PAGENO="0001"
90th
1st
~
Congress
Session
JOINT COMMITTEE PRINT
J
~
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE
A COMPENDIUM OF PAPERS ON PROBLEMS AND POLICY ISSUES
IN THE PUBLIC AND PRIVATE PENSION SYSTEM
SUBMITTED TO THE
SUBCOMMITTEE ON FISCAL POLICY
OF THE
JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE
CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES
Part III: Public Programs
COLLEcE ~ ~UTh
CAMDEN, N~ J~
~ 9 ~ DECEMBER 1967
Printed for the use of the Joint Economic Committee
U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE
DV~ DO~200 WASHINGTON 1967
For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office
Washington, D.C. 20i02 - Price 60 cents
2.:i s-n')
~ / ~i4 ~ ~` y
PAGENO="0002"
SENATE
JOHN SPARKMAN, Alabama
J. W. FULBRIGHT, Arkansas
HERMAN E. TALMADGE, Georgia
STUART SYMINGTON, Missouri
ABRAHAM BIBICOFF, Connecticut
JACOB K. JAVITS, New York
JACK MILLER, Iowa
LEN B. JORDAN, Idaho
CHARLES H. PERCY, Illinois
ECONOMISTS
WILLIAM H. Mooan JoHN B. HENDERSON GEOSGE R. IDEN
DONALD A. WEBSTER (Minority)
SUBCOMMITTEE ON FISCAL POLICY
MARTHA W. GRIFFITHS, Michigan, Chairman
HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES SENATE
HALE BOGGS, Louisiana WILLIAM PROXMIRE, Wisconsin
WILLIAM S. MOORHEAD, Pennsylvania HERMAN E. TALMADGE, Georgia
WILLIAM B. WIDNALL, New Jersey, STUART SYMINGTON, Missouri
DONALD RUMSFELD, Illinois JACOB K. JAVITS, New York
JACK MILLER, Iowa
CHARLES H. PERCY, Illinois
NELSON D. MCCLtJNG, Economic Con~uitant
II
JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE
[Created pursuant to sec. 5(a) of Public Law 304, 79th Cong.]
WILLIAM PROXMIRE, Wisconsin, Chairman
WRIGHT PATMAN, Texas, Vice Chairman
HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES
RICHARD BOLLING, Missouri
HALE BOGGS, Louisiana
HENRY S. REUSS, Wisconsin
MARTHA W. GRIFFITHS, Michigan
WILLIAM S. MOORHEAD, Pennsylvaiiin
THOMAS B. CURTIS, Missouri
WILLIAM B. WIDNALL, New Jersey
DONALD RUMSFELD, Illinois
W. E. BROCK 3D, Tennessee
Es~ecut ire Director
JAMES W. KNOWLES, Director of Research
JOHN R. STARK,
PAGENO="0003"
LETTERS OF TRANSMITTAL
DECEMBER 11, 1967.
To the Members of the Joint Economic Committee:
Transmitted herewith for the use of the members of the Joint Eco-
nomic Committee and other Members of Congress is part III, "Public
Programs," of the compendium of paper entitled "Old Age Income
Assurance," prepared for the Subcommittee on Fiscal Policy.
The views expressed in this document do not necessarily represent
the views of members of the committee or the committee staff, but
are statements of issues and alternatives intended to provide a focus
for hearings and debate.
WILLIAM PROXMIRE,
Chairman, Joint Economic Committee.
DECEMBER 8, 1967.
1-lion. WILLIAM PRoxMniE,
Chairman, Joint Economic Committee,
Congress of the United States, Washington, D.C.
DEAR MR. CHAIRMAN: Transmitted herewith is part III, "Public
Programs," of the compendium of papers on problems and policy
issues in the public and private pension system, entitled "Old Age
Income Assurance."
Part III deals specifically with public programs and contains 13
papers contributed by invited specialists.
The subcommittee is indebted to these authors for their excellent
contributions, which we believe will add much to a general awareness
of the issues in retirement income policy, particularly as these relate
to old age and survivors insurance and tax programs. The time and
learning devoted to the preparation of these papers should do much
to stimulate interest and to assist in policy decisions concerning future
programs for old age income assurance.
Dr. Nelson McCiung, consultant t-o the subcommittee, is responsible
for the planning and preparation of the compendium, with the edi-
torial assistance of Aime McAfee, and the advice and suggestions of
other members of the committee's professional staff.
As the Executive Director's letter indicates, the compendium should
not be viewed as an expression of views or conclusions of the committee
staff, nor should it be viewed as an expression of views of the subcom-
mittee or individual members.
MARTHA W. GRIFFITI-IS,
Chairman, Subcommittee on Fiscal Policy.
In
PAGENO="0004"
Iv
LETTERS OF TRANSMITTAL
DECEMBER 17, 1967.
Hon. MARTHA \~T GRIFFITI-Is,
Uk ci~iinan~ Subcommittee on Fiscal Policy,
Jo i'nt Econon~ic Committee.
U.S. Congress, TVa.shington, D.C.
DEAR MADAM CHAIRMAN: Transmitted herewith is part III, "Public
Programs," of the compendium of papers entitled "Old Age Income
Assurance." This study was prepared at your request in orde.r to bring
together current thinking on the questions of retirement income ~J"~-
grams and thereby contribute to policy decisions by focusing attention
on tile more promising solutions to tile income problems of older
people.
The compendium, which is being issued in five parts, confirms the
fact that programs to aid older people have grown in number, size,
and complexity, and that the coordination of these programs and
their cofllbuled impact on the income of older people have received
very little attention. Clearly, public policy issues exist with respect
to coordinating these programs, appraising their effects on the econ-
omy, and improving their equity.
Part III, "Public Programs," contains contributions by the authors
listed below. Tile committee is indebted to these contributors who have
given generously of their time and expertise to provide tile latest avail-
able information and competent analytical perspective on this im-
portant subj ect.
Prof. Henry J. Aaron Prof. Hugh Macauiay
Dr. George A. Bishop Dr. Joseph A. Pechman
Dr. John A. Brittain Mr. Ray M. Peterson
Prof. Cohn D. Campbell Prof. Gaston V. Rimlinger
Mrs. Rosemary G. Campbell Prof. Robert N. Schoeplein
Prof. rung-Ping Chen Prof. James H. Schulz
Dr. Elizabeth Deran Prof. Michael Taussig
Prof. David Donaldson Prof. Richard D. Young
Dean E. A. Gaumnitz
Tile maj or work in planning and compilillg this compendium was
undertaken by Dr. Nelson McClung, consultant to the Subcommittee
on Fiscal Policy, with the advice and suggestions of other members
of the staff. He was assisted in the editorial work by Anne McAfee.
Nothing herein should be interpreted as representing either the opin-
ions of the staff or the members of the committee on any of the matters
discussed.
JOHN R. STARK,
Executive Director, Joint Economic Committee.
PAGENO="0005"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE
Part III: Public Programs
CONTENTS
Page
Letters of transmittal III
CONSIDERATIONS AFFECTING SocIAL SECURITY DURING THE 1970's, by
Dean E. A. Gaumnitz, Graduate School of Business, University of
Wisconsin 1
THE OBJECTIVES OF SOCIAL SECURITY, by Dr. Joseph A. Pechman, Direc-
tor of Economic Studies, the Brookings Institution, Professor Henry J.
Aaron, University of Maryland, Professor Michael Taussig, Rutgers
University 5
ISSUES IN FUTURE FINANCING OF SOCIAL SECURITY, by Dr. George A.
Bishop, Director, Federal Affairs Research, Tax Foundation, Inc...~ 21
COST-BENEFIT RATIOS UNDER THE FEDERAL OLD-AGE INSURANCE PRO-
GRAM, by Professor Cohn D. Campbell, Dartmouth College, and Mrs.
Rosemary G. Campbell 72
INFLATION AND PRODUCTIVITY IN TAX-BENEFIT ANALYSIS FOR SOCIAL
SECURITY, by Professor Yung-Ping Chen, University of California, Los
Angeles 85
THE REAL RATE OF INTEREST ON LIFETIME CONTRIBUTIONS TOWARD
RETIREMENT UNDER SOCIAL SECURITY, by Dr. John A. Brittain, Senior
Staff Member, the Brookings Institution 109
ON THE OPTIMAL MIx OF SOCIAL INSURANCE PAYMENTS, Professor David
Donaldson, University of British Columbia 133
MATHEMATICAL APPROACHES TO THE MACROECONOMICS AND PLANNING
OF OLD-AGE PENSION SYSTEMS, by Professor Richard D. Young, Pro-
fessor Gaston V. Rimlinger, Rice University 137
"EARLY RETIREMENT" TRENDS AND PENSION ELIGIBILITY UNDER SOCIAL
SECURITY, by Professor James H. Schulz, University of NeW Hampshire~ 156
TAX MEASURES PROVIDING INCOME ASSISTANCE TO OLDER PERSONS, by
Professor Hugh Macaulay, Clemson University 169
SOME ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF HIGH TAXES FOR SOCIAL INSURANCE, by
Dr. Elizabeth Deran, Senior Research Analyst, Tax Foundation, Inc_ 181
INCOME TAX INDUCEMENTS FOR PERSONAL RETIREMENT SAVING, by
Professor Robert N. Schoeplein, University of Connecticut 202
OLD-AGE INCOME ASSURANCE BY LIFETIME INCOME SPREADING WITH
DEFERRED TAXATION AS THE NATURAL TREATMENT, by Mr. Ray M.
Peterson, F.S.A 209
AUTHORS LISTED ALPHABETICALLY
AARON, Prof. Henry J 5
BISHOP, Dr. George A 21
BRITTAIN, Dr. John A 109
CAMPBELL, Prof. Cohn D 72
CAMPBELL, Mrs. Rosemary G 72
CHEN, Prof. Yung-Ping 85
DERAN, Dr. Elizabeth 181
DONALDSON, Prof. David 133
GAUMNITZ, Dean E. A 1
V
PAGENO="0006"
Vi CONTENTS
Page
MACAULAY, Prof. Hugh 169
PECHMAN, Dr. Joseph A 5
PETERSON, Mr. Ray M 209
RIMLINGER, Prof. Gaston V 137
SCHOEPLEIN, Prof. Robert N 202
SCHULZ, Prof. James H 156
TAUSSIG, Prof. Michael 5
YOUNG, Prof. Richard D 137
PAGENO="0007"
CONSIDERATIONS AFFECTING SOCIAL SECURITY
DURING THE 1970'S
BY DEAN E. A. GAui~rNITz°
This summary is prepared upon the assumption that there are many
studies, both completed and underway, by the staff of HEW that re-
late to problems that are likely to need attention during the next dec-
ade or two. Many of these studies are known to the author but equally
there are many that are unknown, and, hence, it is possible that this
summary may make suggestions relating to problems that have already
been analyzed in great detail.
1. A persistent and perennial problem that has been much studied
but definitely not solved and which has an extreme impact upon re-
tirees is that of inflation. I need not repeat the well-known statistical
summary that may be currently updated which demonstrates the ero-
sion of rising price level on the monthly benefits of the elderly. Un-
fortunately, this type of economic hardship affects those either covered
or not covered by social security. It also places a heavy burden on peo-
ple in all walks of life and at varying ages, but especially those whose
incomes are largely determined by formula rather than dependent upon
shifts resulting from forces that work in the marketplace. Included
in this latter group, in addition to retired people, will be those benefit-
ing by other types of governmental programs, and not gainfully em-
ployed, such as the total group of welfare recipients, or in general those
receiving public assistance.
The traditional attitude existing in the minds of many who are
closely associated with social security types of programs is that prob-
lems of inflation are to be analyzed by those with fiscal responsibility,
the Federal Reserve, the U.S. Treasury officials, banking groups, and
others. The immediate past history and the likely changes that are
related to the serious economic disturbances tha.t will be with us for
the next few years, as a minimum, make it mandatory for those con-
cerned with retirement benefits to give relatively more attention to
methods of controlling inflation instead of restricting their efforts to
techniques of contending with its effects through alterations in the
benefit structure.
A united front involving recommendations from many economic
groups would be likely to come closer to designing an effective program
to combat inflation than one that would result by delegating the re-
sponsibility only to monetary and fiscal authorities. People in this lat-
ter category need broad general understanding and support if they are
to achieve an approach to reasonable stability in the price level con-
sistent with adequate growt.h.
*Graduate School of Business, University of Wisconsin.
1
PAGENO="0008"
2 CYLD AGE' LNCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
2. A few decades ago, when the social security program was in its
infancy, there was a considerable amount of attention given to the simi-
larities and differences between a social and private insurance pro-
gram. It was pointed out that benefit formulas in relation to payments
by the individuals bore a closer individual actuarial proportionality in
a private than in the social insurance system. That is, the approxima-
tion to actuarial equivalence in a private system not only exists in the
aggregate but also on a. class-by-class basis in the insurance program.
Some people argued that there should be actuarial soundness in the
aggregate but the approximation need not be very close among the
classes. For example, it was a part of the specific planning in the benefit'
structure in social insurance that those who had worked a short time
to achieve full covurage would, on the average, stand to receive more
benefits per dollar of contribution than would be received by a person
who was covered for a much longer period. Similarly, a person whose
average income was twice that of another would not receive beneats
in the same proportion.
The gradual changes that have taken place in social security benefits,
contribution rates, and the time of achievement of full coverage, when
coupled with retirement benefits earned through private pension plans,
may result in net yield of benefits in relation to contributions that
would be inconsistent with the criteria, established as the foundation.
More specifically, a given social insurance program may be based in
its benefit structure on a very reasonable set of criteria. Goals may be
consistent with modern social philosophy. A similar statement may
exist for other types of social programs administered by the Govern-
ment, such as welfare programs. Private pension plans may also be
based on criteria considered reasonable by those who negotiated the
agreement. The difficulty may arise, however, when these programs
are combined into a conglomerate for the individuals concerned. Pro-
gressive versus regressive effects should be analyzed. Studies should,
therefore, be made to ascertain whether or not an undesirable disparity
exists, and if so, an indicated solution should be forthcoming. Such an
analysis must presuppose the existence of criteria to serve as a founda-
tion for evaluating a total system iiistead of treating social and private
pension plans as though only one type existed.
This idea definitely does not. contemplate the suggestion that. there
should be contractual or statutory dependencies existing in one pro-
gram with respect to another, but, rather, the planning in one sphere
should be based on the assumption that other programs are in existence
and will continue.
3. The social security progra.m was born in an atmosphere of eco-
nomic depression and a general lack of confidence in our total social
and economic system. Unemployment was widespread and was especial-
ly injurious to those in the older age groups. The dole became socially
unacceptable, and, therefore, the voting public was ripe for favorable
action on a system that would provide retirement income to those who
had completed several years of active employment. A benefit structure
was designed that would be as high as possible in cornpar~son with
rates of contribution which had to supply the funds for the disburse-
ments. Also, benefit payments were to be made as soon as possible with
due regard being given to adequacy of the resources in the program.
PAGENO="0009"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 3
The originally scheduled changes in contribution rates and benefits
have been altered in a more favorable direction on more occasions than
were apparently contemplated by those who framed and passed the
initial legislation. With three decades of experience and the generation
of a much higher level of activity, one would have guessed that charita-
ble types of programs would have been in less need in proportion to the
total. It has come as a surprise to many students of the problem that
the affluent society has not been associated with decreased pressures for
welfare programs at the same time that payments based on a "right"
instead of a need have been so sharply increased.
A study should be made to attempt to lay a philosophical foundation
for judging the desirable proportionality that should exist between
present provision for future existence compared with allocation of re-
sources to solve current problems. It would appear that a constantly
rising percentage of social income allocated for preparing for the
future should not be carried to an unproductive limit. This is espe-
cially serious when social and private systems are combined in their
effects, and when private savings of those in higher income groups
would be on the rise in spite of graduated income and inheritance taxes.
The questions are whether or not there should be a desirable upper limit
on the proportion of present income used for provision for the future.
What are the philosophical and economic criteria for this judgment?
The next question would be the determination of a limit, but pre-
sumably with some flexibility.
4. At the time of the peak discussions surrounding the formation of
the Social Security Act, the emphasis was on security in the economic
sense of the term. Little or no attention was given to a consideration
of problems of health, happiness, and social adjustment, except insofar
as these problems could be translated into payments, stated in terms of
monthly income per retiree.
Duriiig the past few years it has become evident that economic secu-
rity, especiaily in an affluent society does not lead to social or emotional
stability. In fact, some have argued that greater provision for retire-
ment income, beyond a reasonable minimum, provides more time for
individuals to become dissatisfied and, therefore, emotionally disturbed
about other aspects of security than those of an economic nature. Stud-
ies should be made to uncover relationships between economic and non-
economic disturbances in society relating to those segments of our
population which stand to benefit from programs of retirement benefits
of the material sort.
5. There has been increasing concern given to the mobility of pen-
sion rights. Several studies have indicated that mobility of such rights
does not seem to be as great a deterrent to job mobility as had earlier
been presumed. Greater flexibility in private pension systems, together
with the features in the social schemes have, perhaps, tended to de-
crease restrictions on job shifts. In general, such flexibility should be
contributory to the proper allocation of human resources. Studies
should be made to ascertain the industries and areas that contribute to
immobility of such resources and to throw light on the adverse effects,
if immobility is indeed an apparent cause of dissatisfaction. In view of
unrest that exists in many segments of society, a study should be de-
signed to determine the casual connection, if any, that exists b@tween
PAGENO="0010"
4 OLD AGE IXCOME ASSIJHAXOE-PART III
immobility and the difficulty faced by some segments of society in be-
coming socially adjusted in new surroundings. Unfortunately,. it is
possible that mobility that permits greater production by a proper allo-
cation of resources is likely also to create social disturbances resulting
from such change. If studies were to indicate that such is the case, some
light should be thrown on the possible direction of solutions. If irregu-
larity of employment, shifting employment, nonvesting of benefit
rights, the failure to make individual provision for retirement, and
social dissatisfaction in new surroundings are found in essentially the
same groups or classes of people, these groups might be the sources of
growth in public assistance programs. This package of difficulties
should be studied and tentative solutions determined.
6. Extreme changes in marriage and birth rates associated with the
disturbances of World War II are going to yield sharp fluctuations in
the numbers and proportions of our population that reach age 65 be-
fore this century is over. Such rapid changes, when their impact is felt
upon our retirement programs, will affect the funds available for in-
vestment and, therefore, the base for growth in our industrial system.
When we will enter a period of sharply increased disbursements for
retirement purposes, this appears likely to be the time when there will
be a substantial increase in those seeking jobs at the beginning of their
adult careers. Such disbursements for retirement purposes may de-
crease the availability of funds for industrial growth and housing. A
study should be made to see whether or not this coincidence is likely
to occur, and if so, the provision can be made at the present time to
alleviate the disturbances likely in the future.
PAGENO="0011"
THE OBJECTIVES OF SOCIAL SECURITY
BY JOSEPH A. PECHMAN, hENRY J. AARON, and. MICHAEL TAUSSIG*
Social security serves two related but conceptually distinct objec-
tives. The first is to guarantee minimum income support for the aged,
the disabled, and dependent survivors. In recent years, the success of
the program in achieving this welfare goal has been increasingly
judged by the degree to which it keeps beneficiaries out of poverty. The
second objective is to help moderate the decline in living standards
when the earnings of the family head cease because of retirement, dis-
ability, or death. This earnings replacement objective is independent of
the goal of preventing poverty; benefits go to families at all income
levels. Both objectives of social security must be carefully defined,
because acceptance of the current program and proposals for improv-
ing it hinge on the public's evaluation of their comparative
importance.
The case for a social security program intended to achieve these
objectives depends in part on the observed inability of most people to
niake adequate financial provision for retirement, disability, or pre-
mature death. Mainly, however, it depends on what appear to be widely
shared humanitarian values: that (a) the aged, the disabled, and de-
pendent survivors of deceased family heads should not have to live in
destitution, and (b) the Government should help to protect individuals
against cfttast.rorpbic losses of income. It is a~1so widely agreed that
people should be eligible for benefits without degrading eligibility
tests. The purpose of this chapter is to explain the implications of ex-
plicit acceptance of these values for broad policy decisions in social
security.
Widespread acceptance of the basic objectives explains why social
security is a successful institution. On the other hand, disagreement
about decisions concerning the proper level and composition of benefits
arises largely because social security has an appealing but distorted
image based on a misleading analogy to private insurance. This image
impedes intelligent consideration of alternative means of shaping
the course of the program. In practice-as well as in principal-so-
cial security is not a substitute for private insurance, but rather a
mechanism for transferring financial resources from the working gen-
eration to those who cannot work because of age, disability or de-
pendency status. This is a point that has been emphasized by many
economists and is no longer in serious dispute.1 The key issues revolve
*The authors are, respectively, director of economic studies, the Brookings
Institution; associate professor of economics, University of Maryland; and as-
sistant professor of economics, Rutgers University. This paper is part of a forth-
coming book on "Issues in Social Security" being prepared for the Brookings
Institution.
I See, for example, Ida C. Merriam, SocioZ ~ecur~ty Fi~tancing, Federal Security Agency,
Social Security Administration, Division of Reseatch and Statistics, Bureau Report No. 17
(1953), pp. 2, 135; and Paul A. Samuelson, `Social Security," Newsweek, Feb. 3, 1967,
p. 88.
5
PAGENO="0012"
6 OLD AGE INCOME ASSTJRA~iOE-PART III
around methods of establishing criteria for determining the size of
the transfer and for distributing and financing benefits.
RATIONALE FOR SOCIAL SECURITY
In an economy where most economic decisions are freely made, why
does society choose to override individual choice between private con-
sumption and saving for the risks covered by social security? For sim-
plification, the following discussion of this question is limited to the
problem of providing income during retirement, but the analysis can
be generalized to the other risks.
NEED FOR A GOVERNMENT PROGRAM
Each person faces daily a multitude of choices about how to spend
his income or wealth-how much to spend on food, clothing, enter-
tainment, and other current wants, and how much to set aside for re-
tirement when earned income declines sharply or ceases. In the absence
of compulsory social insurance, each person will make these decisions
on the basis of his own tastes. He will invest his savings so as to achieve
what he regards as the best mix of yield, liquidity, and safety. In mak-
ing these decisions, the rational person will balance the cost of saving
(foregone consumption today) against the benefits of saving (larger
income in retirement) and will set aside t.he amount he considers ap-
propriate. Each person should be able to achieve an optimum alloca-
tion of consumption between his working life and his retirement
years-optimum in the sense that no other allocation would make him
better off. Any other pattern is, by definition, not better and probably
inferior.
In this view of the world, social security must, by assumption, "dis-
tort" the allocation of consumption and is, therefore, an unjustified
interference with individual choice. Many persons may be forced to
"save" more of their income than they would desire. In the extreme
case, an individua.l with no dependents who is certain he cannot sur-
vive to retirement age would "prudently" save nothing for his retire-
ment. Yet, social security taxes deprive him of the opportunity to
dispose freely of a substantial part of his income. Social security also
interferes with the freedom of workers to decide how to invest that
portion of their income claimed by social security taxes. If they are
skilled investors, they might use these funds to purchase assets with
higher yields than the returns which social security implicitly pro-
vides. Such individuals would not gain from social security; actually,
they may have a lower total income in retirement.2
Although attractive to anyone who values individual freedom in
making economic decisions, this conception of the role of individual
choice in providing for retirement is unrealistic. It does not take ac-
count of the. fact, which even the most severe critics of social security
will generally concede, that voluntary savings cannot yield the poor
worker (i.e., the worker whose income is close to the amount necessary
for subsistence) an income sufficient for retirement.~ A family which
2 The views described here are expressed forcefully by Milton Friedman in Capitalism
and Freedom (University of Chicago Press, 1962), pp. 1ST-189.
~Ibid,., p. 184.
PAGENO="0013"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 7
cannot feed and clothe itself adequately from current income cannot be
expected to sacrifice present consumption to provide for uncertain con-
sumption needs in retirement.
T he problem of poverty does not in itself negate the `argument for
individual provision for retirement, for there is no reason to presume
that poor people are necessarily inferior judges of how best to allocate
whatever income they may possess. If some are too poor to purchase
adequate amounts of any commodity, including savings, a possible solu-
tion is to supplement their incomes through transfer payments. When
incomes reach whatever level is deemed socially adequate, each person
could then determine the amount of retirement protection he wishes
to buy.
This discussion opens up major issues concerning Government poli-
cies of income supplementation for all the poor. It is sufficient to note
at this point that nobody has yet recommended a system of transfer
payments that would provide the poor with a sufficient margin for
saving, as well as for current consumption.
Furthermore, even individuals who have sufficient earnings during
their working lives may have insufficient savings at retirement, either
because they incorrectly gage their retirement needs or because their
personal investments turn out badly. Most people would agree that the
aged poor should not be left unaided in these circumstances, and that
the Governmeiit bears the ultimate responsibility of providing income
support for such unfortunate people. Because humanitarian values
prevail in our society, it may be assumed that the Government will
guarantee a minimum subsistence level of income for the aged (and
perhaps for other groups as well). The notion that Government should
guarantee a minimum level of income support for all the aged has
widespread acceptance.4 Because "subsistence" is a subjective concept,
and because the costs of providing income support for the poor are
large, the precise level of support to be guaranteed is a controversial
issue.
Once society agrees on a minimum income guarantee, however, a
further decision is required on the conditions under which the guar-
antee will be provided. The Government can either provide minimum
subsistence payments to each eligible person regardless of his other
income, or it can make them av~ailable :oiTly if his income falls below
a stipulated level. The former method-the universal demo grant-is
followed in Canada and some other foreign countries. The latter
method-the welfare approach-is exemplified by the public (includ-
ing old-age) assistance programs in the United States.
Old-age reti~ement benefits in this country are paid on terms which
fall somewhere between these extremes, although they are much closer
to those of the universal demogrant than to those of welfare. Only
persons who have worked long enough to qualify for the required
insured status are eligible to receive benefits. Persons who meet this
qualification receive payments without consideration of their income
and wealth. Only if an insured person earns enough to be disqualified
See, for example, Bert Seidman, "The Case for Higher Social Security Benefits"
AFL-CIO American Pederationist, vol. 74, No. 8 (January 1967), pp. 1-8; and Chamber
of Commerce of the United States, Poverty: The Sick, Disabled, and Aged (Washington:
1965), pp. 69-73.
PAGENO="0014"
8 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
by the earnings test is he denied benefits at age 65. Further, retirement
benefits are not intended solely to guarantee a subsistence income to
beneficiaries.
The welfare method has one great advantage over the universal
deinogrant: if the proportion of the aged requiring government help
is small and if the administrative costs of determining need are not
excessive, `the ~bj ective of preventing destitution is accomplished at
`minimum expense `by limiting payments to those with demonstrated
need. Nonetheless, the welfare method has been rejected `by most people
`because of two aspects.
First, a welfare program separates people into two groups-those
who support. themselves and those who require Government help.5 The
degree to which this distinction is degrading depends in large measure
on the method `by which eligibility for benefits is ascertained (i.e., the
means test). WThen the test involves detailed probing, and frequently
degrading investigations, the number of eligible persons who will even
apply for benefits is severely limited; this is evident from the history
of public assistance. On the other hand, eligibility for veterans' dis-
ability pensions is determined on the basis of a simple income affidavit,
subject. to sample audit, supplied annually by recipients. Neither a
sense of alienation nor reticence to apply for }~nefits has been noted
in this program.
Second, the welfare method may weaken individual incentives to
save for retirement needs. Many persons would have a strong incen-
tive to save less for retirement than they would if there were no Gov-
ernment program. They may safely enjoy maximum consumption in
their youth, once they know that they can fall back on Government
assistance when they retire. In addition, the fact that improvident
individuals could finance retirement at public expense may discourage
saving by people who otherwise would prefer to provide for their own
retirement needs rather than depend on Government support.. The
importance of these perverse incentive effects depends critically on
the implicit "tax rate" used under the guarantee. If benefits are re-
duced Si for each $1 of investment income (that. is, a iOO percent tax
on investment income), the disincentive effects are bound to be far
more severe than if benefits are reduced, say, 30 cents for each $i of
investment, income (that is, a 30 percent tax on investment income) .~
The price of rejecting the welfare method of dealing with the aged
poor is vastly higher expenditures to attain the same objectives. This
price should be explicitly acknowledged as the cost of avoiding the
humiliation of the means test and any discouragement of private sav-
ings that might occur. The historical development of old-age, sur-
vivors, and disability insurance (OASDI) and old-age assistance pro-
grams in the United States shows that our society has been willing
to pay t.his cost.
Experience in t.he past with the means test under public assistance
has resulted in an unfortunate emotional tendency in the community
~This point is developed fully by Robert M. Ball, "Social Insurance and the Right to
Assistance," SociaT Service Review, vol. 21, No. 3 (September 1947), pp. 331-344.
6 These aspects of social insurance are carefully discussed by Richard A. Musgrave, "The
Role of Social Insurance in an Overall Program for Social Welfare," The American System
ol 5ocia~ In&uraflCe, Its Philosophy, Import, and Future Development (Princeton University,
forthcoming).
PAGENO="0015"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 9
to reject indiscrirninantly any eligibility test for OASDI benefits.
It should be kept in mind, however, that the benefits to be derived
from any device that avoids the problems traditionally associated with
the means test, and yet holds down the costs of public assistance, are
potentially enormous. The search for such a test, similar perhaps to
the test for veterans' disability pensions, continues.
The earnings test, while unpopular, does reduce significantly the
cost of OASDI without raising the problems outlined above. First,
since only a minority of persons eligible to receive social security
benefits engage in full-time employment and thus may be subject to
the earnings test, OASDI benefits are paid to the majority of the
aged. Thus, the problem of segregating a minority to be singled out
as the needy group does not arise. Second, because the earnings test is
by design not an income test, it does not take account of the income
from accumulated assets and, therefore, does not penalize individual
savings.
BENEFITS ABOVE POVERTY LEVELS
The argument thus far supports the establishment of a Government
program that guarantees a minimum of income support for the aged.
But many of the characteristic features of the social security system
go much further. While minimum benefits fall well below the officially
defined poverty thresholds, benefits at the upper end of the sale are
above subsistence levels and bear some relationship to the individual's
lifetime earnings. A number of arguments have been made in support
of such a system; in combination they add up to an impressive case.
Shortcomings of individnal savings decisions.-The principle that
individuals should make the bear responsibility for the decisions that
affect their own economic well-being underlies much of the intellectual
opposition to an old-age insurance program. Individuals are deemed
to be the best judges of their own preferences. That many individuals
often make foolish decisions, as recognized after the fact, is not neces-
sarily objectionable; for in learning from their mistakes, they may
develop self-reliance and accumulate practical knowledge that will
be to their advantage when they make later decisions. The principle
of individual responsibility is the basis of the case for free choice
about economic matters in general, and there is no strong objection
to it in most practical applications.
Decisions about saving for retirement, however, are vastly more
difficult than nearly any other economic decision which most people
are called upon to make. They depend on subjective appreciation of
wants in a much later period-possibly four or five decades. They
require an individual to consider his future stream of earnings and
other income, and to recognize several possibilities: that he will be
married and have a family; that he may be unemployed involuntarily
for considerable periods of time; and that he may become disabled or
die prematurely. To save intelligently, the individual must also be
able to appraise the probable future purchasing power of the income
from various assets. Most important of all, the individual may not be
aware of his mistakes until he is close to retirement, when the con-
sequences are irremediable.
There is widespread myopia with respect to retirement needs. Em-
pirical evidence shows that most people fail to save enough to pre-
PAGENO="0016"
10 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
vent catastrophic drops in postretirement income. In 1962, the median
amount of investment income of all aged persons was less than $300.~
Not only do people fail to plan ahead carefully for retirement; even
in the later years of their working life, many remain unaware of im-
pending retirement needs.8 Unfortunately, the mistakes of youth are
to a large degree irreversible, since it is generally impossible to ac-
cumulate in a short period just before retirement sufficient assets to
provide adequate retirement income. In an urban, industrial society,
Government intervention in the saving-consumption decision is needed
to help implement individual preferences over the life cycle. There
is nothing inconsistent in the decision to undertake through the po-
litical process a course of action which would not be undertaken in-
dividually through the marketplace.9
Even if an individual plans ahead and gages accurately his retire-
ment needs, it is questionable that he has sufficient knowledge about
other relevant considerations to make the necessary saving consump-
tion decisions. The depression of the 1930's illustrated dramatically
the difficulties that even experts encounter in planning their personal
investments. The information required for intelligent longrun invest-
ment planning is expensive; for small investors, the cost of hiring
professional investment counseling (for example, in the form of pur-
chases of shares in a mutual fu1ld) is frequently prohibitive. De-
ficiencies in Government economic policy that permit depressions and
inflations may sweep away the carefully planned saving of even the
most provident and skillful iiivestors. The available evidence suggests
that the problem of uncertainty may explain why people do not save
enough. Apparently, once a private pension plan has provided a mini-
mum base of retirement income, most people are willing to save more
on their own, rather than less.'°
A person who is saving for retirement generally faces the invest-
ment dilemma of choosing between fixed yield assets that offer little
protection against inflation and other instruments that require finan-
cial sophistication or carry considerable risk. Time deposits in com-
mercial banks and other institutions fall into the first category. Yields
on such deposits offer small returns after allowance for the steady
increase in prices that has occurred since the end of World War II.
Common stocks fall into the second category; as the major form of
savings, they are beyond the sophistication of the majority of the pop-
ulation. Even if an experience like the stock market crash of 1929 is
Lenore A. Epstein and Janet H. Murray, The Aged Population of the United States:
The 1963 Social Security Survey of the Aged (U.S. Department of Health, Education, and
Welfare), Social Security Administration Report No. 19 (1967), table 3.18, p. 302.
S According to a field survey taken in 1960, less than half of nonretired persons over 55
years of age were able to estimate the amount of income that they would obtain from
their retirement program and from social security. More than two-thirds were unable to
estimate their income requirements during retirement. (`See James N. Morgan, Martin H.
David, Wilbur J. Cohen, and Harvey E. Brazer, Income and Welfare isv the United States
(McGraw-Hill, 1962), p. 442. See also the discussion by Derek C. Bok, "Emerging Issues in
Social Legislation: Social Security," Harvard Law Review, vol. 80, No. 4 (February 1967),
pp. 738-739).
This tendency to make economic decisions politically Is reviewed by William J. Baumol,
Welfare Economics and tile Theory of tue State (second edition, Harvard University Press,
1965). (See also Stephen A. Marglin, "The Social Rate of Discount and the Optimal Rate
of Investment," Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 77, No. 1 (February 1963), pp.
95-U 1.)
10 See Phillip Cagan, The Effect of Pension Plans on Aggregate Saving: Evidence From a
Sans pie Survey, National Bureau of Economic Research, Occasional Paper No. 95 (Coluni-
bia University Press, 1965) ; and George Katona, The Mass Consumption Society (McGraw-
Hill, 1064), cli. 10.
PAGENO="0017"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 11
discounted as unlikely to recur, it would be dubious social policy to en-
courage large-scale investment by individuals in common stocks. Other
savings instruments-for example, Government saving bonds, cash,
annuities-all suffer from one or the other of these shortcoirnngs as
vehicles for large amounts of long-term savings."
Shortcomings of private pension plans.-The shortcomings of pri-
vate pension plans persist despite substantial incentives given by the
income tax and other Federal statutes for the development of adequate
plans by industry. A major incentive is the provision that allows an
employer to deduct from his taxable income up to 5 percent of his
payroll for amounts set aside in a pension plan approved by the
Internal Revenue Service. The employee is not required to pay income
tax until ho receives pension benefits.12
Only about one-fifth of the total number of persons aged 65 and
older now receive private pension benefits. By 1980, the proportion
will be between a third and two-fifths.'3 Moreover, the benefits paid
are, on the whole, small, Many plans are not insured, and many are
inadequately financed. Vesting is long delayed, so that job mobility
is preserved only at the price of surrendering pension credits. Given
the limited coverage of private pension plans, the inadequacy of their
benefits for many covered workers, and their other shortcomings, they
can hardly be expected to provide sufficient earnings protection in old
age for more than a minority of the work force for many years to
come.'4
Social costs of inadequate provision for retirement.-As pointed
out earlier, it becomes difficult to hold to the principle of individual
responsibility when the consequences of individual mistakes are
extreme. The case for social intervention becomes overwhelming
when it is recognized that one individual's mistakes affect not only
his own well-being but also that of his family, friends, and local
community. Even those true believers in individual responsibility
who could bear with equanimity the suffering of the individual
"responsible" for his own fate find it difficult to justify the suffer-
ing of other "innocent" persons.
The social costs that result from inadequate provision for retire-
ment are considerable, even if all the aged are guaranteed a sub-
sistence income. Suppose that, in the absence of a social old-age
insurance program, an individual with an average income during
his working years retired without any personal savings. If he were
guaranteed only a minimum subsistence income, the fall in his liv-
ing standard would impose serious costs on his relatives, friends,
and local community. Even under present social security provisions,
heavy costs sometimes fall on children or others who have to make
it possible for aged persons to maintain living standards close to
those which they had enjoyed earlier. To lighten such costs a Gov-
ernment program to provide income maintenance related to pre-
vious income standards is needed. To guarantee only a minimum,
poverty-line level of income is too severe a policy in a society in
which maintenance of status depends so critically oii the maintenance
of previous levels of income.
11 For a summary of a recent study of this problem, see H. J. Maidenberg "Personal
Finance: Annuities at Age 65," New York Times, June 22, 1967, p. 51, col. 5.
12 Internal Revenue Code, sees. 401-404.
13 Daniel M. Holland, Private Pension Funds: Projected Growth, National Bureau of
Economic Research. Occasional Paper No. 97 (Columbia University Press 1966)
14 See Robert 11. Ball, "Policy Issues in Social Security," Social Security Bulletin vol 29
No. 6 (June 1966), p. 5. .
83-200-67-pt. 3-2
PAGENO="0018"
12 OLD AGE INCOME ASS.URA~CE-PART III
DETERMINING THE LEVEL OF BENEFITS
rile factors discussed thus far lead to the conclusion that the
payment of retirement benefits above subsistence levels of income
is consistent with valid social objectives. But, to justify the need for
some social intervention in providing for retirement is easier than
to determine the proper degree of intervention. The ethic of indi-
vidual responsibility has greater and greater force, the higher an
individual's income. The social interest in maintaining very high
incomes is correspondingly very weak. To take an extreme example:
there is no justification for public provision of retirement benefits
based on the full income of a high-level executive whose earnings
exceeded $100,000 a year for many years. Some compromise between
amounts no greater than those necessary to guarantee subsistence
income levels and amounts related to incomes at the upper tail of
the distribution is necessary. But, the choice within this wide range
is a pragmatic decision, on which analytical considerations are of
little help. In reaching a decision, the desirability of making public
expenditures for other purposes must be weighed against the desir-
ability of pushing up social security benefits for those with rela-
tively high preretirement incomes. The present modest level of
OASDI benefits certainly does not exceed the wide range suggested
by this analysis; minimum benefits unfortunately fall short of the
levels needed for subsistence.
In practice, OASIDI benefits above the minimum are determined on
the basis of preretirement earnings. The ratio of benefits to preretire-
ment earnings is called the "replacement rate," because benefits are
supposed to replace those earnings. The benefit formula is structured
so that replacement rates vary inversely with previous earnings; the
higher the preretirement earnings, the lower the replacement rate.
Thus, while high earners are entitled to larger absolute benefits, their
benefits are less relative to previous earnings than are those of low
earners.
This structure, is roughly consistent with the two objectives discussed
earlier. The high replacement rate for the low earner and the minimum
benefit can be interpreted as a guarantee of minimum income support
for the aged. The larger absolute benefits paid to the high earner can
be viewed as an effort to meet the objective of preventing drastic
declines in the incomes of the nonindigent aged. This interpretation
of the OASDI benefit structure corresponds roughly to the tradi-
tional social security concepts of social adequacy and individual equity.
IMAGE OF SOCIAL SECURITY
Social security is most commonly viewed as a system of mandatory
insurance, different in important respects from private insurance, but
nonetheless insurance. This analogy shapes the image of social security
and thereby influences the prevailing body of beliefs, conceptions, and
opinions that govern popular understanding of the system. It has
played a major part in developing public support. Nevertheless, the
analogy is strained and, in the end, seriously misleading.
PAGENO="0019"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 13
SOURCES OF TIlE INSURANCE ANALOGY
Use of the insurance analogy to characterize social security in the
United States has popular appeal because the nature of individual sav-
ing and private insurance is familiar and enjoys considerable re-
spectability and even prestige. The flow of funds between the individ-
ual and the ultimate user of these funds is a vital part of a free market
economy. Insurance companies are, furthermore, an important inter-
mediary in this process; they channel the savings of many individuals
to firms that wish to add to their productive capacity. The rates of
return on individual savings reflect in large part the productivity of
the physical capital they finance. There is, thus, a connection among
the amount an individual saves, the value of his accumulated assets
at retirement, the value of the annuity he can purchase with his previ-
ous savings, and the creation of additional physical capital and pro-
ductive capacity in the economy. Provided the economy's resources are
fully employed, these relationships are straightforward and are
widely understood.
The vocabulary of the social security system helps to promote the
insurance analogy. The very names-social insurance, old-age and
survivors insurance, and disability insurance-suggest the analogy.
Individual contributions (payroll taxes) are formally paid into trust
funds. Beneflts to retirees, survivors, and the disabled are formally
based on preretirement earnings and are paid from the same trust fund
accounts. Since interest is credited on trust fund balances, it is tempt-
ing to conclude that the trust funds are similar to the reserves of
private insurance companies. Finally, statements by social security
experts often tend to reinforce the parallel to private insurance. The
following excerpt from a recent article by the Commissioner of Social
Security is representative of many similar writings:
The idea [of social security] is simply that while people
work and are earning they contribute a part of their earnings
to a fund, with contributions from the employer and now, in
many countries, also from the Government. When earnings
stop because one is too old to work or too disabled to work or
because the wage earner in the family dies or because there
is no job to be had or there are extra expenses connected with
illness, for example, then the accumulated funds from all con-
tributors are used to make up for the loss of income or to meet,
in part or in whole, the expenses incurred. In return for
setting aside some of the money one has when one is earning,
the system provides an assured income when one is not.
Social insurance, like all insurance, averages out among all
who are covered the risk that is too much for any one individ-
ual to bear.15
The following statement by Barbara Wootton expresses a very differ-
ent view:
As things are, everybody now recognizes an increasing ele-
ment of fiction in current income schemes. As Americans have
`-~ Robert M. Ball, "Policy Issues in Social Security," SociaZ Security BuUetin, vol. 29,
No. 6 (June 1966), pp. 3-4.
PAGENO="0020"
14 OLD AGE INCOME ASSIJRANCE-PART III
cause to realize, the coverage of income-maintenance schemes
tends almost irresistibly to expand. But, as these schemes be-
come more generalized, their insurance basis becomes more
and more illusory; until in cases where, as in Britain, virtually
universal coverage has been attained, fiction ousts fact alto-
gether.
At this point, the simple facts of the situation are that bene-
fits on a. prescribed scale have been promised, and that funds
must be provided to meet them; that is all. In these circum-
stances, the allocation of precise fractions of contributors'
payments to cover particular risks becomes an academic,
rather than a. genuinely actuarial, exercise. The performance
of this exercise in the sacred name of insurance demands, how-
ever, elaborate and expensive systems of recording the expe-
rience of millions of beneficiaries. These monumental systems
are indeed a. tribute to the skill and accuracy of the adminis-
trators who devise them. and to the ingenuity of the mechani-
cal devices employed in their operation; but, are they really
necessary, and have the, indeed, any meaning? Is it, in fact,
worth maintaining what has become no more than a facade? 16
The fact that OASDI benefits are designed to achieve objectives
other than individual or group equity is obvious to casual observers
as w-eli as to those who are intimately familia.r with the system. Social
security officials have, frequently stressed that social insurance differs
from strict insurance. principles because of considerations of social
adequacy. However, they do not seem to regard such differences as
sufficiently basic to require abandonment of the insurance vocabulary.
For example, the Chief Actuary of the Social Securit.y Administra-
tion has said:
It is recognized that the use of the term "social insurance"
may result in some misunderstanding of the basic nature of a
social security program by the general public, who will tend
to think of it in terms of their acquaintance and knowledge of
private insurance, or even Government insurance involving
a contractual relationship (such as the nationa.l service life
insurance program, crop insurance, and parcel post insur-
ance). Nonetheless, the term "socia' insurance" is a very
popular one both here and abroad, and by usage and dictionary
meaning seems proper.17
Belief in the insurance nature of the relationship between an in-
dividual's OASDI benefits and taxes is the basis of the image of social
security. The most important implication of this image is the belief
15 "The Impact of Income Security on Individual Freedom," In James E. Russell (ed),
National Policies for Education, Health, and Social Services (Doubleday, 1955), pp.
386-387.
17Robert J. Myers, Social Insurance and Allied Government Programs (Irwin, 19651,
p. 8; also see pp. 8-10, where the differences between social Insurance and private Insur-
ance are carefully discussed.
For the views of a representative of the private Insurance industry who expresses con-
cern about the analogy between private Insurance and social security, see Roy hi. Peterson,
"Misconceptions and Missing Preceptions of Our Social Security System (Actuarial Anes-
thesia)," Transactions of the Society of Actuaries (November 1959), P1). 812-851. Peterson
has also collected quoted statements by various top public officisis which demonstrate the
prevalence of the belief in the insurance analogy: "The Coming Din of Inequity," .Journal
of the American Medical Associatsou, vol. 176, No. 1 (April 1961), p. 38.
PAGENO="0021"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 15
that each individual pays for his own benefits, and, therefore, that he
receives his benefits not as a matter of public charity, but, rather, be-
cause the benefits are his earned rights. This view largely explains
why being a social security beneficiary carries no stigma. It is also
responsible for the belief that benefits cannot legally be withheld from
any entitled person.
Another feature of the system-the relationship of both benefits and
contributions to an individual's earnings during his working life-
seems to imply and be implied by the insurance analogy. Basing
benefits on previous earnings is accepted as a simple matter of equity:
individuals who pay more into the fund receive higher benefits when
they retire just as individuals who choose to pay higher insurance
premiums subsequently receive larger annuities from private insurance
companies. It seems a fair conclusion that these elements of the private
insurance analogy, which are understandable to most citizens, con-
tribute to the tremendous appeal of social security to virtually all
classes of society.
SIMPLE ECONOMICS OF SOCIAL SECURITY
Nevertheless, when the terminology of social security is stripped
away and the structure of the system is examined, it is clear that the
private insurance analogy is largely invalid. Decisions about how re-
tirement benefits should be distributed and how they should be financed
are, in principle, independent. In fact, to make benefits depend dire6tly
on the amount an individual has paid in taxes would be inconsistent
with the objectives of the program.
The Committee on Social Insurance Terminology of the American
Risk and Insurance Association has suggested a detailed definition of
social insurance which lists many of its characteristics. The committee
states explicitly that one major characteristic is that "the benefits for
any individual are not [emphasis added] usually directly related to
contributions made by or in respect of him, but, instead, usually redis-
tribute income so as to favor certain groups such as those with low
former wages or a large number of dependents." The committee added
that its "definition of social insurance shows that in addition to pos-
sessing some characteristics which it shares with voluntary insurance
written by private insurers, social insurance possesses many unique
characteristics." 18
In practice, the relationship between individual contributions (that
is, payroll taxes) and benefits received is extremely tenuous. Present
beneficiaries under OASDI receive far larger benefits than the taxes
they paid, or that were paid on their behalf, would entitle them.
Furthermore, this situation will continue indefinitely-though to a
decreasing extent-as long as Congress maintains benefit levels in line
with higher wage levels. This arises because OASDI is not an insurance
system, but a transfer payment system that distributes to the aged a
share of the gains from the growth in the overall productivity of the
economy.
Some participants in private group retirement plans also receive far
larger benefits than they are entitled to on `the basis of their own
iS Bulletin of the Commission on Insurance Terminology of the American Risk and
Insurance Association, vol. 1, No. 2 (May 1965), p. 2.
PAGENO="0022"
16 OLD AGE INCOME ASStRANCE-PART III
contributions. This situation is common at the beginning of a system,
since full benefits are freque.ntly awarded to workers who have con-
tributed to the retirement plan for only a fraction of their working
lives. This practice gives rise to "past. service credits," the liability
which future beneficiaries (or the employer) must bear. Past service
credits are also genera.ted when a mature retirement system is liberal-
ized, to the extent that those near retirement age partake of liberalized
benefits without having had to make commensurate contributions.
The similarities between past service credits in group insurance and
the aspect of OASDI make equating of the two types of programs
tempting. Despite this similarity, the analogy between group insurance
and social security is just as tenuous and misleading as the more general
analogy between individual insurance and social security. One obvious
difference is that failure of a firm to pay premiums for a group in-
surance plan terminales the insurance for all members of the group,
whereas employees covered by OASDI are credited with quarters of
coverage even if the firm does not pay the tax due.
The key distinction between the two approaches-private insurance
and social security-turns on whet.her an individual currently in the
labor force and paying ta.xes into the soc.ial security trust funds is
paying for the benefits of current retired workers and survivors or
for his own or his family's future benefits. In individual insurance,
each person's premiums are contractually tied to his own and his
family's future benefits. No insurance company knows how many new
policies it will sell, and, therefore, does not know the amount of its
future cash inflow from premiums. `Conse.quent.ly~ it must charge its
present customers enough to create a. reserve fund sufficiently large to
meet its future financial obligations.
In social security, on the other hand, the level of payroll taxation
is set to defray costs of benefits for the curre'ntlii retired. The social
security program (for very good reasons discussed in chapter 7) has
been financed on a virtua1 cash or pay-as-you-go basis in recent years.
The accumulated reserves are sufficient to cover only approximately
1 year of benefit payments at present benefit levels. Moreover, on bal-
ance, the reserves have not increased in t.he la.st decade. It is true that
most social security bills project surpluses in the distant future, but
these are quickly eliminated by later legislation. Each new law con-
tains benefits a.nd taxes t.hat provide a rough balance in the trust
funds for the first couple of years, with surpluses projected there-
after. Before t.he surpluses are realized, however, benefits are liberal-
ized, new tax rate increases are scheduled for future dates, and the
cycle is repeated. In other words, the money which workers cur-
rently pay into t.he funds is not stored up or invested, but, is paid
out conc.urrei~tly as benefits to the various categories of current bene-
ficiaries. Workers pay for benefits to eli~ible nonworkers. The future
benefits of present workers, their dependents, or their dependent sur-
irivors will be paid ~n similar fashion out. of the cont~ibu~tions of the
working pqpulation a.s of some future date.
The fact that a fund is not accumulated at some explicit interest
rate does not imply that an individual in the OASDI retirement
program fails to share in the growth of the economy. Economic and
population growth assures to the average individual covered by the
PAGENO="0023"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 17:
program an implicit rate of return in a currently financed social
security system, even if tax rates are fixed. If generation 1 pays t per-
cent of its earnings Y1, to support retirement benefits under OASDI,
then its tax burden is tY1. Generation 2 similarly pays the same t
percent of its earnings, F2, to support retirement benefits equal to
tF2 for generation 1. If population and the labor force grow at lOOi
percent a year and per capita earnings grow at lOOj percent a year,
then after a generation of n years, tY2 tF1 (1 +i) (1 ± j) ~ The
implicit interest rate that generation 1 receives on its OASDI taxes
under the above assumptions is 100 (i+j) percent, or the sum of the
rates of growth of population and per capita earnings. Generation
2 and all future generations will receive the same implicit return on
their taxes as long as population and per capita earnings contmue
to grow at the same rates.19
Thus, the analogy of an individual paying for his own insurance
policy with contributions based on earnings is not applicable to
social security. Unlike a private insurance firm, OAJSDI does not have
to accumulate large reserve funds to meet its future financial commit-
ments. When benefits promised to current workers come due, the
funds will be provided out of tax revenues as of that future date. The
financial soundness of the social security program does not depend
as it does for a private insurance firm, on prudent financial manage-
ment of present premium income, but rather on the Government's
effective power of taxation. The Government's ability to collect taxes
sufficient to provide adequate social security benefits in the future
depends critically on the maintenance of a sound Federal tax system
in a healthy, grewing economy. The fatter the rate. of economic growth,
other things equal, the lighter the burden of taxation that will be
required to finance any given level of future social security benefits.
If social security taxes were increased enough to result in surpluses
in the Government budget that were used to create a reserve fund,
the consequences for the "financial soundness" of the program would
hinge on whether the process affected the rate of growth of the econ-
omy. If the economy were at, or below, a full employment level of
income when social security taxes were increased, and if the Govern-
ment did not take some offsetting action, the result would `be a fall
in the level of income and a lower rate of growth. If, on the other
hand, the Government offset the surpluses by expansionary monetary
policy or by increased Government capital formation, the result would
be a higher rate of growth. The point is that the creation of a social
security reserve fund is, in the first instance, only a transfer of mone-
tary claims from the private sector to the Government. The ultimate
effect of this initial monetary transfer depends on a great many fac-
tors; it is certainly incorrect to assume that there is a mechanism that
automatically transforms a Government reserve fund into increased
stock of productive capital and, therefore, increases the rate of eco-
19 This point has been made many times, dating back to the basic article by Paul A.
Samuelson, "An Exact Consumption-Loan Model of Interest With or Without the Social
Contrivance of Money," Journal of Political Economy, voL 66, No. 6 (December 1958), pp.
467-482. (See also Peter Diamond, "National Debt in a Neoclassical Growth Model,"
.4mer~can Economic Review, vol. 60, No. 5 (December 1965), pp. 1126-1150; and Henry J.
Aaron, "The Social Insurance Paradox," Canadian Journal of Economics and Political
Science, vol. 32, No. 3 (August 1966), pp. 371-374.)
PAGENO="0024"
18 OLD AGE IXCOME ASSFURANCE_PART III
nornic growth. The above are the relevant considerations to be taken
into account in planning and financing a social security program.'°
They raise difficult conceptual and pragmatic problems for overall
Government economic policy-problems for which the precepts of
private insurance are not relevant.
However, not all the implications of the insurance concept of social
security are irreconcilable with the simple economics of the program.
Consider, for example, the basic issue of whether social security bene-
fits can be regarded as an earned right by recipients. If, in return for
his own contributions to the social security funds an individual does
not earn a quid pro quo in the private insurance sense, he does earn
a quid pro quo in a sense that is, perhaps, even more fundamental.
Since he gives up part of his earnings during his own working life to
support the aged during their retirement, he has a strong moral claim
to similar support from future working-age genera.tions during his
own retirement. Under social security, the individual has moral rights
rather than legal rights.2' In this sense, the benefits are earned rights,
bitt the vahchty of tins proposition does not in any way depend upon tdie
insurance analogy.
The practical importance of discarding the insurance analogy is not
to discredit the concept of social security, but rather to dispel basic
misconceptions about certain aspects of the OASDI program. Once
the insurance analogy is seen to be false, the social security "contri-
bution" must be regarded as a tax, not an insurance premium, nor, in-
deed, as a "contribution" in the generally acceptable sense. The finan-
cial interchange between generations does not depend on the existence
of a particular tax-.the payroll tax. lit arises because each generation
of workers undertakes to support the eligible nonworking population
and implicitly expects similar treatment.'2
Social security payroll taxes are legally earmarked, but they are
not econom:icaliy earmarked. Congress and the President jointly have
total discretion about which kinds of taxes (including those on pay-
rolls) shall be used to pa.y for whatever expenditures they jointly
conclude are worth making. If Congress should decide to end the ear-
marking of the payroll tax (but should allocate it to the general fund)
and to earmark enough of, say, the corporate income tax to pay for
social security benefits, nothing would be changed except some ac-
counting. Or, if Congress should decide that all taxes are to be de-
posited in the general fund and then should appropriate sufficient
funds each year to pay for social security, again nothing would be
changed. In each case, the taxes paid by individuals and businesses
would be unaltered, the amount of borrowing by the Government from
the public would be unaffected, and the expenditures of the Federal
Government would be the same.
Labeling the payroll tax as a contribution is sometimes regarded
as a crucial factor in gaining public understanding and acceptance
~ For a thoughtful discussion of the Implications of social security financing see John
J. Carroll. Alternative Methods of Financing Old-Age, Survivors, and Disability Insurance
(University of Michigan. 1960), chs. 1 and 3.
"The courts have held that "~ * * the noncontractual Interest of an employee covered
by the act cannot be soundly analogized to that of the holder of an annuity whose rights
to benefits are bottomed on his contractual premium payments" (Flemniing v. Ncstor, 363
U.S. 603. 1900). The only assurance that benefits will continue to be paid Is congressional
unwillingness to repeal the program.
"See Ida C. Merriam, op. cit.
PAGENO="0025"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 19
of the program. Presumably, this practice allows individuals to con-
nect the lowering of income now with the promise of benefits later.
But, the same effect could be achieved by devices that do not involve
a, payroll tax. For example, a certain percentage of the individual's
income tax, or of his taxable income, could be designated as a tax to
support OASDI. The tax could be withheld by the employer and
labeled as the "OASDI tax" on the individual's final tax return, very
much as is done today with the payroll `tax on the employee's W-2
withholding form. The psychological connection between the tax and
promised benefits would remain intact under this alternative, without
resort to the payroll tax.
The basic point that emerges from the foregoing observations is
that the payroll tax is not a necessary feature of the social `security
system. Payroll tax receipts are part of the total revenues of the Fed-
eral Government, and should be evaluated on their merits as a source
of taxes. This means that the desirability of changes in payroll taxes
should be weighted against changes in other taxes and that social secu-
rity benefits should be financed by the methods which are most equi-
table and most conducive to economic growth and efficiency.
In place of the insurance analogy, social security should be regarded
as an institutionalized compact between the working and nonworking
generations, a compact that is continually renewed and strengthened
by every amendment to the original Social Security Act.23 When
viewed in this light, a social security program has the eminently de-
sirable function of forcing upon society an explicit decision at each
point of time on the appropriate division of income and consumption
between workers (the young) and nonworkers (the old, survivors,
and disabled). Workers and nonworkers alike participate in the deni-
ocratic process that shapes this vital distributional decision. The
social security system is the mechanism by which society settles the
issue of intergenerational (worker-nonworker) income distribution
through the political process rather than leaving its resolution to
private decisions and the market.
This last point is more general than the narrow issue of preventing
poverty among the aged. ,Consider two workers, A and B, who always
earned at least the maximum taxable wage and thus qualify for the
maximum benefit; however, A is married to a woman aged 65 or older
while B is unmarried. These two workers are treated most unequally.
The benefit paid to A (and his wife) is 50 percent greater, while they
are both living, than the benefit paid to B; and a widow's benefit is
payable after A's death, while only a small lump-sum payment is paid
to B's survivors (as it is also to A's), despite the fact that, by assump-
tion, each ha.d equal earnings before retirement and the question of
poverty is not at issue. The wife's benefit is an extremely important,
explicit redistributional device that has no connection with the prob-
lem of poverty. In short, the benefit structure under OASDI is, like
the system of personal exemptions under the personal income tax, a
23 The outstanding statement of this view of social security is by Paul A. Samuelson,
"An Exact Consumption-Loan Model of Interest With or without the Social Contrivance
of Money," op. cit., pp. 479-482. The best introduction to social security for the serious
student is the entire Samuelson article and the later exchange, "Consumption-Loan Interest
and Money." "Reply," and "Rejoinder," in Journal of Political Economy, vol. 67, No. 5
(October 1959), pp. 512-525, between `Samuelson and Abba P. Lerner concerning some
points raised by the article.
PAGENO="0026"
20 OLD AGE IXCO~iE ASSrRA~cE-PART III
means by which society can adjust the distribution of income that re-
suits from the workings of the private market for nonmarket, welfare
considerations, such as family size.
SnM~r~nY
The case for social security rests on a solid basis. Given widely ac-
cepted humanitarian values and a few fundamental facts about eco-
nomic behavior in our culture, it follows that the Government should
maintain and continually strengthen the social security system to
protect individuals from severe declines in living standards in retire-
ment and against other risks. To serve the purposes which justify its
creation, the system should be ifuanced by the best methods available
to the Government at any given time; it should guarantee minimum
benefits sufficient to keep beneficiaries out of poverty; and it should
pay benefits above the minimum level determined, at least in part, by
the previous income or earnings experiences of beneficiaries.
Two basic features of the social security system which are widely
approved and help to explain the public's acceptance of the system as
a desirable permanent public institution can be traced to the analogy
with private insurance. These features are the belief that benefits are
earned rights to which no stigma attaches, and that they depend at
least in part on past earnings of participants. The insurance analogy
is misleading, however, in fundamental respects. On the assumption
that the trust funds will continue to be financed approximately on a
current basis, the currently employed will always be taxed enough to
pay for the benefits of those who are retired. The practical importance
of distinguishing between social security and private insurance is that
it forces the maj or elements of the social security systern-ttaxes and
benefits-to be considered in the appropriate perspective. Benefits of
the currently retired need not, and should not, depend on their past
taxes; they should be based on an explicit decision reached by dem-
ocratic political processes as to how much of the Nation's total income
should be allocated for retirement benefits. Similarly, the tax should
not be regarded as an insurance premium, but rather as a financing
mechanism-to be judged on its own merits-for a large, essential
Government program.
PAGENO="0027"
ISSUES IN FUTURE FINANCING OF SOCIAL SECURITY
~ GEORGE A. BIsHoP*
CONTE NTS
Foreword Page
I. Introduction and Summary 22
II. Expansion of Social Insurance, Future Costs, and Limits to Payroll
Taxation 29
Growth of social insurance in the United States 30
Probable future costs 34
Population projections 34
Official cost and benefit estimates 36
Limits to payroll tax financing 39
III. Financing Principles in Social Insurance 41
Shifts in financing principles for OASDI 41
The concept of "actuarial soundness" 45
IV. Major Alternatives in Financing Social Insurance 46
Maintaining the present balance of objectives 47
Providing a general revenue contribution 49
Modifying the payroll tax 50
Separating welfare and insurance elements 51
V. Possibilities and Problems in a Two-Tier System 52
The Canadian system 52
Meaning of "Social insurance" 53
Justification for a wage-related, contributory system 54
Redistribution in OASDI 56
Complexity 58
Welfare versus insurance cost 59
Economic effects 60
Coordination with other public policies relating to the aged_ 61
Appendix:
A Diagrammatic Analysis of Social Insurance Taxation for Retire-
ment Benefits 63
TABLES AND CHARTS
Table:
1. OASDIII tax rates and maximum tax base under existing law and
under Administration's proposals of January 1967, 1967 actual,
1968-74 scheduled or proposed 22
2. Maximum tax base; combined tax rate and maximum tax on em-
ployer and employee for OASDHI, 1937-67 actual, 1968-87
scheduled 30
3. Major changes in coverage under OASDI, 1935-66 32
4. Projections of the U.S. population by broad age groups, 1965-2050 36
5. Joint economic committee staff projections GNP, social insurance
contributions and benefits, and total Government receipts and
expenditures, 1965 actual, and 1975 projected 38
Chart:
1. Average maximum, and minimum old age benefits and employee con-
tributions in constant dollars, 1940-66 31
2. OASDI trust fund receipts, expenditures, and assets, 1937-68 33
3. Growth in population, United States and key European countries,
1965-80 35
*Director, Federal Affairs Research, Tax Foundation Inc., New York.
NOTE: The views expressed in this paper are the author's and do not neces-
sarily reflect the views of the Tax Foundation.
21
PAGENO="0028"
22 OLD AGE INCOME ASSTJRANCE-PART III
Page
A-i. Hypothetical population age distribution 64
A-2. Hypothetical individual's wage, tax, and pension history, level-wage
assumption 66
A-3. Hypothetical individual's wage, tax, and pension history, increasing-
wage assumption 68
I. INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY
In 1966 a group of Senators introduced a bill providing for a 50-per-
cent increase in old-age retirement benefits, and liberalization of other
social insurance benefits.' This increase would be financed in part by
higher payroll taxes coming mainly from a rise in the maximum tax-
able wage to $15,000. The bill also included a. proposal for the use of
general revenues to meet a portion of the costs. Eventually over one-
third of social security trust fund outla.ys would be borne by sources
other than payroll taxes.
This bill was an indication of current pressures at work to modify
social security. It went much further than the administration's pro-
posa.ls introduced in January 1967, and these provided for substantial
amendments to the Social Security Act. The administration's pro-
posals were modified and scaled down in the bill reported by the House
Ways and Means Committee on August 7, 1967 (H.R. 12080). This bill
provided for a. 12~-percent increase in benefits, an increase in the
amount an individual may earn and still get. full retirement benefits,
and various other modifications of benefits. To finance these increased
benefits, the taxable earnings base would be increased from $6,600 to
$7,600 effective January 1, 1968, and tax rates in future years would be
changed as shown in table 1.
TABLE 1.-OASDHI 1 TAX RATES AND MAXIMUM TAX BASE UNDER EXISTING LAW, UNDER ADMINISTRATION'S
PROPOSALS OF JANUARY 1967 AND UNDER H.R. 12080 AS REPORTED BY THE HOUSE COMMITTEE ON WAYS AND
MEANS, AUGUST 1967, 1957 ACTUAL, 1968-74 SCHEDULED OR PROPOSED
Schedul
Year
Maximum
ed under existi
ng law
Administr
ation's 1967 p
roposals 2
H.R. 12080 as reported by the
Committee on Ways and Means,
August 1967
Combined
Tax rate
Maximum
Combined
Tax rate
Maximum Combined Tax rate
taxable
tax rate on
on self-
taxable
tax rate on
on sell-
taxable tax rate on on self-
wage
employerand
employee
em-
ployed
wage
employerand
employee
em-
ployed
wage employerand em-
employee' played 2
1967 $6, 600 8. 8 6. 4 $6, 600 8. 8 6. 4 $6, 600 8. 8 6. 4
1968 6, 600 8. 8 6. 4 7, 800 8. 8 6. 4 7, 600 8. 8 6. 4
1969 6, 600 9. 8 7. 1 7, 800 10. 0 7. 3 7, 600 9. 6 6. 9
1970 6. 600 9. 8 7. 1 7, 800 10. 0 7. 3 7, 600 9. 6 6. 9
1971 6, 600 9. 8 7. 1 9, 000 10. 0 7. 3 7, 600 10. 4 7, 5
1972 6,600 9. 8 7. 1 9, 000 10. 0 7. 3 7, 600 10. 4 7. 5
1973 6. 600 10. 8 7. 55 9, 000 11. 1 7. 55 7, 600 ii. 3 7. 65
1974 6,600 ~10.8 7.55 10,800 411.1 7.55 7,600 ~11.3 7.65
1 Old age, survivors, disability, and hospital insurance.
2 Set out in HR. 5710.
3 Includes portion of rate for hospital insurance (in which no change in the existing schedule was proposed by the Ad-
ministration in 1967). The hospital portion is scheduled to rise from 1 percent in 1967-72 to 1.1 percent in 1973.
4 Further increases are scheduled to 11.6 percent (HR. 5710) or 11.8 percent (HR. 12080) in 1987.
A further increase is scheduled to 11.3 percent in 1987.
Source: Social Security Administration.
1 Congressional Record, Senate, vol. 1,12, ~o. 122, 89th Cong., 2d sess., July 28, 1966.
pp. 16605-16612. The bill (S. 3661) was introduced by Senator Robert Kennedy and
sponsored by eight other Senators.
PAGENO="0029"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 23
The process of liberalizing social security benefits is likely to con-
tinue, bringing with it a continued increase in social security taxes. This
prospect raises important questions whidh the present study ti~ies to
answer at least in part. Among these questions are the following:
(1) Is the tax burden of caring for the aged likely to become
unduly heavy?
(2) More specifically, is the burden of taking care of the aged
likely to strain the limits of the payroll tax? In other words,
has the payroll tax about reached the upper limit to which it
can be pushed?
(3) Have we substantially abandoned the contributory prin-
ciple in favor of a "social adequacy" concept in OASDI 2
programs?
(4) What are the alternatives in attempting to resolve the con-
flicts between "social adequacy" and the strains of increasing
payroll taxation?
These are the major questions examined here. Other questions
touched on include `the following: Do recent increases in social secu-
rity benefits call for a substantial change in the present income tax
treatment of the aged? It is likely that the expansion of social insur-
ance will endanger the growth of private pension plans and private
provision for old age through other means? How are OASDI pro-
grams to be related to direct welfare programs?
Prof. Eveline Burns, of Columbia University, in a recent article
entitled "Social Security in Evolution: Toward What?" has distin-
guished three stages in the evolution of social insurance in most West-
ern countr~ies.3 The first she described as follows:
the initial form in which social insurance bore every-
where the imprint of its private insurance analogy. Benefits
were closely related to contributions; equity, rather than ade-
quacy, which scarcely came into question, was emphasized;
coverage was limited to the best risks with sizable previous
employment records; and the costs were assessed solely on the
potential beneficiaries and their employers.
Stage II she described as characterized by: "~< * * almost irresisti-
ble pressures to extend coverage-to additional persons and additional
risks-and these extensions would in turn modify the principles and
policies governing eligibility, benefits, and methods of financing. As
the poorer and more irregularly employed were brought into the sys-
tem, the strict relationship between benefits and earnings would become
evermore untenable because of the necessity to insure a meaningful
benefit to covered workers with low earnings. [The latter part of stage
II would be marked by consideration of] * * * the desirability of
a contribution from the general revenues."
Finally, stage III would be reached when * * thanks in large
measure to the widespread of social insurance, there was general a~-
2 OASI refers to the old-age and survivors insurance program which dates from 1935
(and the i939 amendments which included survivors insurance). OASDI includes in addi-
tion the disability insurance program which was adopted by the 1956 amendments to the
Social Security Act.
Canadian Tact' Journal, July-August i966, pp. 326-336. Professor Burns had originally
set out these stages in a paper, "Social Insurance in Evolution," American Economic Re-
view Supplement, vol. 34 (March 1944), pp. 199-211.
PAGENO="0030"
24 OLD AGE INCOME ASSDRAXCE-PART ill
ceptance of the doctrine of public assurance, without a. means test.,
of a minimum income for all."
The evolution Professor Burns has described is certainly not immu-
table. While it is not an exact description of the growth of social se-
curity in the United States, her outline does indicate possible direc.-
tions of change. The present study is mainly concerned with the ques-
tion of alternatives to following such stages further in the United
States.
The changes in social security considered by Congress in 1967 in-
volved a. multitude of issues of benefit levels for various groups, changes
in the maximum taxable income base, changes in the maximum earn-
ings limit for retirement benefits, and so forth. No attempt is made here
to examine all of these issues, or to deal with unemployment insurance
or direct public welfare programs (such as general old-age assistance,
aid to dependent children, and aid to the blind) covered in proposed
social security amendments.
Rather, the focus of the study is on questions of long-term financing
of OASDI programs. Limits on payroll taxation are considered, and
alternative ways of revising the present basis of financing are ex-
amined.
In summary form the answers suggested to the major question listed
above are as follows:
(1) The fvture ta~ burden for the aged.-The most. recent projec-
tions of the Bureau of the Census indicate that the ratio of the popula-
tion aged 65 and over will remain nearly a constant proportion (about
18 percent) of the population aged 20 to 64 through 1985. Thus the
burden on the working population will depend primarily on the ex-
tent to which retirement and other benefits to the aged are increased
in relation to average wages and salaries. Unlike some other countries,
the United States is not currently in the position of having to shoulder
an increasing tax burden because of a substantial rise in the. proportion
of the aged to the working population.
(2) is the burden of taking care of the aged likely to strain the
limits of the payroll tace? Has the payroll tace abovt reached the npper
limit to which it can be pushed?
While the proportion of the aged to the working population will
not change substantially in the next few decades, it. is likely that. Con-
gress will endeavor to improve the economic position of the aged and
to extend the range of risks covered by OASDI programs. Such
changes could well require significant increases in payroll taxes in
excess of those already scheduled under present law.
Under existing law the combined employer and employee, tax rate
is scheduled to reach 9.8 percent of taxable wages up to $6,600 in 1969,
and under the bill currently pending in Congress (H.R 12080) the rate
would reach 9.6 percent of $7,600. The scheduled rate in H.R.. 12080
will exceed 11 percent of taxable wages by 1973. The maximum tax on
~.n employee in 1968 would be increased from $290.40 under present
law to $334.40 under H.R. 12080. The maximum combined tax on
employer and employee would increase from $580.80 to $668.80.
These are heavy taxes on a.n income of $6,600 or even $7,600. By way
of comparison, a family with two children and an income of $5,000 in
1967 would pa.y a Federal income tax of $306 (`assuming standard de-
ductions). If this family had more tha.n one wage earner, its direct
payroll taxes would exceed its income tax.
PAGENO="0031"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSIJRANCE-PART iii 25
The employee also bears some part of the employer's portion of the
tax whether the tax is assumed to be shifted forward in the prices of
goods and services or to be shifted backward in the form of lower
money wages. (It is also possible that some portion of the tax falls on
profits and other nonwage income.)
Moreover, a combined payroll tax rate approaching 10 percent of
taxable wages is likely to have significant effects on business decisions
on investment in capital equipment, and on the hiring of unskilled
workers. A 10-percent tax on labor may intensify problems of unem-
ployment or partial unemployment among those groups whose un-
employment rate is already high.
The level of the payroll tax may be limited by another type of
consideration. It would not be reasonable, in the view of many people,
to levy social security payroll taxes at a rate in excess of what benefits
of a similar nature would cost if the employee were to provide them
through private forms of saving and insurance.
The payroll tax has risen to a level such that if a young worker
today, with earnings at least equal to the maximum taxable base,
computed the total of his expected payroll taxes plus interest over his
lifetime, the value `of his "contributions" would in many cases sub-
stantially exceed the discounted value of his expected benefits.
While experts differ in their views of how these calculations should
be made, such comparisons suggest a definite kind of limit to payroll
taxes. Young workers who begin to find themselves in this situation
can be expected to offer more and more objection to increased payroll
taxes.
Moreover, a general economic question is involved. It concerns allo-
cating to social insurance, through payroll taxes, resources that would
have more value in the purchase of private insurance and pensions.
The significance of such a limitation may be disputed by those who
point out that the insurance analogy is a very loose one and the object-
ive of "social adequacy" is more important. This leads to the third
major question dealt with in this study:
(3) Have we substantially abandoned the contributory principle in
favor of a "social adequacy" concept in OASDI programs?
From the beginning, the old-age and survivors insurance program
was a mixed system aimed in part at relating contributions to benefits
("individual equity") and in part at maki~ig benefits "adequate" in
terms of rough standards of minimum consumption levels. These two
concepts of "social ad~quacy" and "individual equity" are generally
conflicting, because very low income groups cannot be expected to pay
a full "price" for the benefits provided under social security.
The old-age benefit structure, moreover, is heavily weighted in favor
of those with low earnings records. The old-age retirement benefit in
1966 amounted to 62.97 percent of the first $110 of average monthly
covered wages, plus 22.9 percent of the next $290 of average monthly
covered wages, plus 21.4 percent of the remainder.
In addition, `the provisions for minimum amounts of monthly bene-
fits give the system a strong emphasis on social adequacy. The pressure
to go further in this direction was illustrated by the 1987 proposal
of the Administration to raise the minimum old-age retirement benefit
from $44 per month to $70 per month. Such an increase would have
been almost exclusively based on the concept of social adequacy. In
fact, the Ways and Means Committee modified this proposal to provide
PAGENO="0032"
26 OLD AGE INCOME ASSrUHANCE-PART III
a minimum benefit of $50 per month, at least partly on the grounds
that an increase in the minimum to $~0 would be too great a departure
from the principle of a wage-related, contributory system.
In short, while we have not entirely abandoned the contributory
principle in that benefits and administrative costs in the aggregate are
paid for through payroll taxes, the financing of these programs has,
in the course of time, put less emphasis on the relation between the
individnal's contributions and the benefits he will receive.
(4) TTT/iat are the alternatives in attempting to resolve the conflicts
between "social adequacy" ard the strains of increasing payroll
taxation?
Recent debates and pressures for change suggest various possibili-
ties for revision in OASDI financing. Four major alternatives are
examined here:
(a) Continue approximately the present balance between the objec-
tives of social adequacy and individual equity, accepting the possi-
bility of increased conflicts and strains as the payroll tax rate and
base increase.
(b) Provide a general revenue contribution to OASDI trust funds
with a probable increase in the emphasis given to social adequacy.
(c) Modify the payroll tax by substantially increasing the maxi-
mum `taxable wages or by introducing an exemption to reduce the
burden on low income groups.
(d) Separate the benefits schedule in two portions, one of which
would be closely related to contributions on an individual equity basis,
and a second which would explicitly be based on adequacy considera-
tions and be financed separately by general revenues.
The choice among these alternatives depends in part on value judg-
ments concerning the relative i~nportance of the objectives involved.
However, technical and economic issues are also involved. The chief
issues of both kinds in brief are as follows:
(a) IJlaintainirg the present system.-Through a long political
process the LTnitecl States has developed a social insurance system that
provides a working balance between the objectives of adequacy and
inclividuni equity. This balance is being strained as the payroll tax
burden grows. Some view this "strain" as a useful restraint on exces-
sive expenditures for benefits.
On a more technical level, the present system of payroll tax financing
contains an important fiscal control device. The system requires the
levying of additional payroll taxes at the same time that increased
benefit levels are adopted, and the taxes are set. so as to meet expected
benefits and administrative costs over a bug period. This is a device
that is often absent in the Federal Government's general budget,
although similar procedures have been proposed for administrative
budget pro~rams.
A general revenue contribution to OASDI trust funds could be
fitted into the same type of fiscal control procedure. For example, any
proposed increased levy for social security could require an increase
in income taxes earmarked for OASDI trust funds. Even with such
a procedure, benefits might increase faster than with exclusive reliance
on the payroll tax both because income tax revenues are more respon-
sive to economic growth a.nd because Congress might be more ready
to use an income tax levy than a payroll tax increase to raise the
PAGENO="0033"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 27
benefit schedule. Until recently, however, the payroll tax was rela-
tively low. People generally appear to have had an exaggerated ideL
of `the extent to which they were paying for their own benefits. The
increase in benefits may have seemed of more significance to the public
generally than the increase in taxes.
The attitude toward payroll taxes could change markedly. At cur-
rent and prospective payroll tax levels, an income tax increase for
the purpose of raising benefits levels might seem to be an easy way
out of the conflict between adequacy and individual equity.
(b) Providing a general revenue contribution.-Many who argue
for a general revenue contribution do so because they want a large
increase in social security benefits. They see such a contribution as a
means of raising benefits `to more "adequate" levels in relation to
minimum family budget standards.
Moreover, it is argued that not only is the payroll tax high, but
that this is a poor way to finance increases in benefits. If the OASDI
system is to become an instrument for preventing or removing poverty,
it would hardly be fair to do so with a payroll tax that reaches its
maximum at $6,600 or $7,600. An increased emphasis on social ade-
quacy would more logically be achieved through taxes levied on the
general taxpayer.
Historically, another argument has been used for a general revenue
contribu'tion. It is that in the transitional stage to a "mature" social
insurance system, most people become eligible for benefits even though
they have not "contributed" anything like the full cost of those bene-
fits. Until most workers have contributed during a full working life-
time at rates commensurate with the benefits they will receive, there
is a large windfall accruing to current beneficiaries. This windfall,
it is argued, constitutes an "unfunded liability" the burden of which
should be borne by all taxpayers through revenues rather than through
the payroll tax alone. Use of the payroll tax is largely justified by `the
relation between an individual's contributions and his benefits, so that
the "redistribution" in favor of current beneficiaries receiving wind-
falls should be met by a general levy.
(c) Modifying the payroll tax.-A closely related proposal is to
modify `the payroll tax to make it more like an income tax: to allow
personal exemptions and to increase substantially the maximum wage
base. This would relate the tax burden more closely to "ability to pay"
and check the increasing "regressivity" of the total tax structure that
goes wi'th increased reliance on the payroll tax.
A higher maximum wage base would also mean increased benefits.
Under the present benefit structure, which is heavily weighted in favor
of those with low earnings records, a higher maximum tax base would
serve to increase the emphasis on social adequacy. Benefits would go
up for those earning as much or more than the maximum taxable
wage, but not in proportion to `the increase in wages or payroll taxes.
Such an alternative would depart further from the contributory, or
"individual equity," basis of financing.
(d) Separating the benefit schedule and its financing into two
portions.-The conflict between the objectives of social adequacy and
individual equity suggests the possibility of separating the major
elements in OASDI programs designed to meet these different objec-
tives: one which would emphasize "insurance"~ elements, and another
which would emphasize welfare or adequacy elements.
83-200-67-pt. 3-3
PAGENO="0034"
28 OLD AGE INCOME ~ASSiJRANCE-PAR'T III
In the broadest terms, the "welfare" element consists of that part
of benefits which is determined primarily on the basis of adequacy-
in particular, the minimum benefits which bea.r no relation to average
covered wages of the beneficiary except that covered wages must be
very low. The "insurance" element consists of that part of benefits
which is, or can be, related to average covered wages. Such a separation
would involve a substantial revision of the benefit structure and raise
many problems of defining an appropriate relation between benefits
and the individual's contributions.
Some countries have developed social security systems which dis-
tinguish more clearly than in the United States between contributory
social insurance programs and other forms of socia.l security. Canada,
for example, now has a two-tier system consisting of a universal old-
age pension, financed by a surcharge on the individual income tax,
the corporation income tax, and the Federal sales tax, plus a contribu-
tory "Canada pension plan" financed by payroll taxes much more
closely related to benefits than in the United States. Each part of the
system is financed through a separate trust fund. Thus the "fiscal
control" element is present in both parts of the system.
A separation of insurance elements means a greater reliance on the
benefit principle of taxation. The economic argument here is as follows:
Where the benefits of public expenditures go to specific groups of indi-
viduals, and where ta.xes for the support of these expenditures can be
effectively levied on these same groups, the public will, on the whole,
be better off than if these expenditures were financed out of general
revenues.
Isolating an insurance element in social security raises questions of
whether there are insurable risks that are unlikely to ~e met `by private
enterprise and private saving, and for which compulsory coverage by
a governmental system may be justified.
From the beginning of the social security system, compulsory pro-
vision for old age has been justified in part by the argument that with-
out such provision many of the aged would become public charges.
This argument still has relevance in a period of growing incomes and
substantially full employment though perhaps less tha.ii in the 1930's.
As family income increases, provision for their own retirement be-
comes one of the services that more and more people want to buy.
Forcing people to save through social insurance may appear to be
an undue interference with individual choice. However, the evidence
seems to be that social security has had the effect in the past of height-
ening people's awareness of the need for saving for old age and pro-
tection against risks of death and disability. Whether or not this ef-
fect' may continue is another matter. If social security taxes continue
to rise, the ability of people to save in other ways may be limited.
It would not seem reasonable to compel purchase of Government in-
surance on a scale that would cheek the growth of private provision
for old age.
However, the arguments may be arrayed on the question of coin-
pulsory saving for old age, at least a minimum of such compulsion
is accepted in most Western countries. Acceptance `of such compulsion
seems to be a part of the decline of dependence on the family as an
old-age security system.
Certain limitations of private provision for old age continue to pro-
vide a justification for a governmental system. Even though an em-
PAGENO="0035"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 29
ployee might not choose to save toward his old age, some portion of
the cost of a minimum old-age pension has come to be regarded as a
necessary part of the cost of production of goods and services.
Our social insurance system compels nearly every , employer as well
as his employee to contribute to OASDI. The employee remains cov-
ered and, in a sense, received credit for his and his employer's contri-
bution no matter how often he changes jobs. These features of quick
"vesting" of pension and insurance rights and of "portability" are
the very features that are difficult to provide for all employees under
existing private pensions.
This difference between private and "social" systems is due in part
to the fact `that the building up of investment reserves is the essential
means by which private pension plans insure that funds will be avail-
able for pensions when covered employees retire. A social insurance
system with nearly universal coverage does not need this device to
insure payment. The Government's promise t'o pay, although not in the
form of a contract, is sufficient for most people, and it `is `backed pri-
marily by the power to tax rather than by a reserve fund. For this
and other reasons, Congress has, in effect, accepted a virtual pay-as-
you-go system with only limited reserves for contingency purposes.
A pay-as-you-go social insurance `system is a current taxing process
to meet current benefit payments and expenses. This process may have
little effect on the national rate of saving and investment; if anything,
the effect is to reduce the rate of national saving because those who
currently pay taxes are generally net savers, while beneficiaries gen-
erally are dissaving. Private pension funds, on the other hand, ac-
cording to recent studies, have a substaiTtial effect in increasing the na-
tional rate of saving. This consideration would become important if
social insurance were provided on such a scale as to check the growth
of private pension funds or private saving in other forms.
A separation of "welfare" and "insurance" elements in OASDI pro-
grams could mean a more efficient and more equitable financing system.
But, it would be difficult to accomplish. It would involve complex prob-
lems of relating benefits to contributions; some value judgments on the'
importance of the objectives of "social welfare" and "individual
equity"; and basic economic and political decisions in drawing an.
appropriate line between social and private insurance.
Sections II and III provide a brief review of the expansion of social
insurance in the United States and of shifts in the financing principles'
involved. Section IV `presents major alternatives or possibilities for re-
vising the present system of financing OASDI programs. Section V
examines in more detail the last alternative described above; namely,
a possible separation of major welfare and insurance elements in
OASDI programs. This alternative has so far received very little con-
sideration in the United States.
II. EXPANSION OF SOCIAL INSURANCE, FUTURE COSTS, AND LIMITS TO
PAYROLL TAXATION
Governmental policies toward the aged took a sharp turn in the mid-
1930's with the adoption of the essential basis of the present social secu-
rity system. T'his history of `social security has been told and analyzed
PAGENO="0036"
30 OLD AGE INCOME~ ASSURANCE-PART III
in a voluminous literature.1 For the purpose of the present study, only
a few of the major changes in the early history need be noted. how-
ever, some sub~tantia1 changes in the past two decades need more em-
phasis than they have so far received.
GROWTH OF SOCIAL INSURANCE IN THE UNITED STATES
The Social Security Act of 1935 embodied a program for old-age
retirement benefits supported by payroll taxes levied in equal amounts
on the employer and employee in industry and commerce.2 Benefits
for dependents and survivors were added in 1939.
The initial maximum wage base, which remained unchanged until
1951, was $3,000. The initial tax rate was 1 percent on the employer
and 1 percent on the employee. This rate remained unchanged until
1950 (table 2).
TABLE 2.-MAXIMUM TAX BASE, COMBINED TAX RATE, AND MAXIMUM TAX ON EMPLOYER AND EMPLOYEE FOR
OASDHI' 1937-67 ACTUAL, 1968-87 AS SCHEDULED IN SOCIAL SECURITY AMENDMENTS OF 1965
Year
Maximum taxable
base
Combined tax
rate 2 (percent)
Maximum tax
-
Combined em- E
ployer-employee 3
mployee only 3
1937-49
1950
1951-53
1954
1955-56
1957-58
1959
1960-61
1962
1963-65
1966
1967-68
1969-72
$3,000
3,000
3, 600
3,600
4,200
4,200
4,800
4,800
4, 800
4, 800
6,600
6, 600
6,600
2.0
3.0
3. 0
4.0
4.0
4.5
5.0
6.0
6. 25
7. 25
8.4
8. 8
9.8
$60
90
108
144
168
189
240
288
300
348
554
581
647
$30
45
54
72
84
95
120
144
150
174
277
290
323
1973-75
1976-79
1980-86
6,600
6,600
6,600
10.8
10.9
11.1
713
719
733
356
360
366
1987 and alter
6,600
11.3
746
373
I Old age, survivors, disability, and hospital insurance. Disability not included until 1956; hospital insurance, not until
1956.
2 Beginning in 1951, the self-employed covered by the system were subject to a rate equal to three-quarters of the
combined rate on employer and employee.
3 Rounded to nearest dollar.
Source. Social Security Administration.
In constant dollars, the maximum tax payable fell until 1950 (be-
cause of the fixed tax rate and ceiling on the tax base). Since that
date, the maximum tax has increased very substantially in constant
dollars, and much more than the average, maximum, and minimum
monthly benefits (chart 1).
1 U.s. Department of Health, Education, and Welfare, Basic Readings in Social Security
(Washington, D.C., 1960), a bibliography of basic references. (See also Tax Foundation
Research Bibliography No. 20, The Social Security Payroll Taco, and Research Publication
No. 5, Economic Aspects of the Social Security Taco, pp. 9-20.)
2 The Social Security Act covered a wide range of programs In addition to old-age
Insurance. The various public assistance programs and unemployment Insurance are not
examined In this study.
PAGENO="0037"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
31
-~
~
- j_ ± -- + ~
1
_____ ~9
! ~
~ ~ Th L ~ ;N ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~
~ ~ ~ h ~ I ~ H- ~ ~ ~ ~) H H-HH f-i--H ~ L~f IH
1 ~ ~i ~ iu~~ L!~!
~ ~ ~! H HH ~-4-hH-H--~ H~J~ ~ 1 ~ t\~HI
~t I I HI ~ ____________
~ ~
°
1 - . . t ::-- . ... :...,`l~;: :;r~l;~~:I;\--J:/-
- ~ L-_-1 .__L_LLJ~ ~L4JI~j_LJ ~L~J/ I
I I ~
I - - ~r~yr1-~~t -
~ .. TTHI .::::: .: :. .i.;t~:t :j:~~: :~- ~
I ~_~I~L ~41 I -
I:-. ..~. :~ . :~ :. ...:.:I:.. :>~~..:I~.:-I:-:. f?i:f.;:~.n~- :1:::
- ~ ~
-~--------F--------~-------I-----~-------__~---.--------- .i~
-
~1~4-~I I `1 Ii
:1:': L..! -. .i_* J._::I;:.-1 ::t:-:-I --i-- ~-` 0
---T~-I....:..: :. .--I-~~_~. ;!...L: I:: i :::~.. :f_4_~~~j~jj:
~i;~1T: ~~:j- I~:.H
L-'E~ ~
PAGENO="0038"
32 OLD AGE IYCOME ASS1JRA~CE-PART III
No substantial change in coverage, was made until 1951 when self-
employed (except farmers and professional people) were included
along with certain other groups. Other changes in coverage are shown
in table 3.
TABLE 3.-MAJOR CHANGES IN COVERAGE UNDER OASDI `1935-66
Effective
Compulsory coverage added
. Elective coverage added
date
1937
1951
All workers in commerce and industry, except railroads, in conti-
nental United States, Alaska, and Hawaii.
Self-employed (except farm and professional), regularly employed
farm and domestic workers, Federal civilian workers not under
retirement program, Americans employed outside United States
by American employers, residents of Puerto Rico and Virgin
Islands.
None.
State and local government employees
not under retirement system, em-
ployees of nonprofit institutions.
1955
1956
Farm self-employed, professional self-employed (except lawyers
and medical professionals), most farm and domestic workers,
Lawyers, dentists, optometrists, chiropractors, osteopaths, vet-
erinarians, and other medical professionals (except doctors of
medicine), materially participating form-landlords, Armed
Forces.
State and local government employees
under retirement system, ministers.
1961
1965
Residents of Guam and American Samoa, Peace Corps volunteers
Doctors of medicine
I OASI only prier to 1956; OASDI prior to 1956.
Source. Social Security Administration and Tax Foundation, "Economic Aspects of the Social Security Tax" (New
York: 1966).
In 1955 coverage was substantially broadened to include farmers,
most professional, self-employed people, and State and local govern-
ment employees (on an elective basis) whether or not they were
covered by State and local retirement systems. At the same time,
the maximum tax base was raised to $4,200.
By 1966 the combined employer-employee rate was up to 8.4 percent
and the maximum tax base was $6,600. The 1966 tax increase was
the largest increase in the history of the act.
Over the first 20 years of operation, the assets of the trust funds
accumulated to $23 billion, and thereafter fell off somewhat (chart 2).
The trust fund assets are expected to increase substantially again in
the future under present law. The rate of growth, however, is likely
to be smaller than the rate in the years prior to 1956.
PAGENO="0039"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
33
ri ~
I.
H~ ~
I~! H~11-~ ~
~ c,cL~L _____
L~ ~ _
~ HiLL _____
J~L~-kH~ :~L1~ ~Lt~
EILI TTf~4~4~444444;
~ ~1T~T - fl~
i~ -~ L I
.._~J_~_____
L~\L~
.: - :.[
PAGENO="0040"
34 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
The most significant change in the system since 1956 was the addi-
tion in 1966 of health insurance for those aged 65 and over. Health
insurance (popularly known as medicare) is a two-part program, one
of which, the "basic" program, is compulsory and financed by a sepa-
rate portion of the tax rate amounting in 1967 and 1968 to 0.5 percent
for the employee (and also for the employer and self-employed). The
basic program provides certain inpatient hospital services, post-
hospital home health visits, posthospital extended care facility services
(i.e., skilled nursing homes), and outpatient diagnostic services. The
second part of the program is a supplementary medical insurance
plan which covers the major part of the doctors' bills and certain
other services for those 65 and over. This portion of the program is
financed jointly by monthly contributions of persons who elect to
participate and by a contribution from general Government revenues.
The addition of health insurance was not only a major departure
in the kind of risks covered, but also was the first use of voluntary
type program and of a continuing general revenue contribution.
PROBABLE FUTURE COSTS
Increased social security benefits and the expansion of the kinds
of risks covered suggest that in the future we will be paying a heavy
tax burden for the support of the aged.
The question of the future size of the tax burden for social security
type programs is at least as important as the closely related questions
of how that burden is to be allocated among different groups of people
and types of taxes.
Total social security tax collections have risen rapidly, not only in
absolute terms, but also as a percentage of total Federal tax collections.
In 1949 OASI tax collections amounted to 4.1 percent of the Federal
total; by 1967 the share had risen to 16 percent. This shift is a sub-
stantial change in the Federal tax structure.
Are we likely to see this share continue to rise substantially?
POPULATION PROJECTIONS
The first step in answering this question is to look at the prospective
growth in the aged population as compared with the total population
and the labor force. A recent set of charts published by the National
Industrial Conference Board shows that, as compared with the coun-
tries of Western Europe, the United States is in a relatively easy
position in the ratio of dependent to working population (chart 3).
Over the next decade and a half the number of people aged 65 and over
in the United States will rise almost in the same proportion as those
of working age, while the younger age groups will increase less
rapidly (table 4). In Western Europe, by contrast, the population
aged 65 and over will increase relatively much more than the working
population.
PAGENO="0041"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
35
00
00
100
cH~Kr. 3
G~o~th in Popu'ation
U. S..and.. K~y european Countries
lnda;~o~, 1965 100
Total Population
Worhinçj Age
Under 15
965 `70 `75 `80 1965 `70 `75 `80
Note: Projections by Oreanization for Economic Cooperation and Development
Population e,cludes mig~otion. Data osof Jorwary 1 of years shown
Sources: OECD; The Confo~eoce 8oerd
Spaces betwoen ticfl~ represent 5poin?s
o! th~ Index
GERMANY
- 57.9 million,
/
100
PAGENO="0042"
36 OLD AGE INCOME ASST.JEA~CE-PART III
TABLE 4-PROJECTIONS OF THE U.S. POPULATION BY BROAD AGE GROUPS, 1965-2050
LOW-COST PROJECTION
Year
Population (in thousands)
65 sod o
Percent of
ver as-
Ratio of
Under 20
20 to 64 65 and
Total
over
total
20 to 64
1965
1970
1975
1980
1990
2000
2010
2020
2030
2040
2050
10,139
82. 400
85840
90,313
106,181
119, 023
133,672
151,593
169, 326
190,189
213,160
103,209 18.711
111.500 20,296
121245 22,016
131,858 24.044
149,144 28,185
174, 838 29, 577
204,336 31,753
227,542 41,382
255, 057 50, 437
289,091 54,151
322,410 62,426
202,059
214,196
229,101
246 215
283,510
323, 438
369,761
420,517
474, 880
533,431
597,996
9.3
9.5
9.6
9.8
9.9
9. 1
8.6
9.8
10.6
10.2
10.4
.181
.182
.182
.182
.189
. 169
.155
.182
.198
.187
.194
HIGH-COST PROJECTION
1965
1970
1975
1980
1990
2000
2010
2020
2030
2040
2050
80 139
81,868
82,629
85331
93, 481
98,353
103,111
109,756
115,348
121,520
128, 087
103,209 18,711
111,580 20,405
121,439 22.304
132,195 24; 585
149. 303 29, 458
171,142 31,756
193,385 34,706
205. 170 45,386
215.544 55,678
229,968 58,470
241, 154 63, 209
202,059
213,853
227,372
242,111
272, 250
301,251
331,202
360,312
386,570
459,958
432, 450
9.3
9.5
9.8
10.2
10.8
10.5
10.5
12.6
14.4
14.3
14.6
.181
.183
.184
.186
.197
.186
.179
.221
.258
.254
.262
Source: Reproduced from `United States Population Projections for OASDHI," Social Security Administration Actuarial
Study No. 62, December 1966.
The difference is not quite so significant as these figures would
suggest because the increase in the. labor force in the United States
will consist, relatively more than in Western Europe, of the younger
age groups whose average productivity is lower; indeed, in the
United States the number in the group 45 to 65 will scarcely
increase at all.
In short, so far as mere numbers are concerned, the problems of
meeting the needs of the aged in the United States `will be no
greater tha.n in the past. There are also other influences working to
reduce the public burdens for the age.d. One is the expansion of
private pension funds and a. general improvement in the income and
asset position of the aged. On the other hand, the aged represent a
large fraction of the "poor" in this country, and efforts to raise
their relative, as well as their absolute living standards, could sub-
stantially increase the burden.
OFFICIAL COST AND BENEFIT ESTIMA'I~S
A chief function of the Office of the Actuary in the Social Seen-
r1ty Administration is to make both long- and short-range estimates
of future benefits, administrative costs, and contributions under
social security programs.3
These estimates are usually made on the basis of the existing level
of wages and the Jevel of benefits under existing or proposed legis-
The latest of these studies is Long-Range Cost Estfsnate.s for Old-Age Surrivors and
Disability Insurance, 1966, Actuarial Study No. 63, January 1967.
PAGENO="0043"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 37
lation. On the "level wage" assumption-i.e., the general level of
wages is assumed to stay constant-account is taken of projected
changes in population by age group and the likely numbers of bene-
ficiaries and their average benefit levels.
The latest projections show a sizable increase in the OASDI trust
funds. On the basis of these projections, there have been proposals
to limit increases in benefits in the near future to levels that would
merely use up the prospective growth in contributions as the popu-
lation increases, and involve no tax rate of maximum wage base
increase.4
While the "level wage" assumption is the actuarial procedure
officially sanctioned for long-range estimates, it obviously leaves
open the questions of what the effects will be of rising wage and
price levels, and of increased levels of benefits that very likely will
be adopted in the future.
Short- and intermediate-range projections are made on the
assumption of increasing wage levels, but for the purpose of esti-
mating fiscal effects rather than determining contribution rates. The
short-range estimates are important for purposes of economic poli-
cies affecting stability and growth in the near future. The long-
range estimates affect primarily the determination of contribution
rates and the distribution of the costs or burden of the program.5
The level wage `assumption builds a moderate safety factor into
the cost estimates. More importantly, it is argued that long-range
cost estimates (in the TJnited States) are for a fixed schedule of
benefits related to current economic conditions. Consequently, it
would be illogical to use an increasing earnings assumption without
also using a "dynamic" assumption about `benefit levels; and to do
this would involve the actuary in the difficult task of projecting
future legislative changes in benefits. An increasing earnings
assumption would be appropriate only if the benefit schedule in the
law were also "dynamic"; i.e., automatically adjusted `for changes
in earnings levels.6
However, for at least two reasons use of the level wage assumption
may be questioned. The first is that recent economic and legislative
history shows that realistically a "dynamic" benefit structure must be
taken into account. It can be argued that the most relevant set of as-
sumptions for actuarial analysis of social security financing-and
thereby for determining the allocation of costs- is the "dynamic" set
which takes account `both of increasing wage levels and prospective
increases in benefit levels. (See appendix.)
The second reason is that since more and more economic policy deci-
sions, both public and private, are based on long-range projections
that take account of likely price increases as well as growing levels of
The U.S. Chamber of Commerce and the National Association of Manufacturers took
this position in statements before the House Ways and Means Committtee In i967.
For further discussion see 1-lenry Aaron, "Benefits Tinder the American Social Security
System, in Otto Eckstein, ed. Studies in the Economics of Income Maintenance (Wash-
ington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1966), pp. 53-61. For an explanation of the
long-range methodology see Robert J. Myers, Social Insurance and Allied Government
Programs (Homewood, Ill.: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1965), ch. VIII.
6 Robert J. Myers, "The Applicability of Projected Economic-Trend Assumptions In
Medium- and Long-Range Actuarial Cost Estimates for Pension Systems." reprint from
Actas de La III Conference Internacional cia Actuaries y Estadigrafos de la Seguridad
Social, Madrid, November 1962.
PAGENO="0044"
38 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
"real" income, it is important to look at social insurance projections
based on these more realistic assumptions.
The staff of the Joint Economic Committee of Congress has recently
released a long-range projection entitled, U.S. Econon-tie Growth to
1978: Potentials and Problems. This study projects contributions for
social insurance under scheduled rate changes but on assumptions of
increasing money and real wage levels. It also projects social insurance
benefits on the basis of estimates of broadened programs that will
affect future payments. These projections suggest a 160-percent in-
crease in the amount of OASI contributions from 1965 to 1975, while
gross national product is expected to increase by 77 percent. OASI
contributions would go from 2.6 percent or GNP in 1965 to 3.7 percent
of GNP in 1975. (See table 5.)
The projections are based on existing programs or programs just
adopted. The figures for 1975 could be much larger if average benefit
levels were substantially liberalized.7
TABLE 5.-JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE STAFF PROJECTIONS OF GNP, SOCIAL INSURANCE CONTRIBUTIONS
AND BENEFITS, AND TOTAL GOVERNMENT RECEIPTS AND EXPENDITURES
1965 ACTUAL AND 1975 PROJECTED
Amount in billions Percent of GNP
1965 1975' 1965 19751
GNP $681.2 $1,205.0
Personal income 535.1 961.8
Contributions for social insurance 2 29. 2 66. 0 4. 3 5. 5
OASI 17. 4 45. 0 2. 6 3. 7
Unemployment insurance 3.8 6.8 .6 .6
Other 8.0 14.5 1.2 1.2
Government transfer payments to persons 37. 1 79. 5 5. 4 6. 6
OASI 18. 1 42. 7 2. 7 3. 5
Unemployment insurance 2. 3 4. 4 . 3 - 4
Other 3 16. 8 32. 4 2. 5 2. 7
Total Government re:eipts and expenditures:
Federal Government:
Receipts under 1965 tax law 124. 9 246. 9 18. 3 20. 5
Expenditures4 123.4 203.1 18.2 16.9
Surplus or deficit (-) 1. 6 43. 8 (5) 3. 6
State and local governments:
Receipts (less Federal grants-in-aid) 64. 1 131. 0 9. 4 10. 9
Expenditures (less Federal grants-in-aid) 62. 5 130. 6 9. 2 10. 8
Surplus or deficit (-) 1. 6 0. 4 (5) (5)
I Price level for GNP assumed to rise at 1.5 percent per year. Average annual gain in real output per man-hour was
assumed to be 3 percent. Unemployment was assumed to be 4 percent of labor force (projection B).
2 Unden existing legislation with adjustments for scheduled changes in tax rates and wage base.
3 Expendituren under new programs in present legislation extrapolated in part on a judgmental basis. (See source, p. 21.)
4 Assumes some reduction in defenve expenditures after 1967, and an increase in Federal grants-in-aid from
$11,200,000,000 in 1965 to $25,000,000,000 in 1975.
o Less than 0.05 percent.
Source: `US. Economic Growth to 1975: Potentials and Problems" study prepared for the Subcommittee on Economic
Progress, Joint Economic Committee, 89th Cong., 2d sess., 1966, pp. 21, 24, 27.
These projections indicate that social insurance programs will con-
tinue to rise relative to national income and product. However, the
Cost and benefit estimates on increasing earning assumptions were included In The 1966
4nsso'al Repo,-t of tile Board of Trustees of the Federal Old-Age and Survivors Insurance
and Disability Insurance Trust Funds, Feb. 28, 1966. pp. 39-40. These estimates showed
slightly lower level of contributions and benefits for 1975 than the Joint Economic Com-
mittee sta~ study.
PAGENO="0045"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 39
rise will essentially be due to new and expanded programs rather
than to growth in the numbers of aged relative to the total or the
working population.
LIMITS TO PAYROLL TAX FINANCING
The history and scheduled increases in the social security payroll
tax are shown in table 2 (p. 30). Under existing law the combined
employer and employee tax rate is scheduled to reach 9.8 percent of
taxable wages up to $6,600 in 1969. Under the bill, reported by the
House Committee on Ways and Means in August 1967 (H.R. 12080),
the rate would reach 9.6 percent of $7,600. The scheduled rate in H.1R.
12080 will exceed 11 percent of taxable wages by 1973.
The maximum tax for an employee in 1968 would be increased from
$290.40 under present law to $334.40 under 11.11. 12080. The maximum
combined tax on employer and employee would increase from $580.80
to $668.80.
These are heavy taxes on an income of $6,600 or even $7,600. By way
of comparison, a family with two children and income of $5,000 in
1967 would pay a Federal income tax of $306 (assuming standard
deductions). At lower income levels the social security tax for most
families would exceed the income tax. If the family had more than
one wage earner, its direct payroll tax would substantially exceed its
income tax.
The employee also bears some part of the employer's portion of the
tax whether the tax is assumed to be shifted forward in the prices of
goods and services or to be shifted backward in the form of lower
money wages.8
That the payroll tax is reaching very burdensome levels was brought
home to many people in 1966 when the maximum tax, as a result of
a combined rate and base increase, went up by $103 for the employee
alone-an increase of 59 percent in 1 year. The reaction of organized
labor was shown in a recent publication of the AFL-CIO :~
Clearly, the point is nearing when it will be difficult to tax
low-paid workers at much higher rates. This creates a
dilemma. Sooner or later, the principle that payroll taxes
shall be the sole source of funding should be modified or
goals must be lowered to the less than adequate improvements
that can be financed this way.
A combined payroll tax rate approaching 10 percent of taxable
wages is likely to have significant effects on business decisions. A 10-
percent tax on additional labor (at least that involving the hiring
of new employees) could well tip the balance in favor of de.cisions to
invest further in laborsaving equipment.1° Moreover, the payroll tax
is a relatively heavy tax on lower paid, less skilled labor. The impact
may be significant on industries which rely more than the average on
such labor. A tax impact which discourages the hiring of unskilled
workers goes in the opposite direction to Government policies and pro-
B There Is also the possibility that a portion of the tax may be shifted to profits and rents.
Bert Seidman, "The Case for Higher Social Security Benefits," reprinted from the AFt,-.
ClO Federationist, January 1967.
iS For further analysis, see Tax Foundation, Economic A8pects of the ,S~ocial ~5ecurity Tax
(New York, 1960), ch. III.
PAGENO="0046"
40 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
grams which are designed to relieve the relatively high unemployment.
rates among unskilled groups.
It is true that other taxes also have undesirable effects, but those of
a payroll tax of 10 percent or more of wages up to a limited amount
in most respects seem likely to be more significant than those of in-
come taxes."
The level of the payroll tax may be limited by another type of con-
sideration. It would not. be reasonable, in the view of many people,
to levy social security payroll taxes at a rate in excess of what similar
benefits would cost if the employee were able to provide them through
private forms of saving and insurance.
The payroll tax has now risen to a. level such that, on the basis of
certain assumptions, the. total value (including interest) of eimploijee
taxes pa.id over a lifetime on the wages of some people now entering
the labor force will exceed the discounted value of benefits to be re-
ceived by these "new entrants." For example, a. calculation by Mr. Ray
Peterson, formerly vice president of the Equitable Life Assurance
Society of the United States, shows that the total value of employee
taxes paid (under the Social Security Act. as amended through 1965)
by a sin qle male retiring in the year 2010 would exceed his retirement
benefits by 65 percent.'2
A calculation by the Chief Actuary of the Social Security Ad-
ministration shows t.hat the average new entrant into the labor force
today would just about pay for his retirement benefits from his own
contributions.'3 (The contributions-benefit ratio varies substantially
with family status, age of entry into the labor force, age of retirement,
and other factors.)
For workers who earn at least the maximum taxable wages, a further
increase in the payroll tax could substantially exceed such a limit,
because benefits are heavily weighed in favor of those with lower
earnings.
It has been argued that a. substantial portion of the employer's tax
is shifted `back to the worker in the form of lower money wages and
should, consequently, be `taken into account in such comparisons of
taxes and benefits.'4 Oii the other hand, it is argued that, regardless
of the incidence of the tax, the employer's portion is a general contribu-
tion on behalf of all covered workers and cannot be attributed directly
to the employee on whose wages the. tax is levied.
The individual employee is likely to be mainly concerned with the
size of his own contribution, changes in which have a direct impact
on his take-home pay. From a broader economic point of view, the
value of resources diverted to social insurance should be compared with
their potential value in private use~. Potential private uses may in-
clude not only private personal saving, but also private pension plans
largely financed by employer contributions. If the principle of "in-
U For a discussion of effects, see Elizabeth Deran, "Some Economic Effects of High Taxes
for Social Insurance," paper prepared for the Joint Economic Committee Compendium on
Old-Age Income Assurance, 1967.
~ Tax Foundation, Economic Analysis of the Social Security Ta~ (New York, 1966), p. 4S.
13 Robert J. Myers, "Analysis of Whether the Young Worker Receives His Money's Worth
under' Social Security," mimeographed memorandum, Social Security Administration.
Mar. 5, 1967. More detailed calculations can be found in Studies on the Relationship of
Contributions to Benefits in Old-Age Benefit Awards, Social Security Administration
Actuarial Note No~ 20; June 1965.
n James 51. Buchanan and Cohn D. Campbell, "Voluntary Social Security," Wall Street
Journal, Dec. 20, 1966.
PAGENO="0047"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 41
dividual equity" is judged to be of primary importance in social in-
surance, then employer contributions can hardly be omitted entirely
from comparisons of individual tax-benefit ratios.
In summary, the expansion of social insurance programs in the
United States is pushing the payroll tax to discernible limits. Views
on these limits depend in part on judgments concerning the relative
importance of insurance elements versus the objective of "social ade-
quacy." The scale on which both these objectives are being pursued
is emphasizing the conflicts between them and the need for reexamin-
ing the major policy alternatives.
III. FINANCING P1UNcIPLE5 IN SOCIAL INSURANCE
In a short space it is impossible to do justice to the extended analyses
and debates that have raged over the financing of social insurance
programs.1 Nevertheless, some review of how we got where we are in
1967 is necessary to an analysis of current policy alternatives.
SHIFTS IN FINANCING PRINCIPLES FOR OASDI
The reports of several advisory groups on social security programs
constitute a record of the "mainstream" of thought on social security
financing. The first of these groups, the Committee on Economic Se-
curity, provided the initial recommendations for present programs
in 1935. Its history, activities and views, have been reviewed by its
executive director, Edwin E. Witte, in The Development of the Social
Security Act (Madison, University of Wisconsin, 1962).
This committee based its recommendations for old-age insurance
in part on two general financing principles, one of which was not
adopted in the `original act, and another which was subsequently
sharply modified. Its recommendation `for a general revenue contribu-
tion to the trust fund in addition to payroll taxes was not adopted.
The principle of accumulation of a substantial reserve to meet future
liabilities was very much modified by later amendments.2
The 1939 amendments included substantial changes in benefits and
contributions. The scheduled increase in the tax rates in 1940 was
postponed, so that the accumulation of reserves was on a much smaller
scale than contemplated earlier. The relationship between individual
contributions and benefits was also weakened.
In the 1939 amendments, "proponents of a pay-as-you-go financing
won a victory but the extent of the victory was uncertain." As shown
in chart 2, contributions continued to exceed expenditures and the
assets of the fund grew rapidly.
Few substantive changes were made in social security financing
during the 1940's. Scheduled rate increases were further postponed,
reducing the rate of accumulation of assets. The Revenue Act of 1943
made provision for general revenue contribution whenever it might
1 For a summary of the controversIes over accumulating a reserve, see John J. Carroll,
Alternative Methods of Financing Old-Age, Survivors, and Disability Insurance (Ann
Arbor: University of Michigan, Institute of Public AdmInistration, 1960), ch. III.
2 The extent to which the committee and the original Social Security Act embraced a
reserve financing principle was obscured in part by attempts to deal with problems of
constitutionality (Witte, op. cit., pp. 146-149). In the Ways and Means Committee report
on the social security bill, old-age benefits were projected at $2.2 billion for 1965 and
reserves at $30 billion (H. Rept. 615, 74th Cong., 1st sess., Apr. 5, 1965, p. 6) thus
indicating a substantial reliance on the reserve principle.
Carroll, op. cit., p. 4.
PAGENO="0048"
42
OLD AGE INCOME ASSTJRANOE-PART UI
be required, but this provision was removed in 1950 without ever being
used.
The postponement of scheduled rate increases meant not only that
the assets of the fund grew more slowly, but also that the existing
tax rates were far less than would be necessary on an individual con-
tributory basis, or an individual actuarial rate basis, to provide for
the cost of benefits to individuals covered by the system. An individual
actuarial rate has been defined as a rate "sufficiently high to cover the
full cost of benefits for a person who pays it for his full working life-
time" ~ taking account of interest. Such an actuarial rate basis would
primarily reflect the "individual equity" principle, as contrasted with
the principle of "social adequacy":
Individual equity means that the contributor receives bene-
fit protection directly related to the amount of his contribu-
tions-or, in other words, actuarially equivalent thereto.
Social adequacy means that the benefits paid will provide for
all contributors a certain standard of living. The two concepts
are thus generally in direct conflict, and social security systems
usually have a benefit basis falling between complete individ-
ual equity and complete social adequacy.5
The late 1940's appear to ha.ve been the last time that the individual
equity principle was specifically considered in planning social security
amendments. The 1948 report of the Advisory Council on Social Se-
curity put considerable emphasis on this principle:
The Council favors as the foundation of the social security
system the method of contributory social insurance with bene-
fits related to prior earnings and awarded without a means
test. Differential benefits based on a work record are a reward
for productive effort and are consistent with general economic
incentives, while the knowledge that benefits will be paid-
irrespective of whether the individual is in need-supports
and stimuintes his drive to add his personal savings to the
basic security he has acquired through the insurance system.
Under such a social insurance system, the individual earns a
right to a benefit that is related to his contribution to
production.6
The 1948 report also repeated the recommendation for a general
revenue contribution:
The Council believes that old-age and survivors insurance
should be planned on the assumption that general taxation will
eventually share more or less equally with employer and em-
ployee contributions in financing future benefit outlays and
administrative costs. Under our recommendations, a full
rate of benefits will be paid to those who retire during the
first two or three decades of operation even though they pay
only a fraction of the cost of their benefits. In a social insur-
Ibid., p. 29.
~ Robert 3. Myers, Social Insurance and Allied Government Programs (Homewood, Ill.:
Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1965), p. 6.
6 Advisory Council on Social Security to the Senate Committee on Finance, Recommenda-
tions for Social Security Legislation (S. Doe. 208, 80th Cong., 2d sess., Washington, D.C.:
1949), p. 1.
PAGENO="0049"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART in 43
ance system, it would be inequitable to ask either employers
or employees to finance the entire cost of liabilities arising
primarily because the act had not been passed earlier than it
was. Hence, it is desirable for the Federal Government, as
sponsor of the program, to assume at least part of these ac-
crued liabilities based on the prior service of early re-
tirants. * * * Such a contribution is particularly a~ppropri-
ate in view of the relief of the generaft taxpayer which would
result from the substitution of social insurance for part of
public assistance.7
Congress, however, rejected the recommendation for a general reve-
nue contribution.
The 1950 amendments si.thstantially liberalized benefits and in-
creased the taxable wage base, as well as providing a new schedule of
future increases in payroll tax rates. Extensions of coverage and lib-
eralizations of benefits further weakened the relation between contribu-
tions and benefits. Substantial increases were provided for those al-
ready receiving retirement benefits. In general, benefits were to be
computed on recent postwar levels of earnings, regardless of the fact
that the individual's lifetime contribution reflected in part the much
lower levels of pre-World War II wages and salaries. Inflation almost
inevitably forced a shift in emphasis to "social adequacy" for older
workers and those already retired.
The Social Security Act Amendments of 1956 empowered the Secre-
tary of Health, Education, and Welfare to appoint periodically an
Advisory Council on Social Security to. review existing law and pro-
grams. The first Advisory Council was appointed in 1957 and made
its report on January 1, 1959. The second Advisory Council was ap-
pointed in 1963 and made its report on January 1, 1965.
The reports of these two advisory councils marked a change in em-
phasis in financing methods. Both councils emphasized their belief
in the principle of "self-support," in other words, continued payroll
financing without a general revenue contribution. Both also emphasized
a belief in the "current principles" of the system. However, the con-
tent, wording, and emphasis of the recommendations indicated a sub-
stantial change from the report of the Advisory Council of 1948.
One change was a virtual acceptance of the principle of pay-as-
you-go financing. While this shift was not stated outright in the
texts, the recommendation on the role of the trust funds in the 1959
report was as follows:
The Council approves of the accumulation of funds that are
more than sufficient to meet all foreseeable short-range con-
tingencies, and that will therefore earn interest in somewhat
larger amounts than would be earned if the funds served only
a contingency purpose. The Council concludes, however, that
a "full" reserve is unnecessary and does not believe that inter-
est earnings should be expected to meet a major part of the
long-range benefit costs.8
~ Ibid., p. 13.
The 1959 Report of the Advisory Council on Social Security Financing, reprinted in
William Haber and Wilbur J. Cohen, Social Security, Programs, Problems, and Policies,
Selected Readings (Homewood, Ill.: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1960), pp. 149.
83-200-67-pt. 3-4
PAGENO="0050"
44 OLD AGE IYCOME AS.SrURA~CE-PA.RT III
The Council expressed the belief that "the trust funds are and will
continue to be larger than would be required for contingency purposes
alone."
The 1965 report of the Advisory Council on Social Security rec-
ommended that:
The contribution rates now scheduled in the law should be
adjusted to avoid the rapid increase in trust fund assets that
will otherwise begin with the rate increases schedule for
1966 and 1968.~
The virtual acceptance of pay-as-you-go and changes in the benefit
structure marked a further departure from the individual equity
principle in social security financing. The relation between the individ-
ual equity principle and pay-as-you-go financing is not a simple one.
It is possible to have a social insurance system related to "individual
equity" with or without the accumulation of a reserve fund. However,
when the advisory councils "reaffirmed" the principle of self-support
(in that payroll taxes should provide sufficient revenue in the long
run, with little accumulation of reserve funds, to meet benefit pay-
ments and administrative costs), they failed to spell out the implica-
tions for the individual.
There were critics and students of the social security system who did
emphasize these implications. Robert M. Clark, who made a detailed
study of the British and American social security systems for the
Government of Canada, noted in 1959 that:
The critical test of the actuarial soundness of the [OASI]
program is * `I yet to come * * This is readily apparent
from the fact that by 1969 the tax rates for [OASI] will have
to be raised from the combined rate * * * of 4 percent in
1958 to 81/2 percent * * ~. Sooner or later voices are likely to
be raised in the Congress saying that the burden of con-
tril)utiOnS for the program is becoming too heavy for a sig-
nificant fraction of the self-employed, or for the lower in-
come groups. Some will demand a subsidy from general reve-
nues, others a change in the tax structure to reduce the burden
On those with relatively low incomes.10
The implications were further developed by Mr. Ray Peterson in a
paper for the Society of Actuaries in 1959.11
The questions involved here are difficult ones which have not really
been subjected to sufficient economic and actuarial analysis appro-
priate to a wealthy and growing economy with substantially full
employment. Certain problems of individual equity in a pay-as-you-go
social insurance system are examined in the appendix. These problems
are reflected in the concept of "actuarial soundness."
The Status of the Social Security Program and Recommendations for Its Improvement
(Washington. D.C.: 1965), p. iS.
10 Economic Security for the Aged in the United States and Canada) a report prepared
for the Government of Canada (Ottawa: Queen's Printer, 1960), vol. I, p. 155.
11 "Misconceptions and Missing Perceptions of Our `Social Security System (Actuarial
Anesthesia)." Transactions of the Society of Actuaries, vol. II, meeting No. 31, November
1959, pp. S12-919.
PAGENO="0051"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSIJRANCE-PART iii 45
THE CONCEPT OF ~`ACTUARIAL SOUNDNESS"
As the social security system has developed in the United States,
the concept of "actuarial soundness" used by the Social Security
Administration has been reduced to the single question of whether
expected revenues from contributions and interest will be sufficient
to meet expected benefit payments and adminstrative costs. To quote
one description by the Division of the Actuary: 12
The concept of actuarial soundness as applied to the OASI
program differs to a considerable extent from this concept
as it is applied to private insurance. Certain points of similar-
ity exist, especially in comparison with private pension plans.
The most important difference arises because OASI can be
assumed to be perpetual in nature, with a continuing flow of
new entrants resulting from the compulsory nature of the
program.
Accordingly, it may be said that the OASI system is actu-
arially sound if * * * future contribution income plus fu-
ture interest receipts will support the outgo for benefits and
administrative expenses over the long run. * * *
This aggregative concept might more accurately be called a concept
of fiscal control. This is because the main effect of the principle is to
insure that revenues will be forthcoming to meet expected benefits.
The principle does not insure that individuals now entering the labor
force will necessarily "get their money's worth."
An essential purpose of standards of "actuarial soundness" is to
insure that funds will be available to meet claims and benefits. This
purpose may be consistent with various contribution schemes and
financing methods. In private individual insurance, the relation
between an individual's contributions and his expected benefits is
necessarily an important element in "ratemaking," the equivalent of
contribution schedules in social insurance.
The declining importance of the individual equity principle in
OASDI is reflected in the infrequent use of the "actuarial rate" in
discussions of the cost of social insurance. On the basis of private
individual insurance, ~~`l * * the actuarial rate expresses the value of
the benefits to the individual." 13 With the weighted benefit schedule
of the OASDI system, such an actuarial rate would be a group rate:
Low wage earners get large benefits in relation to their con-
tributions than do high wage earners, and the actuarial rate
represents the average value of the benefits for persons in
each age group that has the opportunity to contribute over a
working lifetime.14
Just how much redistribution from higher to lower wage earners
is consistent with such a group "actuarial rate" has never been speci-
fied. The differentials in contribution-benefit ratios vary not only
with earnings levels but also with marital status, retirement age,
12 Tue Financial Principle of Self-Support in the Old-Age and Survivors Insurance Sys-
tem, Social Security Administration Actuarial Study No. 40 (Washington, D.C.: i955) p. 5.
13 Robert M. Ball, "What Contribution Rate for Old-Age and Survivors Insurance ?"
Social Security Bulletin, July1949, p. 4.
14 Ibid.
PAGENO="0052"
46 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
and other factors. Nevertheless, the expected (discounted) value of a
typical individual's benefits or "protection" could hardly be allowed
to fall below the value of the individual's own contributions without
causing legitimate protests on equity grounds. Moreover, if the whole
social insurance system is to be justified substantially as a wage-related,
contributory system, a similar limit must apply in some degree to
the employer's contribution.
This review of financing principles indicates that the principle
or "individual equity" in OASDI programs needs detailed re-
examination.
IV. MAJOR ALTERNATIVES IN FINANCING SOCIAL INSURANCE
The conflict between the objectives of "social adequacy" and "indi-
vidual equity" were notably illustrated in 1967. The Administration's
proposed social security amendments (contained in H.R.. 5710) were
designed largely to make the OASDI programs a more effective
instrument in the "war on poverty."
The President's message on older Americans (Ja.nuary 23, 1967)
said:
Although social security benefits keep 51/2 million aged
persons above the poverty line, more than 5 million still live
in poverty.
A great nation cannot tolerate these conditions. I propose
social security legislation which will bring the greatest
improvement in living standards for the elderly since the act
was passed in 1935.
The adequacy objective was reflected in the large increase in the
maximum tax base (which raises the tax relatively more than benefits
for those with earnings near or above the maximum), in the increase
in minimum old-age retirement benefits from $44 to $70 per month,
in the special provisions for those with 25 years or more of coverage,
and in other provisions. The proposed 60-percent increase in the mini-
mum old-age retirement benefit was intended particularly to provide
more adequate benefits to low-paid and irregularly employed workers,
whose contributions, even under the proposed increases in tax rates
and the maximum tax base, would by no means provide for such
benefits. "Every insured worker retiring at or after age 65 would
be paid at least $70, regardless of how long he worked under the
program."
The concern of the House Ways and Means Committee with main-
taining a wage-related system was evident in the questioning of
administrative officials and elsewhere.2 In answering questions on the
proposed minimum old-age benefit before the committee, W. ,J.
Cohen, Under Secretary of the Department of HEW, admitted that
1. U.S. House of Representatives, Committee on Ways and Means, Section-by-Section
Analijsis and Evplanation of Provisions of H.R. 5710, the "Social Security Amendments of
1967" as Introduced on Feb. 20, 1967 (prepared and furnished by the Department of
Health, Education, and Welfare), committee prInt, 90th Cong., 1st sess., p. 22.
2 In a letter to the New York Times, dated Aug. 9, 1967, Representative Barber B. Con-
able Jr. (R., N.Y.), a member of the House Ways and Means Committee, said: "Social
security has had wide acceptance and strong support because through it a man can invest
In his retirement, rather than simply suffer another form of taxation * * * Social security
must remain a substantially wage-related supplement If It is to continue as a valuable and
widely supported aid to the working man. * * * (New York Time8, Aug. 14, 1967).
PAGENO="0053"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSIJRANCE-PART iii 47
* * perhaps there is some modification in policy that is embodied
in this proposal. We think the system should be consistent with the
philosophy of a wage-related system and still make a substantial con-
tribution to the reduction of poverty; we think that those two objec-
tives should be kept in mind but always balanced so that people who
have higher earnings and who contribute more get more." ~
The concern of the Ways and Means Committee was evident also
in the sharp cut backs in proposed increases in benefits and payroll
taxes in the bill (H.R. 12080) reported by the committee on August 7,
1967 (see(table 1, above, p. 22).
Recent debates and current pressures for change suggest various
alternatives or possibilities for the future financing of OASDI pro-
grams.4 Four alternatives, illustrating the major value judgments and
economic issues involved, are examined here: (1) To continue approxi-
mately the present balance between the objectives of social adequacy
and individual equity; (2) to provide a general revenue contribution
to OASDI trust funds; (3) to modify the payroll tax to reduce the
burden on low income groups; and (4) to divide the benefit schedules
into two portions, one of which would be based on "adequacy," and
one which would directly reflect individual contributions, and to
finance each portion separately by different forms of taxation.
MAINTAINING THE PRESENT BALANCE OF OBJ~EOTIVES
Through a long political process the United States has developed a
social insurance system that provides a working balance between the
objectives of adequacy and individual equity. Indeed, some such bal-
ance may be taken as one of the distinguishing features of "social
insurance."
The Committee on Social Insurance Terminology of the American
Risk and Insurance Association, in its most recent redrafting of the
definition of "social insurance," listed as one of the conditions or
characteristics of such insurance the following:
The benefits for any individual are not usually directly re-
lated to contributions made by or in respect of him but instead
usually redistribute income so as to favor certain groups such
as those with low former wages or a large number of
dependents.~
The extent of redistribution consistent with "social insurance,"
however, is largely a matter of value judgments. The current balance
in objectives is being strained as the payroll tax burden grows. In the
view of one member of the House Committee on Ways and Means, a
substantial increase in the redistribution of income in favor of low
income groups under social insurance programs: ~`* * * would re-
make our social security system into an extension of the welfare pro-
Quoted in American Enterprise Institute, Legislative Analysis, Proposed Social Security
Amendments of 1967 (Washington, D.C.: 1967), pp. 25, 26.
Hospital insurance and the voluntary medical supplementary insurance, adopted in
1905. are not separately examined here. They involve another range of issues in addition to
the fundamental issues of objectives in the older "insurance" programs. The innovations
In financing health insurance, Including a general revenue contribution for SMI, neverthe.
less serve to illustrate problems in financing the older programs.
Unpublished mimeographed draft dated spring 1967.
PAGENO="0054"
48 OLD AGE D~COME ASsrEA~CE-PART III
grams. We would then be in the position of requiring greater
contributions for welfare from the wage earner than from the general
taxpayer." 6
It is also argued that the present financing system, relying only on
payroll taxes, provides a restraint on expenditures that would be re-
moved by a shift to general revenue financing. Representative Wilbur
D. Mills, chairman of the House Ways and Means Committee, once
said:
I do not believe there should ultimately be a contribution
from general revenues. If there is such a contribution, there
is no real deterrent to demand for extremely high payments.7
The present system of payroll tax financing contains an important
fiscal control device. Whenever increase benefits are proposed, the
I-louse Ways and Means Committee, under whose jurisdiction social
security falls, must also consider the long-range financing of such
benefits as well as administrative costs. When the benefits schedule is
revised, the contributions schedule is also revised to insure that suf-
ficient revenues will be forthcoming to meet all benefits and other costs.
This is a device that does not operate in the general budget, although
similar procedures have been proposed for administrative budget
programs.
The effect of this fiscal control device on the level of expenditures in
the past may be questioned. Other countries have social insurance
systems in which the same type of fiscal procedure operates, except
that a general revenue contribution is a part of the additional levy
that goes with increased benefits. A recent study comparing social
insurance systems in different countries shows that partial reliance on
general revenues in social insurance systems is not associated with
higher expenditures: "`~ * * the proportion of national income de-
voted to social security is higher in some of the countries that rely less
on general revenues for financing these expenditures."
Over the last two decades in the United States, the tendency of social
security benefit increases to be associated with election years suggests
that the benefit increases have been of more concern to the public
than the payroll tax increases. LTntil recently the payroll tax was rela-
tively small, and people appear to have had an exaggerated idea of the
exteilt to which they were paying for their own benefits. After survey-
ing the opinions of various groups in the United States, Robert M.
Clark concluded:
Most Americans are enthusiastically in favor of old-age,
survivors, and disability insurance. They feel that this is their
program and not something the Government does for them
* * most people have a highly exaggerated idea of the ex-
tent to which they have or will have paid for their benefits.9
6 Representative Barber B. Conable. Jr., New York Times, Aug. 14. 1967.
Statement in an interview quoted by Robert M. Clark, Economic Security for the Aged
in the Usiited States and Canada, a report prepared for the Government of Canada (Ot-
tawa: Queen's Printer. 1960). vol. I. p. 155.
8 Henry Aaron, "St~cial Security: International Comparisons." in Otto Eekstein. ed.,
Studzes in the Economics of Income Maintenance, Washington, D.C. The Brookings Insti-
tution, 1967, p. 20.
Op. cit., p. 179.
PAGENO="0055"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 49
The small extent to which benefits have been prepaid is shown in
an estimate by the Chief Actuary of the Social Security
Administration:
For those now on the rolls (1964), it is likely that they
would have paid, at most, for about 10 percent of the benefits
actually payable to them.'°
As indicated in section II, the tax-benefit ratios have changed
drastically for new entrants to the labor force. The ratio of the value
of the employee's tax payments to the expected value of the benefit
under existing legislation would be nearly tenfold greater for persons
retiring in 2010 than for those retiring in 19652' If people have had
illusions in the past about the degree to which they were paying for
their own social security, these illusions are likely to be dispelled in the
future. The impact of payroll taxes at current and prospective levels
will almost certainly generate opposition to increased social security
benefits.
Maintaining approximately the existing balance of objectives in
OASDI programs will be difficult in the future even if that balance is
deemed desirable.
PROVIDING A GENERAL REVENUE CONTRIBUTION
The objective of more adequate ben~fits was clearly a part of the
proposed general revenue contribution in the social security bill (S.
3661) introduced in 1966 by Senator Robert Kennedy. In introducing
this bill, he said:
* * in 1964, two out of five aged couples in this country
had incomes, of less than $3,000. One out of four had income
of less than $2,000.
For these elderly people, social security has still not lived
up to its original promise to avert economic insecurity in
retirement. We must now keep that Pro1i~ise. We must now
provide adequate benefits, and we can do so with fiscal sound-
ness to all who are insured. We must explore the full potential
of the social security system to serve as a guarantor of the
retired years of our people.12
In addition to emphasizing adequacy, some proponents of a general
revenue contribution argue not only that the payroll tax is high, but
that this is a poor way to finance increases in benefits. If the OASDI
system is to be made more of an instrument for preventing or remov-
ing poverty, it would hardly be fair to do so with a tax that reaches a
maximum at $6,600 or $7,600. An increased emphasis on social ade-
quacy would more logically be accomplished through tax burdens
based on ability to pay.
On the benefits side, it is argued by others that a general increase in
social insurance benefits would be an expensive way to reduce poverty
because benefits would also be increased for those well above the pov-
10 Statement quoted in American Enterprise Institute, Legislative Analysis Proposed
Social Security Amendments of 1967 (Washington, D.C.: 1967). p. 41.
U Tax Foundation, Economic Aspects of the Social Security Tax (New York, 1966), p. 45.
Comparisons were based on an interest rate of 31/a percent, and assumed that the indi-
viduals earned the maximum taxable wage or more.
Con gressional Record-Senate, vol. 112, No. 122, July 28, 1966, p. 16605.
PAGENO="0056"
50 OLD AGE INCOME ASSrURA~OE~PART III
erty line at the same time. If the prime dbjective is to improve the eco-
nomic position of those below the poverty line, a dollar of expenditures
will go further in other programs than through increases in the social
insurance benefit structure.'3
Historically, a more technical argument has been used for a general
revenue contribution. It is that in the transitional stage to a mature
social insurance system, most people become eligible for benefits even
though they have not contributed anything like the full cost of those
benefits. Until most workers have confribu~ed a lifetime at rates com-
mensurate with the benefits they will receive, a large windfall will
continue to accrue to current beneficiaries. This windfall, it is argued,
constitutes an unfunded liability the burden of which should be borne
by all taxpayers through general revenues rather than through the
payroll tax. Since the use of the payroll tax is largely justified by the
quid pro quo element, the redistribution in favor of current beneficiar-
ies receiving windfalls should be met by a general levy.
This position has been countered by the argument that under the
present system, the employer's contribution is really a contribution on
behalf of all workers and cannot be attributed to the particular indi-
viduals on whose wages the tax was levied. Thus the employer's con-
tributions may be used for redistributive purposes to whatever extent
one may deem such redist.ribution to be consistent with social insur-
ance. In particular, the employer's contribution may be considered an
appropriate way to finance the windfalls accruing to current bene-
ficiaries during the process of approaching a mature social insurance
system.
The social insurance system, as it has operated to date, will never
in fact reach maturity because the benefit structure will continue to be
revised upward at least to take account of increased prices and prob-
ably also to provide the aged with improved real incomes as the
Nation's average standard of living rises. Because Congress will
almost certainly take account of these dynamic elements on the bene-
fits side, it would be more realistic to take account of such changes in
determining the allocation of the related taxes in the long run.
MODIFYING THE PAYROLL TAX
Closely related to a general revenue contribution is the proposal to
modify the payroll tax to make it more like an income tax: to allow
personal exemptions and to increase substantially the maximum wage
base. Such changes would check the growing impact of direct taxes
on low-income groups that goes with increased reliance on the payroll
tax.'4
It is argued that * * the distinction between the personal income
tax and the social security tax, qua taxes, is almost cpmpletely
arbitrary," `~ and so the impact of the two taxes should be examined as
a unit. Such a viewpoint would, in effect, mean giving up the contribu-
tory principle as the primary justification of the payroll tax.
~` Christopher Green, Negative Taxes ant the Poverty Problesm (Washington, D.C.: The
Brookings Institution, 1967), pp. 41-43.
14 Henry Aaron, "Rate Progressivity and the Direct Taxation of Personal Income," Taxes,
the Tax Magazine, vol. 44. No. 7. July 1966, pp. 497-503; Joseph M. Bonin, "OASDHI
Taxation and the Progressivity of the Federal Tax Structure," Taxes, the Tax Magazine,
vol. 45. No. 2, February 1967, pp. 137-140.
~~Ibid., p. 498.
PAGENO="0057"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART iii 51
A high maximum wage base would also mean increased benefit levels.
With the present type of benefit structure, which is heavily weighted
in favor of those low earnings records, a higher maximum base would
also serve to increase the emphasis on adequacy.'6
Even more than a general revenue contribution, the alternative of
modifying the payroll tax would reflect the social adequacy objective
and mean almost complete departure from the principle of relating an
individual's contributions to his benefits.
SEPARATING WELFARE AND INSURANCE ELEMENTS
The conflict between the objectives of social adequacy and individ-
ual equity suggests the possibility of separating the major elements
in OASDI programs designed to meet these different objectives.
These portions of the programs may also be called the welfare and
insurance elements. In the broadest terms, the welfare element may be
defined as that part of benefits which is determined largely on the basis
of adequacy. Thus, the minimum old-age benefits bear no relation to the
average covered wages of the beneficiary except that these wages must
be low and the beneficiary must have a record of some covered
employment.
The insurance element, on the other hand, would consist of that part
of benefits which, is, or can be, related to average covered wages. This
relation would not be the strict relation between individual premiums
and value of benefits in private individual insurance; it would neces-
sarily be a looser relationship more characteristic of private group
insurance and group annuities. Moreover, many of the variations in
risks that may be taken into account in private insurance might not be
appropriate for a social insurance program-such as differences in
length of life characteristic of different races or income groups or areas.
In group insurance, "equity requires that, within the bounds of prac-
ticality, each group pay a premium which reflects its expectation of
loss." 17 State regulation usually provides that * * * the benefits pro-
vided under a policy must be reasonable in relation to the premium
charged." 18
Isolating an insurance element in OASDI programs raises funda-
mental questions of whether there are insurable risks that are un-
likely to be met by private enterprise and private saving, and for which
compulsory coverage by a governmental system may be justified.
Because of the overlay of the social adequacy objective in the past,
these issues have not received the detailed analysis that would be appro-
priate if the emphasis in social insurance were to be shifted toward the
individual equity principle.
A separation of insurance elements would mean greater reliance on
the benefit principle of taxation. The economic argument here is that
16 "* * * under the cash-benefits portion of the OASDHI system, the basic benefit
amount (payable to a worker retiring at age 65 * * *) is $107 a month for a person
earning $275 a month, whereas it is $168 a month for a person at the maximum creditable
earnings of $550 a month. Thus, although the latter individual contributes twice as much
as the former individual, his benefit rate is only 57 percent higher." (Robert J. Myers,
"Employee Social Insurance Contributions and Progressive Taxation," to be published in
the Journal of Risk and Insurance.)
17 Morton D. Miller, "Manual Rate Making in Group Life Insurance," In Group Insurance
Handbook (Homewood, Ill.: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1967), p. 184.
18 Ibid.
PAGENO="0058"
52 OLD AGE INCOME AS:STJRAXCE-PART III
where the benefits of public expenditures can be attributed to specific
groups of individuals, and taxes for the support of these expenditures
can be efficiently levied on these same groups, people will, on the whole,
be better off than if these expenditures are financed out of general
revenues.
With annual expenditures of approximately $20 billion for social
insurance, the potentia.l for more economic and equitable allocation of
these resources is large.
V. Possimr.~m~s AND PROBLEMS IN A Two-TIER SYs~M
The conflict between the objectives of social adequacy and indi-
vidual equity suggests the possibility of separating the major ele-
ments in OASDI programs designed to meet these different objec-
tives, and to provide different kinds of financing for each.
At least in a formal sense, we now have "separate" systems for
old-age and survivors insurance, disability insurance, hospital insur-
aiice, and supplementary medical insurance (SMII). Each is assigned
a designated part of the tax rate (except for the optional "pre-
mium" in the case of SMI), and each is assigned a separate trust
fund. For supplementary me clical insurance, the Government makes
a. contribution from general revenues equal to the total premiums of
participants.
It would be feasible to go to a system in which minimum retire-
ment benefits, for example (or other noninsurance portions of beiie-
flts, were financed from, say, a specified rate on individual taxable
income (a.s defined for income tax purposes). Insurance elements
would continue to be financed by payroll taxes. A system on such
lines is now being used in Canada.
THE CANADIAN SYSTh~M
In 1952 the Govermnent of Canada adopted a universal old-age
pension of a flat amount per person, paid without a means test, and
financed by a three-way tax on individual incomes, corporation
incomes, and manufacturers sales. (The manufacturers sales tax is
an important part of the Federal tax system in Canada.) The three-
way tax was originally a 2-percent (now 4-percent) surcharge
levied on the base of these three major Federal taxes. The pension
was originally $40 per month. It is now $75 per month.
In 1965 Canada adlopted, in addition to this imiversal old-age
pension, a wage-related contributory system, called the Canada pen-
sion `plan, under which individual contributions are closely related
to benefits.'
The Canada pension plan provides retirement pensions, disability
pensions, children's, wives', and widows' benefits in case of death or
disability, and a lump-sum payment at death. Benefits are to be
adjusted in accordance with the cost of living (and eventually
related to the average wage level).
1 Further details can be found In Tue Canada Pension Plan (Ottawa: The Queen's
Printer: 1965).
PAGENO="0059"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
53
The plan is financed by "contributions" from the employer, the
employee, and the self-employed. Currently the employer and the
employee each pay a tax of 1.8 percent on taxable earnings up to
$5,000, with a $600 exemption. The self-employed pay a tax of 3.6
percent on earnings from $600 to $5,000. The contributions are
deductible for income tax purposes, while benefits will be taxable
income when paid.
The retirement pensions eventually will amount to 25 percent of
annual covered earnings up to the maximum of $5,000 with an
allowance for low or nonearning years. Full retirement pensions
first become available on January 1, 1976. Until that date reduced
amounts of pensions will be paid to those eligible. Where both
husband and wife have contributed, both `are entitled to retirement
pensions.
This system appears to have developed more in response to public
demands for old-age security than as a fully thought-out scheme
for social insurance.2
MEANING OF "SOCIAL INSURANCE"
If revision of the U.S. system were to be in the direction separating
elements based on the individual equity principle, an essential problem
would be. to define more clearly the insurance elements appropriate
in a compulsory governmental s~tem.3
A good deal of analytical effort has gone into developing a defini-
tioii of "social insurance." ~ Part of the problem of terminology is
that the definition depends in some degree on judgments concerning
appropriate methods of financing and the extent to which concepts
of adequacy can be combined with a wage-related, contributory sys-
tem. The definition is also likely to change a.s actual social security
systems evolve.
A recently revised draft (spring 1967) of the definition of "social
insurance" by the Committee on Social Insurance Terminology of
the American R.isk and Insurance Association reads in part as follows:
SOCIAL INSURANCE.-A device for `the pooling of risks by
their transfer to an orga.nization, usually governmental, that
is required by law to provide pecuniary or service benefits to
or on behalf of covered persons upon the occurrance of cer-
ta.in predesignat.ed losses under all of the following condi-
lions:
(1) Coverage is compulsory by law in virtually all
instances.
(2) Eligibility for `benefits is derived `~ * from con-
tributions having been `made * * * by or in respect of
2 On the political history of the old-age pension, see A. Kenneth Eaton, Essays in. Taxa-
tion (Toronto: Canadian Tax Foundation, 1906), pp. 132-157. On the . Canada Pension
I'lan, see Irving J. Goffman, Some Fiscal Aspects of Public Welfare in Canada (Toronto:
Canadian Tax Foundation, 1965), p. 100. There were precedents, however, In other coun-
tries, particularly West Germany (Old-Age and Sickness Insurance in West Germany in
1965, Social Security Administration Research Report No. 13, Washington, D.C.: Govern-
ment Printing Office, 1965).
A theoretical analysis of medical insurance relating to private nonprofit systems as
well as to government can be found in Kenneth J. Arrow, "Uncertainty and the Welfare
Economics of Medical Care," American Economic Review, vol. LIII, No. 5, December 1963,
pp. 941-973.
C. Arthur Williams, Jr., "Social Insurance-Proper Terminology ?" The Journal of
Insurance, vol. 30, No. 1, March 1963, pp. 112-128.
PAGENO="0060"
54 OLD AGE INCOME ASSTJRANCE-PART III
the claimant ~ * ~; there is no requirement that the in-
dividual demonstrate inadequate financial resources, al-
though a dependency sta1tus may need to be established.
(3) The method for determining the benefits is pre-
scribed by law.
(4) The benefits for any individual are not usually
directly related to contributions made by or in respect
of him but instead usually redistribute income so as to
favor certain groups such as those with low former wages
or a large number of dependents.
(5) There is a definite plan for financing benefits that
is designed to be adequate in terms of long-range con-
siderations.
(6) The cost is borne primarily by contributions
which are usually made by covered persons, their em-
ployers, or both.
(7) The plan is administered or a.t least supervised
by the Government.
(8) The plan is not established by the Government
solely for its present or former employees.
This definition accurately reflects the state of social insurance today,
but it does not point up the current problems in social insurance
financing.
JTTSTIFICAT[ON FOR WAGE-RELATED CONTRIBUTORY SYSTEM
The traditional arguments for a socia.l in-suranee system, in addi-
tion to adequacy considerations, still have relevance.
Since the beginning of the social security system, compulsory pro-
vision for old a.ge has been justified by the argument that without
such provision many of the aged would become public charges, or
direct welfare recipients. If many people voluntarily provide for their
own old age while others do not, the former will end up paying part
of the old age costs of the latter.
The force of this argument has diminished somewhat with the
increasing private financing resources of the aged although the ma-
jority of OASDI beneficiaries still have no other source of "retire-
ment income." ~ As income rises, providing for their own retirement
becomes one of the services that more and more people want to buy.
At low-income levels, the implicit discount rate that many people
put on saving for old age is undoubtedly high. This is suggested by
the extremely high-interest rates t.lia~t many rpersons at low-income
levels (and in low-income countries) are willing to pay for borrowing
of any sort.
Forcing people to save through social insurance may appear to be
an undue interference with individual choice.6 However, the evidence
seems to be that social security has had the effect in the past of height-
Robert M. Ball. "Policy Issues in Social Security." Social Security Bulletin, June 1966,
p. 5, and The Aged Population of the United States, the 1963 Social Security Survey of the
Aged, Social Security Administration Research Report No. 19 (Washington, D.C.: Govern-
ment Printing Office, 1967).
6 The economic question of whether the individual savings in the form of social insurance
taxes will actually be turned into real national saving and investment is another question
which is examined below, p. 55.
PAGENO="0061"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 55
ening the people's awareness of the need for saving for old age, and
also has given them a start on which to build additional private savmg
and insurance. The fact that the initial tax rate in this country was so
low (1 percent) for nearly a decade and a half perhaps contributed to
some illusion as to how much insurance was actually being pur-
chased-as Mr. Robert Clark has indicated, people generally have an
exaggerated idea of how much they have contributed to their own
benefits.
In any case, far from checking the growth of private insurance,
social security seems to have stimulated it.~ Whether or not such a
relation may continue is another matter-if social security taxes con-
tinue to rise, they may well limit the ability of people to save in other
ways.
However, the arguments may be arrayed on the question of compul-
sory saving for old age, at least a minimum of such compulsion is
accepted in most western countries. Acceptance of such compulsion
seems to be a part of the decline of dependence on the family as an old-
age security system.
The limitations of private provision for old age continue to provide
a justification for a governmental system. Even though the employee
might not choose to save toward his old age, some portion of the cost
of a minimum old-age pension should probably be regarded as a nec-
essary part of the cost of production of goods and services. As more
than one writer on insurance economics has pointed out, we set up
accounts to take care of depreciation and obsolescence of physical
assets; and at least part of the cost of life insurance and retirement
for individuals should be treated in a similar fashion by the firm as
well as the individual.8
The rapid growth of group insurance and private pension plans
shows a recognition in the market that the current cost of production
includes some provision for the worker after he reaches an age of
retirement or one in which he can no longer work productively. But,
despite the growth of what has been called the corporate social security
system,9 the workings of the labor market are usually such that the
individual firm is not forced to take into account the cost of maintain-
ing workers after they rctire, at least for employees who remain with
one firm for a short time. To insure that such costs are taken into
account in current production may be regarded as one of the economic
justifications for a social insurance system.1°
The social insurance system compels every employer as well as the
employee to contribute an equal amount to OASDI. The employee
remains covered, and in a sense, receives credit for his and his employ-
er's contributions, no matter how often he changes jobs. These features
of immediate "vesting" of pension and insurance rights and of "port-
Philip Cagan, The Effect of Pension Plans on Ajjgregate ~S'aving, National Bureau of
Economic Research, Occasional Paper No. 95 (New York, 1965), pp. 6, 82; and John H.
Magee, Life Insurance (Homewood, Iii.: 1958), p. 361.
S. S. Heubner, The Economics of Life Insurance, third edition (New York: Appleton-
Century-Crofts, 1959), particularly ch. 7.
Harland Fox, "The Corporate Social Security System and Workmen's compensation,"
The Conference Board Record, vol. I, No. 2, February 1964, pp. 7-16.
10 There are "external costs" involved in provision for old age which usually Is not
taken into account by the individual and the firm. In a similar way, private business
accounting did not adequately take account.of depreciation costs before the advent of the
income tax. (George Terborgh, Realistic Depreciation Policy, Machinery and Allied Products
Institute, Washington, D.C., 1954, pp. 2, 3.)
PAGENO="0062"
56 OLD AGE INCOME ASSrRANCE-PART III
ability" are the very features that are difficult to provide for all em-
~1oyees under private insurance.
Social insurance thus provides a means of insuring that all, or
nearly all, individuals and firms take account of costs of old age and
disability that otherwise would fall on the general taxpayer.
One of the distinctive features of social insurance is that it provides
a means of taking care of the "transitional" costs of instituting old-
age income insurance without. necessarily involving the long period for
the buildup of reserves and the growth of investment income that are
an essential part of private insurance and pension plans.
Under a pay-as-you-go system, the present labor force pays taxes
which are used to support the present beneficiaries. Those who are
currently paying taxes receive, in exchange, a promise by the Govern-
ment (though not in the form of a contract) to provide them with
certain benefits or "protection." This promise to pay can provide to-
day's worker with "his money's worth" even though the taxes are used
currently to support persons whose contributions have been far less
than the cost of their benefits. The social insurance system is more than
a process of redistributing income by age group (or by income level).
By relating an individual's contributions to his benefits, a mutually
advant.ageous exchange (between people in different age groups) can
be achieved,1' while under an income redistributing system, some
people necessarily give up something to provide a gain for others. By
general consensus, some income redistribution is necessary in providing
for the needy aged-our society does in some way take care of the
destitute. But, at any level of old-age benefits, the economic position of
most individuals could be improved by providing a financing system
in which benefits are related to contributions, and income redistributing
elements are separately financed by general revenues (or. more strictly,
from the individual income tax). (The meaning of redistribution is
discussed further on page 57.)
This point is closely related to the traditional argument that. social
insurance gave people a sense of collecting by "right" rather than as
welfare recipients. If people have "paid for" social security on an
individual equity basis, the payroll tax is of much less significance as
a tace than if it is essentially being used for income redistribution.12
REDISTRmUTION IN OASDI
The "welfare" element in OASDI is reflected in the substantial
amount of income redistribution that is effected through these pro-
grams. The two major kinds of redistribution involved are: (1) from
higher to lower income groups, and (2) from those currently working
and "contributing" to those who are receiving benefits substantially in
in excess of their own contributions in the past. In addition to these
"This and some related propositions were demonstrated by Paul A. Samuelson in his
article, "An Exact Consumption-Loan Model of Interest With or Without the Social Con-
trivance of Money," Journal of Political Economy, vol. 46, No. 6, December 1958, pp.
467-482. See also the appendix below, p.63. An opposing view, that on true economic
exchange can be made betweea generations by social Insurance, can be found in Abba P.
Lerner, "Consumption-Loan Interest and Money," Journal of Political Economy, vol. 67,
No. 5, October 1959, pp. 512-525. Lerner's view, in effect, is a denial of the possibility of a
quid pro quo financing basis In a pay-as-you-go social insurance system.
"For further elaboration of the benefit principle as applied to social insurance, see
W. Glenn CampbelL "The Economics of Social Security and the Theory of Government
Finance," National Tea' Journal, vol. 4, No. 2, June 1951, pp. 167-179,
PAGENO="0063"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 57
types of redistribution, the existing benefit structure and conditions
of eligibility discriminate in favor of certain groups of people regard-
less of income level or age.13
Neither of the two maj or kinds of redistribution-by wage level or
by age group-can be easily measured, in part because of problems
of definition. Redistribution by income level can be defined with
respect to the existing benefit structure and contribution levels: Row
do the existing or expected benefits compare with contributions under
present law for people at different income levels? Studies done on
this basis indicate a~ substantial redistribution from those whose earn-
ings are near Or above the maximum taxable level, to those whose
earnings are well below the maximum.'4 Such comparisons made at
any point of time must assume some expected benefit levels and past
or future contribution levels, which may turn out to be unrealistic.
Redistribution by income level may also relate to the total relation
between payroll taxes paid by all groups at different income levels
and the benefits received by all families at different income levels.15
This collective redistribution is useful for examining broad fiscal
effects of the social insurance system. It has little direct relevance to
the problems of equity because it does not distinguish between age
groups by income levels and takes no account of quid pro quo ~lemen'ts.
"Intergenerational" redistribution is also subject to definitional
problems. The extent to which an individual pays for his own benefits
is debatable. Some would attribute to the individual not only the
employee's contribution but also all or a part of the employer's con-
tribution. Others argue that the employer's contribution cannot be
attributed to the individual employee but is a general contribution
for the support of all covered workers. Some would argue that even
the employee's contribution has so little relation to benefits that the
whole process is a transfer with no real element of payment in exchange
for a service.~°
A true, wage-related pension system would be more than a transfer-
each individual would have "paid for" his pension during his working
years.
The transitional problems involved in providing "adequate" bene-
fits during the period between the initiation of the program and the
Lime when most people will have contributed over a working lifetime
constitute perhaps the most difficult problems of equity. The problems
are difficult because to have a program of importance in the transi-
tional period, benefits cannot be based solely on contributions paid.
The principle of social adequacy is given an important role, and it
means "windfalls" to most beneficiaries during the transition to a
"mature" system.
13 Elizabeth Deran, "Income Redistribution Under the ~oc1al Security System," National
Tax Journal, vol. 19, No. 3, September 1966, pp. 276-285; and Henry Aaron, "Income
Transfers Under Social Security,' in Otto Eckstein, ed., $tudies in the Economics of Income
Maintenance (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1967), pp. 61-72.
14 Ernest C. Harvey, "Social Security Taxes-Regressive or Progressive ?" National Tax
Journal, vol. 18, No. 4, pp. 408-414.
15 For example, Tax Foundation, Tax Burdens and Benefits of Government Expenditures
by Income Class, 1961 and 1965 (New York: 1967), pp. 32, 33.
16 "Pension benefits are too loosely related to contributions for the annuity analogy to
hold In any meaningful sense." (Old Age Income Assurance: An Outline of Issues and
Alternatives, materials prepared by the committee staff for the Subcommittee on Fiscal
Policy of the Joint Economic Committee, 89th Cong., 2d sass., Washington, D.C., Govern-
ment Printing Office, 1966, p. 8.)
PAGENO="0064"
58 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
The question of how the costs of these windfalls are to be distributed
has now been largely answered by past decisions in this country;
namely, through employer's contributions and the flow of employee
contributions from new entrants to the labor force. A justification for
this kind of financing can be made on the same grounds as the
justification for a "mature" wage-related system, as long as the transi-
tional financing does not fall outside the limits of the principle of
"individual equity."
It is argued in the appendix that the transitional problems of
financing under a pay-as-you-go system can be consistent with the
principle of individual equity. The implication of this conclusion is
that in separating "welfare" and "insurance" elements, it is redis-
t.ribution by income level for current contributors, not "intergenera-
tional" redistribution, that is logically financed by general revenues.
Intergenerational redistribution can, under reasonable assumptions,
be financed by payroll taxation subject to the individual equity prin-
ciple for current contributors. The "transfer" payment to current
beneficiaries does not mean that current taxpayers will not "get their
money's worth" in exchange for their own contributions.
COMPLEXITY
One of the considerations in a shift of emphasis to the individual
equity principle would be an increase in the complexity of theoretical
and administrative problems. The aggregate principle of "actuarial
soundness" now being used is simple as compared with the problems
of relating individual contributions to individual benefit levels.
A considerable expansion of the research programs of the Social
Security Administration would probably be required. As the Chief
Actuary once pointed out:
The principle of individual equity is difficult to disagree
with. The problem arises that this principle is easy to discuss
in general but relatively difficult to define specifically. Certain
questions arise: Should only workers who actually earn the
maximum taxable wage for every year of their working life
be considered, or should a probable wage-history basis be
used? Should retirement be assumed to occur at the earliest
possible age, or should the probability of retirement at later
ages be considered? Should allowance be made for the prob-
abilities of marriage and parenthood, or should only single
men and single women be considered? * * * `7
A detailed analysis of risks and costs would involve the Social Secu-
rity Administration in more actuarial work similar to that done by
private insurance companies, but with different kinds of "packages"
of insurance and annuities. Some change in the treatment of single
and married persons would probably be necessary, and perhaps account
should be taken of the varying risks for certain categories in the
population. However, many variations in risks might not be appro-
priate to consider in a social insurance program-where significant
1~ The Financial Principle of Self-Support in the Old-Age and Survivors Insurance
System, Social Security Administration Actuarial Study No. 40 (Washington, D.C., 19~),
p.3.
PAGENO="0065"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 59
differences in length of life are characteristic of different races or
income groups or areas. Costs and benefits undoubtedly would not be
as closely related as is likely under private insurance.
There is precedent for detailed cost-benefit analysis for tax pur-
poses in the Federal highway program.18 The problems involved in
relating benefits to contributions for social insurance are probably
less complicated than for highway programs. The very fact that cash
payments and receipts are involved, rather than benefits that must be
estimated, simplifies the problems. Social insurance is analogous to
private group insurance rather than to individual life insurance, and
the problems of dealing with particular age groups as a whole, rather
than with individual risks, are simpler to handle.
Moreover, the proposal that individual contributions be actuarially
related to benefits is not a new one. It `has been explored by the Social
Security Administration and by various study commissions and inch-
viclual experts in the past.'9 Other countries have relied in varying
degrees on a contributory, wage-related, insurance program.
WELFARE VERSUS INSURANCE COSTS
How much would a social insurance system cost if welfare elements
were largely eliminated? The answer would depend in part on the
extent of risks covered as well as on the definition of such elements.
One way of estimating the rechistributive element by income level
would be to examine OASDI benefit levels in relation to "actuarially
justified" pensions. Such estimates have been made by Henry Aaron,
but he did not carry them to the extent of estimating an aggregate
amount of redistribution involved.20 Nevertheless, his estimates show
a benefit-contribution ratio at low-wage levels of two to three times
the ratio at maximum taxable income levels.
Another way of estimating the order of magnitude of the redis-
tri'but'ive element in social `security is to assume `that the aged at low-
income levels are the major beneficiaries of the redistributive elements
in the system. Recent estimates indicate that about one-third of
OASDI beneficiaries would have income above "poverty levels"
($1,500 for single persons and $1,900 for a couple) without OASDI
benefits. About 41 percent of beneficaries are kept above "poverty
levels" by OASDI payments.2'
18 Under the Highway Revenue Act of 1956. the Bureau of Public Roads was directed:
* to make available to the Congress information on the basis of which it may deter-
mine what taxes should be imposed by the United States, and in what amounts, in order
to assure, insofar as practicable, an equitable distribution of the tax burden among the
various classes of persons using the Federal-aid highways or otherwise deriving benefits
from such highways. In order to carry out this purpose, the Secretary of Commerce, in
cooperation with other Federal officers and agencies and the State highway departments,
was directed to make a study and investigation of-
(1) The effects on design, construction, and maintenance of Federal-aid highways,
of the use of vehicles of different dimensions, weights. and other specifications, and
the frequency of occurrences of such vehicles in the traffic stream;
(2) The proportionate share of the design, construction, and maintenance costs of
the Federal-aid highways attributable to each class of persons using such highways
and
(3) Any direct and indirect benefits occurring to any class, in addition to benefits
from actual use of such highways." (Supplementary Report of the Highway Cost
Allocation Study, H. Doe. 124, 89th Cong., 1st sess., Mar.24, 1965, p. III.)
19 Robert M. Ball, "What Contribution Rate for Old-Age and Survivors Insurance ?"
Social Security Bulletin, July 1949, pp. 3-9.
20 "Income Transfers Under `Social Security," in Otto Eckstein, ed., Studies in the Eco-
flOflhiCS of Income Maintenance (Washington, D.C., the Brookings Institution, 1967),
pp. 61-72.
21 Ida C. Merriam, "Socifol Security Benefits and Poverty," Research and Statistics Note
No. 6, Feb. 24, 1967, table 2.
83-200-67-Pt. 3-5
PAGENO="0066"
60 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
The orders of magnitude involved can also be illustrated by esti-
mating the cost of the present minimum retirement benefit if it were
financed as a separate element of the benefit structure for all retired
bneficiaries. If a minimum old-age pension of $44 per month were
paid to all persons currently receiving retirement benefits (111/2 mil-
lion in 1966) the cost would be about $500 million per month as com-
pared with actual monthly retirement payments of about $980 million
in 1966 22 (or about $6 billion per year as compared with actual retire-
ment payments of about $12 billion per year).
The cost would be much less if it related only to those receiving
the minimum retirement benefit.23 A fia.t minimum retirement ben-
efit for all beneficiaries would be "uneconomic" in that it would apply
to those not really in need. More strictly defined, a "welfare" element
would be related in some way to a means test. The OASDI system, in
effect, has a means test in its record of earnings. For most bene-
ficaries, other sources of income are of minor importance.
The direction in which a separation of welfare and insurance ele-
ments leads is a complete revision of the benefit structure. The exist-
ing weighting of benefits in favor of low-income groups would be
replaced by a more closely wage-related schedule of insurance bene-
fits. The adequacy objective would be reflected instead in a noninsur-
ance payment also dependent on the beneficiary's record of past and
current earnings. The record of attachment to the labor force would
become the chief distinguishing feature between OASDI payments
and public assistance. Tile measure of "means" or needs in the OASDI
system is rough, but a major function of public welfare programs to
deal in detail with tile variation in needs of low-income families. The
OASDI payment would be a basic cash payment for purposes of public
assistance programs, as is now the case, for beneficiaries of both types
of programs.
ECONOMIC EFFECTS
An important policy objective in revision of the social insurance
system is the minimizing of distorting economic effects. One of the
limits on payroll taxes is the possible differential effects on different
kinds of industries. These have been examined in a previous tax foun-
dation study, as have the problems of relating social security financing
to countercyclical fiscal policy.24
One of tile major problems that bears on social security revision is
the effect on economic growth. This question has been debated and
examined at great length, in the past, in connection with tile issue of
building up reserve funds. The insurance analogy seemed to call for
a large reserve fund, but the possible deflationary effects of building
up such a fund were a major consideration in the shift to a virtual pay-
as-you-go system. Moreover, many questioned whether a reserve fund
invested in Government securities would have any real effect on na-
tional savings and investment. If the build-up of a financial reserve
had no real effect on the rate of investment, the economic argument
~ ~SociaZ ~5ecurity Bvlletin~, March 1067, table M-9, p. 31. These figures refer to retired
workers only. They exclude dependents' and survivors' benefits.
~ "In 1964, 16 percent of the 1,042,000 benefit awards were based on a PIA (primary
insurance amount) at the minimum." (Lenore A. Epstein, "Workers Entitled to Minimum
Retirement Benefits Under OASDHI," E~'ocial S'ecurity Bulletin, March 1967, p. 3.)
24 Economic Aspects of the Social Security Tax (New York: 1966).
PAGENO="0067"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART iii 61
for a reserve fund was largely removed. In contrast the reserves of
private pension funds are generally managed in such a way that they
are directly channeled into real investment; they also appear to have
the effect of increasing the rate of national saving. A pay-as-you-go
social insurance system transfers income from the working population,
who are savers, to the nonworking population, who for the most part
are nonsavers. Consequently, such a system is likely to reduce the
real rate of national saving and investment and thus decrease the
rate of economic growth.
A pension system that does not serve to increase future national
productive capacity from which increased pensions must be paid-
and which may even reduce future growth-has a disadvantage in com-
parison with a system that serves to increase economic growth (on the
assumption that a higher rate of economic growth is desirable). Par-
ticularly, when we are reaching a stage where public policies may have
important effects on the relative growth of public versus private pen-
sion systems, the possible effects on economic growth become
significant.
Under certain assumptions, reserve fund financing of social in-
surance could well lead to increased national saving and investment,25
but it is by no means certain that a reserve fund invested in Govern-
ment bonds will have this effect. An attempt to insure such an effect
has been made under the Canada pension plan by investing its assets
in Provincial government securities. Presumably the uses made of
long-term borrowing by Provincial governments are such as to increase
real national investment. Such investment of funds obtained from a
compulsory government pension program does serve to reduce de-
mands on the capital market by Provincial governments and should
leave more funds available for private business investment.
In any case, there is a broad range of policies open to Government
to promote economic growth, and the financing of a contributory
social insurance program must be taken into account in formulating
policies for growth and stability. However, this does not mean that
social insurance financing should necessarily be used as a major in-
strument for pursuing such goals.
COORDINATION WITI-I OTHER PUBLIC POLICIES RELATING TO THE AGED
A revision of social insurance programs to put the primary emphasis
on the contributory principle would necessarily involve revisions in
other policies and programs affecting the aged. These include the in-
come tax treatment of the aged, the tax treatment of private pension
plans, and he coordination of social insurance with other welfare
programs.
The increasing coverage and rising level of benefits under social
security have made the issues of the various policies toward the aged
closely interdependent. Issues in the tax treatment of the aged were
of relatively minor importance when the level of social security bene-
fits was so low in relation to the size of personal exemptions that few
people were affected by tax exemption of social security benefits. But,
rising levels of both public and private pension payments, combined
~ Richard A. Musgrave, The Theory of Public Finance (~New York: 1959), pp. 565-567.
PAGENO="0068"
62 OLD AGE IYCOME ASS~URA~CE-PART III
with fixed dollar amounts of personal exemptions, make it more diffi-
cult to ignore the problems of equity involved in existing provisions
for income tax treatment of the aged.
A shift to a social insurance system with primary emphasis on the
contributory prmciple, combined with a separate financing of "wel-
fare" elements, could Provide a better basis for the income tax treat-
ment of the aged.
Current exemption from taxable income of social insurance contri-
butions, as under the Canadian system, and inclusion of benefits in
taxable income at the time paid could improve individual equity by
relating the income tax liability more closely to current disposable
income (although this is not the only consideration involved). Such a
change in the treatment of social insurance contributions has been
proposed by several tax experts in the TJnitecl States.26
The question of the respective roles of public and private pension
plans has apparently been given relatively little consideration in the
past. Lack of attention to this question has probably been clue to the
narrow coverage of private pension plans until recent. years. As re-
cently as 1950 private pension plans covered only 9.8 million persons,
including those receiving benefits. In the same year 85.9 million per-
sons (in'~luding retired beneficiaries) were covered by OASDI. In
1950 the number of persons covered by private plans amounted to 11
percent of those covered by OASDI. By 1965 this ratio has risen to
20 pe.rcent.2~
The question of coordination of public policies on pensions and re-
lateci systems is thus becoming much more important. Social insurance
has generally been thought of as providing a "floor" of protection
against loss of income and the other risks covered. 1-lowever, a "floor"
of protection is subject to a wide range of interpretation.
The level of contributory pensions, on an individual equity basis,
should take account of the extent to which private pensions and other
provisions for old age are likely to provide for old a.ge. It would not be
reasonable to provide compulsory governmental pensions at. a. level
that would check the growth of private provision for old age. The
coverage and benefits provided by private pension plans as time goes
on will probablychange substantially.25
At the low end of the benefit scale. concepts of adequacy have obvi-
ously dominated social security benefits. The OASI system was orig-
inally intended gradually to replace a substantial portion of old-a~e
assistance, and it has at least partially achieved this goal. The number
of old-age-assistance recipients reached a peak of 2.8 million in 1950
and thereafter declined steadily to 2.1 million in 1966.29 Increases in
receipts of other public assistance programs have, in part, offset this
decline.'0 The close relation between OASIDI programs and public
For example. Ray M. Peterson. "Federal Taxation in Relation to Lifetime Income
Spreading and the complementary Roles of the Public and Private Retirement Programs."
in proceecling~. iSth National conference of the Tax Foundation, pt. II. Pension Fund
Problems, Private and Public (New York: 1967), pp. 17, iS; Joseph L. Seligman. Jr..
"Pension and Other Employee Benefit Plans," in Tax Revision. Compendium, Con pendium of
Papers on Broadening the Tax Base, submitted to the Committee on Ways and Means,
Us. House of Representatives. November 1959. vol. 2. pp. 136S. 1369.
Institute of Life Insurance, Private and Public Pension Plans in the United States
(New York: 1967), p. 3.
25 Further discussion of the relative roles of public and private pension programs can
be found in Dan M. McGill, `Major Policy Issues in American Private Pensions." Trans-
actions, Social of Actuaries, 1966 Annual Meeting Number, vol. iS No. 52. pp. D405-D416.
The expansion of public pension plans in Canada appears to have had a significant effect on
private pension plans (Benjamin T. Holmes, ibid., panel discussion, p. D442).
n Social Security Bulletin, June 1967, p. 43 and Annual Statistical Supplement, 1965,
p. 103.
30 Further discussion cnn be found in Robert J. Myers. Social Insuiance and Allied
Government Programs (Homewood, Ill.: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1065), ch. X.
PAGENO="0069"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART iii 63~
assistance is indicated by the fact that about four-fifths of the old-age-
assistance recipients also are OASDI beneficiaries.31 At the low end
of the income scale, the distinction between old-age assistance and
OASDI benefits is tenuous. Although the OASDI benefit it techmcafly
paid without a "means test," the record of covered wages, as noted
earlier, becomes essentially a means test for those receiving minimum
benefits. . .
A two-tier system of "social insurance" has substantial possibilities
for more equitable and more economic use of resources. An insurance
portion, more strictly defined, would be limited to risks not covered
by private insurance and pension plans. A welfare element, to be
economic (in contrast with the wasteful type of universal old-age
pension plan used in several countries), would have to be related to
a measure of need, as minimum benefits under OASDI in effect now
are. Separate financing of these elements would appear to be feasible
on lines already used in supplementary medical insurance.
APPENDIX
A DIAGRAMMATIC ANALYSIS OF SOCIAL INSURANCE TAXES FOR RETIrn~-
MENT BENEFITS 1
A simplified model of the economy can serve to highlight the major
issues of financing social insurances. The main question examined here
is the relationship between a pa.y-as-you-go social insurance tax rate
and an "actuarial" insurance tax rate. To put the problem another way,
what is the relationship between a collective or aggregate view of social
insurance financing and an individua.l's cost-benefit view ~
Let us assume that-
(1) The population grows at a constant rate per year.
(2) Every individual enters the labor force at a given age,
a1, works through age. a2 and dies at age. a3 + 1.
(3) Everyone gets the same wage. (This is a useful simplifying
assumption that serves to separate problems of financing over time
from the problem of redistribution by income levels.)
(4) Everyone retires with a social insurance pension equal to
the current wage, or some fraction of the current wage. (In the
case of an increasing wage assumption-i.e., a model with in-
creasing productivity-the individual's pension increases at the
same annual rate as the wage.2)
(5) Full employment is continuously maintained.
POPULATION AGE DISTRIBUTION AND TilE SOCIAL INSURANCE TAX
Under the above assumptions, the population age distribution is
shown in chart A-i. Since the population increases at a constant rate,
the age distribution shows up as a straight line on a semilog chart.
Although there is no zero boundary on such charts, area L can be
taken as representing the labor force, and area. B. as representing the
retired population.
31 Ibid., p. 143.
1 This analysis is largely based on Henry Aaron, "The Social insurance Paradox,"
Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, vol. 32, No. 3, August 1966, pp.
371-374.
I in this case we will be using "double dynamic" assumptions, as Dr. Myers has referred
to them ; namely, a level of benefits tied to an increasing level of wages. (See above,
pp. 2o, 26, and `1/ic 1966 Annual Report of the Board of Trustees of the Federal Old-Age
and Survivors Insurance and Disability Trust Funds, H. Doe. No. 392, 89th Cong., 2d
sess., Feb. 28, 1967, pp. 39, 40.)
PAGENO="0070"
64
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
In any given year, if we assume that the pension is equal to the wage,
the social insurance tax rate, on a pay-as-you-go system, must be equal
to the ratio of the retired to the working population; namely,
R
L
The size of the retired population and the labor force depend on (1)
the number of years people spend in retirement, n=a3-a2, (2) the
J~g~
PAGENO="0071"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART iii 65
years spent in the labor force, m~ a2 - a1 +1, and (3) the rate of
growth of population.3
Altogether, the social insurance tax rate, F, is determined by four
variables or constants:
p=the ratio of the pension to the wage
n=the number of years people spend in retirement
m=t.he number of years people spend in the labor force
t= 1 +the rate of growth of popula~tion.
It should be noted that the pay-as-you-go tax rate is not dependent
on the level or rate of growth of wages. The whole operation of tax
collection and pension payments may be assumed to occur within 1
year, so that we have no problem of payment lags.
Of the four factors affecting the social insurance tax rate, we
might assume any three to be constant, and the fourth to be the main
determinant of the tax rate. Thus, if we assume that the ratio of the
pension to the wage, the number of years in the labor force and in
retirement are constant, we can say that the pay-as-you-go tax rate
depends on the rate of growth of population.4
THE INDIVIDUAL~S ~~AOTUARIAL" RATE
To turn from the aggregate point of view to the position of the indi-
vidual, chart A-2 shows, with a constant wage level, the total amount
of wages paid to an individual over his working life, area W (i.e., the
rectangle a1a2w2w1). Similarly, the amount of pensions paid to an
individual over his retirement years is represented by the area F (i.e.,
the rectangle a2a3w3w2).
If the interest rate were zero and he did not discount the future, the
individual would have to save, or tax himself, at the rate
TP
w=w,
in order to provide himself for his old age (where T=total taxes paid,
and P=total pensions received). The collective pay-as-you-go tax
rate,
R
-it,
is necessarily less than the individual's required rate of saving,
T
8 The labor force, L, is the sum of the population in each age, a, to a2 :L=P(1+t+t2
+ +t"-') where P is the oldest age group and Pt'~-' is the youngest age group in
the labor force. Similarly, the retired population is the sum of the population In the ages
a,+1 to a.,: R=P(t-1+t-2+ +t-~) where Pt-1 is the youngest age group and Pt-'~
is the oldest age group in the retired population. The social Insurance tax rate, F, is deter-
mined by the ratio of the pension to the wage, p, and the ratio of retired to working
population:
F=p~
For the next three decades in the United States, the population aged 65 and over bears
an almost constant ratio to the population aged 20 to 64. This ratio rises from 18.1 percent
In 19135 to about 19 percent in 2000. (United States Population Projections for OASDHI
Cost Estimatcs, Social Security Administration, Actuarial Study No. 62, Washington, D.C.,
December 1966, p. 23). Thus, it would be more realistic to say that the social insurance tax
rate In the United States will depend upon the ratio of the pension to the average wage.
PAGENO="0072"
~CI) ~
CDpW
~
~
CD
0
0
0
0
(J)
(1)
c~i
m
PAGENO="0073"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART iii 67
discounted value of his pensions at the. time of retirement is area P
less area. D. With interest available, he has to save, or tax himself, at
a lower rate than with no interest because of the accumulation of in-
terest on his savings and the discounting of the value of his pension.
Inspection of the charts suggests the break-even point. The ad-
vantage of t.he collective pay-as-you-go rate is just offset when the
interest rate is equal to the rate of growth of population.5
If the interest rate exceeded the rate of population growth, the mdi-
viclual would fare better by doing his own saving than he would under
a collective pay-as-you-go insurance system. The question of whether
there would be a positive iiiterest rate in an economy in which wages
remained constant is a complex one. In a more elaborate model, Pro-
fessor Samuelson has shown that under conditions similar to those
assumed above, the interest rate will indeed be determined by the rate
of population growth.°
THE INSURANCE TAX COMPARISON IN A PROGRESSING ECONOMY
We have shown that the collective pay-as-you-go tax rate is incle-
peiident of the rate of growth of wages. I-low-ever, the rate of growth
of wages (or "productivity") affects the individual's calculation of his
required rate of saving. With a growing wage rate, lie will have to tax
himself more in every year before retirement in order to provide a pen-
sion that. grows with the level of w-ao~es from his year of retirement..
If he is to keep up with the. Joiies' after his retirement, lie will have
to tax himself at a hit~he~ rate over his workin~1ife.7
Under an increasing-wage assumption, the additional saving re-
quireci will more or less offset the additional value obtained from in-
terest-depending on the extent to which the rate of interest exceeds
to the rate of growth of wages.
As Henry Aaron has shown in a slightly different formulation,8 the
collective pay-as-you-go rate will be equal to the individual's "actu-
aria.l" rate, where the interest rate is approximately equal to the sum
of the rate of growth of population and the rate of growth of wages.
This relationship is shown by a comparison of charts A-i and A-3.
In chart A-3, an increasing wage assumption is illustrated by the
rising wage and tax curve. For the sake of direct comparison with
chart A-i, interest is shown on chart A-3 accumulated graphically
from yea.r a5 to year a1. The interest shown in area I~ is the amount
that would be accumulated if the interest rate w-ere just equal to the
rate of growth of wages. The interest shown in area 12 plus area I~ is
the amount that would be accumulated if the interest rate were just
equal to the sum of the rate of growth of wages and the rate of growth
Let Tm =the tax paid in the last year of working life. T'=the total taxes paid over the
individual's working life, and r=i+the rate of interest. Then: T'=Tm(1+r+r2+ .
+r"-1). Similarly, let w5= the wage paid in the last year of working life, and P' =the
discounted value of the individual's pension payments at the time of his retirement. Then:
+r-~). From these equations and those in footnote 3, it follows that
T'=P' when the interest rate is equal to the rate of population growth.
° Paul A. Samuelson. "An Exact Consumption-Loan Model of Interest With or without
the Social Contrivance of Money," Journal of Political Economy, vol. 46, December 1958,
pp. 467-4~2.
Even if he chose only to provide himself a pension equal to the average wage when he
retired, he would also have to save more in his working years when his wage averaged less
than the wage in his last working year.
Op. cit., pp. 373, 374.
PAGENO="0074"
68
OLD AGE IYCOME ASSTJRANCE-PART III
T
~ (T~es)
Interact c~u~21 to ~re.a aae~s ~
iutorsst rate eç~i31 to tao rate of grooth
of v~es. interact c~.e1 to areac Ii & 12
~ interest rate cçiasl. to the rate
of grc'at'~ of ~ plu the rate of ~revth -
of popailatice.
of population. (For illustrative purpose in these charts, the rates of
growth of wages and population were assumed to be 2 percent per
annum.) Inspection of charts A-i and A-3 indicates that the social
insurance tax rate,
1?
HYPOThETICAL IODIVIDUAL~S WAGE, TAX AND PENSION HISTOHY
(Increasing Wage Asstmption)
12
(IntercotC)
Ii
(IntereotC)
PAGENO="0075"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 69
under these assumptions, is ju~t equal `to the individual's actuarial rate,
7,
w~here T', the ac'cumu~iated amount of `taxes plus `interest over a work-
ing life is equal to P', `the discounted value of pensions recifived over
the years of retirement. Any ratio of the pension to the wage affects
the social insurance tax rate and the individual's rate equally.
By way of comparison, individual's in 1967 could generally expect
to get an interest rate on the order of 4½ percent on riskless forms of
savings. The average rate of gro'wth of "productivity" is on the order
of 3 percent, depending on just how, and over w'hat period, it is cal-
culated. The expected rate of population growth (in age groups over
20) from 1965 to 2000 is just 1.5 percent.
There are, of course, various other influences affecting the compari-
son between social insurance and private `saving for old age.9 One of
these is that that most private annuities and other forms of safe invest-
ments do not readily offer the individual the option of providing him-
self with a growing pension. However, the kind of comparison made
above could also be made on the assumption that each individual re-
tires with a pension equal to the wage (or some fraction of the wage)
in his last working year. If everyone retired with a pension equal to
the wage at the time he retired, the pay-as-you-go social insurance
tax rate would be slightly lower, and so would the individual's "ac-
tuarial" rate.
More realistically, w'hat is `done in the United States is that Congress
periodically takes a long-range (or intermediate-range) look at social
insurance benefits and revises them upward on th~ `basis of projections
which assume continuation of the existing level of wages and a fixed
scale of benefits. If this revision is done often enough, the "actuality"
comes close, in its major relevant characteristics, to the model `assumed
above.
In one important respect, however, `the above model differs from
the actual situation: the model assumes a mature system in which
everyone contribu'tes for a full lifetime. In fact, the U.S. system is a
long way from maturity both because few people `have actually con-
tributed for a working lifetime and `because, as a result of liberaliza-
tions, far fewer people have contributed for a long period at a level
of taxation consistent with `the current level of benefits. This situation
raises special problems.
PROBLEMS OF TRANSITION
The financing problems in a period of transition to a mature system
depend upon the way in which transitional financing is arranged.
A social `insurance `system could be pu!t inJto effect immediately wi'th
the same collective tax rate as under a mature system. Since it can be
assumed that such a system would represent a taxing of all wages in
one year to pay for the pensions of the retired population in that same
year, the tax rate in the first year of operation would also be determined
by the ratio of the retired to the working population (given the ratio
o Such matters as the absence of selling costs in a compulsory system will not be con-
sidered here.
PAGENO="0076"
70 OLD AGE IYCOME ASSURA~CE-PART III
of the pension to the. wage and the. number of years of working life
and the number spent in retiremeilt).
It might seem then that we have no problems of transition. It has
been argued in most of the literature on:this subiect that under a pay-
as-you-go system there is necessarily a large unfunded liability to be
met during the transition to a mature system. Those who collect a full
pension before contributing over a. full lifetime receive a windfall.
It does not. follow, however, that. because of such windfalls, the
younger age groups will pay a social insurance tax rate higher than
their actuarial rate. The above analysis shows that the social insurance
tax rate will be equal to the individual actuarial rate, for someone
who works a lifetime under the system, where the iiiterest rate is ap-
proximately equal to the sum of the rate of population grow-th and
the rate of growth of wages. This will be true regardless of any un-
funded liability. Here lies the paradox of social insurance. The younger
age groups are taxed to provide for the aged, but the younger age
groups also get au equivalent quid pio quo in the Government's promise
to pay future benefits. At the. same time, the aged receive windfalls.
Is someone getting something for nothing-or without others having
to give up something?
The answer to this paradox is to be found in the assumption of per-
petual exponential growth.1° The point to be emphasized in consid-
ering social insurance financing is that the pay-as-you-go insurance
rate cannot, oii assumptions used above,'1 exceed the highest individual
actuarial rate as long as the interest rate does not. exceed the sum
of the rate of growth of population and productivity.
The problem of unfunded liabilities is essentially this: Only the
youngest age group in the population will be paying its full actuarial
rate. All older age groups will pay a progressively lower rate, ac-
tuarially, clown to the group just retiring when the system is insti-
tuteci: and this group pays a zero price unless there are provisioiis
for actuarially reduced benefits and minimum periods of coverage
necessary to qualify for benefits.
In order to minimize this price discrimination, most social insur-
amice systems do not immediately pay full benefits. But., neither do
they postpone full benefits until the system reaches maturity. Because.
full benefits are not postponed until the system reaches maturity, most
individuals will pay a social insurance tax rate below their own mdi-
vidua.l actuarial rate. This unfunded liability, however, cannot make
the collective tax rate exceed the indlividual actuarial rate, even for
those just entering the labor force.
INCOME REDISTRIBUTION
It. may be concluded that the cause of current. high social insurance
tax rates (in relation to actuarial levels for young age groups earning
15 This assumption is the basis of certain get-something-for-nothing chain letter schemes.
It was also the assumption underlying many fraternal insurance societies around the
turn of the century. (Frank G. Dickinson. "The Social Security Principle," The Journal of
Insurance, vol. 27, No. 4. December 1960. pp. 5-10.1
11 One of these assumptions is that a free capital market exists and that private forms
of savings are available to the individual. It was also assumed that the social insurance
system would have no effect on the interest rate. In the extreme case, the Government
could continue to raise its promise to pay until tl1e pension was several times as large as
the wage. If the tax rate rose to 100 percent, the rate of interest (and discount) would
presumably be infinite.
PAGENO="0077"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 71
the maximum taxable wage or more) is an element in the system which
was excluded from the model used above; naniely, redistribution by in-
come level. The model assumed that everyone got the same wage. and
the same pension.
In the United States the retirement benefit is not a straight pension
or annuity reflecting past levels of earnings. Rather, the. benefit struc-
ture is set up so that, under the 1954 act; for example (later provisions
are somewhat more complicated, but the same in principle), monthly
retirement benefits amounted to 55 percent of the first $110 of average
monthly covered wages, plus 20 percent of the next $240 of average
monthly wages. Thus, the benefit structure is such as to provide a
large discrimination in favor of very low incomes. On the other hand,
the tax rate is a flat rate up to the maximum table wage. The struc-
ture of taxes and benefits together result in a large amount of in-
come redistribution by income levels.'2
Currently, average retirement benefits are substantially below the
maximum benefits payable to those with covered wages equal to or in
excess of the maximum (chart 1, p. 31). If the maximum wage base
were substantially raised, and a benefit schedule similar to the present
one (in relation to covered wages) were retained, the extent of re-
distribution by income level would be increased. In effect, further
redistribution would be accomplished by greater price discrimination
between those with high and low taxable earnings.
Redistribution effected through a. system of price discrimniation
by income level will generally be less advantageous for the community
as a whole than the same redistribution effected through an income
tax and an equivalent subsidy to low income groups through transfer
payments."
`~ Analyses of redistribution in the social security system can be found in Elizabeth
Deran. "Income Redistribution Under the Social Security System," National Tax Journal,
vol. 19, No. 3, September 1966, pp. 276-285; Ernest C. Harvey, "Social Security Taxes-
Regressive or Progressive?" National Tax Journal, vol. 18, No. 4, December 1965, pp. 408-
414 ; and Henry Aaron, "Income Transfers Under Social Security." in Otto Eckstein, ed.,
Studies in the Economics of Income Maintenance (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Insti-
tution, 1967), pp. 61-72.
`~ A demonstration of this kind of proposition applied to medical care can he found in
Kenneth J. Arrow, "Uncertainty and the Welfare Economics of Medical Care," American
Economic Review, vol. 53, No. 5, December 1963, pp. 957, 958.
PAGENO="0078"
COST-BENEFIT RATIOS UNDER THE FEDERAL OLD-AGE
INSURANCE PROGRAM
BY C0LIN D. CAMPBELL* and ROSEMARY G. CAMPBELL
INTRODUCTION
What is the relationship between the value of accumulated old-age
insurance taxes that persons pay into the OASDI trust fund and the
retirement benefits that they can expect to receive on reaching age
65? If there were a close relationship between taxes paid in and the
value of benefits received, the Federal old-age insurance program
would conform to the popular conception of it as a kind of public in-
surance system. Workers covered by social security usually believe
that they are paying for their future old-age benefits with the taxes
they pay in during their working years. They conceive of themselves
as purchasing an insurance policy, and for a person with the average
life expectancy, the value of the taxes paid in would be similar to
the value of the benefits received.
In keeping with this insurance conception of the program, social
security benefits have often been referred to as annuities, and the tax
payments have been called premiums. Originally, the Social Security
Administration expected to accumulate a large trust fund. When the
Federal old-age insurance program began, financing it by payroll
taxes-even though they are regressive-was justified on the basis
that it was an insurance system. Though the tax would be a much
larger percentage of the income of the poor than of the rich, both
would be paying for an annuity to be received during their old age.
Such taxes would he in accordance with the benefit principle of taxa-
tion. Also, as an insurance program, no means test would be neces-
sary to qualify for benefits on reaching age 65. Benefits were granted
to all retired persons who qualified because it was believed that most
would-more or less-have paid for their old-age pensions.'
Early in its development, the Federal old-age insurance program
departed in practice from this insurance concept. From 1937 to 1950,
planned tax increases from the original 2 percent were continuously
postponed. There have been eight amendments raising benefits, in-
cluding the benefits of those already retired. "New start" provisions
permitting persons to use high-income years and shorter periods as
the basis for benefits, were adopted in 1939 and 1950. Coverage has
been expanded several times to bring in additional beneficiaries who
have contributed little to the fund. The 1965 amendment extends
coverage to self-employed physicians and improves benefits for di-
*professor of Economics, Dartmouth College, Hanover, N.H.
`In the 1935 act, refunds, including a payment to compensate for interest, were to be
paid to persons whose tax contributions were too small to make them eligible for benefits
and to estates of persons who had not received in benefits the amount they paid in.
72
PAGENO="0079"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 73
vorced wives and widows who remarry. More and more the system
has provided pensions for all retired persons regardless of whether
or not they have paid for them.
The following examination of cost-benefit ratios under the Federal
old-age insurance program shows how far the program has, in fact,
departed from the popular conception of insurance. Section I includes
estimates of cost-benefit ratios for persons retiring in 1967. Section II
includes estimates of cost-benefit ratios as provided in the law for
young persons entering the system. Section III outlines some of the
problems in making cost-benefit estimates.
I. COST-BENEFIT RATIOS FOR PERSONS RETIRING IN 1967
A person retiring in 1967 could have paid social security taxes for
no longer than 30 years. The value of his OASDI taxes accumulated
at rates of interest on series E savings bonds until 1963 and 4 percent
thereafter is at most $6,580-$4,720 in taxpayments and $1,860 in
interest. Table 1 shows that up to 1950 the maximum taxpayment
per year for old-age and survivors insurance was only $60. The tax
rate was 2 percent-i percent on the employer and 1 percent on the
employee-and the maximum wage base was $3,000. Since 1950, the
tax rate and the wage base have been gradually raised. In 1966 the
tax rate, excluding medicare, was 7.7 percent; the maximum wage
base, $6,600; and the maximum taxpayment, $508 per year.
TABLE 1.-COMBINED EMPLOYER-EMPLOYEE TAX RATE, THE MAXIMUM WAGE BASE, AND THE MAXIMUM ANNUAL
TAXPAYMENT UNDER OASDI, EXCLUDING MEDICARE
Years Combined employer-employee Maximum wage base
tax rate (percent)
Maximum tax payment per year
1937-49 2 $3,000
1950 3 3,000
1951-53 3 3,600
1954 4 3,600
1955-56 4 4,200
1957-58 4.5 4,200
1959 5 4,800
1960-61 6 4,800
1962 6. 25 4, 800
1963-65 7. 25 4, 800
1966 7.7 6,600
1967-68 7.8 6,600
1969-72 8. 8 6, 600
1973on 9.7 6,600
$60
90
108
144
168
189
240
288
300
348
508
515
581
640
A person retiring in 1967 has had, since 1939, survivors' insurance
for his wife and young children in case he died early. Since 1956,
he has also had disability insurance. If it is assumed that 20 percent
of taxpayments of the worker who lives to retirement has gone to
pay for these other forms of insurance, this person has paid a maxi-
mum of $5,263 for old-age insurance alone.
A worker retiring in 1967 who has paid in the maximum is entitled
to an annual pension of $1,631, plus $816 for an aged wife, a total of
$2,447. As shown in table 2, a pension of this amount, discounted at 4
percent for the average length of life that they can expect-14 more
years-is worth $26,631. Their social security benefits are worth five
times the value of the payroll taxes he has paid in.
PAGENO="0080"
74 OLD AGE IXCOME ASSTJRAXiCE-PART III
TABLE 2.-COST-BENEFIT RATIOS FOR PERSONS ALREADY RETIRED UNDER TIlE FEDERAL OLD-AGE INSURANCE
PROGRAM
Total
Annual
Value
Cost-bean-
Age and starting date
under OASI
Retire-
most
date
Average annual
wage
Total
value
of
OASDI
taxes 1
value of
taxes for
old-age
insurance
alone 2
pension
for
man
and
wife
of
pension
for
14
years
fit ratio
(column 5
divided by
column 7,
percent)
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
Married man:
40 in 1937
37 in 1937
35 in 1937
35 in 1937
35 in 1937
Married man, with a tax paymentcom-
puted in terms of constant dollars:
1962
1965
1967
1967
1957
1967
Maximum base
Maximum base
Maximum base
~ maximum buse...
~ maximum base~
Maximum base
$3,782
5,200
6.579
4,934
3.289
8,700
$3,026
4,160
5,263
3,947
2,632
6,960
$2,330
2,371
2,447
2,023
1,618
2,447
$25,358
25,804
26,631
22,017
17,609
26, 631
12
16
20
18
15
26
35 in 1937.
Married man with working wife: 35
in 1937.
1967
Maximum base
13, 157
10, 526
3,262
35, 501
30
Single person: 35 in 1937
Self-employed, married man: 49 in
1951.~
1967
1967
Maxmum base
Maximum bane
6. 579
3,635
5, 263
2,908
1, 631
2,447
17, 750
26,631
30
11
1 Compounded at E-bond rates until 1963 and 4 percent thereafter.
2 80 percent of column 4.
3 Discounted at 4 percent interest.
First covered in 1951.
Many retired workers have had an even more attractive bargain.
Social security pensions may now be based on covered wages only since
1951, and the lowest 5 years in wages may be excluded. It. is possible for
a worker retiring in 1967 to obtain a pension worth $26,631 even if
he paid no taxes before 1956, but. maximum taxes since then. At age
65, the value of such a person's taxpayments for old-age insurance
would be only $3,031. He would receive almost nine times what he
has paid in. Most workers who have been "blanketed" into the syster~i
since it began have received similar bargains, although over time th.~
low cost-benefit ratios of these groups will disappear. Coverage w-a~
extended to domestic workers, farm wage workers, and the self-
employed in 1951, self-employed farmers in 1955, dentists and military
servicemen in 1956, and self-employed physicians in 1965. In 1950 only
62 percent of the labor force was covered compared with over 90 per-
cent in 1967.
A group that has not had such a good bargain is those who are single
at retirement-whether a bachelor, widower, or, in some cases, di-
vorceci. A single worker who has paid maximum taies since 1937 and
retires in 1967 is entitled to receive a. Pension of only $1,631 per year.
This is because he does not receive a secondary benefit for an aged wife..
Single persons are not. supposed to need as large a pension as married
couples-although this is not always the case. This Pension is worth
$17,750, compared to the total value of his taxes for old-age insurance
of $5,263. His cost-benefit ratio is 30 percent. (See table 2.)
The cost-benefit. ratios of working couples are also relatively high. If
a man and his wife, retiring in 1967, have both been employed and paid
maximum taxes since 1937, together they will have paid in taxes worth
$10,526. But, a. wife cannot receive both the pension she is entitled
to as a wife and the pension she herself has earned. She receives only
the larger of the two. A working wife is not supposed to need both
the wife's portion of her husband's pensioim and the pension she her-
PAGENO="0081"
OLD AGE IT~COME ASSURANCE-PART III 75
self would be entitled to through her own tax payments. The maximum
amount that this retired couple may receive is $1,631 each, a total
pension of $3,262 per year. A pension of this amount, discounted at 4
percent to age 65, is worth $35,500, and their cost-benefit ratio is 30
percent.
Married women workers are a significant group in the total labor
force, and their numbers have been growing rapidly. In 1940 there
were only 7 million married women workers in a labor force of approx-
imately 56 million persons. In 1964 there were about 20 million married
women workers (including widows) out of a total labor force of some
74 million. In most cases, a married woman worker. will not. have
worked long enough or at high enough wages to earn an old-age bene-
fit that is larger than the amount she would automatically be entitled
to as a wife (half her husband's benefit). A woman worker retiring
in 1967 must be employed at least 31/4 years in order to be eligible for
benefits of her own, and 8 years' wages must be averaged to compute
benefits. If she has worked over 31/4 years, but. less than 8 years, zeros
are counted for the years in which she was not employed, and her bene-
fits will tend to be low. In the future, the law provides that a woman
born after 1928 be employed at least 10 years to be eligible for benefits
on reaching age 65 and that wages for 35 years be averaged as a. basis
for her benefits
How have retired persons who have earned less than the maximum
wage base fared under the Federal old-age insurance program? A
worker, retiring in 1967, who has paid taxes on three-quarters of the
maximum base since 1937 has paid old-age taxes worth $3,947. He and
his wife would be eligible for an annual pension of $2,023. Such a
pension is worth just over $22,000, and his cost-benefit ratio is 18 per-
cent, as compared with 20 percent for the worker who has paid the
maximum tax. If he has paid one-half the maximum tax since 1937,
the cost-benefit ratio would be 15 percent. The lower cost-benefit ratios
for persons with wages below the maximum w-age base are intentional.
The social security law does not reduce their benefits in proportion to
the taxes paid in.2
Self-employed persons, another distinct group under tile social se-
curity program, have relatively low cost-benefit ra.tios because their
tax rate is one and a half times the employee's tax rate. (or three-
fourths the combined employee-employer tax rate). Also, t.hey were
first included in 1951. The purpose of the lower t.a.x rate OH t.he self-
employed was to avoid overtaxing tile self-employed relative to those
working for an employer, on the assumption that tile entire tax on
the employer is not shifted to the employee. Table 2 shows t.ha.t t.he
2 Although the law provides for higher cost-benefit ratios for persons with higher average
annual incomes up to the maximum wage base, there are several offsetting factors that
may. in fact, reduce cost-benefit ratios for the higher income groups and raise them for
the lower income groups. Higher income groups probably live longer on the average than
lower income groups and thus collect benefits for a longer period, of time. Also, the ex-
clusion of social security old-age benefits from Federal income taxation raises the benefits
of higher income groups relative to the taxes paid in. Eventually persons with low incomes
will pay in taxes for a larger number of years because they ty;pically start to work at a
younger age. Also, if there is a larger percentage of working couples among lower income
groups than among higher income groups, this would tend to raise cost-benefit ratios for
the lower income groups. In addition, the work income test which excludes some persons
who work after fi5 from receiving old-age benefits may affect the lower income groups more
adversely than the upper income groups.
53-200-GT-pt. 3-G
PAGENO="0082"
76 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
maximum accumulated tax payments for old-age insurance of a self-
employed person retiring in 1967 is $2,908, compared with benefits for
himself and his wife worth $26,631. This is a cost-benefit ra.tio of only
11 percent. In 1965, 6.6 million persons out of 62.7 million-li percent
of civilian employees covered by OASDI-were self-employed.3
The estimated cost-benefit ratios for different groups of persons re-
tiring in 1967, shown in table 2, indicate that the prevailing concep-
tion of social security as an insurance program in which workers are
purchasing an annuity is incorrect. In fact, a significant net transfer
over their lifetime is being made to the 15 million persons who are
currently receiving old-age pensions.
Because of the inflation between 1937 and 1967, the real value of the
taxes paid in is larger than the nominal amount. Table 2 shows that
in terms of 1966 dollars the total value of tax payments for old-age
insurance for the man contributing the maximmn from 1937 through
1966 is $6,960, approximately 32 percent more than the nominal value.
Even so, the value of his tax payments for old-age insurance alone
would be worth only 26 percent of t.he value of the pension he is en-
titled to for himself and his wife.
Table 2 also shows that cost-benefit ratios for persons retiring in
recent years have been increasing. The married man who retired 5
years ago, in 1962, paid in, at most, only 12 percent of the value of his
pension. Two years ago it was 16 percent. Today, it is 20 percent. The
reason for this increase is that payroll taxes have been increased
sharply. Underlying this is the fact that the old-age insurance sys-
tem attempts to collect each year just enough through the payroll tax
and through interest on the trust fund to cover benefit disbursements.
The system has become more costly as larger numbers of persons have
retired who are eligible for higher benefits, and a.s benefits for those
already retired have been increased to keep up with the cost of living
or to provide larger minimum benefits.
Because of the variation in the cost-benefit ratios among different
categories of retired workers, the social security program is trans-
ferring more income to some groups than to others. Those benefited
most are the self-employed, those blanketed in after the program was
initiated, workers whose wives have not been employed, and workers
with less than the maximum wage base. Those benefited least are single
persons and working couples.
II. COST-BENEFIT RATIOs FOR YOtTNG PERSONS
For young persons, cost-benefit relationships are uncertain. The tax
rate on payrolls, the maximum wage base, and benefit levels may be
ra.ised in the future, a.nd future trends in interest rates are difficult to
forecast. Nevertheless, an examination of the cost-benefit ratios in the
current law for young persons entering the system shows some of the
problems ahea.d.
A young person starting work in 1967 at the age of 22 and earning
at least $6,600 per year for the next 43 years is scheduled to pay
~ Social Security Bulletin, Annual Statistical Supplement, 1965, page 4.
PAGENO="0083"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 77
OASDI taxes (excluding medicare) worth $68,076, if 4 percent inter-
est is assumed. (See table 3.) In 1967 the rate of tax for old-age,
survivors, and disability insurance was 7.8 percent, and the maximum
tax per worker was approximately $515 per year. This total will be
gradually increased until it reaches $640 in 1973. The tax payments
over his lifetime amount to approximately $27,000, and the accumu-
lated interest to $41,000. After deducting 20 percent of the total value
of his taxe,s for survivors and disability insurance, the amount paid
in for old-age insurance alone would be $54,461.
TABLE 3.-COST-BENEFIT RATIOS FOR PERSONS OF DIFFERENT AGE SCHEDULED UNDER THE CURRENT FEDERAL
OLD-AGE INSURANCE PROGRAM
Total
Value
Cost-bene-
Re-
Total
value of
An-
of
fit ratio
Age and starting date
tire-
ment
date
Average annual
wage
value of
OASDI
taxes'
taxes for
old-age
insurance
alone'
nual
pen-
sion
pension
for 14
years'
(col. 5
divided by
col. 7)
(percent)
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
Married man:
30 in 1937
22 in 1937
22 in 1945
22 in 1949
22 in 1955
22 in 1967
22 in 1967
22 in 1967
Married man with working wife:
22 in 1967.
1972
1980
1988
1992
1998
2010
2010
2010
2010
Maximum base
Maximum base
Maximum base
Maximum base
Maximum base
$6,600 or more
$4,950
$3,300
$6,600 or more each
$11,000
20,873
32,002
38,932
50,108
68, 076
51,057
34,038
136, 152
$8,800
16,698
25,602
31,145
40,087
54,461
40,846
27,230
108,922
$2,636
2,776
2,848
2,871
2,963
3,024
2,496
1,927
4,032
$28,688
30,212
30,995
31,246
32,247
32, 911
27,164
20,977
43, 881
31
55
83
100
124
165
150
130
248
Single person: 22 in 1967
Self-employed, married man: 22
in 1967.
2010
2010
$6,600 or more
$6,600 or more
68,076
49,608
54,461
39,686
2,016
3,024
21,941
32,911
248
121
`Compounded at E-bond rates of interest until 1963 and 4 percent thereafter.
2 80 percent of column 4.
Discounted at 4 percent interest.
The maximum retirement benefit that this young worker is sched-
uled to receive is $3,024 per year-$2,016 for himself and $1,008 for his
aged wife. A pension of $3,024 at age 65 could be financed with ac-
cumulated tax payments of only $32,911-much less than the value of
the taxes he is scheduled to pay in. This young worker's cost-benefit
ratio is 165 percent.
Table 3 shows that if workers have paid in the maximum taxes and
expect to continue to do so until retirement, the break-even point under
the present law is 39 years of age. Workers older than this gain;
workers less than 39 years of age lose. For those with incomes below
the maximum wage base, the break-even age is lower. Young men who
are married and earn less than the maximum wage base have relatively
small cost-benefit ratios, even though in both cases shown in table 3 the
cost exceeds the benefits. In addition, cost-benefit ratios are relatively
low for self-employed young persons starting employment in 1967, but
very high for single persons.
Over the years, *the prospective cost-benefit ratios for the young
entrant into the labor force have varied. Table 4 shows that in 1937 the
cost-benefit ratio for the young worker starting employment at age
22 was 133 percent. At that time, it was thought that young workers
PAGENO="0084"
78 OLD AGE INCOME ASSLRANCE~PART Ill
and their employers would have to pay in somewhat more than the
value of their own pensions in order to provide pensions of reasonable
size to those who would retire soon after the program began. The 1950
amendment to the Social Security Act significantly lowered the cost-
benefit ratio for young workers because of the substantial increases in
benefits made at that time. Since 1950, cost-benefit ratios have risen
from 100 percent to their present high levels primarily because of new
programs widening the coverage, higher minimum benefits, and the
maturing of the system.
TABLE 4.-COST-BENEFIT RATIOS FOR NEW ENTRANTS UNDER PROGRAMS EXISTING AT TIME OF ENTRY
Starting date at age 22
Total value
of expected
taxes 1
Total value
of expected
taxes for
old-age
insurance
alone 2
Annual pen-
sion
scheduled
for man and
wife
Value of
expected
pension for
14 years
Expected
coot-benefit
ratio
(cot. 3 divided
by col. 5)
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
1937
1950
1960
1965~
1967
$14,776
19,665
43,509
47,877
68,076
4 $14,776
15,732
34,807
38,302
54,461
$1,020
1,440
2,286
2,286
3,024
$11, 101
15,672
24,879
24,879
32,911
133
100
140
154
166
Under proposed 1967 amendments:
1968
1974
109,449
118,813
87,559
95,050
4,440
4,536
48,321
49,366
181
193
1 Compounded at E-bond rates of interest until 1963 and 4 percent thereafter.
2 80 percent of col. 2.
3 Discounted at 4 percent interest.
The social security system did not include survivors and disability insurance in 1937,
Prior to amendments of 1965.
Recently pro~osec1 amendments to the Social Security Act would in-
crease further the cost-benefit ratios of young workers. Table 4 shows
that under H.R. 5710, the amendment to the Social Security Act~ pro-
posed in 1967, the cost-benefit ratio for a young married worker paying
the maximum in taxes would rise to 193 percent by 1974.~ This law
would increase minimum benefits from $66 to $105.
What can be definitely said about the current tax and benefit. sched-
ules is that benefits must be increased in the future if young persons
today are going to get their money's worth. But, if benefits are in-
creased in the future, will payroll tax rates also have to be increased?
This will depend primarily on the extent to which growth in the labor
force and increases in the productivity of labor can support the re-
quireci increases in revenues without an increase in tax rates. Also, it
will depend on whether or not the maximum wage base of the payroll
tax is raised with increases in labor productivity. Under the present
law, social security taxes automatically rise with the wages of persons
earning less than the maximum wage base, but for other workers in-
creases in the wage base require an act. of Congress. During the past 30
years, the maximum wage base of the social security tax has been
raised only four times.
HR. 5710 also sets a ceiling of $90 a month for benefits to nonworliing wives-much
loss than half the maximum prOpOse(l primary benefit of $2SS per month, This would result
in higher cost-benefits ratios for couples without a working wife.
PAGENO="0085"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 79
If increases in revenues from payroll taxes based on increases in the
productivity of labor are needed in the future to give young workers
their money's worth, such funds will not be available to support
further developments of the social security system as an antipoverty
program. The historical development of the social security system has
been toward the gra.nting of more adequate benefits to persons regard-
less of whether or not they have paid for them. If this trend continues,
substantial additional revenue will be needed to support both the in-
surance and the welfare objectives of the social security system. Con-
tinuous increases in the maximum wage base and either higher payroll
tax rates or the development of other sources of revenue will probably
be necessary.
III. SOME PROBLEMS IN MAKING COST-BENEFIT COMPARIsoNs
The computer programs used to calculate the total value of the taxes
paid in and the benefits expected are shown in figures 1 and 2.~ The
~Iogi'am in figure. 1, entitled "Taxes," illustrates the method of cal-
culating the total value of the taxes paid in by a young worker entering
the system at. age 22 in 1967. He is scheduled to pay $514.80 per year in
taxes for 1967 and 1968, $580.80 per year from 1968 to 1971, a.nd
$640.20 per year from 1972 until retirement 37 years lat.er. A rate of
interest, of 4 percent is assumed. The value of the taxes he pays in is
$68.076, as shown in table 3.
The program in figure 2 entitled "Annuity" illustrates the method
of calculating the value of the. benefits expe.c.ted by a. worker retiring
in 1967 who has earned the maximum benefit and has a wife who is
also 65. They are entitled to a benefit of $2,447 per year. It is assumed
that they can expect t.o live 14 years and that. the rate. earned on the
unused balance is 4 percent. The value of their benefits is $20,631, as
shown in table 2.
(a) TT7hat rate o~ i'nterest 8houid be used?
To estimate t.he value of ta.xes paid by a.n employee and his em-
ployer, the t.ax payments of pe.rsons retiring in 1967 were compounded
at current rates of interest on a.lternative forms of saving. The fol-
lowing rates of intere.st on E bonds were used until 1963 and 4 per-
cent., the rate on savings deposits, was used thereafter:
Rates of interest on. series B, U.S. savings bonds
Rate ot interest
Years (percent)
1937 to mid-1952 2. 9
Mid-1952 to 1950 3. 0
1957 to mid-1959 3. 25
Mid-1959 to 1902 3 75
For diccounting future benefits and for estimating the value of taxes
paid in the future, a rate of interest of 4 percent was considered to be
a.s good a forecast as possible. For persons retiring in 1967, changes in
the rate of interest used do not change significantly the resulting cost.-
Tlip~e n"o.rrenis are written in ha~ic. See John G. Kemeny and Thoma.s E. Kurtz,
"°.` ~ic." third edition. (Hanover, N.H., Dartmouth College Computation Center, Jan. 1,
lOud).
PAGENO="0086"
80 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART Ill
Fig~iro 1
TAXES
10 READX,S
20 FØRN=1TØ3
30 READ Y (N)
40 READ T (N)
50 NEXT N
60 FØR.Q=1TØ3
70 F~RF=1TØT(Q)
80 lET S = (s. * x) ÷ ~ (Q)
90 NEXT P
100 ~EXT Q
110 PR~T S
120 DATA 1.014~,0, 511h80, 2, ,58~.80, 1', 6i~.2O, ~7
130 END
RUN
TAXES
68076.
Figu~ 2
ANNUITY
10 PLEAD X,Y
20 IETS~0
30 F~'RN~1TØ1~4'
40 lET S = S + X * (1-.Y) `~(~l)
50 NEXTN
60 p~I~T S
70 DATA.2L~+7, .04
80 END
RUN
26631.1
PAGENO="0087"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSIJRANCE-PART Ui 81
benefit ratios. The cost-benefit ratio for a married person retiring in
1967, who has paid in the maximum, is 18 percent using 3 percent in-
terest, 21 using 4 percent, and 25 using 5 percent interest. But, for a
young person entering the system in 1967, changes in the rate of inter-
est cause large differences in cost-benefit ratios. For a married man
paying the maximum, the cost-benefit ratio is 121 percent using 3 per-
cent interest, 165 percent using 4, and 227 percent using 5 percent
interest. This is because the taxes paid by young workers are accumu-
lated over 43 years rather than 30 years. Also, the early tax payments,
which are held the longest and account for much of the accumulated
interest, are larger for young entrants today than they were for persons
retiring in 1967.
(b) What life expectancy should be assumed.5
The Life Insurance Fact Book gives the following predictions of
life expectancy for persons who were 65 years of age in 1964:
Years remaining
Color and sex at age 65
~\Thjte male 13.. 0
White female 16. 3
Nonwhite male 12. 8
Nonwhite female 15. 6
Average, all races 14. 6
To simplify the calculations, all of the estimates in this study assume
the same life expectancy for both husband and wife (14 years) and
the same age for both husband and wife. More exact assumptions
would change the cost-benefit ratios very slightly. Also, it was assumed
that life expectancy would not change in the decades ahead.
(c) What is the cost of survivors and disability insurance.5
The cost-benefit ratios estimated in this study are retrospective. They
refer to persons who live to age 65 and retire.~ The value of the taxes
paid in is the total amount accumulated over the working life of a
person up to age 65. The estimated value of the old-age benefits is
based on the expected life of a man and his wife at age 65.
Part of the payroll taxes that persons pay prior to reaching age 65
represent the cost of the disability and survivors insurance that they
have had during their working years. In 1965, payments for survivors
and disability insurance amounted to $5.6 billion, approximately 30
percent of total OASDI payments of $18.3 billion. This is consider-
ably more than the 20 percent deduction assumed in this study. The rea-
son for the difference is that in this study, payments to widows of hus-
bands who live to age 65 are consider.ed as old-age rather than survivors
insurance benefits. The estimated deduction of 20 percent includes the
total cost of disability insurance, but only that portion of survivors
benefits paid to young widows with children and to aged widows of
insured persons who died before age 65.
6Life Insurance Fact Book, 1966 (New York, Institute of Life Insurance, 1966), p. 95.
Persons not living to age 65 pay in differing amounts of taxes, depending on how long
they live. Most of them live until near age 65 and pay in close to the full amount of taxes
for persons with their in.comes. Even though they do not receive old-age benefits, their
survivors-widowedi mothers with children under their care and their widows on reaching
age 65-do.
PAGENO="0088"
82 OLD AGE INCOME ASSLRANCE-PART III
The social security law allocates seven-tenths of 1 percent (raised
from one-half of 1 percent in 1965) of covered payrolls to a special
disability insurance trust fund. On this basis, the funds allocated for
disability insurance amount to approximately 9 perceilt of total pay-
roll taxes for OXSDI.
No specineci amount is set aside for survivors' benefits. Approxi-
match- one-third of those who start work in their early twenties do
not live to age 65.~ If it is assumed that two-thirds of the survivors'
benefits paid to widows are paid to widows of workers who live to
retirement, the remaining perceilt age of total benefits for disability
and survivors insurance is approxunately ~O percent.9
NUMBER OFSURVIVORS ATSINGLEYEARS OF AGE, OUT OF 100000 BORN ALIVE, BY COLOR AND SEX, UNITED
STATES, 1964
Age
White male
Nonwhite male
20
65
96.099
66,009
93,334
50,341
(d) Is the payroll tax on the employer a cost to the employee?
In this study, both the portion of the payroll tax that is nominally
paid by the employer and the portion deducted from the employee's
paycheck are included in the cost to the. worker of his old-age pension.
This is based on the belief that payroll taxes on an employer are soon
shifted to his employees. A payroll tax increases the employer's labor
cost and decreases his demand for labor. This spread over all firms
slows up the rise in wages. so that the wage earner, in effect, pays the
employer part. of the tax as well as that nominally levied on the
employee.10
Beliefs concerning the incidence of the payroll tax on the employer
vary widely. The estimates of cost-benefit ratios b Myers and Oppal
and by Peterson. shown in table 5. exclude completely the 1)ayroll tax
on the employer. On the other hand, in a recent study of social security
contributions and benefits. Aaron makes the same assumption as in this
study-that the entire tax on the employer is shifted to the worker.1'
Aaron relates the old-age pe31s1o3~s of typical workers in various in-
dustries to their "actuarially justified annuities." Although he presents
the comparison ill a. different way, the issues discussed are similar to
those in the studies of cost-benefit ratios.
The followiow fiwures are taken from ITS. Peon rtment of Health. Educotion. and Wel-
fare. Vital Statistics of the Fnited States, 1904. vol. II. Mortality. Pt. A. sec. ~. table 5-a.
0 Estimates of the cost of different components of social security coverawe may be found
in table 14 o~' Robert .1. Myers, `Social Insurance and Allied Government Programs'
(JTo"°wood. ill.. IrwIn. lO4ITfl. p. ~
10 For n'~ intires~ing account of the incidence of the payroll tax or the employer. ~pp
Paul Dour1'.~. Ooci.il S'ciiritv in the' E nitcil States." second edition (New York. Wh~t~le-
5°v Hruse. 39~91. pa. 02-OC. He co'lcludes that ainder conditions of pure competition, the
entire cost o~ the tax on the co~pioyci' would be frnnsfor"ecl to the workers, and cinder
m°no'~olv. in n'ost c'~ee, it woul-l he at Jeiist oarti'~lly shifted.
~ Henry .~fl~'on. "Ren~0ts OTm'er the Ainei'ieaii Social Sccu"itv System," in Otto Eckoteln,
ed,tion, Stpd'ee in the Economics of Income Maintenance (Washington. D.C.. Brookiiigs.
11)07 ) . up. 02-07. -
PAGENO="0089"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 83
TABLE 5.-COMPARISON OF COST-BENEFIT RATIOS MADE BY MYERS AND OPPAL, PETERSON, AND
CAMPBELL
lIn
percenti
Retirement date
Myers and
Oppal 1
Peterson
Campbell
Interest rate used
3 percent
3 percent 33-i percent
4 percent
4 percent
(1)
(2) (3)
(4)
(5)
Married man:
1962
7.6
7.2 7.9
8.6
12
1965
10.2
9.5 10.4
11.4
16
1970
16.0
14.7 16.2
17.8
1980
31.4
29.9 33.6
37.7
55
1990
47.8
47.6 54.3
62.0
2000
66.6
66.8 77.9
90.9
2010
78.6
82.7 97.9
116.2
165
Single man: 2010
132.6
139.7 164.9
195.1
248
1 Prior to 1965 amendments.
Source: Robert J. Myers and Bertram Oppal, "Studies on the Relationship of Contributions to Benefits in Old-Age
Bnnefit Awards," actuarial note No. 20 (Washington, U.S. Department of Health, Education, and Welfare, Social Security
Administration, June 1965), table 3; and Ray M. Peterson, addendum to table 3 of actuarial note Ms. 20, issued June 1965
by the Social Security Administration. Elizabeth Deran uses estimates by Ray M. Peterson in her stody, "Income Redistri-
bution Under the Social Security System," Nat. Tax Jour., XIX (Soptomber 1966), pp. 281 and 214. Estimates by Peterson
were also used in the Tax Foundation, "The Economic Aspects of the Social Security Tax" (New York, Tax Foundation,
Inc., 1966), p. 48.
Because both the study by Myers and Oppal and that by Peterson
assume that the tax on the employer is not shifted to the. worker, their
estimates of cost-benefit ratios are considerably smaller than those
made in this study. (See table 5.) This difference alone would cause
their estimates of the cost to the worker of social security benefits to
be one-half those in this study. Another difference between their esti-
mates and those here is that they did not deduct 20 percei~t of the
taxes paid in for survivors and disability insurance. This difference
would tend to make their estimates larger than those in this study.
A third difference is the interest rates used. The use of 3 percent by
Myers and Oppa.l is lower than the rates assumed since 1957 in this
study and would tend to make their estimated cost-benefit ratios
relatively low. They also assume the pei~on started work at. age 20
rather than at age 22-tending to make their cost-benefit ratios
slightly higher.
(e) Should an adjustment be made for the tax-free rature of social
securit~j benefits ~
The estimates of cost-benefit ratios in this study have not taken into
consideration the tax-free status of social security benefits. To persons
in high income brackets, social security benefits are worth more than
their face value. For example, if a retired person is in the 19 percent
bracket, additional tax-free income of $2,400 is worth over $3,000. If
a person is in the 50 percent bracket, it is worth $4~800. The cost-benefit
ratios of retired persons in high income brackets, taking account of
this factor, would decline as their income increases.
(f) Should a tax-free build up of contribution-s be assumed~
The estimates of the value of the taxes contributed in tables 2, 3,
and 4 assume that the accumulated interest earned is not taxed as
PAGENO="0090"
84 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
personal income. Social security taxes are treated like premiums of a
private annuity. The earnings are built up, tax free, during the period
in which premiums are paid in. If it were assumed that the annual
interest income was taxed as current income, the accumulated value
of the social security ta.xes paid in would be less and the cost-benefit
ratios would be smaller.
IV. CONCLUSION
Despite different possible assumptions, the studies of cost-benefit
ratios that have been made by various authors lead to similar con-
clusions.12 The first is that the insurance concept of the social security
system in which workers are supposed to be purchasing an old-age
annuity with the taxes they and their employer are paying is largely
a myth. It is a popular analogy and is often repeated in newspaper
editorials and statements by imblic officials, but, there is, in fact., little
to support it. The second conclusion is that cost-benefit ratios vary
considerably depending on the age, sex, income, and occupation of a
person. Some of these differences are the result of ad hoc changes in
the program as it has developed. There is a need to reexamine social
security as a program of income tra.nsfers in order to assure that it is
fulfilling the objectives of public policy. Although it is usually assumed
that the social security system redistributes income so as to benefit
lower income groups, it is not obvious that it is actually doing so. The
final conclusion is that unless the ta.x paid by the employer is not, in
fact, a cost to the employee, the cost-benefit ratios of young entrants
into the labor force have become very high. Because scheduled benefits
may be raised in the future, the terms of the current law do not
necessarily mean that young persons are not going to get their money's
worth. They do indicate the need for a social security model which
explicitly assumes increasing benefit levels. One of the objectives of
such a model might be to provide a closer balance between costs and
benefits for young workers.
`~ See particularly Ray M. Peterson, "Misconceptions and Missing Perceptions of Our
Social Security System (Actuarial Anesthesia) ." Transactions of the Society of Actuaries,
XI (November 1059), 812-851, and "People, Pensions, and Production," address at 11th
Annual Southwestern Economics Forum, University of Southwestern Louisiana, Lafayette,
La., Mar. 7, 1962.
PAGENO="0091"
INFLATION AND PRODUCTIVITY IN TAX-BENEFIT
ANALYSIS FOR SOCIAL SECURITY
BY YUNG-PING CHEN*
In the nature of a progress report, the purpose of this paper is to
offer some preliminary answers to the following questions bearing upon
the retrospective and prospective views of the relationships of social
security taxes and social security benefits:
(1) Do workers gain or lose on their taxes for social security?
(2) As a means of financial protection, is private insurance
superior to social security from the standpoint of monetary costs?
Or could a worker obtain more benefits from a private insurance
contract if he purchases it with the taxes otherwise paid into
social security?
(3) How are the relationships of taxes to benefits influenced by
considerations of price inflation and productivity gains, especially
with references to the future?
In section I, several existing studies of social security "gainers" and
"losers" are briefly summarized, with particular emphasis on their
approaches and assumptioiis. A worker is a gainer when lie and/or his
family have, or will have, received more benefits than what he has
contributed. A worker becomes a loser if he and/or his family have,
or will have, received less benefits than what he has contributed. In
the same section, alternative estimates based on a set of assumptions
consistently applied to certain hypothetical workers in different cir-
cumstances are presented. In section II, cost comparisons between
private insurance and social security are made on the basis of three il-
lustrative workers. In section III, taxes-to-benefits relationships in
future years are examined under various assumed conditions regarding
price inflation and productivity. Section IV contains some concluding
remarks.
I. TAX-BENEFIT RATIO ESTIMATES
The relationships of taxes to benefits under social security have been
estimated by various writers. In earlier studies, these relationships
were expressed in percentage terms, although the word "ratio" was
*T1~e author is on the faculty of the Department of Ecoiiomics, University
of California, Los Angeles. He is indebted to Profs. Harold Somers and Roland
McKean for valuable comments on an earlier draft. Helpful actuarial opinions
were received from Messrs. Leonard Berekson, Kenneth Clark, Sylvester Maru-
sich, Robert J. Myers, and Forrest Ockels, and also from Drs. Chester Healy,
Malcolm Heslip, and Irving Pfeffer. None of these persons or the organizations
with which they are associated should be held responsible for the views ex-
pressed here. This paper is a summary of one phase of a research project
in progress on income maintenance in old age. The project has been supported
by grants from the Institute of Industrial Relations, Bureau of Business and
Economic Research, Research Committee of the Academic Senate, all of UCLA.
Computations were performed at the computing facility, also of UCLA. Able re-
search assistance in the overall project has been rendered by Messrs. Kwang-wen
Chu, Jose Acosta, and Robert Black.
85
PAGENO="0092"
86 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
sometimes used. In summarizing these estimates in subsections A and
C below, their percentage figures are quoted. However, in the alter-
native estimates reported in subsections B and P below, taxes-to-
benefits relationships are identified as "tax-benefit. ratios" for brevity
and clarity. These ratios are obtained by dividing the total corn-
pounded value of taxes by the total discounted value of benefits, both
as of a given year. rfo compare with other estimates, tax-benefit. ratios
in tables 1, 2, and 3 need to be multiplied by 100. (See tables 1, 2, and 3
on pp. 73,74, and 77.)
Gainers in social security are discussed in subsections A and B, and
losers in C and D. A worker is a. gainer if he has a tax-benefit ratio
of less than unity (or smaller than 100 percent in previous studies)
the larger the gains, the smaller the ratio. A worker becomes a loser
if his tax-benefit. ratio is greater than unity (or larger than 100 percent
in previous st.udies) ; the larger the losses, the larger the ratio.
A. SOCIAL SECDIHTY GAINERS : SUMMARY OF EXISTING ESTIMATES
With respect to gainers, four sets of computations may be noted.
The Social Security Administration has reported two sample studies
of the relationship of contributions to benefits.' Both samples were
chosen by usmg an account number digital pattern designed to yieldl
a. random sample of 100 awards each. Sample No. 1 was selected from
benefit a.wards in August 1960, and No. 2, in September 1962, reflect-
ing different. insured reqllirements. When contributions were ac-
cunmlated at. 3 percent interest and benefits were discounted at the
same rate, sample No. 1 showed the value of contributions as a per-
centage of the value of total benefits to be 5.5 percent. for male and 4.1
percent. for female beneficiaries. The corresponding figures in sample
No. 2 were 8.5 percent. and 4.8 percent, respectively. Contributions
included only the taxes paid by the employee and those paid by the
self-employed. The mortality basis used was the U.S. Life Tables for
White Persons, 1949_51.2 Total benefits included those for old-age,
1 Robert J. Meyers and Bertram Oppal. "Studies on the Relationship of Contributions
to Benefits in Old-Age Benefit Awards." Actuarial note No. 20. Social Security Administra-
tion. U.S. Department of Health. Education, and Welfare. Jane 1965.
° According to Life Tables for 1949-51, the average number of years of life remaining at
age 65 was 13.S6 for all whites (12.T5 for white males and 15.00 for white females). The
following table shows tile life expectancies for different groups in the population. as well
as improvements in mortality during a period of 10 years. (See the following table :)
AVERAGE NUMBER OF YEARS OF LIFE REMAINING AT AGE 65
Populatios groups
1949-51
1959-62
Total population
13.13
14.39
Total males
12.74
12.95
Total females
14.95
15.10
Total whites
13.16
14.44
White males
White females
12.75
15.00
12.97
15.18
Total noswhites
13.59
13.96
Nonwhite males
Nonwhite females
12.75
14.54
12.84
15.12
"Life Tables for 1949-51," U.S. Department of Heslth, Educofion, and Welfare, Public Health Service, National
Office of Vital Statistics, vol. 41. No. 1, Nov. 23, 1954, pp. 9, 11, 13, 15, 17, 19, 21, 23, and 25.
"United States Life Tables: 1959-61. U.S. Department of Health, Education, and Welfare, Public Health Service,
Public Health Service Publication No. 1252, vol. 1, No. 1, December 1964, pp. 9, 11, 13, 15, 17, 19, 21, 23, and 25.
PAGENO="0093"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 87
t~ged wife, mother, child, potential widow's benefit of aged wife or
mother, and lump-sum death benefit, but excluded those arismg from
potential wife's and widow's benefits of young wives currently ineli-
gible for benefits because of age.
In the same study, if only old-age benefits and lump-sum death
payments were considered, the value of contributions (compounded at
3 percent) as a percentage of the value of benefits (discounted at 3
percent) would be 7 percent and 4.1 percent for male and female
beneficiaries in sample 1; 9.7 percent for males and 4.8 percent for
females in sample 2.
For different categories of persons selected on the basis of their
family status and occupation, Elizabeth Deran has presented con-
tribution-to-benefit estimates for imaginary individuals.3 For the work-
ers whose benefits were influenced by family status, their contributions
as a percent of benefits ranged from (a) 9 percent for a married man
age 65 with a never-employed wife age 35 and two children ages 3 and
5, to (b) 13 percent for a married man age 65 with a never employed
wife age 62 and one child age 15, and to (c) 21 percent for either a
single man age 65 or a married couple, both age 65 and both of whom
had worked. In the group of those whose contributions were affected
by occmipation because of the different dates at which various occupa-
tions first came under social security, the percentages ranged from (a)
8 percent for a military serviceman with wife never employed, both age
65, to (b) 10 percent for a farm worker with wife never employed, both
age 65, and to (c) 23 percent for a nonfarm self-employed individual.
Miss Deran's figures were computed with the following assumptions:
(1) For an employed person, only his or her portion of the social se-
cu~ity taxes was considered; for a self-employed individual, the en-
tire social security taxes paid were taken into account; (2) workers
always earned at least as much as the maximum taxable earnings; (3)
contributions were compounded at 3 percent interest and benefits were
discounted at the same rate; (4) contributions were made for 29 years
from 1937 through 1965; and (5) benefits were received for 10 years
from 1966 to 1975.
Cohn D. and Rosemary G-. Campbell have also considered the re-
1 ationship between contributions and benefits.4 They estimated that
these workers retiring in 1967, 1972, 1980 (their respective ages in 1937
being 35, 30, and 22) will all be gainers, for their contributions will
last only 2.3, 3.9, and 7 years, respectively. Their estimate also showed
that a retirant in 1992 (age 22 in 1949) would about break even, with
his contributions a little more than necessary to pay benefits for 14
years.
The following assumptions used by Campbell & Campbell were
different from those in other studies: (1) They considered only the
old-age benefits, and they used only 80 percent of contributions (that
is, a1lowii~g 20 percent of contributions as the cost for survivors and
`Elizabeth Deran, "IncOme Redistribution under the Social Security System," National
Tax Journal, vol. XIX, No. 3, September 1966, pp. 280-283.
Cohn D. and Rosemary 0. Campbell, "Explanation of Computations of Contributions
versus Benefits Under the Federal Old-Age Insurance Program," an unpublished manu-
script by courtesy of the authors.
PAGENO="0094"
88 OLD AGE lYCOME ASSTJRAYOE-PART III
disability benefits); (2) contributions consisted of the combined
employee and employer social security taxes; (3) these contributions
were compounded at current interest rates (those paid on series E
bonds until 1963 and 4 percent thereafter) ; and (4) benefits consisted
of the retirement benefits for the worker and his wife.
They compared the accumulated value of contributions of a worker
with the amount it required to provide him and his wife retirement
benefits for 14 years. If the total value of the taxes he and his employer
have paid is not enough to pay the benefits for 14 years, to which he
and his wife are entitled, lie has had a bargain, or is a gainer. Their
approach may be described as one in which the retiree draws on a
fund (for example, a bank account) which he has built up with his
own as well as with his employer's taxes at compound interest and
which continues to earn interest on the declining balance (declining
because of withdrawals for annual benefits).
Still another study, that of Henry Aaron, is available.5 His
calculations showed that the social security system of 1962 gave
relatively more benefits per dollar of social security taxes to the lower
paid worker, and that there was a subsidy to all income levels in the
sense that workers received greater benefits than what they had
contributed. He used the following assumptions: (1) Social security
taxes were paid from 1937 to 1961; (2) social security benefits began
in 1962 (the ending date was unspecified in the study) ; (3) estimates
were made for workers who had lived to age 65 (he ignored the
possibility of a death before age 65 as well as the possibility of supple-
mentary benefits) ; (4) the workers bore the full burden of the com-
bined employee-employer taxes (he indicated that alternative assump-
tions about the incidence of OASDI taxes did not alter the results sub-
stantially-this is somewhat surprising to the present writer) ; (5)
arbitrary wage patterns of money wage for each year had a constant
real value in 1947-49 dollars of from $500 to $15,000; and (6) two
alternate rates of interest, 3 percent and 6 percent, were used.
Under the respective assumptions noted, these several studies have
shown that those who have retired, or will retire during the next two
to three decades, will have received benefits which are greater than
their taxpayments.
B. SOCL~L SEGLEITY GAINERS: ALTERNATIVE ESTIMATES
Since a variety of assumptions has been used in previous studies,
it is difficult to generalize. Broadly speaking, many estimates of tax-
benefit relationships have been computed for the worker whose earn-
ings were at least equal to the maximum taxable earnings (later re-
ferred to as the maximum earner). With respect to tax contributions,
these estimates assumed. either no-backward shifting or full-back-
Henry Aaron, "Benefits under the American Social Security System," studies in the
Economics of Income Maintenance, Otto Eckstein, ed. (Washington: The Brookings Insti-
tution; 1967), pp. 63-67.
PAGENO="0095"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 89
ward shifting of the employer portion of social security taxes.6 On
the benefit side, some estimates considered oniy the combined retire-
ment benefits for the worker and his wife. Finally, tax-benefit rela-
tionships have been estimated in current dollar terms with a certain
assumed rate of interest for compounding taxes and discounting
benefits.
However, (1) the maximum earner is not the typical; the case of
the worker whose earnings are near the average taxable earnings (in
short, the average earner) needs to be investigated; (2) the assump-
tions of both no-backward shifting and full-backward shifting of the
employer social security taxes are extreme (it would be mstructiveto
consider the possibility of partial-backward shifting) ; (3) since dif-
ferent family circumstances occasion varying benefit payments, tax-
benefit relationships need to be computed for persons of diverse family
statuses; and (4) tax-benefit relationships in current dollar terms
are significantly altered if they are recomputed in constant dollar
terms. When taxpayments and benefits recipients span long periods
of time, price inflation becomes a very important consideration. The
allowance of price inflation has the effect of raising the rate at which
° The judgment on the shiftability of the employer portion of the social security taxes
is a difficult one. While the Social Security Administration (SSA) estimates ignored the
employer tax, studies by Campbell & Campbell (C. & C.) assumed that the worker bears
the full burden of the employer tax. Since the relationship between taxes and benefits is
importantly affected by this assumption, the question warrants some discussion.
Both SSA and C. & C. considered the question of backward shifting in the form of lower
wages to the workers-with SSA completely rejecting it and C. & C. fully accepting it.
Apparently, neither `SSA nor C. & C. entertained the possibility of forward shifting in the
form of higher prices. Nor did they discuss the possibility of backward shifting in the
form of lower prices to the suppliers of other productive agents.
It is a reasonable assumption that an employer will attempt to shift his taxes onto
someone else-either forward to the consumer by means of higher prices, or backward to
the worker in the form of reduced wages, or backward to the owner of factors of produc-
tion, other than labor. In the process of shifting, however, the employer encounters many
obstacles in both the product and the factor markets. Given time, it would be comparatively
easier for the employer to overcome these interferences. Since workers are consumers, they
may bear part of the employer taxes as both employees (in backward shifting) and as
consumers (in forward shifting)~ In the long run, therefore, labor as a group would most
likely bear a substantial part of the taxes formerly paid by the employers. To the extent
forward shifting occurs, employers themselves will bear part of the burden as well in their
capacity as consumers. Moreover, to the extent forward shifting takes place, persons not
covered by social security will bear part of the burden of the employer taxes.
While tho exact extent to which the employer taxes are shifted to the workers remains
uncertain, the exact amount each individual worker bears the taxes, shifted by his em-
ployer, is even more uncertain. Uncertainty arises, because (1) the employer may "over-
shift" (i.e., passing on more than the taxes he paid) or "undershift" (i.e.., passing on less
than the taxes he paid) ; (2) the extent to which workers qua consumers bear the burden
depends, among other factors, on their individual consumption patterns; and (3) the extent
to which workers qua employees bear the burden depends on the specific time and place
of their employments.
Even though it is impossible to ascertain the precise amount of the employer tax that
falls upon the worker, it seems unreasonable to assume that no such shifting takes place.
On the other hand, the assumption that the entire amount of the employer taxes is auto-
matically borne by the worker, too, appears stringent. In this study, estimates of tax-benefit
relationships are presented with three assumptions concerning the extent to which a worker
bears the employer taxes-no-backward shifting, full-backward shifting, and half-backward
shifting. Possibly, more than half-backward shifting occurs.
Family statuses are a significant factor in considering tax-benefit relationships. In 1966,
out of a total of approximately 3.3 million benefit awards (excluding some 750,000 awards
to persons with special age 72 benefits), about one-half of them were awarded to retired
workers. Approximately 12 percent of the awards went to wives and husbands, including
wife beneficiaries, under age 65 with children in their care, and entitled divorced wives.
The remainder, about 38 percent of the total benefit awards, were awarded to children,
widowed mothers, widows and widowers, and dependent parents. social ~S~ecurity Bulletin,
vol. 30, No. 8, August 1967, p. 32.
PAGENO="0096"
90 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
taxes are compounded and benefits are discountedl.S In this section,
aliernative estimates of tax-benefit. relationships that attend to these
four considerations, are presented.
Tax-benefit ratios for the maximum earner are shown in table 1, and
those for the average earner, in table 2. These. workers are assumed to
retire in 1966 after 20 years of work, from 1937 to 1965. The column
headed "Taxes" lists the three. assumptions regarding the shiftability
of the. employer tax. Ratios based on the no-backward shifting assump-
tion are to ba found in the row of figures called "Employee Taxes."
Ratios based on the. assumption that only one-half of the employer
tax is shifted to the employee are registered in the row labeled "Em-
ployee Taxes plus 50 percent of Employer Taxes." Ratios based on
the assumption of full-backward shifting are located in the row be-
tween the above twO.
Total taxes are computed by-
T=~ E1t1(1±r) m=i
Where T= Sum of the compounded value of t.axes paid from Janu-
ary 1, 1937 through December 31, 1965.
Taxable earnings i~' year.
t~ = Conubinecl employee-employer tax rate in i~ year.
r=Assumeclrateofinterest=.03.
.i= Index of years= 1 rn.
rn.=Nu~mber of taxpaying years=29.
These workers are assumed to receive benefits from 1966 to 1979. The
columns headed "Benefits" suggest three possible family circumstances,
each with different benefit amounts. For example, ratios for the worker
who receives his retirement benefits are placed in the column headed
"Employees' Retirement Benefits."
Total benefits for these. workers are computed by-
B=~ (1±r)~
Where B Sum of the discounted value (to 1965) of the expected
benefits from January 1, 1966 through December 31, 1979.
= Annual benefits of ~` year, determined by the average of
the taxable earnings in the 10 years before retirement.
= Assumed rate of interest.= .03.
= Inclex.ofyearsl
= Number of benefit-receiving years 14.
S Price level changes need to be taken into consideration in tax-benefit ratios, with
price inflation, the accumulated value of taxes (paid in the early period) may be under-
stated if money magnitudes are used in compounding. Similarly, benefits, which are received
in a late period, need to be discounted more, in the face of price inflation. For example, if
the interest rate used is 3 percent. and if the price Inflation rate is 2 percent, then the rate
used in compounding and discounting becomes 5 percent when price inflation is considered.
This rate is equal to the highest interest rate that savings and loan associations now offer.
Some persons may prefer to use rates higher than 5 percent. Although the results based on
higher interest rates are not included in the paper, calculations can easily be performed.
PAGENO="0097"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 91
The comparative ratios relative to different earnings bases, to alter-
native employer tax shifting assumptions, and to various family sta-
tuses are shown in the upper half of tables 1 and 2. Some interesting
contrasts may be mentioned.
(a) Maximum versus average earner: Considering only employee
taxes, the maximum earner is estimated to contribute less than 17 per-
cent if he just receives his retirement benefits (a ratio of 0.17) ; for the
average earner, the ratio is about 0.13.
(b) Full backward shifting versus half-backward shifting of the
employer taxes: Assuming full backward shifting, approximately 33
percent of the maximum earner's retirement benefits come out of his
contributions (a ratio of 0.33); if only one-half of his employer's
taxes is assumed to have shifted to him, his contributions amount to 25
percent of his benefits (a ratio of 0.25).
(c) Employee's retirement benefits versus maximum family pay-
ments: Under the assumption of no backward shifting, if he receives
only his retirement benefits, the maximum earner contributes less than
17 percent toward his benefits (a ratio of 0.17), but if he has a family
eligible for the maximum benefit payments, his contributions amount
to about 7 percent (a ratio of 0.07).
The above ratios are based on current dollars. The effect of price
inflation is indicated in the ratios in the lower half of tables 1 and 2,
where total taxes and total benefits are both calculated in terms of
constant dollars.
The formula for the total compounded value of taxes in real terms
is-
rn rn-i rn-i
T=E E~t1(l+r) (l+p)
i=:1
where the actual Consumer Price Indexes from 1937 to 1965 are
used.
The formula for the total discounted value of benefits in real terms
is-
~ bj/(l-Fp)1
B==~-
i' (l±r)~
where the annual rate of price inflation of 2 percent is assumed for 1966
through 1979.
The compounded value of taxes in real terms is greater than the
compounded value of taxes in money terms, since the multiplica.nds
in the formula (the taxes) have been enlarged by the rates of price
inflation. Therefore, the taxes are being accumulated at a higher rate
when taxes in real magnitudes, rather than taxes in money magni-
tudes, are compounded. The discounted value of benefits in real terms
is smaller than the discounted value of benefits in money terms, as
the dividends in the formula (the benefits) have been reduced by the
rates of price inflation. As a result, the benefits are being discounted
at a higher rate when benefits in real terms, as opposed to benefits
in money terms, are converted to present values. Consequently, tax-
83-200-67--pt. 3-7
PAGENO="0098"
92 OLD AGE II~C0ME ASSURANcE-PART III
benefit ratios in constant dollars are approximately 50 percent higher
than the ratios in current dollars. For example, the highest ratio of
0.50 (0.33 in current dollar terms) is found for the maximum earner
whose contributions include both his own as well as his employer's
taxes, but whose benefits are limited to his own retirement benefits.
The lowest ratio of 0.11 (as opposed to 0.07 in current dollars) is
associated with the maximum earner who is not assumed to bear any
of the taxes his employer pays, but who is credited with the maximum
family payments.
The following conclusions are supported by the preceding discus-
sion: (1) There are gainers in sodial security, hilt depending on earn-
ings levels and family statuses, some gain more than others, with the
same assumptions regarding (a) the shiftability of the employer's
taxes, and (b) therate of interest; and (2) if price inflation is recog-
nized in tax-benefit ratios, the gainers are not gaining as much-
in real terms, they contribute about 50 percent more than what they
are shown to contribute in current dollars.
It should be realized that the gains belong either to (a) persons
who have or `will have lived to receive retirement or disability bene-
fits, or to (b) those who have survivors to be paid benefits. Moreover,
these persons will not become gainers unless they have been awarded
benefits for a period of time long enough so that their benefit rece~pts
outdistance their taxpayments. Of course, there are always losers
either because (a) they have not, or will not have, lived to be awarded
benefits, (b) they do not have survivors to be entitled to payments, or
(c) they or t.heir survivors have, or will have received `benefit payments
for a period of time sufficiently short so that their taxpayrnents out-
last their benefit receipts.
C. SOCIAL SEOURITY LOSERS: SUMMARY OF EXISTING ESTIMATES
The foregoing estimates have demonstrated that the tax-benefit
ratios will be low for the participants in social security who have
retired or will have retired in the next 20 years or so. However, the
ratios will be high and in some cases very high for those who will be
retiring in the more distant future, when estimated taxes and benefits
are based `on the provisions in the current law. The estimated relation-
ships between contribiltions and `benefits in future years are sum-
marized here.
The Social Security Administration has presented certain calcula-
tions of the accumulated value of contributions and the present value
of future benefits for various illustrative categories of individuals
attaining age 65 in different years from 1962 to 2010.~ Under the
Estimates of contribution-to-benefit ratios in the future are found in Meyers and Oppal,
op. cit. Their estimates were based on the provisions of the Social Security Act before the
1965 amendments, and they used zero and 3-percent interest rates for alternative computa-
tions. Ray M. Peterson has calculated these ratios to reflect the law as amended in 1965.
See his unpublished Addendunv to Myers and Oppal, op. cit., September 29, 1965. For
alternative sets of estimates, Peterson used zero, 3, 3i~, and 4 percent interest rates.
Some of his figures are cited here.
PAGENO="0099"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 93
Social Security Act as amended in 1965, with a 4-percent interest
rate, a single male person retiring in 1990 will have a tax-benefit per-
centage of 104; for a married male retiring in 2010, 43 years from now,
the percentage will be 116.
These percentages were calculated on the following assumptions:
(1) Worker is alive at age 65 and retires at that time, attaining
age 65 at the beginning of the year; (2) worker is an employee at
maximum covered earnings in all years after 1937, or after attaining
age 20, if later; (3) married worker has a wife the same age, 65;
(4) alternative interest rates of 3, 3.5, and 4 percent for compounding
contributions and discounting benefits are used; (5) contributions in-
clude only the taxes paid by the worker and exclude that portion of
his tax for health insurance; and (6) mortality basis is the U.S. Life
Tables for White Persons, 1949-51.
Campbell & Campbell also have calculated the relationship of con-
tributions to benefits for different individuals retiring in selected
years in the future.'° They showed that a worker who retires in 1998
will have enough contributions to pay benefits for 19.8 years, whereas
he is expected to receive them for only 14 years according to the aver-
age life expectancy. A new entrant, age 22 in 1966, retiring in 2009,
will have an accumulated fund sufficient for retirement benefits for
more than 31 years. Both of these workers are "losers" under social
security.
The approach and assuniptioiis used by the Campbefls for these
estimates are the same as those underlying their calculations for those
retiring through 1992, cited in subsection A above. For the conveni-
ence of the reader, certain basic assumptions are restated here. Bene-
fits included only those for a man and his wife, and contributions
consisted of 80 percent of the total employee and employer taxes.
Benefits were discounted at 4 percent interest and the compound in-
terest rate for accumulating contributions was also 4 percent. The
comparison of costs and benefits was based on the approach in which
the retiree draws on a fund, such as a bank account, which he has
accumulated at 4 percent compound interest with the tax dollars
he and his employer have paid; he does this in order to pay retire-
ment benefits to his wife as well as to himself, with the declining
balance in the fund continuing to earn interest. A retiree is a loser
if his fund is not reduced to zero or exhausted at the end of 14
years.
Under the assumptions specified, the general conclusion in these
studies is that young workers of today, especially those now joining
social security, will have contributed more than that which they may
expect to receive in benefits.
10 Campbell & Campbell, op. c4t.
PAGENO="0100"
94 OLD AGE INCOME ASSTJRANCE-PART III
D. SOCIAL SECURITY LOSERS ALTERNATIVE ESTIMATES
Estimates of the relationships of taxes to benefits for the losers are
likewise affected by earnings level, employer tax shifta.bility, family
status, and price inflation. Table 3 contains tax-benefit ratios for the
maximum and average earners. Tile total compounded value of taxes
and the total discounted value of benefits are derived from the same
formulas as used for the gainers, except that the nmnber of years for
tax payments is different.
For present purposes, only case I in table 3 is relevant. Case I ratios
are based on the following assumptions: (1) The taxable earnings
ceiling will be $6,600, the present level, throughout the contribution
period, 43 years; (2) -workers' earnings are assumed to remain at the
present levels ($6,600 for tile maximum earner, and $3,215 for the
average earner) ; (3) benefits will be based on the average of the
taxable earnings during tile last 10 years of employment, and the
benefit formula in the future will be the same as that used at present;
(4) benefits will be received for 14 years; `~ and (5) the interest rate is
3 percent for compounding and discounting.
As shown in the table, under the assumption of no-backward shift-
ing, tile ma.xnnum earner loses wilen Ile receives only his retirement
benefits (a ratio of 1.16) ; he gains under other family circumstances.
Tile average earner gains in all situations with the no-backward-shift-
ing assumption, his lowest ratio being 0.45.
If the half-backward-shifting assumption is followed, the maximum
earner loses eitller when he alone receives retirement benefits (a ratio
of 1.74) or when he and his wife both receive benefits (a ratio of 1.16).
Under tile same assumption, the average earner loses only ill one situa-
tion-when he receives only the retirement. benefits, his ratio being 1.35.
Alternatively, when full-backward shiftmg is assumed, the maxi-
mum earner loses even when lle is credited witll tile maximum family
payments, but the loss is rather small, with a ratio of 1.05; the average
earner loses unless he is entitled to the maximum family payments.
Whell case I ratios are computed ni constant dollars, with an assumed
annual rate of price inflation of 2 percent, nearly all ratios exceed
unity, the highest being more than 4.50. These ratios are not presented
ill tabular form.
Tile foregoing discussion may be summarized: (1) Under the as-
sumptions used in computing tax-benefit ratios in future years, there
are still gainers in certain circumstances; (2) there are losers, but
some lose more than others, depending upon earnings levels and
family status, given the same assumptions on (a) the shiftability of the
11 If life expectancy at age 65, in the future, is more than 14 years as assumed, total
benefit payments will be larger, and, therefore, tax-benefit ratios will be lowered. There was
some improvement in mortality rates between 1949-51 and 1959-61, as evidenced in the
table in footnote 2. Although extrapolation of this trend may not be reasonable, some
lengthening of life expectancy may be expected. If so, contributions may need to be
increased.
PAGENO="0101"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 95
employer taxes, and (74 the interest rate; and (3) in constant dollar
terms, gainers gain less and losers lose more than is shown in calcula-
tions based on current dollars. For the reasons explained previously,
this, in effect, means that the higher the rate of interest used in com-
pounding taxes and discounting benefits, the smaller the gains or the
greater the losses.
Of course, it should be emphasized that the losers identified in this
section refer to the workers who are assumed to pay taxes for 43 years
and to receive benefits for 14 years. These workers may become gainers
if they pay taxes for a shorter period of time or receive benefits for a
longer period of time, with the result that they receive more than they
have paid in taxes.
It is true that some workers will have paid into social security more
than the.y may expect to receive in benefits under the assumptions
specified above. This phenomenon has been used by some writers to
argue that a young worker of today will fare better financially if he
uses the tax dollars which he and his employer pay into social security
to purchase coverage from a commercial life insurance company. This
proposition will be examined in the following section.
TABLE 1.-RATIOS OF TOTAL TAXES (1937-65) TO TOTAL BENEFITS (1966-79)-THE MAXIMUM EARNER
Price level
Taxes
Benefit
Employee's
retirement
benefit
Employee's
retirement
and wife's
benefits
Maximum
family
payments
Current prices, 1937-65
1965 price
Employee taxes
Combined employee-employer taxes
Employee taxes plus 50 percent of em-
ployer taxes.
Employee taxes
Combined employee-employer taxes
Employee taxes plus 50 percent of em-
ployer taxes.
0. 17
. 33
.25
. 25
- 50
- 38
0. 11
. 22
. 17
. 17
. 33
. 25
0. 07
. 15
- 11
. 11
- 23
- 17
Note: See notes following table 3.
TABLE 2.-RATIOS OF TOTA
L TAXES (1937-65) TO TOTAL BENEFITS (
1966-79)-T
HE MAXIMUM
EARNER
Price level
.
Taxes
Benefit
Employee's
retirement
benefit
Employee's
retirement
and wife's
benefits
Maximum
family
payments
Current prices, 1937-65
1965 price
Employee taxes
Combined employee-employer taxes
Employee taxes plus 50 percent of em-
ployer taxes.
Employee taxes
Combined employee-employer taxes
Employee taxes plus 50 percent of em-
ployer taxes.
0. 13
- 25
. 19
.18
.35
.26
0.08
- 17
- 13
. 12
- 24
. 18
0.06
- 13
- 09
.09
- 18
- 13
Note: See notes following table 3.
PAGENO="0102"
TABLE 3.-RATIOS OF TOTAL TAXES (1966-2008) TO TOTAL BENEFITS (2009-22) UNDER ALTERNATIVE CONDITIONS: THE MAXIMUM EARNER AND THE AVERAGE EARNER
t.4
Employee's retirement benefit Employee's retirement and wile's benefits Maximum family payments
Worker and taxes -______________________ _________________________________
I II Ill IV V VI I II Ill IV V VI I II Ill IV V VI
Maximu m earlier: 1.-i
Em ployee taxes 1. 16 0. 69 0. 53 0. 51 0. 39 0. 45 0. 77 0. 46 0. 36 0. 34 0. 26 0. 30 0. 53 0. 32 0. 24 0. 23 0. 18 0. 20 ~,.
Combined employee.employer taxes 2.32 1. 39 1.07 1. 01 .78 .89 1. 55 .93 .71 .67 . 52 .60 1. 05 .63 .49 .46 .35 .41 ~
Employee taxes plus 50 percent of employer taxes 1. 74 1. 04 . 80 . 76 . 58 . 67 1. 16 . 69 . 53 . 51 . 39 . 45 . 79 . 47 . 36 . 34 . 27 . 31 o
Average earner:
Emclayee taxes . 90 . 52 . 40 . 39 . 30 . 35 . 60 . 35 . 27 . 26 . 20 . 23 . 45 . 26 . 20 . 20 . 15 . 17
Combined employee-employer taxes 1.80 1.04 .80 .78 .60 .69 1.20 .70 .54 .52 .40 .46 .90 .52 .40 .39 .30 .35
Employee taxes plus 50 percent of employer taxes 1. 35 . 78 . 60 . 59 . 45 . 52 . 90 . 52 . 40 . 39 . 30 . 35 . 67 . 39 . 30 . 29 . 23 . 26
ç~a.
(I)
NOTES TO TABLES 1, 2, AND 3
1. The maximum earner is the worker whose earnings are at least equal to the maximum taxable 5. Maximum taxable earnings in canes II and III are assumed to be changed every 10 years. ~a-.
earningx. The average earner is the worker whose earnings are at the level of the average taxable Projections of the maximum taxable earnings in future years are based on the relation between aver-
earningx. Calculations in tables 1 and 2 assume tax payments for 29 years and benefit receipts for age taxable earnings and maximum taxable earnings from 1937 to 1965. The data on the average C)
14 years. Calculations in table 3 assume tax payments for 43 years and benefit receipts for 14 years. taxable earnings in past years were provided by the Office of the Actuary, Social Security Adminis- t'l
2. Tax-benefit ratios are obtained by dividing the total compounded value of taxes by the total tration, letter to the author, Apr. 7, 1967. Average taxable earnings after 1966 are assumed to increase
discounted value of benefits. To illustrate, the ratio is 0.5 when the discounted value of benefits is at 3 percent per year.
twice as much as the compounded value of taxes; the ratio is 2 when the compounded value of taxes 6. The annual rate of increase in cases III and V (4.2 percent) is the average rate of increase in
is twice as much as the discounted value of benefits, benefit payments to the retired worker from 1940 to 1966, computed from "Average Monthly Benefit
3. Formulas for computing the total compounded value of taxes and total discounted value of Amount in Current Payment Status for the Selected Types of Beneficiaries, in Actual and Constant H
benefits are explained in the text. The benchmark year for compounding and discounting in tables 1 Dollars, Dec. 1940-66," a table provided by Dr. Benjamin Bridges, Jr., Division of Research and
and 2 is 1965; in table 3, it is the year 2008. Statistics, Social Security Administration, April 1967. 1-
4. Tax-benefit ratios in table 3 for the 6 cases (I through VI) are computed according to the con-
ditions listed in the table at end of notes.
PAGENO="0103"
See the following table referred to in note 4.
ALTERNATIVE CONDITIONS AFFECTING TAX-BENEFIT RATIOS IN TABLE 3
Case
Item
I II III IV V VI
C
Maximum taxable 1966-2008, $6,600 1966-75, $6,600; 1976- Same as in II 1966, $6,600; increasing Same as in IV Same as in IV.
earnings. 85, $9,000; 1986-95, at 5 percent per
$12,000; 1996-2005, annum.
$16,000; 2006-8,
$20,000. * .
Worker s earnings_ - $6,600, 1966-2008 (maximum 1966, $6,600 (maximum - -- do 1966, $6,600 (maximum -- - do Do.
earner); $3,215, 1966-2008 earner); $3,215 (aver- earner); $3,215(aver- 0
(average earner), age earner), both in- age earner), both in-
creasing at 3 percent creasing at 5 percent
per annum, per annum.
Benefit computation Annual benefits are based on the Annual benefits are Benefit in the first year Annual benefits are Benefit in the first year Benefit in the first year ~,,
formua. average of the taxable earn- based on the average (2009) is the same as based on the average is the same as in IV. is the same as in IV. CI)
ings in the last 10 years of of the taxable earn- in II. Benefits in later of the taxable earn- Benefits in later years Benefits in later years Co
employment (1999-2008). The ings in the last 10 years are assumed to ings in the last 10 are assumed to in- are assumed to in-
benefit formula is: (a) 62.97 years (1999-2008). increase at 4.2 per- years (1999-2008). crease at 4.2 percent crease at 2 percent
percent of the first $1,320 of PIA as percent of cent per annum. PIA as percent of per annum, per annum, which is ~`
annual earnings. (b) 22.90 ATE for the maximum ATE for the maximum the assumed annu~I ~
percent of the annual earnings and average earners and average earners rate of price inflation. 0
between $1,320 and $4,800, are the same as in I. are the same as in I.
(c) 21,40 percent of annual I
earnings over $4,800 up to
$6,600. Under this formula, the
primary insurance amount
(PIA) as a ratio to the average
taxable earnings (ATE) for the
maximum earner is approxi- -`4
mately 30 percent; for the
average earner, it is about
39 percent.
Combined employee- 1966, 7.7 percent; 1967-68, 7.8 Same as in I Same as in I Same as in I Same as in I Same as in I.
employer tax rates. percent; 1969-72; 8.8 percent;
1973-2008, 9.7 percent.
PAGENO="0104"
98 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
II. SOCIAL SECURITY vs. PRIVATE INSURANCE: COMPARATIVE COST
In order to examine the proposition that a young worker of today
will receive more financial protection if he purchases private insurance
with the tax dollars he and his employer are paying into social Se-
durity,12 it is necessary to compare these two methods in terms of the
comparative cost for the same benefits. Putting aside health benefits,
social security provides (1) old-age, (2) survivors, and (3) disability
benefits in a single package. Since no private insurance carrier offers
an equivalent policy, precise comparisons are most difficult. There
are those who would argue that it is well-nigh impossible to make
such comparisons because of both the large number of parameters
involved and the large degree of variations in the types of policies
offered by private insurers. For the present purpose, however, it is
imperative that an att.e~npt be made to offer as nearly accurate a
comparison as possible, and that the cost comparison be done with
respect to the three t.ypes of benefits a-s a whole.
~Tith the aid of actuaries in and out of the insurance industry,
several sets of estimates have been obtained on the premiums required
by commercial insurance carriers for providing the benefits that social
security offers. These estimates represent the rates used for both
participating and nonparticipating policies by as many as seven
insurance companies. Although it is reassuring that several of them
come very close to one another, these estimates are merely suggestive
in nature, and they serve to indicate the range of premiums that an
insurance company would probably charge. It should be emphasized
that much care has been taken to assure that the premium rates
quoted are those necessary for providing the benefits that are virtually
equivalent to those available under social security. As a consequence,
some of the ra.tes incorporated in the range of premiums reported
below are not. those for the policies currently available: rather, these
rates are for the policies that. are designed to provide benefits nearly
identical to those under social security.
For purposes of appraising the value of potential survivors and
disability benefits in addition to retirement benefits, the estimates
are provided for three hypothetical workers, A, B, and C. For ease
of identification, their characteristics are listed in tabular form as
follows:
Worker
Earnings in
1966 and
thereafter
Age in 1966
Age of-
Wife
Children
No. 1
No. 2
A
B
C
$1,800
3,000
6,600
22
22
22
22
22
22
2
2
2
1
1
1
`° This proposition has been supported by the computations of the cost for retirement
benefits under social security, after deducting 20 percent of the combined employee-
employer social security taxes. Twenty percent of the combined taxes are treated as the
cost for the provision of survivors benefits and disability benefits under social security.
See Cohn D. and Rosemary G. Campbell, "You'll Never Get Back All Those Old-Age `Con-
tributions'," Washington Post, Nov. 7. 1965, p. E-3, and also, James M. Buchanan and
Cohn D. Campbell, "Voluntary Social Security," Wall Street Journal, Dec. 20, 1966, p. 14.
PAGENO="0105"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 99
In the cost comparison in subsections A through E, it is assumed
that the worker will have at his disposal the full amount he and his
employer are paying into social security, if he decides to purchase
private insurance coverage instead. Subsection F briefly indicates the
comparative figures under alternative assumptions concerning whether
the employer contribution to social security will be available to the
employee.
Presented here are the comparative costs for survivors benefits,
disability benefits, and retirement benefits, first separately and then
combined. Given minor variations, survivors benefits are provided
for by a family income policy based on decreasing term insurance;
disability benefits are provided for by a disability income policy
with a 180-day waiting period; and retirement benefits, by a no-refund
retirement annuity contract.
A. SURVIVORS BENEFITS
In the case of the worker's death, the annual benefits expected of
social security under the 1965 law are shown below, followed by the
range of annual premiums which an insurance company would prob-
ably charge for the same benefits.
Year Worker A Worker B Worker C
-_----------_---------------------------_------------------------_-----
1968-82 $1 440.00 $2,428.80 $4,416.00
1983-85 1 408.80 1,831.20 3,024.00
1986 704.40 915.60 1,512.00
2006-life 775.20 1,006.80 1,663.20
Lump-scm death payments 234. 60 255. 00 255. 00
ANNUAL PREMIUMS (FOR SURVIVORS BENEFITS)
Worker 1968-82 1983-85 1986
1987-2008
A $1004130 $100-$130 $50470
B 145- 180 125- 155 65- 95
C 240- 300 200- 260 100-140
$60-$80
75- 100
110-150
The basic assumptions regarding the expected social security bene-
fits are-
(a) 75 percent of the primary insurance amount (PTA) for
each child until age 22, assuming school attendance.
(b) 75 percent of PTA for the mother until the youngest child
attains age 18.
(a) 82½ percent of PTA for the mother who resumes benefit at
age 62, assuming no remarriage.
(d) The private insurance policy would not be issued until age
24 (1968), because social security requires 6 quarters of coverage
before benefit payments commence.
(e) In the private insurance policy, no provision is made for
children's benefits beyond age 18 if the child were disabled before
age 18 and the disability continued beyond that age.
PAGENO="0106"
100 OLD AGE IYCOME ASSIJRANCE-PART III
B. DISABILITY BENEFITS
For the (equivalent) benefits provided under the 1965 social security
law in case the worker becomes disabled before age 65, the annual
disability benefits and the range of annual premiums which an illsur-
ance carrier would probably charge are as follows:
ANNUAL DISABILITY BENEFITS (SUBJECT TO THE "MAXIMUM FAMILY PAYMENT"
LIMITATION)
Year Worker A Worker B
Worker C
1971 to 1982 $1, 440. 00 $2, 428. 80
1983 to 1985 1, 440. 00 2, 428. 80
1986 1, 407. 60 1, 830. 60
1987 to 2008 938. 40 1, 220. 40
$4, 416. 00
4, 032. 00
3, 024. 00
2, 016. 00
ANNUAL PREMIUMS (FOR DISABILITY BENEFITS)
[These premiums are for those occupations eligible for the lowest ratesl 1
Worker 1971-82 1983-85 1986
1987-2008
A $30-$40 $30-$40 $30-$40
B 45- 70 45- 70 40- 50
C 75-125 70-115 60- 90
$20-$30
30- 40
45- 60
1 These premium rates are those available to the workers in occupations, such as executive positions, office work, teach-
ing, merchandising, and the like, which involve small chances of hazards. Such occupations are identified in the insurance
industry as class AAA or class A-i or similar designations. Higher rates are charged the insured when they are in class AA
or class A-2 occupations, such as physicians, dentists, surgeons, factory superintendents, foremen, etc. Still higher rates
are charged the insured who are classified in class A or A-3 occupations-auto mechanics, butchers, carpenters, bus or
taxi drivers, etc. There are further classifications such as class B or class A-4. It suffices at this time to point out some differ-
ential rates. The current premium rates charged by 1 insurance company for the same disability benefits quoted in the
text for worker C (with annual earnings of $6,600) during 1971-82 follow:
Class AAA $128
Class AA 145
Class A 176
It can be seen that a class AA worker will pay almost 15 percent (and a class A worker, nearly 40 percent) more than
a class AAA worker. Moreover, there are the class M or class "No" workers who cannot purchase coverage from a private
insurer
The basic underlying assumptions concerning the expected bene-
fits are-
(a) PTA for the worker to age 65.
(b) 50 percent of PTA for each child until age 22, assuming
school attendance.
(c) 50 percent of PTA for the mother until the youngest child
attains age 18.
(d) The cost for the resumption of the mother's benefits later
as a widow's benefit is not included in the cost for disability pro-
tection. Rather, the cost of widow's benefits is included in the
retirement benefits below.
(e) The private insurance policy would not be issued until age
27 (1971), because eligibility for social security requires 20 quar-
ters of coverage in the 40 quarters preceding the date of disability.
C. COMPARISON OF COSTS FOR SURVIVORS AND DISABILITY BENEFITS
Since the number of years in which taxes for social security and
premiums for private insurance differs, total taxes and total premiums
are calculated on the basis of present values so as to reduce them to a
PAGENO="0107"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART iii 101
comparable basis. In this study, 30 percent of the combined taxes
paid by the worker and his employer are assumed to be the contribu-
tion to social security for these two benefits.'3
PRESENT VALUES OF PREMIUMS AND TAXES AT 3 PERCENT INTEREST
(FOR SURVIVORS AND DISABILITY BENEFITS)
Worker
Private insurance
Social security
A
B
C
$2,500-$3,000
3,500-4,200
5,700-7,400
$1,250
2,100
4,600
These comparative figures suggest that it would cost these hypothet-
ical workers more to purchase coverage for survivors and disability
benefits from a private insurer than that which they and their employ-
ers are required to pay for the similar benefits under social security.
The figures also suggest that the cost advantage to worker A, whose
earnings are the lowest of the three, is greater than the advantage to
worker B, who in turn, is in a more advantageous position than
worker C who has the highest earnings of the three. Even worker C
is shown to pay substantially more than what he is expected to pay into
social security.
No analysis of disability benefits should be concluded without indi-
cating that not all occupations are insurable by private insurance, and
among the insurable, premiums for the same benefits differ among oc-
cupational classes. (See footnote 1 to table.)
D. OLD-AGE RETIREMENT BENEFITS
For the annual retirement benefits for a worker and his wife ($1,-
407.60 for worker A; $1,830.80 for worker B; and $3,024 for worker
C) ,`~ the range of insurance premiums charged by an insurance com-
pany would probably be as follows:
Worker
Annual premium
Present values of pr
at 3 percent intere
benefits)
emiums and taxes
st (for retirement
Private insurance
Social security
A
B
C
$120-$180
150-230
250-375
$2,700-$3,000
3,800-5,200
6, 300-8, 500
$2,960
4,900
10, 800
13 Although 20 percent of the social security taxes paid by the employee and his em-
ployer have been assumed to represent the cost for survivors and disability benefits, recent
calculations by the Social Security Administration suggest a 28.3 percent figure. This
figure is based on an example of a male worker who enters covered employment at a young
age, when the ultimate contribution rate is in effect with 1966 average taxable earnings.
Myers indicates that the results of such a calculation are not absolute, but, rather, they
will vary, depending upon a composite of many factors, such as the assumptions made
with respect to interest rates, mortality rates, estimated average earnings, etc. Robert J.
Myers, Letter to the author, June 26, 1967. The present study uses 30 percent for approx-
imatlon and ease of calculation.
14 These amounts are 150 percent of the primary insurance amounts (PIA) due each
worker, since the wife is entitled to 50 percent of the PIA. Therefore, if the worker is alone
to receive the benefits, only two-thirds of the amount indicated are paid to him (i.e., the
PIA.) However, if the wife of the worker is alone to receive the benefits (as a widow), 82.5
percent of the PIA are paid to her.
PAGENO="0108"
102 OLD AGE INCO~'IE ASSURA~CE~-PART III
In terms of retirement benefits, workers A and B would probably
do as well under either system, but worker C suffers a cost disad-
vantage.
E. COMPARI5ON OF COSTS FOR SURVIVORS, DI5ABILITY5 AND RETIREMENT
BENEFITS
In order to compare the entire package of coverage, the total of so-
cial security taxes and of private insurance premiums should be con-
sidered.
Worker
Present values of premiums and taxes at
3 percent interest (for all 3 benefits)
Private insurance 1 Social security
A
B
C. -
$5.300-$6,000 $4,210
7,900-8,700 7,000
13, 200-14, 200 15,400
1 The totals in the column are not equal to the summation of the figures
quoted for the separate policies, because a company's rates may be low on
one policy while high on another.
~Then the three benefits are taken together as a package, worker A
enjoys a distinct cost advantage, and worker B, a somewhat smaller
cost advantage. The cost advantage in both cases is enhanced by the
tax-free treatment of social security benefits. On the other hand,
worker C experiences *a cost disadvantage, but this is reduced since
social security benefits are nontaxable. Further, worker C might even
enjoy a cost advantage if he is employed in an occupation that would
occasion higher insurance premiums from a commercial insurer.
The foregoing computations and observations may now be sum-
marized. (a) With respect to suvivors benefits and disability benefits,
there seems to be a distinct cost advantage in social security vis-a-vis
private insurance for the three `hypothetical workers, A, B, and C, with
the assumed a.ge, earnings, and family circumstances. (b) As for
retirement benefits alone, workers A and B appear to do as well in
terms of comparative cost for coverage either under social `security or
private insurance, while worker C suffers a cost disadvantage. (c)
Taking the package of all three benefits, social security is shown to
offer a. cost advantage to Workers A and B and to present worker C
with a cost. disadvantage. (d) The tax-free nature of social security
benefits increases the cost. advantage to workers A and B, and lowers
the cost disadvantage to worker C. And (e) even worker C may not
suffer the cost disadvantage if he is required to pay higher premiums
than those assumed in the computations for disability benefit coverage
from private in~urance. (See footnote 1 to table.)
F. ALTERNATIVE ASSUMPTIONS ABOUT TI-IE E~IPLOYER CONTRIBUTION
One of the important. assumptions upon which the above conclusions
are based is that, when a worker buys private insurance, he will have
the funds from his employer who now contributes them. to social
security. In other words. implicit in these comparisons is the full-hack-
ward-shifting assumption regarding the social security taxes paid by
PAGENO="0109"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 103
the employer. Under the alternative assumptions, those of no-back-
ward shifting and half-backward shifting, different conclusions as to
the relative cost emerge, as shown in the following table:
Worker
Present values of pr
Private insurance
emiums and taxes a
t 3 percent interest (
for all 3 benefits)
Social security
No-backward
Full-backward
Half-backward
shifting
shifting
shifting
A
B
C
$5,300-$6,000
7, 900-8,700
13,200-14,200
$2,105
3,500
7,700
$4,210
7,000
15,400
$3 150
5 250
11,550
It can be readily appreciated that worker C begins to encounter a
cost disadvantage when more than 75 percent of his employer's taxes
are shifted to him.
G. CERTAIN LIMITATIONS ON COST COMPARISONS
Cost comparisons between social security and private insurance
should not be performed ivithout the recognition o~ certain limita-
tions, several of which may be noted. (a) Single men and single women
pay the same social security taxes as do married persons; the taxes
do not differ as between those married persons with dependents and
t'hose without dependents; and the taxes are the same regardless of
the number of dependents. Taxes vary between and among individuals
only as their earnings differ, up to the maximum taxable earnings. If
the above categories of persons' earnings from employment are the
same, they pay the same taxes, but they are entitled to different
amounts of benefits. (b) A self-employed person pays 50 percent more
in taxes than `the employee portion of `the social security taxes that an
employed worker pays. If their earnings and family circumstances
are identical, their benefits will not differ. (e) A working wife, who
contributes toward `social security just as anyone else, may not in-
crease her benefit, because no one individual can receive the full amount
of more `than one type of benefit. (d) To be "fully insured" under
social security, a worker, attaining age 65 in 1991 or later, needs 10
years or 40 quarters of work covered by social security; to be "cur-
ren'tly insured," a worker needs at least 11/2 year's covered employ-
ment within the 3 years before death or retirement; and to `be eligible
for disability benefits, a worker must be fully insured, and 5 years of
his work must have been in a 10-year peri'od ending when he becomes
disabled. `So long as a worker satisfies these conditions, he is entitled
to the benefit payments under the law. On the other hand, continuity
of payment of private insurance premiums for `the periods of time
specified in the `comparison above is necessary if benefits will be pay-
able. (e) Some persons continue to work after age 65 and thus pay
social security taxes, `but their benefits are not `there'by increased when
they retire. The earnings test before age 72 reduces `benefits to some
persons and eliminates other individuals from receiving benefits, but
there is no such limitation in a private insurance policy. (f) Private
isurance pre'miums include underwriting costs, and private insurance
mortality and disability ra'tes are developed from insured lives,
PAGENO="0110"
104 OLD AGE LNCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
whereas social security has no such underwriting costs (other than ad-
ministrative costs) and uses population experience. (g) The premium
rates reported in subsection lB for all three benefits combined were
obtained from the rates for the three policies separately. To the ex-
tent that there is any cost reduction when the three policies are writ-
ten at the same time for an individual, the private insurance cost esti-
mates used in the comparison -would appear overstated. And (h) the
observations on comparative cost between social security and private
insurance reported in this section are for the three hypothetical work-
ers with the explicit and implicit assumptions regarding age, family
composition, earnings levels, and other relevant factors. Care should
be taken in generalizing their cost positions for all other individuals.
The sole purpose of this exercise is to use these comparative figures to
suggest that it is misleading to consider a certain type of person cov-
ered by social security a.nd then to permit the inference that it applies
to very many cases. One can easily "prove" social security to be a los-
ing proposition if one uses the example of a "confirmed bachelor"
or a "confirmed couple" (i.e., a couple determined not to raise a fam-
ily), or a person who knows he will be employed continuously (or
even a person who knows he will not be disabled). On the other hand,
social security can be shown in a much more favorable cost position
under certain other cases.
Ill. TAX-BENEFIT RATIOS IN THE Fu~nxm~: SEVERAL PosSIBILITIEs
In section I, social security gains and losses were discussed. The
losers, there identified -with respect to the future, represented the re-
sults of but one set of possibilities, based on rather strict and artificial
assumptions. Unrealistic though they may seem, these ratios are not
meaningless, for they reflect the provisions of the existing law. How-
ever, since the present law is virtually certain to change, these esti-
mated ratios are of doubtful predictive value. With these ratios as a
point of departure, explored below are five other possibilities on the
basis of alternative assumptions regarding the maximum taxable earn-
ings, worker's earnings, and the benefit formula. The tax rates used in
all cases, I through VI, are those in effect now and those scheduled in
the present law for future years.
A. "UNVARYING" VERSUS `~INCREASING" ASSUMPTIONS
Case I is based on what may be called unvarying assumptions. To
repeat, it assumes that the maximum taxable earnings will be $6,600 in
the future as at present, that the worker's earnings will remain at their
present levels (the so-called level-earnings assumptions), and that the
benefit formula in 1965 will prevail in future years. These are un-
realistic assumptions and tax-benefit ratios based on them could be
misleading as a projection of -what is likely to happen in the future.
Although the long-range cost estimates (for a period of 75 years)
prepared by the Board of Trustees of the Federal Old-Age and Sur-
vivors Insurance and Disability Insurance Trust Funds assume that
the maximum taxable earnings, the average total earnings of covered
workers, and benefit provisions all remain unchanged, the Bô~rd h~
PAGENO="0111"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 105
customarily provided in its recent annual reports two sets of medium-
range projections (for about 15 to 20 years) by means of alternative
assumptions.15 While one projection assumes that the provisions of
the current law will be in effect in the future, the other projection
assumes that the maximum taxable earnings and benefit provisions are
amended periodically so that the relationships among total earnings,
taxable earnings, and benefit expenditures during the period in ques-
tion are the same as those shown in the long-range intermediate-cost
estimates prepared on level-earnings assumptions. For both projec-
tions, average total earnings of covered workers is assumed to rise at
an annual rate of 3 percent.
The assumptions underlying the second projection are more realistic
and hence more meaningful. `Case II is illustrative of how tax-benefit
ratios would be affected by rising earnings and rising maximum taxable
earnings base. Case II assumes that the maximum taxable earnings
will be adjusted upward at 10-year intervals (see notes to tables 1, 2,
and 3) and the worker's earnings will increase at a rate of 3 percent
annually. As for the benefit provisions, case II uses the same benefit
structure as determined by the benefit formula now in the present law.
Specifically, under existing provisions, the primary insurance amount
of the maximum earner is a little over 30 percent of the average of his
taxable earnings in the last 10 years of employment; for the average
earner, it is approximately 39 percent. These percentages serve the
basis for benefit computations in case II.
As shown in table 3, tax-benefit ratios in case II are all lower than
those in case I-the ratios in case I are reduced by about 40 percent.
In case II, the ratio exceeds unity for the maximum earner only under
two circumstances, and all but one of the ratios for the average earner
are less than unity.
From 1940 to 1966, benefit payments to the retired worker had been
increased at an average annual rate of 4.2 percent.16 In light of this
historical record, it would be of interest to appreciate the effects on
tax-benefit ratios of changing benefit formula without altering the
conditions of the maximum taxable earnings and the worker's earnings
as assumed in case II. Case III, in which benefit payments are increased
annually by 4.2 percent, is set up for such a purpose. As shown in table
3, the tax-benefit ratios in case III are all lower than those in case II.
As compared with the ratios in case I, the ratios in case III are more
than 50 percent less. The maximum earner loses only in one case, having
a ratio of 1.07, whereas the average earner loses in none.
B. ~INCREASING" ASSUMPTIONS 3 PERCENT VERSUS 5 PERCENT
Although the annual growth rate of 3 percent for earnings assumed
in cases II and III is more realistic than the level-earnings assump-
tions in case I, the projected gain in earnings may fall short of what
may actually take place. If earnings `are assumed to rise by the annual
gain in productivity of 3 percent and, in addition, by the annual rise
~` For example, see the 1967 Annual Report, Board of Trustees of the Federal Old-Age
and Survivors Insurance and Disability Insurance Trust Funds (mimeographed).
~ See notes to tables 1, 2, and 3. HR. 5710 is currently under consideration in the U.S.
Congress. This bill proposes, among other things, an `average increase of 20 percent in
benefit payments.
PAGENO="0112"
106 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE'-PART III
in the price level of 2 percent, a growth rate of earnings at 5 percent.
per annum may be speculated. With respect to the maximum taxable
earnings, a continuous upward adjustment of 5 percent per year may
also be contemplated.
The assumption of a 5-percent annual rate of increase in money
wages does not appear unreasonable in light of the record in the post-
war period. From 1947 to 1965, the average annual rate of gain in
output per man-hour in the private economy was 3.2 percent. During
the same period, the compensation per man-hour in current dollars
rose by an average annual rate of 5 percent (a. 3.2-percent rise in real
terms) .~ In a recent study of the potential and problems of economic
growth in the TJnitecl Sta.tes to 1975, the Joint Economic Committee
uses two sets of assumptions. For the A model, (1) prothictivity in
the private sector is assumed to advance at 3.5 percent per year from
1966 to 1970 and at 3.1 percent annually from 1970 to 1975, and (2)
price level is assumed to rise at. an annual rate of 2 percent. from 1966
to 1975. For the B model, (1) the annual growth rate of productivity
is assumed to be a.bout 3 percent throughout the entire period, and
(2) the rate of price inflation is assumed to be 1.5 percent per year.
WTage rates in both the public and private economy are assumed to
rise by the sum of the annual rates of gain in productivity and in
consumer prices. In other words, wage rates in the A model will rise
at 5.5 percent. annual rate. from 1966 to 1970 and at 5.1 percent from
1970 to 1975, and they will increase in the B model by 4.5 percent per
annum for the ent.ire period, 1966 through 1915.18
The effects on tax-benefit rat.ios when worker's earnings and the
ma.ximi.un ta.xable earnings a.re bot.h rising at 5 percent instead of at 3
perc.ent per year are illustrated by the ratios in case IV. All ratios
except one are less than unity for the average earner as well a.s for the
maximum earner. The highest rat.io for the maximum earner is 1.01;
for the average earner, it is 0.78.
Analogous to case III, case V ma.y be considered. This is a case in
which maximum ta.xa.ble ea.rnings a.nd worker's earnings are both
rising at 5 percent per annum, but benefit payments are assumed to
increase at an annual rate of 4.2 percent. As expected, tax-benefit
ra.tios in this case are lower than t.hose in case IV. The highest. ra.tios
for the maximum and for the average earners are 0.78 and 0.60, respec-
tively.
0. INFLATION PROOF SOCIAL SECURITY
Fixed dollar income shrinks in purchasing power during times of
price inflation. Socia.l security systems the world over have attempted
to adjust their benefit.s in the face of inflation. In a.ddition, the benefit
computation formula itself has been changed over time. The mecha-
ii See table 11 In The Economic Situation in 1966, Statement submitted to the Joint
Economic Committee, U.S. Cong.. by Arthur M. Ross, Hearings on. the 1966 Economic
Report of the President, Feb. 8, 1966 (mimeographed).
18 U.S. Economic Growth to 1975: Potential and Problems, Joint Economic Committee
U.S. Congress, 89th Cong., 2d sess. (washington: D.C., Government Printing Office
1966, p. 8). It should be mentioned that lower rates of productivity gain and price level
advance have also been used In projections. The National Industrial Conference Board
assumes for the total economy an annual growth rate of productivity at 2.85 percent to
1975 and an annual price Inflation rate of 1.2 percent to 1975. "The Economy in the Nect
Decade," The Conference Board Record, vol. II, No. 12, December 1965~ pp. 3-23 esp. pp
9 and 10.
PAGENO="0113"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSIJRANCEPART iii 107
iiisms by which these adjustments are made, however, are different. In
some countries, adjustments are provided for by means of a price index
(and/or wage index), under which changes in benefit amounts come
about automatically. In other countries, adjustments are made by an
ad hoc procedure, usually in the form of a legislative decree. Both
methods have their advantages and disadvantages.'9
Cases III and V, discussed previously, are illustrative of the effects
on tax-benefit ratios when rises in benefits contain both allowance for
inflation and additional increase in benefits. In the context of the
present discussion, it would be of interest to appraise the effects on
tax-benefit ratios of a system in which social security benefits are
continuously and automatically adjusted for price inflation. Case VI
assumes that the maximum taxable earnings and the worker's earn-
ings both rise at 5 percent per annum, and that benefit amounts are
raised annually in accordance with the assumed rate of advance in the
general price level of 2 percent.
Table 3 shows that tax-benefit ratios in case VI are higher than
those in case V but lower than those in case IV. None of the ratios are
in excess of unity either for the maximum earner (with the highest
ratio of 0.89) or for the average earner (his highest ratio being
0.69).
IV. CONCLUDING REMARKS
The highlights of this paper are as follows: (I) There are gainers
and losers in social security. The extent of gains and losses depends
critically upon assumptions regarding earnings levels, family statuses,
the shiftability of the employer taxes, and the factor of price infla-
tion.20 (2) Consideration of price inflation in tax-benefit ratios has
the effect of raising the rate at which taxes are compounded and bene-
fits discounted. (3) Cost comparisons between private insurance and
social security suggest that a worker with high earnings (annual
19 The most up-to-date descriptions of the social security systems in the world are avail-
able in Social Security Programs Throughout the World, 1967, Social Security Adminis-
tration, U.S. Department of Health, Education, and Welfare (Washington: U.S. Govern-
ment Printing Office* 1967, 239 pp) Many social security systems provide for automatic
adjustment of benefits to compensate for inflation. Daniel S Gerig, "Automatic Cost-of-
Living Adjustment of Pensions in Foreign Countries," Social security Bulletin, vol. 23 No.
3, March 1960, pp. 16-19, 24). In the United States, two Federal retirement systems ad just
their benefits in accordance with the rate of inflation. John P. Jones, "Amendments to the
Civil Service Retirement Act," Social Security Bulletin, vol. 26, No. 2, February 1963, pp.
i2-i6; and Marice C. Hart, "Cost-of-Living Increases in Military Retired Pay," Social
Security Bulletin, vol. 27, No. 2, February i964, pp. 13-14.
For a discussion of different methods of benefit adjustments, see Robert J. Myers, "The
Effect of Dynamic Economic Conditions on a Static-Provision National Pension Scheme"
Transactions, 17th International Congress of Actuaries, London and Edinburgh, Englan~,
May 1964, pp. 328-336, especially 335-336.
20 Participants in social security gain only at the expense of others, including largely those
also In the program, and partly, those who are not Included In the program (If covered
workers bear less than the full burden of the employer tax). With respect to covered
workers. the direction of income transfer Is (a) from those with higher earnings (up to
the taxable ceilings) to those earning less, due to benefit weighting in favor of the latter
(b) from workers who receive little or no benefits to those who receive or who are credited
with large amounts of benefits (because of differential mortality rates or by reason of
family circumstances), (c) from long-term members to those In the program for shorter
periods of time (but still long enough to be entitled to benefits), either due to differences in
the work history of Individuals or to different dates from which their occupations have
been covered. (d) from both of those workers who have not worked long enough to gain
eligibility and those married women workers who do not receive benefits on their own
contributions to those workers who meet eligibility requirements, and finally, (c) from
employed workers to the self-employed on assumption of full-backward shifting.
In view of the differential mortality experiences of the various groups In the population,
cited in footnote 2, Negro workers may more often lose under social security due to lower
life expectancies. However, this "disadvantage" may be offset by the provisions of survivors
and disability benefits which favor both families with large numbers and persons more
prone to being disabled.
53-200-67--Pt. 3-S
PAGENO="0114"
108 OLD ~GE INCOME ASSIJRANCE~-PART III
wages of $6,600 in the hypothetical case) may be disadvantaged in the
sense that he may be required to pay more for social security than that
which private insurance might require of him for the same benefits.
However, there are circumstances under which even he may not suffer
a cost disadvantage. In contrast, workers of lesser earnings (annual
wages of $1,800 and $3,000 in the examples) seem to enjoy a cost
advantage in social security vis-a-vis private insurance. It should be
pointed out that comparisons are based on monetary costs. Not treated
in the study are the costs associated with compulsion under social se-
curity and those associated with seeking information for private in-
surance coverage. (4) Case I is based on unrealistic assumptions, but
these are used in most currently available analyses. Case II assump-
tions are most realistic, judging from the history of changing
provisions in the past. The assumption of benefit increase at the his-
torical annual average of 4.2 percent in cases III and V may be
questionable, but some increase in benefit payments seems reasonable
to speculate. In cases IV, V, VI, the realization of the assumption of
continuously rising maximum taxable earnings (in accordance with
the rise in worker's earnings) would require a substantial departure
from current practice; this same requirement would apply to the
assumption of automatically adjusting benefit payments to make up
for the loss of purchasing power due to price inflation. (5) If price.
level increases and productivity advances are reflected in setting taxes
and benefits, tax-benefit ratios in the future will be substantially
lower than those computed on the basis of the provisions in the
current law. (6) If automatic adjustment is provided, so as to main-
tain the purchasing power of a given amount of benefits during the
receipt period, tax-benefit ratios are shown to be favorable in case
VI in which taxes rise as workers' earnings and maximum taxable
earnings both increase. And (1) the focus of the paper has been
on the tax-benefit relationships insofar as individual workers are
concerned.
PAGENO="0115"
THE REAL RATE OF INTEREST ON LIFETIME CON-
TRIBUTIONS TOWARD RETIREMENT UNDER SOCIAL
SECURITY
BY JOHN A. BRIrrAIN*
The fifteenfold growth of Federal social security tax receipts since
1949 has stirred a debate over how well workers fare under the system.
The expressed opinions are remarkably varied. For example, Paul
Samuelson pictures a growing nation as "the greatest Ponzi game
ever contrived," with its growth making possible ever-expanding
social security benefits:
The beauty about social insurance is that it is actuarially
unsound. Everyone who reaches retirement age is given
benefit privileges that far exceed anything he has paid in.
And exceed his payments by more than 10 times as much (or
five times, counting in employer payments.)1
On the other hand Milton Friedman speaks of a "raw deal" for young
workers:
Retired persons currently enjoy a bonanza. But youngsters
currently entering the system are getting a raw deal. * * *
To finance the excess payments to the growing number of
retired, taxes have had to be raised repeatedly. As a result
the benefits promised younger workers are much smaller than
the equivalent of the taxes paid on their wages.2
These disparate opinions invite a review of the arguments and a
systematic evaluation of the evidence. However, the stress here will
be on the real rate of interest or return on contributions under the
system, rather than on the lifetime tax-benefit ratios referred to by
Samuelson and Friedman. Projections by means of an abstract model
suggest that even under a variety of assumptions the prospective
return to most new participants under social security is far less at-
tractive than indicated by Samuelson, but better than the "raw deal"
suggested by Friedman. In particular it will be argued that most
*The writer is a member of the Senior Staff at The Brookings Institution.
The issue considered here arose within a general study of the economic effects
of payroll taxation tinder a program supervised by the National Committee on
Government Finance and financed by a special grant from the Ford Foundation.
Helpful suggestions were offered by Henry Aaron, William Birdsall, John
Carroll, Henry Cassidy, Ida Merriam, Robert Myers, Michael Taussig, and
Joseph Pechman. However, the views expres:sed here are those of the writer
alone. Thanks are due Sheau-Eng Lau for invaluable research assistance.
1 "On Social Security," Newsweek, 3an. 13, 1967, p. 88.
2 Milton Friedman, "On Social Security," New8week) Apr. 3, 1967, p. 81.
109
PAGENO="0116"
110 OLD AGE INCOME ASSTJRANCE'-PART III
participants will fare much better than investors in fixed dollar claims
have in recent recades, but nmch less well than long-run investors in
equity capital.~
A. So~IE ISSUES IN THE CoNmov1~sr
Before turning to the evidence, it should be acknowledged that esti-
mation of lifetime tax-benefit ratios for individuals is a somewhat
artificial exercise in the first place. Why should we ask whether a per-
son ultimately recoups in benefits the equivalent of his taxes when the
same question is rarely asked with respect to other taxes? The essence
of the social security system is that it is a current transfer program
under which the working generation pays taxes to finance benefits to
others who have retired. Since the taxes and later benefits assigned to
an individual are not related at all closely as they are under private
insurance, a strong case can be made for completely separate analysis
and evaluation of the tax and benefit structures on their own merits.
Certainly the present existence of a very tenuous relationship between
individual taxes and benefits does not exempt the payroll tax itself
from the cri~icism that it is regressive and a heavy burden on low-
income groups.
Despite these methodological considerations, the question of the at-
tractiveness of social security to individuals has already been recog-
nized for debate, and it is tempting to be diverted to the issue. Part
of the temptation is due to the explicit earmarking of the tax for pro-
vision of benefits. Furthermore, participants in the system have been
encouraged to believe that they are "paying for" their benefits individ-
ually, and many appear to believe that they will get just what they pay
for, as under private insurance. On the other hand. some younger
workers with a long period of taxpaying ahead of them and an even
longer wait for benefits have been grumbling about rising social se-
curity taxes.4 Others are `asking Congressmen whether they are getting
their mone's worth under social security. In view of this increasing
interest and concern, it seems in order to examine the issue within this
framework. However, the objective of such analysis is to throw some
light on the redistributive effects and dynamic features of the overall
system, and it carries no implication that social security should be
evaluated as a conventional insurance program.
SOME EARLIER VIEWS
The contradiction between the evaluations of Samuelson and Fried-
man cited above is due in part to differing assumptions. Samuelson
counted on growth of real earnings of some 3 percent per year to enable
the earning population to pay benefits to the retired population always
This comparison carries no implication that an option to Invest In equity capital could
or should be built into the present social security system. The objective is to provide a
yardstick against which the yield on this form of saving may be appraised. This, of course,
may well be relevant to the decision as to the appropriate ceiling on taxable earnings,
maximum tax rate, and ultimate size of the system.
"We aren't reaching our young people," concedes one tAFL-CIO} politico. * * * For
example, current * * * polls find young union members resentful of the federation's
support for increased social security benefits; the money Is to come from taxes, "and a lot
of our groups don't like this money being taken out of their pockets." (John A. Grimes.
"Labor's Image," Wall Street Journal, Mar. 1, 1961.)
PAGENO="0117"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 111
much greater than the value of their accumulated taxes. However,
he did not spell out the other conditions required in order for this to
occur. Specifically, it is not clear whether he imputed interest to the
accumulated taxes, or whether he discounted the prospective benefit
stream.5
Friedman was referring to the type of analysis presented by Cohn
Campbell and others and based on current legislation.6 Campbell took
the scheduled tax and benefit structure as given and demonstrated that
the value of taxes paid in the name of young workers, plus imputed
interest at 4 percent, would be much greater upon retirement than
the value at that time of scheduled benefits. However, his analysis did
not allow for income growth and the likely corresponding increase in
both taxes and benefits. Although both are expected to increase, this
failure to allow for growth biases the estimate in favor of the "raw
deal" argument since the benefits which a worker can expect grow for
a longer period than the taxes he pays.
Perhaps baffled by the diversity of opinion on how individuals are
faring under the system, one Congressman recently asked social secu-
rity officials how he should answer his constituents on this issue:
I would like an answer to the basic question that concerns
the young person coming under the social security system as to
whether this is a sound financial investment or whether he is
being taken-whether he could invest his money elsewhere
more wisely.7
The Social Security Administration responded with estimates by its
Chief Actuary, Robert J. Myers, and included a critique of the bad-
buy-for-the-young thesis such as that set down by Campbell.8 It was
stated that this argument is not true even if one makes the unrealistic
assumption that present benefit schedules will remain unchanged.9
Even if they were fixed, the Administration argued, social security is
a good buy under present law for the young worker in terms of the tax
which he himself will be asked to pay; on the assumption of a 33/4~
percent interest rate, this was estimated to be only 80 to 85 percent
of the value of the prospective benefits. Even earners paying the
present and proposed maximum tax were said to come out about even.
The findings of Campbell and others were indicted on two addi-
tional counts: (1) Failure to take into account the value of the sur-
vivor and disability insurance protection, and (2) the usual assumption
that the employer tax belongs to, and in the absence of social security,
For technical analysis of dynamic features of a social Insurance system see Paul A.
Samuelson, "An Exact Consumption-Loan Model of Interest With or WTlthout the Social
Contrivance of Money," Journal of Political Economy, LXVI, December i95S, pp. 467-482
and Henry Aaron, "The Social Insurance Paradox," The Canadian Journal of Economics
and Political Science, XXXII, No. 3, August 1966, pp. 371-374.
Cohn D. and Rosemary G. Campbell, "You'll Never Get Back All Those Old-Age `Con-
tributions.' " The Washington Post, Nov. 7, 1965, sec. F, p. 3, and James M. Buchanan and
Cohn D. Campbell, "Voluntary Social Security," Wall Street Journal, Dec. 20, 1966, p. 14.
For similar calculations, see Ray M. Peterson, "The Coming Din of Inequity," The Journal
of the American Medical Association, Apr. 8, 1961, pp~ 34-40, and more recent estimates by
Mr. Peterson reported by Elizabeth Damn in "Income Redistribution Under the Social
Security System," National Tax Journal, September 1966, pp. 276-285.
a President's Proposals for Revision in the Social Security System (hearings before the
Committee on Ways and Means, House of Representatives, Mar. 1, 2, and 3, 1967), question
of Congressman Uliman, p. 329.
8 Ibid., pp. 330-41.
8 Officials forecast that earnings increases will permit Increases in benefit schedules
without higher tax rates.
PAGENO="0118"
112 OLD AGE INCOME ASS~JRANCE~PART III
would be available to, each employee in an amount equal to his own
contribution. These two points are subject to criticism. It is true
that failure to recognize that only part of the tax is designated for
retirement benefits would distort any analysis, but the writers criticized
were generally aware of this problem.1° Much more important is
the second point concerning the treatment of the employer's portion
of the tax. Estimation of the aggregate lifetime burden of social
security taxes on a worker requires an appraisal of the extent to
which the employer's tax is borne by the earner.11 This complex
question cannot be treated in detail here, but it is so ftmdamental
that a brief digression on this problem seems worthwhile.
ON THE INCThEXCE OF THE TAX ON EMPLOYERS ha
The early literature on the incidence of the employer tax was
summed up in 1941:
Economists is~ho, in the years preceding the introduction
of the Social Security Act, had given the problem of incidence
careful consideration, seem to have been in general agreement
that a payroll tax, whether levied on the worker or the em-
ployer, would be paid ultimately by the workers. * * In the
years that have passed since the Social Security Act became
law, the weight of informed opinion still seems to be that the
payroll tax is borne largely by the workers. 12
Although earlier economic reasoning rested on the marginal pro-
ductivity theory of wages under rather simplified assumptions, this
consensus among economists that in the long run labor bears this
very generally applicable tax appears to have persisted, although
with less unanimity.13 The social accounting convention recom-
mended in the U.N. System of National Accownts and followed by
many countries other than the United States also implies that the
employer tax is borne by labor; it is treated as though it were a tax
deducted at the source from employees' income.
Clearly, on the assumption of a highly inelastic aggregate labor
supply and a downward sloping labor demand curve reflecting varia-
tion of the total compensation rate with employment, the marginal
productivity theory shows that labor must absorb a payroll tax if
employment is not to be reduced. However, the essence of the more
general argument is that it should matter little to an employer how
he pays a given a.mount of total compensation (including social se-
~° For example. Campbell was not guilty of this error; he deducted 20 percent of the
tax to remove the portion estimated to be needed to finance OASDI benefits other than
those of the aged. This same 20 percent figure Is mentioned by the actuary as the appro-
priate fraction to eliminate (Ibid., p. 331). In any case the adjustment appears to be of
little nractical consequence; the actuary Indicates In an unpublished memorandum that
disability benefits and survivor benefits due to preretirement death are roughly paid for
by the sum of the contributions for the beneficiaries and by those who die before retirement
without eligible survivors.
11 The Incidence of the employee's tax Is not at Issue since the usual view that direct
taxes on individual earnings rest on those who pay them has rarely been questioned In the
literature on the social security tax.
ila In this section It is argued that the tax paid by employers on behalf of their emnloyees
Is actually borne by the employees. This premise Is fundamental to the later estimates.
but the brief technical case made for It here may be omitted by readers primarily Interested
In the quantitative findings.
1~ Seymour Harris. Economics of Socicl Security, pp. 2S5-286.
~ In the short run the picture is undoubtedly less clear cut. There may be lags in the
response by employers, short-run constraints Imposed by the minimum wage and union
scales and other rigidities.
PAGENO="0119"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 113
curity taxes as well as ordinary fringe benefits) *14 Whatever the de-
gree of competition and elasticities in the labor market a certain level
of total compensation will be arrived at under prevailing conditions
of labor demand and supply.15 Any external imposition of an addi-
tion to total compensation such as the employer social security tax
will tend to be countered by a granting of less compensation of other
types than would be the case without the tax. Following this reason-
ing, the employer contribution is viewed as a substitute for other
types of labor income and in effect paid out of labor's potential share.'6
Although the above argument is entirely theoretical, the present
writer has also completed, but not yet reported, an empirical investi-
gation of the tradeoff between employer payroll taxes and other com-
pensation. The analysis was primarily in a production function type
of framework. Cross-country regressions showed clearly that at a
given level of labor productivity industries in countries with rela-
tively high employer payroll taxes paid a basic wage that was rela-
tively low by about the same amount. Hence the tax is seen to be
shifted to labor since the larger the tax the lower the basic wage the
workers with given productivity tend to receive. Similar results,
though less statistically convincing, were obtained from time series
analysis of U.S. data.
It should be stressed that the criticism by the Social Security Ad-
ministration of the imputation of the employer tax to each employee
does not imply rejection of the previous general argument that labor
as a whole bears the tax. Its argument is on a different ground:
Even though it is true that the employer contribution in
the final analysis is borne in considerable part by employees,
either because they receive lower wages than they otherwise
would or because as consumers they pay higher prices than
they otherwise would, it does not follow that the incidence
of the employer tax falls on wage earners in exact proportion
to the earnings on which the tax is paid. The incidence of the
tax will depend in specific instances on a variety of complex
factors. The employer tax, therefore, may be looked on as be-
ing for the use of the system as a whole, and not as a match-
ing contribution that is to be credited to each particular em-
ployee on the basis of the amount he paid.17
On this ground the employer's tax was disregarded by the chief actu-
ary in his memorandum suggesting that most earners are scheduled
to get more than their "money's worth." 18 However, even if it is agreed
that precise imputation of the burden of the employer tax to indi-
viduals is not possible it is apparent that omission of this part of the
14 are probably not totally indifferent concerning this. They may be willing
to pay somewhat more toward a retirement fund than in basic wage increases because this
may save them charitable obligations later, or because they basically believe forced saving
is a good thing.
15 This does not Imply that the demand and supply conditions yield a unique determina-
tion of the compensation level. They may tend only to determine a bargaining range.
(See, e.g., William J. Fellner, "Prices and Wages Under Bilateral Monopoly," Quarterly
Journal of Economscs, vol. 61, August 1947, pp. 503-532). The point is that the employer
has no reason to react much differently to the tax and other labor costs, respectively.
1~ An attempt by labor to resist this tradeoff process could maintain the basic earnings
rate at the expense of increased unemployment and reduced aggregate earnings. However,
this resistance would not occur if the labor supply were highly inelastic, or if labor
bargained in terms of total compensation in the first place.
`~ President's Proposals for Revision of the Social Security System, op. cit., p. 330-31.
18 Op. cit., pp. 331-46.
PAGENO="0120"
114 OLD AGE LNCOME ASS1JRA~CE~-PART III
tax is bound to produce seriously misleading results. Even if the pro-
ceeds are "for the use of the system as a whole" it does not follow that
the tax is a burden to no one. In other words, the concern here is with
the cost of the tax to the individual worker and not with the cost
to the system of the ultimate benefit to that worker. It is difficult to
understand an analysis which agrees that the employer tax "is
borne in considerable part by employees" and yet ignores it in eval-
uating the tax paid by individuals.19 If it is paid by employees as a
group it must also be paid by them as individuals, and it seems better
to make an imperfect imputation which is roughly right rather than to
settle for being precisely wrong.
Another implication of the exclusion of the employer tax should
be noted. The Myers memorandum discusses the tax on various earn-
ings levels. When no employer tax is imputed to a group of earners
such as the substantial number paying the maximum employee tax,
this implies that lower income earners bear more tha.n their propor-
tional share of this tax if it. is agreed that the tax is borne by employees
as a whole. If so, the lower income employees as a whole would pay
even more than double the employee tax and their "deal" would be
much less good than suggested in the memorandum. Since there is
no reason to expect that this anomaly exists and the employer tax
cannot be realistically ignored, there seems no better alternative than
to impute the employer tax to employees in proportion to the em-
ployee tax. This is in accord with the original theory, since even at
the individual level we presume that the larger the employer tax the
less the compensation of other types which can be extracted by the
employee..
B. THE BASIO MODEL*
If the above reasoning is correct, the method underlying the tax-
benefit ratios preseiited in the Myers memorandum is biased in two
opposite directions. Failure to allow for the longer growth of benefits
than taxes durimm~ a worker's lifetime undervalues the "deal" expected
for a. participant in the system, whereas excluding the employer tax
presumably borne by the worker overvalues the arrangement. An
attempt will be made in what follows to circumvent these opposing
biases.
In this section, and the following, the stress is on average taxes and
benefits per worker under assumed growth patterns, and it is assumed
that the average earner pays the average tax. This per capita. approach
abstracts temporarily from the ceiling on taxable earnings and varia-
tions in the relative position of different types of earners, and focuses
on earner-beneficiary transfers. It also must be achrnowledged that. in-
troduction of assumptions concerning growth of the system introduces
an element of arbitrariness into the analysis. However, it seems likely
that almost any plausible growth assumptions will provide a more
19 T'nis has its counterpart in the treatment of undistrihuteci corporate profits by some
writers on the size distribution of individual incomes. Although it is the common saving
of stockholders as a whole these writers refuse to impute it to Individuals. This pretense
that corporate saving is nobody's income understates the relative income share of high
income ranks.
*Thjs section reports the methodology developed to estimate the rates of return.
It may be omitted by readers more interested in the findings rather than their
technical basis.
PAGENO="0121"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 115
realistic analytical basis than the static assumptions concerning taxes
and benefits accepted reluctantly in previous studies. Similarly, it is
believed that a proportional imputation of the employer tax is prefer-
able to ignoring its burden altogether. However, at this stage the only
imputation is at the aggregate level, since only average taxes and
benefits per worker are being considered. Assuming that workers as a
whole bear the entire tax, it follows that the average tax per worker
must include the tax nominally assigned to employers, regardless of
how it is distributed among workers.
The model to be suggested approximates certain features of the cur-
rent and developing social security system and incorporates available
official data such as projections by the Social Security Administration
of population by age group and mortality rates by sex. The result is a
mixture of theoretical and empirical elements. It abstracts from many
of the details of the present tax-benefit structure in an effort to focus
on the key effects of the growth process. The present analysis also de-
parts from earlier work in another way. Instead of assuming particular
rates of return, the criterion stressed is the estimated yield to a par-
ticular type of participant on his "investment" in social security.
The basic assumptions of this simple growth model are: (1) Real
earnings per employee grow at a fixed rate, r; (2)' real retirement bene-
fits per beneficiary grow at the same rate, r, and, therefore, are relate.d
to average earnings by a fixed factor, Ic; 20 and (3) the system is
financed on a pay-as-you-go basis.2'
The particular tradeoff between the tax rate and the taxable earn-
ings ceiling to be used in raising the required tax is left unspecified
at this stage. Nonretirement benefits and the taxes needed to raise
them are both excluded from this model, and this avoids the bias pro-
duced by weighing old-age benefits alone against taxes raised for
more general purposes. The postulated pay-as-you-go financing and
fixed benefit-earning ratio are intended to provide an approximate
skeleton of the dynamic features of the actual detailed social security
structure. Although never precisely realized, they should permit a
more meaningful analysis of the projected system than that possible
with earnings, tax rates, and benefit rates held constant.
This preliminary framework abstracts completely from the de-
tailed differentials in tax and benefit rates by income levels and family
20 Despite some irregularities this is roughly the experience of the system in the i940-
64 interval. For exninple, when benefits began to be paid in i940 the mean payment for a
beneficiary and wife was about 43 percent of mean earnings of covered workers. In i964
the ratio was 37 percent. The ratio lagged between i940 and i949 as coverage widened
then jumped to the current level and has been relatively stable since. (See Social Security
Bulletin, Annual Statistical Supplement, i964, pp. 27 and 29.) This assumption concerning
the growth rate of average benefits abstracts from the pattern at the individual level under
the present system. Average benefits promised each earner grow with the rise in his tax-
able earnings and with statutory Increases. Only the latter raise benefits after retirement.
Thus the benefits of a newly retired worker will tend to start out above the average level
but lag behind the average in later years. Allowance for this time path would yield a some-
what higher estimate of the present value of the benefit stream upon retirement. However,
this might well be offset by the higher tax estimate that would result from allowing for
below-average earnings In early years and above-average earnings later.
22 Some growth in the actual trust fund is foreseen by the `Social Security Administration
over and above the interest accumulated, but it is generally agreed that the system Is far
closer to a pay-as-you-go basis than a fully funded basis. In fact, the Chief Actuary, Mr.
Myers, interprets the financing basis as unchanged from the beginning "insofar as general
principles are concerned-namely, that full actuarial reserves are not developed ; rather,
over a long-range future period, the income is estimated to meet the outgo." (Letter to
David Lawrence reproduced in Hearings Before the Joint Economic Committee on the
1967 Economic Report of the President, Feb. 7, 5, and 9, i967, pt. 2, p. 354.)
PAGENO="0122"
116 OLD AGE LNCOME ASSURA~'CE~-PART III
type and is concerned only with per capita taxes and per capita bene-
fits. Let-
= average (mean) real earnings in year t
b~ =lcE= average real benefit in year t (where /~ is fixed ratio
of current E~ to b ~)
Wt =total earning (taxpaying) population
R~ =total old-age beneficiary (largely retired) population
T~ =.average real tax in year t (including both employer and
employee contributions)
Assuming pay-as-you-go financing and an exponential growth rate
r and E~,
-~ kE,R~JcEo(1+r)tR~
~- w - w (1)
Given ~ and projections of E, R, a.nd TV, the projected average tax can
be obtained and accumulated along with imputed interest.
The present value of the average benefit stream beginning at age
65 22 then be compared to the accumulated tax. Let-
= average benefit during the year at age n
B =;present value of the average benefit stream at age 65
= probability of reaching age n, given that one has reached
a~e 65
L =l~igth of working career
The discounted present value of the still-growing benefit stream is
given by-
B=~ b85(1+r~65p (2)
However, the first annual benefit at age 65 is-
b65=/cEo(1 +rY'
Therefore, equation (2) may be rewritten as-
B-I'E "f' (l+T)'~'265p
- O~ (1 I `\n-65 n (
n~=65 I~1T't)
It is apparent from equation (1) that the accumulated tax must be
directly proportional to (a multiple of) kE0 which is the average ben-
efit in the initial year. Since equation (3) shows this to be true also of
the present value of `benefits at retirement the initial benefit factor can-
cels out in computation of the tax-benefit ratio; since the latter is
therefore independent of the initial benefit, the accumulated tax can
be stated generally as a multiple of the starting `benefit level, and no
estimate is needed of the latter. Under the assumptions of the model
the ratio of the accumulated average tax to the present value of aver-
age benefits at age 65 depends only on the assumed values of the growth
~ Estimates will be given for this typical retirement age only, although the Social Se-
curity Administration puts the average retirement age at 67. This avoids the complexities
of the "earnings test" but qualifies the results since later retirement leads to more taxes
and less benefits. On the other hand it seems likely that the standard retirement age will
eventually be lowered, so that age 65 may be a plausible compromise.
PAGENO="0123"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 117
rate, the rate of return, the type of demographic projections (includ-
ing P~) and the length of the working career L.
The values of P~ to be used in equation (3) for single males and
single females are derived directly from the official projected mortality
rates for males and females. However, the probabilities to be used in
evaluating the benefit stream of a couple (eligible for wife's benefits)
are compound probabilities involving the mortality rates of both
sexes.~ This evaluation required special treatment which for the first
time required certain a'ssumptions concerning the internal benefit
structure.24
C. PROJECTIONS OF TAX-BENEFIT RATIOS AND RATES OF RETURN FOR THE
RECIPIENT OF AVERAGE EARNINGS
Other studies of the return to p'articipants in the social security sys-
tem have stressed lifetime tax-benefit ratios. Such projections will be
presented, briefly, here, but the main focus will be on a different cri-
terion. The most arbitrary element in T/B projections is the rate of
return imputed to taxes and used to discount benefits. Previous studies
have attempted no deflation of taxes and benefits. However, even if
they had, the real rate of return is probably even more difficult to pro-
ject than the real earnings growth rate, and it also varies enormously
from one type of asset to another. For this reason projections of the
TJB ratios will not be stressed. Instead the measure sought was the
real yield on contributions implied by any given tax-benefit projection.
The real rate of interest on contributions was defined as the particu-
lar rate of return which would equalize the real accumulated tax (plus
imputed yield) and the present value of real benefits discounted at the
same rate at the point of retirement. This is the yield which produces
a tax-benefit ratio of unity according to previous definitions. Before
presenting these, some examples will be given showing the sensitivity
of projected T/B ratios to the assumptions concerning the rate of
return.
THE EMPIRICAL APPROACH
The first estimates are on an average earner basis and continue to
abstract from variations by family structure and income. Estimation
of the tax-benefit ratios on the basis of relations (1) to (3) was rou-
tine, but several aspects of the estimates are relevant to a discussion
of the findings. In the first place, for simplicity the tax was assumed
to be paid annually at the beginning of each calendar year, with an-
nual benefits beginning on the 65th birthday. In effect this simplifica-
tion moves both taxes and benefits one-half year ahead of the pace
23 These three beneficiary types are special cases intended to be illustrative only. It
seems likely that they will have some relevance to the more complex tax-benefit relation-
ships for working couples whose partners had working careers of varying lengths.
24 First consider such a couple with a given starting benefit. (Allowance will be made
ultimately for the fact that couples have higher starting benefits on the average than single
earners.) Assume that upon the death of a wife a widower's benefits become two-thirds of
the level originally received by the couple and a widow's benefits are 55 percent, as under
the present law. Then the present value becomes the sum of three components-benefits
as couple, and potential benefits as widower and as widow. Denoting the probability of
living from 65 to age n as Pnm and Pn~ for males and females, respectively, the present
value of the stream received as a couple is obtained by replacing Pn in equation (3) by
PnmPn~. The potential stream In the widower status is evaluated by replacing Pn by Pn,n
(i-Pnr) and multiplying by two-thirds. For the widow status the probability term is
(1-Pnm) Pn~ and the multiplier is 55 percent.
PAGENO="0124"
118 OLD AGE L~COME ASS1JRA~CE-PART III
scheduled on a monthly basis, but this does not affect significantly the
ratio of the two sums. Secondly, since the official projections of TV~
and R~ were to be used in the computation of the annual tax per earner
by equation (1) it was necessary t.o specify a starting year for the
accumulation of the average tax. The yea.r 1966 was chosen because
it represented the inauguration of the current tax-benefit structure
of the social security system.
Finally, the estimates of lifetime values of T and B ~mder two alter-
native official cost projections were obtained for two or more specified
values of each of several unmeasured variables affecting the estimate
of T and B. The use of various assumed values provides some indica-
tion of the maimer in which variations in the factors affect the T/B
ratio and the yield on contributions. An attempt was made to encoin-
pass a plausible range in each of the following four variables: 25
(1) The projected rate of growth of average real earnings was
put alternatively at 2 percent and 3 percent. The past growth rates
measured over relatively long periods appear generally to have fallen
within this range. For example. one simple estimate shows a growth
rate of 2.45 percent during the 1929-65 interval and 2.62 percent for
1947_65.26
(2) Two alternative sets of population and mortality projections
developed by the Social Security Administration were also used. One
set was prepared on "low-cost" (high birt.h rate and high mortality)
assumptions and one on "high-cost" assumptions. The projected pO~)U-
la.t.ion with taxable earnings was taken to represent Wt. The projected
number of aged beneficiaries was used as the measure of R1.2~ The. low-
cost and high-cost projections of P~ are also deductibles from the offi-
cial actuarial stlidlies.2s
(3) Another factor in the total tax accunmla.tion is the age when
work is begun. Even if all workers paid the average annual tax it
would be necessary to distinguish between those starting early and
those starting late. The taxes were accumuhated from two alternative
starting ages (and, theref ore, for two different values of L). One
earner was assume.d to start work on his 18th birthday at the beginning
of 1966 and pay the average tax over his workingS career; the other
wa.s assumed to start at age 22. Both were assumed to retire at age 65.
(4) The projected real rate of return was placed alternatively at
1.5, 3, 5, and 8 perceiit. A brief digression in support of this wide range.
of rates is probably in order. The objective was to allow for the great
variation among rates of return available on different types of assets
in recent decades. Chart 1 illustrates the contrast between the real yield
This numerical analysis approach was chosen, because the functional form of the T/B
ratio appeared too complex for formal analysis. Under further simplifying assumptions
discussed later this is not the case.
~ These are based on a 1929-65 time series of average annual earnings per full-time
worker deflated by the Consumer Price Index. (The average earnings series was obtained
from The National Income and Product Accounts of the United States, supplement to the
Survey of Current Business, 1966. pp. 106-109.) The estimated growth rates were obtained
from a trend line fitted to the logarithms of the observations.
These two projections are given in Long-Range Cost Estimates for Old-Age, Survivors,
and Disability Insurance System, 1966, Actuarial Study No. 63 by the Office of the Actuary.
Social Security Administration, tables 3 and S. Projections were not available annually.
The average tax was assumed to grow exponentially between the years tabulated.
~ United States Population Projections for OASDHI Cost Estimates, actuarial study No.
62. by the Office of the Actuary, Social Security Administration, gives projected mortality
rates which are assumed to have leveled off after the year 2000. These are given for age
groups at 5-year intervals; they were interpolated to 1-year intervals, according to the
pattern given in U.S. Life Tables: 1959-61, vol. 1, No. 1, U~S. Department of Health,
Education, and Welfare, December 1964.
PAGENO="0125"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
119
on fixed value instruments on the one hand, and equity capital on the
other. The savings account and industrial common stock curves each
show hypothetical annual values in real terms of a single initial in-
vestment of $1 in 1~ll9.29
29Similar curves were also obtained for Index number series for long-term government
bonds, Moody's AAA corporate bonds, and all common stocks. To avoid the index number
problem the yield on mutual funds holding common stock was also considered. Government
bonds generally yielded more than savings accounts and corporate yields were still higher.
Rowever, the contrast between interest rates and the yieM on equity was the most striking
feature of all these comparisons, as it is in chart 1. Finally, although the Consumer Price
Index has been criticized as a deflator, alternative deflators would not dispel this contrast
between real interest rates and the yield on equity.
ChART 1* Illustrative Estimates oI~ the Real Value of Alternative
i9~9 Investments of $1.
PAGENO="0126"
120 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
The annual compound yield between any 2 years can be derived
from the slope of the line on this logarithmic chart. Some of these
yields are given for selected intervals in table 1. Except for a few very
short intervals like 1929-32 the yield on equity greatly exceeded that
on savings. Even an investment in this collection of stocks on the eve
of the 1929 crash would have greatly outperformed the savings series
in the long run, even though the stock series would not have caught
up until 1946. Also, during the postwar rise in interest rates since 1951,
savings yielded only 1.5 percent compared to 13 percent for the com-
mon stock series.
The four specified rates of return were chosen on two considerations.
First, in terms of projections it was appropriate to admit the diverse
options with respect to the long-run rate of return which past experi-
ence suggests are likely to be available. Secondly, it was essential that
the assumed range be wide enough to cover the yields provided in-
dividuals under the social security program in various circumstances.
This was required for accurate interpolation of these implied rates of
return on contributions.
TABLE 1-ILLUSTRATIVE ESTIMATES OF THE REAL ANNUAL RATE OF RETURN ON ALTERNATIVE INVESTMENTS
SELECTED INTERVALS, PERCENT
Interval
Savings accounts
Industrial common stock
1919-65
1. 5
9.2
1929-32
12.0
-27.7
1929-65
0. 9
7. 0
1932-37
1.7
25.1
1937-42
-0.6
-6.9
1942-46
-2.5
17.4
1946-65
0.1
11.2
1951-65
1.5
1.30
Source: See chart 1.
RESULTS FOR THE RECIPIENT OF AVERAGE EARNINGS
As indica.ted above the assumptions of the model permit the lifetime
average tax accumulations to be expressed as real magnitudes and as
multiples of the average benefit in 1966. The nature of the dependence
of *these on our assumptions (including only the two intermediate
rates of return) is indicated in table 2.'° These results show the ex-
pected relationships. The estimated lifetime tax plus imputed return
is greater for high growth rates, high cost projections and the early
starting age. The total accumulation is greater the higher the assumed
rate of return.31
30 The postulated rates of return of 1.5 and S percent are omitted here for brevity. How-
ever, the relationships in this range are included in later estimates of an individual's
effective rate of return under the retirement program.
3' No distinction has been made here between the tax rates on the self-employed and
others. Since the tax on the self-employed is 25 percent below the combined employer-
employee rate, the lifetime tax on employed workers must be somewhat higher than shown
in the table and the tax on self-employed 25 percent below that of the employed. The differ-
ential is scheduled to become even greater in the future. However, if self-employed income
were corrected for imputed profits, their tax rate on earnings might be about the same.
PAGENO="0127"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 121
TABLE 2.-AVERAGE LIFETIME ACCUMULATED TAX ON VARIOUS ASSUMPTIONS, STATED AS MULTIPLES OF THE
AVERAGE BENEFIT IN 1966
Type of projection and starting age
r=2 percent
i=3 i=5
r=-3 percent
i=3
=5
Low cost, start at 18
Low cost, start at 22
High cost, start at 18
High cost, start at 22
29. 64
24. 52
32. 88
26. 98
49. 63
39. 06
54. 25
42. 46
36. 66
29. 80
40. 97
32. 99
59. 42
46. 21
65. 42
50. 52
The present value of the benefit stream at age 65 can be conveniently
and meaningfully stated as a multiple of the initial benefit at age 65.
It was assumed that all earners will work long enough so that bene-
fits will be independent of the starting age. As indicated in the last
section, the present value of this stream will vary with sex and family
composition due to the different mortality projections for males and
females. Table 3 gives the present value of the benefit stream for three
specified types of beneficiaries at age 65. These ratios are consistent
with a priori expectations. The present value varies directly with the
growth rate, and inversely with interest rates. The high cost (low
mortality) estimates show somewhat higher values, and females have
higher values than males because of their lower mortality rates.
Couples eligible for wife's benefit have almost as high values as single
females with the same starting benefits despite the reduction in bene-
fits when one person dies. Since the values for these couples are closer
to those for females than those for males this cut in benefits appears
to be more than offset by the longer period during which at least one
person is expected to receive benefits.
ABLE 3.-VALUE APAGE 65 OF STREAM OF REAL BENEFI TS UNDER VARIOUS ASSUMPTIONS STATED AS A
MULTIPLE OF THE INITIAL ANNUAL BENEFIT ON THE 65TH BIRTHDAY
Type of project and family composition
r=2 percent
i=3
=5
r=3 percent
1=3
=5
Low cost, single male or married male with wife who worked.
Low cost, single female or married female with nondependent
husband
13. 13
15.60
11.26
13.16
14. 28
17.14
12. 15
14.30
Low cost, couple eligible for wife's benefit
High cost, single male or married male with wife who worked - - -
High cost, single female or married female with nondependent
husband
15. 10
13. 92
16.39
12. 75
11. 86
13.72
16. 56
15. 20
18.08
13. 86
12. 84
14.98
High cost, couple eligible for wife's benefit
15. 89
13. 33
17. 50
14. 55
Tables 2 and 3 form the basis for derivation of lifetime tax-benefit
ratios for a recipient of average income. If it were reasonable to assume
that a single benefit-earnings ratio k defined this starting benefit for
the average earner it would be necessary only to restate table 3 in
multiples of the 1966 starting benefit and take the ratio of the tax
measures in table 2 to the benefit measures in table 3. However, a rough
allowance will be made in this section for one feature of the present
°2The adjustment factors for table 3 are based on the earlier assumption that average
real benefits grow at the annual rate.
PAGENO="0128"
122 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
and proposed social security laws-the variation of the initial benefit-
earnings ratio with the. composition of re.tired worker families. The
only distinction considered was that between (a) couples in which the
male retired worker is entitled to benefits for a wife, and (b) all other
retired workers, whether married or not. Under current and proposed
law the benefit-earning ratio is about 50 percent higher for group (a)
than for group (b). This was taken into account in the tax-benefit
ratios for average earners reported in table 4,33
TABLE 4.-ESTIMATED AVERAGE LIFETIME TAX-BENEFIT RATIOS FOR RECIPIENTS OF AVERAGE EARNINGS,
VARIOUS ASSUMPTIONS, PERCENT
Type of projection, starting age,
family composition
r=2 percent
=3 1=5
r=3 percent
=3
1=5
Low cost, 18, male 1
Low cost, 18, female 5
Low cost, 18, coupleS
Low cost, 22, male 1
Low cost, 22, female2
Low cost, 22, couple3
High cost, 18, male 1
High cost, 18, female 2
High cost, 18, couple3
High cost, 22, male 1
High cost, 22, female 2
High cost, 22, coupl
102. 6
86. 3
59. 4
84. 8
71.3
49. 1
107.2
91. 1
62.6
88. 0
74. 7
51.3
200. 1
171. 1
117. 8
157. 6
134.7
92. 6
207.7
179. 5
123.1
162. 4
140. 5
96.4
76. 6
63. 8
44. 0
62. 2
51.9
35. 7
80.4
67. 7
46.6
64. 8
54. 5
37.6
146. 0
123. 9
85.3
113. 5
96.4
66. 3
152.0
130. 3
89.5
117. 4
100. 6
69.1
1 Single male or married male with wife who worked.
2 Single female or married female with nondependent husband.
3 Couple eligible for wife's benefit.
Source: Table 2 and table 3 (adjusted to multiples of 1966 starting benefit level).
The estimated tax-benefit ratios show the expected relationships.
High growth rates, low imputed return, low-cost projections and a
late starting age make for relatively good buys. The extreme cases
ander the particular assmnpt.ions of table 4 are T/B ratios of 36 per-
cent and 208 percent.34 The participant would clearly get a bargain in
all cases if the growth rate were as great. as the rate of return, but he
would generally fare poorly if the growth rate were substantially
lower. The college graduate who starts work at 22 fares much better
than the high school graduate in this special case in which they both
earn the average wage; ~ couples with nonworking wives do relatively
well. However, it is apparent that the T/B ratios are so heavily de-
pendent on the rate of return assumed that any absolute evaluation
n The 1964 Annual Statistical Supplement to tile Social Security Bnlletin, p. 47, indicates
that about one-eighth of new retired worker families in 1964 were headed by males entitled
to benefits for nged wives or for younger wives with at least one child. Ignoring the small
number who had child beneficiaries only, a rough indication of the effect of the differential
can be obtained by assuming this one-eighth of retired workers had an average starting
benefit-earnings ratio 50 percent above that of all others. The total benefit earnings ratio P
is a weighted mean of the P's for the two subgroups, implying that these P's are approxi-
onately 1.41 P and 0.94 P. respectively. These factors were used to obtain separate T/B
ratios for the two subgroups.
~ The spread would, of course, be much wider if a wider range of rates of return were
considered.
~ Tlais comparison should be qualified by recognition that college graduates have a higher
average wage and generally lower statutory benefit-earnings ratios. Some effects of the
graduated benefit-earnings schedule are discussed in sec. D.
PAGENO="0129"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 123
of the tax-benefit relationship provided to different groups under the
system would be arbitrary. More meaningful is the implied rate of
return for each group-the rate which equalizes the value of the tax
and benefit streams. These are given in table 5 and may be compared
with alternative yields on investment which have been avaliable in
the past, such as those illustrated earlier in chart 1.~ If past experience
is a plausible guide, social security participants in these categories will
fare much better than they would if offered the option of a private
savings program. On the other hand these relatively attractive rates
of return fall considerably short of the long-run yield on eqthty capital
in recent decades.
TABLE 5-ESTIMATED REAL RATES OF RETURN ON CONTRIBUTIONS FOR RECIPIENTS OF AVERAGE EARNINGS,
VARIOUS ASSUMPTIONS, PERCENT
Type of projection, starting age, family composition
r=2 percent
r=3 percent
Low cost, 18, male 1
Low cost, 18, female 2
Low cost, 18, couple 3
Low cost, 22, male 1
Low cost, 22, female 2
Low cost, 22, couple 3
High cost, 18, male 1
High cost, 18, female 2
High cost, 18, couple 3
High cost, 22, male `
High cost, 22, female 2
High cost, 22, couple 3
2.92
3. 43
4.52
3. 53
4.06
5. 23
2. 78
3. 28
4. 38
3.42
3.92
5. 12
3.83
4. 35
5.51
4.58
5.11
6. 28
3. 68
4. 21
5. 32
4.46
4.98
6. 16
1 Single male or married male with wife who worked.
Single female or married female with nondependent husband.
3 Couple eligible for wife's benefit.
The yields projected for these average earners under various as-
sumptions range from 2.78 percent to 6.28 percent. This spread in-
dicates substantial income redistribution among categories of
participants. However, even the least-favored group (single male,
starting work at 18, facing a high-cost system and a slow-earnings
growth rate) would fare much better over the long- run than private
savers have in the past. Clearly the key assumption of the present
analysis is that benefits keep pace with earnings. Insofar as the as-
sumption holds, the social security participant, like an investor in
equities, generally has a considerable advantage over an investor in
fixed dollar obligations subject to inflationary erosion.
D. THE EFFECT OF INDIVIDUAL EARNING LEVEL ON THE RATE OF
RETURN ON CONTRIBUTIONS
Until now the ceiling on taxable earnings and the relationship of
benefits and past earnings have not been considered. In terms of trans-
~° The estimated yields here and later were obtained by semilogarithmic interpolation.
Inspection showed a close linear relationship between log T/B and the four specified rates
of return 1. The estimates are linear interpolation for tlue value of i yieldiing log T/B0.
83-200-67-pt. 3-9
PAGENO="0130"
124 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
fers on a lifetime basis, another major redistributional feature of the
social security system is the relatively high benefit-earnings ratios
assigned to low-income groups. This feature is clearly "progressive"
in the classical sense.37 The extent of progressivity under a given tax-
benefit structure varies with the relation bet.ween the earnings ceiling
and average earnings. Departing from the previous emphasis on the
average earner, the progressivity of the system will be considered
here via the particular examples of the ceiling and benefit-earnings
structure in effect since 1966 and the new laws proposed in 1967.
Two revisions of the previous per capita analysis are required.
In the first place, in the presence of a. ceiling on taxable earnings it
is no longer true that the recipient of average earnings pays the
average tax. This mean tax is paid by a worker who earns the mean
taxable income throughout his career. Secondly, it is now recognized
that the benefit-earnings ratio ic. though still assumed invariant over
time, varies cross-sectionally with the earnings level. The revised tax-
benefit ratios based on the 1966 structure. were obtained in two steps.
First the average taxable earning in 1966 wa.s put at $3,700.~~ Adjust-
ment of the T/B rat.ios to allow for the effect of the graduated benefit-
earnings schedule was t.hen accomplished by a multiplicative correction.
Each multiplier is t.he ratio of the statutory k value for the specifie,d
earnings level to the k value for the recipient. of the mean taxable
income of $3,700.~~ The ratios in table 4 were adjusted by these fa.ctors
associated with earnings. The analysis presumes that the benefit-
earnings ratios in the starting yea.r 1966 remain fixed throughout the
worker's life.
The yield under each assumption and by income level was obtained
as before by interpolation. These yields are reported for selected
income levels in table 6. It is apparent that graduation of the benefit-
earnings schedule produc.es a. substantial graduation in the yield-
earning relationship.4° For example the yields for $2,000 earners are
generally 1l/2 percentage points or more higher than for t.hose earn-
ing $6,600 or more a.nd pa.ying the maximum ta.x. However, even the
most unfavorable projection for the latter continues to show a real
rate of return over 2 percent which is generally better in the long-run
than the savings account yield shown in chart 1.
~ On a static, single-year basis progressivity is also introduced by the tendency for the
taxes on relatively high-income earning population to accrue as benefits to the relatively
low-Income retired population.
38 See Actuarial Study No. 63, op. cit., p. 24.
"Estimates of these statutory 13 values by income level were obtained by Interpolation
in the official tables. The tables are provided by the Social Security Administration in
1967 Social Security Recommendations (mimeographed), Jan. 21, 1967, table following p.
2. The use of statutory 13 values abstracts from details of the moving average of earnings
levels on which benefits are based; there is also no way of knowing whether this schedule
is consistent with our pay-as-you-go assumption. However, only the slope of the benefit-
earning relationship shown in the official schedule Is essential to the present argument.
This allowance for the current degree of graduation serves adequately the broad purpose
of displaying this progressive feature of the system.
40 degree of graduation is probably somewhat exaggerated because no correction
could be made for the higher mortality rates of low-income earners. This makes a given
benefit stream worth less to them than indicated by overall mortality. (They get some
compensation for this in the life insurance features of social security, which are not
considered here.)
PAGENO="0131"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART iii 125
TABLE 6.-ESTIMATED REAL RATES OF RETURN ON CONTRIBUTIONS, VARIOUS ASSUMPTIONS AND EARNINGS
LEVELS, 1966 LAWS
tIn percenti
Assumptions
Taxa
ble earnings
levels
Cost
Age
Type 1
$2,000
$4,000
$6,000
$6,600+
Mean
2 L
2 L
18
18
M
F
3.78
4.27
2.82
3.34
2.39
2.93
2.30
2.85
3. 94
2.92
3.43
4. 52
2
3
L
L
18
18
C
M
5. 34
4.72
4. 43
3.73
4.
3.30
3.21
3.76
3.83
4.35
3
3
2
2
2
3
3
3
2
2
2
3
3
3
2
2
L
L
L
L
L
L
L
L
H
H
H
H
H
H
H
H
18
18
22
22
22
22
22
22
18
18
18
18
18
18
22
22
F
C
M
F
C
M
F
C
M
F
C
M
F
C
M
F
5.22
6. 28
4.46
4.97
6.10
5.51
6. 00
7.17
3.66
4.12
5.22
4.59
5.06
6.16
4.36
4. 83
4.26
5. 36
3.43
3.96
5.13
4.47
5. 01
6.18
2.68
3.18
4.29
3.58
4.09
5.23
3.31
3. 82
4. 97
2.98
3.53
4.71
4.02
4. 57
5.75
2.24
2.76
3.88
3.15
3.67
4.82
2.86
3. 39
4. 88
2.89
3.44
4.62
3.92
4. 48
5.66
2.15
2.68
3.80
3.06
3.58
4.73
2.76
3. 30
48
5. 51
3.53
4.06
5.23
4.58
5. 11
6.28
2.78
3.28
4.38
3.68
4.21
5.32
3.42
3. 92
5. 12
2
H
22
C
6. 06
5. 01
4. 58
3.79
4.46
3 H
3 H
22
22
M
F
5.40
5. 88
4.35
4. 87
3.89
4. 43
4. 33
5.54
4.98
6. 16
3 H
22
C
7.05
6.06
5.63
1 The 3 types of recipient are: M (single male or married male with wife who worked); F (single female or married female
with nondependent husband); and C (couple eligible for wife's benefit).
Yields over 7 percent appear in the table, but these are for the
unlikely case of an earner who waits to start work until age 22, but
nevertheless commands an income only slightly more than half the
mean. However, yields of over 6 percent are projected at this income
level for those beginning at age 22 and eligible for wife's benefits.
Despite the rather pronounced variation in these projected yields
they continue to be bounded by the poor past performance of savings
accounts and the lucrative long-term results of investment in equity.
To illustrate at a very hypothetical level the effect of the recently
proposed social security changes one more set of estimates was com-
puted assuming a $10,800 ceiling and the proposed new benefit-earn-
ings schedule.4' It was estimated that the higher ceiling would yield
an average taxable income of $4,225 in 1966 compared to $3,700 under
the actual ceiling.42 Allowance for this and the proposed change in
the benefit-earnings schedule produces a further graduation of the
yield-earnings relationship, as shown in chart 2.~°
41 This is purely illustrative since this higher ceiling would go Into effect in 1973. Once
more, there Is no way of learning whether the changes are consistent with the pay-as-you-go
assumption. However, the slope of the benefit-earnings schedule Is the key element in this
exercise. The results should be at least indicative of the order of magnitude of changes of
this type.
~ The alternative average taxable earnings In 1966 was estimated by means of the
relationship between the percentage of earnings taxable and the ratio of the ceiling to the
mean available for 1964. in Michael Resnick, "Annual Earnings and the Taxable Maximum
for OASDHI," Social Security Bufletin, November 1966, vol. 29, No. 11, 1965.
~ These sketches do not indicate the relative importance of the two factors in this change.
The proposed new schedule is somewhat more graduated than the old since the proposed
minimum benefit represents a relatively greater Increase than at other levels. However,
even an increase in the ceiling alone would further graduate the yields If the tax rate were
adjusted to keep total tax receipts unchanged; this would Increase taxes of upper income
groups and lower payments by others while leaving benefits unchanged.
PAGENO="0132"
~`/I~L) 2
S7~r~T 3
14r :~
Ji-
3
4.~.
(IT 22.
C/4i~icy ~ J'6.i.'.1~,r~t,.r/I,P r~cTMJ~J~AI YL~~) /7.~, £~(./J/I/.~ .!-EtJC~L. t:JF~
,1S«=I)/fEI~ C-'~c.J tM IM7t2 `//:IoM~ Cc~o(~jEc ~ H'~-~I C.orr 4:~nr.riiiiz~.
A (TcJ;t /11(1; )`~ôco :ep ~ ~/./~jG. 1/1:1, r EA.~i,'i ~ ~
~
*
o
i~f~t.E~ ~aMAL~E. Co~tpLZ~
MT-'~~ pi~o~c'~p
7
~
~(~CW7
2 ~ ~
~
~A.'11~
ACTUAL.-
oLw~2:~___. ~ 2. 2- ~
A~u~j~.S ~~~-`J~i-I I~Ar~ (Pi~i~c~n-)
J»=~:~
Q
a
w
0)
ci
a
Cc)P1~~L
cb Opi-L,
P~oPo~ED
2.. 3
PAGENO="0133"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 127
This summary portrayal in chart 2 attempts to illustrate in one
place the key factors affecting the yield on a participant's saving
under the social security system.44 In each individual chart the higher
yield to low incomes is pronounced. Although not much should be
made of the hypothetical projections labeled "proposed" on the
chart the greater distance between the lines in the vertical direction
shows the effect of a higher ceiling in the starting year and a more
graduated benefit-earnings curve. The boost in the yield to each
category of worker which accompanies a high earnings growth rate
is shown in each graph. The relative advantage of a couple receiving
wife's benefits ~ and the late starter are also pointed up once more.
E. CONCLUDING REMARKS
In a question cited earlier, Congressman Ullma.n asked whether so-
cial security is a sound investment for a young person or whether he is
being "taken." This question has two aspects. In the first place the
differentials among the yields to individuals require evaluation. Sec-
ond, are the absolute levels of the yields sufficient to justify this com-
pulsory saving? The model and statistical projections presented above
offer no unique or unequivocal answer to these questions. However, the
assumptions, reasoning, and projected yields on saving under social
security have been presented in detail so that the reader may evaluate
the analysis and judge for himself the adequacy of the yield accruing
to various categories of participants. It should be reiterated at this
point that there is no logical or practical reason for regarding these
varying yields as the basic criteria for appraising the tax and benefit
structures of the system; the program is so far removed from the pri-
vate insurance model that it is appropriate to evaluate the two struc-
tures independently. Even so the loose tax-benefit relationship that.
does exist justifies a few tentative and qualified observations con-
cerning the projected yields to various groups covered by the system.
Obviously, some participants in social security are faring much
better than others, but this type of differentiation also exists under the
generally approved graduated income tax. The relatively high rate
of return to low income groups under social security is consistent with
their being assigned a low burden under the income tax. The relatively
high return to couples who did not have the benefit of a wife's income
may well be consistent with the objective of redistributing income
in favor of those with greater need. However, this is by no means
certain, since nonworking wives may tend to be concentrated among
high income couples. It is clear, of course, that neither of these redis-
tributional features is consistent with the insurance analogy frequently
associated with the system, but that is irrelevant to their appraisal.
Less acceptable in terms either of values or logic, if we continue to
think in terms of lifetime tax benefit relationships, are the higher
~ Despite the lines drawn on each small graph, it should be noted that each is based
on only two points-one for each growth rate: the actual relation may not be linear. The
relationships for only one of the two cost projections are given, because the differences
between the two are so minor, as may be seen in table 6.
~ The estimates for relatively high earnings levels must be qualified due to their failure
to take account of the current practice of placing a ceiling on wife's benefits.
PAGENO="0134"
128 OLD AGE INCOME ASSTJRANCE-PART III
yields for women 46 and late entrants to the work force. The advantage
of women is minor, but the relative bargain of late starters is not
trivial and would be difficult to justify within this conceptual frame-
work. Presumably, late starters are typically college gTaduates or even
recipients of higher degrees who will tend ultimately to have relatively
high income, but twill be taxed for fewer years and thus enjoy a favor-
able differential comparable to their advantage with respect to military
service.47
This discrimination in favor of the late starter could be alleviated
by increasing the tax rates and/or ceiling sufficiently to permit ex-
emption of earners under 25 from the social security tax.
Another feature of the law which has not been treated explicitly
in the numerical estimates is the tax differential in favor of the self-
employed who are taxed at a rate 25 percent below the combined
employer-employee rate. The self-employed have not been analyzed
separately, because it seems possible that if the appropriate part
of their income were imputed to them as profits their effective tax
rate on earnings might then be on a par with that charged employees.
On the other hand a comparison of national income accounts and tax
return data suggests that underreporting of self-employed income
may be about enough greater than underreporting of earnings to
offset the part of their tax they are currently paying on profits. If so,
the true yield to the self-employed is considerably higher than to
earners a.t the same reported income level. If this were established
it would support elimination of the present statutory tax differential
in favor of the self-employed.
If we depart from the lifetime tax-benefit frame of reference and
consider current tax and benefit structures independently some of
the above appraisals no longer seem valid. For example, the progres-
siveness of the relationship between retirement benefits and lifetime
income cannot hide the fact that the tax used to finance benefits is
heavy and regressive now, and throughout the earner's working ca-
reer. Even though the working poor may ultimately get out more than
they put in, it does not necessarily follow that the later progressivity
of the benefit structure is sufficient to compensate for the prior hard-
ship imposed by the payroll tax. On the other hand, the benefit ad-
vantage of women due to lower mortality may well b.e a progressive
feature, but this depends on the assumption that women tend to have
lower incomes during retirement. Finally, the extra tax pa.id by early
starters compared to late starters with the same income may be justifi-
able on the grounds of ability to pay. In any case the separate ap-
praisals of taxes and benefits generally produce different answers from
those suggested by the lifetime rates of return.
Also relevant, in addition to these various differentials, is the ab-
solute level of these rates of return on contributions under the pro-
~ As is true throughout this paper, this point abstracts from the survivor and dependent
features of the system. These are less valuable to female earners. On the other hand, women
tend to receive higher yields due to less continuous coverage. The point here Is simply
that women fare better than men due to the mortality factor, other things being equal..
~` This assessment abstracts from the fact that early starters may tend to have lower
incomes and greater unemployment and thereby receive favorable treatment due to other
features of the system. The point is that an early start, other things equal, yields unfavor-
able treatment.
PAGENO="0135"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART iii 129
gram. First, consider the aggregate or overall yield to participants
as a whole. No explicit estimates hav.e been made of this aggregate
yield, but a glance at table 5 suggests that it is probably on the order
of 4 percent.~ This rate of return is not inconsistent with the implica-
tion of Aaron's simple model.49 His analysis, like the present one
assumes a fixed exponential growth rate, benefits keeping~ pace with
earnings and pay-as-you-go; however, he adds the further simplifying
assumptions that population grows exponentially and the active and
retired population remain in fixed proportion. Under these conditions
he establishes that the approximate condition for a break-even tax/
benefit ratio of unity is that the real rate of interest equals the sum
of the growth rates of per capita earnings and population. Putting
the earnings growth rate at 2.5 percent and assuming a growth rate
in the work force of 1.3-1.7 percent,5° the Aaron model would also
imply an overall real yield on contributions of around 4 percent.
This provides rough confirmation of the more detailed analysis above,
which took into account demograhpic projections. The empirical re-
sults for specific earner categories, displayed in chart 2, are also
roughly consistent with Aaron's basic relationship.
It is not easy to evaluate an overall projected rate of return on social
security contributions of 4 percent. It has been suggested via chart I
that this yield is very attractive compared to past experience with fixed
dollar claims; it would probably also look good in comparison with the
real yield on an installment purchase of a private insurance annuity.
However, these are all dwarfed by past long-run yields on equity. It is
even more difficult to evaluate the projected 2.5-percent earnings
growth rate and 1.5-percent work force growth rate which are funda-
mental to the 4-percent projection. In any case, it should first be ac-
knowledged that a comparison of the 4-percent projection with the
yield on equity is artificial in some respects. A public retirement scheme
comparable to such a private plan as that developed by the Teachers'
Insurance and Annuity Association, which provides for equity invest-
ment,51 is not feasible under a pay-as-you-go system. The present active
population would not only have to finance pensions for the currently
retired, but also would contribute to a mammoth equity trust fund.
Furthermore, there is no reason to believe the high real yields earned
on equity in the past would be impervious to the large new demand for
securities which would be generated. The bidding up of price-earnings
ratios (while cutting dividend rates) would probably yield real capital
gains at the outset, but a highly unstable situation would be in prospect
as selling of equities by the retired population began to offset buying on
behalf of earners.
As a substantial improvement on the past yields on fixed claims a
4-percent real return under a pay-as-you-go social security program
48 This rough approximation compromises midway between the two growth rates but
weighs heavily the results for starting age iS and beneficiaries not eligible for wife's
benefits.
49llenry Aaron, op. cit., pp. 371-74.
50 This is the range of growth rates in the low-cost and high-cost projections by the Social
Security Administration, for the Intervals 19G5-2000 and 1965-2025, Actuarial Study
No. 63, op. cit., p. 24.
~ As of Jan. 1, i967~ participants in TIAA were permitted to allocate up to 75 percent
of contributions in their name to the college retirement equity fund.
PAGENO="0136"
130 OLD AGE LN:OOME ASSURANCE-PART III
seems tolerable for provision of the basic retirement floor. This avoids
the uncertainties connected with a funded equity program and permits
retention of some generally acceptable redistributive features not like-
ly to survive the more precise individual earmarking to be expected
under funding. On the other hand the larger this compulsory saving
under social security the less earners will be able to invest privately in
mutual funds or other devices for periodic investment in higher yield-
ing equity capital. This consideration is at least relevant to determina-
tion of the optimum size of the social security program.
It is essential to stress, also, that the 4-percent yield itself is hardly a
riskless proposition. Aside from the fallible growth rate projections,
there is not at present any guarantee that benefits will keep pace with
earnings as postulated in the present model. The social insurance pack-
age would look more attractive if the taxpaying population were guar-
anteed that the future earners would pay enough to allow their retire-
ment income to keep pace. In the absence of such assurances, younger
workers are likely to be more impressed by Cohn Campbell's analysis
of existing and proposed tax and benefit schedules than by the hypo-
thetical projections of the model discussed here. The raw deals he por-
trays cannot be ruled out without a public commitment to tie current
benefits to current earnings indefinitely. Without such guarantees con-
tinued grumbling by younger workers can be expected.
The lack of intergenerational contractual obligations is not the
only ground for discontent on the part of social security taxpayers,
however. Although there is a modest degree of progression in the
yield-earnings relationship, the yields at the low end of the income
scale are probably highly unattractive to the poor. Low-income
families frequently choose, or a.re compelled, to borrow at very high
interest rates. It is, therefore, difficult to justify forcing them to save,
even at a real interest rate of 7 percent under social security; they may
at the same time (and in part as a consequence) be borrowing at 36
percent or more. In the context of a war against poverty it is an
ano~aly that a 10~percen~ combined ernDloyer-em~ployee payroll tax
is collected on a $2,500 income of a family of four even though this
family is recognized as incapable of paying any income tax. The
payroll t.ax is regressive because of the earnings ceiling and especially
burdensome to the working poor who get little offsetting help from
welfare. Whatever the ultimate payoff at age 65, the magnitude of
this compulsory saving can hardly be regarded as trivial by workers
living in an income range we have defined as poverty.
It seems appropriate to accept as a working hypothesis that the
young poor family discounts its projected retirement income at a very
high rate. A 6 or 7 percent ultimate real yield on the 10-percent
contribution paid by the young $2,500 earner may sound attractive to
some policvmak~rs, but who wouTd ipresume to call this worker a
profligate glutton if he would rather have the 10 percent row?
The import of this reasoning is not that participation in the social
s~curitv program should he made voluntary: this would have the
virtually certain result that many people would reach retirement age
with few resources and poor prospects. Rather, the heavy and re-
PAGENO="0137"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 131
gressive burden of the present payroll tax structure on the working
poor deserves recognition and alleviation. Despite the durability
of the "insurance pr1nciple" the present tax-benefit package is already
progressive and can be made more so by reforming the payroll tax.
One proposal already receiving attention calls for financing part of
the social security program out of general revenues. However, this
would not eliminate the taxation of poor families. This could be
accomplished by a more far-reaching measure which would allow the
payroll tax to be credited against the income tax and include refunds
in cases in which the payroll tax was the larger. As a more modest
alternative the payroll tax itself could be graduated. An attractive
and less far-reaching reform aimed simply at ending this taxation of
the poor would be institution of exemptions under the payroll tax.
Appropriate exemptions would be those implied by the currently
reigning definition of poverty. Some other countries have already
moved a step in this direction by including a taxable floor in addition
to a ceiling. The exemption device would be more equitable because
of its allowance for family size and structure.
Since consideration is already being given to raising the taxable
ceiling, this would seem an ideal time to introduce exemptions. Part
of the loss in revenue due to exemptions could be recouped by a higher
ceiling and the rest by a higher rate on the reduced base. Exemption
each year of some portion of everyone's income from the tax base
used in computing the tax on both employees and employers would
eliminate a substantial tax on people we have already designated as
poor, even before they pay the tax. It would even make the effective
tax rate mildly progressive among incomes below the taxable maxi-
mum. It is true that this policy would move social security financing
somewhat further away from the "contributory principle" long advo-
cated by social security specialists. However, the connection between
individual payments and benefits is already extremely tenuous in the
present system, and this does not appear to have weakened the pro-
gram. The main advantages claimed for the contributory principle
can be achieved simply by keeping aggregate payments abreast of
aggregate benefits.
The present system already recognizes that some covered workers
should not be taxed at all during `a given year. A worker unemployed
through disability or otherwise for an entire year pays no tax, but
will ordinarily lose no retirement benefits. The exemption device
would simply extend the exemption level from zero income to the
poverty level. In deference to the "contributory principle," it might
be desirable to retain a token contribution in the exemption range,
but at a rate more like 1 percent than the current 10 percent. In `any
case the main point is that families found to be in poverty should not
be forced to contribute substantially even though their projected
return under social security may appear attractive to others more
fortunately situated in the income distribution.
In conclusion it should be reiterated that the projected yields, re-
ported above, are based on an abstract model of earnings and benefit
growth that is no more than a rough approximation of past reality.
If the model and the official demographic projections are fairly realis-
PAGENO="0138"
132 OLD AGE llc~COME ASSURANCE-PART III
tic, new contributors will, in the aggregate, get neither a very good
"buy" nor a very bad one, but will fare moderately well. The evaiua.-
tion of the ~redistributive features of the system is more subjective
and depends upon whether one thinks in terms of lifetime rates of
return, or separate tax and benefit structures. From either viewpoint,
however, a guarantee that benefits will keep pace with earnings, and
the alleviation of the burden of the payroll tax on the poor would
contribute to making social security a substantially more attractive
institution.
PAGENO="0139"
ON THE OPTIMAL MIX OF SOCIAL INSURANCE
PAYMENTS
BY DAVID DONALDSON*
1. I~moirnc~rio~
Social insurance (and transfer) payments can be made in several
different ways. They can be simple cash payments (such as old age pen-
sions), payments in kind (medical care and job retraining programs),
subsidies on specific goods (food stamp programs and bus fare sub-
sidies) and payments in real terms, adjusted for unforeseen price level
changes (the Canada pension plan).
This note attempts to provide a partial discussion of the desir-
ability of these kinds of payments in different situations. Sociological
considerations are not included, though it is recognized that they may
be very important. Furthermore, paternalistic arguments are ruled out,
and consistent preferences by families are assumed.
No distinction is made here between social insurance and transfer
payments. Virtually all the payments that we call transfers are also a
form of social insurance. Relief payments provide insurance against
income loss; payments to the blind and disabled provide insurance for
those born normal, and insurance for all parents. Different public pro-
grams will have different effects, however, on the distribution of life-
time income.
2. INSURANCE IN TIlE PERFECT MARKET
When economists admit uncertainty into their models, the number
of markets necessary to guarantee "optimality" 1 expands enormously.
Instead of a market for each good in each period of time and the
capital market, additional insurance markets that cover every possible
risk and uncertainty that people encounter are necessary. Insurance
contracts would not only be against monetary losses but would provide
cash payments on the occurrence of any uncertain event. If provision
of the insurance market has a real cost in economic resources, then
insurance should not cover all uncertainties, but only the ones in which
the "benefit" exceeds the cost.2
The insurance market is, however, very poorly developed. This can
be explained by several things, among them incentive effects of insur-
ance (see below), lack of information available to insurance companies
*professor, University of British Columbia, Vancouver, B.C., Canada.
1 By "optimality" we mean a Pareto optimum-a situation where a given family can
be made better off only at the expense of others. There are many optimal situations, corre-
sponding roughly to d~tTerent distributions of lifetime income.
2 For a more detailed discussion of these assertions see references 1, 2, 3, and 4.
133
PAGENO="0140"
134 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
and individuals, the pooling of unequal risks, and economies of scale
in group insurance. Some of this is offset by the provision of social
insurance in areas where the market fails.
3. THE EFFECTS OF DIFFERENT TYPES OF PAYMENT IN THE PERFECT
MARKET
In the perfect market, described above, payments made as cash,
kind, or subsidy will have no difference whatever on the family receiv-
ing it if the family is consistent in its preferences. The assumption
of the perfect market allows anyone to sell anything received in kind
at the going market price; consequently, the payments in kind or
subsidies have no different effect from cash payments. Even in the case
of compulsory insurance for old age there will be no effect other than
a change in lifetime income. Any purchase of insurance for old age
can be "sold back" at the market price, and the oniy effect of the plan
will be a redistribution of income resulting from the difference
between market and government prices. The way in which old-age
insurance can, be "sold back" is as follows: Life insured loans are made
for the market value of the premiums; if the individual dies before
retirement, there is no debt.; if lie retires, his pension will just pay
off the loans.
It is obvious, therefore, that policy decisions with regard to sub-
sidies, or payments in kind must take imperfections into account
explicitly. In the normal world opportunities for "selling ba.ck" either
do not exist at all, as in the ca.se of personal services such as medical
care, or exist only at a lower price than the buying price because of
the costs of providing insurance and other markets. In these cases
there will be a great deal of difference in final consumption patterns,
depending on the mix of the various types of payments.
4. INCENTIvE EFFECTS
Insurance contracts may carry with them incentives that change
the behavior of those insured so that the expected gain is increa~ed.
For example, fire insurance provides an incentive to carelessness and
arson; divorce insurance would, if provided, tend to increase the
divorce rate of those insured; unemployment insurance may affect
the effort expended on finding a new job.
These have the effect of either making a given insurance market
smaller or eliminating it altogether. Consequently, there is a good
argument, in these cases for social intervention. Social insurance can-
not, however, merely provide insurance with cash benefits, copying
the private sector. The incentive effects do not disappear. It can,
however, provide or subsidize benefits in kind (usually services) that
cannot easily be sold by the recipients, and that compensate for the
incentive effects of providing the insurance. Examples of social insur-
t~Pce of this kind are job retraining programs for young and old,
marriage counseling services, and training programs for the blind
`and disabled.
Incentive effect.s of a slightly different kind are present in old-aae
pension plans in the United States and Canada and in many relief
PAGENO="0141"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 135
programs for the indigent. In early retirement and in almost all relief
programs, earning income reduces the amount of the payment from
the Government. This provides an incentive against working which
may lead to large social losses, especially in the case of younger people
on relief. The effect is easily eliminated in the old-age case: part of the
pension can be postponed until actual retirement and then increased
over the usual amount to compensate the working old person for the
earlier loss. In the case of relief payments, the solution is not so easy.
Some work has been done on the possibility of incorporating relief and
other payments into the tax system (with negative income taxes being
"paid" by some), and this holds a great deal of promise for solving this
problem.3
5. Cos~s OF MARKET AND SOCIAL INSURANCE
In the perfect market, as shown above, heither the form of insurance
payments nor the timing will affect the rational consumer at all as long
as the market value ~ of his lifetime income is not affected. This the-
orem depends, however, on the assumption that goods `and services can
be resold, and that all market transactions are costless. In fact, how-
ever, market transactions are not costless, and if the Government tries
to minimize these costs, it will find itself providing insurance, and may
find itself making payments in kind, when it wants to change the
distribution of income. If people do buy insurance for old age, disa-
bility, sickness, and so on, Government transfers should (at least in,
part) be provided in transfers to the old, disabled, and sick. Further-
more, if most sick and disabled people want to purchase medical care,
and if purchases of medical care have real costs (purchasers' as well
as administration costs), medical care should be provided directly if
these costs can be substantially reduced without affecting quality.
6. UNcERTAINTY ABOUT PRICES
The optimnality theorems discussed in section 2 assume tha,t all
future prices are known. If they are not, then the appropriate way to
provide general insurance for old age is to provide a real income; that
is, to adjust the benefits year by year for changes in the consumer
price level. This is now being done by the Canada pension plan. A
companion policy to that one would be provision of Government bonds
in real terms. These would be of direct benefit to savers who want in-
surance `against inflation, and to the private insurance market which
could offer many contacts in real terms.
Medical care provided by insurance (rather than cash payments in
the event of sickness) is also required by these considerations. Medical
prices may change independently of general prices, and consequently,
a good way to provide sickness insurance in real terms is to provide
either the care itself or to guarantee payment (whatever it is) for the
necessary care.
`See reference 5.
When dealing with lifetime Income In an uncertain world, it Is necessary~ to use a slightly
different concept of lifetime income. Normally we use present value, but in uncertain con-
ditlons. uncertain incomes are converted to a present value by using prices of insurance
contracts Instead of simple bonds.
PAGENO="0142"
136 OLD AGE INOOME ASSTJRANCE-PART III
7. OTHER CONSIDERATIONS
Some things that receivers of social insurance payments want have
public-good aspects. A good example of this is social centers for the
aged. These should, therefore, be provided free or subsidized.
An interesting argument for providing goods in kind as benefits of
social insurance programs applies to the case of social insurance di-
rected at children and dependent wives. Since husbands cannot always
be counted on to act in the interest of the rest of their families, benefits
provided in kind which cannot be sold are appropriate in these cases.
School lunch and food stamp programs are obvious examples.
8. CoNcr~usIoN
It is clear from the above discussion that there are a great many
cases when the economist's rule that cash is best breaks down, even
under his usual assumptions of nonpaternalism and consistent prefer-
ences. The reason for this is the fact of great and important imper-
fections in the insurance market.
REFERENCES
1. Arrow, Kenneth J., "The Role of Securities in the Optional Allocation of
Risk-Bearing", Review of Economic studies, vol. 31, 1963-64, pp. 91-96.
2. , "Uncertainty and the Economics of Medical Care", American
Economic Review, vol. 53, 1963, pp. 941-973.
3. Lees, D. S., and Rice, R. 0., "Uncertainty and the Economics of Medical Care:
Comment", American Economic Review, vol. 55, 1965, pp. 140-154.
4. Debreu, G~, Theory of Values, New York, 1959.
5. Green, C., Negative Taxes and the Poverty Problem, the Brookings Institu-
tion, Washington, 1967.
PAGENO="0143"
MATHEMATICAL APPROACHES TO THE MACROECO-
NOMICS AND PLANNING OF OLD-AGE PENSION SYSTEMS
BY RICHARD D. YOUNG and GASTON V. RIMLINGER*
I. INTRODUCTION
The American social security system has become a vast undertaking
which affects the present or fu'ture welfare of nearly every citizen. By
the end of 165 over 163 million people had been issued social secui~ty
account numbers. Today OASDHI is paying benefits to some 23
million people and collecting contributions from about 70 million
employees and self-employed persons. Most striking is the fact that
over the last 15 years income and expenditures of social insurance
have risen over twice `as fast as gross national product.1 Macroeco-
nomic magnitudes of this order inevitably raise questions about the
long-run stability of the system. It is obvious, for example, that social
insurance expenditures cannot indefinitely increase faster than the
gross national product. Much less obvious, however, is the rate of
benefit increase that can be sustained in the long run and the char-
acteristics of a plan consistent with this rate. The objective of this
paper is to work out mathematical approaches that may assist social
security planners in dealing with such problems in a rigorous analytical
manner.
The question of permanently sustainable increases, or in a more
general sense of permanently sustainable rates of benefits, `is highly
important because of its obvious policy implications. It involves both
micro and macro economic issues. The micro issue has `to do with the
proportion of current income individuals are willing to forgo for
the sake `of future pensions. In this paper we will not b~ able to deal
with this issue.2 The macroeconomic problem is concerned with the
rates `of benefit and contribution that `are consistent with such macro
variables as the growth of national `income and of the work force.
We `are primarily `concerned with th'is bundle `of problems.
One aspe'ct `of `these problem's involves the solvency and burden of
social security. Since `the inception of the social insurance program,
critics have raised doubts in the popular mind `about its solvency and
issued ominous warnings `about its ultimate burden. There seems to
be implicit in such warnings the view that later generations will bear
* Rice University. This research was supported by the National Science Foun-
dation under grant No. NSF GU-1153.
We wish to acknowledge and express our thanks for the benefit of discussions
with Profs. Stanley Besen, Ru'i de Figueiredo, Ferdinand Levy, and David
Nissen on topics related to the content of this paper.
1 For data, see Social Security Bulletin, Annual Statistical Supplement, 1965.
2 For a theoretical treatment of this problem, see Gaston V. Rimlinger, "A Theoretical
Integration of Wages and `Social Insurance," Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. LXXVII,
August 1963, pp. 470-484.
137
PAGENO="0144"
138 OLD AGE INCOME ASSTJR.ANCE-PART III
a heavier contribution burden in relation to benefits than earlier gen-
erations. Students of social insurance answer the question about sol-
vency by pointing out that in a. public insurance program there is no
need to provide actuarial reserves against future contingencies. These
are met from future income. But this means that the relationship
between contingent benefits and future taxable income is of crucial
importance. This relationship leads directly to the question of benefit
versus burden for succeeding generations.
We sha.ll assume that in order to be sustainable, the rates of con-
tribution and benefit must not only adequately meet the needs of the
present generation of beneficiaries, but that they must also meet the
needs of each succeeding generation, and at the same time they must
avoid allowing one generation to become a net burden on another.
In other words, we need to devise an old-age pension plan that. meets
the criteria of both social adequacy and intergenerational equity.
We use this concept of equity to mean that each generation is en-
titled to benefits equal to the interest compounded value of its own
contributions.~ The benefit increases which are consistent with this
plan, assuming they are also consistent with wage-pension preferences,
can be considered sustainable increases.
We need to recognize at the outset the likelihood of incompatibility
of our dual criteria, of social adequacy and intergenerational equity.
Only in an ideal world with continuous and invariant changes is there
some assurance of compatibility, but not in a world subject to fluc-
tuations in earning and employment levels. To deal with the uneven
empirical environment our best alternative is to work out a plan which
enables us to minimize deviation from established criteria. In this
paper we approach this problem in two steps. First, we develop a math-
ematical model that. generates sustainable rates on the assumption that
there is no conflict between social adequacy and intergenerational
equity. Second, we introduce a linear programing model which enables
us to minimize the disutility stemming from shortrun inconsistency
between the two criteria. In section V we shall argue that planning
based on the linear programing model establishes, among other benefits,
an improved medium for the application of the research efforts of
social scientists to the planning problems of the social security system.
Before turning to these models, we shall present, in the following sec-
tion, the basic features of our pension plan and the main assumptions
of the analysis. For the sake of analytical simplicity we have ab-
st.racted from many aspects of the real world, and we have deviated
in important respects from the structure of the existing old-age pension
system. These abstractions a.nd deviations, however, do not affect the
general theoretical objectives of this analysis.
II. S~'irncrun~ OF THE PENSION PLAN
Our mathematical models are restricted to old-age pension plans.
We deal only with primary beneficiaries and do not take into account
their dependents. Nor are we directly concerned with survivorship
The conflict between equity and social adequacy can exist on both intragenerational
and intergenerational levels, we do not deal with ifltragenerational (intracohort) redje-
tributlons of benefits, which can be treated separately from questions of intergenerational
redistribution and equity.
PAGENO="0145"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART ill 139
benefits for widows, orphans, or other dependents. The plan analyzed
below is financed completely from contributions, without any govern-
mental subsidies. All contributions are credited to particular workers
and serve as the basis for benefit calculations. We assume that these
contributions represent the burden of the worker, even though em-
ployers may pay part of them. The contribution is calculated as a
percentage of his total wage or salary. At any point of time this per-
centage is the same for all covered individuals, but it may increase or
decrease over time. Benefits are treated in a special way in our model
in that they are paythle in a lump sum at the point of retirement. We
make this assumption for analytical purposes. This lump sum can
readily be translated into a paid-up annuity and actual payment can
be made in the form of monthly benefits, or in any other way. We
shall not, however, concern ourselves with this feature.
The eligibility conditions of our plan are very sinTiple. An individual
becomes entitled to benefits after he has spent a specified number of
years, g years to be exact, in covered employment. It is assumed that
the entire work force is occupied in covered employment and that all
workers retire as soon as they become eligible. Another assumption
we make is that there are no deaths during the working span, so
that all workers who earn benefits could collect all of their benefits,
regardless of how long they live after retirement.
Our analysis is concerned with a plan that has been in existence
long enough to be fully matured, meaning that all current beneficiaries
have contributed over g years. We focus our attention on the cohort
of individuals entering the system at a given point or period of time.
For the sake of convenience we may think of the cohort as representing
all individuals entering the system in a given year, although in the
limiting case the entry time interval could be reduced so that cohorts
represented single individuals. After g years, all individuals in a
cohort retire and become entitled to a pension based on previous con-
tributions. The pension system makes a lump-sum payment to the en-
tire cohort. Then the payment is presumably converted into annuity
income and other benefits that are distributed among members of the
cohort. This conversion of the lump-sum payment into individual
benefits may well invlove intracohort redistribution designed to insure
that the minin'ium retirement income in the cohort meets social ade-
quacy criteria. We shall not examine the details of this redistribution.
In our model all members of a cohort stay employed continuously once
they have entered covered employment. This enables us to treat each
cohort as a unit for contribution and benefit calculation.
In the mathematical formulation of our pension system there are two
sets of variables which have to be solved for (1) the schedu'e of tax
rates, and (2) the schedule of lump-sum benefit payments due each
cohort at retirement. These variables are to be determined so that they
satisfy the objectives of the social security system. In our mathemati-
cal models, these objectives, or criteria, take on the nature of con-
straints. Our main general constraints are the following:
A. Social adeq~iacy.-Beriefit levels should be sufficient to provide
retirement income that is no lower than a specified minimum.
B. Eqvit~.-Tlie relationship between contributions and benefits
should be compatible with accepted standards of social justice. This
83-200-67-pt. 3-1O
PAGENO="0146"
140 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
criterion is susceptible to various interpretations. As indicated earlier,
we use it to mean benefits of each cohort are equal to its contributions
plus interest.
C. Solvency.-The system has to generate sufficient contributions to
pay all benefits and administrative costs when these are due. It does
not accumulate reserves or incur debts in the long run.
D. Administrative simplieity.-Contributions and benefits should
be easy to understand, compute, and predict.
E. Stability.-The contribution rates should be sustainable in the
long run, which means that the system should not require or imply a
tax rate that increases beyond reasonable limits a.t any future time.
Certain other assumptions and characteristics of our models may be
stated at this point. We take the macroeconomic variables, such as the
growth of income and of population as given, and we do not take into
account any impact of social security on these variables. Our models
are deterministic in the sense that all relevant aspects of the future are
assumed to be known except benefits a.nd contributions.
III. A MATHEMATICAL MODEL OF A PERMANENTLY
SEti-SUsTAINING SYsTEM
In this section we develop a continuous model of a social security
system. Although this model has serious limitations, it leads to useful
insights and hypotheses on the nature of the set of solutions to our
problem of deriving a social security system tha.t satisfies the con-
straints A through E.
We assume the following data are given:
g~ The working lifetime.
w(t,n) The wage rate at time t for workers that have been in the
work force for n time units. This function is defined and
continuous for all t»= 0 and all n in the interval O«=n«=g.
D(t) = The rate of entry into the work force at time t. This func-
tion is defined and continuous for all t »= 0.
a~An interest rate used to relate social security contributions
to benefits.
The requirements B, C, and D are implemented as follows:
B. Equity.-We set the lump-sum payment to the cohort that retires
at time t equal to the total contribution made by this cohort during its
working lifetime plus interest continuously compounded at the rate a.
C. Solvene?,.-We require that the total (tax) revenue of the social
security system at time t be equal to the lump-sum benefit paid to the
cohort that retires at time t.
D. Administrative simpiicity.~We require that the social security
tax rate at time t, which we define as r(t), be charged against all in-
come from work at time t.
These assumptions, together with specified initial conditions are
enough to determine the social security tax rate r(t) for all ~»=g. We
note the specific absence of the social adequacy condition among those
above that are sufficient to determine the tax rate schedule r ( t). We
note also that the tax rate schedule r(t) is sufficient, together with the
equity condition, to determine the schedule of lurrrp-sum benefit
payments.
PAGENO="0147"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART in 141
We shall now develop the mathematical model.'
The total income of the social security system at time t (for t »= 0)
is given by
w(t,x)D(t-x)r(t)dx. (3.1)
The lump-sum payment due the cohort that retires at time t is (for
t »= g) given by
5 w(t-g+x,x)D(t-g)r(t-g+x)e°~dx. (3.2)
We assume (3.1) and (3.2) are equal for each t »=g. Thus,
D(t_g)5 w(t-g+x,x)r(t-g+x)e~~dx
(3.3)
I w(t,x)D(t-x)dx
Jo
From (3.) it is apparent that the tax r(t) is defined in terms of the tax
rates r(t-k) where Oy+ir then K-ir>0. If this inequality holds
then RLe~_T)t will increase exponentially and eventually surpass any
finite upper limit. Since r(t) »=RLe~'~'~t a>y+ir implies that r(t) will
increase without bound. Hence, a>y+ir is inconsistent with the
stability constraint.
By a symmetric argument it is apparent that if ag, the working lifetime.
1 The final specification of the weights C1,C2 . . c,, is psychologically easier and procedurally much more
complex than our discussion here suggests. contrary to appearance, the values of C1,C2 . c,, can be spec-
ified without forcing the decisionmaker into an a priori specification of his utility function over the variables
afl,,. And the line3r form of Z is less restrictive than it appears. Specifying the parameters c~
that define Z amounts to provisionally specifying a tangent hyperplane to an indifference surface rather
than the surface itself. A sequence of such provisional specifications leads to final specification of the tangent
hyperplane at a utility maximizing point. For details see Bertil NSslund, "Decisions Under Risk (Eco-
nomic Applications of Chance-Constrained Programing)," doctoral dissertation, Carnegie Institute of
Technology, November 1964.
PAGENO="0155"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 149
SOLVENCY CONSTRAINTS
r(t)±y(t,k)=V(t), (t=1, 2, . . . T). (4.4)
SOCIAL ADEQUACY CONSTRAINTS
For each t, 1 ~ t «= T, we require
V(t)(»=IV(t). (4.5)
The simplicity of this set of constraints is somewhat deceptive. N(t)
is defined as the minimum lump-sum benefit sufficient to support
socially adequate retirement income for all members of the cohort at
time t. Thus N(t) is the result of solving an actuarial problem that is
constrained by a given policy regarding redistribution within the
cohort.
EQUITY CONSTRAINTS
Because the benefits paid in the first g -1 years of the timespan
from year 1 to year T may involve obligations that were present at
the beginning Qf t~he timespan, we shall treat these years separately.
We let 0(1, x), (`x =1, 2, . . . , g), represent an array of given con-
stants that individually denote the present value at the beginning of
year 1 of the financial obligation of the pension system to the cohort
that is in its xth year in the work force during year 1. For each t,
1«=t«=g-1 we require
V(t)»=O(1, g-t+1)at+~y(k, g-t+k)at~r(k). (4.6)
The constant a used in (4.6) has, of course, the role of an interest
rate. The determination of this rate is clearly a matter of social policy.
The results of section III, as well as more general considerations,
would suggest setting a at the percentage growth rate of total wage
income.
For the cohorts that enter the work force during the timespan of
our problem, we require that V(t) should be no less than total con-
tributions with interest. Thus, for each t, g«=t~ T, we require,
V(t)»=~y(t-g+k, k)a~r(t-g+k). (4.7)
TERMINAL CONDITION CONSTRAINT
The terminal condition constraint simply sets an upper limit on the
present value at time T of payments to the social security system from
cohorts that will retire after time T. This constraint represents the
stability requirement in a limited sense. The constraint is a barrier to
providing social security benefits in the present that are only consistent
with increasing tax rates in the future or with a failure to honor equity
constraints in the future.
PAGENO="0156"
150 OLD AGE fl~COME ASSURANCE-PART III
Defining
x-l
0(T, x)=~y(T-1c, x_k)akr(T_k), (x=1, 2, . . . , g-1) (4.8)
k~O
as the obligation of the system to the cohort that is in its xth year in
the work force at time T, the total unredeemed obligation at time T is
given by
c-i
0(T)=~O(T, x). (4.9)
x=O
Our constraint is simply
0(T)«=H. (4.10)
This raises two questions:
(i) How is H determined?
(ii) How does this constraint balance the interests of those that
retire before and after year T?
Before answering these questions we shall note that without any
constraint such as (4.10) the likely result would be a solution implying
an unjustifiably large 0(T), since the benefits derived from a large
0(T) would be enjoyed before T, within the scope of the problem,
while the costs of redeeming the debt 0(T) would be borne after T,
beyond the horizon of the problem. Thus we have bounded 0~T)
from above.
Analysis of the calculus model indicates that 0(T) grows at the
percentage rate a. This is consistent with longrun stability of the
social security tax rate, if and only if a is equal to the percentage
growth rate of total wage income. Thus we would recommend setting
H=KaT (4.11)
where K is the obligation of the system at t= 1; i.e.,
K=~0(1,x)=0(1). (4.12)
Without undertaking an analysis that is beyond the scope of this
paper, we cannot make definitive claims for (4.11) and (4.12) as a
means of preserving intergenerational equity. The idea behind (4.10),
(4.11), and (4.12) is that a unique consta.nt tax rate r, is consistent
with the obligtion 0(1) at the beginning of the period; and we
assume that r, is normative in this sense: an obligation 0 (T) at T,
that is consistent with r, represents an optimal balancing of the inter-
ests of those that retire before and after T. WTe emphasize again that
determination of an optimal longrun average rate v, or an optimal
time path T(t) is a problem we do not attempt to solve here.. And
determination of appropriate terminah conditions must follow from
the explicit or implicit solution of such a. problem. Hence. our terminal
constraint is only concitionalli- normative.'
`The analysis of the appendix to see. III is relevant here in two respects. First, the gen-
eral nature of the connection between the obligation at t, 0(t), and a tax rate r for suc-
ceeding periods is explored there. Second. the results of that section suggest that (expo-
nential) weights might be appropriately included on the right side of (4.9).
PAGENO="0157"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 151
THE OBJECTIVE FUNCTION
We define the slack and artificial variables as follows:
w~(t) EE~A measure of violation of the solvency constraint (4.4) for
period t. w1(t) is positive if the social security tax yield in year
t is less than V(t).
s2(t) A measure of surplus fulfillment of the social adequacy con-
straint (4.5) for period t.
w2(t) ~A measure of violation of the social adequacy constraint (4.5)
for period t.
~3(t) A measure of surplus fulfillment of the individual equity con-
straint (4.6) or (4.7) for period t.
w3(t) ~A measure of violation of the individual equity constraint (4.6)
or (4.7) for period t.
A measure of surplus fulfillment of the terminal constraint
(4.10).
W4A measure of violation of the terminal constraint (4.10).
We next define c1(t) as a measure of the cost associated with a unit of
w2(t) where i= 1, 2, 3, and t= 1, 2, . . ., T. We define c4 analogously.
Our objective function is: Minimize
3 T
Z=c4w4+~~c1(t)w~(t).
i=1 ~=1
SUMMARY STATEMENT OF THE PROBLEM
The entire problem can be stated as follows: Minimize
3 T
Z= c4w4+ ~~c1(t)w~(t)
i=1 t=1
subject to
V(t)»=0 (t=1 . . . . T)
r(t)»=0 (t=1 . . . . T)
w1(t) »=0 (i=1, 2, 3; t=1 . . . . T)
s~(t) »=0 (i=2, 3; t=1 . . . . T)
(t=1 . . . . T)
V(t) -s2(t) +w2(t) =N(t) (t= 1 . . . . T)
V(t)-~[y(k,g-t+k)at~r(k) -s3(t) +w3(t)
=O(1,g-t+1)at(t=1, 2, . . . g-1)
V(t) -~[y(t-g+k,k)a~]r(t-g+k) -s3(t) +w3(t)
=0(t=g,g+1 . . . T)
g-lx-1
~>J~{y(T-k,x-k)air(T-k) +s4-o,4=H
x=lk=o
PAGENO="0158"
152 OLD AGE INCOME ASSTJRANCE-PART III
COMMENT AND EXTENSIONS
The model we have formulated is meant to demonstrate the possi-
bility of formulation of our social security planning problem as a
linear program. Except for mtroduction of the social adequacy con-
straints (4.5), we have aimed at keeping the model as simple and as
analogous to the calculus model as possible. In this development we
have suppressed many possible elaborations. We now list a few of
the possible modifications and refinements that can be added to the
linear programing model.
1. The tax rates may be varied between cohorts in the same year.
This would lead to an expanded set of variables r(t,x) (t= 1 . . .
x=1 . . . . g). It appears likely that such exjansion of the set of varia-
bles would entail additional constraints limiting the variability of
social security tax rates. It also appears likely that allowing a more
varied tax rate structure would reduce violation of the other con-
straints. It is also possible, and possibly desirable., to constrain the
variability of tax rates over time in a model in which the tax rate
only varies with time.
2. The solvency constraint can (and should) be relaxed to permit
temporary surpluses and deficits. This can be accomplished easily
within the linear programing framework.
3. The equity relation can be expressed in a variety of forms. For
example, the retirement benefit can be related to average income, aver-
age income over the last k years in the work force, or average income
over the k years of highest wages. Linear programing will accommo-
date all these possibilities.
We believe, however, that relating benefits to total interest-weighted
payments has several advantages in addition to those cited in section
III. It permits straightforward comparison of social security with
other means of providing for retirement income, and it permits the
development of simple relations between the social security interest
rate and natural economic and demographic parameters.
A related use of the linear programing model is to analyze and coin-
pare various benefit formulas (such as, for example, those mentioned
above) with the interest-weighted contributions under various assump-
tions as to the growth of wages and the work force.
4. It is possible to include constraints establishing an upper limit
on the total individual contribution to the social security system and!
or an upper limit on the social security tax rate.
5. The model might be expanded to include detailed representation
and control of the process of providing annuity income to the retired
population.
6. In case it were possible to satisfy all constraints, our objective
function would not be a useful means of achieving a best schedule of
rates and benefits. This difficulty can be resolved by expanding the
objective function to include nonzero (and normadly negative) c5 co-
efficients corresponding to the slack variables, s~ (t), (i= 2, 3; t= 1,
...,T).
These coefficients could also be meaningfully introduced into the
c~bjective function in cases where some artificial variables are positive
in an optimal solution. For example~ it might be socially desirable to
have a larger terminal obligation 0 (T) than that permitted by (4.10).
PAGENO="0159"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 153
This could create the opportunity for surplus fulfillment of some
of the constraints (4.5), (4.6), (4.7). Deliberate violation of (4.10)
might occur if the constant tax rate r~ that is consistent with the initial
obligation 0(1), were considered too low in the long run. In this case
a higher terminal obligation than that established by (4.10) (and
(4.11) and (4.12)) would be justified.
A brief commentary is in order on the problem of specifying the
coefficients of the objective function. Relative values must be estab-
lished for running the system at a deficit, paying various cohorts less
than they earn and/or less than a socially adequate benefit, and for
creating a terminal obligation that implies a higher future tax rate.
Moreover, if higher future tax rates are acceptable, then windfall bene-
fits are available and their distribution over various cohorts depends on
the objective function coefficients assigned to the slack and artificial
variables and the paramater H that constrains the terminal obligation
0(T). The difficulty of establishing these coefficients is considerable;
but it should be emphasized that this intrinsic difficulty is merely spot.-
lighted-not created-by the linear programing formulation. In the
next section we shall offer further comment on the problems of param-
eter specification in the linear programing model.
The linear programing problem formulated here should involve
no serious computational difficulties for values of T even greater than
100. Some of the elaborations we have suggested might involve many
more va.riaJbles and constraints-but even then the computational out-
look is favorable. These more elaborate models, in common with the
simple model, have a special network structure; this means that
prospects would be excellent for finding or developing a special al-
gorithm capable of practical computation of very large problems. A
second potential benefit of this special structure is the possibility,
which we have nQt yet explored, for further analysis and interpreta-
tion of the social security planning problem by means of duality theory
of linear programing.
Hopefully we have indicated by these remarks that a range of for-
mulations exist for this problem and that more analysis will be re-
quired before definitive knowledge is available to outline the limits
and possibilities inherent in the social security mechanism.
V. CONCLUDING OBSERVATIONS
Our purpose here is to relate our analysis to a more general view of
the social security planning problem. This problem requires a practical
synthesis of complex empirical data and predictions, a balancing of
the interests `of present and future generations, and compliance with
underlying administrative and economic realities. While it is obvious
that theoretical work by economists, sociologists, statisticians, etc., can
be useful to the planner, the exact means' of applying such expertise
are less obvious. Basic reliance, of course, must always be placed on the
synthetic ability of the informed, intelligent planner. But, well defined,
systematic procedures that guarantee optimality, if appropriately used,
can certainly benefit the planning process. Such procedures are in-
creasingly beneficial if they explicitly `formalize the channels through
which empirical predicti'ons, value judgments, and theoretical results-
e.g., from economics-impinge on the final plan.
PAGENO="0160"
154 OLD AGE INCOME ASSIJRANCE-PART III
We contend that our linear programing model is just such a plan-
ning tool. It is directly useful a.s a~ rational, disciplined merc.haiiism for
detailed planning in terms of empirical data. and requirements. It has
immense indirect value because. it provides an ideal junction through
whichi general theory may be used to shape detailed and specific plans.
The linkage between theories and plans is through the parameters of
the linear programing model.
To expand on this point and relate it specifically to the analysis in
this paper we shall sketch juxtaposed, stereotyped "before and after"
views of the general planning process as altered by the use of linear
programing. Informal planning methods, however competently and
effectively employed, typically do not separate questions of fact, value,
and logical implication. For the outsider, at least, it is frequently dif-
ficult to distinguish analysis and intuition, objective and subjective
information, personal and general value judgments. This does not
mean that informal planning is necessarily chaotic or irrational; we
only contend that it is generally incomprehensible to outsiders and only
partially understood by many insiders. Moreover, planning efforts on
problems that involve considerable intrinsic complication are fre-
quently accomplished by circumscribing the problem to a point where
attention may be confined to a small manageable subset of the poten-
tia.lly relevant variables and relations.
Programing methods lead to several important changes as the
result of a new division of labor. Analytical manipulations are rele-
gated to a computer-executed algorithm. This greatly increases the
planners' ability to deal with large and complex problems. Freed from
the burden of analysis, the planners' judgment is focused on specifica-
tion of the parameters for the programing model. Thus, one large, com-
plex, and somewhat ill-defined problem is transformed into a* list of
individual, comparatively precise questions. Answering these questions,
by providing specific values for the parameters of the programing
model, supplies the essential information and judgments needed to
specify a plan.
The simplification of the planning problem and the shift of atten-
tion to parameter specification should have two important effects. A
more efficient allocation of the planners' effort. in estimating the im-
portant unknowns in the problem should result. A more portentous
result is that application of general theories (economic. statistical,
sociological, etc.) to the problems of parameter specification is quite
immediate, while the application of such theory in informal plan-
ning procedures is much less direct and obvious. Thus, by adopting
programing methods, the planners achieve significant gains in poten-
tial ac.cess to an immense reservoir of useful knowledge.
The parameters of the linear program model in section IV require
demographic and economic predictioiis, relative valuations on prov~d-
ing various cohorts smaller benefits than the interest-weighted value
of their contributions, relative valuations on providing various co-
horts a less than socially adequate retirement. benefit, and relative val-
uations on increases in the future tax rate. Problems of this sort can
be and have been dealt with by social scientists. It is particularly im-
portant to note that theory from the social sciences may not completely
determine a parameter but will frequently limit the range of a param-
PAGENO="0161"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 155
eter or will require that certain relations hold among the values of
several parameters. 1~esults of this form, while mysterious and un-
satisfactory to the layman who wants simple answers, can have tre-
inendous power in simplifying the problem of parameter specification.
We have provided in this paper a limited but hopefully instructive
example of the use of general mathematical models of social and eco-
nomic meChanisms to specify parameters in a planning model. It will
be recalled that the model of section 111, while quite simple and ab-
stract, did, nevertheless, yield useful restrictions on the form of the
equity constraint and on the value of in the linear programing model.
The continuous model was also useful in clarifying the issues involved
in specifying a limit on the terminal obligation, 0(T), in the linear
programing model. Thus we would stress the essential complemen-
tarity of the models developed in sections III and IV. The linear pro-
grarning model provides a means of planning and an explicitly sys-
tematic means of applying general theories to the planning' process.
The continuous model is a means of deducing restrictions on the param-
eters and structure of the linear programing planning model.
At present, parameter `specification would, in practice, have to be
accomplished under the dominant influence of informed, intelligent,
subjective judgment. With time, the accumulation of experience and
reliable theory should narrow the range of subjective `discretion and
decrease the expected impact of subject'ive error. We would emphasize
that the existence and use of a planning procedure that invites the
application of theory is critical to the evolutionary development of a
symbiosis of theory and practice.
General and abstract models, framed to elucidate essential charac-
teristics of a social security system, or one of the systems that interact
closely with the social security system, are thus seen to `be doubly useful:
they further general understanding and they can serve specific pur-
poses in social security planning. The model of `section III, while of
some use in both respects, is neither comprehensive nor essentially
novel. A fuller understanding of the social security problem requires
relaxation of the assumptions we have made to isolate a simple, tract-
able, initial `problem. Two more general problems are certainly ger-
mane. The first problem involves optimal schedules of tax rates and
benefits. Here it should be noted that the deduction of necessary and/or
sufficient characteristics of optimal schedules could be very useful in
constraining a planning model. The second problem arises from con-
sidering feedbacks of the social security system on the work force,
the working span and on output. It is plausible that definitive work
on these problems, and others related to the use of the social security
mechanism, would be stimulated by a social security planning opera-
tion that used mathematical programing methods.
83-200-67-------1 1
PAGENO="0162"
"EARLY RETIREMENT" TRENDS AND PENSION
ELIGIBILITY UNDER SOCIAL SECURITY
BY ~LEs II. SCHULZ*
The failure and/or inability of individuals in the past to prepare for
an ever-growing number of retirement years through personal or group
action has resulted in today's poverty stricken retired aged population.
There has now been accumulated enough reliable statistical informa-
tion to clearly demonstrate the existence of a relatively low economic
status for all but a small minority of the current U.S. aged population.
The situation is particularly bad for retired individuals and families
which must rely upon savings and various forms of nonwork income to
maintain their standard of living. Survey data for the United States
indicate that these resources are quite small for much of the popula-
tion currently retired.'
In recent years, however, significant changes regarding retirement
security have taken place in the United States. Improved and broad-
ened social security, mushrooming private pension plans, medicare,
and extended economic prosperity should provide better retirement
protection in the future. The question, therefore, arises: Will the
changes which have occurred and are occurring in the U.S. institu-
tional provisions for retirement security significantly improve the
economic circumstances of future generations of older people?
This paper will report on findings which indicate that the future
economic circumstances of retired persons relative to the rest of the
population will not be significantly improved. It will then discuss
the question of "early retirement" and the desirability of reducing the
social security eligibility age.
1. 5mrur~i~ THE RETIREMENT PROCESS
In order to investigate the future economic circumstances of the re-
tired aged population, a simulation rnod& has been constructed to in-
corporate and represent the essential features of the major private and
public pension systems existing in the United States. In addition, the
model has been designed to take into account relationships among
important demographic and work force variables influencing the pen-
sion position and savings behavior of individuals in the economy.
Various methodological tecimiques have been used by researchers for
simulating or representing reality.2 The technique used in conjunction
with the model cited above is stochastic simulation-stochastic in the
°Assistant professor of economics, TJniversity of New Hampshire; currently
Fuibright lecturer in economics, University of Teheran, Iran.
1 See. for example. Lenore A. Epstein and Janet H. Murray, "The Aged Population of
the TTnited States-The 1903 Survey of the Aged," Social Security Administration, Re-
search Report No. 19 (Washington: Government Printing Office, 1907).
2 For an elaboration of this point, see "Simulation: a Symposium." .4merican Economic
Review, vol. 50 (December 1960), pp. 893-932, especially the article by G. Orcutt nncl
M. Shubik.
156
PAGENO="0163"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 157
sense that the model allows for the element of chance in addition to
asserting specified relationships among the variables. Given certain
specified inputs, probabilities of occurrence for various events can be
specified. Utilizing the services of a high-speed electronic computer,
the model can then be used to investigate the problem under considera-
tion (i.e., to project pension income and asset distributions for a future
aged population).
The details of this model and previous research findings have been
reported upon elsewhere.3 Before proceeding further, however, they
will be summarized:
1.1 The life process model
In order to project pension income and assets of the retired aged,
it is necessary to construct a "life process" model which will permit
those activities of individuals to be simulated which have an important
influence on pensions and assets. These activities can he divided into
the following four categories:
(a) Demographic.
(b) Work force and earnings.
(c) Pension status.
(d) Asset accumulation.
A large sample of persons in the U.S. populatioii, who were, in gen-
eral, between the ages of 45 and 60 in 1960, is aged 20 years, using
the simulation process.4 At the end of 20 years, these people are age
65 or over and represent the aged population in 1980. Naturally not
everyone in 1960 between 45 and 60 can be expected to live at least 20
years. Hence the first life process activity considered in the simulation
model is death. A probability of death for each particular year is
specified for individuals based on their sex, race, and age. A random
drawing from the associated probability distribution is used to deter-
mine whether an individual will die or live that year. Similarly, prob-
abilities are specified for other possible occurrences built into the
model-labor force exit and entry, job change, pension coverage, vest-
ing, periods of unemployment, etc.5
Each possible "occurrence" specified in the model is treated in a
manner similar to the live-die occurrence-each person being con-
sidered in turn. By sequential handling of the various occurrences it
is possible to make the consideration of any one occurrence dependent
on occurrences which had been handled before it. Once 1 year's simu-
lation is completed, the individual, if he had survived, is aged another
year and the process immediately repeated. This continues until the
year 1980 is reached (i.e., completion of 20 "passes" in the computer).
After all individuals have been processed, the resulting sample popu-
James H. Schulz, "The Future Economic Circumstances of the Aged: A Simulation
Projection, 1980," Yale Economic Essays, vol. 7 (spring 1907), pp. 145-212.
The basic data used. are from the "one-in-a-thousand sample." a set of tapes produced
by the U.S. Bureau of Census which contains separate records (including demographic,
work force, and income information) of a 0.1 percent sample of the U.S. population as
recorded in the 1960 census. See "One-in-a-thousand Sample Description and Technical
Documentation," U.S. Census of Population and. Housing: 1960 (Washington, undated).
The subsample used for the simulation consisted of 33,680 persons.
For example, the probability that a nonwhite female of age 50 would die in year 1961
was specified as .011. A random number generator was used to generate a number between
1 and 1,000. If the number generated were greater than 11, the individual was considered
to live through the year. Conversely, if the random number generated were 11 or less, the
individual was considered to have died in that particular year.
PAGENO="0164"
158 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
Tiation represents the major part of the future aged population, smce
the surviving individuals are now 65 to 85 years of age.
During the simulation, work income, pension coverage, and asset
histories are kept for each individual. Social security benefits for those
persons retired and no longer in the work force (and eligible) can be
calculated by applying the average "creditable" wage income gener-
ated by the simulation to a social security benefit formula.. Where
applicable, private pension benefits and government pensions can be
estimated based on employee annual wage and/or years of service.
Having calculated private and public pension benefits, a "census"
is taken of the retired population at the end of the simulation period,
and various distribution of pension income and assets for couples and
unrelated persons can be derived.
The simulation technique permits working at the micro-economic
level. In addition, sensitivity testing of the model is used to represent
a particular system (i.e., the simulation can be rerun many times with
one or more parameters being altered each time). Such tests are useful
in indicating whether any of the parameters (especially those which
are crudely estimated because of data limitations) can seriously distort
the results if in error. In addition, such tests help to identify which
parameters are most important with regard to policy decisions relating
to the area under investigation. Policy alternatives can, therefore, be
evaluated using the simulation model to see how certain institutional or
behavioral changes would affect the results.
"Possibly one of the most valuable contributions of simulation to
date (is) the discipline imposed by the necessity of precise1~~ defining
for the computer both tile problems and questions to be answered." ~
Simulation forces the investigator to work through the system bemg
represented at a very low level of aggregation. Tile requirements for
programing tile model being used require that one attempt to identify
all tile slg1lificant influences, their direction, and tileir interrelation-
ship.
1.2 Prior research findings
In all attempt to find out more about tile economic situation of re-
tired older peolie iii the future, distributions of pension income aris-
ing out of social security, private, and governmellt pension coverage
and assets in retirement were projected. For tIle vast majority of
retired persons social security payments together with private pension
benefits are now, and promise to be in the future, the dominant source
of retirement income.7 By projecting these benefits, the projections
sought to investigate the extent to wilicil the income situation of the
retired aged in the future might be improved.
The object of these projections was not so much to predict what the
actual future economic circumstances of the retired aged would be in
1980; 8 rather it was an attempt to investigate the pensions and assets
which one could expect to be available to the aged, given the existing
institutional pension structure and certain assumptions with regard
Martin Shubik, "Simulation of the Industry and the Firm," American Economic Review,
vol. 50 (December 1966), p. 913.
~Epstein, op. cit., p. 36. . . . .
8 ObvIOUSlY future benefits depend in large part upon public and private pension decisions
still to be made.
PAGENO="0165"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 159
to changes in these institutional arrangements in the next decade and
a half. No attempt was macic to predict dramatic changes which might
possibly take place in the future with regard to individual and/or
group views concerning the provision of income in retirement. Instead,
an attempt was made to better understand what income the existing
pension structure would provide and whether changes in this structure
might indeed seem necessary or desirable.
It was necessary to make many as~nunptions to make the proection.
Many of these resulted from inadequate data. Still others were neces-
sary because it was impossible to know with certainty whatchanges in
the U.S. pension system would occur in the future. Because the results
of the simulation were in part dependent on the assumptions made,
the simulation was run a number of times under different sets of as-
sumptions. It would have been impossible in terms of time and cost
to run the simulation using all possible combinations of assumptions;
instead, only a~ few of interest and importance were considered.
In general, where doubt existed as to the appropriate assumption, the
decision was made in favor of being consistently liberal, producing a
probable upward bias in the income and asset projections. This was
clone to avoid the criticism that the research findings resulted from
restrict~ve assumptions, restrictive in the sense that they conflicted
with some other person's idea of normalcy.
Despite this bias, the results were definitely not encouraging with
regard to the future economic situation for retired aged. The study
found that, while the existing pension system can be expected by 1980
to have produced a sizable shift upward in the distribution of pension
income for aged persons, there would still be a large proportion of aged
units in 1980 with "very low" pension incomes. In addition, using vari-
ous different measures of income "adequacy," it was found that little
or no improvement in the adequacy of aged income (from pensions and
assets) can be expected relative to the rising incomes of the rest of
the U.S. population.9 Tables 1 through 5 present the projected distri-
butions.
TABLE 1.-PROJECTED TOTAL PENSION INCOME DISTRIBUTION FOR RETIRED COUPLES AND
UNMARRIED INDIVIDUALS, 1980'
]ln percent]
Total pension income
Couples
Unmarried units
Less than $10002
$1,000 to $1,999
$2,000 to $2,999
5
16
28
32
19
31
$3,000 to $3,999
$4,000 to $4,999
$5,000 to $9,999
$10,000 and over
25
14
12
(3)
11
5
3
(3)
Total
4100
100
I Pension income includes benefits from social security, private pensions (including State and local plans), and Federal
retirement programs.
2 Includes units without pensions.
3 Less than 1 percent.
4 Totals may not sum to 100 percent due to rounding.
The standards used were tise social security poverty index and the TJ.S. Bureau of Labor
Statistics, "Budget for a Retired Couple."
PAGENO="0166"
160 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
TABLE 2.-PROJECTED INCOME FROM SOCIAL SECURITY AND PRIVATE PENSIONS FOR RETIRED COUPLES AND
UNMARRIED INDIVIDUALS, 1980
[In parcent[
Couple units 1 Unmarried units 1
Amount of income Income from Income from Income from Income from
social private social private
sacurity pensions security pensions
Less than $1000 4 35 17 49
$1,000 to $1,999 21 39 26 34
$2,000 to $2,999 43 17 51 11
$3,000 to $3,999 30 6 7 3
$4,000 to $4,999 2 2 0 1
$5,000 and over 0 (2) 0 (2)
Total 3100 103 - 100 100 -
I Recipients only.
2 Indicates less than 1 percent.
o Total may not sum to 100 percent due to rounding.
TABLE 3.-MONEY INCOME DISTRIBUTIONS OF RETIRED UNITS, 1962 AND 1980 PROJECTIONS
[Percent distribution[
Less $1,000 $2,000 $3,000 $4,000 $5,000 $10,000
Item than to to to to to and Tofal
$1,000 $1,999 $2,999 $3,999 $4,999 $9,999 over
Couples:
1962' 7 32 31 13 7 7 2 100
1980: 2
(a) Pension income only 5 16 28 25 14 12 0 100
(b) Pensian plus asset income 3 4 11 20 26 19 20 1 100
Unmarried individuals:
1962 51 35 9 2 1 1 100
1980:
(a) Pensian income only 32 19 31 11 5 3 0 100
(b) Pension plus asset income 4 13 24 26 17 16 1 100
1 Based on data from U.S. Social Security Administration, 1963 Survey of the Aged.
2 Simulation projection run 2 assumptions.
o Pension income plus 4~-percent return from fioancial assets. No estimation of public assistance, veterans' benefits,
rents, and contributions by relatives are included.
TABLE 4.-INCOME DISTRIBUTION OF RETIRED COUPLES, 1962 AND 1980 PROJECTIONS
Couples Under $1,000 to $2,000 to $3,000 to $4,000 Total
$1,000 $1,999 $2,999 $3,999 and over
1962' 7 32 31 13 16 100
1980 money pension plus asset income 2 4 11 20 26 40 100
Real pension pius asset income a 11 29 31 18 11 100
1 Based on data from U.S. Social Security Administration, 1963 Survey of the Aged.
2 Simulation projection run 2 assumptions.
3 Assumes average price level rise in future will be at the same rate which occurred during the 1955-65 period (1.6
percent yearly).
TABLE 5.-AGGREGATE PERSONAL INCOME ESTIMATES FOR THE RETIRED AND NONRETIRED POPULATION, 1980
1960 1980
1. Total personal income of retired aged persans (billions) - $26 {I $70.5
2. Total personal income of nonretired persons (billions) $416 {l $328.0
3. Personal income par capita for retired aged persons $2, 144 {I~ ~
4. Personal income percapita for nonretired persons over age 20 $4 104 {~ ~
5. Ratio of retired aged per capita personal iscome to nsoretired (over age 20) par
capita personal income 0.52 {l~ ~: ~
6. Retired aged personal income as a percent of total personal income 6 {Ii ~: ~
7. Retired agad population as a percent of the total U.S. population 6. 5 8. 3
PAGENO="0167"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 161
The projected asset picture for older people was somewhat better.
Given "strong" saving behavior, aged units in 1980 could be expected
to have accumulated substantially greater `total assets than aged units
possessed in 1962. Given past experience, however, a large proportion
of these assets would be in the form of less liquid home equity; pro-
jected aged financial assets in 1980, although distinctly improved
over the 1962 situation, were much smaller than projected total assets.
The saving rate and assumptions upon which the estimates were
based were, as in the ease of social security benefit increases, considered
liberal. The simulation model assumed that all units saved, subject
only to the qualification `that this saving was reduced as a result of'
unemployment experiences. In contrast, however, a large proportion
of' people currently reach retirement age with little or no personal
financial assets. The "1963 Survey of the Aged" found, for example,
that 22 percent of couples, and approximately 35 percent of unmarried
individuals between the age of 62 and 64, were without financial assets,
and that 9 percent and approximately 20 percent, respectively, had no
assets of any kind.'0 Whether personal savings behavior for retire-
ment will change significantly for a large segment of the population,
therefore, still remains to be seen.11
2. THE QUESTION OF EARLY RETIREMENT
The research results summarized above indicate a possible need for
additional action to improve the incomes of future aged persons. Such
a conclusion assumes that the aged population desires (and that so-
ciety in general concurs) to be able to maintain a standard of living
for most aged units which is comparable in some way to the rest of
society. Rejected is the idea `that old age is a hibernation period where
living slows down almost to a stop while people wait for death.
"Whether we should have a society in which a large fraction of the
public scrimps in their productive years to provide themselves with a
higher standard of life in old age than `they ever enjoyed in the prime
of life," 12 or whether we should have a society-as now-in which a
large fraction of the public lives in retirement, at a significantly lower
standard of living than they enjoyed while the head' worked, is a legiti-
mate question to be decided by people~-individuaiiy and/or collec-
tively. There are, of course, a whole range of intermediate alternatives.
The remainder of this paper focuses upon one economic aspect of
the aged question receiving increased attention. It studies some of the
possible implications of retirement at earlier ages. In addition, it
raises objection to proposals advocating reduction of the eligibility
age for social security retirement benefits.
3. THE EARLY RETIREMENT TREND
There is a rapidly accumulating body of data which indicates a sig-
nificant rise in "early retirement" (i.e., `before age 65) among male
10 Epstein. op. cit., table 4.5.
11 For addltlonal problems associated with savings in the form of home equity, see James
H. Schools, "Some Economics of Home Ownership," Gerontologist, vol. 7 (March 1967),
PP 7~~-74. ~
`~ Milton Friedman, "Capitalism and Freedom" (Chicago: University, of Chicago Press.
1962), p. 189. Friedman attributes this position to proponents of a policy of governmental
intervention in retirement planning.
PAGENO="0168"
162 OLD AGE IYCOME ASS~JRAXCE-PART III
workers in the United States. Data from the Current Population Sur-
vey, for example, show that nonparticipation in the labor force among
men age 55 to 64 rose from 11.5 to 15.5 percent between 1956 and
1966.13
Much of this rise in nonparticipation occurred among men age 60
to 64 and has occurred during recent years. Table 6 shows the 1961-66
participation rates for males between the ages of 60 and 64. It can be
seen that the participation rates have been failing rather sharply,
especially after the m1nimum social security eligibility age of 62.
TABLE 6.-CIVILIAN LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION RATES FOR MEN, ANNUAL AVERAGES, 1961-66
Age
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
60
85.5
85.9
88.1
85.5
86.0
85.9
61
85.6
81.9
83.5
84.6
83.3
83.4
62
82.0
80.5
79.7
78.2
78.7
79.4
63
79.9
76.9
75.5
74.1
72.5
71.1
64
74.9
74.2
71.5
71.5
67.7
67.4
Source: Unpublished data,
U.S. De
partmeo
t of Lab
or, Bore
so of Labor Statistics.
The reasons for this trend are not definitely known. A 1963 survey
of salary and wage workers, age 62 to 64 (retiring since. 1957), found,
however, that only 9 percent reported retiring because they "preferred
leisure." 14 Almost 75 percent reported retiring because of poor health
(53 percent) or involuntary loss of job (22 percent). Whether poor
health was the real reason for those who gave it as an explanation for
retirement. or just a. rationalization by some unable to find work is not
known. Using a rather stringent disability definition, the Bureau of
Labor Stat.istics found only 30 percent of men age 60 to 64 who were
not in the labor force in 1966 unable to work because of long-term
mental or physical disabilities.15 The appropriate percentage probably
lies somewhere between the Social Security and Bureau of Labor Sta-
tistics findings.
F. Le Gros Clark has de.scribed part. of the problem which may be
arising as follows:
In the remote past. it. had always been possible to let a man
moderate his efforts or change his style of work as soon as the
years began to tell. The advance of mechanization made this
progressively less practicable. Industry has now reached a
point at which the dilemma is becoming self-evident; mann-
fac.ture and transport cannot economically absorb more than
a small proportion of their human wastage; i.e., the "mar-
ginal" tvnes of laborer embodied in many of their older em-
ployees. The result has been the creation of an extended :c~~
man's land," lyine between the close of a man's normal work-
ing life and the time when true old age at last supervenes.16
11 ~U~~ri S. Holland. `Adult Men Not in the Labor Force." Monthly Labor Review, vol.
90 (Mn~cli 1967). p. 7.
~ Lerore A. EpsteIn and Janet H. Murray. "Tlae Aced Population of the United States-
The 1903 Sotial Security Survey of the Aged," Research Report No. 19 (washington,
Goi-e"n~nent Printing Office. 1907). table 8.4.
15 Holland, op cit.. table 1. The BLS count of men "unable to work" excludes, however,
men with temporary injuries or Illnesses and men with some combination of minor dis-
abilities.
1~ "Work. Age, and Leisure" (London, Joseph, 1966), p. 13.
PAGENO="0169"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 163
Other possible reasons for early retirement include age discrimina-
tion and unemployment arising out of cyclical fluctuations or techno-
logical change. A recent Labor Department study on age discrimina-
tion in employment concluded that older workers who leave or lose
their jobs are often unable to find other work because of discriminating
hiring practices `by employers. The study reported that "approxi-
mately half of all job openings which develop in the private economy
each year are closed to applicants over 55 .years of age, and a quarter of
them are closed to applicants over 45." `~
What happens to the older worker who loses his job because his plant
closes or a~ machine replaces his skill? Faced with the very difficult, if
not impossible, task of getting another full-time job, he is often forced,
after unemployment benefits expire, to live off of savings, relatives, or
relief. As soon as he reaches the age of social security early retirement
eligibility (currently age 62 for males), he is likely to "retire."
The Social Security Administration reports that "during the past
4 years close to half the men and two-thirds of the women workers
awarded retirement benefits under the social security program have
been under the traditional age of 65." 15 Just how many of these early
retirees were forced to retire `because of poor work prospects is not
exactly known.
There is clearly a vital need for additional information and research
on the early retirement question; we need to know more about the
pre- and post-retirement work history, assets, health, and total re-
tirement income of persons retiring before age 65. Until we know more
of this information, formulation of successful public policy in this
area will be very difficult.
4. REDUCTION OF THE SOCIAL SECURITY ELIGIBILITY AGE
Evidence of older worker employment difficulties caused Senator
Robert Byrd, of West Virginia, to propose an amendment to the 1965
social security-medicare bill (now law), to reduce the initial eligibility
age for social security retirement benefits from the present age 62
to age 60. The `benefits were to be actuarially reduced based on the
number of years payment began before age 65. The Senate passed the
proposal by voice vote without a dissenting word being spoken, but
the amendment was later dropped in conference. Senator Byrd, how-
ever, has continued to press in recent years for passage of a similar
amendment to the law.
In view of the inadequate information currently available on mo-
tivations for early retirement (discussed above), and in view of the
possible social consequences (discussed below), it would seem that the
Byrd proposal requires more careful study before enactment than it
has received thus far by Congress.'° If the Byrd amendment becomes
law, this country may find itself taking a step backward in the war
on poverty; the effect of the Byrd amendment might be to push mil-
lions of Americans into even deeper retirement poverty.
17 iTS. Department of Labor, "The Older American Worker-Age Discrimination in Em-
ployment." (Washinaton, Government Printing Office, June i965), p. 6.
~ Lonore A. Epstein, "Early Retirement and Work-Life Experience," Social Security
Bulletin. vol. 29 (March 1966), p. 3.
~° No formal committee hearings have ever been held, although It has been passed by the
Senate a total of 3 times.
PAGENO="0170"
164 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
If, for example, a worker covered by social security has an earnings
history which makes him eligible at age 65 for social security benefits
of $100 per month,2° Senator Byrd's amendment would pay him two-
thirds that amount ($66.66) should he retire at age 60. This benefit
would not increase to $100 per month when the retired worker reached
age 65; instead, it would remain at the lower level for the rest of his life.
The premise upon which Senator Byrd based his desire for earlier
social security eligibility is to some extent praiseworthy. In 1965 he
argued:
The basic object of reducing the retirement age to 60 is to
free the worker at that a.ge so that he may make an independ-
ent decision, based on his own situation, as to whether he
can, with dignity, continue to work * * ~* Best evidence
shows that many men and women between the age of 60 and
65 are simply unable to work. Secondly, it is also quite clear
that workers in this age group who are a.ble to work experi-
ence extreme difficulty in finding suitable employment. And
finally, it is becoming increasingly evident that our new
productivity is shortening the length of our working life just
as certainly as it has shortened the length of the workiiig
week.2'
And in 1966 he argued:
Despite the fact that many Americans are living longer,
they are not necessarily working longer. Many have physical
disabilities which prevent them from participating in our
fast-moving industrial process. Many more, although willing
and able to work, find themselves the. victims of discrimina-
tory employment practices and technological changes which
favor the young. The net result is that many older men and
women a.re forced into retirement years before they are able
to qualify for retirement benefits.22
The solution to the problem of a rising number of unemployed older
workers is not necessarily to force these workers into earlier and earlier
retirement with smaller and smaller retirement pensions. This is Sen-
ator Byrd's solution. This is also the solution of the overwhelming
bulk of private pension systems in the United States which also cut
drastically pension benefits of early retiring worke.rs.
There are at least three major costs associated with such a solution.
First, by encouraging, and, in many cases, forcing workers to retire
early with reduced private and public pension benefits, the resulting
retirement income may be seriously inadequate. This is especially true,
given the current and projected inadequacy of pension income (de-
scribed in the first section of this paper), for large numbers of retired
persons. In addition, early retirees are more likely to be workers with
low educational attainment, low earnings, poor work histories and,
hence, with low pension income.23 Thus, foi~ example, in 1966, under the
20 The approximate average benefits paid to men in 1966.
~ Congressional Record (washington: Government Printing Office. July 7. 1965), pp.
15792-15793.
22 Congressional Record (Washington: Government Printing Office, Oct. 12. 1~9G6), p.
25295.
~ ~ee `Educational Attainment of Workers in March 1965," Monthly Labor Review
(March 1966), pp. 250-257.
PAGENO="0171"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSIJRANCE-PART iii 165
most recent benefit level, the average social security award to an early
retiree male was about $1,000 per year. For males not retiring early, the
average benefit award was about $1,350.24
Second, there is the loss in real output arising out of the consequent
reduction in the labor force. Evidence indicates that most workers
prefer the monetary and psychological benefits of employment to re-
tirement at present levels of private and public pensions. Those workers
who desire and are able to work without adversely affecting the pro-
ductivity of others can keep up total output and keep down the
"burden" of supporting the nonworking portion of the population.25
Third, by institutionalizing age 60 as the initial eligibility age for
social security, Congress may, in effect, be setting a guideline which
would tend to push the average age of retirement in the United States
lower. This phenomenon was clearly evident following the establish-
ment of social security and the eligibility age at 65 in the thirties. And
the recent establishment of eligibility at age 62 may in part be respon-
sible for the problem about which we are now concerned. Reducing the
eligibility age encourages employers, for example, under pressure from
younger workers to force more workers into retirement and to be more
reluctant or unwilling to hire and, where necessary, to train older
workers.
5. SIMuLATION ANALYSIS OF RETIREMENT TRENDS
In order to show the possible effects on retirement income of lower-
ing the social security eligibility age, pension income distributions for
1980 are projected using the simulation model described in section I.
Three projections are made, each based upon different assumptions
regarding the trend of retirement rates for males. Tabulations are also
presented of projected pension income by age of retirement.
5.1 Early retirement simulations
Proj ection I was a hypothetical construct. It assumes no change
over time in the age 45 and above male retirement rates, maintaining
retirement rates at. the level existing in 1960.26 It also maintains the
1960 situation regarding male eligibility for social security (i.e.,
benefits available only at age (35 or over with no early retirement at
reduced benefits possible).
The attempt is to simulate a situation which would approximate
what might have happened if the social security system had not
changed. Of course, this presumes that the necessary economic meas-
ures (i.e., appropriate monetary, fiscal, and labor force policies) would
be taken so as to provide jobs for workers in satisfactory employment.27
The resulting retirement before age 65 would, therefore, be due to per-
sonal preference for leisure over work of problems of health, and
24 Social Security Bulletin. vol. 30 (June 1967), table Q-G.
23 This burden Includes, in addition to pensions and other Income maintenance programs,
the costs of social services required to reduce and to deal with the psychological shock of
retirement cifecting many workers.
20 Stuart H. Garfinkle. `Tables of Working Life : Length of Working Life for Men," U.S.
Bureau of Labor Statistics Bulletin 1001 (Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office,
19i~0l Stuart H. Gcrflnkle, `The Length of Working Life for Males. 1900-GO," Manpower
Report No. 8 (WashIngton: Government Printing Office, 1964), table A.
27 By satisfactory employment is meant employment In jobs at earnings levels close to
the workers' peak earnings.
PAGENO="0172"
166 O~D AGE TYCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
would not be due to involuntary retirement arising out of unfavorable
employment opportunities.
Projection II results from introducing a moderate upward trend in
the male retirement rates between 1960 and 1980. This trend is based
on projections of participation rates for older males by the Bureau of
Labor Statistics.28 Social security retirement benefit eligibility at age
62 is assumed available for men after 1962.
Projection III assumes a larger decline in the average age of retire-
ment. The retirement rates for this projection are estimated from pro-
jected participation rates, using a technique developed by Stuart H.
Garflnkle.~° The trend in participation rates is based upon the data
presented in table 6, which shows recent. estimates of male ParticiPa-
tion rates over the 1961-66 period. Social security eligibility at age 60
is assumed.
Table T shows the resulting pension income projections. The effect of
early retirement and early pension eligibility (under the assumption
assumed) is to cause the income distribution to shift. down at the
lower end. This results in a sharp rise in the number of persons pro-
jected as receiving very low pension income-income which is, by
present adequacy standards, inadequate.30
TABLE 7.-PROJECTED PENSION I NCOME DISTRI BUTIONS, 1980
[Percent distributioni
Pension income
Retire
d couples
Retired
unmarried
I
If
III
I
II I
II
Less than $1,000
$1,000 to $1,999
$2,000 to $2,999
$3,000 to $3,999
$4,000 to $4,999
$5,000 to $9,999
4
17
28
24
12
16
5
16
28
25
14
12
6
25
26
21
12
11
32
20
21
20
5
2
32
19
31
11
5
3
34
26
25
10
4
2
Total
100
100
100
100
100
100
Source: Simu!ation model (see text).
5.2 Pro~ected pen.sion-ear'nings ?`atios
In a~ study of future aged pension income adequacy, which I have
not yet fully completed, the effects of early retirement upon income
adequacy are illustrated quite vividly. The measure of incop~e. adequacy
being used in the study is the amount of wage replacement after retire-
ment provided by pension income.
Table 8 shows some of the preliminary findings of this study.°' It
presents the projected ratio at retirement of total pension income to
average earnings 5 years prior to retirement for married males (who
were age 45 to 60 in 1960). The tabulation is broken into three groups
by age at time of retirement: less than age 60, 60 to 64, and over 64.
U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. "Labor Force Projections for 1970-SO," Monthly Labor
Review, 85 (February 1965), 129-140.
2~ Op. cit.
~° The social security poverty index, for example, is presently about $2,500 for couples
and 51.7.50 for unmarried persons.
°1 The simulation, model described above (in modified form) was used to make these
projections.
PAGENO="0173"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 167
TABLE 8.-PROJECTED' RATIO OF TOTAL PENSION INCOME 2 TO PRERETIREMENTEARNINGSn FOR RETIRED
NONAGRiCULTURAL MALES~
[Percent distribution[
Age at retirement
Ratio -
Less than 60 60-64 65 or over
Less than 0.10 16 6 3
O 10 to 0.19 50 19 10
0.20 to 0.29 23 27 13
0.30 to 0.39 5 21 26
0.40 to 0.49 3 11 15
0.50 to 0.59 1 5 12
0.60 to 0.69 1 4 7
0.70 to 0.79 0 3 5
0.80 to 0.89 -. 0 1 2
1.0 or more 1 1 4
Total a 100 100 100
1 Source: Simulation model (see text).
2 Social security, private pension, and/or Government employee pension.
3 Average of 5 years prior to ret:remeet.
4 Married males only.
2 May not sum to 100 percent due to rounding.
The replacement ratios for men retiring before age 60 were much
worse than those for men retiring at the "normal" age of 6u or more.
For example, oniy about 3 percent of those retiring before age 60
are projected to have a replacement of 50 percent or more of their
average annual earnings from pension income. In contrast, a little less
than one-third o-f those retiring at age 65 or after are projected to
have a replacement above 50 percent.
6. RETIREMENT POLICY
The preceding sections have raised a number of questions regarding
the advisability of lowering the eligibility age for social security at
this time. Above all, there is a clear need for additional information
regarding the reasons for the apparent rising numbers of males re-
tiring before age 65.32 In addition, it would be helpful to have de-
tailed studies available on the experience other countries have had
with early retirement provisions different from those of the U.S.
social security system and with special unemployment provisions for
older workers.33
Social security eligibility (with actuarial reduction) at age 60 or
some other age could give greater retirement flexibility to older
workers. But this expansion of the worker's freedom of choice regard-
ing retirement planning necessities an economic environment which
allows him to work if he is willing and able. If he is unable to work,
because of age discrimination or because he lacks an appropriate skill
or just because of the lack of jobs in a depressed labor market, retire-
ment flexibility becomes meaningless. Early social security eligibility
then becomes a sop or substitute for public assistance. At the same time
32 A study by the Social Security Administration, of early~ retiring persons in its "Con-
tinuous Work History Sample," who became eligible or "entitled" to retirement in 1964 is
almost completed and promises to offer additional insight Into the question.
- 2~ For example, Austria and west Germany both have "special" early retirement pro-
ViSiOns.
PAGENO="0174"
168 OLD AGE INOOME ASSURANCE_PART III
it forces the worker into a situation of having to elect lower pension
income in retirement for the rest of his life.
What is needed is improvement in public and private disability
coverage and provisions, institution of extended unemployment com-
pensation benefits for older workers similar to those in the Javits-
Ha.rtke amendment,34 and job retraining and age discrimination legis-
la.tion.'~ These measures, together with a vigorous labor market sus-
tained by appropriate monetary-fiscal policy, would create the en-
vironment necessary to expand retirement flexibility.
If the Nation cannot., or will not, provide jobs for those older persons
wanting to work, then it should face up to the responsibilities of insur-
ing that private and public pension programs provide enough income
for people to live decently, regardless of whether they retire early or
late.
`~ The amendment was passed by the Senate in 19G~, but did not pass the House.
~" There is some question as to just how useful such legislation can be. Older persons
may be difficult to train because of poor education, unreceptiveness, etc. Discrimination
because of age is not likely to be any easier to eliminate than race discrimination.
PAGENO="0175"
TAX MEASURES PROVIDING INCOME ASSISTANCE TO
OLDER PERSONS
BY HUGH MACAULBY*
1.0 Tax relief and incon-te maintenance
l,~Thether the aim be income maintenance or income assurance, the
income of older persons, or of any persons, may be raised by a variety
of measures. We may help such persons in their search for employ-
ment and higher earnings so they may enjoy the prescribed income.
They may be given assistance by private or public charity on the
basis of their need, or they may qualify for transfer payments on
grounds other than need. They may be given tax treatment that is
more favorable than that given to persons similarly situated in all
relevant respects except age. A variety of approaches abounds, but
the use of taxes is a recognized and commonly accepted means for
achieving the stated end. rJ~he customary emphasis on "aftertax in-
come" brings home the point that if a person's income cannot be
changed, it might be possible to change his taxes and still attain the
goal of a higher residual income.
1.1 Advantages of tax preference
Not only is tax preference an available option; it is popular with
both givers and receivers and is often chosen. The former may prefer
tax relief over increased payments because new or heavier taxes are
avoided, the. benefits do not appear as Government expenditures which
are subject to annual review and frequent criticism, and the arrange-
ment does not require a new or expanded agency or bureaucracy to
administer the benefits. Those receiving tax benefits are pleased with
their enhanced aftertax position and seldom view `their situation as
anything other than justly deserved. They also appreciate the fact
that they are less likely to be asked to submit and justify annual re-
ports, file reports, or account for expenditures. While `Congress may
often be chided for its expenditures on this group or that group, less
often does there seem to be a complaint of unfairness in tax favor
given. The usual approach is to recognize existing tax favor, assume
it is justified, and plead for its extension to other equally deserving
groups.
1.2 Disadvantage of tax preference
The arguments against tax preference are equally imposing, but
they appeal to different persons. The Treasury Department and those
concerned with the efficient operation of the revenue system stress the
difficulty in finding a tax t.hat can be altered to benefit the precise
group one chooses to help. If the need is to help the aged, a reduction
in the income taxes of older persons is of benefit only to those who
*Professor, Clemson University.
169
PAGENO="0176"
170 OLD AGE I~OOME ASSTJRAXCE-PART III
have both age and income. Persons who are older but poorer may not
benefit from this measure.
To illustrate the point, the Treasury estimates that in 1966 tax pref-
erences to the aged costing $~.3 billion annually were going to 11
million of an estimated 18 million aged persons. Only one-fourth of
these benefits went to persons whose incomes (including social security
and railroad retirement benefits) were $3,000 or less. An additional
one-fourth went to persons with incomes between $3,000 and $5,000.
The remaining one-ha.lf went to persons with incomes over .$5,000.
No benefit went to the approximately 40 percent of the aged whose
incomes were the lowest (13, p. 5). It is doubtful that this was the
distribution of benefits envisioned when the measures were enacted.
Secondly, we have often seen how tax preference granted to one
group generated political pressure to extend the benefits to similar or
closely related groups. The exemption from tax given to railroad re-
tirement benefits was probably significant in its effect on the tax
treatment later accorded social security benefits which, in turn, served
as justification for the favorable tax treatment accorded other income
under the retirement income credit. WTithin limits the extension may
not be a serious problem, but it can lead to the destruction of the tax
system. The larger the benefits from tax preference, the higher must
be the tax rates required to raise a given amount of revenue. The high-
er are these rates, the greater is the pressure to gain exemption from
tax.
Thirdly, a system of taxation, already complex from special pro-
visions, becomes increasingly difficult or impossible to comprehend as
new exemptions are added. While those qualifying for the special treat-
ment may profit, those who serve as tax consultants or in other ways
advise or assist taxpayers are also beneficiaries. Complex special pro-
visions, as for example those dealing with the sale of a residence by a
person over age 65, increase the likelihood that intended beneficiaries
will not understand the favorable provisions and so fail to benefit from
them. This is reported to be particularly true with regard to the
present retirement income credit (8, p. 197).
1.3 Definition-s of tax favor
It may be readily agreed that tax preference is a source of aid, but
agreement may not be so readily forthcoming as to what con.stitutes
tax preference. Relief from a given tax may be viewed as a. justified
exemption from the power to destroy. The exemption from income
taxation of interest on State and local bonds and the exemption of
church property from taxation might be cited as examples.
Whether tax preference is involved might also depend on the defini-
tion of the tax base. An income tax should apply to income, but are
contributions made by an employer to a pension plan to be considered
as income to the employee? Since Congress defines the tax base, it
may include or exclude items as it sees fit, although there is bound
to be disagreement among constituents as to the propriety of the
definition chosen or implied. A third area of disagreement might
appear when it is agreed that the item is legitimately taxable. properly
a part. of the tax base, but should be,excluded because some similar
or closely related item is exempt. Examples abound: The retirement
PAGENO="0177"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 171
income credit, depletion allowances for coal, exemption of old-age
insurance benefits from income taxation, the taxation of small busi-
ness corporations as partnerships and vice versa, and others.
Before it is argued that a given group of persons or form of pay-
ment is given tax favor, it would be well to state the assumptions
that underlie the position. ~Vith this warning in mind, we will examine
some of the forms of payment that are often listed as sources of tax
preference for the aged.
2. OIL-AGE INSURANCE
While the old-age, survivors, disability, and hospital insurance pro-
gram, as part of a broader social security program, is itself financed
with a tax, the emphasis here will be on the income tax treatment of
the payments and benefits made under the old-age insurance (OAT)
part of the program. The aims, accomplishments, and operation of the
program as it now exists is a proper topic for another paper.
Contributions to the program are made by employees at a prescribed
rate and are matched by employers. Self-employed persons contribute
at 11/2 times the rate contributed by employees. The contribution of the
employee and the self-employed person are considered part of ad-
justed gross income and so may become subject to the income tax. Con-
tributions by the employer on behalf of his employees are not taxed to
either of the parties. Benefits when received are not included in ad-
justed gross income and so are not subject to the income tax.
With these benefits to the aged exempt from income tax, the after-
tax incomes of those who receive them are higher than they other-
wise would be and so some contribution is made to the aims of income
maintenance or income assurance. But these gains go only to those
whose other incomes are high enough to make them subject to the in-
come tax or whose other incomes are high enough that with these bene-
fits they would become taxable. Those whose incomes are below these
levels do not benefit from this provision. Further, the higher the per-
son's taxable income, the greater the value of the provision to him.
Benefits are, therefore, distributed in direct proportion to the tax
bracket of the recipient.
It may be felt by some that while the income tax exemption of OAT
benefits helps only the aged who are relatively better off, at least the
exemption does not hurt those in the lower brackets. If, however, the
loss in general revenue from this source must be replaced, income taxes
and/or other taxes must be increased. Musgrave's study of the incidence
of taxes and the more recent study by the Tax Foundation indicate
that while Federal taxes are on balance progressive, the overall struc-
ture is much less progressive than the tax rates imply, and some taxes,
like excises and customs are actually regressive (4, pp. 97-98; 7, p. 20).
Thus, for every $3 that a family making over $15,000 has to pay in
taxes to make up for the loss in revenue, a family making less than
$2,000 must pay $1. Those in the lowest income brackets receive no
benefit from the tax exemption of OAT benefits, but they will help
make up the tax loss.
The amount of revenue lost by the nontaxability of retirement insur-
ance benefits was estimated by Muntz, in 1957, to be between $400 and
$500 million (3, pp. 355-356). At that time these benefits were 5.7 bil-
83-200-67-Pt. 3-12
PAGENO="0178"
172 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
lion annually, but by 1965 they had more than doubled to 12.5 billion
annually (5, p. 14; 6, p. 6). The Internal Revenue Service in its "Sta-
tistics of Income" has analyzed the returns of taxpayers over 65, but
OAT benefits are not reported by taxpayers and so it is uncertain which
taxpayers are benefiting from this tax exemption or how large the
revenue loss is. However, two-thirds of the 3 million taxable returns
reported no wa.ge income, and so there was no barrier from this source
to receiving benefits. In fact, almost 50 percent of each group of re-
turns showing over $15,000 adjusted gross income showed no wage or
salary income (11, p. 89). These persons who reported no wages could
have received their full OAT benefits and enjoyed significant tax
savmgs.
The exemption of these benefits from tax does not conform to the
accepted standards of either vertica.l or horizontal equity, and several
writers have proposed that the benefits be included in taxable income.
There is a departure from the standards of vertical equity as expressed
by the tax rates because OAT benefits received by wealthy persons will
be subjec.t to the same zero tax rate as those received by low-income
beneficiaries. The concept of horizontal equity is violated by having
two persons whose incomes are equal, one receiving OAT benefits and
the other receiving an equal amount of wage income, but subject to
different tax rates.
These benefits are tax preferred in the sense that the general defini-
tion of income as given in the Internal Revenue Code specifically in-
cludes retirement benefits. "Except as otherwise provided in this sub-
title, gross income means all income from whatever source derived,
including (but not limited to) the following items: * * (9) Annui-
ties; (10) Income from life insurance and endowment contracts; (11)
Pensions: * * (9, sec. 61) ." Accordingly, retirement benefits are
normall included in adjusted gross income to the extent that they
exceed the amount contributed by and previously taxed to the recipient.,
but OAT benefits are tax exempt in their entirety.
The proper tax treatment of amoimts paid as workers' contributions
is not so widely agreed on as the tax treatment of benefits. Some argue
for the exemption of contributions from taxable income because, as they
propose, benefits will be. taxed later (3). Others point out that with a
retirement income credit still operative, benefits, though incluclible in
adjusted gross income, could still escape taxation, and so contributions
should be taxed to compensate for this exemption (1). Tn view of the
variety of forms of income covered by the retirement income credit and
not previously taxed, this latter policy would seem to single out OAT
for prepayment of taxes in anticipation of future possible exemption.
A stronger case can be built if one combines the generally accepted
definition of jncome supported by most economists, that income is the
algebraic sum of changes in net worth plus consumption, with the
treatment of insurance as proposed by Vickrey (14, pp. 58-85). His
point is that insurance against a future loss of inco~ne is analogous to a
business expense and should be deductible under a personal income
tax. Thus, the contribution made under OAT could be viewed as a
legitimate expense of guaranteeing future income under given con-
tingencies and should not be a part of adjusted gross income. The later
payments of benefits would then be taxable. For the individual tile
PAGENO="0179"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART iii 173
system would involve a deferral of tax from the time when the con-
tribution was made until when the benefits were received. But, since the
OAT program is operated on the basis that contributions should ap-
proximately equal benefits in each year, there would be no deferral of
adjusted gross income for the Treasury.
An income insurance system such as OAT basically makes transfer
payments from those who are working to those who are retired. Any
given individual who works and contributes to the system may never
receive retirement benefits should he die before retirement age. A tax
on his contributions would be a levy on something that leads neither to
his consumption of goods or services nor to a~ change in his net worth.
He does enjoy a peace of mind knowing that if he lives to retirement,
income will be forthcoming; but, this benefit, to a small degree, is a
result of the service by the insurance agency and, to a large degree,
stems from the transfer of payments from one group to another. The
average recipient of benefits today gets back, tax free, far more than
the contributions on which he paid tax, but increasingly many covered
workers will pay income tax contributions which they will never see
matched in equal payouts.
if a worker had received, through 1966, the maximum wage subject
to OASDI tax since taxes were first collected in 1937, he would have
paid in social security taxes $2,384.20, all of which would have been
includable in his adjusted gross income and could have been subject
to income tax. His expected benefits, if he and his wife had retired at
age 65 in 1967, would be over $30,000. If he and his wife enjoyed
normal life expectancy, he would have paid income tax on only 8
cents of every dollar he received. The Treasury estimates that for per-
sons retiring in 1966, as much as 89 percent of their OAST benefits
would have been includable in adjusted gross income if these benefits
were treated like other retirement benefits (13, p. 14).
The proposed tax treatment would result in a much larger tax base
because all benefits would be included in adjusted gross income while
only contributions by employees and self-employed persons are now
included. However, because those who receive benefits are likely to have
lower incomes at the time of receipt, the tax rates and total taxes col-
lected could be lower. Tn 1957, Muntz estimated that the taxation of
benefits and the tax exemption of contributions would produce a net
revenue decline of about $300 to $400 million (3, pp. 357-358). Table I
compares contributions with benefits for 1965.
TABLE l.-OASI CONTRIBUTIONS AND BENEFITS, 1965
[In millions of dollars[
Contributions
Benefits
Employee contributions
Employercontributions
Self-employed persons contributions
Old-age retirement benefits
Survivorship benefits
Lump sum poyments
7,440
7,618
959
12, 542
~
217
Tstal
16,017
16,738
Source: Social Security Bulletin, Annual Statistical Supplement, 1965, pp. 6, 9.
PAGENO="0180"
174 OLD AGE INCOME ASST5RAXCE-p,ART III
The Trea.sury Department has recommended the inclusion of OAT
benefits in adjusted gross income and the adoption of a new, higher
old-age exemption that would in effect leave nontaxable 90 percent
of the aged persons receiving social security benefits. The other 10 per-
cent of the beneficiaries would be taxable; but to allow for the return
of previously taxed contributions, never would more than two-thirds
of their benefits be subject to tax. There is no mention of a tax exemp-
tion for contributions (8, pp. 199-201).
The Treasury's proposal has the advantage of treating OAT bene-
fits like all other forms of income, but in effect this is achieved by ex-
tending a new and larger exemption to all forms of income for 92 per-
cent of the persons over 65. The problem of nontaxibility of OAT beñe-
fits is settled; the problem of the exemption remains and will be.
discussed later.
By contrast, the proposal advanced in this paper and outlined above
would result in higher taxes on the aged, but only on those who are
taxable or near taxable. Additional taxes that would result would be
collected from aged individuals in increasing proportion to their
total income; additional benefits from these taxes could be distributed
to the less affluent in inverse proportion to their other income or in any
other pattern that seemed just.
Tf at the same time employee contributions were exempt from tax,
there might be a net reveiiue loss and a net loss to the aged as a group.
Offsetting this would be a greater equity of treatment. Persons young
and old with equal incomes would pay eciual taxes: or if it were felt
that older taxpayers deserved special consideration, this could be given
by an exemption applied to all forms of income or by special deduc-
tions applicable only to those taxpayers incurring the added expenses.
Equity between generations would also he improved for no longer
would a tax be levied on those persons who for years made OAT con-
tributions, but because of an early death never enjoyed increased con-
smnption or net worth from benefits; and only those persons who
received benefits from t.heir contributions would now be taxed on this
gain.
3. PRIVATE PENSION PLANS
TJnder most private pension plans employers, and sometimes em-
ployees% contribute to a fund to provide pensions to workers when they
retire. These plans, too, have enjoyed phenomenal growth.
TABLE 11.-PRIVATE PENSION AND DEFERRED PROFIT-SHARING PLANS
1950
1960
1965
Annual contributions by employers (million)
Annual contributions by employees (million)
Number of workers covered (thousand)
Number of workers receiving benefits (thousand)
Benefits paid (million)
Reserves (billion)
$1. 750. 0
$330. 0
9, 800. 0
450. 0
$370. 0
$12. 1
$4, 690
$790
21, 200
1, 780
$1, 750
$52
56, 660. 0
$1, 090. 0
25, 400. 0
2, 750. 0
$3, 180. 0
$85. 4
Source: Social Security Bulletin, April 1967, p. 20.
The tax treatment of payments into the funds largely Parallels that
of OAT, but the treatment of benefits differs. Employee contributions
are included in the employee's taxable income: employer contributions
are generally excluded; earnings of the pension funds are generally
PAGENO="0181"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 175
not taxable. Benefit payments are considered in part a return of pre-
viously taxed contributions, which are not taxed, and in part a pay-
ment from contributions of the employer and the earnings of the
pension fund, which are taxable.
Assistant Secretary of the Treasury Stanley Surrey holds that this
tax treatment results in a loss of Federal revenue of between $1.4 and
$3.8 billion, depending on how one reckons the taxable nature of the
payments, but estimated roundly at $3 billion. He holds that the pay-
ments by employers do not meet the general requirements for deduct-
ibihit.y; there must be a fixed liability on the employer to make a fixed
payment to a definite person. The mere possibility that the employer
may in the future have to provide his workers with a pension and that
he is recognizing that obligation with a payment into a pension fund
is not sufficient under the general principles of tax law to permit a
deduction by the employer. Further, lie notes, if the contribution is
vested for the employee, general tax principles would hold that he
has received taxable income (12, pp. 412-417).
The sums cited by Surrey are significant and would appear to con-
tribute to income ma!intenance for the aged. But, since benefits are
taxable to the extent not previously taxed, the tax savings must accrue
from some source other than the partial exemption of benefits. It is
the exemption from present tax accorded to contributions by employers
and the exemption of earnings of pension funds that are considered
tax favor. Yet two arguments may be offered to support the present
treatment: one on the basis of definition of income and one on the
basis of comparison with the treatment of similar payments.
Payments by employers into a pension fund are customarily required
by an agreement between employer and employees. These payments
cannot be recaptured by the employer until all obligations of the fund
are met. The payments would appear then to be legitimate costs of
doing business, paid to the fund and properly deductible to the em-
ployer, although Surrey holds that these conditions are not sufficient.
Payment.s by employers into the OASDHI fund are similar in all
relevant respects except that they are required by law while pension
plan contributions arise from employer-employee negotiations. If it
is feared that employers will abuse this relationship by contributing
and deducting more than is necessary to fund the obligations and later
recovering these funds, penalties equal to the value of the tax post-
ponement could be levied. If abuses can be handled as they develop,
similar tax treatment of the employer contributions to the two funds
would seem appropriate. Nowhere does anyone seem to have questioned
the deductibility of the employer contribution to OASDHI.
Surrey holds out the possibility that employer contributions could
be held deductible for the employer but considered as income to the
employee, hut, that this treatment would apply only where the em-
ployee receives a vested interest in the fund. Where the employee has
no vested interest, he cannot be held to have received anything of
value for his consumption or increased net worth and so he should
not be taxed.
This treatment seems to misconstrue the meaning of the term
"vested." Vesting does not customarily mean that the employee is
assured of a payment from the fund. It does mean that even though
he leaves his present employer, he will be eligible for a retirement
PAGENO="0182"
176 OLD AGE ll~~COM.E ASSURANCE-PART III
pension, but, only if he lives to the prescribed retirement age. Should
he die before that time, he will receive little or nothing. The vesting
provision is, in effect, no different from the conditions of the OAT pro-
gram. Yet, apparently, no one has argued that the employer's contri-
bution under that program be considered taxable income to the
employee.
Contributions by employees to pension funds are taxed to the em-
ployee and this may be considered proper, although it seems to differ
from the treatment proposed in this paper for employee contributions
under OAT. However, employee contributions under pension plans
customarily belong irrevocably to the employee and will be returned
to him even if he should die before retirement. They are, in effect, a
form of savings. This arrangement differs significantly from that
existing under OAT. It should also be noted that unlike OAT where
financing is shared equaJly by employers and employees, financing of
private pension plans by employee contributions is the exception
ratl1er tha.n the rule.
Only the tax treatment of pension fuuds remains. The preference
here would .depend on one's philosophy of business taxation. Earnings
of proprietorships are imputed to owners and taxed. A part of cor-
porate profits is usually neither paid to stockholders nor imputed to
them, and so the corporate income tax is levied as an indirect way of
reaching the increased net worth of the stockholder. In the case of
pension funds, the beneficiaries of increased net. worth will be those
contributors who live to retirement; but, they have no present tan-
gible claim, and, hence, no increase in net worth. Nor will they have
a claim until they retire, and even then the amount will .depend on
how long they live. Viewing the situat.ion from another standpoint, we
already grant to life insurance companies. savings and loan associA-
tions, and the OSDI fund, a low rate of tax, or no tax at all, on earn-
ings. Thus, the definition of income and the treatment of similar sav-
ings institutions both argue for low rates or a zero rate of tax on the
earnings of pension funds.
The document prepared by the subcommittee notes that the exist-
ing tax treatment of pension plans is often supported by comparing
it with the tax favor given by the deferral of tax on unrealized asset
appreciation. The present writer reaches the same conclusion that the
exist.ing tax treatment of pension plans is justified. but on entirely dif-
ferent grounds. The comparison cited is. in fac.t, a weak foundation on
which to base the. taxat.ion of nension plans. Tn the first place, many
economists would argue t.hat increases in asset value provide a basis
for taxation, whet.her or not they are realized. But.. second and more
important, increases in asset values are forms of savimr, while pension
plans do not provide saving, but., insurance. The difference between
the two is significant.
In sum, the argument. that pension plans and similar deferred corn-
pensation arrangements receive tax preference and provide the aged
with a tax-forgiveness or tax-deferral subsidy is not i-a]id. Given the
concept of income that underlies our income tax, and given the tax
treatment. of OAT benefits, railroad retirement benefits, and most other
retirement. plans. pension plans are. not. receiving more favorable or
preferential treatment. There would seem to be no tax subsidy to this
form of old-age income.
PAGENO="0183"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 177
4. DOUBLE ExE~rrTIoN
Taxpayers over age 65 are allowed a double exemption when comput-
ing their taxes. Since a. double exemption is given to only a few other
taxpayers; i.e.,'those who are blind and those students who have ad-
justed gross income but are also dependents, it may be argued that this
provision constitutes tax preference for the aged.
While taxpayers over age 65 find their after-tax income increased
because of this provision, this gain is subject to the general criticism
previously cited: The benefit goes to those persons over 65 who have
income high enough to be taxable, and the value of the benefit and the
revenue lost to the Government vary directly with the taxpayer's mar-
ginal tax bracket-the greatest tax saving going to those whose incomes
are the highest.
In 1960 there were 6,668,000 additional $600 exemptions taken be-
cause of age (10, pp. 11, 95). This amounts to over $4 billion of income
that may have escaped tax. How much revenue is lOSt by the extra
exemption depends on the marginal tax rates of those taking the ex-
einption; in 1959 Wilbur J. Cohen estimated the cost at $600 million
(2, p. 542). The figure is doubtless higher now because of the increase
in the number of persons over age 65 and the rise in annual average
incomes.
The extra exemption was added in 1948 because, according to the
Senate report on the revenue bill, the rise in prices that occurred during
the war and in the postwar period and the increase in taxes during the
war imposed a burden on older persons which they could not offset by
accepting full-time jobs at prevailing high wages. Since high prices
and high taxes apply to all persons without regard to age, higher ex-
emptions might well have been granted to all persons. If `the concern
were over the fixed income `aspect of the problem, favorable treatment
could be given to all who held such securities as bonds, savings accounts,
life insurance, and fixed pensions and annuities, and not to those who
owned homes, real estate, or common stocks. But, this opens a Pan-
dora's box of requests for tax treatment reflecting the effects of price
level changes on all assets.
A natural sympathy extends to those who are old and it may be that
society believes they deserve to receive more income before they are
required to pay tax. This means, however, that younger persons with
the same income will pay a higher tax, even though their problems may
be equally or more serious, but different, revolving around educating
their children, buying a home, financing a business, or providing for
their old age. One economist has noted that it is entirely possible that
the young can outearn the old.
The President has proposed that the additional exemption for per-
sons over age 65 be discontinued and that in its place be substituted
a special exemption that is much higher, being approximately equal
to the present extra exemption, the additional standard deduction
related to the exemption, and the maximum primary social security
benefit, which is now exempt from tax (8, pp. 198-207). This proposal
will exempt a man and his wife, both age 65, from any income tax
until their income exceeds $5,777. A younger worker with a wife and
the same income from wages and using a standard deduction would
pay $810 in income tax and $254 in social security tax. Even if the
PAGENO="0184"
178 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
younger family included two children, the taxes would be $301 and
$254, respectively. Obviously this preferred treatment of the elderly
is of considerable aid to them. In fact, under the President's proposal
preferential treatment may continue until the income of the elderly
couple reaches $15,200. There would seem to be some question as to
the desirability of extending tax preferences to persons at this level
of income just because they are 65 or older.
The 1?roposed new exemption is intended to benefit only low- and
middle-income taxpayers and is designed to disappear as incomes rise.
A. simpler and more understandable way to achieve the same result
would be to increase the progressivity of the tax rates. If it is honestly
felt that a certain mimmum sum is needed to support the taxpayer
over 65 and that all income over tha.t amount should be taxed, the de-
duction should apply to all taxpayers over 65 and not just to those
with relatively low or modest incomes.
The disappearing exemption also creates a tax rate anomoly in that
over the income range where it disappears, the tax rate is suddenly
doubled. Not. only is the extra dollar of income taxed, but., since a. dollar
of deduction is lost, a second dollar appears in the tax base.
To summarizeS both the existing and proposed extra exemptions nmst
be supported with arguments as to why the needs of the elderly
exceed those of the young. If there are such needs, they might. better
be handled as special deductions, as is done with the medical expense
deduction. The benefits, estimated at $600 million in 1959, go to only
those older persons whose incomes are high enough to make them tax-
able. and the tax saving is again greater for those in higher income
brackets. In 1964 over 600.000 tax returns of persons over 65 showed
adjusted ross income over $10,000 and for this group tax benefits were.
thelargest (11,1). 89).
5. RETIREMENT INCOME CREDIT
The retirement income credit. is one of those provisions that arose be-
cause of the. most-favored-taxpayer philosophy. Social security and
railroad retirement benefits were exempt from tax, but other forms of
retirement. income were not. Hence, the Internal Revenue Code was
changed, iii 1954, to allow the taxpayer a credit at the minimum tax
rate on other forms of retirement income up to an amount roughly
comparable to the maximum primary social security benefit.
Here is a provision whose cost and distribution can be readily de-
termined.
TABLE Ill-RETIREMENT INCOME CREDIT, 1964
Number of
Adjusted gross income returns
Amount of
credit
(thousand)
Average
psr return
Under$1,000to$5,000 714,187 $67,119 $93.98
$5,000 to $10,000 358,317 55,364 157.30
$10,000 to $50,000 209, 911 33, 693 160.51
$50,000 to $1,000,000 pies 17, 687 2,897 163.79
Total 1,300,102 160, 073
Source: Statistics of Income, Individual, 1964, p. 90.
PAGENO="0185"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSIJRANCE-PART Iii 179
Given the exemption of certain forms of retirement income, the
retirement income credit may be justified to some extent on grounds
of horizontal equity. However, the provision applies on1y to invest-
ment income, is reduced if the taxpayer has wage income, arid is com-
pletely eliminated if his wage income is as much as $3,000. Thus, it.
is not all income of the aged that benefits from this provision but only
certain forms. Further, wage income suffers relative to retirement in-
come not only by being taxable but also by reducing the tax credit.. In
effect, a tax rate from one and a half to two tini~s as high as normal is
imposed on this limited amount of wage income between $1,200 and
$3,000 for single persons over 65.
If social security benefits are made taxable, as has been proposed
above, the justification for the retirement income credit disappears.
If social security benefits continue nontaxable, support on grounds of
eqmty for a retirement income credit will depend on whether one
thinks this form of income should be treated like tax-exempt social
security benefits or like taxable wages. in a period of relatively full
employment, there would seem to be little reason for taxing labor in-
come more heavily than nonlabor income; and even in a period of un-
employment a better policy might be to increase effective demand
rather than to e.ncourage people to leave the labor force.
The President's proposals also include an elimination of the retire-
ment income credit., on the grounds that it is a complicated provision
and that it discriminates against wage income, but the proposal in-
cludes a larger exemption to offset the abandonment of the credit. The
increased exemption has been discussed earlier in this paper.
The retirement income credit has two advantages most other tax
measures lack: it is not so expensive in total, constituting less than 10
percent of the total tax benefits to those over 65, and the value of the
benefit does not increase as the taxpayer's marginal tax rate rises.
However, the discrimination against wage income and the fact that
almost 50 percent of the benefits go to persons with more than
$6,000 adjusted gross income indicate that the same sum could be spent
more effectively if the goal is to assure minimum incomes for the aged.
6. CoNcLusioNs
The tax measures that have been disc.ussed do not exhaust the forms
in which preference is given to older persons. There are or have been
other provisions that give liberal medical deductions, reduce the prop-
erty tax on homes of the elderly, and postpone t.he payment of tax on a
gain from the sale of a residence, but these are minor factors in the
total tax picture. The tax measures that have been discussed at length,
and the tax treatment of closely related forms of income such as that
from self-employment retirement plans, military retirement benefits.
civil service retirement benefits, etc., are the source of most of the tax
benefits.
These measures gave rise to an estimated $2.3 billion in tax reduc-
t.ions which, according to Treasury figures, were distributed among
the elderly approximately as follows:
About 40 percent of this population had too little income to be tax-
able, even without the tax preference, and so received no benefit;
PAGENO="0186"
180 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
About 45 percent of the elderly had less than $5,000 of adjusted
gross income but enough to have been taxable and they received about
50 percent of the tax saving;
The remaining 15 percent of the population had adjusted gross
income over 85.000 and received the other half of the $2.3 billion in
benefits.
It may be that this was the distribution of aid that was intended,
but it does not accord with the usual emphasis on helping those with
less than prescribed levels of income. Further, in the context of lim-
ited resources, more aid to one group means less aid to another.
A first step would seem to be the resolution of the questions raised
by the subcommittee regarding the goals of income for the aged. Once
this is done, tax favor may be considered as a form of implementation;
but the disadvantages such as the shotgun nature of the device, its
failure to benefit those who are not. taxable, the complexity tax favor
adds to t.he code, the uncertainty as to cost, the departure from the equal
treatment of persons with equal incomes, and the usual distribution
of benefits in direct proportion to income should all be considered be-
fore tax preference is adopted as the way to achieve the ends.
LITERATURE CITED
1. Burns, Eveline M., "Taxation of the Aged: Retirement Income Credit and
the Like," in U.S. House. Committee on Ways and Means, Tow Revision
Compendium, Vol. 1, pp. 551-557.
2. Cohen, Wilbur J., "Income and Tax Status of the Aged: Present Situation
and Possible Modifications of Existing Policies," in U.S. House, Commit-
tee on Ways and Means, Tan Revision. Compendium, Vol. 1, pp. 539-550.
3. Muutz, Raymond, "Social Security and the Personal Income Tax," in U.S.
House, Committee on Ways and Means, Tax Revision Compendium, Vol.
1, pp. 353-363.
4. i\Iusgrave, Richard A., "The Incidence of the Tax Structure aad Its Effects
on Consumption," in U.S. Joint Committee on the Economic Report. Federal
Tax Policy for Economic Growth and Stability, pp. 96-113 (1955).
5. Social Security Bulletin, Annual Statistical Supplement, 1957.
6. Social Security Bulletin, Annual Statistical Supplement, 1965.
7. Tax Foundation, Inc., Tax Burdens and Benefits of Government Expendi-
tures by Income Class, 1961 and. 1965.
S. U.S. House, Committee on Ways and Means, "Hearing: President's Proposals
for Revision in the Social Security System," March 1-3, 1967.
9. U.S. Internal Revenue Code of 1954.
10. U.S. Internal Revenue Service, Statistics of Income, 1960, Individual Income
Tan Returns.
11. U.S. Internal Revenue Service, Statistics of Income, 1964, Individual In-
come Tan Returns.
12. U.S. Joint Economic Committee, Subcommittee on Fiscal Policy, "Hearings:
Private Pension Plans," May 1966.
13. U.S. Senate, Special Committee on Aging, "Hearings: Tax Consequences of
Contributions to Needy Older Relatives," June 15, 1966.
14. Vickrey, William, Agenda for Progressive Taxation, New York, 1947.
PAGENO="0187"
SOME ECONOMIC EFFECTS OF HIGH TAXES FOR
SOCIAL INSURANCE
BY ELIZABETH DERAN*
I. INTRODUCTION
Some people maintain that a. dog around the house poses little
trouble relative to the pleasures of pet ownership. But, more than one
softhearted householder has found himself permanent heir to multiple
descendants from an original pet. As the size of the pet population
increases, small irritations become transformed into major problems,
even though each successive animal may not differ from the original
in any significant respect. The owner discovers that minor defects
inherent in any pet and perfectly tolerable in small quantities at some
point in an expansion become overwhelmingly disruptive.
Something of the sort threatens in the case of the payroll tax which
finances the social security system.' No one can pinpoint the particular
stage at which the shortcomings of the social security tax turn into
serious problems, hut it seems likely that the crucial period has already
arrived, or certainly will arrive before the final stage of the presently
scheduled increases has taken effect. When receipts from a tax account
for 17 percent of total internal revenue collections, are 72 percent the
size of the collections from the corporation income tax and 37 percent
the individual income tax-as Treasury estimates for the OASDHI
tax in fiscal 1967-then the tax surely has grown large enough that its
effects become meaningful to the economy. When a tax has reached a
level at which it can exert an important influence on business and family
decisions, then surely the time has come to examine its characteristics
carefully. We ~houid consider to what. extent this tax may be counter-
balanced by other factors operating in the economy, whether its ad-
vantages compensate for its disruptions, how it might be modified,
and then take appropriate action. Yet, very little attention has been
directed to the tax aspects of the social security system since the early
1940's, although the other side of the coin-benefits-has evoked almost
continuous discussion and publications.
This paper considers some of the economic distortions which might
follow when the social security tax is levied at a high enough rate for its
effect to be significant. The problems involved in changing to some
* Senior research analyst, Tax Foundation, Inc.
NOTE: The views expressed in this paper are the author's and do not neces-
sarily reflect the views ~f the Tax Foundation.
I The term "social securIty" as used In this paper encompasses only the Federal old~age.
survivors. disability, and health insurance (OASDIII) program, although in the national
inc°me accounts social security includes unemployment insurance, railroad retirement,
civil service retirement, and other public systems.
181
PAGENO="0188"
182 OLD AGE TXCOME ASSITRAXCE~PART III
other form of financing are examined, and some tentative suggestions
for avoiding or reducing the more dangerous effects are offered.
The nature of the social security tax is such that its effect must be
considered in the personal world o~ individual households and families
as well as in the. world of business and industry. Fndeniably, these two
sectors of the economy intertwine endlessly, but. even the most simple
story cannot be told in one breath. Since the effect of the OASDHI
tax on the economy is far from simple, the analysis will be divided
into two artificial groupings: the tax on employers and the tax on
employees.
II. THE TAX ON THE EMPLOYER
A corporation employing 10 persons. with net. profits up to $13,000,
pays more social security tax than Federal income tax.2 The break-
even point for a 1~-employee firm lies at S19.T73: for a 20-employee
firm, at 826.154. Since no figures are available for net. profit by em-
ployee size, one can only speculate how many firms fail below these
break-even points. Clearly new businesses, those engaged in labor-
intensive lines, and loss firms are most. likely to accrue OASDHI tax
liability in excess of their Federal income tax liability.
OASIDHI taxes need not exceed corporation incomes taxes, how-
ever, before they exert pressure on entrepreneurial decisions. As a
levy on a specific factor of production. this tax qualifies as a prime
candidate for the deflection of business choices whenever its absolute
amount reaches high enough levels that adjustments to reduce the. tax
become prac.tical.
Taxes can exert an effect on the econom in two broad ways: (1)
The taxpayer may take action t.o reduce the tax's pinch on himself,
and his tax-reducing activity then initiates repercussions in `the econ-
omy; or (2) the t.axnayer may decide he cannot mitigate the effect
of the tax (or learns from unsuccessful attempts that he cannot do so)
and then makes adjustments to the lower income position in which he
finds himself. The effects on the economy in case of (2) will not differ
under two kinds of tax (say, a payroll tax and an income tax) of
equal yield, provided the same taxpayers are subject. to both taxes.
But in case of (1), the nature of the tax can make a considerable dif-
ference in the available avenues of escape and the consequent effects
on the economy. One would expect particularly differentiated behavior
when the tax (viewed from the perspective of the employer) applies
to a. specific factor of product.ion, as does the payroll tax financing the
OASDHT system.3 As it. turns out1 the OASDHI tax not only induces
some general effects unlike those from other taxes; it appears also to
affect one industry quite differently from another.
2 Counting the matching employer portion only and assuming salaries of 86.600 or more.
Throunliout this section generally, the assumption is made that the employer must contend
with that portion of the tax levied directly on him, and only that portion. In at least one
case, however, employees apparently were able to shift their tax to employers, and the
possibility should he considered that the figures mentioned in this section should, at the
outer limit, he doubled to take account of the contingency that employees may shift some
or nIl of the tax to employers in the form of higher wages: (See Elizabeth Dernn, "Channes
in Factor Tarrine Shares Under the Social Security Tax," scheduled to be published in the
November 1967 Review of EconomIcs and Statistics.)
2 The same tax when viewed from the persnectiv' of the employee appfl'~n to enrnlngs
but differs sharply from any income tax to which he ordinarily may be subject.
PAGENO="0189"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 183
COMPARATIVE CAPITAL SUBSTITUTION INCENTIVES
Since the OASD1HI tax applies to wages and salaries, an employer
can reduce his tax liability by changing his factor mix so as to reduce
labor utilization in achieving a given product goal. The most obvious
approach lies in the introduction or expansion of laborsaving capital
equipment. The practicability of such an adjustment, however, de-
pends heavily on industry conditions.
The strength of at least four of the barriers to a tax-reducing sub-
stitution of equipment relates to industry conditions. Technical prob-
lems, high absolute cost, financing difficulties, and/or union opposition
to substitution can present formidable obstacles in some industries, but
n&ver arise in others.4 Technical problems unique to the industry can
limit or preclude the availability of laborsaving equipment. For in-
stance, despite years of experimentation, farm machinery engineers
have failed to invent a practical machine to pick grapes. Vending
machines can function as surrogate clerks, but in a sharply limited
way. For still other industries, remarkable laborsaving equipment
exists, but its absolute cost can be formidable, or its scale may prove
unsuitable for any but the largest firms. Petroleum refining provides
one such example. In yet other industries, an almost trivial piece of
equipment, such as an electric screwdriver, can save considerable
amounts of labor, yet financing difficulties may preclude even modest
outlays for additional equipment. For example, mobile home maim-
facturers, as a group, report acute difficulty in obtaining financial sup-
port and generally must borrow from relatives or friends-a situation
which makes substitution of laborsaving equipment a remote possi-
bility. Union resistance to automation seems more determined in some
industries-newspaper publishing, for instance-than in others, and
may act as a significant barrier to an otherwise feasible change in labor-
capital proportions.
In those industries where such difficulties can be overcome, there
remains the question of the price at which a given piece of equipment,
with known laborsaving potential and durability, should be purchased.
The answer depends primarily on the current price of the con-
templated equipment vis-a-vis the discounted cost of labor which will
be saved over the expected life of the equipment.5 The large increase
authorized by the Social Security Act of 1965 (particularly the base
increase from $4,800 to $6,600) makes a marked difference in the
second variable, opening widely differing opportunities for tax-saving
capital substitution which, while peculiar to one period, illustrates the
general point that the significance of the payroll tax varies from one
industry to the next. The increased base makes little difference in
total tax liability in those industries where the average wage lies near
the old base. But, the effect of the base increase is sharply felt in
those industries where average wages exceed the old base, amounting
to as much as $75 additional tax liability per employee in 1966 (con-
sidering the employer's share alone) and successively higher amounts
in subsequent years as the rate automatically increases.
Other variables associated with investment decisions-uncertainty of future tax treat-
ment of capital goods, uncertainty as to the Income stream which will be generated by the
additional investment, and the risk of decreased flexibility in output levels associated with
a larger fixed investment-seems less Immediately linked to industry variables.
Other considerations may include the effect of the substitution on the quality of output
and associated changes In the amount of nonlabor Inputs.
PAGENO="0190"
184 OLD AGE INcOME ASSURANCE-PART III
The OAS1DI-ll-induced increase in the discounted cost of an average
worker for selected industries appears in table 1. The discounted
present values (at 5 percent) of the OASDHI tax on one worker
under previously scheduled rates and under the new rates 6 are com-
puted for a 10-year period. Since in all but a few of the industries
listed, the average annual wage exceeds the $4,800 base, the present
value of the tax exhibits a relatively small range under the old rates.
On the other hand, because the $6,600 base lies above the average for
many of the listed industries, the present value of the tax under the
new law varies widely by industry.
TABLE 1.-PRESENT VALUE OF EMPLOYER OASDHI TAX ON 1 WORKER, 1966-75, BY INDUSTRY
Average
annual
earnings 1
1966 value of
1966-75taxo
n 1 worker2
Under prior
law
Under 1965
amendments
Additional
tax under
1965
amendments
All mineral industries
Metal mining
Anthracite mining
Bituminous coal and lignite mining
Oil and gas extraction
Nonmetallic minerals mining
All manufacturing industries
Food and kindred products
Tobacco manufacturing
Textile mill products
Apparel and other
Lumber and wood products
Furniture and fixtur*s
Paper and allied products
Print, publishing, etc
Chemicals and allied
Production of petroleum and coal
Rubber and plastic products
Leather and leather products
Stone, clay, and glass
Primary metal industries
Fabricated metal products
Machinery, except electric
Electrical machinery and services
Transportation equipment and ordnance
Instruments, etc
Miscellaneous manufacturing
All wholesale and retail trade
Wholesale trade
Retail trade
All services
Hotel, roominghouses, etc
Personal service
Miscellaneous business service
Automobile repair service
Miscellaneous repair service
Motion pictures
Amusement and recreation
$6, 800
7,200
6, 400
7, 000
6, 500
6,400
5, 800
4,800
4,600
3,900
4,700
5, 100
6,600
6, 500
7, 600
8, 300
6, 200
4, 200
6, 300
7, 600
6,700
7, 300
6, 600
8, 000
7,000
5,200
5,400
7,200
4,700
4,300
3,700
4,200
6,200
5, 000
6,600
6,000
4,900
1, 670
1,670
1, 670
1, 670
1, 670
1,670
1, 670
1,670
1,600
1,357
1, 635
1, 670
1,670
1, 670
1, 670
1, 670
1, 670
1,461
1, 670
1, 670
1, 670
1, 670
1, 670
1, 670
1,670
1,670
1,670
1,670
1,635
1,496
1,287
1,461
1,670
1, 670
1, 670
1,670
1, 670
2, 459
2,459
2, 385
2, 459
2, 422
2,385
2, 161
1,788
1,714
1,453
1,751
1, 900
2,459
2, 422
2, 459
2, 459
2, 310
1, 565
2, 347
2, 459
2, 459
2,459
2, 459
2, 459
2,459
1,937
2,012
2,459
1,751
1,602
1,378
1,565
2,310
1, 863
2, 459
2,236
1, 826
789
789
715
789
752
715
491
118
114
96
116
230
789
752
789
789
640
104
677
789
789
789
789
789
789
267
342
789
116
106
91
104
640
193
789
566
156
1 For 1965, rounded to nearest $100.
~At 5 percent compound interest, computed as follows: Value under prior tax=.34789W, W $4,800. Value under 1965
amendments=.372587W, W $6,600.
Source: U.S. Department of Commerce. The National Income and Products Accounts of the United States, 1929-65,
table 6, 5, p. 109.
The differences between the two sets of discounted OASDHI tax
values suggest how much more an employer c.an now consider paying
for laborsaving machinery per labor unit replaced, as a consequence
of the tax increase. The largest differeflce occurs in the industries with
average salaries equal to or exceeding the new base. For instance, in
The new rates for the employer portion of tax are 4.2 percent in 1066; 4.4, 1067-68;
4.9, 1069-72; 5.4, 1973-7,5. The rates continue to rise until they reach 5.65 percent in 1987:
the base remains at $6,600 annually throughout. The old rates are: 4.125 in 1966-67; 4.625
in 1068; and thereafter, on a $4,800 base.
PAGENO="0191"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 185
manufacturing of transportation equipment, to take one example, the
value of the additional tax on one worker for 10 years comes to $789.
Suppose a manufacturer of transportation equipment had been con-
sidering a piece of equipment which would last 10 years and replace
10 men, but, with a price somewhat too high. The 1965 amendment
might make the contemplated investment worthwhile, since it in-
creased by $7,890 the discounted value of the labor to be replaced. But,
for such equipment the increased value of the replaced labor in the
case of the operator of a hotel would amount to only $910; or of a
retailer, $1,160.~
OTHER TAX ADJUSTMENT ACTION
Capital substitution, however, represents but one of many steps the
employer might take to reduce the actual burden of his tax liability.
The stub of table 2 outlines four other possible courses of action, plus
the barriers which miight interfere with successful implementation of
each action. A moment's consideration of the table reveals that the
strength of the barriers and the consequent appeal of each action
largely depend on industry constraints.
TABLE 2.-ESTIMATED STRENGTH DF BARRI ERS TO POTENTIAL TAX-ADJUSTING ACTIONS, 3 SELECTED INDUSTRIES
Potential action and barriers
Strengt
-
Automobile
manufacturer
h of barrier conf ronting-
Grapagrower
Department
store owner
Action-Reduce wages, or withhold increases:
Barriers:
(a) Strong union
(b) Long-term contract in effect
(c) Demand for labor high
(d) Employer's compassion
Action-Increase product price:
Barriers:
Strong
do
Moderate
Weak
Weak
do
Moderate
Strong
Moderate.
Do.
Weak.
Moderate.
(a) Fear general sales reduction
(b) Fear loss of sales to competitors
(c) Fear antitrust authorities
(d) Sufficient increases lead to awkward pricing...
(e) Generally tow level of prosperity in economy~
Action-Substitute skilled workers:
Moderate
do
Strong
Weak
Moderate
Moderate
Strong
Weak
do
Strong
Do.
Strong.
Weak.
Moderate.
Do.
Barriers:
(a) Insufficient supply of workers
(b) Substitution would not increase productivity
enough.
Action-Reduce nonlabor costs:
do
Strong
Moderate
Weak
Do.
Do.
Barriers:
(a) Suppliers not amenable to pressure
(b) Most nonlabor costs relatively fixed
Action-Substitute laborsaving capital equipment:
Barriers:
Moderate
do
Strong
do
Strong.
Moderate.
(a) Technical problems
(b) High absolute cost
(c) Financing problems
(d) Union opposition
Weak
Moderate
do
do
do
Weak
Moderate
Weak
Strong.
Weak.
Moderate.
Weak.
Subjective estimates of the strength of each barrier have been made
for three divergent industries chosen for illustrative purposes. The
reaction of employers in each of these industries and the probability of
successful tax-shifting activity turn out quite differently in each case.
To take one possible course of action, wage rate deduction:
Some simultaneous increase in the price of the machinery seems probable, the amount
depending, in part, on how labor Intensive the appropriate capital goods industry might be
and how successfully It Is able to pass on its own OASDHI tax increase via higher prices.
Because of the unavailability of data on which to base a meaningful adjustment ~for
variance about the mean, table 1, to some degree, overstates the present value of tlse tax.
In the case of those industry subgroups and individual workers who lle below the industry
mean, the increase in the mean will not affect their present value, or will affect it less
than the average indicated.
PAGENO="0192"
186 OLD AGE IXCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
The necessity of dealing with a powerful union and the proba-
bility of a long-term contract currently in effect present formi-
dable obstacles to the auto manufacturer, but virtually none to the
grape grower and only moderate ones to the usual department
store owner.
The level of demand for labor probably affects the department
store owner least, since he can call on young people just entering
the labor market, housewives, and, because of the timing of his
peaks with respect to other businesses, moonlighting employees
from other industries. The grape grower, on the other hand, can-
not rely on such labor since his work calls for endurance and a
degree of skill, and time pressures imposed by the nature of his
product sharply limit the practicability of using moonlighters.
Similar problems confront the auto manufacturer.
The employer's compassion seems most likely to interfere with
wage reduction in the case of the gra.pe grower, who generally
obtains his workers from cultural groups with large families and
consequently high levels of need compared with their relatively
low wages. Since average earnings in auto manufacturing lie at
approximately double those in retail trade, compassion introduces
relatively little deterrent in the former a.nd perhaps moderate
deterrent in the latter.
All barriers considered, then, the auto manufacturer probably has
little hope of decreasing wage rates, the grape grower perhaps can do
so if his pity does not interfere, and the department store owner may
have a reasonable chance. of passing on the tax via wage cuts or with-
holding of raises.
Similarly, differences in the effectiveness of the barriers may be ob-
served in connection with increasing the price of the product, substitut-
ing skilled workers,8 reducing nonlabor costs, and substituting labor-
saving capital equipment, not only for the three industries chosen for
illustration in table 2, but for almost any group the reader might select
from differing major industry categories. Employers in some indus-
tries will find they can implement several of the tax-adjusting actions
with relative ease; others perhaps can undertake only one such a.ction,
and tha.t with difficulty; yet others will be effectively blocked from any
tax-adjusting action at all and consequently must bear the full weight
of the tax themselves.
AVERAGE RATE OF A TAX BY INDUSTRY
One rather drastic, and necessarily longrun, adjustment to the tax
comes a.bout if employers change product or line of business in an effort
to minimize the tax.9 As long as all industries receive approximately
equivalent treatment, such tax-induced movement would offer no gain.
But, if the typical rate of tax varies from one industry to the next, a
high enough rate can, over the long run, force entrepreneurs out of the
heavily taxed areas and into the favored ones.
The advantage from using skilled workers relates to the base ceiling. For instance, three
semiskilled employees at an annual salary of $6,000 each create (at 1907 rates) an em-
plover tax liability of $S30. If two highly skilled workers at $9,000 annually can produce
eqi~lvOent output, total salary will be equal In both cases, but the OASDHI tax liability
will come to only $550, for a tax saving of $256.
° This adjustment may not be made so much by existing employers as by new employers
who enter a low-tax Industry, rather than a high-tax Industry when the latter would be
preferable on nontax grounds alone.
PAGENO="0193"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 187
Because it is imposed on one cost of production-labor-the
OASDIEH tax falls with peculiarly uneven impact from one industry
to the next. If the effective rate of tax is measured with respect to
wages and salaries, the tax falls with relatively heavy force on labor-
intensive industries. At the same time (and not predictably operating
in either a compensating or reinforcing direction), the tax falls with
comparatively light impact on those industries with average wages
higher than the maximum tax base, since it applies at a uniform rate
only up to a specified maximum of wages and salaries. In fact, by al-
most any measure one might select, social security taxes show a wide
range in the intensity of their impact on differing industries.
Useful material on annual social security tax collections by industry
has not been generally available. Fortunately, the Social Security Ad-
ministration was able to provide unpublished data for 1963, a year in
which the Department of Commerce conducted a number of full-
scale economic censuses. Computations relating tax collection data to
some of the industrial data available appear in table 3~b0
Three ratios were selected: Tax liability as a percent of total wages
(T/W), tax liability as a percent of value added (T/VA), and tax
liability as a percent of value of shipments (T/VS). A comparison of
T/W for a group of industries shows the relative impact of the tax
considered as a levy on payroll; T/VA and T/VS illustrate how sig-
nificant the tax is relative to other costs of production. Ideally, yet
another ratio, with some measure of profits for the denominator, would
have completed the picture, but suitable data could not be found.
TABLE 3.-EMPLOYER OASDI TAX LIABILITY AS PERCENT OF TOTAL WAGES, VALUE ADDED, AND VALUE
OF SHIPMENTS, BY INDUSTRY, 1963
Total
OASDI
OASDI tax liabi
percent of
Iity as
-
Quartile I
Industry tax
liability
(millions)
Total Value
wages added
Value
of T/W T/VA T/VS
ship-
ments
All mineral industries ~100. 07 2. 68 0. 63 0. 46
Metal mining 13. 04 2. 50 . 92 61 1 1 2
Anthracite mining 1. 88 3. 20 1. 56 .79 3 4 3
Bituminous coal and lignite mining 21. 80 2. 86 1. 34 . 91 2 2 4
Oil and gas extraction 44. 06 2. 56 . 40 . 30 1 1 1
Nonmetallic minerals mining 19. 28 2. 89 1. 10 . 82 2 1 4
All manufacturing industries 2, 647. 81 2. 65 1. 38 . 63
Food and kindred products 255. 56 2.96 1. 17 .37 2 2 1
Tobacco manufacturing 12. 31 3. 72 . 73 . 27 4 1 1
Textile mill products 114.66 3.39 1.87 .73 4 4 3
Apparel and other 145. 05 3.27 1. 84 .85 3 4 4
Lumber and wood products 72.20 3. 09 1.79 .78 3 4 3
Furniture and fixtures 52.27 3.03 1.70 .89 2 4 4
Paper and allied products 99. 56 2. 84 1.34 .61 1 2 2
Printing, publishing, etc 139. 88 2. 54 1. 33 . 87 1 2 4
Chemicals and allied 155. 49 3. 13 . 88 .49 3 1 2
Production of petroleum and coal 36. 64 3. 23 . 99 . 20 3 1 1
Rubber and plastic products 65. 18 2. 76 1. 40 . 71 1 3 2
Leather and leather products 41. 16 3. 35 1. 08 . 98 4 4 4
Stone, clay, and gloss 99. 93 3. 11 1. 42 . 81 3 3 3
Primary metal industries 202. 68 2. 62 1. 34 . 57 1 2 2
Fabricated metal products 188. 33 2. 95 1. 60 . 82 2 4 3
Machinery, except electric 262. 04 2. 74 1. 52 . 86 1 3 3
Electrical machinery and services 238. 07 2. 56 1. 40 . 80 1 3 3
Transp3rtation equipment 301. 56 2. 58 1. 32 . 54 1 2 2
Instruments, etc 57.96 3.03 1.45 .95 2 3 4
Miscellaneous manufacturing 52.13 2.88 1.46 .80 2 3 3
Footnote at end of table.
1O Less extensive but similar compntations for 1957 and 1962 appear In "Economic
Aspects of the Social Security Tax," New York, Tax Foundation, 1966, p. 22.
83-200-67-pt. 3-13
PAGENO="0194"
188 OLD AGE INCOME ASSIJRANCE-PART III
TABLE 3.-EMPLOYER OASDI TAX LIABILITY AS PERCENT OF TOTAL WAGES, VALUE ADDED, AND VALUE
OF SHIPMENTS, BY INDUSTRY, 1963-Continued
Industry
Total
OASDI
tax
liability
(millions)
OASDI tax liabi
percent of
Total Value
wages added
Iity as
-
Value
of
ship.
ments
T/W
Quartile'
T/VA
T/VS
All wholesale and retail trade
1. 449. 40
3. 17
.24
Merchant wholesale
Building material and farm
General merchandise stores
Food stores
Auto dealers and service stations
Apparel and accessories
Furniture and home equipment
Eating and drinking places
Miscellaneous retail stores
518. 08
62. 60
172. 19
160. 88
169.29
64. 75
49. 05
144. 32
108.21
2. 86
3. 62
3. 39
3. 78
3.01
3. 31
3. 19
3. 55
3. 18
. 14
.43
. 47
. 28
.27
. 46
. 45
. 78
. 36
2
4
4
4
2
4
3
4
3
1
1
2
1
1
2
1
3
1
All services 2
383.95
3. 15
.86
Hotel, roominghouses, etc
Personel service
Miscellaneous business service
Automobile repair service
Miscellaneous repair service
Motion pictures
Amusement and recreation
54. 67
95. 64
117. 23
36. 71
19. 81
20. 02
39. 86
3. 80
3. 26
2. 86
3.23
2. 66
2. 73
3. 61
1. 08
1. 04
. 77
. 67
. 66
. 74
1. 00
4
3
2
3
1
1
4
4
4
3
2
2
3
4
Ranked from lowest to highest percentage, for all indsstries.
2 Excludes services for which no matching data could be found (medical, legal, education, etc.).
Source: Computations based on unpublished data provided by Social Security Administration; Department of Com-
merce, 1963 Census of Mineral Industry, 1963 Census of Business, 1963 Census of Manufacturing.
Table 3 shows values of T/WT for individual industries which range
from 2.50 percent for metal mining (low tax, reflecting high average
wages) to 3.79 percent (high tax, reflecting low average wages) for
hotels and other lodging places. This is to say, the rate applying to
hotels, etc., is a.bout 50 percent higher than that applying to metal
mining. Similar variation shows up within broad industrial groups.
Mineral industries ra.nge from the previously cited low for metal min-
ing up to 3.20 percent for anthracite mining. In manufacturing, print-
ing and publishing have the lowest T/W, 2.54 percent; tobacco has
the highest, 3.72 percent. Wholesale and retail trade run from 2.86
percent for merchant wholesalers to 3.78 percent for foodstores. Serv-
ices range from 2.66 percent for miscellaneous repair service to the
previously cited 3.79 percent for hotels and other lodgings.
T/VA varies from 0.40 percent for oil and gas extraction to 1.98
percent (five times higher) for the manufacture of leather and leather
products. T/VS ranges from 0.14 percent for merchant wholesalers to
1.08 percent (seven times higher) for hotels and lodgings.
The answer to the question, "Which of the three measures provides
the most realistic guide t.o how heavily the tax falls?" must remain
subjective. For some lines, however, all three measures show similar
relative positions. When the ratios for all 41 industries, listed in table
3, are ranked and divided into quartiles, six industries seem to be
lightly taxed no matter the basis chosen, and seven others, heavily
PAGENO="0195"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSTJRANCE-pART III
189
taxed on any criterion. All three ratios are in the first or second
quartile-i.e., lightly taxed relative to the median-for metal mining,
oil and gas extraction, and four lines of manufacturing-food and
kindred, paper and allied, primary metal, transportation equipment.
All three ratios fall into the third or fourth quartile-i.e., heavily
taxed relative to the median-for anthracite mining, and the manu-
facturing of four kinds of products-textile mill; lumber and wood;
apparel, leather, and leather products; and stone, clay, and glass.'1
For the majority of industries, the three measures indicate a mixed
position. Perhaps these differences yield some hint as to which tax-
adjusting action these industries are most likely to take. For instance,
a firm whose T/W lies in the bottom quartile but whose T/VA and
T/VS, in the upper ranges, might have more incentive to try to reduce
wages or introduce laborsaving equipment. Conversely, a low T/VS
and a high T/VA and T/W might incline a firm more toward attempt-
ing price increases.
ESTIMATED RESOURCE MISALLOCATION
The preceding material points up an important disadvantage of the
social security tax: an undeniable lack of neutrality. We can reason-
ably anticipate that the interindustry tax rate differentials, and oppor-
tunities for successful tax-adjusting behavior, will lead to changes,
with the net result a waste of some resources. Assuming that the pretax
pattern of production (in terms of input techniques and output com-
position) was as efficient as possible under all existing constraints
aside from the tax, then any changes made in response to the tax neces-
sarily will move the economy to a less efficient position.12
Some notion of how much tax distortions cost the economy can be
obtained by applying a method developed by Harberger for a similar
purpose in connection with the corporation income tax.'3 Harberger
has observed that "meticulously exact" results necessarily elude the
economist who aspires to measure waste, but adds that even estimates
with "substantial error" can be helpful in areas where intuitive judg-
ment is the alternative.'~ It is in such a spirit that the computations in
table 4 are presented. The absolute figures should be considered a first
approximation of the roughest sort, but nonetheless a better guide to
the underlying reality than the alternative-an uninformed guess.
11 In the case of those Industries for which only T/W and T/S could be computed, both
measures fell into Qi or Q2 for three lines (merchant wholesalers, auto dealers and service
stations, and miscellaneous repair services) and into Q3 or Q4 for four lines (eating and
drinking places,, hotels and lodging places, personal service, amusement and recreation).
12 It is my tentative belief, developed at greater length under the effect on the employee,
that such pretax efficiency does not necessarily exist, as a consequence of ordinary human
inertia. Under such circumstances, a tax increase can have a triggering effect on the tax-
payer. forcing him to take advantage of maximizing opportunities which have developed
since he last assessed his position, and possibly improving ecoaomywide resource allocation.
1~ Arnold C. Harberger, "The Corporation~ Income Tax: An Empirical Appraisal." in
U.S. Congress, Committee on Ways and Means, Tax Revision Compendium, November 1959,
pp. 23.1-250.
14 Harberger, "The Measurement of Waste," American Economic Review, May 1964,
pp. 58-76.
PAGENO="0196"
190 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
TABLE 4.-ESTIMATED COST OF DISTORTION UNDER OASDI TAX ON EMPLOYERS, SELECTED INDUSTRIES, 1963
OASDI tax
(millions)
OASDI tax as per
cent of national
income originat-
ing in industry
- Industry per-
centage minus
average
percentage
Cost of
distortion
(millions)
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
Farms $81.0 0.46 -1.16 $117.1
Agricultural services, forestry, and fisheries 19. 5 1. 62 0
Metal mining 13. 0 1. 62 0
Coal mining 21.8 1. 82 +. 20 2.4
Crude petroleum and natural gas 44. 1 1.52 -. 10 (1)
Mining and quarrying of nonmetallic minerals 19. 3 1. 93 +. 31 (1)
Contract construction 495. 2 2. 05 +. 43 22. 3
Food and kindred products 255.6 1.91 ±29 5.6
Tobacco manufactures 12. 3 1. 02 -. 60 2. 2
Textile mill products 114.7 2.44 +. 82 15.8
Apparel and other fabricated textile products 145. 0 2. 54 +. 92 24. 1
Paper and allied products 99.6 1.92 +. 30 2.3
Printing, publishing, and allied industries 139. 9 1. 92 ±. 30 3. 3
Chemicals and allied products 155.5 1.50 -.12 (1)
Petroleum refining and related industrias 36. 6 - 80 -. 82 15. 4
Rubber and miscellaneous plastic products 65.2 1.98 ±. 36 2. 1
Leather and leather products 41.2 2.42 +. 80 5.4
Lumber and wood products, except furniture - 72. 2 2. 00 ±. 38 2. 6
Furniture and fixtures 52.3 2.18 +. 56 3.8
Store, clay, and glass products 99. 9 1. 96 ±. 34 3. 0
Primary metal industries 202.7 1.76 ±. 14 1.2
Fabricated metal products 188. 3 2. 05 ±. 43 8. 5
Machinery, except electrical 262.0 1.87 ±. 25 4.3
Electrical machinery 238. 1 1.93 ±. 31 5.9
Transportation equipment and ordnance 356. 6 1. 61 -. 01 (1)
Instruments 58.0 1.66 +04 (1)
Miscellaneous manufacturing industries 52. 1 2. 08 +. 4~ 2.6
Local, suburban, and highway passenger transporta-
tion 45.2 2.66 +1.04 9.2
Motor freight transportation and warehousing 139. 8 2. 03 +41 5. 8
Water transportation 38. 2 2. 12 +. 50 2. 2
Air transportation 35. 8 1. 88 +. 26 (1)
Pipeline transportation 3.7 .92 -.70 (1)
Transportation services 12. 1 2.02 +40 (`)
Communication 129.1 1.32 -.30 4.4
Electric, gas, and sanitary services 112.4 1.09 -.53 14.4
Wholesale and retail trade 1,449.4 1.97 +35 44.8
Banking, credit agencies, holding and other invest-
mentcsmpanies 152.9 2.01 +39 5.8
Security and commodity brokers 19.6 1.40 -.22 (1)
lnsurance carriers, brokers, and real estate 236.1 .53 -1.09 264.9
Hotels and other lodging places 54.7 2.28 +. 66 5. 2
Personal services 95.6 1.80 -i-. 18 (1)
Mincollaneous business services 117.2 1.78 +. 16 (1)
Auto repair, auto services, and garages 36. 7 1. 67 +. 05 (1)
Miscellaneous repair services 19. 8 1. 52 -. 10 (1)
Motisn pictures 20.0 2.23 +. 61 1.7
Amusement and recreation services, except motion
pictures 39.9 2.00 +.38 1.4
Medical and other health services 223. 6 1. 66 +. 04 (1)
Legal services 22.7 .67 -.95 1.5
Nonprofit membership organizations 77.5 1.68 ±. 06 (1)
Miscellaneous professional services 65. 5 1. 39 -. 23 1. 2
All industries listed above 2 6,489.2 1.62 612.4
I Less than $1,000,000.
2 Excludes railruad transportation, education services, private households, government and government enterprises,
rest ef the world.
Source: Department of Commerce, "The National Income and Product Accounts of the United States, 1929-65," pp.
20-21; unpublished data provided by Social Security Administration.
The rationale of table 4 is that we may obtain some clue to the effect
of tax distortions on the structure of production by comparing results
under the existing tax with results under a theoretical flat rate tax of
equivalent yield, levied on each industry in proportion to its contribu-
tion to national income. The latter tax would be essentially neutral in
its effects.
Column 2 suggests the distortions inherent in the OASDI tax. The
tax, taken as a percentage of national income originating in each in-
dustry, amounts to an average of 1.62 percent for all the industries
PAGENO="0197"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART -iii 191
considered, but ranges from as low as 0.46 percent for farms to as high
as 2.66 percent for local, suburban, and highway transportation. Col-
unrn 3 presents the same information as column 2, but subtracts the
average percentage from each industry percentage to underline that
some industries suffer "overtaxation" and others enjoy "undertaxa-
tion."
Estimates of the cost of the tax distortion, based on two probably
unrealistic but computationally helpful assumptions, appear in column
4. These two assumptions are (1) that employers pass the tax forward
in the form of price adjustments, and (2) that the price elasticity of
demand approximates unity in all industries concerned. Granted these
assumptions, it follows that, because the tax-induced change in price
results in an equal percentage change in quantity in the opposite direc-
tion, production will be higher in an undertaxed industry, and lower
in an overtaxed industry, than under neutral taxation.
Harberger has demonstrated that the cost of distortion, given the
two preceding assumptions, can be approximated as follows:
Under neutral taxation, consumers could buy previously overtaxed
products for a lower price and would have to pay more for previously
undertaxed products. Assuming an approximately even distribution
of consumer preferences, the cost of distortion can be represented
graphically by a triangle whose height equals the percentage in column
3 of table 4 times the initial price, and whose base is this same per-
centage times the initial quantity. For example, in the case of the
contract construction industry, the area of this triangle equals (0.0043)
(0.0043) (0.5) = 0.00092 times the value added in the industry, $24.2
billion. The result of the computation, $22.3 million, is shown in
column 4.
All told, the uneven taxation illustrated in table 3 resulted in an
underproduction in some lines and overproduction in others, for a total
cost of distortion of roughly $660 million.
On the heels of such apparent precision, I wish to reiterate that the
figures in tahle 4 are meant to do no more than indicate order of magni-
tude, particularly with reference to the current situation. Quite aside
from the conceptual limitations of the mathematical approach,15 there
is the further problem that since 1963 the relationships shown in col-
umn 2 have changed, primarily because the ceiling on the social security
tax base has risen from $4,800 to $6,600 and the rate, from 3.625 to
4.4 percent. Nonetheless, the basic point of the table cannot be brushed
aside: while the exact amount remains vague, undoubtedly the social
security tax results in some degree of wasteful application of the
economy's resources.
III. TI-IF TAX ON THE EMPLOYEE
IMPACT ON FAMILY BUDGETS
For many taxpayers, the portion of tax levied on the employee re-
sembles an income tax. in a very peculiar version. For lower and
median income ranges, the OASDHI tax often takes a larger fraction
of the family `budget than the Federal income tax, especially when
15 See Harberger, "The Corporation Income Tax: An Empirical Appraisal", op. cit., pp.
235-236.
PAGENO="0198"
192 OLD AGE INCOME ASSTJRANCE-pART III
the family is large. Even for the relatively small family of four (par-
ents and two children), the typical breakeven point below which the
social security tax exceeds the income tax lies at $5,027, at 1967 rates
(table 5). Latest available estimates indicate that about 23 percent of
the families this size earn income lower than the break-even income.
With three children, the break-even point rises to $6,263 and the per-
centage of families affected, to about 35 percent; with 4 children,
$7,106 and a.bout 47 percent; with five children, $7,654 and about 62
percent. About 35 percent of the families with at least two children
pay more social security tax than Federal income tax.
One widely discussed characteristic, the apparent regressivity result-
ing from the flat rate and base ceiling, raises interesting issues of
equity, welfare, and differential spending patterns.16 But the basic
problems and conclusions differ little from those which would arise in
connection with a regressive income tax, have been discussed exten-
sively, and will not be reexamined here.
TABLE 5.-BREAR-EVEN POlfIT, FEDERAL INCOME TAX AND SOCIAL SECURITY TAX, BY FAMILYSIZE, 1967 RATES
Percent of
Breakeven families with
Family size point 1 income below
breakeven
point 2
Parents,2 children $5,007 23
Pareots,3children 6,029 35
Parents, 4 children 7, 116 47
Parents,5chilcjren 7,654 62
Parents, 2 or more children 35
1 Annual income below which social security tax exceeds Federal income tax, based on 1967 rates. Assumes only 1
parent is employed and that a joint income tax return is filed.
2 Based on latest available distribution, for 1965 income.
Source: Bureau of the Census, `Income in 1965 of Families and Persons in the United States" (series, p. 60, No. 51),
(January 1967, p. 21).
PRESSURES FOR WAGE INCREASES
The OASDHI base ceiling may create a unique problem, since it
causes many taxpayers to experience a discontinuity of take-home
pay. As a consequence of the method by which the tax is levied, a tax-
payer earning, say, $9,000 (about 30 percent of families reported in-
come of $9,000 or higher in 1965) paid a monthly social security tax
of $31.50 for the first 8 months of 1966 (4.2 percent of a monthly salary
of $750) plus $25 in the ninth month. During October, November, and
December, the family received monthly take-home pay $31.50 larger
than during the first 9 months of the year. A great deal then depends
on what the taxpayer chooses to do with his additional take-home pay.
If he merely saves it, or even if he regards it as a temporary bonanza.,
no particular problem arises. But, if he has no tax awareness, and
casually spends the extra money, he well may make an unnoticed up-
ward adjustment in his standard of living, and will find the jolt quite
1~ The issue of the regresslvity of the tax should be evaluated in a broader perspective
hot essential to the discussion here. See E. Deran, "Income Redistribution Under the Social
security System," National Tax Journal, vol. 19. No. 3 (September 1966), pp. 2T6-28u.
PAGENO="0199"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART iii 193
painful when once again OASDHI is withheld from his paycheck in
January. It seems possible that such a stimulus might trigger him to
press for an increase in a salary level he previously considered
adequate.
The theoretician may protest that such an effect would have no
importance, on grounds that both employer and employee seek max-
imizing positions with resultant equilibrium precluding any wage
negotiations in response to purely psychological phenomena. But, it
seems to me that maximization theories, no matter `how venerable, over-
look the common human tendency to feel indifferent to small inequi-
ties and inefficiencies. If we may judge by the works of early English
novelists, the business world known to Adam Smith may have been a
good deal more responsive to the "invisible hand" than the economy
of today. In fact, a person exhibiting a relentless drive for profit maxi-
mization today may seek treatment for a "competition neurosis." In a
society where relatively few find themselves at a subsistence level, it is
hard to believe that typical employers and employees continuously
assess their economic position with a view to maximizing returns. I
suspect that employees in particular do not engage in frequent evalua-
tions, since the opportunity cost of constant alertness ordinarily would
be forgone leisure. Consequently, it seems probable that employees
might overlook the development of opportunities for a wage increase
until some minor trauma such as the January reduction in take-home
pay awakens them to their neglected opportunities.17
OTI-IEP. ADJUSTMENTS TO TAX
It will not always happen, of course, that the employee can bargain
successfully in his try for a wage increase. In that case, he must make
some sort of adjustment to reduced take-home pay. The most probable
alternatives: Reduction of consumption expenditures, reduction of
saving (or increased borrowing), increased pretax income through an
additional job or overtime. The effects of these adjustments, in no way
unique to the social security tax, have been analyzed frequently and
at length in textbooks and journal articles, and need not be spelled
out here.
A possible subtle effect of the tax might be noted in passing, al-
though it is not amenable to proof by any means other than intui-
tion. From one point of view, it might be held that the tax "discrimi-
nates" against the low~paid, unskilled worker, via the incentives it
creates for employers to substitute more productive, skilled workers
when practicable.18 Consequently, at high enough rates the tax might
accentuate other influences in the economy which reduce the supply
of jobs for the unskilled, with adverse effects on employment levels.
What response the unskilled worker might make to this situation can-
not be predicted. He may sink into permanent apathy and despair, he
might engage in rioting, or he might seek training which would move
him into the ranks of the semiskilled.
17 Just such a case may have occurred In Puerto Rico when the tax was Introduced there
in 1951. See footnote 3 above. It should be noted that the employer can experience a similar
jolt, multiplied by the number of his employees.
iS See footnote S above.
PAGENO="0200"
194 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
IV GENERAL REVENUE FINANCING AS AN ALTERNATIVE
The preceding discussion makes it clear that the OASDI-1I tax, like
any other tax, exhibits the usual quota of faults, all of which become
more acute as the level of the tax rises. In view of these. shortcomings.
should we abandon the present method of financing the social security
system by turning in part to general revenue financing, as some have
suggested?
There is one immediately apparent "advantage" to supplementmg
the finances of the system with funds from general revenues: benefit
levels probably could be increased substantially without any further
increases in payroll taxes, which possibly could even be frozen at their
present level. While such a possibility may offer considerable appeal,
it is important to think a few steps beyond such a nirvana before
meraing into it.
W~hat, actually, does general revenue financing imply? Although
there is temptation to think of general revenue as a never-failing cruse,
in fact it is merely the conglomerate of collections from nonear-
marked taxes. In 1966, about 88 percent of Federal revenue came
from income taxes (about two-thirds from individuals and the bal-
ance from corporations), 9 percent from excise taxes, and 3 percent
from estate and gift taxes. For all practical purposes, then, general
revenue financing amounts to income tax financing. It follows that
general revenue financing for the social security system would require
a choice between two unpleasant alternatives: scuttling of some pres-
ent areas of expenditure-an unlikely prospect-or imposition of in-
come tax rates higher than would otherwise be necessary.'9 A capsule
idea of tile consequences of general revenue financing can be obtained
by comparing the major ways in which payroll taxes and income taxes
differ, as shown below:
Increase iM payroll tax
Increase in income tax
Effect of increased tax on resource
allocation,
Effect of increased tax on economic
stability,
Effect of increased tax on individuals_ -
May be severe on new and marginal
firms (taxes all firms).
Especially severe on labor-intensive
firms.
Induces movement of resources to less
heavily taxed industries,
No predictable relationship to business
cycle.'
Possibly regressive
Benefits seem earned (tax-benefit link
possible).
Allows new firms to develop, marginal
firms to survive (taxes profitmaking
firms only).
Especially severe on firms using large
amounts of equity capital.
Little, if any, tax-induced industry
shifts.
Some degree of built-in stabilizer.
Progressive.
Benefits are charity (no tax-benefit link
possible).
`See Economic Aspects of the Social
Security Tax, Tax Foundation, New Yort
., 1966, pp. 51-54.
When the major differences between the two taxes are thus arrayed,
the choice between financing additional benefits by increasing one tax
rather than the other begins to look like tile Scylla-Charybdis pas-
sage. For insta.nce, one might prefer tile income tax because it allows
new firms to develop, but since the income tax also allows inefficient
marginal firms to continue to operate, perhaps tile OASDHI tax, with
iS This paper does not seem the place for a discussion of "fiscal drag," but for those who
would contend the "surplus" could be channeled into the social security system, let It he
noted that the "excess" funds would vanish under suitable rate reduction.
PAGENO="0201"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART iii 195
its harsher treatment of marginal firms, would be preferable. The in-
come tax and payroll tax, in fact, would appear to be a nicely comple-
mentary pair, as long as both are kept below seriously repressive levels.
In any event, it obviously would be unrealistic to contend that the
faults of the social security tax exert a more oppressive effect than
those of the income tax, since both can exhibit extremely unpleasant
characteristics as rates increase.
V. A WAY OUT OF THE DILEMMMA: REALISTIC APPROACHES TO CosTs
I have attempted to show that the OASDHI tax leads to a number
of undesirable effects. Raising equivalent funds through general reve-
nue financing may reduce some of the problems, but only at the ex-
pense of aggravating another set of difficulties. It would seem that
the taxpayer has been boxed into a depressing trap.
Sometimes, however, traps are more of the captive's own devising
than externally imposed. There is a weak point in the social security
system, which just possibly may provide an avenue of escape: the as-
sumption that the costs of the system must continue to increase.
In the past, three important factors have led to the need for in-
creasing taxes to finance the social security system:
1. The anticipation that benefits must be increased to maintain a
decent standard of living for our elders.
2. The intergeneration transfer, which will continue to some degree
until the early part of the next century.
3. The interbracket income redistribution which has been quietly
increased in intensity, with resultant changes in the entire philosophy
of the system.
Before we abandon all hope, perhaps we should consider the impor-
tance of each of these elements for the integrity of the entire system,
and whether and changes might be made which would ease the financ-
ing pressures.
BENEFIT LEVELS
Like many others of my generation, I was brought up in an Ameri-
can subculture which respects old age, and would be among the first
to agree that our elders should be able to live in comfort and dignity.
I also agree with Jung that old age is a. time for retrospection and
introspection, a time to prepa.re for whatever lies beyond, and concede
that this vital task certainly cannot be accomplished under economic
pressure. I nonetheless feel that the time has come to consider the mat-
ter of increasing benefits in a realistic framework.
The basic problem stems from uonsidering the social security pen-
sion as providing the older person's entire support, rather than as the
floor it was originally meant to be, and in fact is, for many of the re-
tired. In evaluating the adequacy of benefits, several points must. be
remembered. Older people generally have accumulated assets which
reduce their out]ays (such as a house) and often, in addition, income-
bearing assets. Increasing numbers receive supplemental income from
private pensions. Still others are capable of and would benefit from
part-time, light work that would enable them to bring their combined
pension-earnings income to a comfortable level but for the strictures
imposed by the social security system. At the same time, it must be
PAGENO="0202"
195 OLD AGE ll~7COME ASSURANCE-PART III
recognized that substantial numbers of the elderly depend almost en-
tirely on their OASI pensions.
For example, consider the archetypal cases of three sisters, all
widows on social security, whose personal circumstances nea.tly illus-
trate the problem and point a way to a solution. Mrs. A was married
to a barber, a wonderful man who told marvelous stories but never
was able to save a dime. Mrs. A quickly ran through the few assets he
left, and really can't live on her pension. Her highest skill is baby-
sitting. Her sister, Mrs. B, is a competent woman with a keen business
sense who was left a good farm. She would very much like to operate
the farm herself, but instead, because of earnings limitations, must rent
it if she wants to `collect her OASI pension. She has enough income,
but worries constantly about the failure of her tenant to take a long-
run view in his management of the farm. Mrs. C, on the other hand,
married a man who died a millionaire; so, she has no worries about
money at all.
The question is, should the pensions of Mrs. B and Mrs. C be in-
creased so that Mrs. A can live decent.ly? When the problem is put in
the perspective that comes from thinking a.bout real people (as distinct
from "the elderly" or "the poor"), it is clear that Mr's. A's needs should
be met in a. framework that would not waste funds on the other two.
Mrs. A needs welfare; the other widows do not, although Mrs. B would
benefit `from an easing of the earnings limitation. It would be wasteful
to extend welfare to all three in t.he form of social security benefits
high enough to meet Mrs. A's need.
How high, then, should benefits be? The answer, I think, `is that they
should be as `high as can be supported by today's level of payroll tax-
which, after the ad~ustments suggested in the next two sections. may
be considerably higher than present levels. Anything more should be
treated as welfare, and handled outside the social security framework.
THE INTERGENERATION TRANSFER
No one now receiving an OASI pension has paid social security taxes
all his working life. In fact, a 21-year-old man who entered the labor
force when the social `security system first began in 1937 will not nor-
mally retire until 1981. The consequence, as shown in table 6, is that
the `cumulative value of taxes at 3.5 percent `compound interest falls
quite a bit short of the discount value, also at 3.5 percent, of probable
benefits in the case of pensioners retiring relatively early. Generally,
single individuals retiring before 1990 and married men retiring before
2010 receive a windfall. But, the table also illustrates who pays for the
windfall: the younger participants, the value of whose taxes massively
exceed their probable bene~ts. For instance, if he lives out his normal
lifespan a. single male entering the work force in 1965 will pay (not
counting matching payments from his employer) OASDI taxes with
about $12,800 more than the discounted benefits he can expect, corn-
puted on the basis of implicit 3.5 percent interest under existing law.
Where does the $12,800 go? No chicanery is involved: someone has to
pay for the pensions of those who have not been covered by the system
long enough to pay their own way `c.ompetely. This transfer of funds
from the younger generation to the older generation is an extremely
important reason for the present high rates of tax.
PAGENO="0203"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 197
TABLE 6.-VALUE OF TOTAL EMPLOYEE TAXPAYMENTS AND BENEFITS, AND TAXPAYMENTS AS PERCENT
OF BENEFITS, SELECTED RETIREMENT YEARS, 1962-2010
Value of
Year of retirement taxpayments
at 3.5-per-
cent
interest i
Vale
e of benefits discounted
at 3.5 percent2
Value of taxpayments as percent
of value of benefits
~
Single
male
Married
male
Single
female
Single Married Single
male male female
(percent) (percent) (percent)
1962 $1,981 $14,995 $25,225 $17,437 13.2 7.9 11.4
1965 2, 270 15, 483 26, 050 18,227 14. 7 10. 4 14. 9
1970 4, 567 16,797 28, 270 18, 639 27. 2 16. 2 24. 5
1980 10, 144 17,960 30,235 20,234 56. 5 33. 6 50. 1
1990 16,830 18,425 31,021 20,899 91.3 54.3 80.5
2000 25,225 19,239 32,397 21,963 131.1 77.9 114.9
2010 32, 496 19,704 33, 183 22, 495 164. 9 97. 9 144. 5
1 Based on social security law as amended in 1965. Assumes worker is employed (as an employee) at maximum
covered earnings in all years after 1937, or after attaining age 20, if later. Excludes portion ef tax earmarked for health
insurance, and entire employer tax. Taxpayments are the same for single male, married male, and single female.
2 Assumes worker is alive at age 65 and retires at that time (attaining age 65 at the beginning of the year). Married
worker and his wife are the same age.
Source: Unpublished computations prepared by Ray M. Peterson, formerly vice president and associate actuary'
the Equitable Life Assurance Society of the United States.
One comfort about the intergeneration transfer problem is that
time alone will heal it, provided, of course, it doesn't damage the
system irreparably before then. Something along the lines suggested
by Professors Buchanan and Campbell might reduce the current
strain on the system: a bookkeeping adjustment which would treat
the cost of the intergeneration transfer as a national debt (and hence
chargeable against general revenues), rather than an obligation on
the social security trust fund.' This done, it likely would be possible
to reduce social security taxes while maintaining present benefits or,
alternatively, increase benefits considerably while freezing rates at
their present level.
INTERBRACKET INCOME REDISTRIBUTION
The social security system has always included some degree of redis-
tribution from high- to low-income levels, with lower paid workers
receiving pensions representing a higher percentage of their average
taxable income than was true of taxpayers at the upper end of the
spectrum. The redistribution element has gradually increased over the
years, particularly with respect to those pensioners receiving benefits
determined by the legal minimum. Minimum pension beneficiaries
(who may or may not be low-income beneficiaries) have enjoyed rela-
tive gains because the level of the floor has gradually increased, while
the level of qualifying earnings has remained stationary.
The ratio of the basic monthly benefit to average monthly taxable
wages (B/W) may be taken as a rough comparative indicator of how
much a beneficiary is getting back, relative to what he paid in taxes.
In a comparison of two beneficiaries, the one with the higher B/MT
may be considered the gainer, because he gets more back for each tax
dollar he pays in. Over time, income will be redistributed from the
low B/W beneficiary to the high B/W beneficiary, since the latter gets
a better bargain than the former.
Table 7 shows B/W for three categories of taxpayers under pro-
visions of all benefit schedules to date, plus under the current Presi-
1 James M. Buchanan and Cohn D. Campbell, "voluntary Social Security," Wall Street
Journal, Dec. 20, 1966. The Buchanan-Campbell proposal is considerably more intricate
than I have indicated above, and includes a proposal that taxpayers be allowed to with-
draw from the system. I am not convinced that the complete plan is workable unless drastic
changes can be made in the income redistribution elements of the systeno.
PAGENO="0204"
198 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
dential proposal. The first column gives B/W for beneficiaries earning
the highest level of taxable wages; the second colunrn, for beneficiaries
who received the legal minimum because their qualifying wages were
so low the ordinary rules for computing benefit levels did not apply;
the third, for beneficiaries just above the floor, a category we perhaps
could consider the "normal" low-wage taxpayer.
TABLE 7.-RATIO OF MONTHLY BASIC BEN EFIT TO AVERAGE TAXABLE WAGES, SELECTED BENEFIT LEVELS, 1939-65
Year enacted
Average monthly taxable wage
of monthly benefit
s as multiple
CoI. (2) as
multiple of
cal. (1)
Cal. (3) as
multiple of
col. (1)
(1) (2)
(3)
Minimum
Minimum
Maximum wage
wage qualifying 1
wage not de-
pendent on
benefit floors
1939
.24 .6
.40
2.5
1.7
1950
.27 1.2
.50
4.4
1. 8
1952
.28 1.5
.55
5.4
2.0
1954
.31 1.8
.55
5.8
1.8
1958
.32 2.0
.59
6.2
1.8
1961
.32 2.4
.59
7.5
1.8
1965
.31 2.6
.63
8.5
2.0
Increase, 1939-65 (percent)
Presidential proposal
29. 2 333
. 32 4. 2
57. 5
. 72
240. 0
13. 5
17. 6
3. 4
1 Assumes $50 earned per quarter in all 4 quarters each year employed (see text footnote 22).
Equal to $25 in 1939; $40 in 1950; $45 in 1952; $54 in 1954; $56 in 1958; $68 in 1951; $70 in 1965.
Source: Computations based on Robert J. Myers, Old-Age, Survivors, Disability and Health Insurance Provisions:
Legislative History, 1935-OS, Social Security Administration, July 1965; Committee on Ways and Means, Section-by-section
analysis and explanation of provisions of H.R. 5710, the "Social Security Amendments of 1937 * * *", February 1967.
B/W has increased for all three categories. For beneficiaries earn-
ing the maximum wage, it increased from 0.24 in 1939 to 0.31 in 1954,
where it stands today. For the normal-low wage beneficiary, B/W
began at 0.40 in 1939, and has risen gradually to 0.63 today. In striking
contrast, B/W for those receiving the minimum benefit has risen from
0.6 to 2.6 today.2 Over the 26 years since 1939, B/W increased about
29 percent for the high-wage beneficiary, 57 percent for the normal-
low wage beneficiary, and 333 percent for the minimum benefit
category.
Inevitably, the uneven changes in B/W brought changes in the
relationship among the three categories. B/W for the normal-low wage
category began 1.7 times as large as the B/W for the high-wage
category, then slowly increased until today is 2 times as large as the
latter. B/W for the minimum category began at 25 times the high
category, rapidly increasing to 8.5 times in 1965.
The President's proposal would accelerate the trend of the past
quarter century to an incredible degree. B/W would remain unchanged
at 0.31 for high beneficiaries, and shoot to 4.2 for minimum bene-
ficiaries. Under this proposal, B/W for normal-low beneficiaries would
be 3.4 times as large as for high beneficiaries, while B/WT for minimum
beneficiaries would be 13.5 times as large as for high beneficiaries and
4 times as large as for normal-low beneficiaries.
2 The base used for estimating the minimum wage was conservatively set at $16.67. on
the basis that since tbe beginning of tbe system, $50 earnings in a quarter will give a tax-
payer a quarter of coverage. A representative of the social security regional office, New
York City, has pointed out to me that present law specifies a person is covered if he has
one such quarter of coverage for every year which has elapsed s5nce 1951, or, in effect,
average monthly earnings of .S4.17 since that date. I prefer to assume my low-wage tax-
payer earned $200 a year, rather than the $50 which could qualify him, on the practical
ground that a $4.17 base would lead to results that, while technically correct, would appear
too ridiculous to believe.
PAGENO="0205"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 199
Most people would take the view that, despite the truly astonish-
ing relationship between the upper and lower ends of the benefit sched-
ule, the minimum benefit considered in the absolute provides a pathet-
ically low income. Obviously, not even an ascetic could manage on the
present $44 per month, or even on the $70 suggested by President
Johnson. In fact, it is impossible to use the social security system
to provide a suitable income for people at the lower end of the income
spectrum unless we are willing to junk the entire underlying philos-
ophy and transform the social security system into a particularly
wasteful welfare mechanism.
Another point to consider is the fact that an unknown proportion
of those receiving minimum benefits have not necessarily been low-
income earners. For instance, there is the case of an astute lady who
was anticipating retirement from administrative work in a public
school system not at that time under social security. She persuaded
her brother, who owned a large department store, to hire her to tie
bows for gift wrapping, spending just enough time at the chore for
the $50 quarterly earnings requisite for coverage. As she pointed out,
she certainly didn't need the income from bow tying, but it was silly
to pass up the social security for which she could so easily qualify,
and she accumulated quarters of credit just as assiduously as she
accumulated growth stock.
Unfortunately, the Social Security Administration was unable to
provide direct information on the percentage of minimum-level bene-
ficiaries who fall into relatively high income categories. Table 8, which
is based on the Social Security Administration's 1963 survey of the
aged, provides some indirect information which suggests that married
couples ~ receiving the minimum level of benefits are not necessarily
the most disadvantaged group. While only 45 percent of the bene-
ficiaries in the $40 primary insurance amount (PTA) category received
retirement income other than their social security pension, the median
value of this inv~ome lay at a higher point for the lowest PTA. than
for any other PTA category. In fact, retirement income other than
OASDHT for the minimum PTA group was 20 percent larger than
for either the highest PTA or the "norrnal"-low PTA, and double the
value of the middle PTA category.
TABLE 8.-RETIREMENT INCOME AND SOURCE, BY PRIMARY INSURANCE AMOUNT, MARRIED COUPLES, 1962'
Primary insu
rance amount
$40
$41 to $59
$60 to $99
$100 and
more
Retirement income other than OASDHI:
Median amount
$1,215
$1,000
$605
$1,000
Percent with such income
45 54
67
87
Percent with retirement income from:
Employer pensions, public and private, other than
OASDHI
15
11
14
39
Veterans' pensions and compensations
Assets
15
32
21
39
14
57
16
77
Private annuities
3
2
3
6
1 Does not include retired married women whose husbands are not entitled to OASDHI.
Source: Leonore A. Epstein and Janet H. Murray, `The Aged Population of the United States," Sucial Security Admin-
istration, Office of Research and Statistics, Research Report No. 19 (scheduled for publication July 1967), pp. 328-331.
While table 9 shows data for married couples only, similor relationships among PIA
groups appear for nonmarried beneficiaries. However, the actual figures, particularly dollar
amounts, differ considerably. Data for various categories of single beneficiaries may be
found in the source cited for table 8.
PAGENO="0206"
200 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
An examination of the sources of non-OASDHI retirement income
(table 8), which include public a.nd private employer pensions, veter-
ans' pensions, income from assets, and private annuities, suggests that
low PTA beneficiaries may derive their supplementary retirement in-
come primarily from public pensions. Generally, the percentage re-
ceiving income from each source is not notably larger, and is some-
times smaller, for the minimum group compared with other groups.
However, the fact that the percentage receiving employer pensions in
the minimum PTA group is second only to the percentage for the high-
est PTA group seems curious, since one might deduce that pensions
from a private employer (i.e., in employment covered by OASDHI)
could not be substantial if an individual qualifies for no more than a
minmum OASI pension. Hence the conclusion follows that 45 percent
of the low PTA group probably have retired under public programs
such as Federal civil service or railroad retirement, receiving pensions
large enough to account for their highest "other" retirement income
cited above. Obviously, it is easily possible for employees of Federal
civil service, railroads, and State systems not linked to social security
to qualify for minimum benefits by taking part-time jobs in covered
industries for a few years. The higher the minimum benefit, the more
these people will be tempted to take the trouble to qualify. If, on the
other hand, the needs of the genuinely poor were met through a wel-
fare arrangement outside the social security system, few of those re-
tired under other government programs would qualify for the heavily
subsidized minimum pensions.
CoNCLUsIoN
An important choice lies before Congress today. It can transform
the social security system into a peculiar sort of welfare program, or
can make the repairs that will return the system to the sound principle
of an earned pension for all Americans. if the former is the goal, then
Congress may as well swing over to general revenue financing, which
can best support the spiraling costs which inevitably will ensue. But, if
Congress wants something resembling the original system, with its
liberating tax-benefit link-a system, I think, best fits the American
ideals of independence and self-respect-then it must attend to the
major peril to that system, the excessively high costs which require
dange~rously high payroll taxes.
Two important steps will go far toward reducing costs without
undermining the philosophy or financial soundness of the system.
(1) The cost of the one-time-only intergeneration transfer should be
identified-a difficult but not impossible chore-and subsidized out of
general revenue. Such an adjustment would relieve the financial pres-
sures on the system without opening a Pandora's box to benefit levels
supported out of seemingly limitless funds.
(2) The concept of the minimum benefit should be recognized as a
wasteful device which has reached an inappropriately high level rela-
tive to the rest of the benefit schedule. While it might be politically
unrealistic to scrap the concept altogether, the minimum should be
restored to a more reasonable point relative to other benefits.
PAGENO="0207"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART iii 201
Action suggested under step (1) will make possible an overall in-
crease in benefits without accompanying increases in rates or base, but
it is unrealistic to try to use the social security system alone to provide
an adequate living for all of our elderly citizens. We can and should
meet the needs of our indigent aged through a generous but separate
Federal program.
The social security system today lies in grave danger of degenerating
into an undignified form of Federal dole. But, if Congress will act
with courage to preserve the original concept of the system, endless
generations can continue to accept their checks with the satisfaction
and self-respect that go with an earned retirement.
PAGENO="0208"
INCOME TAX INDUCEMENTS FOR PERSONAL RETIRE-
MENT SAVING
nr ROBERT N. SCHOEPLEIX*
The present schedule of retirement benefits under social security
(OASDHI) again is being criticized as "inadequate." This has a f a-
miliar ring; the elderly experience recurring purchasing power gaps as
labor force earnings and consumer prices rise. The Federal Govern-
ment has four broad courses of action in upgrading the guaranteed
maintenance income for the aged: (1) Increase the benefit schedule
under OASDHI; (2) adopt and expand complementary public as-
sistance programs; (3) introduce a new income tra.nsfer program. such
as a negative income tax; (4) provide inducements-usually through
tax incentives-to accelerate the rate of private retirement saving.
This paper 1 focuses on the issue whether income tax inducements can
significantly increase t.he rate of personal retirement saving. A par-
ticular form of incentive has received recent attention. The basic pro-
posal is to create a special Federal income tax deduction for current
personal retirement saving (including current employer pension con-
tributions in some variants of the proposal) ~2 Some 6.5 million or so
self-employed taxpayers presently are eligible for such a "personal
pension" deduction under the individual income tax, but these self-
employed represent only about 10 percent of all taxpayers under age
65.~ The Canadians have such a deduction in their national income tax,
and eligibility is extended to virtually all taxpayers.4 These United
States and Canadian programs may have been adopted with several
objectives in mind, including equity considerations. If these tax-incen-
tive schemes are to complement social security, however, the relevant
performance test is the consequent increase in the rate of personal
saving.
*Unjversjty of Connecticut.
1 J am indebted to Charles M. Tiebout and Gardner M. Brown, Jr.. for their comments
in reviewing a draft of this paper, though I am responsible for errors that may remain.
The Institute for Economic Research, University of Washington. provided financial support
for computer research.
2 Cf. U.S. President's Committee on Corporate Pension Funds and other Private Retire-
ment and Welfare Programs. Public Policy and Private Pension Programs, Washington.
1965. U.S. Congress, Joint Economic Committee. Hearings: "Private Pension Plans." 89th
Cong., 2d sess., spring 1966.
This special income tax deduction to induce personal retirement saving should not be
confused with the proposal to permit income-tax deductions of employee OASDHI con-
tributions, discussed in U.S. Congress. House, Committee on Ways and Means. Hearings on
President's proposals for revision in the social security system, 90th Cong., 1st sess., Mar.
1-3, 1967, pt. I, pp. 19~-2O1.
`The program is titled the "Self-Employed Individuals Tax Retirement Act of 1962"
(76 Stat. 809), and frequently is cited as "H.R. 10" in trade journals. The eligibility esti-
mate is based on U.S. Treasury "Statistics of Income, Business Tax Returns, 1962," ad-
justed to 1964 preliminary returns. The total represents the sum of partners in partner-
ships with net profit plus sole proprietors with net profit.
~ Registered retirement savings plan. Stat. Can. 1957, 16S.c.29.
202
PAGENO="0209"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 203
Few eligible taxpayers presently are utilizing the "personal pension"
deductions in either the United States or the Canadian programs-
about 1 percent and 2 percent of those eligible, respectively. The evalua-
tion in this paper indicates that taxpayers indeed may bB wise in ignor-
in~ this particular tax incentive scheme. In short, the attraction of
this program in inducing incremental personal saving may be over-
rated. The income tax advantages in participation superficially may
appear attractive, but a closer examination shows that the relative
dollars-and-cents advantages in fact may be quite nominal. More-
over, these "personal pension" programs have severe constraints on
liquidity and on forms of investment, and these restrictions must be
weighed against any supposed increase in investment yields because
of preferential income tax treatment.
A. THE UNIVERSAL PERSONAL-PENSION DEDUCTION: RELATIVE NET
YIELD ADVANTAGES IN PARTICIPATION
The present individual income tax does tend to discourage personal
saving for future needs-~by the compound effect of permitting current
deductions on borrowing charges, coupled with the taxation of interest
earnings on savings.5 This announcement effect can be mitigated by
permitting special income tax treatment of selected transactions, there-
by increasing their net (aftertax) yields on taxpayer investment. This
difference in net yields is the stimulus for increased personal saving.
Response will depend on the interest elasticity of personal saving to
changes in net yields, and, of course, the magnitude of change in yield.
Given the mechanics of alternative income tax treatment, one can
compare the relative net yield advantages of two or more taxpayer
alternatives. Some abstractions are in order, however, to provide a
consistent basis for comparison. Assume initially that a taxpayer is
restricted in investment to a specific corporate bond, but has income
`tax alternatives in purchasing and realizing income from these bonds.
The gross (before tax) yields, risk, and liquidity aspects of the tax
options are equal, `but alternative tax treatment may affect net (after-
tax) yields.
Assume further-for comparative purposes-that the taxpayer
withhold's a specified sum from gross income, for retirement saving
purposes.6 This is not to suggest that the individual in question is a
"target" saver, because we in fact are interested in changes in the
rate of personal saving as a consequence of the income tax incentive.
Rather, this model illustrates the relative change in net yields, as the
basis for taxpayer response.
The taxpayer's savings would be subject to "standard" tax treatment
if he had no tax options. This approach (designated option A) may
be termed the "no tax `break" situation. The individual has set aside
a certain sum from gross income, but current income taxes first must
Alan williams, Public Finance and Budgetary Policy. (New York, 1i~63), pp. 62-65.
6 One alternatively can structure the argument with retirement saving as a function of
disposable income. The advantage of tax deductibility can be illustrated as an addition to
the initial investment; e.g., Rz (i+-j-~-))=R~ where Rd=desired savings from dispos-
able income, and R is the actual increased basis for investment because of the current
deduction.
83-200-67-pt. 3-14
PAGENO="0210"
204 OLD AGE LYCOME ASSURANCE-PART Ill
be paid on this saving. The net (aftertax) basis for investment does
generate annual income, but these realized gross yields are immediately
subject to tax under the "standard" tax approach. The individual does
have a final fund at age 65 after all this income taxation, and no fur-
ther income tax is levied on this accumulated net wealth at time of
withdrawal.
To illustrate, assume that our individual intends to save $400 from
gross income. Income taxes first must he paid, and $260 will remain as
the basis for retirement saving if our taxpayer faces a 30-percent mar-
ginal tax rate. The taxpayer invests in 6-percent corporate bonds, sub-
ject to an annual levy on current earnings of the same 30-percent mar-
ginal tax rate. If our saver presently is 35 years old, his final fund
at age 65 from this single contribution will be $962. In order to com-
pare alternative tax effects, we must relate this final fund to the initial
gross saving of $400. Our individual finds that because of income taxes
his effective net (aftertax) yield is 2.97 percent of his initial $400.
Now, assume that the individual income tax is amended to permit
an alternative tax treatment (designated option B) of personal sav-
ing. This alternative summarizes the essential features of the "per-
sonal-pension" deduction both under the U.S. Self-Employed Indi-
viduals Tax Retirement Act and the universal Canadian personal
saving program. First, the individual can deduct his allowable per-
sonal-pension saving from current taxable income, thereby avoiding
any present tax liability. Second, earnings on investment are subject
to tax liability only at ultimate withdrawal. Taxes also are levied on
the original principal on withdrawal.
Our figurative saver now can invest his entire $400 in the same 6-
percent corporate bonds. He will find at the end of 30 years that his
gross final fund has grown to $2,297. Our individual now must include
these moneys in reportable income at time of withdrawal. Assume that
the entire final fund is withdrawn at age 65, and that the individual's
marginal tax rate is 18 percent. This reduced marginal tax rate reflects
the pensioner situation of lower total reportable income in retirement
years. For his efforts, the taxpayer now has his $1,884 net purchasing
power at withdrawal. This represents an effective net (aftertax) yield
of 5.30 percent on the original $400 of gross intended saving.
One compares the net-after all taxes-final retirement moneys,
illustrating t.he differential effect of alternative tax treatment.
R=Dollars of retirement saving from gross income ($400).
i~= Marginal tax rate during contribution year (0.30).
i= Nominal annual gross yield on investment (0.06).
q=Marginal tax rate on investment annual gross yield (0.30).
t=Marginal tax rate at time. of withdrawal (0.18).
m= Number of years between contribution a.nd withdrawal (0.30).
Standard option A: {(1-r)R] [1~4~~i(l_q)]m A=net final fund.
Deduction option B: (1-t)R(1+i)m B ==net final fund.
(1+j)m _(~~T 1+i ~
A(i-r) [1~j(1_q)Jmn~1_r) L1+i(1-q)J
PAGENO="0211"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 205
The effect of changes in each parameter on Z can be noted.7 The
relative advantage of a "personal-pension" deduction becomes more
attractive as the ratio of current-year marginal tax rate to expected
withdrawal-year marginal tax rate (i.e., r/t) increases.8 Note that tax
option B still will give a greater net final fund even when the respective
rates are equal (r =t), because of the tax shelter.9
The net yield advantage of the personal pension deduction can be
quite attractive to a taxpayer with a high current marginal tax rate,
if this were the only preferential tax treatment option. This can be
illustrated for arbitrary values q =0.3 and i = 0.06.
The essential point is that a taxpayer is not restricted to these two
income-tax alternatives; there are other attractive options to increase
net (aftertax) yields. Capital gains is a familiar alternative. In capi-
tal gains as in the standard approach, an individual establishing a
retirement-saving fund first must pay income taxes on current earn-
ings before investment. If the interim earnings on principal are not
"realized" for tax purposes until retirement, these sheltered earnings
will be subject to a capital gains marginal tax rate, assumed to be
0.5t at withdrawal.1°
Using the same illustrative parameters as in the first two tax op-
tions, our taxpayer will realize a $1,409 net final fund, or an effective
net (aftertax) yield of 4.29 percent. The net final fund under capital
gains option C is calculated as the original net investment and accu-
mulated earnings, minus the capital gains marginal tax rate on earn-
ings at the time of ultimate withdrawal.
C=R(l-r) (l+i)m_~[R(l_r) (1+i)m_R(l_r)]
=R(1-r) (1±i)m(l_~)+~R(1_r)
[i+ (1
The "personal pension" deduction (option B) now is compared with
other available tax options (e.g., capital gains option C). The rela-
tive effective net yield advantage of the "personal pension" deduction
is reduced by over 40 percent in the illustrative example. However,
one cannot state categorically that the relative effective net yield
>0, >0 dq <0; 0<1 q r, 1 <1,
th dm dq -
Specific values of the marginal tax rates also are significant in addition to the absolute differences. Thus
the advantage is greater when (t, r) (0.2, 0.5) than when (t, r) = (0.1, 0.4). The advantages of preferential
tax treatment is a function of the level of potential tax liabilities.
Assume q=0.3, i=0.06. If marginal tax rates in the contribution year and payoff year are equal, the
payoff advantage of B over A is
M Z=B
Earning years A
10 1.18
20 1.40
30 1166
10 This is an oversimplification of capital gains rates, but will serve for illustration.
PAGENO="0212"
206 OLD AGE LNCOM~ ASSURANCE-PART III
advantage will be reduced (Z'l ,200.
(Corrected formula for case I of appendix B of Cabinet committee
report.)
Case 11(a):
X(0.815)~/(4%) =
where
Y-0. 185 (y_X(o.81s) @)=1,200.
Case II:
X(0.815)3j/(4%) =
where
Y-0.075 (~_i(c115)(n))=1,200.
(This formula for case II, as shown in the appendix B of the report, is
incorrectly stated therein although it was correctly applied.)
Case 111(a):
1,200. (4°/)
XSflf(4%)=ö-~1_~a65
PAGENO="0242"
236 OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III
Case III:
- 1,200- ~
XS~/(4%)=ö-~_5a65( ~
Factors used:
S~/(4%)=42.4743; 8251(3.26%) =38.3143.
S~(4%)=96.9l4; S4o/(3.26%)=81.302.
a65~4%)=10. 1987; ~~~(326%)= 10.7827; ê~= 14.206.
Case
Valuesofq
uantityY
n=25
n=40
(a)
11(a)
II
1266.09
1226. 00
1343.48
1254.31
1266.09
1226. 00
1379.63
1266.87
PAGENO="0243"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 237
APPENDIX III
PAY-AS-YOU-GO FINANCING VERSUS ADVANCE FUNDING
A. ALGEBRAIC ANALYSIS
An employer who contributes $1 now to his pension fund will
thereby be able to discharge a benefit payment of $(1+j) 1 year
later, or more generally $ (1+ j) n years later, where j is the annual
net yield of the pension fund. A taxpaying employer also gets a $1
deduction now for income tax purposes.
On the other hand, if the employer does not fund in advance, he
keeps his $1, less taxes at rate t (assuming the employer would con-
tribute from current earnings), and can invest it in his business or
elsewhere at an annual rate of return of i before taxes, or i (1- t)
after taxes. When, n years later, he makes the benefit payment of
$(1 +j) ~ the resulting deduction reduces his taxes by t(1 + j)fl.
The employer's choice of financing method has two important con-
sequences:
(1) For the em~ployer.-Making the comparison at time n, pay-as-
you-go financing is better for the employer if the amount gained by
riot funding in advance; i.e., $ (1- t) [1 + ~ (1- t) ] ~ is more than
tire net cost of the benefit; i.e., $ (1- t) (1 + j) ~ Advance funding is
preferable for the employer if and only if j>i (1- t).
(2) For the Federal Government.-Suppose money is worth ic per-
cent per year to the Federal Government~ Then, making the compari-
son at time n, pay-as-you-go financing is better for the Federal
Government if the value of the taxes on the original $1 and on its
subsequent earnings; i.e.,
r=n-i
$t(l +k) ~+$ti(l -t) ~ [1 +i(l -t)]T(l +k) n-r-1
r=O
-Wl+k~+$ ~t~l-t~ [l+i(1-t)J"-- l+k)~
- I / [l+i)l-t)} -1+k)
is more than the tax loss at time n, which is $t(l ~j)n.
Advance funding is preferable for the Federal Government if and
only if
t~l+ ~t~1+k~+
I ~ 1[l+i(l-t)] -(l+k)
(N0TE.-Formulas developed by Harrison Givens, Jr., associate
actuary of the Equitable Life Assurance Society.)
PAGENO="0244"
238
OLD AGE L~OOME ASSURAYCE-PA.RT III
B. NUMERICAL ILLUSTRATIONS
Average
Employer's gross invest- Percent rate of return on pension fund
earnings rate ment
(percent) earnings
period
(years) 4 4~ 5 534 6 7 8 9
5 25 0.795 0.896 1.099 1.137 1.279 1.618 2.041 2.570
30 .779 .899 1.038 1.196 1.379 1.827 2.416 3.185
534 25 .757 .853 .961 1.082 1.218 1.540 1.944 2.447
30 .735 . 849 . 980 1. 130 1. 302 1. 726 2. 282 3. 009
6 25 .720 .812 .915 1.030 1.159 1.466 1.850 2.329
30 .694 .802 .925 1.067 1.230 1.630 2.154 2.841
734 25 - 620 . 699 . 788 . 887 .999 1. 263 1. 593 2. 006
30 . 583 . 673 . 777 . 896 1. 032 1. 368 1. 809 2. 385
10 25 .481 .543 .611 .688 775 .980 1.236 1.557
30 .432 . 499 - 576 . 664 .765 1. 014 1. 341 1. 768
1234 25 - 372 .419 .472 . 532 . 598 .757 . 955 1. 202
30 .318 .367 .424 .488 .563 .746 .986 1.300
15 25 .286 .323 .363 .409 .461 .583 735 .926
30 .232 .268 .310 .357 .412 .546 .721 .951
2.67 PERCENT (663~ PERCENT OF 4 PERCENT): NET VALUE OF MONEY TO GOVERNMENT
5 25 0.847 0.995 1.076 1.212 1.364 1,725 2.177 2.741
30 . 840 .970 1. 119 1. 290 1. 487 1. 971 2. 605 3. 435
534 25 . 806 .908 1. 024 1. 153 1. 297 1. 631 2. 070 2. 606
30 .792 .914 1.055 1.216 1.402 1.858 2.456 3.238
6 25 .766 .864 .973 1.096 1.232 1.559 1.968 2.478
30 .746 .862 .994 1.146 1.321 1.751 2.315 3.052
734 25 . 657 .741 . 835 . 940 1. 058 1.338 1. 688 2. 125
30 .623 .719 .830 .957 1.103 1.462 1.933 2.549
10 25 .507 .571 .644 .725 .816 1.032 1.302 1.639
30 .458 .529 .611 .704 .811 1.075 1.422 1.874
1234 25 .389 .439 .495 .557 .627 .793 1.000 1.260
30 .335 .387 .446 .514 .593 .786 1.039 1.369
15 25 .298 .336 .379 .427 .480 .607 .766 .965
30 .243 .281 .324 ~374 .431 .571 .755 .996
RATIO OF VALUE OF TAXES RECEIVABLE UNDER PAY-AS-YOU-GO FINANCING TO VALUE OF TAXES FOREGONE
UNDER ADVANCE FUNDING
3 PERCENT (6634 PERCENT OF 4.5 PERCENT): NET VALUE OF MONEY TO GOVERNMENT
PAGENO="0245"
OLD AGE INCOME ASSURANCE-PART III 239
B. NUMERICAL ILLUsTRATIONs-continued
RATIO OF VALUE OF TAXES RECEIVABLE UNDER PAY-AS-YOU-GO FINANCING TO VALUE OF TAXES FOREGONE
UNDER ADVANCE FUNDING-Continued
2.08 PERCENT (52 PERCENT OF 4 PERCENT): NET VALUE OF MONEY TO GOVERNMENT
~IIIIII !0 ~! L9G~1_~.1f~L222 ~ 1 s 2.73
15 25 ~ 818 11003788
NOTES
"Northeast" area: Advance funding favorable to both Government and employer.
Middle area: Advance funding favorable to employer, unfavorable to Government.
"Southwest" area: Advance funding unfavorable to both Government and employer.
0
PAGENO="0246"