exports of such products are likely
to rise dramatically.
But the race is generally to the swift, at least in the short run; and
liberalization, to the extent that it does materialize, will obviously
most favor countries that are initially pr~jared to export. This means
above all the North; and next, Hong Kong, India, Israel, Mexico,
PAGENO="0214"
206 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
Philippines, Pakistan, Taiwan, Argentina, and Brazil, perhaps rough-
ly in the order of their current exports. For most of the rest of the
South, there is little or no short-run capacity to supply the world
market for manufactured products. The advantages, for their trade
and industrial development, of a nondiscriminatory system of one-way
tariff cuts for manufacturers are long run, except where tariff reduc-
tions facilitate simple raw material processing.
PREFERENTIAL SYSTEMS
The South, in the name of economic justice, seeks preferential treat-
ment, not free trade. The call for preferences is the clarion of
TJNCTAD's own Great Society and must be understood, as any such
rallying cry, less for its content than for the aspirations it embodies.
Prebisch's economic theories and policy proposals are the rational-
izations for a profound sense of injustice. Therefore, the economics
of preferences are only a minor aspect. Nonetheless, we will begin
our discussion of the subject with a review of the economic issues.
There are two kinds of preferential systems for manufactured prod-
ucts in effect today: (1) customs unions and free trade areas, which, in
principle, offer duty-free entry to members only on all products
(EEC, EFTA) and (2) preferences for all or some products, offered
by rich countries to poor ones on a reciprocal or nonreciprocal basis
(EEC preferences to associated overseas states, TJ.S. free trade with
Puerto Rico and preferences to the Philippines; Commonwealth pref-
erence offered by the United Kingdom). The two are similar in many
respects. In this study, I will deal only with the second, particularly
with its world wide application.
A preference system in its simplest form allows free entry to the
exports of the preference-receiving countries in the markets of pref-
erence-granting countries, while the exports of countries not receiving
preferences continue to be dutiable. The principle proposed, but not
voted on, at UNCTAD in 1964 would have been such a one-way prefer-
ence. The South would receive preferences in Northern markets, but not
grant them to the North in return. An infinite number of variations of
one-way discriminatory free trade is possible and we will discuss
some of them, after examining the basic theme.
The arguments for a worldwide system of preferences from north
to South are all based on the judgment that itis desirable or expedient
for the North to promote the industrialization of the South; or, from
other motives, at least to give the impression of promoting it. The
economic case is based on the belief, reinforced by the effective tariff
argument, that preferential treatment will hasten industrialization
by offering the LDC's the near equivalent of a protected infant-
industry market. in the North, as well as the possibility of economies of
scale in production, arising from the Size of that market. Underlying
that belief is the tacit assumption that income elasticities of demand
virtually dictate industrialization as the route to prosperity and trade
growth. Given these beliefs, the principal arguments favoring pref-
*erences are as follows: (1) the future gains accruing to the South from
further trade liberalization are uncertain, both because of doubts
surrounding the results for the South of the GATT negotiations eoii-
eluded in June .1967 in light of exemption lists, which drop many
PAGENO="0215"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 207
products of interest to the South from the tariff-cutting procedure;
(2) even if those gains were forthcoming and large, infant-industry
and equity grounds conspire to warrant further concessions to the
South; (3) the income transfer involved in making price concessions
to the South is small but is more acceptable politically to donor and
recipient than the equivalent foreign aid subsidy; (4) many LDC's
have gone as far as-and often farther than-they should in import
substitution, so that any device to encourage export-promotion is de-
sirable; (5) the South wants preferences, and the North's costs would
be negligible, whether or not the alleged gains materialize.
The arguments against preferences are: (1) they tend to promote
and perpetuate economic inefficiency-even the valid infant-industry
and scale-economy arguments are grounds for subsidy rather than
preference; (2) rather than improving North-South relations, prefer-
ential systems would exacerbate them for a variety of reasons-they in-
evitably discriminate in effect against some LDC's and some Atlantic
countries, they would create an automatic obstacle toward further
efforts to liberalize world trade (because reduction of tariffs also re-
duces the preference margin), and they would, if successful, create a
type of economic dependence on northern concessions that is incon-
sistent with the South's struggle for independence; (3) preferential
systems are strikingly complicated to administer in any event, and im-
possible to manage without inequity to some parties; (4) preferences
are likely to bring with them the reverse of the effects intended, be-
cause the introduction of preferences gives Northern producer interests
a chance to legislate restrictive "safeguards," that would be impossible
under a nondiscriminatory tariff policy (known technically as "most-
favored-nation" or MFN system); (5) the gains from preferential
systems would be small, because tariffs, even effective tariffs, are gen-
erally low now in light of the South's cost disadvantage, and would be
still lower after GATT negotiations are completed; (6) preferences
are an inferior way to give aid and lead to an inequitable distribution
of aid costs.
It must be obvious by now that the differences in assumptions,
goals,'and estimates of the fact are so great that there can be no final
answer. I favor extension of preferences to the South, whether or not
on a worldwide basis, providing they are temporary with fixed expira-
tion dates (preferably set by reduction of MFN tariffs to the pref-
erential rate), or, failing that, are limited by quota. or other device.
My reasons for supporting preferences are based on the beliefs that the
North should do more than it now is to help improve Southern living
standards, and tha.t preferences will make some contribution in that
direction. They would create both administrative problems and incen-
tives to inefficiency but would also provide positive incentives to
domestic and foreign investment that could make a big difference to
the rate of economic and social development, of some countries. The
stress on efficiency overlooks material issues: (a) short-run efficiency
and long-run . growth are not necessarily achieved by the same meth-
ods.; (h) there may be a conflict between efficiency and equity; (c) pref-
erence-induced increases in Northern investment abroad will strength-
en the Southern lobby in the North, and may therefore. be a risk worth
`taking, at least for those who generally support Southern claims. In
practice, the best way to reconcile the conflicts between the gains and
PAGENO="0216"
208 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
losses from preferences is to tie the adoption of temporary preferences
into a general system of progressive reduction of MFN tariff rates, as
discussed below.
SOME PROPOSALS FOR PREFERENTIAL SYSTEMS
The French Pktn.-The Brasseur plan, as advanced by France in
1963, provides for negotiations of separate bilateral agreements in a
system of selective, temporary, and decreasing preferences. Each pref-
erence-granting country decides in each case to whom it will accord
preferences, for what products, with what tariff quotas, with what
preference in argin, and with what duration.
The application of this system by 20 northern countries to 70 LDC's
for 1,000 products would require the equivalent of 1l/2 million bilateral
negotiations. Furthermore, each preference-granting country would
not operate in a vacuum. Its decisions about each bilateral preferential
offer would be made in light of the decisions made by other Northern
countries, so that de facto multilateral negotiations would be super-
imposed on the system. These are virtually certain to be crippling
obstacles to a large-scale system. The French Government has tacitly
recognized the defects and its current proposals for preferences no
longer stress the merits of the Brasseur plan.
The French system, however, offers some decided advantages in
theory. It assures one or a few preference-receiving countries of ex-
elusive preference. Therefore, domestic or foreign investors in the
preference-receiving country are able to rely on a relatively sure ex-
port market, once they are able to meet the preference-granting coun-
try's domestic price for the product. Worldwide extension of prefer-
ence offers no such guarantee. A second advantage, for governments,
of the French system is its flexibility. Internationally, it can be used
as a device to help friends or punish the recalcitrant; at home, it can
be used to protect domestic industries, or to threaten those who fail
to agree to government price, investments, or employment guidelines.
Finally, in theory, it is the most equitable system, in terms of equaliz-
ing benefits received, because it allows the preferences to be adapted to
provide for the circumstances of each country. In practice, of course,
the political pressures for foreign and domestic interests would pre-
vent the attainment of such a goal, even if the preference-granting
country were inclined to aim at it. LDC's have shown little enthusiasm
for the Brasseur plan, because of its complexity and the evident co-
lonialist connotations.
The LDG PZan.-Tiie administrative headaches are~ by no means
dispelled if the South's most recent proposals are accepted instead. At
TJNCTAD meetings in 1965, the LDC's asked for general one-way
preference, with larger margins for the least-developed countries than
for those that are already semi-industrial. This plea for equity requires
the very difficult determination of which preference category each
LDC falls into. The LDC proposal also specifies a quota-free prefer-
ence, with no products exempted. This is a blow in favor of adminis-
trative simplicity, but if insisted upon as a condition, it would foreclose
the possibility of general preferences. The prospects for Northern ac-
ceptance of a: system that allows unlimited preferential access to all
corners can best be judged by reference to the recent history of textile
imports on MFN basis.
PAGENO="0217"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 209
Furthermore, the graduation of preference margins is a plea for
equity in Southern eyes, although its short-term effec:tiveness in pro-
moting, for example, African exports of manufactures may be
doubted. But it implies an inequity in the North. High-tariff coun-
tries in the North would bear a greater adjustment burden than low-
tariff countries. Equity in this sense requires equal tariff reductions
among preference-granting countries.
But in practice, this kind of "damage-limiting" equality can be
achieved only by setting preferential rate import quotas by product
and, thereby, creating considerable administrative problems. If, as has
been suggested in the name of equity, portions of each product quota
were assigned to each LDC, effective administration would become a
real challenge.1° Furthermore, if, as Johnson proposes, exporters'
quotas were made negotiable to allow nonexporting LDC's to sell
their rights to those that can benefit from the preference, the claim
to equity would be increased at the expense of still greater adminis-
trative novelty.
One-way F'iee Trade.-The optimum system, to combine ease of
administration, Northern political imperatives, and genuine impact on
development, requires: (1) quota-free preferences; (2) a list of ex-
cepted products-those that now compete effectively in the North; (3)
an escape clause that allows tariffs to be reimposed if imports exceed
some stated proportion of domestic demand; (4) and, most important
politically, establishment of general preferences as a step on the road
to a worldwide MFN system.
This system, like most income-redistributing policies, is rife with
inequity. It also leaves unanswered such knotty questions as which
countries should be eligible for preferences, what the escape clause
criteria should be, and whether the preference should be permanent
or temporary, worldwide, or selective. But it has the sovereign advan-
tage of being workable, and of encouraging the industrial develop-
nient of those countries that are actually ready to industrialize.
It is generally believed that preferences should be temporary to
avoid setting up a permanent vested interest in discrimination.
Prebisch has suggested that no LDC be allowed to benefit from prefer-
ences for a specific product for more than 10 or 15 years, for example.
This device would allow new producers to enter the market over
time and submit established LDC producers to the test of world
competition. However, this approach introduces substantial complex-
ity because of the large numbers of countries and products. Further-
more, established LDC suppliers will be reluctant to surrender their
"temporary" preferential advantages. They may well band together
under the banner of "la justice exige que seul le provisoire dure."
The politics of the situation therefore dictate a somewhat different
approach. If preferences are to be temporary, they should be estab-
lished on the principle of according advance reductions to LDC's in
a general program of worldwide MFN reductions. For example, if
the North accords LDC's a 50 percent tariff reduction on manufac-
t.ured products for 10 years, the preference would end not by raising
the preferential rate back to the preexisting MFN rate, but by lower-
ing the MFN rate to the preferential rate. This method presents dual
1~ How. to ilstrlbute country quotas to exporters offers no fewer difficulties than how to
set the size of the quotas initially. .., .
PAGENO="0218"
210 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
advantages. First, it increases the pressure on Northern countries to
i'educe their trade barriers. Failure to reduce their tariffs simply per-
petuaites LDC's competitive advantage. School, and for similar rea-
sons, it reduces the ability of LDC's to perpetuate the preferential
margin.
If preferences are integrated into a system of staged MFN reduc-
tions in this manner, no major recasting of the existing trade system
would be required (although GATT rules would have to be
amended). Furthermore, it even offers some prospect of mutual ad-
vantage. Countries that seek liberal trade can then look upon prefer-
ences as a way station toward that goal. Countries that seek to help
LDC's can harness free trade efforts to their wagon.
On the other hand, a system of this kind is likely to meet opposition
on several counts: from countries that are not interested in general
tariff reductions, from LDC's seeking perpetual preference, and par-
ticulariv from LDC's that are still at very early stages of develop-
ment. The latter group might fear that progressive MFN reductions.
would in fact leave them with no significant preference margin by the
time they were ready to export manufactured products.
No system of preference administration can avoid the problems
raised by the fact that some people will be hurt more than others
and some helped more than others. But the remedy for this does not
lie along the lines sought by France and the LDC's. It requires instead
adjustment assistance for Northern firms that suffer damage and shifts
in the distribution of foreign aid for those LDC's that fail to benefit.
THE EFFECTS OF PREFERENCES
The attack and defense of preferences seems to become more in-
tense as our ignorance of its effects becomes more apparent. Instead
of responding by trying to clarify the facts about trade, development,
and industrialization, policymakers all too often seem to take ideolog-
ical refuge in one or another version of whatever, theory happens to
be congenial.
Unfortunately, we know rather little about t.he effects of prefer-
ences. Sometimes, when other incentives or prerequisites were present,
they have apparently had a marked effect on trade (Puerto Rico). In
other cases, the results have not been striking.
Commonwealth Preferenee.-Only one preferential system, that of
the British Commonwealth, has been studied in detail." The studies
review the effects of preferences from the time they were introduced
(1932) until 1962. During that period, United Kingdom imports from
the Commonwealth increased relatively by nearly one-third, account-
ing for 30 percent of all British imports by value before preferences
were introduced and rising to an average of 40 percent during the
period 1960-64. During the early postwar period this increase was
even more marked, but both GATT tariff cuts and the easing of the
dollar shortage have had their effects. In the period 1959-65, for ex-
ample, Commonwealth imports fell from 44 percent to 36 percent 0±
the United Kingdom import total.
The preference is highest for manufactures, averaging about 20 per-
cent, ad valorem, in 1962, compared with an average of 11.8 percent
ii Political and Economic Planning, "Commonwealth Preferencein the United Kingdom,"
London. 1961: R. W. Green, "Commonwealth Preference," Board of Trade Journal, June
11, 1965, pp. iv-xix. and Dec. 31, 1965, pp. 1551-58.
PAGENO="0219"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 211
for all imports enjoying preferences in that year. If nondutiable im-
ports are included, the figure is much lower, because most foodstuffs
and raw materials are duty-free from any source. The average duty
on Commonwealth imports has fluctuated considerably over the years.
The areas that export manufactured products to the United King-
dom therefore benefit from higher margins than the 7.2 percent
Commonwealth-wide average.
Manufactured products accounted for 9 percent of United Kingdom
imports from the Commonwealth in 1957, 14.5 percent in 1962, and
16 percent by 1964. The principal beneficiaries in respect to manufac-
tured imports were Hong Kong, India, and Pakistan, benefiting re-
spectively in 1962 from average preference margins of 19, 11, and 14
percent.
The pattern of United Kingdom trade was significantly affected by
the preferential system. The United Kingdom took 14 percent of its
total imports of manufactured products from LT)C's in 1964, a higher
proportion than any other industrial country. Three-fourths of this
amount came from preferential suppliers.
Although the effects were significant, they were hardly revolution-
ary. The principal factors in mitigating preferential effects were: the
gradual erosion of preferential margins resulting from MFN tariff
reductions; the United Kingdom had a comparative advantage in man-
ufactures and received reciprocal preferences in Commonwealth
markets in some cases; Asian members best able by virtue of economic
structure to profit from preferences were remote from the United
Kingdom, so that transport costs and unfamiliarity of the market may
have loomed large; after independence, these countries generally
turned to import-substitution as the easiest form of industrialization.
There is no evidence that Commonwealth countries, or other prefer-
ence-receiving LDC's, have had a more rapid growth of manufactured
exports than nonpreferred suppliers. In fact for the period 1960-65,
for a group of 65 LDC's including all the major exporters, manufac-
tured exports of those not receiving preferences increased by 100
percent, while those of preference-receiving nations rose by only 67
percent. Part of this difference reflects a statistical factor. Hong Kong,
India, Pakistan, and the Philippines, all receiving preferences, ac-
counted for half of the 65 countries' manufactured exports. All prefer-
ence-receiving LDC's combined accounted for two-thirds of the South's
manufactured exports in 1964. Therefore, the more rapid relative
growth of exports to the North from nonpreferred suppliers largely
reflects the fac.t that they started from a small base, about $320 million
in 1960, compared with $914 million in that year for preference-re-
ceiving countries. These data for the 1960-64 period illustrate both the
gains from preferences and their limitations. The grant of preferences
undoubtedly makes some contribution to the dominant role of prefer-
ence-receiving nations in world markets for LDC manufactures. But
the data also illustrate that preferences are not essential to the develop-
ment of LDC trade in manufactured products, as witness the very
rapid growth of exports from Mexico, Israel, Taiwan, and South
Korea since 1960.
The results of Commonwealth preferences offer an example of the
primacy of preconception over analysis in these matters. The prefer-
ence system demonstrated modest but helpful effects for the benefici-
PAGENO="0220"
212 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
aries. These presumably would have been greater if the preferential
market was larger and less remote, and the exporting nations' inde-
pendence longer established. The steady growth of United Kingdom-
manufactured imports from the preferential area since 1957 supports
this latter opinion. Yet much contemporary public discussion ignores
this, by stating either that the results would be negligible for the
South or difficult for the North.
BALANCE-OF-PAYMENTS EFFECTS
A second point at which the scanty observed results differ from the
evidence is in the estimate of what preferences would do to balance
of payments. It is claimed that the United States cannot given prefer-
ences because they would lead to increased imports, thereby worsening
the balance of payments. The problem is analytically quite complex,
because increases in U.S. imports from LDC's have a series of effects
on the balance of payments.
If the new imports from LDC's substitute for goods previously
imported from the North, then the balance-of-payments results will
depend on the relative extent to which North and South spend addi-
tional foreign exchange earnings in the United States. Obviously, if
Northern countries use dollar earnings to build up reserves, while
LDC's use them to finance imports, then a switch in the source of
supply from North to South benefits the U.S. balance of payments.
But the full effects depend not only on the initial disposition of the
dollars earned by foreigners, but also on subsequent rounds of spend-
ing.
Some research has been carried out in order to measure the balance-
of-payments effects of tied aid compared with untied aid. This research
indicates that there are sharp differences among LDC's in their margi-
nal propensities to spend additional dollars, tied or untied, in the
United States, but that these intercountry differences narrow when
additional rounds of respending are taken into consideration.
Two points stand out: (1) during 1960-64, LDC's increased their
imports from the United States one-third faster than the growth of
LDC exports, while their imports from the rest of the North increased
oniy half as fast as LDC exports; (2) although U.S. exports to the
North increased at the same rate as to the South, these increases were
smaller than either the rate of Northern trade growth or the growth of
Northern exports to the United States.
These data offer some implication therefore, that diversion of U.S.
imports from North to South results in an improvement of the U.S.
trade balance. Naturally, these aggregative computations offer only
an indication. The data for the 1960-64 period also reflect an accentu-
ated U.S. emphasis on tied aid, as introduced under pressure of
* America's balance-of-payments concerns. For the period under review,
this may have been a dominant element in the rapid growth of U.S.
exports to LDC's.
Countries that face substantial trade diversion from preferences
(such as Japan) are unlikely to recoup fully through these respending
effects. But those whose exports are not highly competitive with poten-
tial LDC exports may well gain on balance. If, as seemslikely, LDC's
spend all their addition~l foreign exchange earnings, the effect for all
PAGENO="0221"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 213
industrial countries, as a group, is neutral. The question at issue, how-
ever, is the country-by-country incidence of that effect. Some indus-
trial countries would benefit, in balance-of-payments terms, while
others would lose. The analysis that would help to answer the ques-
tions "who?" and "how much?" remains to be performed.
PREDICTING THE TRADE EFFECTS OF GENERAL PREFERENCES
Whatever the likely balance-of-payments effects, or the record of
existing preferential systems, they give us no sure guide to the trade
effects of the proposed general system. The estimates that have been
made so far are not very helpful, because they are based on static
analysis, and are defective, even in those terms, because of our igno-
rance of the relevant supply and demand elasticities. However, they
serve some purpose in indicating whether short-run effects are large
or small.
One such estimate has been made by Grant L. Reuber.12 He has made
various assumptions about trade effects for LDC's of: (1) reducing
MFN tariffs to zero; (2) reducing MFN rates only enough to main-
tain existing preference margins; (3) maintaining MFN rates for the
north and reducing LDC rates to zero. Not surprisingly, he concludes
that the South would benefit most from the last alternative. With an
average tariff of 12 percent and a demand elasticity of minus 2, he
estimates that LDC exports of manufactured products subject to sig-
nificant tariffs, but not now subject to quantitative controls, would in-
crease by 25 percent (or $250 million), and exports of noncompeting
unmanufactured products by 2.4 percent (or $350 million), for a total
effect, at 1961 trade levels, of $600 million. If quantitative restrictions
were removed from competing goods, he estimates an additional $1.1
billion of imports would result under "optimistic" assumptions.
Reuber points out that these effects are negligible compared with cur-
rent levels of trade and aid.
Johnson has said that Reuber's is too low an estimate because it
neglects effective protection. He offers an estimate for increases in
manufactured exports alone under free trade of $600 million. Prefer-
ential trade results would be correspondingly greater. But if a figure
of $600 million is used to adjust IReuber's estimates, the short-run
trade effect of preferences becomes about $1 billion, even if existing
quantitative restrictions are retained.
As an alternative to this approach, I have estimated the effects on
a different set of assumptions, and emerged with a result that is not
significantly different. My method was to assume that the developed
countries would allow a preferential duty-free tariff quota to the
South on a product-by-product basis. There were three additional
assumptions: (1) Preferences would not be extended products for
which the South is now competitive; (2) tariff quotas would not be
effective in stimulating imports of manufactured products either when
existing tariffs are below 5 percent ad valorem, or when, no matter
what the tariff level, technology and scale problems seem insurmount-
able; (3) preferential quotas would be set at 5 percent of last year's
imports of all products. Using 1962 data for Western Europe, Japan,
12 "Canada's Interest in the Trade Problems of the Less-Developed Countries," Private
Planning Association of Canada, Montreal, 1964, pp. 23-29.
PAGENO="0222"
214 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
Canada, and the United States, this exercise produced the following
results:
I. Manufactured products with average tariff below 5 percent
A. 1962 Northern imports from-All sources, $4.1 billion; LDC's,
$30 million.
B. Potential preferential imports under 5 percent tariff quota,a $175
million.
II. Manufactured products with average northern tariffs greater than
5 percent
A. 1962 Southern imports from-All sources, $31.8 billion; LDC's,
$277 million.
B. Potential preferential imports under 5 percent tariff quota,a $1.3
billion.
At the May 1965 meeting of the UNCTAD special committee on
preferences, the South asked for a preferential system that would al-
low duty-free entry under a global quota of 10 percent of all Northern
imports. The effect if each of the Northern countries took 10 percent
of their manufactured imports from the South compared with 1963
trade levels would be equivalent to $5.1 billion. The total increase in
imports under these assumptions would have been $2.5 billion, because
1963 Northern imports from the South, including metals, were worth
$3.1 billion.13 If, on the other hand, we assume that the global duty-
free quota would result in a 10-percent increase in imports, then the
value of the trade increase would be $5.2 billion, a sum far in excess
of any current estimates. In practice, the entire range of aspirations
represented by the $2.5 billion "minimum" and the $5.2 billion "maxi-
mum" lies above what can reasonably be expected from preferences
in the short run.
Halting as these initial estimates are, they can be considered solid
compared with estimates of the full effects, allowing for all the dy-
namic considerations discussed earlier. The best we can say now is
that the evidence supports neither LDC hopes nor Atlantic countries'
fears of "market disruption." Obviously, if under a 5-percent tariff
quota, or similar limiting device, the initial (2 to 5 year) trade effect
is of the order of $1 to $2 billion, the aggregate damage to Northern
producers is negligible.
CONCLUSIONS
For many Southern countries, sharply increased production and ex-
ports of processed materials and manufactured goods are probably
one condition of rapid economic growth. In some cases, the pos-
sibilities are fairly good under a liberal nondiscriminating trading
system. Some countries would really not benefit much unless they
could get preferred treatment. Others are now too underdeveloped
to export manufactures (except refined ores and foodstuffs), even with
preferences. They will need considerable time and assistance before
they can look even to domestic industrial markets.
a Jf all quotas are used by LDC's. Tariffs weight3d by trade.
b Excluding products for which LDC's are now major suppliers.
13 This increase of $2.5 billion, added to the $&1 billion existing level, gives a total of
$5.6 billion, not $5.1 billion. The discrepancy arises from the fact that the United States
and the TJnited Kingdom now take more than 10 percent of their manufactured imports
from the South.
PAGENO="0223"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 215
In theory, preferences in Northern markets benefit the South more
than free trade, because they confer a price advantage over com-
petitors. This advantage could be offset if the grant of preferences
were tied to restrictions on entry. In any event, the benefits of pref-
erential systems are likely to be important only to the semiindustrial
countries in the short run. These short-run increases in LDC exports
might be of the general order of $1 billion annually under a system of
one-way free trade, if existing quantitative restrictions are maintained.
In the long run, preferences should help shift world location of
processing industries toward the raw material sources, encourage
greater domestic and foreign investment in industry, and promote a
greater awareness of trade opportunities. Not even the roughest guess
of the size of these effects is possible.
The case for preferences is in large part political, because they in-
volve, among other elements, a transfer of resources and adjustment
costs to Northern producers. If the North wants to be associated with
the South and influence its policies, encouragement of trade ties can
have its uses, at modest cost. Conversely, the refusal to grant prefer-
ences, unless it is accompanied by some other form of aid, does nothing
to reduce North-South tensions. This is an important consideration
for the United States, which is still saddled with its somewhat nega-
tive UNCTAD record. Unfortunately, its stand on preferences re-
mained unaltered, despite strong pressures from other OECD countries
and LDC's at the 1966 meetings of the UNCT'AD preferences com-
mittee. Ultimately, U.S. policy will be forced to change, as already
foreshadowed by President Johnson's statement at Punta del Este
ill April 1967. However the prolonged delay probably benefits neither
North nor South. The system proposed by other OECD countries
was objectionable because it was based on tariff quotas, which are all
too likely to be used as tokens of preferential treatment with little real
effect. Nonetheless, the U.S. refusal to agree to any scheme can hardly
be viewed as a constructive alternative.
It is one thing to affirm, as I have, that political and economic
advantages could stem from preferences, and quite another to claim
either that the benefits would be vast, or the pitfalls negligible. There
is no evidence to support the view that the economic transformation
of the South awaits only the infant industry effects of preferences.
Nor can the view be dismissed that the use of preferences is likely
to be either as an instrument of trade restriction, somewhat in the
manner of TJ.S. sugar legislation, or as a token gesture that will
arouse more resentment than support in the South. But new policies
normally have their risks, and these are no different. In this case, the
political risks seem more modest than the gains.
Finally, each underdeveloped country is a special case, and each
will develop differently. Whether Northern policies are enlightened
or not, some of today's poor nations will inevitably prosper, while
others, by comparison, will seem to stagnate. In a century-long per-
spective there will be countries that will far surpass a tenfold growth
of per capita income, and others that will not even be close. This in
turn will raise new questions of international equity and perpetuate
old ones. Arbitration of these discords will be the task of another era.
The success of contemporary generations in attacking poverty will
be measured by how much or how little its descendants need be con-
cerned with the issues I have analyzed here.
PAGENO="0224"
IMPORTS OF MANUFACTURES FROM LESS DEVELOPED
COUNTRIES
BY HAL B. LARY
The following analysis is condensed from a comprehensive study being
prepared for publication by the National Bureau of Economic Research.
The study is subject to revision in the light of comments by the board of
directors of the National Bureau and other readers, and the present
abridged version is submitted on the author's own responsibility.
July 1967.
CHAPTER I. THE PROBLEM AND A SUMMARY OF FINDINGS
INTRODUcTION
It seems to be generally agreed that newly developing countries will
need to achieve a rapid and sustained rise in export earnings to cover
their growing imports of capital goods and other essentials and to
service their foreign borrowings. Failure to attain such an increase, or
to receive ever larger foreign aid, would impose a foreign exchange
constraint on their growth, even though the major transformation re-
quired is in their internal economic and social structures and in their
capacity to save and invest.
Looked at from this point of view, the figures in table 1-1 are not
reassuring with respect to the export performance of the less developed
countries.' Over the period 1950 to 1965 these countries, exclusive of
the major oil producers among them, increased the current dollar
value of their exports to the developed countries by 4.2 percent an-
nually on the average. Their exports to each other, again omitting
the major oil producers, were only slightly larger in 1965 than in 1950.
Over the same period the dollar value of trade among the developed
countries rose at an average annual rate of about 9.4 percent, or per-
haps a percentage point less if figured at constant prices. Total exports
of developed countries to the destinations covered by table I-i were
about 21/2 times those of the non-oil-producing less developed countries
in 1950 and were five times as great in 1965.
The need for a faster increase in exports of the less developed
countries will not be elaborated here, since it has been studied at
length by the United Nations and others. One may question alternative
projections of the likely "foreign exchange gap," or the validity of
the gap approach. But there seems to be little room for doubt that
exports of the less developed countries will need to rise faster than
heretofore as one of the conditions for their economic development.
The contrasting performance of exports of developed and less de-
veloped countries reflects, in addition to factors on the supply side, the
faster growth of world demand for manufactures than for most of
I Throughout this study the less developed countries are taken as comprising all of the
Western Hemisphere except the United States and Canada; all of Africa except the Union
of South Africa; the Middle East except Turkey; the rest of Asia and the Far East except
Japan, mainland China, and North Korea; and Oceania except Australia and New Zealand.
216
PAGENO="0225"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 217
TABLE I-i--EXPORTS OF DEVELOPED AND LESS DEVELOPED COUNTRIES, 1950 AND 1965
Value (billions of dollars at
current prices)
Compound
annual rate
of growth,
1950-65
(percent)
1950
I
1965
World exports (total)
Exports of developed countries (total)
To each other
To less developed countries
Exports of less developed countries (total)
To developed countries
To each other
Exports of less developed countries, excluding major petroleum
producers b (total)
To developed countries
To each other
53.5
156.3
7.4
35. 9
122. 5
8. 5
25.0
10. 9
95.5
27. 0
9.4
6. 2
17. 6
33. 8
4. 5
12.4
5.2
26.2
7.6
5.2
2.5
14. 1
23. 7
3. 6
10. 0
4. 1
18.5
5. 2
4.2
1. 7
All figures exclude exports to and exports of Eastern Europe, the U.S.S.R., and mainland China.
Countries excluded are Algeria, Iran, Kuwait, Libya, Netherlands Antilles, Saudi Arabia, Trinidad and Tobago, and
Venezuela.
Note: Figures may not add to totals shown because of rounding.
Source: Various statistical publications of the United Nations.
the primary products which make up the bulk of the exports of the
less developed countries. Reasons for the relative lag in trade in pri-
mary products include economies in their use, the continuing develop-
ment of synthetic substitutes, and the growing complexity and sophis-
tication of final products, all of which tend to reduce the input of raw
materials per unit of output.
It will therefore be accepted as a starting point for the present
analysis that the increase in exports of the less developed countries
will have to be largely in manufactured goods. Some countries ex-
ceptionally well endowed with natural resources may be able to meet
their growing foreign exchange needs through sales of primary prod-
ucts in crude or processed form. The oil-exporting countries form a
small and privileged group in this regard. Broadly viewed, however,
there is little reason to suppose that the influences tending to retard
the growth of trade in primary products have run their course. If
this is a correct judgment, a solution commensurate with the growth
needs of the less developed countries will presumably entail a rapid
increase in their exports of manufactures to the advanced countrIes.
LABOR-INTENSIVE MANUFACTURES
This study seeks to identify the kinds of manufactures best suited
to the growth of exports and to examine the pattern and prospects of
trade in these items. By definition, the less developed countries have
little accumulated capital or technical skill. Any comparative advan-
tage which they may hold or attain in manufacturing for export,
apart from strongly resource-based industries, is therefore likely to
be in industries which are intensive in the use of relatively unskilled
labor and sparing in the use of both physical and human capital.
Such a course encounters obvious problems and resistances on the
side of the developed countries. But it also offers them the possibility
of shifting scarce manpower from traditional lines of production
S2-246-137-----15
PAGENO="0226"
218 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S.FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
to other industries where labor can be more productively combined
with their capital resources.
Such a course may also be unwelcome to some of the less developed
countries, implying concentration on relatively simple types of manu-
facturing and perhaps excessive exposure to the risks of international
trade. These disadvantages are scarcely greater, however, than those
entailed in their present heavy reliance on exports of primary prod-
ucts. And, if the analysis given here points in the right direction, a
willingness to focus initially on labor-intensive lines of manufacturing
may be a necessary condition for evolving toward the production
of goods with, as Fei and Ranis say, "an increasing skill and ingenuity
component over time." 2
It may be further objected that, apart from qualifications such as
that just given, the approach taken here makes no specific allowance
for the possibility that comparative advantage may shift as develop-
ment proceeds, thanks to internal and external economies of scale and
other dynamic influences associated with growth. How much weight
should be attached to this possibility in the present context is difficult
to say.
One factual observation deriving from this study is that, if the
argument is deemed to be relevant to, or consistent with. the need to
increase export earnings of less developed countries, there is little
indication that any of these countries have so far become competitive
in the more capital-intensive lines of manufacturing (except, of course,
those based on the exploitation of natural resources). Usually, how-
ever, dynamic considerations have not been related to problems of
export promotion but have been invoked rather to favor a strategy of
import substitution and may be subject to the same need of cautious
reappraisal as that seen below.
Still another possible objection to the present approach is that,
even within a comparative cost framework, the emphasis may be too
much on labor intensity to the neglect of other conditions affecting
the ability of less developed countries to sell manufactures in the
markets of the more advanced countries. Some industries are more
strongly market-oriented than others, and ease of communication be-
tween producer and customer may bear importantly on their location.
Even in such cases, the increasing speed of international communi-
cations and growing experience in procuring abroad may open up new
possibilities of siting production where costs are lowest. This is illus-
trated by the evolution of the garment industry in Hong Kong toward
high-fashion goods and also by the encouragement given by American
companies to the production of electronic and other components in
low~wage countries.
THE OVERSPILLVIEW OF EXPORTS
The usual approach to the problem of increasing exports of manu-
factures by the less developed countries has been along the lines of
what Wmston Churchill once called the overspill view of exports in
Britain. That is, concentrate first on developing the home market,
and this ~will create the conditions needed for an efficient and rising
export trade.
2John C. H. Fe! and Gustav Ranis, "Development of the Labor Surplus Economy."
Homewood, Ill., 1964, p. 303.
PAGENO="0227"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 219
W. W. Rostow has put the point in the following way, with more
specific reference to the problems of the less developed countries:
"What I am asserting, then, is that the expansion of the domestic
market which is required to produce a modernization of rural life
and an ample market for domestic industry is also the proper base
for the development of diversified exports." ~
A similar conception seems to infuse programs of financial assist-
ance to the less developed countries. The International Bank's loans
and feasibility studies have mainly focused on the infrastructure and
the home markets of the less developed countries and have rarely
served more directly to develop their exports. Our AID programs have
also been chiefly concerned with strengthening the internal conditions
for development, though some of the studies of investment opportuni-
ties which it has helped to finance point toward export possibilities.
The Export-Import Bank has well merited the first half of its name by
granting credits to finance sales of capital equipment and other goods
to the less developed countries. But little of its financing has been
aimed at stimulating imports from them.
The power and transportation facilities, machinery, and technology
made available through these loans and grants do, of course, help to
build up the economies of the less developed countries and may ulti-
mately serve to diversify and strengthen their exports. Moreover, these
public agencies no doubt consider, with some reason, that investment
opportunities offering attractive export prospects are particularly
suited to private initiative and financing and do not require public
development aid.
It seems fair to observe that the advanced countries have accepted
restrictive import policies by the less developed countries as a necessary
accompaniment of industrial development, and also have so far made
little adjustment in their own policies to facilitate the growth of im-
ports of manufactures from the less developed countries.
Under these conditions, it is remarkable that this trade, at least in
some products, has grown as fast as it has in recent years. The growth
has, however, been very unevenly distributed by exporting as well as
by importing countries-a fact that underlies the trade demands put
forward with increasing vigor by the less developed countries during
and since the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development
(UNCTAD) in 1964. The need to find better ways of expanding their
exports is evident. The means proposed to this end-on either side-
are more debatable, sometimes seeming primarily designed to shift
responsibility for action to other countries while avoiding commit-
ments that might entail awkward adjustments on one's own part.
LIMITATIONS OF MARKET SIZE IN THE LESS DEVELOPED COUNTRIES
However persuasive the argument may seem, it rather begs the ques-
tion to say, with Rostow, that the most effective base for the export
of manufactures is a large domestic market. According to one esti-
mate, only five of the less developed countries have national incomes
(converted to dollars at prevailing rates of exchange) larger than
Connecticut. These are India, Pakistan, Brazil, Mexico, and Argen-
W. W. Rostow, "Economic Development In Asia," Department of State Bulletin, May
31, 1905, p. 850.
PAGENO="0228"
220 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S.FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
tina, to which perhaps Indonesia (with poor statistics but a popula-
tion of 100 million) should be added. Though the beginnings of in-
dustry go back rather far in some of these countries, none of them
has yet done sufficiently well in exporting manufactures to Vindicate
±he overspill view.
The six countries just mentioned account for more than half of the
total population of the less developed countries, but that still leaves
a host of people and problems outside as well as inside. Close to 100
of the less developed countries have a population smaller than 15
million, and in two-thirds of them it is less than 5 million.
On the whole very poor, they are smaller still in size of market
compared with most developed countries. More such countries are
being born as Malta, Gambia, the Mauritius Islands, and the few
other remaining European possessions move toward and achieve in-
dependence. This proliferation of small and minuscule nations is
largely a product of the swift unraveling of colonialism after World
War II, though in Central America it goes far back into the last
century.
Uncertain Prospects for Regional Integration
In principle, one way of meeting this dilemma is by integration of
these splinter economies into larger and more viable regional group-
ings following, at a great distance, the example of the Europea~n Com-
mon Market. There are excellent reasons favoring this course and com-
mending it to outside support-even apart from any hope which
harried officials in developed countries may hold of being thereby
relieved in some measure of the problem of increasing imports from
the less developed countries.
So far, efforts to combine into larger regional entities have brought
little specific result. In some areas, the trend is rather the ot.her way, as
indicated by the strains and disruptions experienced in the West
Indies, Malaysia, East Africa, and Nigeria. Little progress is evident
in the Maghreb, which was supposed to embrace the Arab States of
North Africa. The most promising of these regional endeavors, the
Central American Common Market, illustrates the limitations more
than the potentialities of such arrangements. It brings together a f air-
ly homogeneous group of countries, compared with most others, and
even so adds up to only 12 million people with a combined pnrchasing
power less than that of any one of a. number of European and Ameri-
can cities. Now a far larger, more difficult, and more distant objective
has been set with the commitment by the heads of the Latin American
States in April 1967 at Punta del Este, "Beginning in 1970, to estab-
I ish progressively the Latin American Common Market, which should
be substantially in operation within a period of no more than fifteen
years." The length of the period set for achievement of the objective
attests to the difficulties to be overcome.
In some regions political and social frictions may well be the maior
obstacle to regional integration. The economic difficulties include dis-
parities in the levels of development attained by different countries
of the same region, since laggard countries tend to fear competition
by their more advanced nei~hbors. Even more awkward problems
may be presented by disparities among countries in the levels and
4 From the "Dechiration of the Presidents of America," Department of State Bulletin,
May 8, 1967, pp. 712-721.
PAGENO="0229"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 221
structures of production costs and prices. Barriers of the latter nature
are, in turn, largely the result of the exaggerated pursuit of "import
substitution" as a means of promoting industrial development.
COSTS OP EXCESSIVE IMPORT SUBSTITUTION
A developing country has some room for choice in orienting its new
industries toward replacing imports rather than expanding exports.
Initially, the emphasis is likely to be on the former course, since im-
ports attest to a market already in being at home and susceptible of
being reserved against foreign competition. Most and perhaps all de-
veloped countries have followed this course in the early stages of their
growth and, indeed, still cling to protection even though with little
basis any more for invoking the "infant industry" argument. Within
limits, this course is consistent with the "overspill" view of exports,
since, if the industries chosen for protection are well suited to a coun-
try's potentials, substitution for imports in its home market may set
the stage for competition in export markets later on.
These limits, however, can be quickly exceeded. A less developed
country's imports typically embrace a far greater variety of goods
than its exports. The difference is all the more striking if one consid-
ers not merely final goods but also the materials, parts, and capital
equipment entering into their production. Import substitution may
therefore soon spread a country's resources too thin over numerous
small and insufficient enterprises, and extend to types of production
ill suited to its conditions, with the unfortunate result of raising costs
even in industries in which it should otherwise be able to compete. A
further consequence is to deny the economy the stimulus to efficien~
and innovation which exposure to competition in domestic and foreign
markets can provide.
In other words, "backward and forward linkages" with other in-
dustries may prove to be a burden rather than a blessing if the indus-
tries selected for promotion are not well suited to a country's capabili-
ties and size. This may happen even in the largest of the less developed
countries.
Considerable caution would therefore seem to be warranted with
respect to the various internal and external economies which have
frequently been invoked in favor of capital-intensive industries at
early stages of economic development.
The frustrations of import substitution were the subject of an
urgent warning by Rai~l Prebisch in his advance message, as Secretary
General, to the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development.
Based largely on his close observation of the Latin American countries,
lie found that the "easy phase" of import substitution had about
reached its limit in the countries which had followed that course, and
that it could not go farther without considerable waste. He also found
that high tariffs to protect narrow national markets had "encouraged
the establishment of small uneconomical plants, weakened the incentive
to introduce modern techniques, and slowed down the rise in produc-
tivity."
"Thus," Prebisch continued, "a real vicious circle has been created as
regards exports of manufactured goods. These exports encounter great
difficulties because internal costs are high, and internal costs are high
PAGENO="0230"
222 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S.FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
because, among other reasons, the exports which would enlarge the
markets are lacking. Had it been possible to develop industrial exports,
the process of industrialization would have been more economical, for
it would have made possible the international division of labour in
manufacturing."
Responsibility for exaggerated import substitution does not fall
only on the governments of the less developed countries and their
advisers. Two World Wars and the great depression in between were
reason enough for many countries to try to produce at home what,
in those circumstances, they were no longer able to buy abroad. But the
least to be said in criticism of the less developed countries is that so
far they have shown little tendency to reverse course and expose their
small monopolies to outside competition.
REGIONAL OR INTERNATIONAL INTEGRATION
Under the conditions described, negotiations for regional integra-
tion by various groups of less developed countries are likely to mean
hard bargaining for mutual support, and reciprocal sacrifice, of high-
cost industries. With each participant concerned lest it lose more
than it gains, the difficulties of arriving at agreement and successful
implementation are apparent.
Considered in this light, it may be significant that the one regional
grouping which has been showing signs of progress toward integra-
tion-the Central American Common Market-is one whose member
states had previously remained relatively open to the outside world
and consequently did not differ widely from each other in their cost
and price structures. Nor, it must be added, did the members differ
much in the relatively low state of their industrial development. There
may be, in fact, some risk that the progress now being registered in
their manufacturing output and in their trade with each other could
prove to be another example of what Prebisch called the "easy phase"
of import substitution. The outcome is likely to depend on how suc-
cessful they are in diversifying and expanding their exports to other
countries at the same time they increase their trade within the area.
Political conditions permitting, other countries with relatively sim-
ple and open economies may be able to form local economic unions on
the Central American model. That experience also suggests the para-
doxical thought that countries whose import substitution has gone
much further, such as most of the other Latin American countries,
may be able to move toward regional integration only by first rein-
tegrating with the world economy and bringing their cost and price
structures more in line with those outside. A different, and perhaps
more realistic, strategy is evidently reflected in the renewed effort to-
ward economic union undertaken at Punta del Este; namely, as Joseph
Grunwald has expressed it, that integration is a "means of lifting the
Latin American countries to a level of economic maturity where, with-
out the aid of inefficient protection, they will eventually be able to
compete as equal partners with the developed nations."
The expectation underlying this strategy, as expounded by Grun-
wald, is that integration would expand market perspectives, allow a
more rational allocation of resources, permit economies of scale, spur
competition, and stimulate private investment. Also, a "protected re-
gionwide market" would provide the catalyst needed to break down
PAGENO="0231"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 223
economic, political, and social rigidities and restore economic viability.
This may be a correct appraisal of the Latin American problem and
the most promising way of accelerating growth in the region. It seems
unlikely, however, that this approach will significantly alleviate the
need for a rapid increase in exports to other areas, particularly in view
of the extended period-1970-85--over which the common market is
to be achieved. In the worst case, regional integration could hinder
such an increase in exports if it were to mean the spread of cost-raising
import substitution to countries in the region which, otherwise, would
set their policies toward becoming more competitive in world markets.
To recapitulate, this study accepts as its point of departure that if
the less developed countries are to earn foreign exchange in amounts
commensurate with their needs, they will have to achieve a rapid in-
crease in their exports of manufactures to the developed countries.
This is where the world's buying power is concentrated, as long as
levels of economic development remain so far apart, and it is also
where the less developed countries will have to obtain most of the
capital equipment and much of the materials and even some of the
food needed by their growing economies and population.
FACTOR INTENSITIES IN THE UNITED STATES AND ABROAD
The next question is to try to identify the kinds of manufactures in
which the less developed countries are most likely to hold or to be able
to achieve a comparative advantage in international trade. The "fac-
tor-proportions" theorem identified with Heckscher and Ohlin pro-
vides a persuasive, but much disputed, answer to this question. Accord-
ing to that theorem, countries may be expected to have a comparative
advantage in goods requiring relatively large inputs of the particular
factors of production-whether labor, capital, or natural resources-
with which they are most liberally endowed and, correspondingly, a
comparative disadvantage in the production of goods embodying their
scarce factors. A given country would therefore export goods of the
first type and import goods of the second type-on the assumption
that there are no hindrances to the flow of trade. In the context of the
present study this would mean that, apart from industries based on
such natural resources as they might have, the less developed countries
would tend to specialize in labor-intensive goods and to import capital-
intensive goods. More developed countries with greater capital re-
sources and a highly skilled labor force would show the opposite
pattern, at least in their trade with less developed countries.
The criterion used here for measuring, or at least approximating,
inputs of both human capital and physical capital on a common basis
will be value added by manufacture per employee. Put very loosely,
"value added by manufacture" is what remains after subtracting the
value of materials consumed from the gross value of output in any
given industry or industry group. Differences from industry to indus-
try in value added per employee are assumed to measure differences
in the aggregate flows of services from the factors of production
employed in the manufacturing process (and exclude therefore in-
direct factor inputs such as materials used). It is further assumed that
these services may be ascribed either to human capital or to physical
capital, and that, in interindustry comparisons, the wage and salary
PAGENO="0232"
224 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S.FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
part of value added is a good proxy for the first and the remainder
of value added a good proxy for the second.
Though affected by various market imperfections, value added per
employee has significant advantages as a measure of factor intensity in
manufacturing. One is that this measure may be taken to reflect the
flows of services into the manufacturing process from both human
capital and physical capital, and permits their treatment on a com-
mon basis. Another advantage is that value added per employee is
available in considerable industrial detail for the United States and a
number of other countries from their censuses of manufactures. The
use of this measure contasts with the usual reliance on more in-
frequent statistics of stocks of physical capital as a measure of capital
intensity, sometimes supplemented by verbal qualifications with re-
gard to skill requirements.
To test the validity of this approach, value added per employee is
broken down into its wage-and-salary component and the rest, and
significant relations are found across industries between the first and
other measures of skill and between the second and stocks of physical
capital. It appears that value added per employee is a reasonably
good, though not infallible, guide to the capital intensity of different
industries.
By this criterion, the labor-intensive industries include such major
industry groups in the census of manufactures as textiles, clothing,
lumber and wood products, furniture, leather and leather products,
and the broad group of miscellaneous manufactures. These main in-
dustry groups are relatively homogeneous in that very few of their
component industries exceed the national average for wage and non-
wage value added.
Industries which are extremely capital-intensive by both criteria
employed here include chemical products and petroleum refining.
Another industry which would fit into this category is the tobacco
industry, ranking very high in nonwage value added though low on
the wage scale. Here again there is a .high degree of homogeneity in
the component industries of these major groups.
The remaining major industry groups fall closer to the overall
averages of wage and nonwage value added for all U.S. manu-
facturing. They are also much more diverse in composition by these
criteria. Some of the latter fall well within the capital-intensive
sector-for example, blast furnaces and steel mills, primary nonfer-
rous metals, automobiles, tires and tubes, paper and paperboard mills,
hydraulic cement, flat glass, alcoholic beverages, flour mills, sugar
refining, and some other food processing industries. Other components
fall well within the labor-intensive sector, including a number of items
of interest in the present analysis-rubber shoes, motorcycles and
bicycles, cutlery and various other metal products, pleasure craft and
other small boats, glass containers, chinaware and pottery, ceramic
tiles, canned seafood, canned fruit and vegetables, paper and paper-
board containers, and various kinds of printed matter and printing
services.
This allocation leaves a number of other industries and products
near, or beyond, one or the other of the margins of the labor-intensive
sector, among them being metal castings and stampings; hardware
and tools; plumbing and heating equipment; household fans, automo-
PAGENO="0233"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 225
tive electrical equipment, radio and television sets, and other light elec-
trical goods; sewing machines and typewriters; various types of ma-
chinery; surgical and medical instruments; some measuring or scientific
instruments; and watches and clocks.
As will be noted later, most of the items just enumerated are mar-
ginal also in the sense that exports by less developed countries form
only a very small part of international trade in these goods. They are
nevertheless of particular interest, since these products could be re-
garded as next in line for the achievement of an export potential by
some of the less developed countries as the growth of their experience
and capacity in manufacturing permits them to move beyond the
more strongly labor-intensive types of production. And one may fur-
ther observe that the development of labor skills (including man-
agerial experience and technical abilities) seems no less important
than the growth of physical capital, if this kind of evolution is to occur.
It may be asked, however, whether any pattern of industries by fac-
tor intensity discerned for the United States would hold true for other
countries. Doubt on this score is natural, given the lower wage rates
and higher capital costs generally prevailing in other countries, espe-
cially the less-developed ones. All industries will no doubt tend to use
more labor in relation to capital in poor low-wage countries than in
richer ones, at least in auxiliary services if not in basic production proc-
esses. But if this substitution were stronger in some industries than in
others, the ranking of industries by factor intensity would also differ
from country to country. And if the tendency were widespread, it
would means that-contrary to the "strong factor intensity" hypoth-
esis underlying the factor proportions theorem-one could not con-
fidently rank industries according to their requirements of labor and
capital nor look at the relative factor endowments of different coun-
tries for clues to the likely composition and direction of their foreign
trade.
Despite problems of comparability, the analysis of value added per
employee in the United States and other countries developed at vari-
ous levels of industrial aggregation gives little evidence of factor-
intensity reversals. The comparisons tend rather to support the strong-
factor-intensity hypothesis underlying the factor-proportions theorem
and, more specifically, the relevance of the U.S. pattern of factor in-
tensities to other countries a..t very different levels of economic devel-
opment and with very different factor-price ratios. The selection 0±
labor-intensive manufactures based on value added per employee in
the United States stands up well on the basis of similar data for other
countries, including detailed comparisons with the United Kingdom,
Japan, and India.
Apart from any influence which may be exerted by differences in
factor-price ratios, the interindustry pattern of factor intensities may
change because the rate of technological advance is faster in some in-
dustries than in others, leading to new combinations of the factors
of production. And these changes may be registered sooner in some
countries than in others, depending on technological leadership, entre-
preneurial initiative, and the conditions of competition:
In recent years a good deal of attention has been given to the rate
of technological progress and changing factor proportions in textiles,
especially cotton textiles. Thus, A Study on Cotton Textiles prepared
PAGENO="0234"
226 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S.FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
by the GATT Secretariat,5 states that "the industry is continually
improving its performance through a shift to new types of equipment
embodying technical advances and innovations at every stage of pro-
duction," and that "the cotton industry in the industrialized countries
and some of the less developed exporting countries is undergoing fun-
damental changes." "Use is being made of huge investments for this
new equipment," the GATT study reports, and it adds: "A modern
cotton industry is regarded as being among the most highly capital-
intensive of the manufacturing industries."
How far this and other similar assessments are correct is important
for reasons that transcend the identification of labor-intensive manu-
factures for analytical purposes. For one thing, technological advance
in textiles is thought to have been stimulated by the rapid growth of
exports by some of the less developed and other low-wage countries.
Developments in the industry could therefore be regarded as illus-
trative of the kind of competitive response which, in still other prod-
ucts, could slow down or even thwart the growth of exports by less
developed countries. Secondly, the prospect of a highly capital-
intensive cotton textile industry is sometimes invoked as a reason
why, in the meantime, imports from less developed countries should
be curbed.6 Commercial policy is thus summoned to the support of
economic projections.
While the rate of technological innovation in cotton textiles is
impressive, it may be exaggerated to suppose that the process is sig-
nificantly faster than in manufacturing as a whole and to conclude
that the industry is becoming strongly capital-intensive. The evidence
for the United States is consistent with the view that there has been
heavy investment in modernization in the last few years in cotton tex-
tiles, but it gives little reason to think that the industry is becoming
capital-intensive compared with manufacturing in general and ceas-
ing to be appropriate to the factor endowments of the less-developed
countries. According to the criteria applied in this study, cotton tex-
tiles and the textile industry in general still rank among the most
labor-intensive of the manufacturing industries, and they will be so
treated in the analysis of trade.
The contrary view that a fundamental change in textiles is under
way may rely unduly on comparisons wi'th the industry's own past
characteristics and performance and fail to allow for the progress
made by manufacturing in general. The illustrations frequently given
of developments in the industry also suggest a tendency to confuse
the technological optimum with average practice at any one time.
CHAPTER II. TRADE IN LABOR-INTENSIVE MANUFACTURES
CHARACTERISTICS OF THE TRADE
Probably the most important generalizations that can be made
about imports of labor-intensive manufactures by developed from
less developed countries are, first, that these imports are small and,
second, that they have been growing i apidly in recent years
General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, Geneva, July 1966. The passages cited are
from p. 55.
6 For further discussion of the responses of developed countries to increased imports of
textiles from the less-developed countries see p. 237.
PAGENO="0235"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 227
Another broad generalization is that the trade is rather uneven in
its composition by products and in its distribution by both exporting
and importing countries. By product, textiles and clothing make up
a particularly large share of the total, though some other light manu-
factures have recently been rising more rapidly. Among the countries
of origin, Hong Kong holds an extraordinary position, and, all to-
gether, the less developed countries of the Far East are paramount
over other areas as suppliers of labor-intensive manufactures to de-
veloped countries. Among the latter, the United States, the United
Kingdom, and West Germany account for by far the greater part of
these imports, and they also take the greater part of imports of labor-
intensive manufactures from Japan and other low-wage countries.
Relative Size of Im~ports
A noteworthy feature of this trade is the small size of U.S. imports
of labor-intensive manufactures from the less developed countries in
relation to U.S. production of similar goods. The value of U.S. output
(or "value of shipments") in 1965 of the items selected as labor-
intensive was $138 billion. Imports of these items from all sources in
1965 were equal to only about 4.1 percent, and those from less de-
veloped countries only 0.7 percent, of that amount. These ratios were
particularly low for certain items which may be described as "mar-
ginally labor-intensive." Exclusive of these items, total imports were
about 4.2 percent, and import from the less developed countries about
1.1 percent, of domestic output. A similar comparison, if it could be
made, would probably yield a slightly higher ratio of imports from
the less developed countries to the domestic production of other de-
veloped countries considered as an entity, but with sharp contrasts
among the members of the group.
Looked at in relation to total imports of labor-intensive manufac-
tures, the share supplied by the less developed countries is much larger
in this country than in other developed countries-about 18 percent for
the United States in 1965 versus 6 percent for other developed coun-
tries taken as a whole, or 25.8 and 10.5 percent, respectively, exclusive
of the "marginal" items. This observation has to be set against the
much more limited role which imports in general play in the U.S.
economy than in most other countries. Even so, the ratios (again exclu-
sive of the marginal items) seem very small in most cases-between 3
and 8 percent in all of the smaller European countries and Canada.
In France, despite its longstanding economic ties with African coun-
tries and the tariff preferences extended to them, the 1965 ratio is only
12.3 percent, or slightly larger than in West Germany with 11.1 per-
cent and much less than in the United Kingdom with 19.2 percent.
As a final comparison, on the basis of the 1965 trade returns, labor-
intensive manufactures make up less than one-tenth of total imports
of the developed countries from less developed countries. Coffee, cocoa,
and tea alone bulk larger in the total, and crude petroleum 2.7 times
larger. Labor-intensive manufactures are less than half as large as
other products classed as "manufactures," the latter being more capital-
intensive and generally having an evident i~ atural-resoiirce orientation
(major examples being petroleum products and nonferrous metals).
Ti e only items of which the latter is not time `tre of negligible con
sequence iTi the trade.
PAGENO="0236"
228 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S.FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
It is noteworthy, however, that developed countries' imports of
labor-intensive manufactures from the less developed countries rose by
almost 11 percent from 1964 to 1965 in contrast to an increase of less
than 4 percent in all other products. This relative gain was achieved
despite the fact that the defensive balance-of-payments measures taken
by the United Kingdom toward the end of 1964 and, more particularly,
the tightening of restrictions on textiles seem to have fallen with spe-
cial severity on its imports of labor-intensive manufactures from some
of the Commonwealth countries. Developed countries other than the
United Kingdom raised their imports of labor-intensive manufactures
from less developed countries by 17.5 percent in 1965.
Product Composition of the Trade
Textiles, clothing, and accessories made up about one-third of
1965 imports of labor-intensive manufactures by developed from less-
developed countries. (If burlap and other coarse fiber products are
also counted in the textile group, the latter accounted for some 44
percent of the total.) The concentration of the trade by product is
therefore pronounced, but it is perhaps less extreme than sometimes
suggested by the attention given to textile imports from low-wage
countries. Comparison of the 1965 results with those for 1964 indicates,
moreover, that the concentration may be diminishing, the textile items
having increased by 10.4 percent compared with an overall increase
close to 27 percent by a wide assortment of miscellaneous light manu-
factures (excluding food items and industrial materials). Both figures
are strongly influenced by the British measures noted above. De-
veloped countries other than the United Kingdom increased their
imports of textiles, clothing, and accessories by about 25 percent and
those of miscellaneous light manufactures by 37 percent from 1964
to 1965. The corresponding increases for the United States alone were
34 and 44 percent, respectively.
Distribution by Importing Countries
Of total imports of labor-intensive manufactures by developed from
less-developed countries in 1965, the United States accounted for 41.4
percent. The United Kingdom was next with 17.6 percent, and West
Germany third with 12.7 percent. Together, these three countries took
almost 72 percent of the total. The United Kingdom's share had been
as high as 22 percent in 1964, but was reduced in 1965 with the ab-
solute decline in its imports from the less-developed countries, while
those of the United States and West Germany continued to rise.
Rapid increases are also found for several countries-Sweden, Aus-
tria, Japan, Australia, and New Zealand-whose imports are relatively
small. Others, including the European Common Market members ex-
cept West Germany, show small shares in total imports of labor-in-
tensive manufactures from the less-developed countries, small ratios
to their own imports of like products from all sources, and low rates of
increase.
There are considerable differences in the distribution of the main
product groups among importing countries. The share of the United
States is particularly high-more than half of the total-in the rapid-
growth miscellaneous light manufactures. The Common Market coun-
tries take a relatively large part-twice as much as the United States-
of the labor-intensive food products. The United States, the United
Kingdom, and West Germany account for three-quarters of total un-
PAGENO="0237"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 229
ports of textiles, clothing, and accessories from the less-developed coun-
tries. AU three show considerable variety in the product composi-
tion of their imports from the less-developed countries. The United
Kingdom's imports are, however, more concentrated Ofl Common-
wealth countries, which enjoy preferential entry to the British market,
than those of the United States and West Germany. The much smaller
total of French imports of labor-intensive manufacturers from the less-
developed countries is composed to the extent of two-thirds of food
products, leather, and lumber, chiefly from Africa. Japan's imports of
labor-intensive manufactures from the less-developed countries are
extraordinarily small by almost any standard. In these products
Japan's role vis-à-vis the less-developed countries is, at least for the
time being, far more that of a competitor than that of a customer.
Distribution by Exporting Countries
Hong Kong alone supplied 28 percent of total imports of labor-
intensive manufactures by developed from less-developed countries in
1965, outranking India and the whole of Latin America with less than
one-fifth each. The extraordinary role of Hong Kong is not sufficiently
indicated by the overall percentage just cited: Its share in labor-inten-
sive food products and industrial materials was negligible, reflecting its
lack of land and other natural resources, but it supplied half of the
textile group and more than half of miscellaneous light manufactures.
Other less-developed countries of the Far East brought the combined
share of that area to two-thirds of the total. Extraordinarily rapid
rates of increase from 1964 to 1965 were shown by severa.l of these
countries, notably South Korea and Taiwan. It may be noted that their
highest rates of increase were in miscellaneous light manufactures, and
this was generally true of the less-developed countries in other regions
as well.
No less remarkable than the vigor shown by the exports of some
of the small Far Eastern countries is the failure of some of the larger
less-developed countries, with an earlier beginning of industry, to
compete on a significant scale in the markets of the developed coun-
tries for labor-intensive manufactures. These countries include Argen-
tina, Brazil, Chile, Mexico, the Philippines, Egypt, Algeria, and
Morocco. With the exception of Brazil, whose exports in 1965 gave
some promise of renewed growth, these countries also failed to share
in the general rise in exports of labor-intensive manufactures from
the less-developed countries in 1965. Their participation is especially
weak in miscellaneous light manufactures, which include some of
the more rapidly growing items. Nor should it be supposed that the
minor role played by these countries as exporters of labor-intensive
manufactures to the developed countries is to be explained by a more
impressive performance in capital-intensive manufactures. Exports
of such manufactures by the less-developed countries, apart from
strongly resource-based products, are exceptional. Some of the excep-
tions are, however, of possible interest in the present connection. They
include $15,758,000 of iron and steel exported by Mexico to the United
States; $1,002,000 of tires and tubes exported by Israel to Western
European countries as well as smaller amounts from Morocco, India,
and the Philippines; $363,000 of trucks from Morocco to France; and
$90,000 of insulated wire and cable exported by Argentina to the
United States.
PAGENO="0238"
230 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S.FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
Past Growth, 1953-65
MARKET POTENTIALS
The rate of growth in imports of labor-intensive manufactures by
developed from less developed countries in recent years has probably
been much faster than had been expected. For instance, in a study
published in 1964, Bela Balassa projected an annual rate of increase
of 5.5 percent in exports of manufactures by less developed to devel-
oped countries over the period from 1960 to 1975, prices being as-
sumed to remain constant.7 By contrast, the total of the labor-inten-
sive items plotted in chart TI-i shows imports in 1965 41/3 times as
CHART 11-1
of countries reporting on a c.i.f. basis have been adjustod
t( an approxiwate f.o.h. basis.
Australia, Japan and Switzerland.
CbliLL Italy and ti'e Netharl suds.
dAustria Denmark, Norway and Sweden (Switzerland and Portugal not included).
~ Bela Balassa, "Trade Prospects for Developing Countries," Homewood, Ill., 1964, p. 66
and tables A3.1.1 and A12.
Imports of Labor-Intensive Manufactures by Developed from Less Developed
Countries, 1953-65 (current prices)
Mi
Ratio scale
1953 `55 `57 `59 `62 `64 `65
So: Corapiled from publications of U.N. Statistical Office.
PAGENO="0239"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 231
large as in 1953, an increase of about 13 percent per annum com-
pounded. This is at current prices, and the annual rate of increase
might be 1 or 2 percentage points less at constant prices.
In other words, the increase foreseen for 15 years was approxi-
mately realized in 5 years. As table Il-i shows, the strength of actual
performance in relation to the projections was pervasive, extending to
most product groups and geographic areas.
Structure of Wages in Less Developed Countries
One of the conditions for a continued rapid growth of the trade is
that the structure of wages in less developed countries not be such as
to nullify their comparative advantage in labor-intensive products.
A few years ago Lloyd Reynolds suggested that "interindustry wage
dispersion tends to reach a maximum some time during the early
stages of industrialization and to diminish gradually after that
point." 8 This is what one would expect under free-market conditions,
assuming that skills are relatively short and unskilled labor abundant
in newly developing countries, and that these disparities in supply are
gradually overcome.
Recently, however, a growing literature indicates that interferences
of one kind or another tend to narrow wage differentials between in-
dustries or occupations in many of the less developed countries and sO
to raise costs in their more labor-intensive manufacturing branches.
Frequently the stress is placed on labor unions as the main force un-
derlying the development of wages. Legal minimum wages may, how-
ever, be a more general and powerful influence on the level and struc-
ture of wages in less developed countries to a degree not matched in
more developed countries. An authoritative analysis in the organ of
the International Labour Office,9 in discussing changes in wage dif-
ferentials by skill in the less developed countries, attributes minimum-
wage policies to widespread disapproval of the wage levels of un-
skilled workers that would otherwise obtain. But he adds that "if
governments insist that unskilled wages should increase independ-
ently of the forces of demand for and supply of unskilled labor, there
is a likelihood that unskilled wages may increase faster than skilled
wages." The author then quotes an earlier article in the same review
(1959), finding "an extreme uniformity of wage rates in Brazil" at-
tributable to public intervention, particularly the minimum wage, and
cites other evidence of a tendency for the skilled-unskilled wage dif-
ferential to narrow in "many African countries" and "some Asian
countries." "This," he explains, "is because legal minimum wages are
relatively high in these countries and are raised from time to time
irrespective of the underlying conditions." 10
Several unfavorable economic consequences are associated with tend-
encies toward uniformity of wage rates irrespective of skills. One is
the discouragement of effort by workers to acquire higher skills.
Another is the inducement to entrepreneurs to adopt more capital-
intensive methods of production than they otherwise would or to save
on labor in other ways, thus inhibiting the growth of employment. A
8 L. G. Reynolds and C. H. Taft, The Evolution or Wage E,'tructure, New Haven, i956,
p. 356.
° "Wage Differentials in Developing Countries: A Survey of Findings," by Koji Taira,
International Labour Review, March 1966, pp. 281-301.
10P. 287.
PAGENO="0240"
TABLE 11-1.-IMPORTS OF MANUFACTURES BY DEVELOPED FROM LESS DEVELOPED COUNTRIES-IMPORTS IN 1960 AND 1965 AND BALASSA'S PROJECTIONS FOR 1975
[In millions of dollars]
Product group
Imports in 1960 (current prices)
Imports in 1965 (current prices)
Balassa's projections for 1975 (1960
(average of high and low)
All
developed
countries
North
America
Western
Europe
Japan
*
Oceania
All
developed
countries
North
America
Western
Europe
Japan
*
Oceania
All
developed
countries
North
America
Western
Europe
Japan
1. Chemicals
2. Leather and footwear
3. Veneer, plywood, wood and cork
nianufactures, and paper
4. Textile yarn, cotton fabrics, and
clothing
5. Jute manufactures
6. Floor coverings and other textile
products
7. Silver, precious stones, pearls,
and jewelry
I Machinery and metal manufac-
tures
9. Other manufactured goods
Total
119
81
50
316
175
102
94
42
96
54
14
25
145
103
39
28
20
53
59
64
23
151
34
59
64
21
37
5
2
1
2
2
20
37
3
5
267
132
140
622
279
217
277
252
284
109
36
97
285
192
65
95
117
173
131
90
39
297
46
142
161
103
89
22
5
2
3
20
24
10
5
3
38
42
7
2
12
227
154
268
658
217
246
291
132
253
CI)
CI)
CI)
0
0
Oceania
CI)
1 ~
3 i~
5~
~ /2
45
7 ~
4 0
3
14 ~..3
127 s.
0
0
100
36
179
281
121
79
88
62
138
111
106
84
332
50
156
190
66
97
15
10
4
9
4
1,075 481 512 12 70 2,470 1,169 1,103 87 111 2,446 1,084 1,192 43
PAGENO="0241"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF TJ.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 233
third effect of particular relevance here is the brake on the diversifica-
tion of exports: A country unable to compete abroad in capital-inten-
sive manufactures may also find itself priced out of the market in
more labor-intensive manufactures and thus forced to continue to rely
on exports of primary products.
These considerations may help to explain why it is that some of the
less developed countries, notably those with an earlier start on indus-
trialization, have fared so poorly in exporting manufactures and why,
in contrast, some others, particularly some of the countries of South-
east Asia, have made such rapid headway.
Possible Areas of Rapid Growth
At least for those less developed countries which do strengthen their
comparative advantage in labor-intensive manufactures, the very un-
evenness of the trade hitherto may provide a key to future growth sec-
tors. Imports from less developed countries of many light consumer
manufactures have scarcely scratched the surface of the market. This
certainly seems true of the United States on even a rough comparison
of domestic production and imports from the less developed countries.
There are, indeed, very few products of which total U.S. imports from
all sources make up a significant part of supply. It seems plausible to
expect that a growing, adaptable economy will absorb increasing
amounts of these miscellaneous consumer goods from the less developed
countries.
This may be true also of many other developed countries, in some
of which imports of consumer manufactures from the less developed
countries have scarcely begun to play a role. Restrictive import policies
and practices are doubtless one explanation. But perhaps also a learn-
ing period is required, and the experience gained by some of the less
developed countries in exporting to the larger and higher cost U.S.
market, and by those of the Commonwealth with their privileged
access to the British market, may now be applied to the conquest of
still other markets.
Some of the greatest opportunities for expansion may be offered
by marginally labor-intensive manufactures. The field of components
and parts for use in electronic products and perhaps also in machinery,
automobiles, and other transportation equipment seems particularly
interesting. American manufacturers of electronic goods have reached
out not only to Japan and Puerto Rico but also to Hong Kong,
Taiwan, and Korea for components or even complete products.
CHAPTER III. COMMERCIAL POLICIES OF DEVELOPED COUNTRIES
The assessment of market potentials concluding chapter II may be
too optimistic. How far the expansionary forces go depends heavily
on the commercial policies of the developed countries with regard to
imports of manufatures from less developed countries. It remains
therefore to consider in this regard both the tariff structures of the
developed countries and nontariff barriers which, in some cases, may
have a far more restrictive effect.
TARIFF STRUCTURES: NOMINAL VERSUS EFFECTIVE RATES
A standing complaint of less developed countries is that the import
tariffs of the developed countries tend to be graduated according to
stage of manufacture so as to bear lightly, if at all, on imports of
82-246-67-16
PAGENO="0242"
234 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF IJ.S.FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
raw materials for use in manufacture and to penalize imports of
processed or finished goods. To the extent that these influences pre-
vailed, many of the less developed countries would have to remain
hewers of wood and drawers of water.
Theoretical and empirical support for the view that the "escalated
tariff structures" of the advanced countries are "a potentially power-
ful inhibitor of economic growth in the underdeveloped countries"
has been developed by a number of distinguished economists. Their
analyses make the point that nominal tariffs may be quite different
from effective tariffs, the latter being related to value added by manu-
facture after taking account of duties paid on material inputs. When
the rates specified in the tariffs are graduated according to stage of
manufacture, the effective rates are higher, and frequently much
higher, than the nominal rates.
Suppose, for example, that an important consignment of cotton
cloth worth $500 is subject to an import duty of $100. Suppose further
that the same amount and quality of cloth produced at home would
require $240 of yarn which, if imported, would bear a duty of $30. In
this case the value added by weaving is $260, protected by a duty of
$70.11 The effective rate of duty, computed in relation to value added,
is therefore 26.9 percent as contrasted with the nominal rate of 20
percent.
Moreover, it may be more meaningful to relate the duty only to the
wage part of value added on the assumption that capital costs are not
likely to be lower, and may well be higher, in less developed than in
developed countries. On this basis, and assuming that payroll makes
up 60 percent of value added in the example chosen, the effective rate
of protection would be about 45 percent. This would be the amount by
which labor costs per unit of output in the importing country could
exceed those in the exporting~ country. The difference will be greater
still to the extent that capital costs, transportation charges, and other
costs work in favor of the importing country. (And, of course, the dif-
ference in earnings per worker will be much greater still when the
difference in productivity of labor is as large as it typically is between
lessdeveloped and developed countries.)
Table ITT-i drawn from a current study by Balassa, presents nomi-
nal tariff rates and estimates of the effective rates, on both of the bases
just described, for a number of intermediate products and finished
manufactures of interest in this study. These estimates necessarily in~
volve an element of approximation regarding input coefficients and
can perhaps best be regarded as illustrative rather than as precise
measurements. In most cases the effective rates are much higher than
nominal tariffs. The effective rates in Japan are in most instances
higher than in the United States or the Common Market. In the Unitéc?
Kingdom, the structure of protection is not very different from that of
other developed countries as far as tariff rates imposed on imports
from outside the Commonwealth are concerned. These rates are, how-
ever, of less relevance than those of other countries (and are accord-
ingly omitted from the table), since imports from the Commonwealth,
including such major suppliers as Hong Kong and India, are gen-
erally free of duty (though not necessarily free of other restraints,
as in cotton textiles and jute products).
~ It is relevant to the history of economic doctrine to note that this example is drawn
from a study of tariff protection and free trade published more thaa 60 years ago by the
Austrian economist and former Underscretary~ of State Richard Scbflhler.
PAGENO="0243"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
235
2
(N C~) C~C ~CC UC 00 ON (0 (0
= C~)
(/)
=
=
>-
()
=
=
C,)
C,)
C-)
=
Q
I->-
=1-
1!~
V
I- .2
-~ C_)___~
-~ .~!
~
.2 -~
~
*! ~E
.2
= (0cC
~0CO
-~ COO
~ E
I
5
~-(o.oO ~~;_;c,~ `u
C'C - - (N C') ON CC) ~ 00 ~ C') CN C') ON
E
c,ur-o ~
= C')
- ~ COON (CC .0(0 -(0000, (0(0 (C) - (0
-~
0
C
C
= =
C C
C-) C
(0 C
0
< 00)
-H01
~
~ 32 C~>~0
~
~ :2 2~2~
>~~` ;~-~g~
~ ~.2~E~222
~
Cu
t~
Cu
~
.2
~
~
~
~
.2 ~ 2
C-,
C,,
PAGENO="0244"
236 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S.FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
It is noteworthy that, though the U.S. tariff appears in general to
be no less graduated or escalated than those of other countries and is
sometimes held to be more so, the effect on the structure of its imports
seems to be much less marked than in some other developed countries,
especially some of the members of the Common Market and Japan.
One important reason is that the United States is itself a major pro-
ducer and exporter of some of the crude materials included in the
table, notably, cotton, cattle hides, and hardwoods. This alone would
tend to cause a higher ratio of manufactured to unmanufactured
imports than would be true of most other developed countries. The
same influence may affect the composition of imports by Canada,
Australia, and New Zealand.
Nevertheless, imports of finished manufactures from less-developed
countries by most countries of Western Continental Europe look very
small, and those of Japan altogether trivial, compared both with their
own imports of crude materials and intermediate products and with
imports of finished goods by the United States from less-developed
countries. Part of the explanation may be that, even if effective tariff
rates in the United States are the same as in Europe or Japan, they
may be less effective, in fact, in restricting imports of labor-intensive
goods, if wage costs per unit of output in manufacturing these goods
are higher here than in other developed countries.
NONTARIFF BARRIERS TO IMPORTS
There are, however, other more specific though sometimes less visible
hindrances to the growth of the trade than those presented by tariffs.
The most obvious, at least so far as they are reported, are quantitative
restrictions. After taking note of some further, but slow, progress in
removing these restrictions, a mid-1966 report by UNCTAD observes
that "the area of exports still affected is considerable and includes a
number of products of major export interest to developing countries."
The report then summarizes the position as follows: "Out of 63 Brus-
sels tariff nomenclature items of export interest to developing coun-
tries, quantitative restrictions on the following among them are still
maintained in the developed countries; namely France 56, Japan 24,
Federal Republic of Germany 21, Denmark 15, Norway 14, Austria 13,
Italy 10, United Kingdom 7, Switzerland 6, Sweden 3, United States 3,
Netherlands 2, Belgium-Luxembourg 2, Canada 1." 12
It is hard to judge the significance of these restrictions, since they
may be nominal in some cases and rigorously enforced in others. It is
even more difficult to judge the incidence and effect of other more
subtle hindrances, such as administrative redtape or collusion among
private producers and distributors within the developed countries, but
the absence of trade is sometimes difficult to explain otherwise.
Though it is difficult to separate from other influences noted, perhaps
something should be allowed for the view that competition is keener
in the U.S. market than in other developed countries, and that Amer-
ican entrepreneurs are more active in seeking out foreign sources of
supply.
12 United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, "Review of International Trade
and Development, 1966," summary of report by the Secretary-General, July 20, 1966
(TD/B/82), p. 15.
PAGENO="0245"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 237
Restraints on Imports of Cotton 7~extiles
The history of cotton textiles in recent years illustrates how the
very growth of trade can be its own undoing through provoking re-
st rictive measures by the importing countries. Following the swift
increase in imports of cotton textiles from India, Hong Kong, and
other Commonwealth sources in the 1950's,'3 the United Kingdom
made a series of bilateral agreements aimed at limiting the further
growth of the trade. The United States, after a rapid rise in imports
from some of these countries and from Japan, took the lead in
negotiating in 1961 a short-term and then, in 1962, a long-term inter-
national cotton textile "arrangement," under which it has made
numerous bilateral agreements for "voluntary restraints" by the ex-
porters. Continental European countries were happy to join in the
arrangement, with the blessing it confers on avoidance of "market
disruption," but for the greater part have continued to prove willing
and able to apply their own import restraints.
These restraints are sometimes more than meet the eye. rfhe director-
general of the GATT, in opening the major review called for in the
arrangement at the end of the third year, noted that all trade restric-
tions on cotton textiles are not fully notified by participating govern-
rnents and urged them to help lift the haze which still rests over this
subject.'4
Despite these open and hidden restrictions, imports of cotton textiles
by the developed countries from developing exporting countries have
increased relatively fast. Those of Western Continental European
countries doubled from about $50 million in 1961 to something over
$100 million in 1964. At that level, however, they still fell short of im-
ports from the same sources by the United Kingdom (around $170
million) and by the United States ($126 million), both of which had
risen substantially as well.
Apart from the United Kingdom, these increases have all been
from extremely low levels compared with home consumption-so low
in several of the `Western Continental European countries that even
their commitment to large percentage increases under the 5-year
arrangement was regarded by some of the exporting countries as
13 The rise in these imports is explained as follows by A. M. Alfred. the chief economist
for Courtaulds Ltd.. in a paper read at the Manchester Statistical Society on November
10, 1965 ("United Kingdom Textiles-A Growth Industry")
On the import side, you will know well that the United Kingdom textile Industry, par-
ticularly the cotton sector, has suffered from an unforeseen consequence of the Imperial
Preference Treaty negotiated at Ottawa in 1932. Under that treaty, It was agreed that
cotton and wool textiles and madeup goods could enter the United Kingdom duty free if
coming from the Commonwealth. At that time there was no textile activity of relevance in
India. Pakistan, or Hong Kong. In fact India (then undivided) Imported 550 million yards
of cloth from the United Kingdom, In 1964 the United Kingdom Imported 450 mIllion
square yards of cloth and madeup goods from India, Pakistan and Hong Kong-a reversal
of a billion yards. This large volume arose because of the channelling of these Common-
wealth exports Into the only country Into which they could come duty free.
After noting that these imports, together with Imports from other underdeveloped coun-
tries made up 35 percent of British consumption, compared with his estimates of 8 percent
for the United States and 9 percent for the European Common Market, Mr. Alfred went on
to speak of "the ridiculous state of affairs whereby the United Kingdom cotton industry Is
the only Industry In any developed country of the world to have zero protectIon against
a major aupplier."
While recognizing that the "market disruption" In the British textile Industry has been
far greater than in other developed countries, one cannot fall to detect in this account a
double standard frequently characteristic of attitudes In developed countries toward trade
with the less-developed countries: Free trade In textiles within the Commonwealth seemed
logical and desirable as long as the flow was from the United Kingdom outward, but ceased
to be so when the flow reversed (through the Initial Impact of British factory-produced
textiles on the Indian handicraft Industry In the 19th century had been no less disruptive
than that more recently experienced In the United Kingdom when the tide turned).
14 Press release GATT/946, Dec. 8, 1965.
PAGENO="0246"
238 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S.FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
bordering on fraud.'5 In his remarks quoted above opening the major
review of the arrangement, the director-general of the GATT ex-
pressed the hope that it had brought some semblance of order into
the trade through restraint actions, and that the parties to the arrange-
ment could begin to give effect to its long-term and positive aims,
including in particular expanded access to markets for the less
developed countries.
It remains to see how much emphasis will be given to these long-run
objectives during the further 3-year period, starting October 1, 1967,
for which the cotton textile arrangement has been extended. At least
as far as the United States is concerned, government officials report-
ing to business groups on the renewal of the arrangement have stressed
rather the objective of avoiding market disruption, the expectation
that the rapid growth of U.S. imports of cotton textiles would be
greatly slowed down, the intention of acting to regulate imports from
new supplies, and continued close cooperation with the industry
through the Management-Labor Textile Advisory Committee. 16 Iii
connection with the extension of the arrangement, stress has also
been placed on the limited extent of the tariff cuts on textiles made by
the United States and other developed countries in the Kennedy
Round. 17
THE PROBLEM OF INCREASED ACCESS TO MARKETS
The issue of preferences
The first condition for a continued rapid growth of exports of
manufactures by the less developed countries to the advanced countries
would seem to be greater accessibility to these markets. Greater accessi-
bility would mean the scaling down of the tariff rates of developed
countries, particularly the effective rates, on goods of which the less
developed countries are actual or potential suppliers; the progressive
loosening of quantitative restrictions, both those imposed by the im-
porting countries and the voluntary restraints exercised by the export-
ing countries; and the identification and removal of other, less obvious
impediments to imports. More broadly, greater accessibility would
mean recognition that international specialization has a place for
the products in which the less developed countries have a comparative
advantage, and that this place will widen and deepen as the rise in
productivity and wages in the developed countries produces divergent
effects on unit wage costs in different industries.
The great debate in recent years on commercial policies affecting
the less developed countries, culminating at the United Nations Con-
ference on Trade and Development in 1964 and still continuing, has
turned increasingly on the issue of tariff preferences; that is, whether
the enlargement of market opportunities for the less developed coun-
tries should be sought within the most-favored-nation framework
embodied in the GATT, whereby the concessions made would be gen-
~ Gardner Patterson, "Discrimination In International Trade: The Policy Issues, 1945-
65." Princeton, 1966, p. 311.
1~ See especially the address by Stanley Neh:mer, Deputy Assistant Secretary of Com-
merce for Resources, before the Underwear Institute in Atlantic City on May 9, 1967.
17 "Because of the import sensitivity of textiles in general here and abroad, the cuts made
by the United States and other major importing countries, average less than 25 percent and
much less than that on the more sensitive product areas such as woolen and manmade
textiles Many textile products were evcluded altogether (quoted from address by the
then Acting Secretary of Commerce. Alexander B. Trowbridge, at the Alabama Interna-
tional Business Forum, Tuscaloosa, May 17, 1967).
PAGENO="0247"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 239
eralized and extended also to developed countries, or whether the less
developed countries should be accorded preferential treatment in rec-
ognition of their difficulties in competing with the developed coun-
tries. Rightly or wrongly, the less developed countries seem to have
become convinced that only a system of preferences would meet their
needs, though they differ among themselves, as well as with the devel-
oped countries, as to what the terms of the preferences should be. The
United States, adhering to the principle of nondiscrimination, has
been in the invidious position of leading the opposition to these de-
mands, sometimes to the point of seeming to be the only voice, in
opposition. Harry G. Johnson, though severely critical of the negative
stance of the United States and of its failure to develop a more positive
and imaginative policy, suggests that, to an important extent, the
United States served as a scapegoat for other countries, especially
the European Common Market countries, which avoided comiuitment
by abstaining from voting while the United States carried the burden
of resistance.17a
After the vast exceptions to the most-favored-nation principle con-
stituted by the European Economic Community and the European
Free Trade Area, the idea of tariff preferences to favor the less de-
veloped countries may appear to be a modest objective. It seems to
accord ill, however, with the realities of the present trading situation
in which, as the director-general of GATT has observed, "the tendency
is, in the sectors where the less developed countries are already com-
petitive, for the developed countries to discriminate against the export
products of these countries.'8 Unless the developed countries are ready
to forgo those features of their commercial policies which seem to fall
with particular severity on exports of the less developed countries,
what expectation can there be of shifting all the way over to discrimi-
nation in their favor?
The heart of the difficulty, as far as exports of labor-intensive manu-
factures by the less developed countries are concerned, is that these
products tend to compete with those sectors in the developed countries
which are frequently the least prosperous and the most successful in
obtaining protection against imports. The problem is illustrated by
one of the provisions of the U.S. Trade Expansion Act of 1962;
namely, that authorizing the President to negotiate tariffs down to
zero on groups of industrial products of which the United States and
the European Common Market together accounted for 80 percent or
more of world exports. This formula reflected an erroneous expectation
that the United Kingdom was about to become a member of the Com-
mon Market (without which the 80-percent level would be realized
only exceptionally). But it also had the important effect of excluding
products, notably textiles, of which Japan and the less developed
countries were significant exporters. In other words, the United States
was prepared to consider reducing tariffs by as much as 100 percent
on products which, as President Kennedy said, "can be produced here
or in Europe more efficiently than anywhere else in the world," 19
but only by half as much in principle (perhaps a good deal less in
17a "Economic Policies Toward Less Developed Countries," Washington, 1967, especially
p. 39~.
18 Address In Bad Godesberg, Germany. Oct. 27. 19~6.
~° See "Department of State Bulletin," Feb. 12, i962~, p. 236.
PAGENO="0248"
240 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S.FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
practice) on products in which Japan and the less developed coun-
tries were most competitive. This, however, is only a specific illustra-
tion of the general tendency of TJ.S. tariffs to bear more heavily on
labor-intensive manufactures than on other goods. It raises the ques-
tion whether, even if the most-favored-nation rule is rigorously re-
spected, unequal tariff treatment of different products may not be
tantamount to unequal treatment of different countries.
The Prebisch Pro posals
Awareness of these difficulties led Hai~tl Prebisch, in his advance
message as secretary~general to TJNCTAD in 1964, to envisage some-
thing less than a fully generalized system of preferences.2° As he saw
it, developed countries could not be expected to give preferential treat-
ment to those industries in the less developed countries that were al-
ready fully competitive in world markets, and each country granting
preferences might therefore establish a reserve list of such products to
be excluded from preferences (but not, he stressed, from most-favored-
nation treatment under GATT). Prebisch's case for preferences was,
as he said, "a logical extension of the infant industry argument" aimed
at enabling the less developed countries to become competitive in
manufactures that they could not now export. Both the duration of
the preferences (a minimum of 10 years was suggested) and the mar-
gin of preference should be great enough to provide adequate incen-
tive for the establishment of new export industries.
Prebisch considered it desirable, but not indispensible, that all de-
veloped countries participate in granting preferences. He hoped that
they would avoid the crippling complexities of a highly selective
country-byproduct approach, but recognized that they might insist on
an overall quota, and possibly quotas on particular categories, govern-
ing the amount of goods to be imported preferentially.
As to the preference-receiving countries, Prebisch recogn1zed that
it would not be easy to set any kind of cutoff point above which coun-
tries would not be eligible. Among those which were eligible, he felt
it necessary to distinguish between the "more advanced" and the "less
developed" among thern, suggesting for the latter wider margins of
preference. This might be reinforced by a special grant of quotas in
their behalf and perhaps even by preferential tariff treatment on items
which the developed countries had reserved from general preferences.
Austra7ian Preference System
Despite vigorous efforts by the less developed countries at TJNCTAD
for a declaration of principle in favor of preferences, all that emerged
in the final act of the 1964 conference was a decision to set up a com-
mittee to consider the best method of implementing such a system and
to discuss differences of views on the question of principle. The topic
seems destined to figure even more prominently in the debates of the
second conference scheduled for 1968. Meanwhile, the only specific
action by way of preferences favoring imports from the less developed
countries is that taken by Australia under a waiver from the most-
favored-nation rule approved by GATT in March 1966. Though
stanchly defended by Australia as a manifestation of its willingness to
20 "Proceedings of the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development," vol. II,
policy statements, 1q64, pp. 35-40.
PAGENO="0249"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 241
help overcome the trade problems of the less developed countries and
as a lead to other developed countries wishing to apply similar meth-
ods, the Australian preferential system may also be taken as indicative
of the limitations and problems in this approach. Its main features
may be summed up as follows from materials made public at the time
of requesting the waiver from GATT: 21
1. Preferential duties, zero in some cases, were to be introduced in favor of
the less developed countries, comprehensively defined, on some sixty items.
2. Each such concession was, however, subject to a quota limit, above which
regular duties would apply to imports from less developed countries.
3. These quotas added up to a total of £A6,680,000, or about $15,000,000, repre-
senting in principle the amount of goods that might enter in a year's time on
a preferential basis.
4. More than 40 percent of this total was made up of items which, it would
seem, were unlikely to provide the basis for any new export industries in less
developed countries, at least in the near future. These included, in particular,
newsprint, £A2,000,000; machinemade paper CA500,000; rubber thread, vulcanized,
~A100,O00; household washing machines, EA150,000; machine tools ~A150,000.
5. Other, generally more likely, items thus added up to £A3,780,000, or about
$8,500,000 in terms of amounts eligible for preferential treatment, made up
chiefly of consumer manufactures.
0. More generally, it was indicated that the list was drawn up so as to omit
"products in which less developed countries are already competitive in world
markets," and that "the preferential rates should be subject to modification as
producers in less developed countries become competitive."
7. On the other hand, it was also indicated that the items specified constituted
an "initial list" and that other products might be added from time to time.
Unless the Australian list were to be significantly expanded, it could
scarcely be said to open up major new export possibilities for the less
developed countries or to provide a challenging example for other
developed countries to follow. Indeed, the positive effect of Australia's
action was at least partially offset by another step taken at the same
time whereby it informed GATT that, in accepting the new part IV
on trade and development, it would not consider itself bound by the
provisions under which the developed countries undertook "to accord
high priority to the reduction and elimination of tariff and nontariff
barriers to products of actual or potential export interest to less devel-
oped countries" and "to refrain from increasing tariff and nontariff
barriers against such products." 22
The "Brasseur Plan"
Except for the exclusion of Hong Kong from the benefits on certain
items, the Australian preferences are available to all less developed
countries, broadly defined. In this respect the Australian system ap-
pears to be more generous than the "Brasseur plan," with which it has
been compared, would be. This plan, named after the Belgian Minister
of Foreign Trade and Technical Assistance who made the proposals
to GATT in 1963, would entail negotiations with individual less
developed countries to determine in each case the products to be
covered, the margin and duration of preference, and the quantities
eligible to benefit. If the plan were seriously looked upon as applying
to most bilateral relationships between developed and less developed
countries and to most items of interest in the trade, the amount of
negotiation and specification required would be astronomical. Patterson
21 From statement and accompanying exhibits submitted by the Rt. Hon. J. MeEwen.
Deputy Prime Minister and Minister for Trade and Industry, to the Australian House of
Representatives on May 19, 1965.
22 From Mr. McEwen's statement of May 19, 1965.
PAGENO="0250"
242 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S.FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
suggests, however, that "this approach had the great virtue to some
members of the European Economic Community that it would
facilitate their safeguarding the value of the existing preferences to
each other and, more important, to the Associated States." 23 It is not
clear how valuable these latter preferences are, in fact, to the Associ-
ated States-i.e., the former African dependencies of France and Bel-
gium-in view of the extremely low level of their exports of manu-
factures to the former mother countries or other members of the
European Economic Community.
Diverse Policies and Common Objectives
The effectiveness of tariff preferences in opening new markets for
the less developed countries cannot be judged in the abstract, but de-
pends on the terms of the preferences in each case. The measures
adopted in Australia and those contemplated under the Brasseur plan
are not reassuring, however, if taken as a foretaste of the kind of
preferential concessions to be expected. Rather, they give point to
Prebisch's warning that "it would not be worth facing all the political
and other difficulties entailed in a new departure from the most-
favored-nation principle simply for the sake of token margins of
preference on a few selected products for a very limited period,
amounting to little more in toto than a gesture in the face of the im-
mense problems of the trade gap." 24 He might have added that, the
more selective preferences are by beneficiaries, the more fragmented
is the bargaining power of the less developed countries and the greater
their economic dependence becomes on particular developed countries.
It is equally true that the gains to be achieved by the less developed
countries through the most-favored-nation approach cannot be judged
in the abstract. In principle, their bargaining position for obtaining
meaningful concessions from the developed countries is strengthened
by three considerations. First, the developed countries have, as noted,
pledged themselves in GATT as well as at UNCTAD to give "high
priority" to the reduction of both tariff and nontariff barriers to the
exports of the less developed countries. Second, the need of the less
developed countries to increase exports to cover their growing import
requirements is widely recognized. Third, the gains from trade between
countries with wide differences in factor endowments should be partic-
ularly large to both sides.
In fact, however, the Kennedy Round of G-ATT negotiations seems
to have been regarded by the developed countries as primarily con-
cerned with trade relations among themselves, with only incidental
benefits to others, and it is by no means clear what will follow to give
effect to their commitments to the less developed countries. As far as
the United States is concerned, the tariff-cutting authority vested in
the executive branch by the Trade Expansion Act of 1962 does not
extend beyond mid-1967, and proposals for a new trade program re-
main to be formulated and approved. In the European Economic
Community there seems -to be an increasing tendency to look on the
common external tariff as a condition for internal unification. while
the, TTnited Kingdom appears to be mainly concerned with ioining the
EEC and nerhaps more inclined to reduce than to increase its imports
from less developed countries.
23 flisernnination ~n Intern `itwnaT Trade n ~Ui1
~ Proceedings of the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, vol. II,
Policy Statements, p. 38.
PAGENO="0251"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 243
Under these conditions, it may be difficult to develop and carry out
a common program of action by developed countries to remove barriers
to imports of manufactures from less developed countries, whether by
the preferential route or by the most-favored-nation approach. The
United States and other countries wishing to provide enlarged trade
opportunities to the less developed countries may therefore be faced
with the difficult choice, noted by Harry Johnson, 25 between (1)
unilaterally reducing tariffs on items of interest to these countries
without insisting on reciprocal concessions by developed countries
benefitting under the most-favored-nation principle, or (2) abandon-
ing that principle and granting concessions to the less developed coun-
tries only, or to some of them, on a preferential basis compared with
the tariff treatment accorded imports from developed countries. The
United States would thus have to abandon one of two basic princi-
ples-either that of reciprocity or that of nondiscrimination.
Whatever the answer to this last. qlie.stion,2e it seems likely that,
viewed as a whole, the trade policies of the developed countries vis-à-
vis the less developed countries will continue to be a mixed bag-equal
treatment in some sectors and areas and unequal treatment in others,
measures to expand trade along with restraints, declarations of good
intentions followed by good, bad, and indifferent results. One of the
weaknesses of the selective preferential approach in particular is that
it lends itself to illusions, by both preference-giving and preference-
receiving countries, as to how much has been accomplished. A great
amount of paperwork may yield very little trade.
In the face of this prospective diversity and uncertainty, the ques-
tion arises whether it would be useful to try to make sure that the
policies pursued by the developed countries, whatever their form in
each case, were consistent with the results aimed at, which would in-
volve quantifying these aims with regard to the levels and rates of in-
crease contemplated for the trade. It may be recalled that Prebisch
broached such an idea in his advance report to the United Nations Con-
ference on Trade and Development in 1964, though it was only briefly
considered, with little support, at that meeting; that is, that targets be
set for developed countries, collectively and individually, with re-
spect to their imports of manufactures from less developed countries.
Possible disadvantages of such a course are immediately obvious. If
the targets were set too low in relation to the potentialities of the
trade, they would be more of a hindrance than a help to its develop-
ment. If they were set too high, achievement of the targets could
present serious embarrassment to private enterprise economies.
~` "Economic Policies Toward Less Developed Countries," pp. 41 and 239.
~ An indication that the United States was willing to consider some modification of its
position against trade preferences was given In President Johnson's statement at Punta del
Este in April 1967 "We are ready to explore with other Industrialized countries-and with
our own people-the possibility of temporary preferential tariff advantages for all devel-
oping countries In the markets of all the Industrialized countries." (See "Department of
State Bulletin," May S, 1967, p. 709.1
The likelihood of a more specific and immediate step, agreed on with other countries, was
indicated in the statement Issued on May 15, 1967, by the director-general of GATT in sum-
ming up the results of the Kennedy Round. Noting that the tariff reductions agreed on in
the negotiations would, in general, be phased over a period of years, he said that the par-
ticipants had, however, "recognized that, for the developing countries, the Immediate Im-
plementation of such tariff cuts would be of great value in maximizing the benefits to them
of these negotiations." He further stated that efforts to achieve the advance application
of the cuts to imports from the developing countries would continue, and that a decision
on this point was expected to be reached by the time that the agreement embodying the
results of the Kennedy Round was ready for signature. GATT press release, May 17, 1967
(GATT 1990).
PAGENO="0252"
244 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S.FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
Such problems may, however, be more theoretical than real in the
present instance. Reasons have been given in chapter II for believing
that the forces underlying the rapid growth of the trade from the early
1950's to the mid-1960's may become progressively stronger. If that
view is correct, it would probably not be too much to suggest that, by
1975, the trade will again have grown fourfold, or more to something
like $10 billion (at present prices). Higher figures could be envisaged
if the enlargement of market opportunities extended to all of the de-
veloped countries, including those that so far have lagged behind.
Fulfillment of targets by the developed countries in these conditions
would not be a matter of creating artificial inducements but of re-
moving artificial impediments to the trade. Some developed countries
might elect to do so by reducing import barriers over the whole range
of products of interest t~o less developed countries and to do so on a
most-favored-nation basis. Some others might choo~e to proceed much
more selectively with respect to both the products and the countries
benefiting by the concessions. Whatever the method, a set of agreed
targets should help to give a common purpose and meaningful con-
tent to their actions.
It would doubtless require a good deal of study and negotiations
to obtain agreement on a global target for imports of manufactures
from the less developed countries that would be both consistent with
their growing foreign exchange needs and acceptable to the devel-
oped countries. Arriving at an agreed basis for distributing a global
target among individual importing countries could well prove even
more difficult.27 If agreement were impossible on such an allocation,
or even on a global target, the effort should at least serve to direct
thinking about commercial policies affecting less developed countries
toward results as well as methods and to make it more difficult to
generate schemes lacking in effective content.
It would no doubt be more difficult-but also more questionable-
to divide up a global import target among individual exporting coun-
tries. Too much depends on their own economic situations and policies
in each case. The Prebisch proposal on preferences calling for grada-
tion of preferential margins among the less developed countries im-
plies that the ability to export manufactures is positively correlated
with their stage of economic development. This must be true in some
sense, if one thinks of potential exports. But the analysis offered here
has also revealed that, typically, the "more advanced" of the less
developed countries, including some that have had preferential access
to certain developed countries' markets, have not done well as ex-
porters of manufactures to developed countries. If, as this experience
suggests, the basic difficulty~ lies in their own economic situations and
policies, it would be of little advantage to them, and an unnecessary
limitation on other less developed countries' possibilities, to reserve for
them specified shares in a global import target. Even in such cases,
however, a more receptive attitude by developed countries toward im-
ports from less developed countries would help to clarify the issues
and to encourage policies in the less developed countries conducive to
the growth of their exports.
Prebisch suggested that the total might be divided up (1) according to each importing
country's consumption of manufactures or (2) according to its share in total imports of
manufactures from all sources. The first criterion, however, would tend to overstate, and
the second to understate, import objectives for large countries with diversified economies
and less dependent on imports than small countries with more specialized economies.
Prebisch concluded that a combination of the two criteria might yield a formula acceptable
to all developed countries (p. 38 of vol. II of the conference proceedings).
PAGENO="0253"
EAST-WEST TRADE: DILEMMA OR 1)ELTJSION?
BY KENNETH R. HANSEN
"A little of both" would be the way to characterize this uniquely
U.S. issue today. On the one hand, there is a virtual standoff in policy
attitudes between the administration and the Congress; on the other,
there are exaggerated fears of harm and hopes of gain regarding any
significant change in U.S. trade policy toward Eastern Europe.
Overshadowing this issue today as it has in the past is a cloud of
self-righteous rhetoric, dire prophesy, and congressional timorousness
which too often obscures the boundaries of our legitimate national
interest and immobilizes U.S. official, business, and cultural forces
which might otherwise be exploring the extent of cost and oppor-
tunity which this area holds for the United States in the 1970's.
Paradoxically, although we have persisted in following a highly
restrictive trade policy with the Communist sphere for over 20 years,
we are not at all sure of the costs and benefits of our prolonged period
of self-imposed abstinence from this trade.
Ironically, we know we have paid a high price in increased isolation
from and friction with our Western Allies by obdurately pursuing
an increasingly divergent trade policy with Communist areas.
Tragically, we are only lately coming to realize that we might
achieve affirmative and peaceful purposes by seeking and granting
trade opportunity rather than yielding this field of traditional Amer-
ican excellence because of apprehension of unequal benefit or one-
sided exploitation by Communist trading states.
Providentially, we now appear to stand on the threshold of change
in East~WTest trade policy.
This paper is intended to probe provocatively but constructively
this congested artery of U.S. vital interest in the hope that our East-
West trade policy paralysis will yield somewhat to the prophylaxis
of plain speaking and while it is not always useful to recount the par-
tially remembered past for fear of redundancy, the overhang of some
past attitudes and actions so strongly biases future decision in this
area that some retrospective analysis seems merited. To a consider-
able degree, U.S. East-West trade policy and legislation must be freed
of past misconceptions and misconceptions of the past before actions
in this field may contribute to our national purposes and objectives
of the future.
* Mr. Hansen, currently vice president for planning of Syntex Corp., was pre-
viously Assistant Director of the Budget, 1961-04, with the Center for Interna-
tional Affairs, Harvard University, and spent many years in East-West trade
work in the United States and abroad during the Marshall plan and subsequently
during the Korean war period. The views expressed in this paper are the author's
only.
245
PAGENO="0254"
246 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S.FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
I. THE HERITAGE OF THE PAST
PEARL HARBOR~ THE COLD WAR, AND M~CARTHY REVISITED
No field of contemporary national policy carries a heavier burden of
colorful, controversial, or connotative public utterance tending to co-
erce attitude and judgment than U.S. East-West trade policy: Scrap
iron to Japan, trading with the enemy, strategic commodities, war ma-
terial, Communist trade, slave labor goods, and Soviet dumping.
From the first overt legislative reference to East-West trade in the
act of Congress authorizing the Marshall plan in the 1948-49 period,
up to-but not including-the present debate on the East-West Trade
Regulations Act of 1966, our official policies, private actions, and pub-
lic dialogs have been dominated by the emotional reactions and appar-
ent moral connotations of the seemingly perpetual state of East-West
tension, hostility, and struggle. As a result there has been little am-
biguity of public opinion in the United States during the past 20 years
on this issue. And as the cold war has waxed and waned, to be suc-
ceeded by Korea, Cuba, and Vietnam in the roster of direct U.S.-
Communist confrontations, the public posture of the United States has
been steadfastly in opposition to "traffic with the enemy." For most of
the period since World War II, therefore, there has existed in the
United States a simple two-valued orientation: the Communist bloc
was hostile to the West; therefore, trade with the East was at the least
unwise-and at worst, treasonable or suicidal.
And, for much of the period, the general thrust of this attitude was
justified. Although in many instances public attitudes were exploited
and public and press sensationalism and congressional demagoguery
were the overreactive concomitants to the more selective and re-
strained executive actions, diplomatic endeavors, and congressional
mandates governing our relations with other c.oiintri es, it was a fact.
that Soviet bloc trade policy in the post-World War II period consti-
tuted a significant threat to the security of the Atlantic community and
other free world countries.
THE 1946-49 PERIOD: THE COLD WAR FREEZE
East-West trade controls, therefore, originated as an aspect of the
cold war and have retained for the United States the form and spirit
engendered by those times.
A vignette of that period shows the vengeful and illogical industrial
dismantling of East Germany and the Soviet zone of Austria by the
Soviet armies, partial looting along with poltical subjugation of parts
of Eastern Europe, and the emergence of Communist attempts to pene-
trate the war-weakened West-European political and economic struc-
tures. This dynamic period saw the hardening of East-West distrust
and the discord of wartime allied interests. East to West and then West
to East, trade and economic intercourse slowly rebuilding in the wake
of war was disrupted and most of that interrupted by the war was not
actively resumed. In addition, extensive and worldwide networks of
Soviet, agents, black-marketeers, and international adventurers en-
gaged in all manner of illicit dealings in so-called strategic trade items
from West to East.
PAGENO="0255"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 247
Systematic attempts were made a.nd often thwarted-to ship stra-
tegic and short supply items from `Western Europe to the Soviet and
satellite economies. As a consequence, the press was liberally festooned
with disclosures of allegedly enormous illegal trade in precision in-
struments, ball bearings, critical and precious metals, prototype and
production machine tools, and other items deemed strategic in nature.
In countermeasure, West-East trade control programs were formu-
lated-initially by individual countries, a.nd later by the soon-to-
be-designated NATO countries in the Coordinating Committee
(COCOM). First-to place embargoes and quantitative controls on
items deemed strategic, and then to strengthen defense against illicit
trade in the form of transshipping, mislabeling, smuggling, false
invoicing, and other devices.
As these Western trade control programs evolved, they became in-
creasingly militant and far reaching. The proposal and adoption of
restrictive measures were virtually unanimous among the Western
allies and Japan. It was in the spirit of the times-the NATO buildup,
the Greek Communist insurgency, the Berlin blockade, the Italian
and French Communist election crises. East-West restrictive trade
policy developed as a measure of resistance to Stalinist aggression and
the strategic control program evolved to become an active element of
the containment strategy.
In these circumstances, the definition of strategic materials did not
constitute a difficult task; there was a presumption that most industrial
items for which there was demonstrated demand by the Soviets were
ipso facto of some strategic imporLance. Similarly, any large quantities
of metals, minerals, or scarce commodities were considered to be of
value to a war machine poised for potential aggression. And finally,
even so-called peaceful goods such as textiles or consumer goods or
agricultural products which might conceivably free up manpower
for the military, or permit reallocation of key resources elsewhere
were popularly viewed as contributing to the warmaking capability
of a potential enemy-the so-called fungibility principle.
It is of major relevance that this combined selective and complete
embargo policy was compatible with other strategic circumstances
of the times a~s well: East-West trade was being conscientiously
throttled by a Stalinist drive for European Communist bloc political
and economic hegemony, and Western Europe was going through a
tremendous effort at economic reconstruction which served to place a
comparable scarcity value on the so-called primary strategic industrial
goods.
Thus, born of necessity and consonant with political policies and
economic circumstances, contrQls on trade with Eastern Europe and
Communist China were both a talisman and an instrument of Western
unity in the face of Communist hostility and aggression.
THE BIRTH OF CONGRESSIONAL "OVERKILL~'
There emerged in this initial period several other concepts, how-
ever, which achieved unwarranted currency in thought and action in
the `United States, and subsequently contributed to friction and dis-
unity among the Western countries. One of these was the rather crude
device embodied in `U.S. legislation of indicating to Marshall plan
and other IJ.S.-aid-recipient countries that if they didn't refrain from
PAGENO="0256"
248 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S.FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
trade in "strategic" materials with the Sino-Soviet bloc, all U.S. mili-
tary and economic assistance would be cut off to them. The list of
strategic items, moreover, was to be determined arbitrarily by the
United States, and (until executive branch protestations prevailed)
action to cut off aid was intended by the congressional authors and
supporters of the legislation to be automatic and irrevocable. After
bitter battles over the so-called Kern amendment to the pending for-
eign aid legislation-there was a compromise whereby action to dis-
continue aid must be taken in the case of shipment of designated
atomic energy and military items (arms, ammunition, and implements
of war)-but aid could be reinstated if the President deemed that the
offending nation would thereafter comply with the embargo. Or if
the items were of a "primary strategic nature" the President could
continue aid if he determined that the discontinuance of aid "would
clearly be detrimental to the security of the United States." 1 These
provisions remain in controlling legislation up to the present day-
but attempts to remove or diminish Presidential discretion have been
numerous in the troubled years of this program up to the present.
In many sectors of U.S. public and congressional opinion, the West-
ern European countries trading modestly in this period with the Euro-
pean bloc and Communist China, were variously held to be profiteers,
ingrates, or foolishly insensitive to the threats of the worldwide Com-
munist conspiracy. Particular criticism was leveled against the
British-heightened because of their additional involvemnet in East-
West trade through their extensive worldwide shipping-and against
the West Germans, considered to be hedging their bets against possi-
Me Communist takeover of Central Europe. Considerable apprehen-
sion was volubly expressed concerning the alleged hunger of the
Japanese for a trade rapprochement with the vast potential market
of Communist China. And as major potential East-West trade ex-
changes of a compensation transaction and barter nature were bandied
about in the international press-considerable anxiety was felt re-
garding possible overdependency of this or that Western country on
the Soviet bloc as a source of supply or as a market. There was, in
short, an atmosphere of suspicion on the East-West trade issue be-
tween the United States and the European countries * * * and this
was conclusively embodied in U.S. legislation from the very outset.
A third aspect of congressional oversight-which happily has not
persisted to the present day-related to the administrators of the
trade control programs themselves. At a very early period, the eco-
nomic warners of the United States were sometimes extolled as
sterling characters who ingeniously thwarted the devious designs of
the Soviets and exposed their worldwide machinations. At a later
period-especially during the reign of terror of Senator Joseph
McCarthy-many of these same people became suspect security
threats or alleged fellow travelers or Communist dupes if they (or
the administration) showed any possible weakness in fervor and effec-
tiveness, or took a policy stand on East-West trade other than of un-
compromising opposition. These circumstances doubtlessly had some
influence on the persistent rigidity of policies in this field up to the
present time.
Defense Assistance Control Act 1951-title I (Battle Act).
PAGENO="0257"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 249
THE 1950-57 PERIOD: THE GROWING DIFFERENTIAL IN CONTROLS
This period-ushered in by the Korean conflict-initially saw a high
level of control, and a reasonably high degree of agreement between
the allies regarding the necessity and value of trade controls.
It was during these years, too, that controls over free world ship-
ping-especially that engaged in the China trade-became a major
element in U.S. international trade relations. "Flag of convenience,"
neutral country and long-term allied ship charter to Sovbloc nations
and Communist China became the target of U.S. diplomatic pressure.
IDuring the Korean conflict these problems became especially acute
and, in general, U.S. efforts were successful in stemming the involve-
ment of free country shipping in intrabloc trade. Little impact, how-
ever, was made on western shipping engaged in carriage of so-called
"peaceful" goods to Communist China and this led to unilateral U.S.
measures such as bunkering controls, denial of use of U.S. ports and
blacklisting of vessel fleets of a common owner from participation in
U.S. Government financed cargoes-especially foreign aid.
These latter types of restrictive measures were short lived and
largely related to the Korean struggle. In most respects they were
psychological in their intent and impact; they had relatively little
effect on intrabloc goods movements. Nevertheless, they were con-
sidered an appropriate adjunct to the military measures being under-
taken in Korea in response to Communist aggression (a similar situa-
tion to that of North Vietnam today). It is noteworthy, however, that
even in the wa.rtime circumstances of those days there was western
unanimity only as it related to denying Communist China strategic
materials and war materials on a longer list than that multilaterally
agreed for denial to the Sovbloc in Europe. No other major trading
nations have followed the U.S. policy of virtually complete trade and
financial embargo of Communist China which still exists in full force
today because of the persistence of Chinese hostility, vituperation and
aggression.
As noted earlier, this period was further marked by the traumatic
effect of McCarthyism on U.S. foreign affairs-initially related to
China trade and later more broadly addressed to terrorizing the U.S.
political countryside. This was widely held by the Europeans to have
contributed to a "freezing" of the U.S. position on East-West trade
controls, and immediately following the Korean war there was soon
evidence of a deep and growing official difference of outlook between
the United States and the Western European countries and Japan
regarding the necessity, utility or relative effectiveness of controls on
trade with the Eastern European countries and the U.S.S.R. The fact
that this was coupled at the time with Soviet blandishments of large
purchase orders and seemingly tempting markets made for even
greater strain. And in 1953-54 the Europeans-led by the United
Kingdom and France-literally forced a severe retrenchment in the
scope and severity of agreed multilateral controls on trade with the
European Soviet bloc. In effect, they challenged the purpose and scope
of the embargoes and asserted the potential positive value of expanded
trade in nonstrategic goods. And this "trade policy gap" which devel-
oped between the United States and Western Europe was soon broad-
ened into a "strategic controls gap" since formal U.S. unilateral con-
trols still extended far beyond the diminishing multilateral level-
52-246-07----17
PAGENO="0258"
250 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S.FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
heralding the polarity of other East-West political objectives and
approaches yet to come. In this connection it is important to note that,
whereas the action taken was to decontrol various so-called strategic
items, the assertion by the NATO countries and Japan 2 was that it
was important to liberalize trade as an instrument of positive policy
in dealing with the Soviet bloc in the post-Stalin period.
l957-6~: TIlE GROWING DIFFERENTIAL IN CONCEPT AND PRACTICE
Strategic Trade
`The trade control gap between the United States and `CoCom coun-
tries became wider throughout this long period. `The differential level
of multilateral controls regarding trade with `Communist China `and
North Korea was rescinded in the multilateral strategic control pro-
gram in July of 1957 although the United States, as noted, still main-
tains complete embargo. In 1958 another substantial revision (freeing-
up) of the CoCom embargo list took place, without any substantial
impact on U.S. unilateral policy. And while there were several subse-
quent additions and redefinitions of the lists, in each instance these
actions have represented `a tacit recognition by the United States that
further agreement to a strict control level by the ~oCom countries was
not possible and that the shared scope of strategic controls would
soon not extend beyond the obvious war materials and some of the
new and more exotic industrial and scientific hardware and technol-
ogy.
Such has indeed been the case-there has been constant net attrition
and "updating" of the strategic lists. The multilateral definition of
strategic has shrunk and become more concentrated on a concept of
assuring a lag in technological development in fields related to modern
warfare, in space missile and nuclear applications especially. Con-
cepts of impairment of economic growth of the U.S.S.R. and the
Eastern European countries by denial of general industrial exports has
long since been abandoned. And denial of trade in hopes to cause
economic disruption, greater cost of production, or inconvenient re-
allocation of resources in the Communist economies are no longer
criteria which govern the multilateral program.
On this basis, much of the present-day multilateral activity re-
volves around discussion and consultation regarding individual st.ra-
tegic trade problems. Orders of large magnitude by the U.S.S.R. or
the other eastern countries for items of generally known end uses,
such as the FIAT auto plant, large diameter oil pipelines, transpor-
tation equipment, special machine tools, et cetera are debated and
dealt with on a. case-by-case basis.
Meanwhile, the trade the West Europeans and Japanese carry on
with the Communist areas has become wider in scope and greater
in magnitude. And the marginally greater permissiveness of recent
changes in U.S. export policy has not altered this disparate trend.
General Trade
`This brings us to the fundamental East-West trade phenomenon
of the past decade. Free world exports to Eastern Europe including
the U.S.S.R. have risen steadily from a low point of $1.1 billion in
2 The CoCom countries.
PAGENO="0259"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 251
1950 to $4.8 billion in 1963, to about $6.2 billion in 1965. Imports have
roughly kept pace: with $1.2 billion in 1950, $4.8 billion in 1963 and
$6.3 billion in 1965. Of this, our CoCom partners have generally ac-
counted for more than half.
U.S. trade, on the other hand has been relatively stagnant over the
same period at a level of between $130-180 million of exports and
roughly $120-130 million of imports. (In 1964 we sold $259 million
worth of surplus agricultural commodities to push our 1-year total to
$340 million of exports versus $99 million of imports, but this has not
been repeated.)
The overall East-West trade development picture, while apparently
dynamic, has not been a runaway situation by any means * * * in the
5 year period 1961-65, total free world trade with Eastern Europe
increased by 49 percent, while free world trade with all countries
increased by about 40 percent. And today, East-West trade only
accounts for about 3 to 4 percent of the total trade of Western coun-
tries. Paradoxically, in spite of early fears of possible dependency of
Western countries on the bloc, trade with the West now plays a rela-
tively more important role in the economies of various of the Com-
munist countries.
The U.S. share of this large and growing market, however, is barely
3 percent-extremely narrow in products exchanged-and declining
in relative terms.
Obviously, this disparity of general trade has not been largely or
even significantly the direct result of our differential strategic mate-
rials control policy. It is partly the result of many circumstances
encountered naturally as obstacles to trade between the market econ-
omy of the United States and the state trading economies of Eastern
Europe. It is the result of a lack of credit, financial and other aid
to bring about enlarged exchange of goods and services~ It is partly
a consequence of the lack of mechanisms of advertising and supply
and distribution and cross-servicing. There are many technical and
objective barriers to expanded United States-Soviet bloc trade. But
principally the relatively small volume of trade has been the result
of the negative thrust of U.S. national policies regarding East-West
trade-amply reinforced or occasioned by public and congressional
opinion vociferously against trading with the Communist areas of
the world.
The only significant breaks in these policies have been the hard-*
fought exceptions won by successive administrations from a grudging
Congress: (i) to permit more liberal trade and credit support for
Yugoslavia in 1949; (ii) Public Law 480 credits to Poland in 1957
and subsequent years; and (iii) the precarious year-to-year and on-
and-off extension of most-favored-natioii (MFN) treatment to be ac-
corded imports from Yugoslavia (1951) and Poland (1960). The other
steps in tins direction have largely been by Executive (Presidential)
initiative in ways not requiring congressional ratification-but also
virtually without congresssional encouragement.
In the past four years these actions have been numerous-John-
son Act credits, extension of Export-Import Bank guarantees to sev-
eral Eastern European countries, liberalization of trade with Ru-
mania, and most recently the decontrol of a number of items from
the general license list of the Department of Commerce.
PAGENO="0260"
252 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S.FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
The current culmination of these actions, of course, is the pro-
posed East-West Trade Relations Act of 1966 now pending before
the Congress.
SOME CONCLUSIONS
Before going into the new issues and future prospects of policy in
this field, it is useful to evaluate further some of these past develop-
ments. While the record of the past is incomplete and far from clear-
I believe it is possible to make some judgments which are relevant
for future policy and action in this important and controversial field.
The hard facts appear to be these:
1. The initiation and active development of East-West trade con-
trols in the Stalinist and Korean periods were appropriate to the
circumstances of the cold war, complementary to our foreign policies,
and contributory to our security objectives.
2. Since this was a critical period in the relative growth of eco-
nomic and military potential of both areas-Western Europe and the
Soviet bloc-and Western Europe had the United States to rely on
as a source of capital, advanced technology, and industrial plant and
markets, there is little question that, with its smaller and less ad-
vanced industrial base, the European Soviet bloc would have been
greatly helped to have had greater or free access to Western supplies
and markets.
3. In some respects, however, this was denied as much by the Soviet
drive for bloc economic hegemony and the other natural obstacles
to expanded trade inherent in the state trading system-as well as the
self-imposed political isolation of the bloc-as it was by the multi-
lateral trade control program.
4. Thus, both the strategic controls program and the mutual dis-
couragement of trade probably worked to the relative economic-mili-
tary advantage of the West, although this period was used behind the
Iron Curtain for pursuing political and economic consolidation of the
Eastern European countries and the isolation may have been a mixed
blessing for the West in this respect.
5. The wide gap that has developed between the United States and
the other Cocom countries from the period of the mid-1950's to today
in the area of strategic trade controls has been vexatious and has ex-
ascerbated relationships among the NATO allies from time to time.
These differences have not been judged to be a threat to our security,
however, even though the availability of machinery and equipment
from these countries offsets substantially the more extensive denIal
of these items by the United States.
6. In any event the additional restrictions in so-called strategic
trade with the U.S.S.R. and Eastern Europe which we specifically
impose today in isolation from our friends and allies must be judged
to have long since ceased to have material significance to the military
and economic potential of the European Soviet bloc.
The utility of the differential in the strategic trade controls can be
challenged on two grounds: (i) Whether in fact, unless available solely
from the United States the Soviet bloc cannot readily obtain U.S.
proscribed exports from elsewhere in the free world, and (ii) whether
the Soviets, generally self-reliant as they are, are truly affected by the
denial in any case.
PAGENO="0261"
ISSTJES AND OBJECTIVES OF IJ.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 253
The justification most often advanced is that were it not for this
differential, the West Europeans would relax the trade even further
(they ship very few of the contested items in any event)-and since
these are largely items of advanced technology, the United States has
some other means to limit their sale to the East through end-use con-
trol over components and technical data control and private industrial
cooperation.
The burden of these arguments are not, and need not be, to pare our
lists of strategic items to the Cocom level. It is far more important
merely to realize that maintaining this differential does not necessarily
serve our national interest in any truly effective manner-and that
we seriously err if we insist that the disagreement of others is not
genuine-or is occasioned by the alleged opportunity to profit at the
expense of our higher standards of trade morality and greater sensi-
bility to security interests.
The discussions, analyses and attempts at reconciling views about
strategic list items have gone on with our European allies and Japan
too long and with too great sincerity to merit that suspicion and
disdain. We shall probably have to just accept the fact that there is
disagreement on this range of items. Similarly, we shall have to ac-
cept the fact that as the economies and technological prowess of the
U.S.S.R. and the other East European countries grow-along with
their military capabilities-it will be harder still to identify items
which would be sought by them in overt trade which will have ap-
parent direct relevancy to Soviet bloc military potential. Our NATO
allies and Japan are not disregarding strategic considerations in their
trade dealings. They do, however, take the view that selective denial
is in any case extremely uncertain as to effectiveness and almost hope-
less to maintain indefinitely in the face of technological progress the
world over. In effect, they question-as we must-whether these
measures are not so extremely marginal in their possible present and
future effect on the relative strengths of East and West as to be almost
inconsequential.
Finally, we should also realize that as we appear to have gained
little in a substantive sense by our insistent and isolated posture, we
similarly have often made it more difficult to obtain the understand-
ing, agreement and cooperation of our friends and allies on other
policies and programs when our apparent and prolonged intransigence
in this field is of related consequence.
7. This brings us to the point of real disparity and difference which
has existed between the United States and our free world friends.
That is, the basic difference in general trade policy vis-a-vis the
European Soviet bloc.
This difference has been based largely upon U.S. political and
foreign policy and public opinion considerations not shared in extent
or degree by most other free world countries. It is exemplified and
underscored by the fact that in the 1961-65 period alone, there has
been an exchange of goods and services between the free world and the
Soviet bloc of an aggregate of about $51 billion-$25.4 billion exports
and $26.2 billion imports. Of this, somewhat over half was CoCom
country trade. And for the same period, total TJnited States-Commu-
nist bloc trade was $1.4 billion ($906 million exports; $496 million
imports).
PAGENO="0262"
254 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
This growing trade gap, rather than the strategic controls disparity,
is the key policy consideration today.
8. Admittedly, this nonstrategic trade is limited by factors other
than trade policy. Foreign exchange shortages, lack of established
channels of trade, inadequate or inappropriate distribution methods,
packaging, servicing, high duties, and other circumstances inhibit the
Communist trading capabilities with the United States. Lack of
marketing contacts, credit arrangements, uncertainty as to business
arrangements, fear for adverse public relations and other obstacles
occur on the side of U.S. business. But generally, the public TJ.S.
posture has been predominantly in opposition to expanded trade for
fear of giving unequal benefits through such trade to the communist
areas.
9. Positive actions to change these circumstances and attitudes have
been generally lacking on both sides-the United States and Eastern
Europe-and steps have only recently been initiated by either side
with any credibility that the actions might literally "mean business."
As noted earlier, however, most of these actions to encourage U.S.
nonstrategic trade with Communist areas have been undertaken on
the U.S. side by Presidential initiative-and largely in the absence of
any congressional mandate. Almost all existing legislation in the field
of East-West trade or pertaining thereto is based upon the cold war
ethic: the Battle Act, the Export Control Act, the Foreign Assistance
Act-and a motley crew of riders to annual appropriation bills and
food-for-peace program.
10. The latest action of the administration-the proposed East-
West Trade Relations Act of 1966-is an effort to obtain congressional
sanction for a different policy approach to East-West trade, and to
change the heretofore predominant sentiment in this area from one
of moral outrage to at least one of acquiescence.
11. Given the long, controversial, and single-valued history of U.S.
East-West trade policy in the past, and current resentment of Eastern
Europe's trade with Cuba and North Vietnam, this will be a difficult
task. Here again, however, the test of any ancillary policy is the
requirement that it further the overall objectives and strategies being
pursued in the national interest; East-West trade relations are an
integral part of our foreign policy. And the manner in which East-
West trade relations are managed in the decades ahead clearly must
be more affirmative and daring than in the past if a positive contribu-
tion is to be sought.
II. THE ISSUES OF THE FUTURE
The initial debate regarding the specific aspects of the administra-
tion's proposed East-West Trade Relations Act of 1966 is already a
matter of congressional record. Its main provisions are clear in con-
cept and intent:
To use peaceful trade as a means of advancing the long-range
interests of the United States.
To authorize commercial agreements with a Communist country
when the President determines-
It will be in national interest.
It will result in equivalent benefit to the United States.
PAGENO="0263"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 255
To authorize the President to confer most-favored-nation (MFN)
treatment for Communist countries' imports as part of the commer-
cial agreements-subject to periodic renewal-and subject to with-
drawal if no longer warranted.
As such, this proposal symbolizes a proposed new formal dimension
of East-West relations: an opportunity approach to trade and political
relationships with individual East European couiitries; a recognition
that possibilities for expanded East European trade with the United
States will require special commercial arrangements; an acknowledge-
ment that access to our market must not be discriminatory if trade is
to flourish; aiid finally, while the proposed bill signifies no change in
the other safeguarding legislation which up to now tended to govern
both the letter and spirit of U.S. policy in East-West trade, it is clear
that this legislation calls for a new direction in trade relations with
Eastern Europe and the U.S.S.R.
There are, of course, certain issues related to the specifics of this
legislative proposal, but it is not necessary to go into these here. They
will be subject to detailed scrutiny in the follow-on hearings. Rather
it is important to go behind the proposed change in overall policy and
to consider the underlying questions and issues which arise regarding
a possible expansion of peaceful U.S. trade with Eastern Europe and
to consider finally how this may relate to other world problems and
the U.S. role in dealing with them.
INCREASED EAST-WEST TRADE: COST/BENEFIT
Given the security context in which this question is inevitably
viewed, the first question is: Will it be possible to bring about an ex-
pansion of peaceful trade without reducing U.S. strategic trade
controls?
Earlier the point was made that these controls are not the real bar-
rier to expanded trade. In fact, very few of the.se solely U.S. pro-
scribed items are proposed for export, and thus, few licenses are de-
nied. More practically, however, the controls do not cover such a vast
range of items so as to seriously inhibit a wide choice of goods from
this country if there indeed were a determination to expand peaceful
trade.
There are other raniifications to this question, however; these have
to do with the attitudes of the Soviets and the Eastern European coun-
tries themselves.
The first is whether they would choose to make an issue of the more
extensive U.S. denial program in the negotiations regarding commer-
cial agreements. Past exchanges with the East Europeans and the
U.S.S.R. have indicated that these measures constituted somewhat
of a "bone in the throat" in relations with the United States. But, by
the same token, in the trade arrangements with other `Western coun-
tries, the strategic control programs have not been at issue to the ex-
tent of seriously interfering with the growth of peaceful trade.
Second is whether the Eastern countries will believe in United States
sincerity and willingness to expand peaceful trade if there is apparent
continued U.S. militancy in maintaining a much higher level of stra-
tegic controls and continual striving to have other free world coun-
tries do so.
PAGENO="0264"
256 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S.FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
Fundamentally, it would appear that maintenance of this differen-
tial will not be a maj or obstacle to expanded East-West trade unless
either side chooses to make it so.
The major question then asked regarding a change in U.S. trade
policy vis-a-vis Eastern Europe, of course, is whether increased trade
with the United States will tend to strengthen the military-economic
system in the Eastern European countries.
The answer is "yes." And the answer will always be "yes" unless
someone has invented a way to bring about an exchange of goods and
services and information where the benefits bestowed will accrue solely
to one party to the exchange-or, where the exchange is so particu-
larized or minuscule as to be devoid of any meaningful economic
impact.
Obviously, trade must be mutually beneficial or it will not take place
between two parties who have the power of consent or denial. And as
long as a significant portion of the total resources of the Eastern Euro-
pean countries are allocated to armaments and armed forces, anything
which materially affects the output and use of those resources will
strengthen that area in some degree as well.
The critical question then is: Will the Eastern Europeans and the
U.S.S.R. obtain gains or benefits from an expansion of nonstrategic
trade with the United States which outweigh the possible benefits
sought to be obtained by the United States? Or the corollary: does
the United States now stand to benefit more by a continued denial and
discouragement of trade in nonstrategic items, than by a policy of
developing and encouraging such trade with Eastern Europe?
A changed official, public, and congressional attitude on these ques-
tions constitutes the major hurdle which the new U.S. initiative in
East-West trade policy must clear. And if the case is to be made, it
will require a steadfast belief that the political gains from such a policy
will be more real and meaningful than the apparent tangible contribu-
tion which might be made through increased trade to the growth and
power of Communist Europe. In effect, increased political opportunity
and the possibility of accelerating the processes of peaceful change in
the Communist areas is considered the crux of the matter, and this is
looked to offset the small potential benefits which the Communist areas
might derive from encouragement of higher levels of trade.
For one thing, it must be made clear that the genesis of this policy
change is to be found in the changing objectives, strategies, and
intent of overall U.S. East-West policies; and, for another, the hoped-
for outcome of a change in East-West trade policy is not only a new
and larger pattern of two-way trade, but a new and more hopeful
pattern of political and economic relationships between the United
States and the nations of Eastern Europe and the U.S.S.R. This is the
basic proposition underlying the new approach; a change in U.S.
East-West trade policy is being pursued primarily as an avenue to
peace-rather than as an adjunct to defense or in hopes of commercial
gain.
It is necessary, I feel, to pursue this question more fully at this
point-even before considering whether, in fact, U.S.-Eastern Europe
nonstrategic trade can be apnreciably increased. The reason for this
is simnie: it will indeed be difficult to increase such trade-and the per-
ceived political benefits must be very apparent before we will be pre-
PAGENO="0265"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 257
pared to undertake the kind of efforts and make the kinds of conces-
sions necessary to bring about meaningful increases in peaceful trade
with the Communist countries.
WIN-LOSE: OR, WIN-WIN?
Heretofore, we have basically applied a "win-lose" calibration
to our East-West trade policy and many of our relations with the
Soviet bloc. By this arithmetic, since the Soviet bloc was a somewhat
industrially retarded and sernihackward adversary in the economic-
military competition between our two worlds, trade which would some-
what strengthen the growth and increase the national income of the
Communist countries was to be generally avoided even though this
similarly denied the west the additional outlets and sources of supply
for burgeoning production and demand. As noted, this logic fitted
consistently with past times and events, both practically and
politically.
As the practical aspects of this have changed-and trade denial has
become of marginal importance as a defensive measure-greater non-
strategic trade has developed and the political climate has been chang-
mg as well. And if the past United States aloofness or hostility to
nonstrategic trade has been judged to be largely ineffectual in the
strategic sense, what, then, must be asked is the balance of political
benefit which increased trade might bring?
It is not difficult to judge that, considered alone, a greater exchange
of goods between the United States and Eastern Europe and the
U.S.S.R. would bring apparent economic benefit to the eastern coun-
tries; there is great diversity, economy and technological content to
the manufactures and industrial and consumer goods we provide from
our large and efficient production base. And while these items in greater
quantity would probably not make a major impact on economic growth
and development of the Eastern European economies-expanded trade
per so would be of considerable benefit to the Communist areas. In
fact, of course, this is already true with regard to existing nonstrategic
trade by Western Europe and other free world countries today. The
economic quid pro quo for us would be of more general and perva-
sive nature-largely associated with cost factors related to alternative
sources of supply, economies of scale and greater competitiveness of
exports, some possible contribution to the balance-of-payments pic-
ture, and the diffuse economic benefits of a slightly higher level of
economic activity engendered by foreign trade-all very small when
considered in comparison with our total trade picture and growth
of GNP.
One might judge from this that if some increase in general world
trade could take place elsewhere without major political implications,
the United States should be highly indifferent to an increase of trade
with the Communist areas-and could as well choose to concentrate
its efforts elsewhere. In other words, by the "win-lose" test, there is
little point in adopting an affirmative policy toward nonstrategic trade
with the Communist areas when we might address the same efforts to
improving the level of trade with other parts of the free world. Be-
sides, the West Europeans and Japan as well as other free world
PAGENO="0266"
258 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S.FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
countries are doing very nicely, thank you, in reciprocal trade ex-
changes with the Communist world, and are not having the trauma of
internal and external political dissent which we generate on this issue.
Obviously, the calculus of judgment is for us to become convinced
that the previous dismal arithmetic of "win-lose"-wit.h U.S. security
presumably the loser-can be transformed into "win-win" where there
is at least equivalent benefit, and that this benefit can be reciprocal
politically as well as economically.
The administration's thesis behind advocacy of a change in U.S.
East-West trade policy is essentially that an increase in nonstrategic
trade and attendant commercial, diplomatic and other contacts will
contribute to the pursuit of peace between otherwise hostile camps.
By this thinking, it is asserted that either increased or diminished
trade in nonstrategic items can today hardiy prove critical or even
very important in East-West economic or military relationships;
whereas it is possible that increased trade and contacts may serve as
a creditable and effective accompaniment to sincere and genuine
efforts to bridge differences and resolve conflicts and create a new ave-
nue for seeking East-West understanding.
The implication of this thesis, it must be added, is also that the
increase of U.S.-Eastern European trade should not be passive-but
should be pressed as a positive element and "instrument" of our for-
eign policy.
This total concept is now embodied in the administration's proposal
now pending before the Congress: the draft statement of purposes.
reads "~ * * to use peaceful trade and related contacts with Com-
munist countries * * * to promote constructive relations * * * to
increase peaceful trade and related contacts * * * to expand mar-
kets~ * * * in those countries by creating similar opportunities * * *
to compete in U.S. markets on a nondiscriminatory basis."
The President has clearly indicated that a change in East-West
trade policy is a corollary to his other efforts toward "building
bridges" to and with the Communist areas.
There is little question that vast changes have occurred and are now
in progress in the Communist world that are favorable to our inter-
est-and that we should seek to reinforce and promote the processes
of change. Most of these changes are well known and documented: the
shattered Moscow-Peking axis, the loosening hold of Moscow over
some of the East European countries, the increasing independent irntia-
tives of these countries in their relations with each other and with
the West. There has been an opening up within the Communist socie-
ties as well-less obvious uses of police power, growing contacts with
Western people, greater travel possibilities, and the much more exten-
sive preoccupation with economic reforms, criticism of Communist sys-
tems and values and inefficiencies, and somewhat of a retreat from
centralized controls and rigid ideological disciplines.
It is this accelerated process of change which provides hope that
enhanced economic intercourse and personal contacts and more exten-
sive diplomatic probing for common interests might reduce the chances
of hostile actions and confrontations between the United States and
the European Communist sphere.
Proposed East-West Relations Act of 1966, sec. 2, statement of purposes.
PAGENO="0267"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 259
INCREASED TRADE: 110W
This brings us to the other major aspect of this policy change: what
are the l?roSPects for an increase of trade?
There are many difficult aspects to the engineering of a greater flow
of trade between the United States and the Eastern European coun-
tries. The most fundamental involve:
1. Providing greater access to the U.S. market, principally by mod-
ification of U.S. tariff restrictions on imports (most-favored-nation
treatment already being sought in pending legislation), improved and
more extensive consular relationships (in process), and commercial
agreements facilitating elements of contractual relationships (author-
ity being sought).
2. Encouragement and support for U.S. efforts to penetrate and
develop the Eastern European markets, including:
Modification of export controls (some action recently taken)
SupportS of U.S. trade missions and trade exhibits (could be
substantially stepped up)
Extension of credit facilities and guarantees (partially under-
taken on normal commercial terms)
Development of better means for personal and business contacts
and relationships.
Most testimony by trade experts indicates that, even with active
promotional efforts and vigorous attempts to remove various barriers
to greater two-way trade, the best that can be foreseen is an annual
level of trade of perhaps a modest $500 million within several years.
This estimate is based upon general premises, however, which need
not hold indefinitely for the future. First, that the extension of com-
mercial credit will be very restricted; second, that the exchange will
continue to be in strict balance; and finally, that shortage of foreign
exchange holdings and lack of capabilities for earning more by the
Eastern European countries will prove a severely limiting factor
to an expansion of trade with the United States.
If, indeed, an expansion of direct United States-Eastern European
trade is deemed beneficial by both parties and reasonably facilitated-
there is no reason to believe that trade preference for U.S. products
might not arise in Eastern European nations as it has with many
other countries-in spite of other -free world competition. Similarly,
there is no compelling reason why the rigid pattern of rigorously bal-
anced exchanges between the Communist nations and Western Euro-
pean areas need be maintained forever. In fact, an eventual three-way
trade and payments development would appear a more logical pattern
than the present-with West Europe importing relatively more from
the East, the eastern countries buying relatively more from the United
States and the usual increases in United States demand for West
European exports completing the circle. Obviously, this change would
take some doing-but it would be consistent with the avowed purpose
of bringing the eastern countries more fully and freely into the. world
trading community. In this case, one could wish that the essence of the
political argument supporting a change in policy would be more con-
sistent with regard to the expected or desired economic outcome of
such a policy. Many of the exponents of the proposed change in United
PAGENO="0268"
260 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S.FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
States east-west policy appear to be somewhat avoiding the implica-
tions of success-at least at the economic level. One must, it seems to
me, set the economic sights as high as the political-and an early
target of $1 billion annual trade would be more in keeping with a
healthy level of economic interchange between these two vast market-
ing areas.
In other words, we should not expect very substantial and affirma-
tive results from policies which are carried out haltingly and almost
grudgingly. If the gains are indeed worth the risks, we should not run
the added risk of suffering inadequate results because of halfhearted
effort.
It is in this area of expectation and disappointment, too, that an-
other feature of the political argument must be touched upon.
TRADE AS AN "INSTRUMENT OF POLICY"
Already we have found creeping into the debate on future East-
West trade policy, a manipulative if not an aggressive overtone which
may ill-serve the formulation of policy in this field. In contrast
to the "little old ladies in tennis shoes" attitudes of fear and moral out-
rage which often dominated earlier discussion, we hear increasingly
the view advanced that peaceful trade is the next best thing to James
Bond for the political subversion of the Soviet bloc and the overthrow
of worldwide communism. According to this view, for example, greater
TJ.S, trade and commercial intercourse with Eastern European coun-
tries would not only permit the economic benefits of greater access to
their markets and greater export earnings for the United States but
the new and prolific East-West contacts engendered by this will vigor-
ously fan the latent fires of European nationalism, cause irresistible
yearnings for capitalistic affluence, quicken the urges for political free-
dom by the broad masses behind the Iron Curtain, and subvert and
transform the Communist system in short order.
Now, this admitted burlesque of an often sincerely expressed ra-
tionale of expanded East-West economic interchange is not to deny or
decry some of the expectations of what might ensue from a change of
policy-marginal, indirect or remote as these developments may be.
The point to be exposed is that-if a straight "win-lose" political cali-
bration is also applied to a change in a trade policy-not only may
there be extreme disappointment and disillusionment, but increased
East-West trade may be discredited for those purposes it can legiti-
mately serve-whereas the other results it may only incidentally or in-
directly promise.
The principal factor to be judged is whether increased East-West
trade will contribute to peace-to its development, and to its mainte-
nance.
As an aggressive "instrument of political policy," trade is not a very
sharp or lethal weapon. Two-way trade is a channel or conduit of
goods, services, knowledge, and personal and official contacts. Ex-
panded trade will serve to increase the plurality of international ex-
changes-and it is an area where there can be struck a balance of
perceived benefit to both parties. In international negotiation it has
already been demonstrated that principles of reciprocity are increas-
ingly being perceived as problems of attempting to match demands
PAGENO="0269"
ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S. FOREIGN TRADE POLICY 261
and concessions on otherwise unrelated matters in order to strike bar-
gains. And it is in this role-as a springboard of discussion and a
medium of exchange-that expanded trade and personal and commer-
cial contacts may contribute to a more hopeful East-West dialog.
If this is so, expanded trade may indeed "fan the winds of change,"
but we would be foolish to expect or demand that it also fan the winds
of insurrection, subversion or disaffection. Our national interest to be
served by a modification of our trade policies as addressed to the
European Communist nations will be to reinforce and promote proc-
esses of change which will make them less a threat to peace and their
regimes less enemies of individual freedom.
Changes are indeed taking place in these areas-major political,
social and economic change-even as they are in free world societies.
And trade can be a major and positive force in both spheres and be-
tween both spheres to increase the possibility of developing coopera-
tive efforts and peaceful pursuits. But it is not a panacea-just as it
is not a dread one-sided threat to our security.
THE BROADER INTERESTS
Much of the preceding discussion has been somewhat artificially
limited to consideration of U.S. trade with the Eastern European
countries and the U.S.S.R. It is clear that an expansion of peaceful
trade between these two areas will not take place in a vacuum-with-
out regard to the policies and actions of other nations and certainly
not without regard to their political, economic and competitive
interests.
In fact, it is in this international and multilateral area-perhaps
more than the bilateral-that more rapid progress may be made. As
East-West trade becomes larger and progresses even further from
the primitive bilateral stage-there will be need to develop better
systems of reciprocal dealings and clearings and adjustments. The
state trading nature of the Communist countries-which renders some
of the traditional bargaining and safeguarding elements of reciproc-
ity in free world trade inappropriate, unenforceable, or unreliable-
will have to be changed to accommodate the legitimate needs of west-
ern commercial practice. An entire range of new undertakings will
have to be worked out: arbitration procedures, protection of patents
and other property rights, settlement of financial claims, agreed prin-
ciples and objective criteria to govern and judge potential market
disruption and dumping. In the final analysis, the Communist na-
tions will have to seek ways to remove commercial obstacles arising
from differences in their economic systems just as Western countries
have adjusted to one another.
With proper authority and flexibility granted the President~, the
United States will be able to become a major factor in bringing this
about-not alone, but in concert again with its other trading partners.
As the TJnited States and the Common Market countries and the
TJNCTAD countries have found it necessary and advantageous to be
members of international financial and trade organizations and ad-
herents to international agreements such as GATT-so, in fact will
the Eastern Europe countries, if they seek meaningful increases in
peaceful trade. Some sort of multilateral machinery-whether in the
form of altered or broadened existing organizations-or newly created
PAGENO="0270"
262 ISSUES AND OBJECTIVES OF U.S.FOREIGN TRADE POLICY
ones, will be needed to overcome the limiting features of present day
East-West bilateral trade relations. And while the United States has
not heretofore expressed interest in or exerted leadership to bring such
developments about, under a changed East-West trade policy this will
be one of the logical next steps to be taken.
It is noteworthy that this change in U.S. policy is proposed to be
undertaken in the dawn of a new trade era in the free world-shortly
following the formulation of the Common Market and the major and
comprehensive trade overhauls of the Kennedy Round and coincident
with greater recognition of the need to concentrate on the other enor-
mous trade gap-that between the developed and less-developed coun-
tries. Perhaps this new era may see East-\'Vest trade as a major vehicle
for political change as well.
In final judgment, therefore, East-West trade need be neither a
dilemma nor a delusion for the United States, but we must be more
forthright and mature in our judgments regarding this field. Too much
is at stake to take sole counsel of our fears as we have in the past; too
little is to be gained if we do not act in confidence that genuine efforts
toward peaceful relations will be reciprocated.
0