PAGENO="0001"
FOREIGN TRADE AND TARIFF PROPOSALS
~ h
HEARINGS
BEFORE THE
COMMITTEE ON WAYS AND MEANS
HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES
NINETIETH CONGRESS
SECOND SESSION
ON
TARIFF AND TRADE PROPOSALS
JUNE 4, 5, 10, 11, 12, 13, 14, 17, 18, 19, 21, 24, 25, 26, 27, 28;
JULY 1 AND 2, 1968
PART 8
Contains June 25, 1968
Printed for the use of the Committee on Ways and Means
11.5. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE
95-159 WASHINGTON 1968
For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office
Washington, D.C. 20402 - Price $1.50
PAGENO="0002"
CECIL R. KING, California
HALE BOGGS, Louisiana
FRANK M. KARSTEN, Missouri
A. S. HERLONG, Ja., Florida
JOHN C. WATTS, Kentucky
AL ULLMAN, Oregon
JAMES A. BURKE, Massachusetts
MARTHA W. GRIFFITHS, Michigan
GEORGE hi. RHODES, Pennsylvania
DAN ROSTENKOWSKI, Illinois
PHIL M. LANDRUM, Georgia
CHARLES A. VANIK, Ohio
RICHARD H. FULTON, Tennessee
JACOB H. GILBERT, New York
JOHN W. BYRNES, Wisconsin
THOMAS B. CURTIS, Missouri
JAMES B. UTT, California
JACKSON E. BETTS, Ohio
HERMAN T. SCHNEEBELI, Pennsylvania
HAROLD H. COLLIER, Illinois
JOEL T. BROYHILL, Virginia
JAMES F. BATTIN, Montana
BARBER B. CONABLE, Je., New York
GEORGE BUSH, Texas
WILLIAM H. QUEALY,
Minority Counsel
(II)
COMMITTEE ON WAYS AND MEANS
WILBUR D. MILLS, Arkansas, Chairman
JOHN hI. MARTIN, Jr., Chief Counsel
J. P. BAKER, Assistant Chief Counsel
PAGENO="0003"
CONTENTS
Part 1
1968: Page
Tuesday, June 4 1
Part 2
Wednesday, June 5
Monday, June 10 649
Part3
Tuesday, June 11 741
Wednesday, June 12 877
Thursday, June 13 1081
Part 4
Friday, June 14 1313
Monday, June 17 1475
Part 5
Tuesday, June 18 1829
Part 6
Wednesday, June 19 2349
Part 7
Friday, June 21 2749
Monday, June24 3173
Part 8
Tuesday, June 25 3479
Part 9
Wednesday, June 26 3865
Thursday, June 27 4201
Part 10
Friday, June 28 4483
Monday, July 1 4669
Tuesday, July 2 4909
Part 11
Summaries 5601
(UI)
PAGENO="0004"
Iv
SUBJECT HEADINGS
Aircraft
Aluminum
Athletic goods
Barber and beauty shop equipment
Bicycle parts and accessories
Ceramic tile, glass, pottery, etc
Chemicals
Coal
Dairy products
Distilling industry
Electronics and cameras
Fish
Fruits and vegetables
Fur
General
Government witnesses
Honey
Industrial rubber products
Iron and steel
Lead and zinc
Leather goods
Machine tools
Meat
Miscellaneous
Oil and gas
Optics
Paper and publishing
Pins, fasterners, etc
Plastics, buttons, etc
Rubber footwear
Stainless steel
Textiles
Umbrellas
Watches
Window shades
Wood and wood products
Date
June 21.
June 24.
June 21.
June 21.
June 24.
June 25.
June 28 & July 1.
July 1.
July 2.
June 21.
June 25.
June 24.
July 2.
June 26.
June 11, 12, 13, 14, 17.
June 4, 5, 10.
June 24.
June 26.
June 18.
June 18.
June 26.
June 21.
June 24.
July 2.
June 27.
June 21.
June 27.
June 21.
June 21.
June 25.
June 21.
June 19.
June 21.
June 25.
June 25.
June 27.
Page
2
5
8
13
19
Press release dated Thursday, May 9, 1968, announcing public hearings
on tariff and trade proposals
Proposed "Trade Expansion Act of 1968," committee print -
Message of the President
Draft bill (H.R. 17551, introduced by Chairman Mills on May 28,
1968, at the request of the administration)
Section-by-section analysis
WRITTEN COMMUNICATION SUBMITTED BY GOVERNMENT
OFFICIAL
Fowler, Hon. Henry H., Secretary of the Treasury, letter dated June 6,
1968, to Chairman Mills 666
ORAL STATEMENTS BY GOVERNMENT OFFICIALS
Agriculture, Department of:
Freeman, Hon. Orville L., Secretary 649, 654
loanes, Raymond A., Administrator, Foreign Agriculture Service__ 439, 649
Labor, Department of:
Wirtz, Hon. W. Willard, Secretary 28, 37
Blackman, Herbert N., Administrator, Bu~reau of International Labor
Affairs
PAGENO="0005"
V
Commerce, Department of: Page
Smith, Hon. Cyrus R., Secretary 28
Garland, Allen H., Director, Trade and Commercial Policy Division_ 439
McQuade, Hon. Lawrence C., Assistant Secretary 28, 439
Consumer Affairs, Special Assistant to the President for, Miss Betty
Furness 649, 662
Interior, Department of, Hon. Stewart L. Udall, Secretary 28, 33
State, Department of:
Rusk, Hon. Dean, Secretary 649
Solomon, Hon. Anthony M., Assistant Secretary for Economic Affairs,
Bureau of Inter-American Affairs 649
Trade Negotiations, Office of Special Representative for:
Roth, Ambassador William M., special representative for trade
negotiations 28, 42, 439, 446, 649
Gates, Theodore R., assistant special representative 439
Malmgren, Harald B., assistant special representative 28, 439
Rehm, John B., general counsel 28, 439
Treasury, Department of:
Petty, Hon. John, Deputy Assistant Secretary, Office of International
Affairs 439
Smith, Fred B., general counsel 28
STATEMENTS OF PUBLIC WITNESSES
Abbitt, Hon. W. M., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Virginia 4819
Abel, I. W., president, United Steelworkers of America 1845, 1895
Abernethy, Hon. Thomas G., a Representative in Congress from the State
of Mississippi 3173
Ackert, James D., Domestic Producers Association of New England - - - - 3386
Ad Hoc Committee of Galvanized Electrical Transmission Tower Fabri-
cators:
Gannaway, Charles B., chairman 2211
Searls, David T., counsel. 2211
Adair, Hon. E. Ross, a Representative in Congress from the State of
Indiana 894
Adams, Charles F., chairman of the board, Raytheon Co 3640
Adams, John Quincy, chairman, coordinating committee, Food Industries
of NewYork, Inc 3297
Adams, Dr. Walter, professor of economics, and director of program on
industrial structures in the Atlantic community, Michigan State Uni-
versity 1430
Aerospace Industries Association of America, Karl G. Harr, Jr., president 1391
AFL-CIO:
Biemiller, Andrew J., director, department of legislation 1091
Goldfinger, Nathaniel, director, department of research 1091
Alcan Aluminum Corp., Eric A. Trigg, president 3370
Aluminum Association, John M. Mitchell 3345
American Aniline Products, Inc.:
Marshall, James J., president, and in behalf of Ad Hoc Committee of
U.S. Dvestuff Products 4724
Stewart, Eugene L., counsel 4724
American Apparel Manufacturers Association, Lawrence S. Phillips 2538
American Association of Oilwell Drilling Contractors, Robert A. Busch-
man, president 4314
American Association of Port Authorities, Roger H. Gilman, first vice
president 861
American Association of University Women, Dr. Lois Torrence 869
American Association of Woolen Importers, Inc.:
Bissinger, Fred, president 2553
Daniels, Michael P., counsel 2553
Smith, David 2553
American Beekeeping Federation, Glenn Gibson, executive secretary 3453
American Cvanamid Co., John M. Fasoli, director of public relations - - - 4651
PAGENO="0006"
VI
American Farm Bureau Federation: Page
Harris, Herbert E., II, legislative counsel 1215
Lynn, John C., legislative director 1215
American Fur Merchants Associations, Inc., Eugene Dreisin, president__ - 4039
American Importers Association:
O'Brien, Gerald, executive vice president 829
Floor covering group:
Herzstein, Robert E., counsel 2599
Imported footwear group:
Hemmendinger, Noel, counsel 4109, 4155
Lipkowitz, Edward, chairman 4155, 4174
Non-rubber-footwear group:
Donohue, Joseph F, and Noel Ilemmendinger, counsel, imported
footwear grOul) 4109
Organic chemicals group:
Graubard, Seymour, counsel 4673
Homes, Walter W 4673, 4706
Hochschwender, Karl 4673, 4704
Stobaugh, Robert B., Jr 4673, 4675
Textile and apparel group:
Daniels, Michael P., counsel 2415, 2417
Hohenberg, Bernard L., chairman 2415
American Iron & Steel Institute, Thomas F. Patton 1845
American Institute for Imnorted Steel, Inc., Kurt Orhan, president 2088
American Loudspeaker Manufacturers Association, Eugene L. Stewart,
counsel 3518
American National Cattlemen's Association:
Carrothers, R. B 3196
House, Bill, president 3196
American Petroleum Refiners Association, Walter Famariss, Jr., president_ 4308
American Producers of Italian-Type Cheeses Association, and Stella cheese
division, Universal Foods Corp., Stephen F. Owen, Jr., counsel 4866
American Retail Federation:
Savona, Vincent 1404, 1409
Selonick, Edward H 1404
American Soybean Association:
Lodwick, Seeley G., vice president 950
Ranaolph, Chet, executive vice president 950
American Textile Manufacturers Institute:
Dent, Frederick B., president 2360
Jackson, Robert C., executive vice president 2360
American `W atch Association, Bertram Lowe, chairman, customs com-
mittee 3705
Anti_Friction-Bearing Manufacturers Association, Bernard J. Shallow,
chairman 2974
Ashbrook, Hon. John M., a Representative in Congress from the State
of Ohio 4829
Ashley, James M., chairman of the board, Trade Relations Council of
the United States, Inc 1109
Ashton, Prof. David J., director, International Center of New England~ 1572, 1573
Association on Japanese Textile Imports, Inc., Mike M. Masaoka, Washing-
ton representative 2490
Athletic Goods Manufacturers Association, William P. Holmes 30.71
Atlanta Artificial Kidney Center, John H. Sadler, M.D., director_ 1324, 1333
Baird Chemical Industries, Joseph M. Baird, chairman of the board~_- 4764
Balgooyen H. W., New York Chamber of Commerce 1271
Barbaree, George, international secretary-treasurer, and Robert Lord,
vice president, International Brotherhood of Operative Potters- - 3756, 3801
Barnard, Robert C., counsel, Synthetic Organic Chemical Manufacturers
Association, and Dry Colors i\'Ianufacturers Association 4483, 4512
Bates, Hon. William H., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Massachusetts 3378, 3865
Bea.rd, Charles H., chairman of the board, National Committee on Inter-
national Trade Documentation 1015
Beckman, Luke F., president, Minster Canning Co 5036
Beckmann, R. J., Domestic Wood Louvered Products Industry 4437
PAGENO="0007"
VII
Beicher, Hon. Page, a Representative in Congress from the State of Page
Oklahoma 3178
Belgian-American Chamber of Commerce in the United States, Inc., Robert
M. Gottschalk, counsel 1597
Bender, Mark G., Ph. D., assistant professor of economics, Holy Cross
College, Worcester, Mass 1659
Bendix International, W. Michael Blumenthal, president 1238
Berry, Hon. E. V., a Representative in Congress from the State of South
Dakota 1085, 3996
Bevill, Hon. Tom, a Representative in Congress from the State of Alabama. 1839
Bicycle Manufacturers Association, Wi]liam M. Hannon, chairman, Wash-
ington affairs committee 4902
Biemiller, Andrew J., director, department of legislation, AFL-CIO 1091
Bissinger, Fred, president, American Association of Woolen Importers, Inc_ 2553
Blackburn, Hon. Benjamin B., a Representative in Congress from the State
of Georgia 1324
Blackie, William, chairman, Caterpillar Tractor Co 1348
Blumenthal, W. Michael, president, Bendix International 1238
B'nai B'rith, Herman Edelsberg, director, International Council 1026
Boeing Aircraft, T. A. Wilson, J)resident 1343, 1347
Boland, Hon. Edward P., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Massachusetts 895
Bonomo, Ralph, Italy-American Chamber of Commerce 1619, 1622
Boot & Shoemakers Union, John E. Mara, president, and George 0.
Fecteau, general president, United Shoeworkers of America, AFL-C10 - 4102
Bradford District, Pennsylvania Oil Producers Association, Pennsylvania
Grade Crude Oil Association, and New York State Oil Producers As-
sociation, J. Paul Jones 4212, 4251
Bradley, Mrs. David G., foreign policy chairman, League of Women Voters
of the United States 982
British-American Chamber of Commerce of New York, Earl W. Kintner 1579
Broun, E. Fontaine, president, Manmade Fiber Producers Association 2464
Broyhill, Hon. James T., a Representative in Congress from the State of
North Carolina 1475
Buchanan, Hon. John, a Representative in Congress from the State of
Alabama 1319
Burch, Robert, Rocky Mountain Oil & Gas Association 4346
Burleson, Hon. Omar, a Representative in Congress from the State of
Texas 4205
Burrows, Fred W., executive vice president, International Apple Associa-
tion 5007
Burton, Hon. Laurence J., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Utah 1478
Buschman, Robert A., president, American Association of Oilwell Drilling
Contractors 4314
Business Builders International, Inc., J. Theodore Wolfson, president 857
Cal-Compack Foods, Gentry Corp., Santa Maria Chili, Inc., and Universal
Foods Corp., W. Ed Crane, in behalf of 5001
California Council for International Trade, Gerald B. Levine, director and
member, U.S. trade policy committee 1280
California Independent Producers & Royalty Owners Association, Joseph
C. Shell, executive director 4212, 4270
California Olive Growers & Canners Industry Committee, G. K. Patterson 4991
California Strawberry Advisory Board, Northwest Canners & Freezers
Association, and Oregon Strawberry Council, Robert E. Ward 3743
Camero, Sergio, administrator, Puerto Rico Economic Development
Administration 4348
Campbell, William C., secretary, industrial rubber products division,
Rubber Manufacturers Association 4190
Carmody, Edward T., vice chairman and director, Timex, the U.S. Time
Corp 3720
Carrothers, R. B., American National Cattlemen's Association 3196
Cast Iron Soil Pipe Institute:
Hunt, Frederick D., foreign trade consultant 2234
Perry, J. Wiley, Jr., chairman, import study committee 2234
Caterpillar Tractor Co.:
Blackie, William, chairman 1343, 1348
Eckley, Robert S., assistant to the president 1035
PAGENO="0008"
VIII
Page
Cement Industry Antidumping Committee, John C. Mundt, vice chairman 1369
Cerf, Jay H., manager, international group, Chamber of Commerce of the
United States 1710
Chamber of Commerce of the United States, Jay H. Cerf, manager, inter-
national group 1710
Cheese Importers Association of America, Martin A. Fromer, counsel 4873
Chester, Howard P., executive secretary, Stone, Glass, and Clay Coordi-
nating Committee 3756
Chesterton, A. Devereaux, director, International Center of New Eng-
land 1572, 1576
Christopher, William F., chairman, tariff committee, Society of the Plastics
Industry, Inc~ 3098
Clay, Henry J., Netherlands Chamber of Commerce in the United States,
Inc 1589
Cleveland Greenhouse Growers Cooperative Association, Jerry Nowinski,
chairman~ 5027
Clothespin & Veneer Products Association, and Slide Fastener Association,
Richard A. Tilden 2752
Coerper, Milo G., German-American Chamber of Commerce~ 1594
Colmer, Hon. William M., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Mississippi 4819
Committee for a National Trade Policy, Carl J. Gilbert, chairman 741
Committee for Economic Development, Howard C. Petersen, vice chair-
man, international economic studies, research, and policy cornmittee_ - - - 1225
Committee of Producers of Ferroalloys & Related Products, Ronald L.
Cunningham 2170
Conneaut Port Authority, Mayor EdwardJ. Griswold, of Conneaut, Ohio~ 1424
Control Data Corp., Hugh P. Donaghue, assistant to the president 1416
Cooper, Mitchell J., counsel, footwear division, Rubber Manufacturers
Association 4148
Cooperating Oil & Gas Association, Clinton Engstrand, vice chairman,
liaison committee, & president and chairman, Kansas Independent Oil
& Gas Association 4212, 4238
Cornett, Hollan, executive board member, United Stone & Allied Products
Workers of America 3756, 3792
Council, Buford W., chairman, tomato committee, Florida Fruit & Vege-
table Association 4951, 4964
Cowherd, Edwin R., vice president, dyestuff and chemical division, GAF
Corn 4640
Cox, J. Ahney, past president and chairman, competition and marketing
agreements committee, Florida Fruit & Vegetable Association 4951
Crane, W. Ed, in behalf of Cal-Compack Foods, Gentry Corp., Santa
Maria Chili, Inc., and Universal Foods Corp 5001
Culbertson, J. Steele, director, National Fish Meal & Oil Association 3429
Cunningham, Ronald L., Committee of Producers of Ferroalloys & Related
Products 2170
Daniels, Michael P.:
American Association of Woolen Importers, Inc., counsel 2553
American Importers Association, textile and apparel greup,
counsel 2415, 2417
Danish-American Trade Council, Inc.:
Hessel, B. H 1626
Wedell, Gustav, chairman, business practices committee 1626
Darman Morton H., chairman of the board, National Association of Wool
Manufacturers and in behalf of National Wool Growers Association 2376
Davidson, Paul H., president, International Importers, Inc., H. William
Tanaka, attorney, in behalf of 3634
Davies Richard, consultant, Synthetic Organic Chemical Manufacturers
Association 4483, 4590
Davis Roy B., president, National Cotton Council of America 2562
Dawson, David H., vice president, E. I. DuPont de Nemours & Co 4596
DeBlois, Robert, New England Fuel Institute 4302
Dellenback, Hon. John, a Representative in Congress from the State of
Oregon 4006
Denney, Hon. Robert V., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Nebraska 3191, 4007, 4843
PAGENO="0009"
Ix
Page
Dent, Frederick B., president, American Textile Manufacturers Institute - 2360
Dent, Hon. John, a Representative in Congress from the State of Penn-
sylvania 3873
Derwinski, Hon. Edward J., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Illinois 1836
Dc Santis, Arthur A., executive secretary, Italy-American Chamber of
Commerce 1619
Dirlam, Dr. Joel B., professor of economics, University of Rhode Island~ 1430
Diouhy, John, executive vice president, Emil J. Paidar Co 3136
Donaghue, Hugh P., assistant to the president, Control Data Corp 1416
Donehower, William L., Jr., Rolled Zinc Manufacturers Association 2306
Donohue, Hon. Harold D., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Massachusetts 1083
Donohue, Joseph F., Nonrubber Footwear Group, and Noel Hemmend-
inger, Imported Footwear Group, American Importers Association 4109
Domestic bicycle tire and tube industry, C. J. Warrell 3450
Domestic Producers Association of New England, James D. Ackert 3386
Domestic Wood Louvered Products Industry:
Beckmann, B.. J 4437
Golden, David A., counsel 4437
Dorn, I-Ion. William Jennings Bryan, a Representative in Congress from
the State of South Carolina 2407
Douglas, Donald W., Jr., vice president, McDonnell Douglas Corp 2783
Dreisin, Eugene, president, American Fur Merchants Association, Inc - - - 4039
Dry Colors Manufacturers Association, Robert C. Barnard, counsel 4483
DuPont, E. I., de Nemours & Co., David H. Dawson, vice president 4596
Dymsza, Dr. William A., research director, International Business Institute,
Graduate School of Business Administration, Rutgers University 1637
Eastern i\'leat Packers Association, Inc., and Meat Trade Institute of New
York, George Kern 3287
Eberlein, John G., chairman, drawback committee, National Customs
Brokers & Forwarders Association of America, Inc 1021
Eckhardt, Hon. Bob, a Representative in Congress from the State of
Texas 1480
Eckley, Robert S., assistant to the president. Caterpillar Tractor Co_~ 1035
Edelsberg, Herman, director, International Council, B'nai B'rith 1026
Electronic Industries Association:
Consumer products division:
Fezell, George H., vice president 3479
Hoffman, Charles N., chairman 3479
International trade matters division:
McCauley, Alfred R., special counsel 3479
Parts and distributor Products divisions:
Stewart, Eugene L., counsel 3518
EMBA Mink Breeders Association, Richard Westwood, president 4012
Emergency Committee for American Trade:
Blackie, William, chairman, Caterpillar Tractor Co 1343, 1348
Purcell, Robert, finance committee chairman, International Basic
Economic Corp 1343, 1350
Watson, Arthur K., chairman 1343
Wilson, T. A., president, Boeing Aircraft 1343, 1347
Engstrand, Clinton, vice chairman, liaison committee, Cooperating Oil
& Gas Association, and president and chairman, Kansas Independent
Oil& Gas Association 4212, 4238
Epstein, Lawrence D., vice president, Perry Products, Co 2243
Eshleman, Hon. Edwin D., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Pennsylvania 2751
Everett, Hon. Robert A., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Tennessee 3196
Fairchild Camera & Instrument Corp., Richard Hodgson, vice chairman,
board of directors 3644
Fallon, Hon. George H., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Maryland 1832
Famariss, Walter, Jr., president, American Petroleum Refiners Associa-
tion 4308
Fasoli, John M., director of public relations, American Cyanamid Co_ - - - 4651
PAGENO="0010"
x
Fect*eau, George 0., general president, United Shoeworkers of America, Page
AFL-CIO, and John E. Mara, president, Boot & Shoemakers Union~ 4102
Fezell, George H., vice president, Consumer Products Division, Electronic
Industries Association 3479
Finkel, Leonard E., president, Umbrella Frame Association of America - - 3140
Fisher, Hon. 0. C., a Representative in Congress from the State of Texas_ 877
Flavor Pict Cooperative, Louis F. Rauth 5023
Fletcher, Aubrey, executive vice president, C. Tennant Sons & Co 2311
Florida Citrus Mutual, Robert W. Rutledge, executive vice president_ - - - 4981
Florida Fruit & Vegetable Association:
Council, Buford W., chairman, tomato committee 4951, 4964
Cox, J. Abney, past president and chairman, competition and market-
ing agreements committee 4951
Peters, John S., manager, membership and industry relations division_ 4951,
4966
Food Industries of New York, Inc., John Quincy Adams, chairman,
coordinating committee 3297
Fox, Stark, executive vice president, Independent Oil & Gas Producers
of California 4212, 4266
French, Charles W., vice president, Pfister Chemical, Inc 4648
Fromer, Martin A., counsel, Cheese Importers Association of America~_ 4873
Fuller, Robert P., chairman, government affairs committee, National
Shoeboard Conference, Inc 4124
GAF Corp., Edwin R. Cowherd, vice president, dyestuff and chemical
division 4640
Galifianakis, Hon. Nick, a Representative in Congress from the State of
North Carolina 4008
Gallagher, Daniel R., director, Green Olive Trade Association 4991
Galvanized Electrical Transmission Tower Fabricators, ad hoc Committee
of (See Ad Hoc Committee, etc.)
Gannaway, Charles B., chairman, ad hoc Committee of Galvanized
Electrical Transmission Tower Fabricators 2211
Geier, Philip 0., Jr., National Machine Tool Builders' Association 2845
Geller, Norman, director, Independent Wire Drawers Association~ - 2194, 2196
Gentry Corp., Cal-Compack Foods, Santa Maria Chili, Inc., and Universal
Foods Corp., E. Ed Crane, in behalf of 5001
German American Chamber of Commerce, Milo G. Coerper 1594
Gerstacker, Carl, chairman of the board, Manufacturing Chemists
Association 44S3, 4484
Gibson, Glenn, executive secretary, American Beekeeping Federation - - - 3453
Gilbert, Carl J., chairman, Committee for a National Trade Policy 741
Gilbert, Robert A., vice president, Investors League, Inc 1031
Gillis, John, vice president, and member, board of directors, Monsanto Co~ 4618
Gilman, Roger H., first vice president, American Association of Port
Authorities 861
Glass, Irving R., executive vice president, Tanners' Council of America,
Inc 4064, 4082
Golden, David A.:
Domestic Wood Louvered Products Industry, counsel 4437
United States Potters Association, customs and tariff counsel 3803
Goldfinger, Nathaniel, director, Department of Research, AFL-CIO - - - 1091
Goldstein, Alan, chairman, national affairs committee, National Footwear
Manufacturers Association 4064
Golson, Charles E., International Engineering & Construction Industries
Council 805
Gottschalk, Robert M., counsel, Belgian-American Chamber of Commerce
in the United States, Inc 1597
Graham, Harry L., legislative representative, National Grange 756
Graubard, Seymour, counsel, organic chemicals group, American Im-
porters Association 4673
Greater Detroit Board of Commerce, Frederick C. Nash, world affairs
committee 1260
Greater Minneapolis Chamber of Commerce, J. Patrick Kittler, chairman,
world trade committee 1290
Green Olive Trade Association, Daniel R. Gallagher, director 4991
Griswold, Mayor Edward J., city of Conneaut, Ohio, behalf of Conneaut
Port Authority 1424
PAGENO="0011"
XI
Guenther, Dr. 1-larry P., dean, School of Business Administration, George- Page
town University 1662
Ilagan, Hon. G. Elliott, a Representative in Congress from the State of
Georgia 3179
Haines, Walter W., organic chemicals group, American Importers Asso-
ciation 4673, 4706
Hall, I-Ion. Durward G., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Missouri 1081
Hamilton, Hon. Lee H., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Indiana 4006
Hannon, William M., chairman, Washington affairs committee, Bicycle
Manufacturers Association 4902
Hansen, Hon. Clifford P., a U.S. Senator from the State of Wyoming~.. 3192
Hardboard Manufacturers, James R. Sharp, attorney 4447
Harr, Karl G., Jr., president, Aerospace Industries Association of America 1391
Harris, Ilerhert E., II, legislative counsel, American Farm Bureau Federa-
tion 1215
Harrison, Hon. William H., a Representative in Congress from the State
of Wyoming 4933
Harsha, Hon. William H., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Ohio 1838, 4831
Ilartke, 1-Ion. Vance, a U.S. Senator from the State of Indiana 1931
1-larvey, Hon. James, a Representative in Congress from the State of
Michigan 4833
Hemingway, Stuart C., Jr., Stainless Steel Flatware Manufacturing Asso-
ciation 3091
Hemmendinger, Noel, counsel:
Imported footwear group, American Importers Association 4109, 4155
Imported footwear group, and Joseph F. Donohue, nonrubber footwear
group, American Importers Association 4109
Henderson, Hon. David N., a Representative in Congress from the State
of North Carolina 3384
1-lejiderson, David W., executive secretary, National Board of Fur Farm
Organizations 4012, 4019
I-Ierkner, George W., executive vice president, Warner & Swasey Co_ 2845, 2971
Herzstein, Robert E., counsel, floor covering group, American Import
Association, and Wilton and \Telvet Carpet & Rug Importers 2599
Hessel, B. H., 1)anish-Amnerican Trade Council, Inc 1637
Hicks, W. B., Jr., executive secretary, Liberty Lobby 1256
Ilillman, Jimmye S., head, Department of Agricultural Economics, Uni-
versity of Arizona 1039
Hobbs, Claude E., chairman, foreign trade committee, National Electrical
Manufacturers Association 3507
ilochschwender, Karl, organic chemicals group, American Importers Asso-
ciation 4673, 4704
Hodgson, Richard, vice chairman, board of directors, Fairchild Camera
& Instrument Corp 3644
I-Ioffman, Charles N., chairman, Consumer Products Division, Electronic
Industries Association 3479
Hohenherg, Bernard L., chairman, textile and apparel group, American
Importers Association 2415
I-Iolmes, William P., Athletic Goods Manufacturers Association 3071
Home, Dr. M. K., Jr., chief economist, National Cotton Council of
America 2562
Horton, Hon. Frank, a Representative in Congress from the State of New
York 4835
House, Bill, president, American National Cattlemen's Association 3196
Hull, Rear Adm. Harry, executive director, International Center of New
England 1572
Hunt, Frederick D., foreign trade consultant, Cast Iron Soil Pipe Institute 2234
Imported Hardwood Products Association, Myron Solter, counsel 4428
Independent Oil & Gas Producers of California, Stark Fox, executive vice
President - 4212, 4266
Independent Petroleum Association of America, Harold M. McClure, Jr.,
president 4212, 4266, 4293
PAGENO="0012"
XII
Independent Wire Drawers Association: Page
Geller, Norman, director 2194, 2196
Muntwyler, F. C., president 2194
Intemann, Herman K., vice president, Union Carbide Corp 4322
International Apple Association, Fred W. Burrows, executive vice presi-
dent 5007
International Basic Economic Corp., Robert Purcell, finance committee
cI~airman 1343, 1350
International Brotherhood of Operative Potters, George Barbaree, interna-
tional secretary-treasurer, and Robert Lord, vice president 3756, 3801
International Center of New England:
Ashton, Prof. DavidJ., director 1572, 1573
Chesterton,A. Devereaux, director 1572, 1576
Hull, Rear Adm. Harry, executive director 1572
International Engineering & Construction Industries Council, Charles E.
Golson 80o
International Importers, Inc., H. William Tanaka, attorney in behalf of
Paul H. Davidson, president 3634
International Leather Goods, Plastics & Novelty Workers Union, AFL-
CIO, Norman Zukowsky, international president 4130
Tnternational Longshoremen's & Warehousemen's Union, Albert Lannon,
Jr., Washington representative 864
International Trade Development Board:
Parker, Joseph 0., chairman 960
Pringle, Vic 960
Investors League, Inc., Robert A. Gilbert, vice president 1031
Italy-American Chamber of Commerce:
Bonomo, Ralph 1619, 1622
De Santis, Arthur A., executive secretary 1619
Jackson, Robert C., executive vice president, American Textile Manu-
facturers Institute 2360
Javits, Hon. Jacob K., a U.S. Senator from the State of New York 3986
Johnson, Lindsay, F., Lead-Zinc Producers Committee 2279
Johnson, Reuben L., director, legislative services, National Farmers Union_ 786
Jones, J. Paul, Pennsylvania Grade Crude Oil Association, Bradford
district, Pennsylvania Oil Producers Association, and New York State
Oil Producers Association 4212, 4251
Kansas Independent Oil & Gas Association, Clinton Engstrand, president
and chairman, and vice chairman, liaison committee, Cooperating Oil &
Gas Association 4212, 4238
Kaplan, Richard, counsel, Division of Imports, Rubber Manufacturers As-
sociation 4190
Kastenmeier, Hon. Robert W., a Representative in Congress from the
State of Wisconsin 4001
Keith, Hon. Hastings, a Representative in Congress from the State of
Massachusetts 3385
Kentucky, Commonwealth of, Hon. Louie B. Nunn, Governor, statement
read into the record by Hon. M. Gene Snyder, a Representative in
Congress from the State of Kentucky 4930
Kern, George, Meat Trade institute of New York, and Eastern Meat
Packers Association, Inc 3287
Kindleberger, Charles P., professor of economics, Massachusetts Institute
of Technology 1652
Kintner, Earl W., British-American Chamber of Commerce of New York. - 1579
Kittler, J. Patrick, chairman, world trade committee, Greater Minneapolis
Chamber of Commerce 1290
Kleppe, Hon. Thomas S., a Representative in Congress from the State of
North Dakota 3195, 4009
Kohnstamm, H., & Co., Inc., Yale Meltzer, manager, commercial develop-
ment and market research, patents, and trademarks 4628
Korzenik, Sidney S., executive director and counsel, National Knitted
Outerwear Association 2577
Kvros, Hon. Peter N., a Representative 4in Congress from the State of
~aine
Laird Hon. Melvin R., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Wisconsin 886
Lakeway Chemicals, Inc., Normand Phaneuf, president 4642
PAGENO="0013"
xiii:
Page
Langdon, Jim C., chairman, Railroad Commission of Texas 4285
Langen, Hon. Odin, a Representative in Congress from the State of Min-
nesota 4943
Lannon, Albert, Jr., Washington representative, International Longshore-
men's & Warehousemen's Union 864
Latta, Hon. Delbert L., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Ohio 3999
Lead-Zinc Producers Committee, Lindsay F. Johnson 2279
League of Women Voters of the United States, Mrs. David G. Bradley,
foreign policy chairman 982
LeBlond, R. K., Machine Tool Co., Daniel W. LeBlond, president~ 2845, 2969
Levine, Gerald B., director and member, U.S. trade policy committee,
California Council for International Trade 1280
Liberty Lobby, W. B., Hicks, Jr., executive secretary 1256
Lipkowitz, Edward, chairman, imported footwear group, American Im-
porters Association -- 4155, 4174
Lloyd, Hon. Sherman P., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Utah 902
Lobred, Leonard K., director, International Trade Division, National
Canners Association 1009
Lodwick, Seeley G., vice president, American Soybean Association 950
Long, lIon. Clarence D., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Maryland 4927
Long, Hon. Speedy 0., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Louisiana . 3189
Lord, Robert, vice president, and George Barharee, international secretary-
treasurer, International Brotherhood of Operative Potters 3756, 3801
Lovre, Harold 0., in behalf of domestic mink ranchers 4012
Lowe, Bertram, chairman, customs committee, American Watch Associa-
tion 3705
Lundquist, James H., counsel, Meat Importers' Council, Inc 3212
Lynn, John C., legislative director, American Farm Bureau Federation__ - 1215
McCauley, Alfred R., special counsel, Division on International Trade
Matters, Electronic Industries Association 3479
McClure, Harold M., Jr., president, Independent Petroleum Association
of America 4212, 4266, 4293
McClure, Hon. James A., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Idaho 1339
McDonnell Douglas Corp., Donald W. Douglas, Jr., vice president 2783
McEwen, Hon. Robert C., a Representative in Congress from the State of
New York 3991
MeVay, M.D., chairman, Government Relations Committee, National
Soybean Processors Association 1234
Mack, James K., counsel, National Confectioners Association of the
United States 3470
Magdanz, Don F., executive secretary, National Livestock Feeders
Association 3266
Mahon, Hon. George H., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Texas 4279
Manmade Fiber Producers Association, E. Fontaine Broun, president~ 2464
Manufacturing Chemists Association, Carl Gerstacker, chairman of the
board 4483, 4484
Mara, John E., president, Boot & Shoemakers Union, and George 0.
Fccteau, general president, United Shoeworkers of America, AFL-CIO - 4102
Marsh, Edwin E., executive secretary, National Wool Growers Association 3288
Marsh, Hon. John 0., Jr., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Virginia 881, 959
Marshall, James J., president, American Aniline Products, Inc., and in
behalf of ad hoc committee of U.S. Dyestuff Producers 4724
Martin, Hon. Dave, a Representative in Congress from the State of
Nebraska 3180, 4834
Masaoka, Mike Al., Washington representative, Association on Japanese
Textile Imports, Inc 2490
Massachusetts Committee for the Preservation of the Groundfish~ In-
dustry, Howard W. Nickerson, chairman-coordinator 3420
PAGENO="0014"
XIV
Matsunaga, Hon. Spark M., a Representative in Congress from the State Page
of Hawaii 2352, 3183 4290
May, Otto B., Inc., Ernest M. May 4616
Meat Importers' Council, Inc., James H. Lundquist, counsel 3212
Meat Trade Institute of New York, and Eastern Meat Packers Associa-
tion, Inc., George Kern 3287
Melt~er, Y ale, manager, commercial development and market research,
patents and trademarks, H. Kohristamm & Co., Inc 4628
Meyer, A., Jr., president, Tanners' Council of America, Inc 4064, 4079
Miller, Henry E., National Retail Merchants Association 802
Minshall, Hon. William E., a Representative in Congress from the State
of Ohio 1834
Minster Canning Co., Luke F. Beckman, president 5036
Mitchell, John M., Aluminum Association 3345
Monagan, Hon. John S., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Connecticut 891
Monsanto Co., John Gillis, vice president, and member board of directors - 4618
Montgomery, Hon. G. V. (Sonny), a Representative in Congress from the
State of Mississippi 4844
Moody, Joseph E., president, National Coal Policy Conference, Inc 4810
Morris, Hon. Thomas G., a Representative in Congress from the State of
New Mexico 899
Moss, Hon. Frank E., a Representative in Congress from the State of Utah 4000
Mundt, John C., vice chairman, Cement Industry Antidumping Com-
mittee 1369
Muntwyler, F. C., 1)reSident, Independent Wire Drawers Association_ - - - 2194
Muskie, Hon. Edmund S., a U.S. Senator from the State of Maine 3868
Nash, Frederick C., world affairs committee, Greater Detroit Board of
Commerce 1260
Nation-Wide Committee on Import-Export Policy, 0. R. Strackbein,
chairman 903
National Association of Wool Manufacturers, Morton H. Darman, chair-
man of the board 2376
National Board of Fur Farm Organizations, David W. Henderson, execu-
tive secretary 4012, 4019
National Canners Association, Leonard K. Lobred, director, international
trade division 1009
National Coal Policy Conference, Inc., Joseph E. Moody, president 4810
National Committee on International Trade Documentation, Charles 1-1.
Beard, chairman of the board 1Q15
National Confectioners Association of the United States:
Mack, James K., counsel 3470
Sifers, Burr, chairman, board of directors 3470
National Cotton Council of America:
Davis, Roy B., president 2562
Home, Dr. M. K., Jr., chief economist 2562
Sayre, Dr. Charles R 2562
National Customs Brokers & Forwarders Association of America, Inc.,
John G. Eberlein, chairman, Drawback Committee 1021
National Electrical Manufacturers Association, Claude E. Hobbs, chair-
man, Foreign Trade Committee 3507
National Farmers Union, Reuben L. Johnson, director, legislative services~ 786
National Fish Meal & Oil Association, J. Steele Culbertson, director 3429
National Footwear Manufacturers Association:
Goldstein, Alan, chairman, National Affairs Committee 4064
Shannon, Thomas F., counsel 4064
National Foreign Trade Council, Inc., Robert M. Norris, president 1495
National Grange:
Graham, Harry L., legislative representative 756
Newsom, Herschel D., master 756
National Knitted Outerwear Association, Sidney S. Korzenik, executive
director and counsel 2577
National Livestock Feeders Association, Don F. Magdanz, executive
secretary 3266
National Machine Tool Builders Association, Philip 0. Geier, Jr 2845
National Milk Producers Federation, Otie M. Reed 4845
PAGENO="0015"
xv
Page
National Retail Merchants Association, Henry E. Miller 802
National Shoehoard Conference, Inc., Robert P. Fuller, chairman, Gov-
ernment Affairs Committee 4124
National Soybean Processors Association, M. D. McVay, chairman, Gov-
ernment Relations Committee 1234
National Wool Growers Association:
Darman, Morton H 2376
Marsh, Edwin E., executive secretary 3288
Nelsen, Hon. Ancher, a Representative in Congress from the State of
Minnesota 4003, 4823
Netherlands Chamber of Comnierce in the United States, Inc., Henry J.
Clay 1389
Neu, Hugo, chairman, Scrap Industry Trade Policy Council 2202
New England Fuel Institute, Robert DeBlois 4302
New York Chamber of Commerce, H. W. Balgooyen 1271
New York State Oil Producers Association, Bradford district, Pennsyl-
vania Oil Producers Association, and Pennsylvania Grade Crude Oil
Association, J. Paul Jones 4212, 4251
Newsom, Herschel D., master, National Grange 756
Nickerson, 1-loward W., chairman-coordinator, Massachusetts Committee
for the Preservation of the Groundfish Industry 3420
Norris, Robert M., president, National Foreign Trade Council, Inc 1493
Northern Textile Association, Fulton Rindge, Jr., chairman 2379
Northwest Canners & Freezers Association, Oregon Strawberry Council,
and California Strawberry Advisory Board, Robert E. Ward 3743
Northwest Independent Steel Mills, Robert L. Phelps, in behalf of 2118
Nowinski, Jerry, chairman, Cleveland Greenhouse Growers Cooperative
Association 5027
Nunn, Hon. Louie B., Governor cf the Commonwealth of Kentucky, state-
ment read into the record by Hon. M. Gene Snyder, a Representative in
Congress from the State of Kentucky 4930
O'Brien, Gerald, executive vice president, American Importers Association 829
O'Hara, Clifford, director, port commerce, Port of New York Authority~ 873
Orban, Kurt, president, American Institute for Imported Steel, Inc 2088
Oregon Strawberry Council, Northwest Canners & Freezers Association,
and Califoriiia Strawberry Advisory Board, Robert E. Ward 3743
Owen, Stephen F., Jr., counsel, American Producers of Italian-Type
Cheeses Association, and Stella cheese division, Universal Foods Corp_ 4866
Paidar, Emil J., Co., John Dlouhy, executive vice president 3136
Palmby, Clarence, executive vice president, U.S. Feed Grains CounciL_~. 795
Palmer, John D., president, Tobacco Associates, Inc 1425
Panhandle Producers & Royalty Owners Association, Don Watson,
president 4212, 4248
Parker, Joseph 0., chairman, International Trade Development Boaid~. 960
Patterson, G. K., California Olive Growers & Canners Industry Committee 4991
Patton, Thomas F., American Iron & Steel Institute 1845
Pelly, Hon. Thomas M., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Washington 3381
Pennsylvania Grade Crude Oil Association, Bradford district, Pennsylva-
nia Oil Producers Association, and New York State Oil Producers
Association, J. Paul Jones 4212, 4251
Pennsylvania Oil Producers Association, Bradford district, Pennsylvania
Grade Crude Oil Association, and New York State Oil Producers
Association, J. Paul Jones 4212, 4231
Pepper, Hon. Claude, a Representative in Congress from the State of
Florida 4822
Perry, J. Wiley, Jr., chairman, import study committee, Cast Iron Soil
Pipe Institute 2234
Perry Products Co., Lawrence D. Epstein, vice president 2243
Peters, John S., manager, membership and industry relations division,
Florida Fruit&Ve~etable Association 4931, -4966
Petersen, Howard ~., vice chairman, international economic studies,
research and policy committee, Committee for Economic Development 1225
Pettis, Hon. Jerry L., a Representative in Congress from the State of
California 1840
PAGENO="0016"
XVI
Page
Pfister Chemical, Inc., Charles W. French, vice president 4648
Phaneuf, Normand, president, Lakeway Chemicals, Inc 4642
Phelps, Robert L., in behalf of Northwest Independent Steel Mills 2118
Philbin, Hon. Philip J., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Massachusetts 2349
Phillips, Lawrence S., American Apparel Manufacturers Association 2538
Pin, Clip & Fastener Association, Myron Solter, safety pin and straight
pin division 2774
Pogeler, Glenn H., president, Soybean Council of America, Inc 1411
Polanco-Abreu, Hon. Santiago, Resident Commissioner, Puerto Rico 4941
Port of New York Authority, Clifford O'Hara, director, port comrnerce - - 873
Price, Hon. Bob, a Representative in Congress from the State of Texas~ 4202
Pringle, Vie, International Trade Development Board 960
Purcell, Hon. Graham, a Representative in Congress from the State of
Texas 4201
Purcell, Robert, finance committee chairman, International Basic Eco-
nomic Corp 1343, 1350
Puerto Rico, Hon. Santiago Polanco-Abreu, Resident Commissioner 4941
Puerto Rico Economic Development Administration, Sergio Camero,
administrator 4348
Quie, Hon. Albert H., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Minnesota 4822
Q uillen, Hon. James H., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Tennessee 1336
Quimby, John, past director, West Coast Metal Importers Association - - 2228
Railroad Commission of Texas, Jim C. Langdon, chairman 4285
Randolph, Chet, executive vice president, American Soybean Assoeiation 950
Rnuth, Louis F., Flavor Piet Cooperative 5023
Raytheon Co., Charles F. Adams, chairman of the board 3640
Reed, Otie M., National Milk Producers Federation 4845
Reifel, Hon. Ben, a Representative in Congress from the State of South
Dakota 4005
Reiser, Ralph, international president, United Glass & Ceramic Workers
of North America 3756, 3767
Rhode Island Textile Association, Fulton Rindge, Jr 2379
Rhodes, Hon. John J., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Arizona 4821
Richman, Gilbert C., button division, Society of the Plastics Industry,
Inc 3131
Rindge, Fulton, Jr., chairman, Northern Textile Association, and in
behalf of Rhode Island Textile Association 2379
Rivers, Hon. L. Mendel, a Representative in Congress from the State of
South Carolina 4922
Robinson, Dana I., Sudbury, Mass 1297
Robison, Hon. Howard W., a Representative in Congress from the State
of New York 4820
Rocky Mountain Oil & Gas Association, Robert Burch 4346
Rodino, Hon~. Peter W., a Representative in Congress from the State of
New Jersey 4669
Rogers, Hon. Paul G., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Florida 4951
Rolled Zinc Manufacturers Association, William L. Donehower, Jr 2306
Rubber Manufacturers Association:
Campbell, William C., secretary, industrial rubber products division. 4190
Cooper, Mitchell J., footwear division 4148
Kaplan, Richard, counsel, division on imports 4190
Ruppe, Hon. Philip E., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Michigan 1842, 4009
Rutledge, Robert W., executive vice president, Florida Citrus MutuaL - - 4981
St. Germain, Hon. Fernand J., a Representative in Congress from the
State of Rhode Island 1087
St. Onge, Hon. William L., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Connecticut 2353, 4842
Sadler, John H., M.D., director, Atlanta Artificial Kidney Center~ 1324, 1333
Santa Maria Chili, Inc., Cal-Compack Foods, Gentry Corp., and Uni-
versal Foods Corp., W. Ed Crane, in behalf of 5001
PAGENO="0017"
XVII
Page
Savona, Vincent, and Edward H. Selonick, American Retail Federation~ 1404,
1409
Saylor, Hon. John P., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Pennsylvania 883
Sayre, Dr. Charles R., National Cotton Council of America 2562
Scandinavian Fur Agency, Inc., James R. Sharp, counsel 4050
Schadeberg, Hon. Henry C., a Representative in Congress from the State
of Wisconsin 1485
Scherle, Hon. William J., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Iowa 1492
Schwenger, Robert B., Kensington, Md 1678
Scrap ludustry Trade Policy Council, Hugo Neu, chairman 2202
Searls, David T., counsel, Ad Hoc Committee of Galvanized Electrical
Transmission Tower Fabricators 2211
Selonick, Edward H., and Vincent Savona, American Retail Federation - 1404
Shallow, Bernard J., chairman, Anti-Friction Bearing Manufacturers
Association 2974
Shannon, Thomas F., counsel, National Footwear Manufacturers Associa-
tion, and Tanners Council of America, Inc 4064
Sharp, James R., counsel:
Hardboard Manufacturers 4447
Scandinavian Fur Agency, Inc 4050
Shell, Joseph C., executive director, California Independent Producers &
Royalty Owners Association 4212, 4270
Shriver, Hon. Garner E., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Kansas 4210
Sifers, Burr, chairman, board of directors, National Confectioners Associa-
tion of the United States 3470
Slide Fastener Association, and Clothespin & Veneer Products Association,
Richard A. Tilden 2752
Smith, David, American Association of Woolen Importers, Inc 2553
Smith, Hon. James V., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Oklahoma 1313
Snyder, Hon. M. Gene, a Representative in Congress from the State of
Kentucky 4843, 4930
Society of the Plastics Industry, Inc.:
Christopher, William F., chairman, tariff committee 3098
Richman, Gilbert C., button division 3131
Solter, Myron, counsel:
Imported Hardwood Products Association 4428
Pin, Clip & Fastener Association, safety pin and straight pin division~ 2774
Soybean Council of America, Inc., Glenn H. Pogeler, president 1411
Stainless Steel Flatware Manufacturing Association, Stuart C. Hemingway,
Jr 3091
Steed, Netum A., president, Texas Independent Producers & Royalty
Owners Association 4212, 4253
Steed, Hon. Tom, a Representative in Congress from the State of
Oklahoma 3176
Steele, Hoyt P., chairman, commercial policy committee, U.S. Council of
the International Chamber of Commerce 1002
Steiger, Hon. William A., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Wisconsin 1486
Stewart, Eugene L., counsel:
American Loudspeaker Manufacturers Association 3518
American Aniline Products, Inc 4724
Electronic Industries Association, parts and distributor products
divisions 3518
Trade Relations Council of the United States, Inc 1109
U.S. Producers of Flat Glass 1504
Stitt, Nelson A., director, United States-Japan Trade Council 2126
Stobaugh, Robert B., Jr., organic chemicals group, American Importers
Association 4673, 4675
Stone, Glass, and Clay Coordinating Committee, Howard P. Chester,
executive secretary 3756
Strackbein, 0. R., chairman, Nation-Wide Committee on Import-Export
Policy 905
95-159-68-pt. 8-2
PAGENO="0018"
XVIII
Stratton, Hon. Samuel S., a Representative in Congress from the State of Page
New York 2405, 4004, 4825
Synthetic Organic Chemical Manufacturers Association:
Barnard, Robert C., counsel 4483, 4512
Davies, Richard, counsultant 4483, 4590
Turchan, Thomas P., president 4483, 4504
Talcott, Hon. Burt L., a Representative in Congress from the State of
California 3181
Tanaka, H. William, attorney, in behalf of Paul H. Davidson, president,
International Importers, Inc 3634
Tanners' Council of America, Inc.:
Glass, Irving R., executive vice president 4064, 4082
Meyer, A., Jr., president 4064, 4079
Shannon, Thomas F., counsel 4064
Taylor, Hon. Roy A., a Representative in Congress from the State of
North Carolina 2350, 4826
Teague, Hon. Olin E., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Texas 3174
Tennant, C., Sons & Co., Aubrey Fletcher, executive vice president 2311
Texa.s Independent Producers & Royalty Owners Association, Netum A.
Steed, president 4212, 4253
Thomas, Victor, general vice president, United Cement, Lime & Gypsum
Workers 3756, 3786
Thomson, Hon. Vernon, a Representative in Congress from the State of
Wisconsin
Thorn, Prof. Richard S., Department of Economics, University of Pitts-
burgh 691
Thorpe, A. E., vice president and secretary-treasurer, U.S. National Fruit
Export Council 853
Tilden, Richard A., Clothespin & Veneer Products Association, and Slide
Fastener Association 2752
Timex, the U.S. Time Corp., Edward T. Carmody, vice chairman and
director 3720
Tobacco Associates, Inc., John D. Palmer, president 1425
Torrence, Dr. Lois, American Association of University Women 869
Tower, Hon. John G., a U.S. Senator from the State of Texas 4264
Trade Relations Council of the United States, Inc.:
Ashley, James M., chairman of the board 1109
Stewart, Eugene L., counsel 1109
Tranoco, Inc., Charles F. Travis, president 4455
Travis, Charles F., president, Tranoco, Inc 4455
Trigg, Eric A., president, Alcan Aluminum Corp 3370
Turchan, Thomas P., president, Synthetic Organic Chemical Manufacturers
Association 4483, 4504
Uecker, William F., Window Shade Manufacturers Association 3857
Umbrella Frame Association of America, Leonard E. Finkel, president_~_ 3140
Union Carbide Corp., Herman K. Intemanu, vice president 4322
Universal Foods Corp., Cal-Compack Foods, Gentry Corp., and Santa
Maria Chili, Inc., W. Ed Crane, in behalf of 5001
Universal Foods Corp., Stella cheese division, and American producers of
Italian-Type Cheeses Association, Stephen F. Owen, Jr., counsel 4866
United Cement, Lime & Gypsum Workers, Victor Thomas, general vice
president 3756, 3786
United Glass & Ceramic Workers of North America, Ralph Reiser,
international president 3756, 3767
United Shoeworkers of America, AFL-CIO, George 0. Fecteau, general
president, and John E. Mara, president, Boots & Shoemakers Umon - 4102
United States-Japan Trade Council, Nelson A. Stitt, director 2126
United States Potters Association, David A. Golden, customs and tariff
counsel 3803
United Steelworkers of America, I. W. Able, president 1845, 1895
United Stone & Allied Products Workers of America, Hollan Cornett,
executive board member 3756, 3792
U.S. Council of the International Chamber of Commerce, Hoyt P. Steele,
chairman commercial policy committee 1002
U.S. Dyestuff Producers, ad hoc committee of, James J. Marshall, in
behalf of, and president, American Aniline Products, Inc~ 4724
PAGENO="0019"
XIX
Page
U.S. Feed Grains Council, Clarence Palmby, executive vice president___ 795
U.S. National Fruit Export Council, A. E. Thorpe, vice president and
secretary-treasurer 853
U.S. Producers of Flat Glass, Eugene L. Stewart, counsel 1504
U.S. Time Corp., Timex, Edward T. Carmody, vice chairman and director. 3720
Walker, Hon. E. S. Johnny, a Representative in Congress from the State of
New Mexico 1337
WTard, Robert E., Northwest Canners & Freezers Association, Oregon
Strawberry Council, and Calif ornia Strawberry Advisory Board 3743
Warner & Swasey Co., George W. Herkner, executive vice president 2845, 2971
Warrell, C. J., domestic bicycle tire and tube industry 3450
WTatkins, Hon. G. Robert, a Representative in Congress from the State of
Pennsylvania 1829
Watson, Arthur K., chairman, Emergency Committee for American Trade 1343
WTatson, Don, president, Panhandle Producers & Royalty Owners Asso-
ciation 4212, 4248
Wedell, Gustav, chairman, business practices committee, Danish-American
Trade Council, Inc 1626
West Coast Metal Importers Association, John Quimby, past director_ - - 2228
Westwood, Richard, president, EMBA Mink Breeders Association___ 4012
Whalley, Hon. J. Irving, a Representative in Congress from the State of
Pennsylvania 4827
White, Hon. Richard C., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Texas 2749, 4211
Whitener, Hon. Basil L., a Representative in Congress from the State of
North Carolina 1499
Willis, Hon. Edwin E., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Louisiana 4206
Willson, H. B., Co., Inc., Robert B. Willson, president 3462
Wilson, T. A., president, Boeing Aircraft 1343, 1347
Wilton & Velvet Carpet and Rug Importers, Robert E. Herzstein, counsel_ 2599
Window Shade Manufacturers Association, William F. Uecker 3857
W olfson, J. Theodore, president, Business Builders International, Inc_ 857
Wyatt, Hon. Wendell, a Representative in Congress from the State of
Oregon 1089
Wyman, Hon. Louis C., a Representative in Congress from the State of
New Hampshire 2353
Zukowsky, Norman, international presicient, International Leather Goods,
Plastics & Novelty Workers Union, AFL-CIO 4130
Zablocki, Hon. Clement J., a Representative in Congress from the State
of Wisconsin 1335
MATERIAL SUBMITTED FOR THE RECORD
GOVERNMENT OFFICIALS
Clubb, Bruce E., Commissioner, Tariff Commission, statement before the
Senate Finance Committee hearings on the International Antidumping
Code, June 27, 1968 1942
Freeman, Hon. Orville L., Secretary of Agriculture, Department of Agricul-
ture inspection /of meat exports from foreign countries to the United
States 696
Furness, ~\Iiss Betty, Special Assistant to the President for Consumer
Affairs, letter dated June 10, 1968, to Chairman Mills 64
Roth, Ambassador William M., Special Representative for Trade Negotia-
tions:
Absolute increase in imports of principal commodities 1960-67_ - - - - - 107
Agricultural concessions received by United States in Kennedy round. 710
Comparison of watch prices 699
Dye exports financed by AID 574
Establishment of STR and TIC 560
European tax systems (including exhibits A through E) 53
Experience to date with the 1968 investments under the mandatory
investments restraint program and relationship of this program to
exports 386
International Grains Arrangement, 1967 394
PAGENO="0020"
xx
Roth, Ambassador William M.-Continued
Justification for adjustment assistance program related to increased Page
imports
Nonrubberfootwear 701
Outline of trade policy study and supporting computer program 442
Preliminary inventories of nontariff barriers 122
Preliminary inventory of nontariff barriers affecting U.S. trade in
agricultural products 123
Preliminary inventory of nontariff barriers affecting U.S. trade
in industrial products 220
Inventory of alleged U.S. nontariff barriers 308
Nontariff barriers, by William B. Kelly, Jr 313
Production of ASP chemicals by one, two, or three firms 599
Progress in the elimination of foreign nontariff barriers 609
Recent changes in the use of nontariff barriers by other countries__ 721
Retaliatory action by United States 645
Selected industries with tariff reduction greater than the overall aver-
age reduction of 35 percent 580
Selectivity of the German added value tax 115
STR consideration of the representations of interested groups 566
Table 1-Chemicals and allied products 521
Table 2-Benezenoid chemicals 522
Table 3-Intermediates 523
Table 4-Dyes and azoics 524
Table 5-Pigments 525
Table 6-Medicinals 526
Table 7-Other benzenoid products 527
Table 8-Comparison of U.S. and EEC tariff rates for large-volume
benzenoid intermediates 528
Table 9-U.S. chemical exports, imports, and trade balance by prin-
cipal destination and source, 1961-67 529
Table 10-Benzenoid chemical rates of duty, ad valorem equivalents,
and 1964 imports 531
Table 11-Chemicals and allied products; new capital expenditures
by selected industries and industry groups, 1958-67_ 547
Table 12-Annual plant and equipment expenditures abroad by U.S.
manufacturing companies: all manufacturing and chemicals and
allied products
Table 13-Estimates of plant and equipment expenditures by foreign
affiliates of U.S. companies, by area and industry, 1965-68 547
Table 14-Chemicals and allied products: sales by American-owned
enterprises abroad and exports from the United States 548
Table 15-Research and development expenditures, by industry,
1958-66 548
Table 16-Selected employment data for chemicals and allied prod-
ucts, industry, intermediate coal tar products industry, and all manu-
facturing industries, 1958-68 549
Table 17-Selected economic indicators for the intermediate coal-tar
products industry, 1958-66 550
Table 18-Index of industrial production (1957-59 equals 100) 550
Table 19-Selected economic data: comparisons of chemicals and
allied products industry with all manufacturing industries, 1958-67 551
U.S. exports, excluding military grant aid, in current and constant
dollars, 1960-67 587
U.S. exports financed under the Public Law 480 and AID programs,
1960-67 575
U.S. imports and exports by major industries 100
Rush, Hon. Dean, Secretary of State:
Analysis of U.S. exports to Europe, 1957-1967 725
Allied efforts in Europe 674
Letter dated June 13, 1968, from Fl. G. Torbert, Jr., Acting Assistant
Secretary for Congressional Relations, to Chairman Mills re plac-
ing before the Federal Maritime Commission the views of the
United Kingdom Government 689
PAGENO="0021"
XXI
Smith, Hon. Cyrus R., Secretary, Department of Commerce: Page
Annual value of ITS. exports, imports, and merchandise balance 83
Commerce export promotion activities-relation to private efforts and
measurement of results 380
Major commodity increases in U.S. domestic exports from 1960 to
1967 98
Major commodity increases in U.S. imports from 1960 to 1967_ 97
Selected data on foreign transactions of the United States in the first
quarter of 1968 available as of the middle of May 1968 88
Trends in U.S. foreign trade, 1960-67 and January-April 1968 95
U.S. balance of payments in the first quarter 1968 84
U.S. trade by end-use categories, 1960-67 93
Wirtz, Hon. W. Willard, Secretary, Department of Labor:
Automotive Products Trade Act of 1965 (APTA) 554
International Labour Organisation (ILO) and working conditions~ 377
PUBLIC
A. & A. Trading Co., et al., H. William Tanaka, counsel, in behalf of
certain importers of electronic products, statement 3654
Adams, Charles F., chairman of the board, Raytheon Co., telegram dated
July 12, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3634
Addonizio, Mayor Hugh J., Newark, N.J., statement 1473
Ad Hoc Committee of Galvanized Electrical Transmission Tower Fabri-
cators:
Letter dated May 31, 1967, from David T. Searls, counsel, Charles B.
Gannaway, Jr., chairman, re imposition of countervailing duties on
imports of Italian galvanized electrical transmission towers 2220
Letter dated July 11, 1968, from David T. Searls, counsel, to Chairman
Mills, re strengthening of countervailing duty statute 2226
Judicial interpretation as to what is a bounty under countervailing
duty law 2216
Adler, Kurt S., Inc., Kurt S. Adler, president, letter dated May 29, 1968,
to Chairman Mills 3170
AFL-CIO, Nathaniel Goldfinger, director, department of research, addi-
tional views on ad~ustment assistance provisions of the Trade Expansion
Act of 1968 1107
Aircraft Locknut Manufacturers Association, et al., George P. Byrne, Jr.,
secretary and legal counsel, statement 3027
Air Transport Association of America, statement 4414
Akin, Paul B., president, Laclede Steel Co., statement 2255
Alabama Garment Manufacturers Association, James Utsey, president,
letter dated June 18, 1968, to Chairman Mills, with resolution attached
and with covering letter from Hon. Bill Nichols, a Representative in
Congress from the State of Alabama 2626
Alabama, State of, Hon. Albert P. Brewer, Governor, telegram dated July
8, 1968, to Chairman Mills 4362
Alaska Fishermen's Union, George Johansen, secretary-treasurer, state-
ment 3444
Allen, John R., vice president, eastern region, McDonnell Douglas Corp.,
letter dated July 16, 1968, to Chairman Mills 2798
Allerhand, Irving W., vice president, Consolidated International Trading
Corp., statement 4186
Allied Chemical Corp., Chester M. Brown, chairman of the board, state-
ment 4785
All-State Welding Alloys Co., Inc., Thomas D. Nast, president, letter
dated July 3, 1968, to Chairman I\'iills 3374
Amalgamated Clothing Workers of America, AFL-CIO, Milton Fried,
director of research, and International Ladies' Garment Workers' Union,
AFL-CIO, Lazare Teper, director of research, letter dated June 14,
1968, to Chairman Mills 2641
Amalgamated Meat Cutters & Butcher Workmen of North America,
AFL-CIO, Abe Feinglass, international vice president, director, fur and
leather department, statement 4182
American Bankers Association, Charls E. Walker, executive vice president,
letter dated June 17, 1968, to Chairman Mills 1809
PAGENO="0022"
~II
American Hand-Made Glassware Industry, 3. Raymond Price, executive Page
secretary of Glass Crafts of America, statement in behalf of 3819
American Hardboard Association, J. Mason Meyer, executive secretary,
statement 4468
American Importers Association:
O'Brien, Gerald, executive vice president, statement on U.S. foreign
trade policy before Trade Information Committee of Office of
President's Special Representative for Trade Negotiations, May
20, 1968 841
Floor covering group:
Rostov, Charles I., statement 2603
Additional statement 2618
Textile and apparel group:
Daniels, Michael P., counsel, report to the President on
investigation No. 332-55 under section 332 of the Tariff
Act of 1930 by U.S. Traiff Commission 2433
American Institute for Imported Steel, Inc.:
Continuous casting; taking over 10 percent of semifinished steel pro-
duction, article from 33/The Magazine of Metal Producing 2103
Deliveries of rolled steel products in countries of the European coal
and steel community 2103
U.S. balance of trade-Steelmaking raw material, 1967 2102
American-International Charolais Association, J. Scott Henderson, execu-
tive secretary, letter dated June 5, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3332
American Iron & Steel Institute, Thomas F. Patton:
Discussions of steel imports with OEP-response to questions by
Congressman Curtis 1917
Steel and the National Security, April 1968 1857
Steel import controls of other countries-response to question by
Congressman Schneebeli 1910
"Uniqueness" of steel-response to question by Congressman Ullman 1908
American Koyo Corp., J. B. Gray, corporate services manager, letter
dated July 9, 1968, to Chairman Mills 2268
American Loudspeaker Manufacturers Association, Eugene L. Stewart,
counsel, letter dated July 3, 1968, to Hon. Jackson E. Betts, a Repre-
sentative in Congress from the State of Ohio, re Far East comparative
wages 3630
American Metal Importers Association, Inc., Aubrey L. Moss, president,
letter dated July 1, 1968, to Committee on Ways and Means 3377
American Mining Congress, J. Allen Overton, Jr., executive vice president,
letter dated May 29, 1968, to Chairman Mills, with attachments 1946
Declaration of Policy-196768 1947
Summary of issues discussed in AMC staff study 1948
Staff study and comparative analysis by the AMC of the International
Antidumping Code 1949
American Mushroom Institute, Ronald B. Hunte, executive director, letter
dated June 26, 1968, to Chairman Mills 5088
American National Cattlemen's Association, C. W. McMillan, executive
vice president, letter dated July 9, 1968, to Chairman Mills, re explana-
tion of the proposed amendments to the 1\'Ieat Import Act of 1964 3211
American Newspaper Publishers Association, Stanford Smith, general
manager, statement 446~
American Paper Institute, Inc., Edwin A. Locke, Jr., president, statement-- 4460
American Pipe Fittings Association, T. William C. Smith, president, letter
datedJune20, 1968, to Chairman Mills 2259
American Scotch Highland Breeders' Association, ~\`Iargaret Manke,
secretary, letter dated June 29, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3331
American Sprocket Chain Manufacturers Association, J. E. Cooper, presi-
dent, R. E. Lambert, chairman, Committee on Government Relations,
and L. E. Stybr, executive director, statement 3039
American Textile Manufacturers Institute, Frederick B. Dent, president,
letter dated July 9, 1968, to Hon. Thomas B. Curtis, a Representative in
Congress from the State of Missouri, re statement of position on H.R.
17551 2388
Amperex Electronic Corp., Frank L. Randall, Jr., president, statement 3505
Anderson, M. Allen, president, Premier Santa Gertrudis Association,
resolution, dated May 26, 1968, with covering letter from Hon. Roman
L. Hruska, a U.S. Senator from the State of Nebraska 3333
PAGENO="0023"
XXIII
Angevine, Erma, executive director, Consumer Federation of America, Page
letter dated July 12, 1968, to Chairman Mills 1739
Arizona Cattle Feeders' Association, D. C. Entz, chairman, board of
directors, statement 3306
Arizona Cattle Growers' Association, statement 3306
Armco Steel Corp., C. William Verity, Jr., president, statement 2253
Ashland Oil & Refining Co.:
Atkins, Orin E., president, letter dated July 5, 1968, to Chairman
Mills 4397
Whealy, Roland A., vice president, statement 4393
Atkins, Orin E., president, Ashland Oil & Refining Co., letter dated July 5,
1968, to Chairman Mills 4397
Australian Meat Board, W. W. Stenning, North American representative,
statement, with forwarding letter from the State Department 3301
Australian Mining Industry Council, statement, with forwarding letter from
Department of State 2322
Australian Wool Tops Exporters, statement, with forwarding letter from
Department of State 2734
Automobile Manufacturers Association, statement 1759
Baldanzi, George, international president, United Textile Workers of
America, AFL-CIO, statement 2628
Barsy, Solbert J., Chicago, Ill., letter dated July 8, 1968, to Chairman Mills_ 2274
Bartel, Andrew, president, Great Lakes Mink Association, statement. - - - 4017
Bass, V. J., vice president, J. E. Barnard & Co., Inc., letter dated June 27,
1968, to Chairman Mills 1806
Battenfeld Grease & Oil Corp. of New York, G. W. Miller, chairman of the
board, statement, with forwarding letter from Hon. Henry P. Smith III,
a Representative in Congress from the State of New York 4422
Ba.ttin, Hon. James F., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Montana:
Economic "abyss" seen by Martin; Reserve chief asks rise in taxes and
spending cut, article from June 12, 1968, New York Times 989
U.S. trade surplus goal unattainable, official says, article from June 6,
1968, Wall Street Journal 988
Bauer, Richard J., president, Independent Zinc Alloyers Association,
statement 2304
Baughman, Harry W., Jr., national president, Window Glass Cutters
League of America, statement 3824
Beeghly, Charles M., Jones & Laughlin Steel Corp., telegram dated June 20,
1968, to Chairman Mills 1926
Bell, David H., president, Ohio Oil & Gas Association, letter dated May 27,
1968, to Committee on Ways and Means 4392
Belridge Oil Co., R. W. Trueblood, president, statement 4269
Bendix Corp., Michael Blumenthal, president, Bendix International,
telegram dated July 12, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3632
Bendix International, W. Michael Blumenthal, president, industry repre-
sentations during Kennedy round 1251
Bennett, William E., president, Kentuckiana World Commerce Council,
Inc., letter dated June 25, 1968, to Chairman Mills, with resolution
attached 1775
Bernard, J. E., & Co., Inc., V. J. Bass, vice president, letter dated June 27,
1968, to Chairman Mills 1806
Beskind, Claire, president, League of Women Voters of the Princeton Com-
munity (N.J.), letter dated June 20, 1968, to Chairman Mills 997
Bethlehem Steel Corp., Edmund F. Martin, chairman, letter dated June 17,
1968, to Chairman Mills 1926
Black & Decker Manufacturing Co., Alonzo G. Decker, Jr., chairman of the
board and president, letter dated June 20, 1968, to Chairman Mills 2268
Blake, Grant, president, Idaho Beekeepers Association, Inc., statement_ - - 3469
Blincoe, Richard D., president, Idaho Cattle Feeders Association, Inc.,
statement 3316
Blood, Mrs. Lawrence, president, League of Women Voters of Reading
(Mass.), letter dated June 25, 1968, to Chairman Mills 994
Blumenthal, Harry & Sons, Inc., Harry Blumenthal, president, letter dated
July 8, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3378
Blumenthal, W. Michael, president, Bendix International:
Industry representations during Kennedy round 1251
Telegram dated July 12, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3632
PAGENO="0024"
XXIV
Page
B'nai B'rith, Dr. William A. Wexier, president, statement 1028
Bommarito, Peter, president, United Rubber, Cork, Linoleum, & Plastic
Workers of America, AFL-CIO, statement 4180
Bourbon Institute, Vice Adm. William J. Marshall, USN (retired),
president 2799
Branch, C. B., executive vice president, Dow Chemical Co., staternent~~ 4793
Brewer, Hon. Albert P., Governor of the State of Alabama, telegram dated
July 8, 1968, to Chairman Mills 4362
Bright Wire Goods Manufacturers Service Bureau, et al., George P. Byrne,
Jr., secretary and legal counsel, statement 3027
Brook, John G., chairman, Lear Siegler, Inc., telegram dated July 12, 1968,
to Chairman Mills 3633
Brown, Chester M., chairman of the board, Allied Chemical Corp., state-
ment 4785
Brown, Hon. Clarence J., Jr., a Representative in Congress from the State
of Ohio, statement 3300, 4887
Brown, L. G., president, Precision Drawn Steel Co., letter dated June 4,
1968, to Chairman Mills, with attachement 2273
Buckner, Emil H., secretary-treasurer, United States Extrusions Corp.,
letter dated June 27, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3377
Bucy, J. Fred, group vice president, Texas Instruments Inc., telegram
dated July 11, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3634
Bullen, George S., legislative director, National Federation of Independent
Business, statement 1730
Burke, Hon. James A., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Massachusetts:
Importation of footwear from foreign countries, material relatiug to 727
Strawberries, statistical tables and comments 3749
Burns, Hon. John A., Governor of the State of Hawaii, statement 2353
Business Builders International, Inc., J. Theodore Wolfson, president,
article from Wall Street Journal entitled "Steel Firms' Profits Are Expected
To Spurt as Outlays Begin To Pay Off, Analysts Say" 859
Byrne, Geor~e P., Jr., secretary and legal counsel:
Service fools Institute, statement 3046
U.S. Cap Screw Service Bureau, U.S. Wood Screw Bureau, U.S.
Machine Screw Service Bureau, Tapping Screw Service Bureau,
Socket Screw Products Bureau, Tubular and Split Rivet Council,
Aircraft Locknut Manufacturers Association, and Bright Wire Goods
Manufacturers Service Bureau, statement 3027
Caggiano, G. Robert, director, Bureau of International Trade, Department
of Commerce and Development, Commonwealth of Massachusetts,
statement 1065
California-Arizona Citrus Industry, statement 5041
California Cattlemen's Association, Will Gill, Jr., president, statement- - 3308
California Dried Fig Advisory Board, Ron Klamm, manager, and managing
director, California Fig Institute, statement 3308
California Fig Institute, Ron Klamm, managing director, and manager,
California Dried Fig Advisory Board, statement -- 3308
Campbell, Dr. Persia, National Consumers League, statement 870
Campbell, R. A., chairman, liaison committee, Cooperating Oil and Gas
Association, statement 4238
Candle Manufacturers Association, H. R. Parker, secretary, letter dated
June 25, 1968, to Chairman Mills--~ 3170
Canned Meat Importers Association, Ronald Wright, president, statement- 3338
Carlip, Mrs. Alfred B., chairman, foreign policy committee League of
Women Voters of Broome County (N.Y.), letter dated June 28, 1968, to
Chairman Mills 998
Carnation Co. Jule N. Kvamme, corporate department, statement 4792
Carson, Mrs. Robert M., president, League of Women Voters of Winter
Park-Orlando, Fla., letter dated June 26, 1968, to Chairman Mills 992
Cast Iron Soil Pipe Institute, Frederick D. Hunt, foreign trade consultant,
letter dated July 22, 1968, to Representative Curtis, re authority in
negotiating International Antidumping Code 2241
PAGENO="0025"
XXV
Cement Industry Antidumping Committee, John C. Mundt, vice chair-
man:
Memorandum on the legal authority of the executive branch to Page
negotiate the International Antidumping Code 1388
Supplementary statement 1384
Certified Livestock Markets Association, C. T. "Tad" Sanders, general
manager, letter dated July 3, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3332
Chamber of Commerce of the New Orleans area, Murray C. Fincher,
president, letter to Chairman Mills, with statement attached 1785
Chernoff, Mrs. Max, president, League of Women Voters of Great Neck,
N.Y., letter dated June 21, 1968, to Chairman Mills 998
Citizens State Bank & Trust Co., Wayne R. Starr, president, letter dated
June20, 1968, to Chairman Mills 1824
Citronbaum, Jack, executive vice president, Luggage & Leather Goods
Manufacturers of America, Inc., statement 4131
Clay, Henry J., Netherlands Chamber of Commerce in the United States,
Inc., letter dated June 25, to Hon. John W. Byrnes, re quantitative
restrictions 1594
Clothing Manufacturers' Federation of Great Britain, and the Shirt,
Collar & Tie Manufacturers' Federation, statement, with forwarding
letter from the Department of State 2736
Committee of Producers of Ferroalloys and Related Products, Ronald L.
Cunningham, letter dated July 12, 1968, from Lloyd Symington, counsel,
to Chairman Mills, re questions addressed by Congressman Curtis~_ 2191
Conneaut, Ohio, city of, Arvo E. Sundberg, statement 2248
Conner, Commissioner Doyle, Florida Department of Agriculture, state-
ment 5069
Conrad, A. B., secretary-manager, West Mexico Vegetable Distributors
Association, statement, with forwarding letter from Hon. Morris K.
Udall, a Representative in Congress from the State of Arizona 5088
Consolidated International Trading Corp., Irving W. Allerhand, vice
president, statement 4186
Consumer Federation of America, Erma Angevine, executive director, let-
ter dated July 12, 1968, to Chairman Mills 1739
Continental Oil Co., statement 4398
Continental Baking Co., George R. Vail, vice president and director, and
president, Morton Frozen Foods Division, statement 3342
Cooper, J. F., president, R. E. Lambert, chairman, Committee on Govern-
ment relations, and L. E. Stybr, executive director, American Sprocket
Chain i\'Ianufacturers Association, statement 3039
Cooperating Oil & Gas Association, R. A. Campbell, chairman liaison
committee, statement 4238
Coors Porcelain Co., Clinton M. Hester, attorney, statement 3827
Copper & Brass Fabricators Council, Inc. ,Y. F. Veltfort, managing director,
letter dated June 19, 1968, to Chairman Mills, with statement attached - - 2325
Cordage Institute, Merle S. Robie, chairman, executive committee, state-
ment 2372
Corn Refiners Association, Inc., Robert C. Liebenow, president, statement 5093
Courtright, C. A., president, Washington Cattle Feeders Association,
letter dated June 5, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3329
Coyne, Robert W., president, Distilled Spirits Institute, Inc., statement - 2811
Crawford, G. R., executive vice president, Smithfield Packing Co., Inc.,
letter dated June 10, 1968, to John M. Martin, Jr., chief counsel, Com-
mittee on Ways and Means 3343
Crompton & Knowles, Corp., James W. L. Monkman, vice president,
statement 4798
Culbertson, W. 0., Jr., president, New Mexico Cattle Growers' Association,
statement - 3322
Cunningham, Ronald L., Committee of Producers of Ferro-alloys & Related
Products, letter dated July 12, 1968, from Lloyd Symington, counsel,
to Chairman Mills, re questions addressed by Congressman Curtis 2191
Curl, William W., president, Texas Citrus Mutual, statement 5083
Curtis, Thomas B., a Representative in Congress from the State of Mis-
souri:
Memorandum to the American Iron & Steel Institute and their
reply-Indirect imports and exports 1921
Memorandum to the Emergency Committee for American Trade and
their reply-Problems of measuring steel export-import trade 1364
PAGENO="0026"
XXVI
Daniel, Mrs. T. Emory, president, League of Women Voters of De Kalb Page
County (Ga.), letter dated July 8, 1968, to Chairman Mills 992
Daniels, Michael P., counsel:
American Importers Association, textile and apparel group, report to
the President on investigation No. 332-55 under section 332 of the
Tariff Act of 1930 by U.S. Tariff Commission 2433
Japan Chemical Fibers Association, statement with forwarding letter
from Department of State 2728
Japanese Chamber of Commerce, woolens division, statement 2743
Swiss Union of Commerce and Industry, statement, with covering
letter from State Department 4771
Danish American Trade Council, Inc., Finish American Chamber of Com-
merce, Inc., Norwegian-American Chamber of Commerce, Inc., and
Swedish Chamber of Commerce of the United States, Inc., statemeat - - 1775
Davis, Warren B. director, planning and economics, Gulf Oil Corp., state-
ment 4401
Davis Wire Corp., James L. Walker, president, letter dated July 9, 1968,
to Chairman Mills, with attachments 2269
Decker, Alonzo G., Jr., chairman of the board and president, Black &
Decker Manufacturing Co., letter dated June 20, 1968, to Chairman
Mills 2268
Del Signore, M., president, et al., Local Union No. 14256, District 50,
United Mine Workers of America, letter dated July 5, 1968, to John M.
Martin, Jr., chief counsel, Committee on Ways and Means 4808
Demeter, Mrs. James, Kolb-Lena Cheese Co., letter dated May 23, 1968,
to Chairman Mills 4901
Dent, Frederick B., president, American Textile Manufacturers Institute,
letter dated July 9, 1968, to Hon. Thomas B. Curtis, a Representative
in Congress from the State of Missouri, re statement of position on
H.R. 17551 2388
Dent, Hon. John, a Representative in Congress from the State of Pennsyl-
vania, nontariff trade barrier inventory by country 3878
Derby, Roland E., Jr., president, Nyanza, Inc., letter dated June 17, 1968,
to Chairman Mills 4802
Dc Santis, Arthur A., executive secretary, Italy-American Chamber of
Commerce, letter dated June 20, 1968, to Chairman Mills, re oil exports
to Italy 1625
Detmers, Mrs. Bruce, president, League of Women Voters of Hamden
(Conn.), letter dated June 24, 1968, to Chairman Mills 991
Deuschle, B. C., president, Shears, Scissors, and Manicure Implement
Manufacturers Association, statement 3063
Distilled Spirits Institute, Inc., Robert W. Coyne, president, statement - 2811
Diversified Wire & Steel Corp., David P. Piering, president, telegram,
dated June 14, 1968, to Chairman Mills 2202
Docking, Hon. Robert B., Governor, State of Kansas, statement 4363
Doherty, Mrs. George, president, League of Women Voters of Anderson
(md.), letter dated July 12, 1968, to Chairman Mills 993
Dole, Hon. Bob, a Representative in Congress from the State of Kansas,
statement 4365, 4888
Domestic Litharge Industry, statement 2301
Dorn, Hon. William Jennings Bryan, a Representative in Congress from
the State of South Carolina:
Additional statement 2412
Joint statement of over 100 Members of the House presented by Mr.
Dorn, secretary, Informal House Textile Committee Group 2414
Dow Chemical Co., C. B. Branch, executive vice president, statement___ 4793
Dray, Margaret B., economist, Chicago, Ill., letter dated May 19, 1968,
to Ways and Means Committee 2275
Dryer, Edwin Jason, counsel, Independent Refiners Association of America,
statement
Duncan, Hon. John J., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Tennessee, letter dated June 13, 1968, to Chairman Mills 4890
Dunn, Stephen F., president, National Coal Association, statement 4423
Eberlein, John G., chairman, drawback committee, National Customs
Brokers & Forwarders Association of America, Inc., pamphlet entitled
"What Is Customs Drawback?" 1024
PAGENO="0027"
XXVII
Edelman, L., vice president, Gafco, Inc., letter dated July 15, 1968, to Page
Chairman Mills 4062
Edgerton, William B., Friends Committee on National Legislation,
statement 1807
Electronic Industries Association:
Jaumot, F. E., Jr., chairman, semi-conductor division, letter dated
July 10, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3507
McCauley, Alfred R., special counsel to consumer products division,
letter dated June 27, 1968, to John M. Martin, Esq., chief counsel,
Committee on Ways and Means, forwarding memorandum of the
Magnavox Co. on color television pricture tubes 3496
Moore, William H., staff vice president, Government products
division, letter dated July 12, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3507
Stewart, Eugene L., counsel, letter dated July 3, 1968, to Hon.
Jackson E. Betts, a Representative in Congress from the State of
Ohio, re Far East comparative wages 3630
Ellis, Don A., treasurer, Tektronix, Inc., statement 3704
EBMA Mink Breeders Association:
Westwood, Richard E., president, statement 4014
Wittig, 1-larley, past president, statement 4013
Emergency Committee for American Trade:
A critique of the Trade Relations Council's analysis of certain 1958/
60-1964 declines in employment 1352
Memorandum from Representative Thomas B. Curtis of Missouri,
and reply thereto-Problems of measuring steel export-import
trade 1364
Entz, D. C., chairman, board of directors, Arizona Cattle Feeders' Asso-
ciation, statement 3306
Erie Technical Products, Inc., George P. Fryling, president, telegram dated
July 11, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3633
Evans, Hon. Daniel J., Governor of the State of Washington, letter dated
June 7, 1968, to Chairman Mills, with position paper attached 1719
Evaporated Milk Association, Fred J. Greiner, executive vice president,
statement 4897
Expanded Shale, Clay & Slate Institute, the Lightweight Aggregate Pro-
ducers Association, and the National Slag Association, statement - - - - - 3813
Farrell Lines, Inc., statement 1791
Feighan, Hon. Michael A., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Ohio, statement 2087
Feinglass, Abe, international vice president, director, Fur and Leather
Department, Amalgamated Meat Cutters & Butcher Workmen of
North America, AFL-CIO, statement 4182
Fezell, George H., president, Magnavox Consumer Electronics Co., tele-
gram dated July 10, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3633
Fin cher, Murray C., president, Chamber of Commerce of the New Orleans
Area, letter to Chairman Mills, with statement attached 1785
Fine & Specialty Wire Manufacturers' Association, J. A. Mogle, chairman,
foreign trade committee, statement 2275
Finish American Chamber of Commerce, Inc., Danish American Trade
Council, Inc., Norwegian-American Chamber of Commerce, Inc., and
Swedish Chamber of Commerce of the United States, Inc., statement~ 17~5
Finney, Wray, president, Oklahoma Cattlemen's Association, letter dated
May 28, 1968, to Chairman Mills 332~
First National City Bank, Walter B. Wriston, president, letter dated
July 12, 1968, to Chairman Mills, with attachment 1810
First Washington Net Factory, Inc., Carl Koring, president, letter dated
May 22, 1968, to John IXIartin, Jr., chief counsel, Committee on Ways
and Means 2727
Fifth Cleveland Steels, Inc., Peter H. Garfunkel, executive vice president,
letter dated May 23, 1968, to Chairman Mills 2272
Fishman, Morris, & Sons, Clinton M. Hester, attorney, statement 2747
Fitch, T. S., president, Washington Steel Corp., letter dated June 28,
1968, to Chairman Mills 1928
Fletcher, Aubrey, executive vice president, C. Tennant, Sons & Co., letter
dated June 21, 1968, to Chairman Mills, re statistics on lead and zinc~ 2318
Florida Department of Agriculture, Commissioner Doyle Conner, state-
ment 5069
PAGENO="0028"
XXVIII
Florida Fruit and Vegetable Association, J. S. Peters, manager, member-
ship and industry relations, letter dated July 29, 1968, to Congressman Page
Thomas B. Curtis, re domestic market for fruits and vegetables 4978
Ford, Hon. Gerald R., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Michigan, letter dated May 27, 1968, to Chairman Mills, with petition
re mink industry attached 4061
Foerch, Mrs. Margaret, president, League of Women Voters of Michigan,
letter dated June 28, 1968, to Chairman Mills 996
Forsythe, Russell, president, and James H. Warner, secretary, Ohio Cattle
Feeders Association, letter dated June 17, 1968, to Chairman Mills, with
attachment 3326
Forward America, Inc., Ed Wimmer, president, radio talk 1733
Foskett, John D., president, Homeshield Industries, letter dated July 3,
1968, to Chairman Mills 3369
Franko, Joseph J., treasurer, B. L. Lemke & Co., Inc., statement 4626
French Chamber of Commerce in the United States, Inc., Raymond J.
Picard, president, statement 1773
Fried, Milton, director of research, Amalgamated Clothing Workers of
America, AFL-CIO, and Lazare Teper, director of research, Interna-
tional Ladies' Garment Workers' Union, AFL-CIO, letter dated June
14, 1968, to Chairman Mills 2641
Friedson, N., Meat-O-Mat, Inc., letter dated June 12, 1968, to John M.
Martin, Jr., chief counsel, Ways and Means, Committee 3344
Friends Committee on National Legislation, William B. Edgerton, state-
ment 1807
Frost, M. F., vice president, Texas Farm Bureau, statement 5081
Fryling, George P., president, Erie Technical Products, Inc., telegram dated
July 11, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3633
Fuel Oil Council of Maryland, Jay D. Kline, president, and Independent
Oil Heat Dealers Association of Maryland, John M. Myers, president,
letter dated July 5, 1968, to Chairman Mills 4420
Gafco, Inc., L. Edelman, vice president, letter dated July 15, 1968, to
Chairman Mills 4062
Galvanized Electrical Transmission Tower Fabricators. (See Ad Hoc Com-
mittee of Galvanized, etc.)
Galvin, Robert W., Motorola, Inc., telegram dated July 12, 1968, to
Chairman Mills 3634
Gannaway, Charles B. (See Ad Hoc Committee of Galvanized Transmis-
sion Tower Fabricators.)
Garfunkel, Peter H., executive vice president, Firth Cleveland Steels,
Inc., letter dated May 23, 1968, to Chairman Mills 2272
Gehl's Guernsey Farms, Inc., John P. Gehl, statement 4894
General Dynamics Corp., John J. Graham, group vice president, telegram
dated July 11, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3633
General Electric Co., statement 3657
Gerst, Leon W., president, Tenneco colors division, Tenneco Chemicals,
Inc., statement 4780
Gill, Will, Jr., president, California Cattlemen's Association, statement.. - - 3308
Glass Crafts of America, J. Raymond Price, executive secretary, on behalf
of the American Hand-Made Glassware Industry, statement 3819
Glass Workers' Protective Leagues of West Virginia, Pennsylvania, Ohio,
and Indiana, Huberta M. Patterson, secretary, West Virginia League,
statement 3826
Glenndenning, Howard A., president, Local Union No. 13896, District
50, United Mine Workers of America, letter dated July 3, 1968, to John
Martin, Mr., chief counsel, Committee on Ways and Means 4809
Goldfinger, Nathaniel, director, department of research, AFL-CIO, addi-
tional views on adjustment assistance provisions of the Trade Expansion
Act of 1968 1107
Golson, Charles E. (See International Engineeiing & Construction In-
dustries Council.)
Gorton Corp., E. Robert Kinney, president, statement 3442
Graham, Harry L. (See National Grange.~
Graham, John J., group vice president, General Dynamics Corp., telegram
dated July 11, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3633
Granite City Steel Co., Nicholas P. Veeder, chairman of the board and
president, statement 2254
PAGENO="0029"
XXIX
Page
Gray, Charles M., manager, Insulation Board Institute, statement 4478
Gray, J. B., corporate services manager, American Koyo Corp., letter
dated July 9, 1968, to Chairman Mills 2268
Great Lakes Mink Association, Andrew Bartel, president, statement 4017
Greater Fort Lauderdale (Fla.) Chamber of Commerce, Marshall M.
Smith, letter dated July 3, 1968, to Committee on Ways and Means 1785
Green, Ronald W., commissioner, Department of Sea and Shore Fisheries,
State of Maine, statement 3445
Greenaway, E., secretary, National Association of Glove i\'Ianufacturers,
letter dated 1\'Iay 28, 1968, to Chairman Mills, with forwarding letter
from the Department of State 2742
Greiner, Fred J., executive vice president, Evaporated Milk Association,
statement 4897
Grube, Mrs. Alfred, president, League of Women Voters of Sheboygan
(Wis.), letter dated June 27, 1968, to Chairman Mills 1001
Guam, Territory of, Hon. Antonio B. Won Pat, Representative in Wash-
ington, statement 3740
Gulf Oil Corp., Warren B. Davis, director, planning and economies,
statement 4401
Haber, Fred S., president, Ocean Freight Consultants, Inc., statement 1801
Hahn, Dorothy Parshley, chairman, foreign economic policy, League of
Women Voters of Palmouth (Mass.), letter dated July 1, 1968, to Chair-
man Mills 994
Hall, Wilfred H., executive vice president, National Oil Jobbers Council,
statement 4366
Hamilton Watch Co., Arthur B. Sinkler, chairman of the board, letter dated
July 12, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3741
Hampton, Robert N., director of marketing and international trade,
National Council of Farmer Cooperatives, letter dated July 12, 1968, to
Chairman Mills 1735
Hansen, Hon. George V., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Idaho 4060
Hansen, Mrs. Howard, president, League of Women Voters of Glen Ellyn
(Ill.), letter dated June 19, 1968, to Chairman Mills 992
Hardwood Plywood Manufacturers Association, statement 4475
Harnischfeger, Walter, Milwaukee, Wis, statement 5098
Harshaw Chemical Co., R. A. Lucht, president, letter dated May 31, 1968,
to Chairman Mills 4800
Hartke, Hon. Vance, a U.S. Senator from the State of Indiana, statement
re International Antidumping Act 1939
Harvey, Dr. E. W., administrator, Otter Trawl Commission of Oregon,
statement 3450
Hathaway, Hon. William D., a Representative in Congress from the State
of Maine, statement 4010
Haughton, D. J., chairman of the board, Lockheed Aircraft Corp., telegram
dated July 11, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3633
Hawaii Cattlemen's Council, Robert L. Hind, Jr., president, letters (with
attachments) dated June 1, and June 14, 1968, to Hon. Patsy T. Mink,
a Representative in Congress from the State of Hawaii, with covering
letter 3308
Hawaii, State of, Hon. John A. Burns, Governor, statement 2353
Hawley Fuel Corp., Mark R. Joseph, vice president, letter dated June 11,
1968. to Chairman Mills 4427
Hays, George L., Mission Creek Angus Ranch, statement, and Mrs. George
L. Hays, president, Idaho Cow Belles, letter dated May 22, 1968, to
Hon. James A. McClure, a Representative in Congress from the State
of Idaho, with covering letter 3335
Heinkel, Fred V., president, Midcontinent Farmers Association & Missouri
Farmers Association, Inc., statement 1310
Henderson, J. Sc~1t, executive secretary, American-International Charolais
Association, letter dated June 5, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3332
Hester, Clinton ]\I., attorney:
Coors Porcelain Co., statement 3827
Fishman, Morris & Sons, statement 2747
Hilton-Davis Chemical Co., R. L. Marienthal, manager of chemical sales,
letter dated June 21, 1968, to Committee on Ways and Means 4801
PAGENO="0030"
xxx
Hind, Robert L., Jr., president, Hawaii Cattlemen's Council, Inc., letters
(with attachments) dated June 1, and June 14, 1968, to Hon. Patsy T.
Mink, a Representative in Congress from the State of Hawaii, with Page
covering letter 3308
Homeshield Industries, John D. Foskett, president, letter dated July 3,
1968, to Chairman Mills 3369
Howard, John A., vice president and general manager, Magruder Color Co.,
Inc., letter dated June 24, 1968, to John M. Martin, Jr., chief counsel,
Committee on Ways and Means 4801
Hunt, Frederick D., foreign trade consultant, Cast Iron Soil Pipe Institute,
letter dated July 22, 1968, to Representative Curtis, re authority in ne-
gotiating International Anti-dumping Code 2241
Hunte, Ronald B., executive director, American Mushroom Institute,
letter dated June 26, 1968, to Chairman Mills 5088
Huston, Charles Lukens, Jr., president, Lukens Steel Co., letter dated
June 24, 1968, to Chairman Mills 2257
Idaho Beekeepers Association, Inc., Grant Blake, president, statement~ 3469
Idaho Cattle Feeders Association, Inc., Richard D. Blincoe, president,
statement 3316
Idaho Cow Belles, Mrs. George L. Hays, president, letter dated May 22,
1968, to Hon. James A. McClure, a Representative in Congress from the
State of Idaho, with covering letter 3335
Independent Oil Heat Dealers Association of Maryland, John M. Myers,
president, and Fuel Oil Council of Maryland, Jay D. Kline, president,
letter dated July 5, 1968, to Chairman Mills 4420
Independent Petroleum Association of America, Dan L. Jones, general
counsel, letter dated July 3, 1968, to Chairman Mills, re selected data
on oils' balance of payments 4276
Independent Refiners Association of America, Edwin Jason Dryer, counsel,
statement
Independent Zinc Alloyers Association, Richard J. Bauer, president,
statement 2304
Insulation Board Institute, Charles i\'I. Gray, manager, statement 4478
Inter-American Committee on the Alliance for Progress (ClAP), Carlos
Sanz de Santamaria, chairman, statement, with covering letter from
State Department to Chairman Mills 1713
International Chemical Workers Union, Walter L. Mitchell, president,
statement 4804
International Economic Policy Association, statement - 1727
International Engineering & Construction Industries Council, Charles E.
Golson:
Article from September-October 1967 issue Worldwide P. & I. Plan-
ning entitled "~Senor, qué es una `U.S. Firm' segdn la AID?" 822
Letter dated June 17, 1968, to Chairman Mills, re clarification of
two points in the council's oral statement 828
Position paper entitled "The competitive position of United States
engineering and construction firms in the international market" - 809
International House, E. M. Rowley, president, letter dated July 10, 1968,
to Chairman Mills, with resolution attached 1786
International Ladies' Garment Workers' Union, AFL-CIO, Lazare Tepcr,
director of research, and Amalgamated Clothing Woikers of America,
AFI~-CIO, Milton Fried, director of research, letter dated June 14, 1968,
to Chairman Mills 2641
International Trade Club of Chicago, statement 1787
International Union of Electrical, Radio & Machine Workers, AFL-CIO-
CLC, Paul Jennings, president, statement 1740
Iowa Beef Producers Association, Orville Kalsem, president, statement_ - 3318
Italy-American Chamber of Commerce:
Dc Santis, Arthur A. executive secretary, letter dated June 20, 1968,
to Chairman Mills, re oil exports to Italy 1625
Laraja, Edward, chairman, Dairy Products Importers Group,
statement 1621
Jackson, Mrs. Robert F., president, League of Women Voters of Greater
Toledo (Ohio), letter dated June 27, 1968, to Chairman Mills 999
Japan Chemical Fibres Association, Michael P. Daniels, counsel, statement
with forwarding letter from Department of State 2728
PAGENO="0031"
XXXI
Japanese Chamber of Commerce, Woolens Division, Michael P. Daniels, Page
counsel, statement 2743
Jardox Fur Co., Arthur Rapaport, letter dated July 10, 1968, to Chairman
Mills 4063
Jaumot, F. E., Jr., chairman, Semiconductor Division, Electronic Indus-
tries Association, letter dated July 10, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3507
Jennings, Paul, president, International Union of Electrical, Radio, &
Machine Workers, AFL-CJO--CLC, statement 1740
Johansen, George, secretary-treasurer, Alaska Fishermen's Union, state-
ment 3444
Johnson, Howard, sales manager, Linen Thread Co., statement 2620
Johnson, Lindsay F. (See Lead-Zinc Producers Committee.)
Johnson, Reuben L. (See National Farmers Union.)
Jones, Mrs. Dewitt C., III, president, League of Women Voters of Fal-
mouth (Mass.), letter dated July 1, 1968, to Chairman Mills 994
Jones & Laughlin Steel Corp., Charles M. Beeghly, telegram dated June 20,
1968, to Chairman Mills 1926
Jones, L. Dan, general counsel, Independent Petroleum Association of
America, letter dated July 3, 1968, to Chaiiman Nulls, re selected data
on oils' balance of payments 4276
Joseph, Mark R., vice president, Hawley Fuel Corp., letter dated June 11,
1968, to Chairman Mills 4427
Kalsem, Orville, president, Iowa Beef Producers Association, statement_ 3318
Kaminski, Jerome, president, International Union of District 50, United
Mine Workers of America, letter dated July 11, 1968, to John M. Martin,
Jr., chief counsel, Committee on Ways and Means 4809
Kansas, State of, Hon. Robert B. Docking, Governor, statement 4363
Katz, Lawrence R., Polan, Katz & Co., Inc., letter dated July 9, 1968, to
Chairman Mills 3157
Kennedy, Edward E., research director, International Union of District
50, United Mine Workers of America, statement 1752
Kentuckiana World Commerce Council, Inc., William E. Bennett, presi-
dent letter dated June 25, 1968, to Chairman Mills, with resolution
attached 1775
Kerr, Robert M., attorney, Specialty Crops Conference, statement 5049
Keystone Steel & Wire Company, Walton B. Sommer, president and
chairman of the board, letter dated June 10, 1968, to Chairman Mills,
with statement attached 1927
King, Hon. Cecil R., a Representative in Congress from the State of
California, letter dated February 13, 1968, to John M. Martin, Jr., chief
counsel, Committee on Ways and Means, re trade ties between the
United States and Canada with replies of the various Federal Depart-
ments 2785
Kinkead Industries Inc., E. R. Meyer, letter dated July 1, 1968, to Chair-
man Mills 3376
Kinney, E. Robert, president, Gorton Corp., statement 3442
Klamm, Ron, managing director, California Fig Institute, and manager,
California Dried Fig Advisory. Board, statement 3308
Kline, Jay D., president, Fuel Oil Council of Maryland, and Independent
Oil Heat Dealers Association of Maryland, John i\1. Myers, president,
letter dated July 5, 1968, to Chairman Mills 4420
Koring, Carl, president, First Washington Net Factory, Inc., letter dated
May 22 1968 to John Martin Jr. chief counsel Committee on Ways
and Means 2727
Kolb-Lena Cheese Co. Mrs. James Demeter, letter dated May 23, 1968,
to Chairman Mills 4901
Kummer, Mrs. Joseph, first vice president, League of Women Voters of -
Ann Arbor (Mich.), letter dated June 20, 1968, to Chairman Mills - - - 99~
Kurtin, Harold, president, National Association of Secondary Material
Industries, Inc., letter dated July 10, 1968, to Chairman Mills 2627
Kvamme, Jule N., corporate department, Carnation Co., statement 4792
Laclede Steel Co., Paul B. Akin, president, statement 2255
Lambert, R. E., chairman, committee on Government relations, J. E.
Cooper, president, and L. E. Stybr, executive director, American Sprock-
et Chain Manufacturers Association, statement 3039
Lang, Ernest U., chief engineer, National-Standard Co., statement 1824
PAGENO="0032"
XXXII
Laraja, Edward, chairman, Dairy Products Importers Group, Italy- Page
American Chamber of Commerce, Inc., statement 1621
Latella, John T., associate counsel, and Allan A. Rubin, vice president and
counsel, U.S. Brewers Association, statement 2826
Lead-Zinc Producers Committee, Lindsay F. Johnson:
Average E. & M. J. price per pound 2300
Factors preceding Presidential Proclamation No. 3257-September
22, 1958 2287
Leaf Tobacco Exporters Association, Inc., Malcolm B. Seawell, executive
secretary and general counsel, statement 1429
League of Women Voters:
Anderson (md.), Mrs. George Doherty, president, letter dated July 12,
1968, to Chairman Mills 993
Ann Arbor (Mich.), Mrs. Joseph Kummer, first vice president, letter
dated June 20, 1968, to Chairman Mills 995
Beverly Hills (Calif.), Mrs. Bruce Rabin, president, letter dated June
18, 1968, to Chairman Mills 990
Broome County (N.Y.), ~\1rs. Alfred B. Carlip, chairman, foreign
policy committee, letter dated June 28, 1968, to Chairman Mills__ 998
Cincinnati (Ohio), telegram dated June 1, 1968, to Chairman Mills~ 999
Columbia-Boone County (Mo.), Mrs. James W. Mackenzie, president,
letter dated June 24, 1968, to Chairman Mills 997
Dc Kalb County (Ga.), Mrs. T. Emory Daniel, president, letter dated
July 8, 1968, to Chairman Mills 992
Falmouth (Mass.), Dorothy Parshley hahn, chairman, foreign eco-
nomic policy, and Mrs. Dewitt C. Jones III, president, letter dated
July 1, 1968, to Chairman Mills 994
Glen Ellyn (Ill.), Mrs. Howard Hansen, president, letter dated June
19, 1968, to Chairman Mills 992
Great Neck (N.Y.), Mrs. Max Chernoff, president, letter dated June
24, 1968, to Chairman Mills 998
Greater Lafayette (md.), Mrs. Ralph Webb, president, letter dated
June 27, 1968, to Chairman Mills 994
Greater Toledo (Ohio), Mrs. Robert F. Jackson, president, letter dated
June 27, 1968, to Chairman Mills 999
Hamden (Conn.), Mrs. Bruce Detmers, president, letter dated June
24, 1968, to Chairman Mills 991
Indiana, Mrs. Robert S. Richey, president, letter dated July 1, 1968,
to Chairman Mills 993
Long Beach (Calif.), Mrs. Marvin Tincher, president, letter dated
June 24, 1968, to Chairman Mills 990
Los Gatos-Saratoga (Calif.), Mrs. Harold Martin, president, letter
dated June 20, 1968, to Chairman Mills 991
Metropolitan Dade County (Fla.), Mrs. Robert T. Phillips, president,
letter dated June 24, 1968, to Chairman Mills 991
Michigan, Mrs. Margaret Foerch, president, letter dated June 28,
1968, to Chairman Mills 996
Midland County (Tex.), Mrs. J. R. Sheeler, president, and Mrs. W. M.
Raimer, foreign policy committee, letter dated June 26, 1968, to
Chairman Mills 1000
New Berlin (Wis.), Mrs. Jack Prochnow, president, letter dated June
22, 1968, to Chairman Mills 1000
New Brighton (Minn.), Mrs. Paul A. Moore, Jr., president, letter dated
June 20, 1968, to Chairman Mills 996
Oklahoma, Jean Thomas, State president, letter dated June 20, 1968,
to Chairman Mills
Princeton Community (N.J.), Claire Beskind, president, letter dated
June 20, 1968, to Chairman Mills 997
Reading (Mass.), Mrs. Lawrence Blood, president, letter dated June
25, 1968, to Chairman Mills 994
Sheboygan (Wis.), Mrs. Alfred Grube, president, letter dated June 27,
1968, to Chairman Mills 1001
Williamstown (Mass.), Anne F. Skinner, foreign policy chairman, letter
dated June 27, 1968, to Chairman Mills 995
Winter Park-Orlando (Fla.), Mrs. Robert M. Carson, president,
letter dated June 26, 1968, to Chairman Mills 992
PAGENO="0033"
XXXIII
Lear Siegler, Inc., John G. Brook, chairman, telegram dated July 12, 1968, Page
to Chairman Mills 3633
Leboeuf, Leonard E., treasurer and general counsel, Stevens Linen Asso-
ciates, Inc., statement 2726
Lemke, B. L., & Co., Inc., Joseph J. Franko, treasurer, statement 4626
Levi, Archie B., president, et al., Oil, Chemical & Atomic Workers Inter-
national Union, letter dated June 27, 1968, to Chairman Mills 4764
Levy, M. Barry, counsel, Toy Manufacturers of America, Inc., statement 3168
Lewis, Joseph H., president, local 12457, District 50, United Mine Workers
of America, letter dated July 5, 1968, to J. W. Martin, Jr., chief counsel,
Committee on Ways and Means 4808
Lichtblau, John H., director of research, Petroleum Industry Research
Foundation, Tue., letter dated July 2, 1968, to Ways and Means
Committee, with attachment 4388
Liebenow, Robert C., president, Corn Refiners Association, Inc., state-
ment 5093
Lightweight Aggregate Producers Association, the Expanded Shale, Clay &
Slate Institute, and the National Slag Association, statement 3813
Lindholm, Richard W., professor of finance and dean of the Graduate
School of Management and Business, University of Oregon 1706
Linen Thread Co., Howard Johnson, sales manager, statement 2620
Locke, Edwin A., Jr., president, American Paper Institute, Inc., statement 4460
Lockheed Aircraft Corp., D. J. Houghton, chairman of the board, telegram
dated July 11, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3633
Long Island Association of Commerce & Industry, and World Trade Club
of Long Island, Fred E. Merrell, secretary, letter dated June 26, 1968, to
Committee on Ways and Means, with position paper attached 1789
Louisiana, State of, Hon. John J. McKeithen, Governor, statement 4207
Loxcreen Co., J. W. Parrish, president, telegram dated July 8, 1968, to
Chairman Mills 3376
Lucht, R. A., president, Harshaw Chemical Co., letter dated May 31, 1968,
to Chairman Mills 4800
Luggage & Leather Goods Manufacturers of America, Inc., Jack Citron-
baum, executive vice president, statement 4131
Lukens Steel Co., Charles Lukens Huston, Jr., president, letter dated
June 24, 1968, to Chairman Mills 2257
McCauley, Alfred R., special counsel to consumer products division,
Electronic Industries Association, letter dated June 27, 1968, to John M.
Martin, Esq., chief counsel, Committee on Ways and Means, forwarding
memorandum of the Magnavox Co. on color television picture tubes_ - - 3496
McClory, Hon. Robert, a Representative in Congress from the State of
Illinois, statement 4011
McClure, Hon. James A., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Idaho, letter dated June 3, 1968, to Chairman Mills, forwarding letter
from Mrs. George L. Hays, president, Idaho Cow Belles, and statement
from George L. Hays, Mission Creek Angus Ranch 3335
McColly, Don W., president, and Jefferson E. Peyser, general counse,
Wine Institute, statement 2803
McDonald, D. L., president, West Central Texas Oil & Gas Association,
statement - 4205
McDonnell Douglas Corp., John R. Allen, vice president, eastern region,
letter dated July 16, 1968, to Chairman Mills 2798
McKeithen, Hon. John J., Governor, State of Louisiana, statement 4207
McMillan, C. W., executive vice president, American National Cattle-
men's Association, letter dated July 9, 1968, to Chairman Mills, re
explanation of the proposed amendments to the Meat Import Act of
1964 3211
Mackenzie, Mrs. James W., president, League of Women Voters of Co-
lumbia-Booiie County (Mo.), letter dated June 24, 1968, to Chairman
Mills
MacRae, John S., & Co., John S. MacRae, letter dated June 6, 1968, to
Chairman Mills 2728
M. & R. Refractory Metals, Inc., R. S. Wood, vice president, telegram
dated July 11, 1968, to Hon. Florence P. Dwyer, a Representative in
Congress from the State of New Jersey, with covering letter 2347
Oii-l59-O8-pt. 8-3
PAGENO="0034"
XXXIV
Magnavox Co., memorandum of the, on color television picture tubes,
letter dated June 27, 1968, to John M. Martin, Esq., chief counsel,
Committee on Ways and Means, from Alfred R. McCauley, special
counsel to consumer products division, Electronic Industries Associa- Page
tion, forwarding memorandum 3496
Magnavox Consumer Electronics Co., George H. Fezell, president, tele-
gram dated July 10, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3633
Magruder Color Co., Inc., John A. Howard, vice president and general
manager, letter dated June 24, 1968, to John M. Martin, Jr., chief
counsel, Committee on Ways and Means 4801
1\'Iaine, State of, Department of Sea and Shore Fisheries, Ronald W.
Green, commissioner, statement 3445
Manke, Margaret, secretary, American Scotch Highland Breeders' Asso-
ciation, letter dated June 29, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3331
Mantle & Costume Manufacturers' Export Group of London, England,
statement, with forwarding letter from Department of State 2739
Marienthal, R. L., manager of chemical sales, Hilton-Davis Chemical
Co., letter dated June 21, 1968, to Committee on Ways and Means - - - 4801
Marks Specialties, Inc., Harry L. Marks, president, statement 3069
Marshall, Vice Adm. Wm. J., U.S. Navy (retired), president, Bourbon
Institute, statement 2799
Martin, Edmund F., chairman, Bethlehem Steel Corp., letter dated June 17,
1968, to Chairman Mills 1926
Martin, Mrs. Harold, president, League of Women Voters of Los Gatos-
Saratoga (Calif.), letter dated June 20, 1968, to Chairman Mills 991
Massachusetts, Commonwealth of:
Caggiano, G. Robert, director, Bureau of International Trade,
Department of Commerce and Development, statement 1065
Governor's Advisory Committee for the Shoe and Leather Industry,
resolution 4063
Mathias, Hon. Charles McC., Jr., a Representative in Congress from the
State of Maryland, letter dated June 20, 1968, to Chairman Mills 4889
May, Hon. R. J., secretary, Rubber and Plastics Footwear Manufacturers
Association, Liverpool, England, with forwarding letter from the U.S.
State Department 4174
Meat-O-Mat, Inc., N. Friedson, letter dated June 12, 1968, to John M.
Martin, Jr., chief counsel, Ways and Means Committee 3344
Mendocino County (Calif.) Farm Bureau, Mayrne Williams, secretary,
letter dated June 19, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3334
Mercker, Albert E., executive secretary, Vegetable Growers Association
of America, statement 5086
Merrell, Fred E., secretary, Long Island Association of Commerce &
Industry, and World Trade Club of Long Island, letter dated June 26,
1968, to Committee on Ways and Means, with position paper attached_ 1789
Meyer, E. R., Kinkead Industries, Inc., letter dated July 1, 1968, to
Chairman Mills 3376
Meyer, J. Mason, executive secretary, American Hardboard Association,
statement 4468
Midcontinent Farmers Association and Missouri Farmers Association, Inc.,
Fred V. Heinkel, president, statement 1310
Miller, G. W., chairman of the board, Pattenfeid Grease & Oil Corp. of
New York, statement, with forwarding letter from Hon. Henry P. Smith
III, a Representative in Congress from the State of New York 4422
Miller, Henry E., National Retail Merchants Association, letter dated
July 12, 1968, to John M. Martin, Jr., from John C. Hazen, vice plesi-
dent-Government, re exports of textiles and textile products 80o
Mink, I-Ton. Patsy T., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Hawaii, letter dated June 20, 1968, to Chairman Mills forwarding material
from the Hawaii Cattlemen's Council 3308
Miracle, Ralph, secretary, Montana Stockgrowers Association, Inc., letter
dathd June 5, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3320
Mission Creek Angus Ranch, George L. Hays, statement, with covering
letter from 1-Ton. James A. McClure, a Representative in Congress from
the State of Idaho
Missouri Farmers Association, Inc., and Midcontinent Farmers Association,
Fred V. Heinkel, president 1310
PAGENO="0035"
XXXV
Page
Mississippi Cattlemen's Association, statement 3318
Mitchell, 0. J., Jr., vice president, Union Steel Chest Corp., letter dated
June 4, 1968, to Chairman Mills 2258
Mitchell, Walter L., president, International Chemical Workers Union,
statement 4804
Modesto, Octavio A., general manager, Seafood Producers Association,
letter dated May 31, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3443
Mogle, J. A., chairman, foreign trade committee, Fine and Specialty Wire
Manufacturers' Association, statement 2275
Moiola Bros., Lawrence Moiola, partner, letter dated May 22, 1968, to
ChairmanMilis 3336
Monkman, James W. L., vice president, Crompton & Knowles Corp.,
statement 4798
Montana Stockgrowers Association, Inc., Ralph Miracle, secretary, letter
dated June 5, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3320
Moore, Hon. Dan K., Governor of North Carolina, statement 2624
Moore, Mrs. Paul A., Jr., president, League of Women Voters of New
Brighton (Minn.), letter dated June 20, 1968, to Chairman Miils - - 996
Moore, Wm. H., staff vice president, Government products division, Elec-
tronic Industries Association, letter dated July 12, 1968, to Chairman
Mills 3507
Moran, C. C., president, Cupples Products Division, H. H. Robertson
Co., telegram dated July 3, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3376
Moss, Aubrey L., president, American Metal Importers Association, Inc.,
letter dated July 1, 1968, to Committee on Ways and Means 3377
Motorola, Inc., Robert W. Galvin, telegram dated July 12, 1968, to
Chairman Mills 3634
Mundt, John C. (~ee Cement Industry Antidumping Committee.)
Murphy Oil Corp., C. H. Murphy, Jr., president, statement 4405
Murray, John E., Jr., vice president, Nicholson & Co., Inc., letter dated
June 24, 1968, to John M. Martin, Jr., chief counsel, Committee on
Ways and Means 5095
Myers, A. Nelson, vice president, marketing, Texas Gulf Sulphur, Co.,
letter dated July 9, 1968, to Chairman Mills 2348
Myers, John M., president, Independent Oil Heat Dealers Association of
Maryland, and Fuel Oil Council of i\'Iaryland, Jay ID. Kline, president,
letter dated July 5, 1968, to Chairman Mills 4420
Nast, Thomas ID., president, All-State Welding Alloys Co., Inc., letter
dated July 3, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3374
Nation-Wide Committee on Import-Export Policy, 0. R. Strackbein,
chairman:
Cost of becoming competitive in ocean shipping 933
Countervailing duty provision, information on 919
Letter dated June 18, 1968, to Hon. Herman T. Schneebeli re U.S.
treatment of imports 926
Nontariff trade barriers 929
Price of becoming competitive in steel 947
Trends in prices on commodities subject to import quotas 918
National Association of Alcoholic Beverage Importers, Inc., John F.
O'Connell, president, statement 2814
National Association of Glove Manufacturers, E. Greenaway, secretary,
letter dated May 28, 1968, to Chairman Mills, with forwarding letter
from the Department~ of State 2742
National Association of Manufacturers, statement 1723
National Association of Secondary Material Industries, Inc., Harold
Kurtin, president, letter dated July 10, 1968, to Chairman Mills_ 2627
National Coal Association, Stephen F. Dunn, president, statement 4423
National Consumers League, Dr. Persia Campbell, statement 870
National Council of Farmer Cooperatives, Robert N. Hampton, director
of marketing and international, trade, letter dated July 12, 1968, to
Chairman Mills 1735
National Council of Jewish Women, Inc., statement 1826
National Customs Brokers & Forwarders Association of America, Inc.,
John G. Eberlein, chairman, drawback committee, pamphlet entitled
"What Is Customs Drawback?" 1024
PAGENO="0036"
xxxv'
National Farmers Union, Reuben L. Johnson, director, legislative services:
Statement of Farmers Union adopted by delegates at the convention Page
in Minneapolis 790
Statement by Reuben L. Johnson to the conference on trade policy
sponsored by the coordinating council of organizations on inter-
national trade policy at the Sheraton Park Hotel, Washington, D.C~ 790
National Federation of Independent Business, George S. Bullen, legislative
director, statement 1730
National Footwear Manufacturers Association:
Nonrubber footwear: Tariff and trade regulations (U.S. Department
of Commerce, Business and Defense Services Administration) - - - - 4093
Richardson, Mark E., president, telegram dated June 13, 1968, to
Hon. Dean Rusk, Secretary of State 2624
National Grange:
Graham, Harry L., legislative representative, excerpt from European
Economic Commission report on the economic situation of the milk
and milk products sector in the Community 782
Newson, Herschel D., master, U.S. agricultural exports to the Euro-
pean Economic Community: value by commodity 781
National Handbag Association, Steven J. Weiss, counsel, statement 4134
National Oil Jobbers Council, Wilfred H. Hall, executive vice president,
statement 4366
National Piano Manufacturers Association, Perry S. Patterson, counsel,
statement 3159
National Restaurant Association, Ira H. Nunn, counsel, statement 3337
National Retail Merchants Association, Henry E. Miller, letter dated
July 12, 1968, to John M. Martin, Jr., from John C. Hazen, vice president,
government, re exports of textiles and textile products 805
National Slag Association, the Expanded Shale, Clay & Slate Institute, and
the Lightweight Aggregate Producers Association, statement 3813
National-Standard Co., Ernest U. Lang, chief engineer, statement 1824
Nebraska Stock Growers Association, E. H. Shoemaker, Jr., president,
letter dated May 25, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3320
Netherlands Chamber of Commerce in the United States, Inc., Henry J.
Clay, letter dated June 25, to Hon. John W. Byrnes, re quantitative
restrictions 1594
Nevada State Cattle Association, Leslie J. Stewart, president, letter to
Chairman Mills 3321
New Mexico Cattle Growers' Association, W. 0. Culbertson, Jr., president,
statement 3322
New Zealand Dairy Board, statement, with forwarding letter from the
State Department 4890
New Zealand Meat Producers Board, statement, with forwarding letter
from the State Department 3304
Newark, N. J., Mayor Hugh J. Addonizio, statement 1473
Newsom, Herschel D. (See National Grange.)
Nicholson & Co., Inc., John E. Murray, Jr., vice president, letter dated June
24, 1968, to John M. Martin, Jr., chief counsel, Committee on Ways and
Means 5095
North Carolina, Governor of, Hon. Dan K. Moore, statement 2624
North Dakota Stockmen's Association, Raymond Schnell, president,
statement 3325
Norwegian-American Chamber of Commerce, Inc., Danish American
Trade Council, Inc., Finnish American Chamber of Commerce, Inc., and
Swedish Chamber of Commerce of the United States, Inc., statement_ - - - 1775
Nunn, Ira 1-I., counsel, National Restaurant Association, statement 3337
Nyanza, Inc., Roland E. Derby, Jr., president, letter dated June 17, 1968, to
Chairman Mills 4802
O'Brien, Gerald, executive vice president, American Importers Association,
statement on U.S. foreign trade policy before Trade Information Com-
mittee of Office of President's Special Representative for Trade Negotia-
tions-May 20, 1968 841
Ocean Freight Consultants, Inc., Fred S. Haber, president, statement 1801
Ocoma Foods Co., 1-larold J. Wendt, vice president, production, letter dated
May31, 1968, toChairman Mills 3344
-O'Connell, John F., president, National Association of Alcoholic Beverage
Importers, Inc., statement 2814
PAGENO="0037"
XXXVII
O'Connor, J. M., executive vice president, Peerless of America, Inc., letter Page
dated July 1, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3376
Odian, Bedros, attorney, Buffalo, N.Y., letter dated May 15, 1968, to John
M. Martin, Jr., chief counsel, Committee on Ways and Means 5098
Oesterle, Father John, Church of St. Teresa, Munhall, Pa., letter dated June
3, 1968, to Ways and Means Committee 5096
Ohio Cattle Feeders Association, Russell Forsythe, president, and James H.
Warner, secretary, letter dated June 17, 1968, to Chairman 1\Iills, with
attachment 3326
Ohio Oil & Gas Association, David H. Bell, president, letter dated May 27,
1968, to Committee on Ways and Means 4392
Oil, Chemical & Atomic Workers International Union:
Levi, Archie B., president, et al., letter dated June 27, 1968, to
Chairman Mills 4764
Riker, Raymond, president, local 8-95, letter dated July 3, 1968, to
John M. Martin, Jr., chief counsel 4807
Oklahoma~ Cattlemen's Association, Wray Finney, president, letter dated
May 28, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3327
Optical Importers Association of the United States, Inc., Julius Simon,
president, statement 3135
Orban, Kurt. (See American Institute for Imported Steel, Inc.)
Oregon, Otter Trawl Commission of, Dr. E. W. Harvey, administrator,
statement 3450
Ornitz, Martin N., president, Roblin Steel Co., letter dated June 24, 1968,
to Chairman Mills, with covering letter from Hon. Henry P. Smith, a
Representative in Congress from the State of New York 2257
Orr, Robert M., president, and Ed Thompson, executive vice president,
Permian Basin Petroleum Association, statement 4281
Otter Trawl Commission of Oregon, Dr. E. W. Harvey, administrator,
statement 3450
Overton, J. Allen, Jr. (See American Mining Congress.)
Pacific American Steamship Association, statement 1790
Parker, H. R., secretary, Candle Manufacturers Association, letter dated
June 25, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3170
Parrish, J. W., president, Loxcreen Co., telegram dated July 8, 1968, to
Chairman Mills 3376
Patterson, Huberta M., secretary, West Virginia League, in behalf of West
Virginia, Pennsylvania, Ohio, and Indiana Glass Workers' Protective
Leagues, statement 3826
Patterson, Perry S., counsel, National Piano Manufacturers Association,
statement 3159
Patton, Thomas F. (See American Iron & Steel Institute.)
Peerless of America, Inc., J. M. O'Connor, executive vice president, letter
dated July 1, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3376
Perkel, George, director of research, Textile Workers Union of America,
AFL-CIO, statement 2630
Perkins, Hon. Carl D., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Kentucky, letter dated June 17, 1968, to Chairman Mills 4889
Permian Basin Petroleum Association, Robert M. Orr, president, and Ed
Thompson, executive vice president, statement 4281
Peters, J. S., manager, membership & industry relations, Florida Fruit &
Vegetable Association, letter dated July 29, 1968, to Congressman
Thomas B. Curtis, re domestic market for fruits and vegetables 4978
Petroleum Industry Research Foundation, Inc., John H. Lichtblau,
director of research, letter dated July 2, 1968, to Ways and Means
Committee, with attachment 4388.
Peyser, Jefferson E., general counsel, and Don W. McColly, president,
Wine Institute, statement 2803:
Phillips, Mrs. Robert T., president, League of Women Voters of Metro-
iolitan Dade County (Fla.), letter dated June 24, 1968, to Chairman
Mills 991
Picard, Raymond J., president, French Chamber of Commerce in the
United States, Inc., statement 1773
Piering, David P., president, Diversified Wire & Steel Corp., telegram,
dated June 14, 1968, to Chairman Mills 2202
Polan, Katz & Co., Inc., Lawrence R. Katz, letter dated July 9, 1968, to
Chairman Mills 3157
PAGENO="0038"
XXXVIII
Precision Drawn Steel Co., L. G. Brown, president, letter dated June 4, Page
1968, to Chairman Mills, with attachment 2273
Premier Santa Gertrudis Association, M. Allen Anderson, president, reso-
lution, dated May 26, 1968, with covering letter from Hon. Roman L.
Hruska, a U.S. Senator from the State of Nebraska 3333
Price, J. Raymond, executive secretary of Glass Crafts of America, on
behalf of the American Hand-Made Glassware Industry, statement - - 3819
Prochnow, Mrs. Jack, president, League of Women Voters of New Berlin
(Wis.), letter dated June 22, 1968, to Chairman Mills 1000
Public Lands Council, Joseph H. Tudor, general counsel, letter dated
May 27, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3333
Purcell, Robert, Emergency Committee for American Trade, a critique of
the Trade Relations Council's analysis of certain 1958/1960-1964 declines
in employment~ 1352
Rabin, Mrs. Bruce, president, League of Women Voters of Beverly Hills
(Calif.), letter dated June 18, 1968, to Chairman Mills 990
Raimer, Mrs. W. M., foreign policy committee, League of Women Voters
of Midland County, Tex., letter dated June 26, 1968, to Chairman Mills_ 1000
Rampton, Hon. Calvin L., Governor of the State of Utah, statement - - - 4059
Randall, Fiank L., Jr., president, Amperex Electronic Corp., statement_ - 3505
Rapaport, Arthur, Jardox Fur Co., letter dated July 10, 1968, to Chairman
Mills 4063
Raytheon Co., Charles F. Adams, chairman of the hoard, telegram dated
July 12, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3634
Reuther, Walter P., president, United Automobile, Aerospace and Agri-
cultural Implement Workers of America (UAW), statement 1755
Richardson, Mark E., president, National Footwear Manufacturers Assoc-
iation, telegram dated June 13, 1968, to Hon. Dean Rusk, Secretary of
State 2624
Richey, Mrs. Robert S., president, League of Women Voters of Indiana,
letter dated July 1, 1968, to Chairman Mills 993
Riker, Raymond, president local 8-95, Oil, Chemical and Atomic Workers
International Union, letter dated July 3, 1968, to John M. Martin, Jr.,
chief counsel 4807
Roach, T. L., Jr., president, Texas and Southwestern Cattle Raisers
Association, letter dated May 28, 1968, to Chairman Mills, with at-
tacliment 3327
Rogers, Hon. Paul G., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Florida, statement 4980
Robertson, H. H., Co., C. C. Moran, president, Cupples Products Division,
telegram dated July 3, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3376
Robie, Merle S., chairman, executive committee, Cordage Institute,
statement 2372
Roblin Steel Co., Martin N. Ornitz, president, letter dated June 24,
1968, to Chairman Mills, with covering letter from Hon. Henry P.
Smith, a Representative in Congress from the State of New York 2257
Rostov, Charles I., floor covering group, American Import Association,
statement 2603, 2618
Rott, Dr. Ernst, executive secretary, United States Austrian Chamber of
Commerce, Inc., letter dated May 29, 1968, to John M. Martin, Jr.,
chief counsel, Committee on Ways and Means, with memorandum
attached 1771
Rowley, E. M., president, International House, letter dated July 10,
1968, to Chairman Mills, with resolution attached 1786
Rubber & Plastics Footwear Manufacturers Association, Liverpool,
England, R~. J. May, Hon. secretary, with forwarding letter from the
U.S. State Department 4174
Rubin, Allan A., vice president and counsel, and John T. Latella, asso-
ciate counsel, United States Brewers Association, statement 2826
Rusmisell, Deane E., president, Work Glove Manufacturers Association,
Inc., statement 2723
Sanders, C T. "Tad," general manager, Certified Livestock Markets
Association, letter dated July 3, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3332
Sanz de Santaniaria, Carlos, chairman, Inter-American Committee on the
Alliance for Progress (ClAP), statement, with covering letter from
State Department to Chairman Mills 1713
PAGENO="0039"
XXXIX
Schmidt, Donald R., president, South Dakota Beekeepers Association, Page
telegram dated June 22, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3470
Schnell, Raymond, president, North Dakota Stockmen's Association,
statement 3325
Schwenger, Robert B., supplemental statement 1680
Scott, Hon. William Lloyd, a Representative in Congress from the State
of Virginia, letter dated July 1, 1968, to Chairman Mills 4888
Seafood Producers Association, Octavio A. Modesto, general manager,
letter dated May 31, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3443
Seawell, Malcolm B., executive secretary and general counsel, Leaf To-
bacco Exporters Association, Inc., statement 1429
Sebastinas, A., president, International Union of District 50, United
Mine Workers of America, Local 15143, letter dated June 14, 1968, to
John M. Martin, Jr., chief counsel, Committee on Ways and Means - - 4807
Segall, Irving, New York, N.Y., letter dated July 11, 1968, to Chairman
Mills 4062
Service Tools Institute, George P. Byrne, Jr., secretary and legal counsel,
statement 3046
Sharp, W. Parker, Pittsburgh, Pa., letter dated June 18, 1968, to Chair-
man Mills 2265
Shaw, Arnold H., counsel, Warehousemen's Association of the Port of
New York, Inc., letter dated June 18, 1968, to Chairman Mills 1801
Shearer, Wendell B., president, Vinyl Maid, Inc., letter dated June 17,
1968, to Chairman Mills 5092
Sheeler, 1\'Irs. J. R., president, League of Women Voters of Midland
County (Tex.), letter dated June 26, 1968, to Chairman Mills 1000
Shears, Scissors & Manicure Implement Manufacturers Association,
B. C. Deuschle, president, statement 3063
Sherwin-Williams Co., G. L. Tickner, eastern manager, pigment, color and
chemical department, statement 4667
Shirt, Collar & Tie Manufacturers' Federation, and Clothing M~nu-
facturers' Federation of Great Britain, statement, with forwarding
letter from the Department of State 2736
Shoemaker, E. H., Jr., president, Nebraska Stock Growers Association,
letter dated May 25, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3320
Simon, Julius, president, Optical Importers Association of the United
States, Inc., statement 3133
Sinkler, Arthur B., chairman of the board, Hamilton Watch Co., letter
dated July 12, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3741
Skinner, Anne F., foreign policy chairman, League of Women Voters of
l~,Tilliamsto~vn (Mass.), letter dated June 27, 1968, to Chairman Mills~ 995
Slesinger, Reuben E., associate dean, professor of economics, division of
the social sciences, University of Pittsburgh, letter dated June 25, 1968,
to Chairman Mills, with article attached entitled "Steel Imports and
Vertical Oligopoly Power: Comment" 2265
Smith, Marshall M., Greater Fort Lauderdale (Fla.) Chamber of Com-
merce, letter dated July 3, 1968, to Committee on Ways and Means - - 1785
Smith, Stanford, general manager, American Newspaper Publishers Asso-
ciation, statement 4465
Smith, T. William C., president, American Pipe Fittings Association, letter
dated June 20, 1968, to Chairman Mills 2239
Smithfield Packing Co., Inc., G. R. Crawford, executive vice president,
letter dated June 10, 1968, to John M. Martin, Jr., chief counsel, Com-
mittee on Ways and Means 3343
Snow & Co., H. R. Snow, letter dated June 6, 1968, to Chairman Mills~ 3334
Socket Screw Products Bureau, et al., George P. Byrne, Jr., secretary and
legal counsel, statement 3027
Sommer, Walton B., president and chairman of the board, Keystone Steel &
Wire Co., letter dated June 10, 1968, to Chairman Mills, with statement
attached 1927
South Dakota Beekeepers Association, Donald R. Schmidt, president,
telegram dated June 22, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3470
Southern California Edison Co., statement 4417
Specialty Crops Conference, Robert I\1. Kerr, attorney, statement 5049
Sporting Arms & Ammunition Manufacturers' Institute, Robert C. Zimmer,
counsel, statement 3081
PAGENO="0040"
XL
Starr, Wayne H., president, Citizens State Bank & Trust Co., letter dated Page
June 20, 1968, to Chairman Mills 1824
Standard Oil Company of California, statement 4408
Steelworkers of America, Local No. 3256, Arvo E. Sundberg, statement__ 2248
Stenning, W. W., North American representative, Australian Meat Board,
statement, with forwarding letter from the State Department 3301
Stephens, Hon. Robert G., Jr., a Representative iii Congress from the
State of Georgia 4886
Stevens Linen Associates, Inc., Leonard E. Leboeuf, treasurer and general
counsel, statement 2726
Stewart, Eugene L., counsel, Parts and Distributor Products Divisions,
Electronic Industries Association and American Loudspeaker Manu-
facturers Association, letter dated July 3, 1968, to Hon. Jackson E.
Betts, a Representative in Congress from the State of Ohio, re Far East
comparative wages~ 3630
Stewart, Leslie J., president, Nevada State Cattle Association, letter to
Chairman Mills 3321
Strackbein, 0. R. (&e Nation-Wide Committee on Import-Export Policy.)
Strate, Martin F., executive secretary, Virginia Beef Cattle Association,
letter dated May 24, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3329
Stybr, L. E., executive director, J. E. Cooper, president, and R. E. Lam-
bert, chairman, committee on Government relations, American Sprocket
Chair Manufacturers Association, statement 3039
Sundberg, Arvo E., representing the city of Conneaut, Ohio and Local
No. 3256, AFL-CIO, Steelworkers of America, statement 2248
Swedish Chamber of Commerce of the United States, Inc., Danish Ameri-
can Trade Council Inc., Finnish American Chamber of Commerce,
Inc., and Norwegian-American Chamber of Commerce, Inc., statement 1775
Swiss Union of Commerce and Industry, Michael P. Daniels, counsel,
statement, with covering letter from State Department 4771
Synthetic Organic Chemical Manufacturers Association (SOCMA),
memorandum concerning testimony given in support of the "separate"
package agreement 4760
Tanaka, H. William, counsel, on behalf of certain importers of electronic
products, A. & A. Trading Co., et al., statement 3654
Tapping Screw Service Bureau, et al., George P. Byrne, Jr., secretary and
legal counsel, statement 3027
Tatem Manufacturing Co., Inc., Stewart M. Tatern, statement 4481
Teague, Randal Cornell, director of regional and State activities, Young
Americans for Freedom, Inc., statement 4909
Tektronix, Inc., Don A. Ellis, treasurer, statement 3704
Tennant, C., Sons & Co., Aubrey Fletcher, executive vice president, letter
dated June 21, 1968, to Chairman Mills, re statistics on lead and zinc~ 2318
Tenneco Chemicals, Inc., Leon W. Gerst, president, Tenneco colors divi-
sion, statement 4780
Teper, Lazare, director of research, International Ladies' Garment Work-
ers' Union, AFL-CIO, and Milton Fried, director of research, Amalga-
mated Clothing Workers of America, AFL-CIO, letter dated June 14,
1968, to Chairman Mills 2641
Texaco Inc., statement 4409
Texas Citrus Mutual, William W. Curl, president, statement 5083
Texas Farm Bureau, M. F. Frost, vice president, statement 5081
Texas Gulf Sulphur Co., A. Nelson Myers, vice president, marketing, letter
dated July 9, 1968, to Chairman Mills 2348
Texas Instruments Inc., J. Fred Bucy, group vice president, telegram
dated July 11, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3634
Texas and Southwestern Cattle Raisers Association, T. L. Roach, Jr.,
president, letter dated May 28, 1968, to Chairman Mills, with attach-
ment 332~
Textile Workers Union of America, AFL-CIO, George Perkel, director of
research, statement 2630
Thomas, Jean, State president, League of Women Voters of Oklahoma,
letter dated June 20, 1968, to Chairman Mills 999
Thompson, Ed., executive vice president, and Robert M. Orr, president,
Permian Basin Petroleum Association, statement 4281
PAGENO="0041"
XLI
Tickner, G. L., eastern manager, pigment, color and chemical department, Page
Sherwin-Williams Co., statement 4667
Tincher, Mrs. Marvin, president, League of Women Voters of Long Beach
(Calif.), letter dated June 24, 1968, to Chairman Mills 990
Tool and Stainless Steel Industry Committee, statement 1929
Toy Manufacturers of America, Inc., M. Barry Levy, counsel, statement - 3168
Trueblood, R. W., president, Beiridge Oil Co., statement 4269
Trugman-Nash, Inc., Bernard A. Trugman, statement 4894
Tubular and Split Rivet Council, et al, George P. Byrne, Jr., secretary and
legal counsel, statement 3027
Tudor, Joseph H., general counsel, Public Lands Council, letter dated
May 27, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3333
United Automobile, Aerospace, and Agricultural Implement Workers of
America (UAW), Walter P. Reuther, president, statement 1755
Union Steel Chest Corp., 0. J. Mitchell, Jr., vice president, letter dated
June 4, 1968, to Chairman Mills 2258
United Mine Workers of America, District 50. (See Glenndenning, Howard
A.; Kaminski, Jerome; Kennedy, Edward E.; Lewis, Joseph H.; Se-
bastinas, A.; and Del Signore, M.)
United Rubber, Cork, Linoleum, and Plastic Workers of America, AFL-
ClO, Peter Bommarito, president, statement 4180
United Textile Workers of America, AFL-CIO, George Baldanzi, inter-
national president, statement 2628
U.S. Austrian Chamber of Commerce, Inc., Dr. Ernst Rott, executive
secretary, letter dated May 29, 1968, to John M. Martin, Jr., chief
counsel, Committee on Ways and Means, with memorandum attached 1771
U.S. Brewers Association, Allan A. Rubin, vice president and counsel, and
John T. Latella, associate counsel, statement 2826
U.S. Cap Screw Service Bureau, et al., George P. Byrne, Jr., secretary and
legal counsel, statement 3027
U.S. Dry Pea and Lentil Industry, statement 5087
U.S. Extrusions Corp., Emil H. Buckner, secretary-treasurer, letter dated
June 27, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3377
U.S. Machine Screw Service Bureau, et al., George P. Byrne, Jr., secretary
and legal counsel, statement 3027
U.S. Wood Screw Service Bureau, et al., George P. Byrne, Jr., secretary and
legal counsel, statement 3027
Utah, State of, Hon. Calvin L. Rampton, Governor, statement 4059
Utsey, James, president, Alabama Garment Manufacturers Association,
letter dated June 18, 1968, to Chairman Mills, with resolution attached
and with covering letter from Hon. Bill Nichols, a Representative in
Congress from the State of Alabama 2626
Vail, George R., vice president and director, Continental Baking Co., and
president, Morton Frozen Foods Division, statement 3342
Vander Ende, Gerrit P., San Francisco, Calif., letter dated May 22, 1968,
to Chairman Mills 5096
Veeder, Nicholas P., chairman of the board and president, Granite City
Steel Co., statement 2254
Vegetable Growers Association of America, Albert E. Mercker, executive
secretary, statement 5086
Veltfort, T. E., managing director, Copper & Brass Fabricators Council,
Inc., letter dated June 19, 1968, to Chairman Mills, with statement
attached 2325
Verity, C. William, Jr., president, Armco Steel Corp., statement 2253
Vinyl i\'Iaid, Inc., Wendell B. Shearer, president, letter dated June 17, 1968,
to Chairman Mills 5092
Virginia Beef Cattle Association, Martin F. Strate, executive secretary, let-
ter dated May 24, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3329
Walker, Charis F., executive vice president, American Bankers Associa-
tion, letter dated June 17, 1968, to Chairman Mills 1809
Walker, James L., president, Davis Wire Corp., letter dated July 9, 1968,
to Chairman iVlills, with attaehments 2269
Warehousemen's Association of the Port of New York, Inc., Arnold H.
Shaw, counsel, letter dated June 18, 1968, to Chairman Mills 1801
PAGENO="0042"
XLII
Warner, James I-I., secretary, and Russell Forsythe, president, Ohio Cattle
Feeders Association, letter dated June 17, 1968, to Chairman Mills, Page
with attachment 3326
Washington, State of, Hon. Daniel J. Evans, Governor, letter dated June 7,
1968, to Chairman Mills, with position paper attached 1719
\\Tashington Cattle Feeders Association, C. A. Courtright, president, letter
dated June 5, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3329
Washington Cattlemen's i~ssociation, Inc., John Woodard, president,
letter dated June 14, 1968, to Ways and Means Committee 3330
Washington Steel Corp., T. S. Fitch, president, letter dated June 28, 1968,
to Chairman Mills 1928
Webb, Mrs. Ralph, president, League of Women Voters of Greater Lafay-
ette (Ind.), letter dated June 27, 1968, to Chairman Mills 994
Weiss, Steven J., counsel, National Handbag Association, statement 4134
Wendt, Harold J., vice president, production, Ocoma Foods Co., letter
dated May 31, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3344
West Central Texas Oil & Gas Association, D. L. McDonald, president,
statement 4205
West Mexico Vegetable Distributors Association, A. B. Conrad, secretary-
manager, statement, with forwarding letter from Hon. Morris K. Udall,
a Representative in Congress from the State of Arizona 5088
Western Dairy Products, Inc., statement 4892
Westwood, Richard E., president, EMBA Mink Breeders, Association,
statement 4014
Wexler, Dr. William A., president, B'nai B'rith, statement 1028
Whealy, Roland A., vice president, Ashland Oil & Refining Co., staternent 4393
Williams, Mayme, secretary, Mendocino County (Calif.) Farm Bureau,
letter dated June 19, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3334
Williams, Oliver, New York, N.Y., statement 5096
Wimmer, Ed, president, Forward America, Inc., radio talk 1733
Window Glass Cutters League of America, Harry W. Baughman, Jr.,
national president, statement 3824
Wine Institute, Don W. McColly, president, and Jefferson B. Peyser,
general counsel, statement 2803
Winn, Hon. Larry, Jr., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Kansas, letter dated July 12, 1968, to Chairman Mills 3168
Wittig, Harley, past president, EMBA Mink Breeders Association,
statement 4013
Wolfson, J. Theodore, president, Business Builders International, Inc.,
article from Wall Street Journal entitled "Steel firms' profits are ex-
pected to spurt as outlays begin to pay off, analysts say" 859
\Von Pat, Hon. Antonio B., Territory of Guam, Representative in Wash-
ington, statement 3740
Wood, R. S., vice president, M. & R. Refractory Metals, Inc., telegram
dated July 11, 1968, to Hon. Florence P. Dwyer, a Representative in
Congress from the State of New Jersey, with covering letter 2347
Woodard, John, president, Washington Cattlemen's Association, Inc.,
letter dated June 14, 1968, to Ways and Means Committee 3330
World Trade Club of Long Island, and Long Island Association of Com-
merce & Industry, Fred B. Merrell, secretary, letter dated June 26, 1968,
to Committee on Ways and Means, with position paper attached 1789
Work Glove Manufacturers Association, Inc., Deane E. Rusmisell,
president, statement 2723
Wright, Ronald, president, Canned Meat Importers Association, state-
ment 3338
Wriston, Walter B., president, First National City Bank, letter dated
July 12, 1968, to Chairman Mills, with attachment 1810
Young Americans for Freedom, Inc., Randal Cornell Teague, director of
regional and State activities, statement 4909
Zimmer, Robert C., Sporting Arms & Ammunition Manufacturers'
Institute, statement 3081
Zwach, Hon. John M., a Representative in Congress from the State of
Minnesota, statement 1494
PAGENO="0043"
FOREIGN TRADE AND TARIFF PROPOSALS
TUESDAY, JUNE 25, 1968
HousE OF REPRESENTATIVES,
COMMITTEE ON WAYS AND MEANS.
Washington, D.C.
The committee met at 10 a.m., pursuant to notice, in the committee
room, Longworth House Office Bu1lding, Hon. `Wilbur D. Mills (chair-
man of the committee) presiding.
The CHAIRMAN. The committee will please be in order.
Our first witnesses this morning represent the Electronic Industries
Association, Consumer Products Division, Mr. Hoffman, Mr. Fezell,
Mr. Allen and Mr. McCauley.
STATEMENT OF GEORGE H. FFIZELL, VICE PRESIDENT, CONSUMER
PRODUGTS DIVISION, ELECTRONIC INDUSTRIES ASSOCIATION;
ACCOMPANIED BY CHARLES N. HOFFMAN, CHAIRMAN; AND
ALFRED R. McCAULEY, SPECIAL COUNSEL, DIVISION ON INTER-
NATIONAL TRADE MATTERS
Mr. FEZELL. Good morning, Mr. Chairman and members of the com-
mittee; my name is George H. Fezell. I am president, Magnavox Con-
sumer Electronics Co., 270 Park Avenue in New York City. I am also
vice-president of the Consumer Products Division of the Electronic
Industries Association, better known as ETA, whose offices are at 2001
Eye Street, NW., Washington, D.C. With me today are Mr. Charles
N. Hoffman, assistant vice president, `Warwick Electronics, Inc., and
chairman of the Consumer Products Division of ETA, Mr. Armin E.
Allen, who is vice president and general manager, Consumer Elec-
tronics Division of the Philco-Ford Corp. and also chairman of the
International Trade Committee of the Consumer Products Division
planned to be with us but, unfortunately, he is ill. Also with me is Mr.
Alfred R. McCauley who is special counsel to our Division on Tnter-
national Trade Matters. We are here today in behalf of the Consumer
Products Division of ETA and Mr. Hoffman and Mr. McCauley will
assist me in answering any questions which the committee members
may have about the matter at hand.
The CHAIRMAN. We appreciate having all of you with us this morn-
ing and are glad to recognize you. If you have to omit any parts of
your statement in order to comply with our time situation your entire
statement will appear in the record.
Mr. FEZELL. Thank you very much, sir.
The Consumer Products Division numbers among its member com-
panies the majority of the U.S. manufacturers of consumer electronic
(3479)
PAGENO="0044"
3480
products-a class of articles which includes color and black and white
television receivers, radios, radio-phonographs, phonographs, tape
recorders and players, and many other home entertainment articles
which serve the needs and desires of the people of this country. The
bulk of the products made and sold by the companies in our division
and the bulk of the components we use in production are wholly
of U.S. origin. However, some of the finished products we sell and
some of the components we use in making products here in the United
States are imported from foreign sources. It is to these electronic
articles-the finished products and components-that our statement
relates.
We appear here today in opposition to H.R. 14597, H.R. 17674 and
similar bills which would specifically impose quotas on imports of
electronic articles and H.R. 16936 and similar bills which would em-
brace these articles in so-called omnibus quota provisions.
The Consumer Products Division opposes qoutas on imports of
electronic articles because they are not needed, they will disrupt
the U.S. market for consumer electronic products, and they may-
most likely they will-result in retaliatory action which will not only
hurt the extremely favorable U.S. balance of trade in electronic
products but also hurt the industries concerned and their workers.
QTJOTAS ON IMPORTS OF ELECTRONIC ARTICLES ARE NOT NEEDED
Quotas are a severe form of protection against imports since im-
ports in excess of a given quantity are embargoed. I submit that only
in exceptional circumstances, where the objective data pertaining
to domestic production and sales, exports, and imports show that an
industry is being seriously injured by imports, should any thought
he given to quotas on imports. Where such data do not show such
injury, quotas are not in order.
1965 1966 1967
Electronic industries:
Sales $17,507,000,000 $20606000000 $22,132,000,000
Exports 1,155,432,000 1,446,736,000 1,775,626,000
Imports 506,770,000 744,767,000 830,231,000
Balance of trade +648, 662, 000 +701,969,000 +045,395,000
ExportsaspercentsaleS 6.6 7.0 8.0
Imports as percent sales 2.8 3.6 3.7
Electronic components:
Sales 4,695,000.000 5,709,000,000 5,486,000,000
Exports 328,550,000 440,436,000 486,801,000
Imports 111,380,000 174,106,000 174,990,000
Balance of trade +217,170,000 +266,330,000 +311,811,000
Exports as percentsales 7.0 7.7 8.8
Imports as percent sales 2.3 3.0 3.1
Consumer electronic products:
Sales 3,641,000,000 4,493,000,000 4,324,000,000
Exports 40, 257, 000 46, 256, 000 46, 609, 000
Imports 287,919,000 385,004,000 449,927,000
Balance of trade -247,662, 000 -338,748, 000 -403, 318, 000
Exports as percent sales 1.1 1.0 1.0
Imports as percent sales 7. 9 8. 5 10. 3
The table was prepared from data contained in the "Electronic Industries Yearbook, 1968," prepared by the marketing
services department of EIA.
Mr. Chairman, the vital signs of this industry refute serious injury.
Sales have risen steadily-from $17.5 billion in 1965, to $20.6 billion
in 1966, to $22.1 billion last year. Sales of over $23 billion are forecast
PAGENO="0045"
3481
for this year. Exports have risen from $1.15 billion in 1965 to $1.44
billion in 1966 and to $1.77 billion last year. Finally, this industry's
favorable trade balance grew from $648 million in 1965 to $702 mil-
lion in 1966 to $945 million last year.
(a) The electronic component industry does not need quota protection
The pending quota proposals are supported by companies which are
members of the Parts Division of the ETA. It is in order, therefore, to
look at the relevant data to see if the overall prosperity of the elec-
tronic industries has been enjoyed by those companies which produce,
sell and export electronic components.
Factory sales of electronic components last year totaled $5.48 bil-
lion, down somewhat from the record 1966 level of $5.70 billion but up
almost 18 percent from 1965 sales of $4.69 billion. Industry estimates
point to a rise in component sales in 1968. Exports of components
climbed steadily from $328 million in 1965 to $440 million in 1966 to
a high of $486 million last year. The U.S. parts producers enjoyed a
favorable balance of trade of $217 million in 1965, $266 million in
1966, and a record $312 million in 1967.
The component segment of the U.S. electronic industries includes
such dynamic companies as Texas Instruments, Fairchild Camera,
General Instrument, Sprague Electric and others. Texas Instruments'
sales in 1966 of $580 million were almost double 1963 sales. Fairchild
in 1966 sold $225 million in products, twice as much business as it did
in 1962. General Instrument also doubled its 1962 output in 1966.
Sprague Electric's 1966 sales of $141,500,000 established a new record
for that company. `While each of these companies may have experi-
enced some letdown in sales and earnings in 1967, reflecting some soft-
ness in the economy experienced by all of us, their course continued
upward.
We respectfully submit, Mr. Chairman, that the components seg-
ment of the electronic industries is not depressed. It is aggressive and
prosperous, in need of no protection from imports.
Employment data also attest to the sound economic status of the
electronic industries and the component segment. In 1967, some 1.2
million persons were employed in electronics manufacturing and re-
lated activities. This was almost double the number so employed in
1958 and about 200,000 higher than the employment level of 1964.
The components industry employed some 434,000 workers in 1967,
more than double the 205,000 workers on the job in 1958 and up 130,-
000 over the 1964 level.
The Bureau of Labor Statistics reports that in 1965 exports of
electronic components accounted for some 23,000 jobs, up from the
16,000 export-supported jobs in 1960. Given that exports of compo-
nents have increased over 48 percent from 1965 to 1967-$328 million
to $486 million-one must conclude that the number of jobs attributa-
ble to exports of electronic components presently exceeds 30,000.
(14 The consumer electronic products industry does not need quota
protection
Thus far I have discussed the facts relevant to domestic sales, em-
ployment, exports and imports of all electronic articles, with partic-
ular emphasis on electronic components. But as I previously indicated,
PAGENO="0046"
3482
the quota proposals pending before this committee would also em-
brace imports of consumer electronic products, and for obvious rea-
sons I would like to turn to this aspect of these proposals.
Basic to the evaluation of any proposal for quotas on imports of
consumer electronic products is the judgment on the U.S. producers
of products which are similar to those being imported as to the need
for such quotas. Thus, at the outset, it is quite germane today that a
majority of U.S. producers of consumer electronic products, speaking
Through the Consumer Products Division of ETA, are opposed to
quotas on consumer electronic product imports. I will be happy to
supply for the record the names of the member companies which sub-
scribe to the views I state here today. These producers-who are ob-
viously in the best position of all concerned to determine their needs
*for protection against import competition-submit that their con-
sidered views must be given a greater weight than those of others,
such as the U.S. component manufacturers, who are not primarily
involved so far as imports of consumer electronic products are con-
cerned.
Sales of consumer electronic products increased some 25 percent
in 1966 over 1965-from $3.7 to $4.5 billion. 1967 sales were $4.3 bil-
lion, almost equal to the sales level attained in the record year 1966.
We confidently expect to repeat and most likely to exceed 1966's per-
formance this year.
Employment in consumer products production has trended upward.
At~ the end of 1966, some 144,000 persons were employed in the produc-
tion of consumer electronic products. Just 5 years previously only 89,-
000 persons were so employed while in 1958, 73,000 workers were in this
industry. Last year's 138.000 employees reflected some soft spots in the
economy as a whole in 1967. but the upward trend was not disturbed.
While exports have not been a very significant factor in the consumer
electronic products market, never in recent years accounting for as
much as 2 percent of sales, nevertheless, the export market for con-
sumer products is growing. In 1965, some $40 million in export sales
were made, while in 1966, $46.2 million worth of U.S.-produced con-
sumer products went abroad. Last year exports totaled $46.6 million.
It is important to note that the U.S. component industry benefits from
this growing export market since it supplies most of the components
which go into these products.
Imports of consumer products in 1966 amounted to $385 million, up
from 1965 totals of $288 million. In 1967, imports were at $449 million.
While imports are presently 10 percent of consumer product factor
sales, a much greater ratio than the 3.1 percent comparable component-
imports~to-componentsa1es ratio, nevertheless, U.S. producers of con-
sumer electronic products oppose quotas on consumer product imports.
This stand is demonstrably sound and is in the best interests of the
American consumer, the consumer products producers and the compo-
nents producers.
PAGENO="0047"
3483
IMPORTS SERVE A USEFUL FUNCTION
Given a number and variety of consumer electronic products which
the American consumer desires and the many combination products
which he demands, it is unlikely that any U.S. manufacturer will make
all of these products. Thus, if a full line of consumer electronic prod-
ucts is to be offered to the American consumer by a U.S. producer, he
must obtain from other sources products which he does not produce.
He will concentrate his efforts in producing those products which he
can make efficiently in volume, thus enabling him to offer to the con-
sumer products whose quality and price reflect these economic advan-
tages. In some instances the only outside source for him for products
which he does not make may be a foreign source. The products he ac-
quires from such source generally will be manufactured to his stand-
ards for sale under his brand name.
Besides expecting a wide variety of consumer electronic products,
the American consumer is very price conscious. Thus, imported pocket-
size transistor radios sell like proverbial "hot cakes" because they are
priced below $10; they would not sell in any such quantities at prices
of $15 or $20. The same is true of small-size black-and-white television
receivers and low-priced tape recorders. If all of these products were
made in the United States, their prices would be significantly higher
than present levels and such higher prices would result in lower sales.
We have prepared two tables which tell the story about prices and
their relevance to the size of the U.S. market for consumer electronic
products.
TABLE I-U.S. FACTORY SALES, ALL CONSUMER ELECTRONIC PRODUCTS AND MOST POPULAR PRODUCTS
(INCLUDING AVERAGE UNIT FACTORY PRICE)
[Quantity (1,000 units); value ($1,000)J
Class of product
1963
1964
1965
1966
All products
Radios:
$2,661,469
$2,842,608
$3,620,129
`$3,714,195
Value
Quantity
Average unitvalue
$520, 034
18,155
$28
$554, 956
18,888
$29
$673, 807
23,400
$29
$728, 127
24,537
$30
TV receivers:
Value
Quantity
Average unit value
Other:
$1,067,061
7,734
$138
$1,271,206
8,713
$146
$1,685,479
9,889
$170
$2,278,884
11,174
$204
Phonographs and record players:
Value
Quantity
Average unit value
$174,089
3,818
$45
$146,371
2,832
$52
$201,286
4, 177
$48
$217,508
4,827
$45
Tape recorders:
Value
Quantity
Average unit value
Other: Value
$103, 924
2,291
$45
$8,819
$88, 382
1,329
$66
$8,351
$106, 580
1,787
$59
$8,889
$123, 344
1,953
$63
$12,740
`1966 "All products" total does not include miscellaneous products of approximately $150,000,000. Data not available.
Source: Current Industrial Reports, 1964, 1965, and 1966, Bureau of the Census, U.S. Department of Commerce.
PAGENO="0048"
3484
TABLE I I-IMPORTS, CONSUMER ELECTRONIC PRODUCTS AND~MOST~POPULAR PRODUCTS, INCLUDING AVERAGE
UNIT VALUE
(Quantity (1,000 units);value ($1,000)(
Class of product
1964
1965
1966
1967
Radios:
Value
Units
Average unit value
TV receivers:
$92,965
13, 600
6. 85
$125,017
19, 351
6. 45
$144,107
25, 129
5. 75
$172,135
24, 200
7. 11
Value
Units
Average unit value
Phonographs:
Value
Units
Average unitvalue
Tape recorders:
Value
Units
Average unit value
39, 225
715
54. 86
20,549
2,357
8.71
46, 335
3, 266
14. 18
59, 586
1,048
56. 85
31,129
3,022
10.30
49, 689
2, 847
17. 45
115, 733
1,524
75. 94
47,050
4,090
11.50
(1)
(1)
(`)
125, 581
1,613
77. 85
30,700
2,819
10.89
(1)
(1)
(1)
1 Not available.
Source: "U.S. Imports of MerchandisefoçConsumption," reports FT 125 and 135,~Bureau of Census, Department of
Commerce.
Table I reflects U.S. factor sales of all consumer electronic products
and of the most popular products embraced by this class.
Table II reflects imports of all consumer electronic products and of
the most popular products included in this class.
The committee will note that in each table in addition to total units
and total value, we have given an average unit value for each of the
named consumer products. Thus, the average unit value of U.S.-
produced radios in 1966 was $30. On the other hand, the average unit
value of imported radios that year was $6.60. The comparable figures
on color and black-and-white television receivers are $204 for U.S.-
produced products and $78.39 for imported products. Phonographs
of U.S.-make average $45 per unit, of foreign-make $10.61.
I submit, Mr. Chairman, that these figures show that what we con-
sumer product manufacturers make and sell in the United States and
what we buy abroad and sell here are really different products. The
availability of the lower priced foreign products complements what
we make here. There is no displacement.
Imports, therefore, are primarily responsible for the large volume
sales in these basic consumer electronic articles. It is also true that
such volume sales of these products bearing the U.S. manufacturer's
trade name materially assist the manufacturer in promoting sales of
his domestically produced articles.
These imports permit many persons in the United States to pur-
chase entertainment, educational, and informational pieces of elec-
tronic equipment which, in the absence of lower priced imports they
would be unable to buy. If these imports were curtailed, no one would
gain and these consumers would lose.
RETALIATION AGAINST U.S. ELECTRONICS EXPORTS MAY RESULT
Annual U.S. exports of electronics articles are presently near the $2
billion mark. If the United States takes restrictive action against im-
ports of electronic components and products this extremely important
PAGENO="0049"
3485
outlet for U.S.-made products and components will be in jeopardy.
For example, while Japan and Hong Kong supply substantial per-
centages of the electronics products sold to the United States, they
are also important customers for exports of electronic products, in-
cluding electronic components, from the United States. Japan's im-
portance as a buyer of U.S.-produced electronic articles is shown by
the data in the following table.
Total imports into Japan originating in the United ~States
Article Percent
Digital computers 91. 9
Jukeboxes -. 94. 5
Integrated circuits 99. 6
Thermionic valves and tubes 76. 4
Silicon transistors 72. 4
Parts of radio-navigational aid, radar, or radio remote control apparatus_ 83. 9
insulated flexible cord 69. 7
Oscilloscopes 85. 7
VHF transmission and reception apparatus 90. 0
Recording tape and wire 77. 7
Electrical analysis apparatus 80. 9
Source: Japan Ministry of Finance; data are for 1966.
Hong Kong, the principal supplier of transistors and other semi-
conductor devices to the United States in 1966, was also the chief im-
porter of U.S.-produced semiconductor parts, having purchased
~13,1O0,OO0 or 43 percent of total U.S. exports.
In sum, U.S. international trade in electronic products is a true two-
way street and the United States enjoys a bigger share of this ex-
change, as these statistics and total favorable balance of trade in
electronic articles-$945 million-will show. Any action which would
reduce or eliminate this advantage would be adverse to the interest of
all concerned.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman, for giving us this opportunity to appear
here today.
The CHAIRMAN. We thank you, Mr. Fezell and Mr. Hoffman and
Mr. McCauley, for coming to the committee this morning.
Are there any questions of these gentlemen?
Mr. BYRNES. Just one, Mr. Chairman.
The CHAIRMAN. Mr. Byrnes.
Mr. BYRNES. On page 12, Mr. Fezell, you provide a table of the per-
centage of imports of certain articles into Japan originating in the
United States. Would you submit for the record at your convenience
the dollar amount that is involved here?
Percentages don't always mean very much. If you are only export-
ing one item the percentage may be 100 percent.
Mr. FEZELL. Sir, we will be happy to do so.
(The following information was received by the committee:)
The dollar amount of the exports in question is approximately $43 million.
Mr. SCI-INEEBELI. Mr. Chairman.
The CIIAIRMAN. Yes, Mr. Schneebeli.
Mr. SOHNEEBELI. Mr. Fezell, on page 4 you list some of the com-
panies in the electronics industry and I don't notice any such well
known names as GE, and Westinghouse, and RCA and Sylvania.
Aren't they in your group?
95-159----6S-pt. 8-4
PAGENO="0050"
3486
Mr. FEZELL. The people that we mentioned here were the com-
ponents manufacturers. Yes; they are. Others are in the components
industry. GE I am sure is involved. They are also in the consumer
electronics business.
Mr. SCHNEEBELI. They are the four leading companies in the
public's mind, aren't they? I was wondering why you omitted the
names of them.
Mr. FEZELL. Here is the list. Would you like me to read the list
of the ones that support our action?
Mr. SCHNEEBELI. Yes.
Mr. FEZELL. Admiral Corp.; Ampex Corp.; Arvin Industries, Inc.;
Bulova Watch Co., Inc.; General Electric Co.; Harmon Kardon, Inc.;
Hoffman Electronics; KLH Research & Development Corp.; Singer;
the Magnavox Co.; Motorola, Inc.; Minnesota Mining & Manufactur-
ing Co.; Olympic Radio & Television (Division of Lear Siegler, Inc.);
Packard Bell; Philco-Ford Corp.; Pilot Radio-Television Corp.;
Symphonic Electronic Corp.; Warwich Electronics, Inc.; Waters
Conley Co.; and Westinghouse Electric Corp.
And the nonmembers of the ETA-Consumer Products Division,
people that do not belong to our association but who support us here
are Curtiss Mathis Television, Emerson Radio & Phonograph Corp.,
Television Manufacturing of America, Inc. (Muntz TV), and that's it.
Mr. SOHNEEBELI. How about RCA and Sylvania?
Mr. FEZELL. RCA abstained. They did not take a side either way.
Mr. SCHNEEBELI. Sylvania?
Mr. FEZELL. Sylvania is for quotas.
Mr. SGHNEEBELI. For what?
Mr. FEZELL. They are for quotas. They are against our stand. They
are not with us on this.
Mr. SCHNEEBELI. Thank you very much.
The CHAIRMAN. Mr. Collier.
Mr. COLLIER. Mr. Fezell, the table on page 12 shows the percentage
of total imports into Japan originating in the United States. Permit
me to say in all kindness that table doesn't mean too much unless it
were translated into actual dollars of imports from the United States.
Percentage of the total imports into Japan is rather insignificant
when we speak in terms of the impact upon our economy. Hence
what does this really amount to in dollars?
Mr. FEZELL. Sir, we have been requested to make available to the
committee the information on dollars. I do not have those here.
Mr. COLLIER. Isn't it true that Japan today has absolute prohibi-
tions on certain types of U.S. electronic equipment?
Mr. FEZELL. Sir, I cannot answer that. I do not know that that is
not so, but to my knowledge I know of no such restrictions.
Mr. COLLIER. It was a leading question because the answer is "Yes,"
and not only that; in the area of electronic components, Japan today
is importing electronic components because it is temporarily economi-
cally expedient to do so.
If this were not a fact and we accordingly look into the future to
see what is involved, let's look at the Texas Instruments-Sony pro-
posal wherein a stipulation provides for Texa.s Instruments to turn
over to the Japanese technical information and their wherewithall in
electronic component production; isn't that true ~
PAGENO="0051"
3487
Mr. FEZELL. I believe that is correct, sir.
Mr. COLLIER. Isn't it obvious then that if this is the situation at
some given time in the very near future those components which the
Japanese are currently importing will no longer have to be imported?
rllhe reason for their importation is an obvious one.
Mr. FEZELL. I am sure that that is a possibility. I can't say that it
will happen. There is always the possibility. I don't know the nature
of the manufacturing type of equipment that Texas Instruments in-
tends to build over there. That happens to be a little out of my area.
Mr. COLLIER. Do you have figures on what percentage of the world
market the United States 20 years ago supplied in table model and
transistor radios and what percentage to which it has shrunk in 1967?
Mr. FEZELL. What percentage we had 20 years ago and what it has
shrunk to?
Mr. COLLIER. A 20-year period.
Mr. HOFFMAN. Congressman, 20 years ago we accounted for almost
the total production; you are speaking about radios as a category
only?
Mr. COLLIER. Table model and transistors, the small type.
Mr. HOFFMAN. Right. The U.S. production today would be about 25,
27 percent.
Mr. COLLIER. It was 70 percent at that time; was it not?
Mr. HOFFMAN. It was even higher than that, Congressman. You re-
ferred to 20 years ago.
Mr. COLLIER. I am talking about the completed article.
Mr. HOFFMAN. Yes; 20 years ago it would have been in excess of
that.
Mr. COLLIER. What percentage of that market does Japan now have,
the world market?
Mr. HOFFMAN. It would be broken down between Japan and Hong
Kong. They now have a production figure of I think in the mid 20
millions.
Mr. COLLIER. What part of the U.S. domestic market did we have
20 years ago? What part of it have we retained, and what part of
that domestic market does Japan have now?
I believe these are totally realistic questions because the figures spell
out the situation.
Mr. FEZELL. Sir, let us double check to make sure we give you the
right numbers.
Mr. COLLIER. OK. I think we ought to have it.
Mr. HOFFMAN. Congressman, I can read it to you right now: The
1967 factory sales of TJ.S.-produced home radios, 8,105,000 units; im-
ports carrying a domestic label 4,463,000; imports foreign labels 19,-
116,000; total imports 23,579,000. The total U.S. home radio market
31,684,000. On the other question you asked me of the 19 million, I
would think a substantial part of that 19 million would be Hong
Kong.
Then the balance would be Japanese.
On the very inexpensive pocket size "cigarette pack" radios, they
have the substantial part.
Now, in Japan they have the higher end of the market. They have
more of the better quality AM and AM-FM radios in this category.
PAGENO="0052"
3488
Mr. COLLIER. Just one further question. Do you think it would be
proper for the U.S. electronic industries to propose exactly the same
nontariff barriers that are presently imposed by the Japanese? Do
you see anything wrong with this type of reciprocity?
Mr. FEZELL. Sir, would you repeat that. I am sorry. I didn't get
the first part.
Mr. COLLIER. I say do you see anything wrong with the United
States imposing the same type of nontariff barriers on imports into
this country of electronic equipment that are presently imposed on
the imports of electronic equipment into Japan?
Is there anything wrong with this type of reciprocity? In other
words, if we are going to have trade we merely establish the same
barriers, tariff and otherwise.
Mr. MCCAULEY. Sir, I would like to answer that if I may. That is
one way of course of doing it. But I think that the better way would
be to try to get the Japanese to relax their barriers.
Mr. COLLIER. Yes, but what happens in the interim? We talk about
reprisals. It seems to me that reprisals for whatever reason are al-
ready existent.
Mr. MCCAULEY. The Japanese may have the wrong reasons for put-
ting on artificial restrictions on U.S. trade, that is true. It is true that
that may be so, but right now the industry we are talking about today
is an industry that enjoys a favorable trade balance of $945 million,
with total exports of $1.8 billion. It seems to me, in a give and take
proposition, if we were to respond to the Japanese and they in turn
responded and you had a charge and countercharge or a stroke and
counterstroke development, then we, having the greatest share of the
trade, would suffer.
Mr. COLLIER. Well, of course share of the trade, does it not develop
from your equipment that cannot be-
Mr. MCCAULEY. Yes, sir; these are U.S.-rnade products that are
made by the electronic industries. They support jobs. They generate
profits and these companies are doing business around the world. It is
well, I think, to point out here that the industry you have before you
this morning differs in marked respect from the several other indus-
tries that have appeared before you prior to today and probably after
today.
Mr. COLLIER. Of course you are mixing apples with oranges because
you are talking about the broad figures. The figures dealing just with
the import and export of electronic equipment between the United
States and Japan would be quite significant.
Mr. MCCAULEY. That is true.
Mr. COLLIER. So stay with the division before us.
Mr. MCCAULEY. That is very true, but I would say that in the GATT
complex of nations, where we are dealing with a set of trade rules
that apply across the board, if one were to try to operate against
Japanese products only this would be a significant departure, it would
seem to me, from the historic MFN approach and we would probably
get in a lot of trouble with other people.
I would just guess that.
Mr. COLLIER. Let's generalize. In 1967, going across the whole spec-
trum, we imported more than $3 billion in goods and commodities
from Japan while exporting slightly more than $2.5 billion.
PAGENO="0053"
3489
That to me doesn't represent a very favorable trade balance.
Mr. MCCAULEY. No, I agree with you; it does not.
Mr. COLLIER. We have had the same experience in the last 2 years
with West Germany, as you are well aware. On the one hand we are
told, "Don't break this down by nations because we are negotiating
on a wide scale." Then in the next instant we are told, "Well, now, we
can't afford to do this. 1Ne have to deal with this one industry, or this
one commodity, or class of commodities and we have to deal with this
within the country."
As of right now I get the impression that we are supposed to deal
just singularly with certain nations and certain commodities on the
one hand, forgetting the rest, and yet the most ardent proponents of
extending the trade negotiations in the 1962 act say we can't look at
it in this vein.
We have to look at the whole spectrum.
That is all I have, Mr. Chairman.
The CHAIRMAN. Any further questions? Mr. Conable.
Mr. CONABLE. Mr. Fezell, do you have any figures on what the
average hourly wage in the electronics industry is in Japan or in Hong
Kong?
Mr. MCCAULEY. We don't have those figures right now, sir.
Mr. CONABLE. Do you know what the average hourly wage in the
electronics industry is in this country?
Mr. FEZELL. I believe, sir, it will be somewhere around $2.28. It
varies in various parts of the country obviously, but it will be from
around $2.28 to around $2.68, somewhere in that area.
Mr. CONABLE. Is the consumer electronics industry unique in its
trade relationships or are there other industries that have the same
sort of pattern?
Mr. FEZELL. Al, I think maybe you better answer that. I am not
too familiar with that area.
Mr. MCCAULEY. I think the basic thrust of what Mr. Fezell said
was this; that a good part of the imports that come into the United
States of the consumer electronics product variety are not products
that displace articles that are made in the United States. They com-
plement the line of products that are made by the several manu-
facturers in the United States.
Now, I wouldn't be a bit surprised if this were not true in some
other industries.
For example, I could assume that if we have a perfume industry
in the United States or a toilet water industry in the United States
it may very well be that imports of those products find their own mar-
ket. They find their own level in this country. They do not displace U.S.
production. They complement it.
One of the important complementary factors in this particular
industry is the fact that where a manufacturer brings in under his own
brand name a low-priced transistor radio he has the benefit of a prod-
uct that bears his name. He has the benefit of a product that he cannot
make here and sell at that price. He gets an extremely broad market
base and he hopes to capture a number of customers who at one point,
as they develop in their economic status, will be buying the more
sophisticated, more expensive products that that manufacturer makes.
PAGENO="0054"
3490
Mr. CONABLE. Well, I take it that you don't intend to extend the
impact of your testimony beyond your own particular industry. Is
that correct?
Mr. MCCAULEY. We really can't, except, as I say, I wouldn't be a
bit surprised that in other industries you have pretty much the same
kind of situation and that is where imports per se, if you take the
totality of imports, that the imports do not head on, in the market-
place, displace a domestic made product.
I would assume there are other cases.
Mr. CONABLE. Has your industry taken any position on the overall
administration bill?
Mr. MCCAULEY. We have not, sir.
Mr. C0NABLE. Do you have any intention of doing so?
Mr. MCCAULEY. We have not really taken a position on it.
Mr. CONABLE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
The CHAIRMAN. Any further questions?
Mr. BYRNES. Mr. Chairman, just one.
The CHAIRMAN. Mr. Byrnes.
Mr. BYRNES. Referring to the table that appears on page 3, you
have a breakdown of the main items that constitute the exports and
the imports of the electronic industries. Your table is broken down
into electronic industries, electronic components, and consumer elec-
tronic products.
I am particularly interested in the main items encompassed in the
exports and the imports of this total.
Mr. MCCAULEY. `We have a table here that runs rather lengthily. I
could insert this in the record and read a few excerpts from it if that
is all right with you.
Mr. BYRNES. `What would these figures look like if we pulled out
computers. I assume that is under electronic industries.
Mr. MCCAULEY. Yes; it is, sir. I can give you that.
Mr. BYRNES. `We do export a considerable amount of our computers
to Western Europe; don't we?
Mr. MCCAULEY. Yes, sir; we do.
Mr. BYRNES. And there is none of that going to Japan as such that
is significant; is there'?
Mr. MCCAULEY. I don't know that, Mr. Byrnes. I do have the totals
on computers.
Mr. BYRNES. I was under the impression that Japan restricted im-
ports of computers because they are attempting to get their own in-
dustry established. They were also placing obstacles in the way of
American computer producers who wanted to establish plants in
Japan in order to have access to at least part of the market.
Mr. MCCAULEY. There were press reports about the Sony-Texas
Instruments arrangement.
Mr. BYRNES. Yes. As I understand it, they have been negotiating
to try to put a plant into Japan as a method of getting their know-
how into Japan, using Japanese labor.
Mr. MCCAULEY. But I believe that will be pursuant to a license
agreement if I am not mistaken.
Mr. BYRNES. That is what I am saying. It is a complete restriction.
They decide whether or not you can establish a plant to say nothing
of whether you can export something to Japan.
PAGENO="0055"
3491
Mr. MCCAULEY. I agree.
Mr. BYRNES. I was really interested in what the pictures would
look like if you took out this large item of computer exports. It is a
big export industry.
Mr. MCCAULEY. I have the computer figure here. For 1967 our
U.S. exports of computers, which would include digital colliputers,
components for computers, and parts and accessories, were $432,518,-
000, a little less than a fourth of total exports.
It may help the record if I read these major companies.
Mr. BYliNES. All right, go ahead. As far as I am concerned it is
sufficient for me if the totals are in the record, b~~t go ahead.
Mr. MCCAULEY. On broadcast radio and television transmitters
and that type of equipment our exports were $77.8 million. Coinmumca-
tions equipment, which is the telephone variety, radio communica-
tions systems, and whatnot, our exports were $163.9 million. Computers
I gave you, $432.5 million.
Mr. BYliNES. Does that include the input and output type?
Mr. MCCAULEY. On the receiving?
Mr. BYliNES. Yes. That is all right. Go ahead. I'm sorry for
interrupting.
Mr. MCCAULEY. Detection and navigation equipment, our exports
were $144.7 million. Testing and measuring instruments, oscilloscopes
and articles such as that, our exports were $339 million and under
miscellaneous other we had $83.2 million.
Then in components, which break down into tubes, semiconductors,
pa.rts, and miscellaneous, our exports were $486.8 million as we stated
in the statement.
Mr. BYliNES. Would the generalization be correct that the greater
portion of these go to Western Europe?
Mr. MCCAULEY. I think so. I think that would be true.
Mr. BYRNES. Very little goes to Japan or any area such as that?
Mr MCCAULEY. I would think so.
Mr. BYliNES. Thank you very much.
The CHAIRMAN. Thank you, gentlemen, very much for coming to
the committee and bringing to us your testimony.
Mr. FEZELL. Thank you, sir.
(The following supplemental statement was received by the
committee:)
SUPPLEMENTAL STATEMENT OF CONSUMER PRODUCTS DIvIsIoN OF THE ELECTRONIC
INDUSTRIES ASSOCIATION
A CASE FOR QUOTAS ON IMPORTS OF CONSUMER ELECTRONIC ARTICLES HAS NOT BEEN
MADE
Speaking to the Committee on Ways and Means in behalf of some U.S. manu-
facturers of electronic parts and components, the Parts Division of the Electronic
Industries Association (ETA) urged legislation imposing quotas on imports of
consumer electronic products and parts.1 The Consumer Products Division of
ETA, which testified on June 25 before the Ways and Means Committee in
1 Those P:~ electronic parts and components manufacturers who do not agree with the
Parts Division's request for quota legislation have notified the Committee on `Ways and
Means of this fact. The Distributor Products Division of EIA and the American Loudspeaker
Manufacturers Association are joined in tile Parts Division statement.
PAGENO="0056"
3492
opposition to import quotas on electronic articles, has analyzed the presen-
tation of the Parts Division and concludes that a case for quotas on imports of
consumer electronic products and parts has not been made.
QUOTAS SHOULD NOT BE IMPOSED WHERE THERE IS NO IMPORT-CAUSED SERIOUS
INJURY TO THE DOMESTIC INDUSTRY CONCERNED
The accepted standard to determine whether quotas on imports should be
considered is-
where the objective data pertaining to domestic production and sales,
exports and imports show that an industry is being seriously injured by im-
ports . . ." (Consumer Products Division's Statement.)
When data are "selected", "computed" or otherwise "tailored", they are not
objective. And not one iota of objectivity is added to such data by clothing them
in travelogue rhetoric.
In our statement to the Committee on Ways and Means we presented the objec-
tive data relevant here. For convenient reference we restate these data here:
1965
1966
1967
Electronic industries:
Sales
Exports
Imports
Balance of trade
Exports as percent of sales
Imports as percent of sales
Electronic components:
Sales -
Exports
Imports
Balance of trade
Exports as percent of soles
Imports as percent of sales
Consumer electronic products:
Sales
Exports
Imports
Balance of trade
Exports as percent of sales
Imports as percent of sales
$17, 507, 000, 000
$1, 155, 432, 000
$506, 770, 000
+1648, 662, 000
6. 6
2. 8
$4, 695, 000, 000
$328,550,000
$111,380,000
+1217, 170, 000
7. 0
2. 3
$3, 641, 000, 000
$40, 257, 000
$287,919,000
-$247, 662, 000
1. 1
7.9
$20, 606, 000, 000
$1, 446,736, 000
$744, 767, 000
+1701,969, 000
7. 0
3. 6
$5, 709, 000, 000
$440,436,000
$174,106,000
+1266,330,000
7. 7
3. 0
$4, 493, 000, 000
$46,256, 000
$305,004,000
-1338, 748, 000
1.0
8.5
$22, 132, 000, 000
$1, 775, 626, 000
$830, 231, 000
+$945, 395, 000
8. 0
3. 7
$5, 486, 000, 000
$486,801,000
$174,990, 000
-f-$311, 811, 000
8. 8
3. 1
$4, 324, 000, 000
$46, 609, 000
$449,927,000
-$403, 318, 000
1. 0
10.3
Source: The table was prepared from data contained in the Electronic Industries Yearbook, 1968, prepared by the
Marketing Services Department of EIA.
These data are taken unadorned, unmodified, and unqualified from the official
Electronic Industries Association source. We have not refined them. We have
not selected some data and omitted others. We have not otherwise offered an
incomplete picture. We have presented all of the relevant data in a "let-the-chips-
fall-where-they-may" approach.
With this as prologue, we turn now to an analysis of the Parts Division's ar-
gument, and the data they proffer in support thereof, that quotas are needed on
imports of consumer electronic products and parts in order to protect U.S. manu-
facturers of electronic parts from series injury due to imports.
THE ARGUMENT OF THE PARTS DIVISION IS BASICALLY ERRONEOUS
The Parts Division argues that since the only imported articles which it wants
regulated are consumer electronic products and components thereof, analysis
of the merits of this request must be restricted to domestic sales, exports and
imports of this narrow class of articles. They insist that those charged with
analyzing their claim of import-caused serious injury must not take into ac-
count U.S.-produced parts and components which are sold domestically or which
are exported for use in making non-consumer electronic products.
Thus, the Parts Division opens its argument by stating that there is
no single `industry' known as the electronic industry. Instead, a group
of distinct industries is referred to as the `electronic industries' because the
articles they manufacture have one thing in common-the utilization of an elec-
tronic circuit."
PAGENO="0057"
3493
We agree that there are a number of separate industries embraced by the
term "electronic industries". Thus, there is a consumer electronic products in-
dustry, a defense electronics products industry, and so forth, and to a large ex-
tent the products produced by one such electronic industry are commercially
different from the products produced by the other electronic industries.
But all of the electronic industries have one thing in common: in producing
the products they make they need electronic parts and components. And they
obtain these needed parts and components from the U.S. producers of such parts
and components.
The Parts Division does not disagree with the fundamental fact that the
market served by U.S. producers of electronic parts and components embraces
the entire output of all of the electronic industries. As they so succinctly state
it-
"Electronic parts and components are the building blocks from which finished
electronic products.. . are assembled."
Since electronic parts and components are indeed the building blocks from
which all finished electronic products are assembled, then the economic state of
the U.S. electronic parts and components industry can only be assessed by
analyzing the overall condition of the total electronic industries of the United
States. Just as the Parts Division bases its claim for quota relief on its interest
in the fortunes of the consumer electronic industry, it has an equally important
interest in the defense, space, and industrial electronic industries. It is some-
what disingenuous for the Parts Division to argue that only their interest in
consumer products and components is relevant here. We submit that their entire
interest-the totality of electronic industries-is the focal point for the economic
analysis needed in assessing their claim of serious injury.
The steel industry analog used by the Parts Division is quite apt here, though
their use of it is erroneous. Thus, they argue that when one analyzes import
impact on the steel industry, he does not sweep: ". . . into the data every type
of article made in this country which contains steel."
But this is precisely what is done. Any economic assessment of the impact
of imports on the U.S. steel industry starts with an analysis of the output of
U.S. steel mills in toto. Whether such steel is sold by the U.S. steel mills to the
auto industry, to the ship-building industry, to one or more of the electronic
industries or to a foreign buyer is beside the point. The pertinent consideration
is the production of steel-and all steel production is taken into account at the
threshold of the economic analytical process.
Thus, we accept the steel industry analog offered by the Parts Division. And
just as total U.S. steel mill output is counted in any assessment of the impact of
imports on the U.S. producers of steel, so also must the total output of the U.S.
electronic parts and components industry be counted in any assessment of the
impact of imports on that industry.
The relevant U.S. industry here, therefore, is the U.S. industry producing
electronic parts and components. It is the economic status of this industry-
measured by its total market, domestic and foreign-which is in issue.
THE RELEVANT OBJECTIVE DATA SHOW THAT THE U.S. ELECTRONIC PARTS AND
COMPONENTS INDUSTRY NEEDS NO IMPORT QUOTA PROTECTION
The electronic industries of the United States, the users of the parts and com-
ponents made by the U.S. manufacturers of such articles, sold some $22.1 billion
in goods last year and industry forecasts point to sales of over $23 billion this
year. The 1967 record level topped 1966's performance by some $1.5 billion and
was almost $5 billion above 1965 sales.
These industries did equally well on the export side. Exports of $1.15 billion
in 1965 increased in 1966 to $1.44 billion. Last year a record $1.77 billion of
U.S-produced electronic articles were sold to foreign buyers.
The U.S. producers of parts and components participated fully in these ever-
increasing domestic and foreign sales of electronic products. Thus, factory sales
of electronic parts and components totalled $5.48 billion in 1967, up 18 percent
over 1965 sales of $4.69 billion. The industry forecasts a rise in sales in 1968.
Exports of components climbed steadily from $328 million in 1965 to $440 million
in 1966 to a high of $486 million last year. U.S. electronic parts and components
producers enjoyed a favorable balance of trade in parts and components alone
of $217 million in 1965, $266 million in 1966, and a record $312 million last year.
These data do not show any injury whatsoever, much less the serious injury
which must precede consideration of import quota protection. The electronic
PAGENO="0058"
3494
industries as a whole, and the parts and components industry in particular, are
viable, prosperous industries in need of no protection from imports.
Notwithstanding this, the Parts Division asserts a claim of import-caused
injury and offers its own data to show such injury. We turn now to an analysis
of their data.
(a) Units versus value
As previously indicated, the Parts Division asserts that the only relevant
data are those relating to domestic sales, exports and imports of consumer
electronic products and parts and components for such products. We have al-
ready demonstrated the unrealistic nature of such assertidn.
But even in the narrow statistical vein in which they choose to force this
discussion, the Parts Division finds it is expedient and necessary to concoct new
rules for presenting what they consider are the relevant statistics. They argue
that import data, to be really meaningful, cannot be expressed in value figures;
one must look at imports in terms of units. Moreover, they say, each consumer
product imported must be counted twice: (1) As a product, (2) as a composite
of component parts. Thus, you first count an imported radio as one radio unit,
then you count the same radio as an import of so many receiving tubes, so many
capacitors, so many diodes, etc.
The objective of computing import data in terms of units rather than value
is quite transparent. A presentation in units is more impressive than one in
value. 2,377,600,000 units is more frightening than $24 million.
Counting finished products twice-as products and as composites of com-
ponents--is equally sticky. The resulting `inflation of the figures serves to permit
more flowery narrative than wouldotherwise be the case.
The Parts Division knows that in a hearing dealing with trade policy, the
relevant consideration is the balance of trade. They also know that trade balances
are always expressed in values, not in units. It is somewhat amateurish to go
against this accepted practice of discussing trade questions and to resort to un-
orthodox statistical plays in order to arrive at exaggerated results.2
While we have difficulty in corroborating some of the un:it figures used by the
Parts Division, especially those which purport to be conversion of imported
products into their components, the use of unit figures in analyzing imports of
consumer electronic products is particularly misleading. In stating imports in
terms of units, the Parts Division forcefully implies that each imported unit
displaces a U.S-produced unit. This is not so-and they know it
We demonstrated in our principal statement to the Committee that the bulk
of the consumer electronic products imported into the United States complement
what can be, and is, made in the United States. We showed that whereas the
average unit value of U.S-produced radios in 1966 was $30, the average unit
value of imported radios was $5.75. Similarly, a U.S.-produced television re-
ceiver in 1966 was valued at $204 per unit; imported receivers were valued at
$78.39 per unit. Phonographs of U.S. make averaged $45.00 per unit; of foreign
make $10.61.
We respectfully submit that these value spreads of 300, 400, or 500 percent
are conclusive evidence that the products in question are commercially different.
The imported radio or television receiver or phonograph does not displace a
ITS-made product. The import find their own market and serve thut market.
If the imports were not available, these markets would dry-up. U.S. products
would not fill the resulting void.
The premise for the unit-statistical approach is, therefore, wrong. The drama
of numbers running into the hundreds of millions and billions is dissipated.
Thus, even in the self-serving, narrow frame of reference which the Parts
Division has created here, their unit statistics prove nothing. They should be
relegated to the "useless" information file where they belong.
(b) Employment data.
The Parts Division points to the fact that whi1e the electronic comnonents
industry employed 396.300 workers in October 1966. employment in April of
1968 was 350,400. This they say represents a loss of 45,900 jobs.2
2 ~1oreover. the Parts Division's "unit" trade balance approach is glaringly deficient.
Nowher~ du they exnress TTS. exourts in terms of unit.
The Bureau of Labor Statistics employment figure for April 1005 is 375.100 (see tnl)le
on following page). This figure reduces time alleged "job loss" to 21.200.
PAGENO="0059"
3495
While Mr. Curtis in his colloquy with the spokesman for the Parts Division
set the record straight and demonstrated the error in this claim of a loss of jobs,
we are constrained to add just a few thoughts.
It is patently disingenuous for the Parts Division to take two average monthly
employment figures-one the highest average monthly employment in the history
of the parts industry and the other a lower monthly figure taken from a slack
Period-and compare the two and then conclude that some 45,900 workers lost
their jobs. It would have been equally wrong for us to have taken the employ-
ment figures for April of 1964 and April of 1966 to show a gain in jobs of 102,900.
The only relevant employment data here are all of the data, not data selected
by the Parts Division or by us. Here are those data:
EMPLOYMENT STATISTI Cs: ELECTRON IC COMPON ENTS INDUSTRY
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
Annual average
January
February
March
264. 8
307. 1
381. 5
360. 6
(1)
259.8
258.3
258.8
280.5
283.3
286.1
351.9
360.9
367.9
393.2
385.8
378.0
352.4
352.7
374.4
April
May
June
258. 3
259.4
260. 1
290. 7
294.6
301.7
374. 3
378.3
387.3
365. 3
354.9
344.4
2 375. 1
2376.0
July
257.9
303.9
384.1
342.4
August
264.4
311.5
392.2
351.5
September
270.2
319.1
392.3
351.8
October
274. 2
330. 1
396. 3
353. 3
November
277.6
338.3
395.9
352.6
December
279.0
344.8
395.9
354.2
Not available.
2 Preliminary.
Sources: Bulletin No. 1312-4 and `Employment and Earnings and Monthly Reports on Labor Force," Bureau of Labor
Statistics, Department of Labor.
While these data, as all such figures, show some peaks and valleys, it cannot
be disputed that employment in the electronic components industry is trending
upwards. Employment this year is picking up at a good pace and no doubt 1968
will at least equal and may even top, record 1966 employment.
We submit that these objective employment data in full are the only relevant
figures. As with so many other statistical series, selectivity distorts the picture
and can be very misleading.
The employment data also attest to the sound economic status of the U.S.
electronic parts and components industry. Like the sales figures given previously,
they negate any claim of serious injury and support the rejection of a plea for
quota relief from imports.
IMPORT QUOTAS WILL HURT THE U.S. PRODUCERS OF CONSUMER ELECTRONIC
PRODUCTS
In our main presentation to the Committee on Ways and Means we demon-
strated the role imports play in the marketing of all consumer electronic prod-
ucts. We showed how the availability of imports materially assists in the mar-
keting of U.S.-produced articles by permitting the U.S. manufacturer of con-
sumer electronic products to offer a full line of products to the consumer.
The Parts Division attempts to lower our standing before the Committee on
Ways and Means by characterizing the members of Consumer Products Division
of ETA for whom we speak as "importers and some manufacturers of products
such as radios, televisions, tape recorders, and phonographs."
Of course any one who imports a product, even an American tourist who brings
back a box of Dutch chocolates, is an importer. To the extent that companies
w-hich are members of the Consumer Products Division import some of the
products they sell and some of the components they use, they are in that sense
"importers".
But to say that because these companies do import some of their products-
"They are the importers; we are the domestic producers" is an irresponsible
appeal to emotionalism. The companies the Parts Division classifies as "im-
porters" in its attempts to capitalize on the prejudically-oriented dichotomy
PAGENO="0060"
3496
between "importers" and "domestic producers", include such American com-
panies as Admiral, General Electric, Motorola, Magnavox, and Westinghouse,
to name just a few. That these companies are just as much American producers
as any of the companies for which the Parts Division speaks is patently obvious.
Collectively they employ hundreds of thousands of workers in the United States
in the production of billions of dollars worth of U.S.-made products. They need
no defense from any one as to their overwhelming standing as U.S. producers
of electronic articles.
The Parts Division accuses these "importers" of wanting "to protect their
investment in foreign plants" while the Parts Division "U.S. producers" want
"to protect [their] investment in American plants, and . . . the employment
which [their] U.S. investment has created."
The weakness of the merits of their case is thus sharply outlined by resort
to this type of shocking invective. Of course it is true that some of the member
companies in the Consumer Products Division have investments in foreign
plants and obviously they desire to protect these investments. Their interest
in protecting their foreign investments no doubt is matched by the interest of
some of the member companies of the Parts Division who also have extensive
investments abroad. We do not find it strange that these member companies
of the Parts Division should take this attitude toward their foreign holdings
and we are not prepared to label such an approach as "un-American".
But the member companies of the Consumer Products Division-some of
whom are named above-have far greater investments in the United States
which call for a greater protective attitude. This is so obvious as not to require
any listing of the billions of dollars of investment which our companies have
in United States plants and facilities. We know that the Committee on Ways
and Means fully appreciates that the companies who oppose the Parts Division's
request for quota restrictions on electronic articles are acting out of a reasoned
concern for their own U.S. interests and the interests of their U.S. workers.
CONCLUSION
We respectfully submit that there is no case for the imposition of quotas on
imports of consumer electronic products and parts and components.
ALFRED R. MCCAULEY, Special Counsel.
(The fo11owin~ letter and attachment were subsequently received
by the committee:)
GRAUBARD, MosKovITz & MCCAULEY,
Washington, D.C., June 27, 1968.
JOHN M. MARTIN, Esq.,
Chief Counsel, Committee on Ways and Means,
Longworth House Office Building, Washington, D.C.
DEAR MR. MARTIN: I am enclosing a memorandum of the Magnavox Company,
dated September 17, 1967, which opposes any move to remove the present tempo-
rary partial suspension of duty on imported color television picture tubes.
Because of developments at the hearing on June 25, 1968, we respectfully
request that the memorandum be inserted at the conclusion of Mr. George B.
Fezell's testimony on that date. For the record, the Consumer Products Division
of the Electronic Industries Association supports the Magnavox position as re-
flected in this memorandum.
Very truly yours,
ALFRED R. MCCAULEY,
Special Counsel to Consumer Products Division, Electronic Industries
Association.
MEMORANDUM OF THE MAGNAVOX Co. ON COLOR TELEVISION PICTURE TUBES
I. INTRODUCTION
The Tube Division of the Electronic Industries Association (ETA)1 and the
Imports Committee of that Division, under date of July 11, 1967, filed a joint
1 The Electronic Industries Association (EIA) is the national Industrial organization of
electronic manufacturers in the United States ETA is composed of a number of divisions,
one of which is the Tube Division. Another division of EIA is the Consumer Products Divi-
sion of which the Magnavox Company is a member.
It is important here to note that the Tube Division does not, Indeed caanot, speak for the
Electronic Industries Association; it speaks only for its own division.
PAGENO="0061"
3497
petition with the Committee on Ways and Means (hereinafter "Coniinittee")
which requests the Committee to-
"favorably consider and report a bill rescinding the unexpired portion of
the moratorium extended to August 31, 1969, on payment of the full import
duties applicable to imports of color television picture tubes previously
granted in Section 54(b) of the Tariff Schedules Technical Amendments
Act of 1965." (Petition, p. 1).
Simply stated, the petition asks Congress to repeal prematurely the present
temporary rate of duty on imports of color television picture tubes of 12 percent
ad valorem and to increase that rate to 30 percent ad valorem immediately.
In support of this requested immediate 150 percent increase in the current duty
on color t.v. picture tubes, petitioners allege that:
1. The reasons for the establishment by Congress of the present temporary
lower rate of duty on color t.c. picture tubes, if they ever existed, no longer exist;
2. The U.S. producers of color television picture tubes and the producers of
glass bulbs for such tubes are experiencing economic distress which is manifested
by the "idling of capacity" and by the necessary "laying off of large numbers
of workers";
3. Sales of color television receiving sets have failed to increase as expected
and, accordingly, existing domestic productive capacity is not being used and
there is "widespread reduction in production, reductions in hours worked by em-
ployees in tube plants, and job layoffs";
4. Imports of color television sets and of color television picture tubes "have
increased strongly". There has been an "upsurge" of imports of color television
sets early this year. Imports of color television picture tubes are on a "steep
rise" and are contributing to the market disruption which is "plaguing the
industry".
On July 28, 1967, The Magnavox Company advised2 the Committee on Ways
and Means that it opposes the action sought by his petition because of the serious
consequences such action would have on Magnavox' operations in the United
States. At that time Magnavox indicated that it had not had an opportunity to
analyze all of the assertions made in support of this petition but that it believed
that a review of all of the pertinent facts and their analysis would show that-
"the requested action is unwarranted and if taken will have a serious
adverse impact on this company and many others who are similarly situated."
Now that Magnavox has reviewed this matter in depth it can unqualifiedly
state that its preliminary conclusion concerning the merits of this petition is
sound and correct. It is abundantly clear, as will be demonstrated herein, that-
1. The reasons which led the Congress to provide a temporary rate of duty on
color t.v. picture tubes of 12 percent ad valorem are as valid today as they were
in 1965;
2. U.S. producers of color t.v. picture tubes and of glass bulbs for such tubes
are not experiencing any economic distress whatever;
3. While sales of color t.v. receiving sets thus far in 1967 have not increased
at the overly-optimistic rate expected by domestic television set makers such sales
are at very satisfactory levels now and all indications are that they will be at
new record levels in the months to come; and
4. Imports of color t. v. picture tubes (the only imported product involved
in this petition) have been, and will continue to be, at such small levels, abso-
lutely and relative to domestic production and sales (including sales for export)
as to constitute no significant factor in the U.S. market for color t. v. picture
tubes so far as U.S. producers of such tubes are concerned.
ir. THE IMPORTS IN QUESTION AND THE RELEVANT U.S. INDUSTRY
At the outset, the dialogue concerning this petition and the action it requests
must be brought into focus. The petitioners seek a recision of the present
temporary 12 percent ad valorem rate of duty on color t. v. picture tubes so that
imports of such tubes will immediately be assessed with a duty of 30 percent
ad valorem-i.e., they seek an increase in the present tariff of 150 percent.
While the Committee appreciates that the only facts relevant to this requested
action are those concerning imports and U.S. production and sales (including
sales for export) of color t. v. picture tubes, petitioners either do not under-
stand this primer consideration or they choose to ignore it in their zeal to
2 Letter to Hon. Wilbur D. Mills, Chairman, Committee on Ways and Means, from George
H. Fezell, vice president-sales manager of The Magnavox Co. 270 Park Ave. New
York, N.Y.
PAGENO="0062"
3498
"make a case" where none exists. Thus, they complain not only about imports
of color t. v. picture tubes, but also about imports of color television receiving
sets. In support of their requested 150 percent increase in the current duty on
color t. v. picture tubes, they cite instances of unfortunate worker lay-off actions
by U.S. companies which the public record shows, and which petitioners know-,
were based in large part either upon market conditions involving black-and-
white television sets or on considerations other than imports of color t. v. picture
tubes. They recite statistics which serve their purpose while they minimize or
fail to mention others w-hich bear more closely on the truth of the issue at hand.
Petitioners' submission is also confusing-apples and oranges" are indis-
criminately mixed or compared as suits the desired end-which the Committee
will appreciate makes analysis difficult. But at the outset, this mark of con-
fusion is itself significant. As is so with all "shot-gun" type approaches, peti-
tioners acknowledge by this tact that their case is weak and show their aware-
ness that success here depends largely upon diverting attention from the relevant
factors.
Since, as is previously indicated, the issue here is whether Congress should
increase the present duty on color t. v. picture tubes, attention must be paid at
the outlet to data concerning U.S. production, sales and imports of such tubes.
Also very relevant are the data pertaining to U.S. exports of color t. v. picture
tubes.
In 1906, U.S. factory sales of color t.v. tubes amounted to 5.6 million units
valued at $620 million while imports of such tubes in that year amounted to
79,657 units valued at $6,480,174.~ Thus, imports amounted to slightly more than
1 percent of U.S. factory sales-a classic (le minirnus situation.
Data for the January-May, 1967, period do not alter this picture. U.S. factory
sales in this period were 2,547,000 units valued at $267,435,000 while imports
were 62,000 units valued at $4,703,000.~ The slight increase in imports in this
period does not disturb the de minirnus character of imports-imports are still
entering at a rate of less than 2 percent of U.S. factory sales.
Thus, these basic relevant data militate against petitioners' claim for an im-
mediate 150 percent increase in the tariff on color t.v. picture tubes. Neither the
absolute figures on imports nor any upward trend one might read into them are
cause for concern by U.S. producers of color tv. picture tubes, much less a basis
of a claim of injury or threat thereof to the U.S. industry concerned. These basic
data show that the petitioners' fears are completely unfounded and their claim
for higher tariff protection is baseless.
Other very pertinent data-relating to U.S. exports of color t.v. picture tubes-
omitted by petitioners, not only buttress the conclusion one must draw from the
basic data, supra, but also demonstrate the incredible nature of petitioners move
to shut off the small number of color t.v. picture tubes being imported into the
United States.
In 1966, total U.S. exports of television picture tubes (both color and black-
and-white) amounted to 808,204 units valued at $15,978,402.~ While the official
U.S. statistics do not break this total down into its color and black-and-white
picture tube components, the U.S. industry reports that its black-and-w-hite t.v.
picture tube sales for export in 1966 amounted to 251,400 units.0 Thus, U.S. color
t.v. ~1cture tube exports in 1966 amounted to 556,804 units, or 68.8 percent of total
U.S. t.v. picture tube exports.7
8 Figures on factory sales from Electronic Industries Yearbook, 1967, p. 53 and import
figures from Import-Export Bulletin, December, 1966, p. 32, both prepared by Marketing
Services Department of ETA.
Electronic Trends, May 1967, prepared by Marketing Services Department, ETA, pp. 21
an~5~ Exports, Report FT-~1O, U.S. Department of Commerce, Schedule B Commodity
Number 7293010, December, 1966.
6 Electronic Industries Yearbook, 1967, Table 41, p. 51.
7 Committee will no doubt be surprised, and perhaps even disturbed, as is Magnavox,
by the implications reflected in the extremely low value-$15,978,402-reported by the
Department of Commerce on 1966 total t.v. picture tube exports of 808,204 units. Given
that of these exports some 69 percent, or 556,804 units, were color t.v. picture tubes, the
resulting average unit value per exported color t.v. picture tube is about $20.00 per tube.
Magnavox is offered color t.v. picture tubes by U.S. tube makers at the following prices:
Tube size Price
19-inch
21-inch 98
22-inch __ 118
25-inch 130
The simple arithmetic average of Magnavox' unit prices is $108.25 per color tv. picture
tube, or about S1/m times the average unit value of U.S. color t.v. picture tube 1966 exports.
PAGENO="0063"
3499
In the first seven months of 1967, total U.S. exports of t.v. picture tubes (both
color and black-and-white) amounted to 259,200 units valued at $8,530,492.8 No
industry figures on either color or black-and-white export sales are available, so
the components of this total figure cannot be identified with certainty. However,
if the 1966 ratio of color and black-and-white exports prevailed during January-
July, 1967, then some 178,840 color t.v. picture tubes have been exported thus far
this year.
It is to be regretted that an industry which enjoys such a healthy export
market, in absolute terms, as does the petitioners' industry here should request
that Congress shut-off imports of color t.v. picture tubes which cannot be more
than a mere annoyance to the petitioners. The petitioners' 1966 exports, as the
figures above show, were almost 7 times the volume of imports and 1967 figures
to date indicate that an equally high multiplier will prevail this year. In these
circumstances one can only imagine what the retort of this industry would be
if the host countries receiving American color t.v. picture tubes were to impose
tariffs which in effect prohibited such exports. As the Committee knows, a funda-
mental factor in trade analysis is the impact on U.S. exports which tariff action
on the part of the U.S. might have. What would it profit the domestic industry
producing color t.v. picture tubes if it were to gain the elimination from the U.S.
market of the small number of imports of foreign-produced color t.i-. picture
tubes and at the same time lose the lucrative markets it presently enjoys for
its tubes abroad? The answer is obvious. The present petition is short-sighted.
Indeed, if it is granted, it might provoke a "cure" much more painful to all con-
cerned than the alleged "illness".
In sum, the basic data show that the U.S. industry producing color tv. picture
tubes is not being, and indeed can not conceivably be, adversely affected by the
minimal quantities of color t.v. picture tubes being imported into the United
States. Imports are but a tiny fraction of U.S. sales. Equally important, they are
a small fraction of U.S. exports of color t.v. picture tubes.
Thus, if the domestic industry producing color t.v. picture tubes is in poor
straits, its condition cannot be laid, in whole or in part, at the door imports.
But the fact of the matter is that this industry is not in any economic distress;
it is a healthy industry, healthier than many other U.S. industries are today.
III. THE DOMESTIC INDTJSTRY CONcERNED-THE PRODUCERS OF COLOR TX. PICTURE
TUBES-IS NOT IN A DISTRESSED CONDITION
As previously indicated, petitioners have liberally sprinkled their submission
to the Committee with some of Webster's choicest adjectives and adverbs aimed
at convincing the Committee that the domestic producers of color t.v. tubes
are in dire circumstances due in substantial measure to imports of such tithes.
The industry is said to be experiencing economic "distress". It is alleged that
production and employment in the industry is "suffering" and that the domestic
market is in a state of "disruption".
While the all-important basic data concerning domestic sales, sales for export,
and imports, cited in the previous Section of this memorandum, belie this claim
of import-oriented distress, the facts are that this industry is not in any dis-
tressed circumstances whatsoever. Its component companies are doing very
well indeed, much better in fact than many other U.S. companies.
The U.S. producers of color tubes include such outstanding companies as
General Electric, the Radio Corporation of America (RCA), General Telephone
and Electronic's Sylvania Division and others who are equally prominent in
their own right.
The three named producers account for the majority of U.S. production of
color tv. picture tubes. Each of these producers is also a producer of color tv.
sets, i.e., each of them is an integrated color set manufacturer which consumes
a large part of its own tube production in the production of color sets.
While admittedly the recent earnings of the U.S. companies producing color
tv. picture tubes have fallen below 1966 record levels (a rather widespread
condition among U.S. companies as the tax-writing Committee on Ways and
Means well realizes) none of these companies can be classed as being in a state
of economic "distress". That this is true is attested to not only by objective
data such as those previously discussed but also by statements of these pro-
ducers concerning the state of their economic health.
8 Supplied by Department of Commerce from preliminary figures in part not as yet
published.
PAGENO="0064"
3500
Thus, General Electric told its shareholders recently that its "Consumer
Electronics Division realized the year's [1966] fastest growth among the Com-
pany's consumer goods businesses." It elaborated on this as follows:
Porta-Color TV, other portable TV sets . . . [and other consumer
electronic products] led the way.
"Sales of large color TV receivers were limited for the major part of
the year by a shortage of color tubes * * ~"
RCA recently told its shareholders that-
"The year 1966 was one of vigorous performance for the Radio Corpora-
tion of America . . . Sales and profits surpassed all previous records for the
fifth successive time and by a greater amount for a single year than ever
before.
* * * * * * *
Our sales and profit momentum is continuing strongly in the first
quarter of 1967." 10
Neither the contribution of color television set sales to RCA's 1966 perform-
ance nor the expectations regarding this market in 1967 were overlooked:
"The vastly increased manufacturing capacity of the color television in-
dustry is responsive to the mounting public demand for color...
"A $51-million expansion program was initiated in 1966 by the RCA Vic-
tor Home Instruments Division, most of it related to color. In addition, con-
struction was started on a new color television picture tube manufacturing
plant in Scranton, Pa., and a new plant in Puerto Rico to make electron
guns for color picture tubes. With our increased facilities in color and other
consumer products we expect to achieve a $1-billion level in total sales of all
home instruments in 1967.
We are confident that the long-range result will be a vigorous com-
puter business that may well contribute as substantially to RCA sales and
earnings in the 1970's as color television and other home instruments do
today." ~
General Telephone and Electronics told its shareholders that 1966 was "an
excellent year" and that there is evrey indication that in 1967 the "electronics"
industry "will continue to grow at a substantially faster rate than the economy
as a whole." 12 General Telephone and Electronics advised its shareholders that-
"Record sales were also achieved in color television sets [and] picture
tubes . . ." n
and reported that its Sylvania Division set "new records" in sales and earnings:
"Sales of Sylvania . . . Color Bright 85 picture tubes reached record levels
in 1966, and further expansion of manufacturing operations was undertaken
to meet heavy demand." 14
Without belaboring the point, the record shows that the U.S. companies which
produce color t.v. picture tubes are not faring badly at all. Certainly none of
them are in a depressed condition.
Thus, not only do the basic data preclude any finding of import-caused injury
to the U.S. industry producing color t.v. picture tubes but the facts also show
that this industry is not in any injured or depressed state. It is a healthy indus-
try, prospering at every turn. Certainly the imports here in question have no
effect on-indeed they cannot affect-this industry's economic well-being.
For these reasons, the petitioner's claim for an immediate, substantial tariff
increase on imports of color t.v. picture tubes must be rejected. Petitioners have
failed to show any reason why they need any tariff relief whatever, much less
the extraordinary relief they press for in their petition.
IV. THE COLOR TELEVISION RECEIVER INDUSTRY IS NOT A DEPRESSED INDUSTRY
Petitioners plead that the industry to which they must look to sell their color
t.v. picture tubes-the color t.v. receiver industry-is also depressed. Here again,
° 1966 Annual Report of the General Electric Company, p. 15. As an integrated color tv.
set producer, General Electric's color tv. picture tube production and sales would closely
parallel its color t.v. set production and sales. Thus, its bullish expressions about its color
tv. set market apply equally to its color t.v. picture tube market.
10 1966 Annual Report of the Radio Corporation of America, p. 3.
11 Ibid., pp. 4-5. RCA is also an integrated color t.v. set maker. See note 9, supra.
22 General Telephone and Electronics 1966 Annual Report, p. 3.
11Ibid.,p.5.
1'Ibid., p. 18. Sylvania is also an integrated color t.v. set maker. See Note 9, 8upra.
PAGENO="0065"
3501
a picture of "gloom and doom" is projected and the Committee is told that the
future of this industry is dark indeed.
At the outset, the petitioners claim that both the color t.v. picture tube industry
and the color t.v. receiving set industry have increased their respective productive
capacities far in excess of their requirements. They blame this development on
the fact that "sales of color television receiving sets have failed to increase at
the rate which the industry in 1965 expected would be the case." `~ Petitioners
view the claimed excess capacity with alarm and use this as their principal basis
for requesting the tariff increase on color t.v. picture tubes.
It is certainly true that to date in 1967 sales of color t.v. receiving sets have
not kept pace with the expectations of most observers as these hopes were ex-
pressed in mid-1966. At that time, the industry was witnessing an unprecedented
consumer demand for color receivers. Many set makers were unable to meet this
demand and, because they believed that this demand would continue unabated,
even increase, they took steps to increase their capacity to turn out color sets
so as not to be caught short in 1967 and subsequent years.
But the failure of 1967 color t.v. set sales thus far to keep pace with the hopes
of the industry is a far cry from proving that the industry is in a depressed state.
Indeed, color t.v. receiver sales in Jan.-May, 1967 reached 1.7 million units valued
at $707,531,000 16 a mathematical annual rate which matches 1966 sales of 4.7
million units.'7 But this first -part 1967 performance was reached in a period when
the U.S. economy as a whole was sluggish and when consumer spending was at a
critical low-point.
The second-half of 1967 promises to see some sigificant reversal of the first-half
for U.S. industry in general and U.S. color set producers in particular. Thus, a
report in the Weekly Television Digest of July 24, 1967 reflects this turn-around:
"There's been some sales lift, fairly good pace of dealer ordering, but mid-
summer color sales picture looks pretty much as you'd expect for any high-
ticket home entertainment product. Manufacturers are still confident of good
consumer buying beginning in Aug. or Sept.-but it hasn't started yet.
"Dealers are expressing confidence by beginning to stock for fall, but in
relatively conservative manner. Good news came last week in distributor-
to-dealer sales figures for holiday week ended July 7-up 26% from last
year's same week (see State of the Industry). It was first increase over
1966 in.6 weeks.
"`Business is pretty good but is isn't showing up in the numbers.' We've
heard this again & again in last few weeks. Probable explanation is that
Industry sales figures for last 4 weeks have included fewer than normal
RCA sets as result of strike which choked off production through July's
first week.
"RCA is now in production, although it's officially in vacation period.
Company encouraged employes to work through vacation, and quite a few
chose to, according to RCA Sales Corp. Pres. B. S. Durant. He told us RCA
has `shortage of merchandise right now.' He reiterated forecast of good fall,
saw 1967 sets being cleaned up in short order with `68-model prices holding
firm. He even mentioned possibility of price increases later in model year
if `significant cost premures' can't be designed out of sets.
"There were individual company reports of improved sales. Philco-Pord
reported June was best single sales month in its history, for all consumer
products, with color TV sales 238% ahead of June 1966, console phonos up
7%. Magnavox, too, said its June orders showed sharp upsurge, resulting in
significantly higher mid-year backlog than in 1966 . . . "(Page 9).
In sum, this is far from a depressed industry. Its present performance is keep-
ing pace with an unprecedented 1966 record (a development which no doubt is
the envy of other industries producing consumer goods) and signs indicate that
1967 will be another record year.
Notwithstanding the facts to the contrary, the petitioners insist that the color
t. v. set producing industry is in a poor state. To prove their point, the petitioners
have chosen a number of news reports which they have paraphrased and which
they offer to the Committee to support their claim. Thus, they submit the following
capsulized comment on a news report concerning Owens-Illinois:
"Owens-Illinois. a major supplier of glass bulbs for color television pic-
ture tubes, reported on April 19, 1967, a 36.6% drop in earnings, and said
15PetftIon, p. 6.
16Electronjc TrendR, May, 1967, p. 6.
17 Industriea Yearbook, 1967, p. 11.
95-15e 0-68-pt. 8--5
PAGENO="0066"
3502
that one major factor causing this was the `failure of color television to live
up to expectations.' (The Evening Star, April 20, 1967) ." (Petition, p. 6).
The body of the news item referred to reads as follows:
"Failure of color television to live up to expectations in the first quarter
of 1967 was one of the factors leading to a decrease in earnings for Owens-
Illinois, Inc., compared with the first three months of 1966, shareholders
were told.
"`Not only was the TV bulb market soft, but the attrition was particularly
severe on the items in which our company had established itself as the prin-
cipal supplier,' chairman J. P. Lenis said." (The Evening Star, Washington,
D.C., April 20, 1967, p. A22.)
At the outset, the failure of color television to live up to expectations is not
cited as a "major" factor in the depressed earnings of Owens-Illinois for the first
quarter of 1967 ; it is "one of the factors". Moreover, whatever problems this
company is having with sales of glass tubes for color t.v. picture tubes, they are
not import-caused:
"* * * Costly problems in the manufacture of color TV tube envelopes, a
temporary imbalance in bottle inventories, and start-up costs related to new
plastic and paper facilities, are the principal factors accounting for tne
decline. By far the most significant of these difficulties is the TV tube
envelope situation. Production problems now seem to be resolved, however,
and Owens-Illinois expects to regain quickly its position in this field, which
is second to Corning Glass works * * ~ 18
In its 1966 Annual Report to its shareholders Owens-Illinois discussed the 4th
quarter 1966 decline in earnings, a situation which no doubt continued into the
1st guarter of 1967 :
"While total sales for 1966 were 10% ahead of 1965, net earnings increased
only moderately over last year and did not fully reflect the increased sales
volume. Earnings for the first three quarters exceeded those of last year,
but fourth quarter earnings were lower than the comparable period of 1965.
This was due to reduced efficiencies and higher labor costs at several key
locations caused by efforts to operate at maximum capacity in areas of
extremely tight labor availability, to preoperating and start-up costs on new
facilities, and to interest expense in financing the expansion program." `~°
A number of news reports in the Wall Street Journal are summarized as
follows:
"General Electric laid off 1,350 workers in December 1966 and 1,075 work-
ers in February 1967 at its Syracuse, New York, television and electronic
components plants, and shut the entire television plant down for a week in
February. GE furloughed an additional 300 workers at its Portsmouth,
Virginia, television plant in January 1967. (The Wall Street Journal, Janu-
ary 26, 1967; January 12, 1967; February 24, 1967)" 20
The cited news items contain these additional points which, while omitted from
the summary set forth in the petition, are quite relevant to the matter at hand
and must be included if the record is to be complete and accurate:
"* * * A GE spokesman at Portsmouth added that the layoffs there were
due to a `slump' in black-and-white TV sales. . . ." (The Wall Street Jowr-
nal, January 12, 1967, p. 2).
"The February closedown will affect production of color and monochrome
TV sets in screen sizes 18 inches and larger....
***
"In Syracuse, Gilbert Dwyer, GE manager of relations and utilities, said,
`The unusually high levels of business activity in the first three quarters of
1906 led to employment levels far exceeding what GE believes to be optimum
for Syracuse.
***
"`Broad seasonal fluctuations are a way of life in TV manufacturing, `Mr.
Dwyer said. `Notwithstanding the annual adjustments, GE's TV employ-
ment has shown a steady increase in recent years.'" (The Wall Street
Journal, January 26, 1967, p. 5).
Manifestly, the bare reference to "lay offs" is meaningless without these sig-
nificant qualifying comments. Moreover, it is somewhat disingenuous to use
18 Opinion Letter, Johnston, Leman & Co., July 21, 1967, dealing with Owens-
Illinois.
19 Annual Report 1966 Owens-Illinois, p. 2.
20Petition, pp. 6-7.
PAGENO="0067"
3503
figures which relate to company actions based on market factors concerning
black-and-white television sets in a petition seeking an increase in the tariff on
color t.v. picture tubes.
Again, petitioners give their version of another news report as follows:
"Westinghouse furloughed 600 workers at its TV-radio plant in Edison,
New Jersey, and also cut back on production of color television sets in Janu-
ary 1967. (The Wall Street Journal, January 12, 1967)." ~
But the news story aiso inciucted this comment:
"Despite the layoffs at Edison, Westinghouse said its labor force there
remains 30% above the year-ago level and 100% above the number employed
in January 1965." (The Wall Street Journal, January 12, 1967, p. 2).
Before this Committee can assess the real impact of the reported Westinghouse
action, it obviously must have all of the facts.
A news report of a lay-off at General Electric's Syracuse, New York plant is
summarized as follows:
"General Electric laid off an additional 1,500 production workers at its
Syracuse, New York, television and electronic components plants in March
1967, in the third major round of furloughs at those plants. Dwindling sales
of color television sets was cited as a primary factor in the cutback. GE
also shut down its Syracuse plants for a week in March in a fourth effort
to cut inventories in face of the decline in television set sales." (The Wall
Street Journal, March 1, 1967).~
The news story contained the following significant statement:
"Company spokesman said the major TV department work suspensions
and employe cut-backs stem from a `decline' in black-and-white set sales
and a `slower than anticipated' growth in color set sales. . . . (The Wall
Street Jo'urnal, March 1,1967, p. 7).
Again, completeness and accuracy demand not only including the role of black-
and-white set sales decline in the lay-off picture but refraining from converting
"slower than anticipated growth" into "dwindling sales".
Another lay-off action news report is paraphrased as follows:
"Standard Kollsman laid off about 1,200 workers at its Meirose Park,
Illinois; Oshkosh, Wisconsin; and Ottumwa, Iowa, television-tuner plants
in April 1967." (The Wall Street Journal, May 2, 1967).~'
Omitted is this very significant fact included in the same news item:
"A Standard Kollsman spokesman noted that some of the layoffs lasted
only a few days." (The Wall Street Journal, May 2, 1967, p. 2).
A news report of Admiral Corporation's first quarter 1967 loss in earnings is
digested by petitioners as follows:
"Admiral Corporation suffered a loss of $275,843 in the first quarter of
1967 in comparison with earnings of $3,667,115 in the first quarter of 1966,
as a result of the softening in demand for color television sets. Admiral's
television and component plants at Harvard and McHenry, Illinois, and
Sun Prairie, Wisconsin, were closed in April `for considerable periods of
time.'" (The Wall Street Journal, May 5, 1967) .~
But this same news story contained facts which showed that Admiral's officers
were not overly concerned:
"* * * At the meeting, Mr. Siragusa said management felt the dividend
should be paid because the slackening in color-television demand was only
`temporary'. * * *
"Admiral is rapidly getting into the production of 18-inch and 20-inch
rectangular color tubes, the executive said The company's tube facilities,
which previously produced only 23-inch tubes, operated at a `substantial
profit' last year, he said.* * ~" (The Wall Street Journal, May 5, 1967, p. 6).
It is abundantly clear that the domestic industry producing color t.v. receiv-
ing sets is not in any depressed state. While it is true that this industry set its
sights rather high and its sales thus far in 1967 have been short of this mark,
nevertheless the industry is doing well and is on its way to another record year
in 1967.
It is equally apparent from the full record that no case of import-caused in-
jury or threat of injury is present here. Petitioners know this, else they would
not have found it necessary to be so selective as to the facts they presented to
21 Petition, p. 7.
~ Petition, p. 7.
~ Petition, p.8.
~ Petition, p. 8.
PAGENO="0068"
3504
the Committee nor would they have found it expedient to omit relevant facts so
clearly known to them.
In these circumstances, the Committee should reject this petition forthwith.
V. THE ROLE OF IMPORTS OF COLOR TELEVI5ION PICTURE TUBE5
The Magnavox Company accounted for a large percentage of U.S. color t.v.
picture tube imports in 1966 and in the first half of 1967. Another large importer
of such tubes is a U.S. company which is a member of the Tube Division of ETA,
one of the petitioners herein.
While Magnavox' color picture tube imports are large in relation to total im-
ports of such tubes, they are relatively small in relation to Magnavox' total
purchases of picture tubes. Indeed, Magnavox buys in excess of 90 percent of its
color t.v. picture tube requirements from U.S. companies who are among the
petitioners herein.
As the Committee knows, Magnavox is not an integrated color television set
manufacturer. Several of the components needed for building a color t.v. set
Magnavox must purchase from outside sources, either domestic or foreign. In
many cases-such as the case with color t.v. picture tubes-the outside domestic
sources available to Magnavox are also producers of color t.v. receiver sets
which are sold in competition with sets made by Magnavox. In other words,
Magnavox purchases color t.v. picture tubes from its competitors in the color
t.v. receiving set industry.
In its report on H.R. 7969, 89th Congress, the bill which became the Tariff
Schedules Technical Amendments Act of 1965 and which established the present
temporary 12-percent duty on color t.v. picture tubes, the Senate Committee on
Finance described Magnavox' posture as a color t.v. set producer which does not
produce color t.v. picture tubes as follows:
"While many television set mani~facturers in this country also produce
picture tubes, there are other set manufacturers who are not equipped to
manufacture tubes but must rely on their integrated competitors or other
sources for picture tubes they need for their sets. Without access to a reason-
ably priced source of picture tubes for their color sets these manufacturers
would be unable to compete in the expanding market for color television pic-
ture sets in this country." ~
In all respects, this statement remains true today. "Without access to a reason-
ably priced source of picture tubes" for its color television sets, Magnavox "would
be unable to compete in the expanding market for color television picture sets in
this country."
Following this fundamental economic mandate, Magnavox has sought out "rea-
sonably priced" sources for its color t.v. picture tube needs. It has made a decision
to purchase the lion's share of its color tube requirements from domestic color t.v.
tube sources; at the same time, it has been forced by the economics of the situ-
ation to purchase a small part of its needs abroad.
The ironic feature of this present move to raise the duty on Magnavox' color
t.v. tube imports by 150 percent is that it originates with those U.S. companies
which enjoy in excess of 90 percent of Magnavox' color t.v. tube business. These
companies are well acquainted, therefore, with the whole spectrum of Magnavox'
color t.v. tube needs. They know also that the domestic prices of color picture
tubes similar to those purchased from abroad by Magnavox are not compatible
with this economic imperative.
In these circumstances, Magnavox can only conclude that the petitioners are
seeking to preclude Magnavox from purchasing its limited foreign color t.v. pic-
ture tube requirements at a reasonable price and are seeking to force Magnavox
to purchase 100 percent of its color t.v. picture tube requirements from U.S.
producers of such tubes-the petitioners herein. Since a tariff increase on color
t.v. picture tubes is not needed to remedy or prevent any injury because there is
no such injury or threat involved, Magnavox has no choice but to reach this
conclusion.
Removing Magnavox' area of choice as to where it can buy certain of its color
t.v. picture tubes at reasonable prices can only hurt Magnavox and its workers.
~ Senate Report No. 530, 89th Congress, p. 9.
PAGENO="0069"
3505
For if Magnavox' competitive potential is impaired, its operations will be hurt
and those who depend on a viable production program will suffer. Even under
the most compelling circumstances the government should be extremely reluctant
to take any action having such dire consequences. But here, where there is no
reason, much less a compelling reason, to take the action proposed by the peti-
tioners, fair play and common sense dictate that no such action should be taken.
We respectfully submit that the small quantities of color t.v. tubes which Mag-
navox purchases from abroad are important to Magnavox. Reason and logic re-
quire that Magnavox be permitted to continue to have access to these needed
color t.v. set components without any additional tariff burden.
VI. CONCLUSION
We have demonstrated in the preceding sections of this memorandum that
there is no basis for the petitioners' request for a 150 percent increase in the
present duty on color t.v. picture tubes. We have shown, moreover, that such an
increase in this tariff will materially affect Magnavox and its workers.
The present temporary rate of duty of 12 percent ad valorem was established
by Congress in 1965 to run for approximately four years. On the basis of this
action by Congress, Magnavox (and no doubt others similarly situated) has made
plans and commitments which are intricately concerned with the preservation of
this 12 percent rate of duty at least until 1969. These plans and commitments
involved the expenditure by Magnavox of a good deal of time, effort and money.
These corporate actions were taken in good faith and reliance on the continuance
of the status quo as regards the tariff on color t.v. picture tubes.
It is inconceivable that Congress would now consider increasing this duty,
unless, as we acknowledged previously, overwhelming and compelling reasons
mandated such action. Since there are no such reasons extant, we respectfully
submit that justice and equity require that the present 12 percent duty on color
t.v. tubes not be increased.
For the reasons given herein, we urge the Committee to reject the petition in
question.
Respectfully submitted,
THE MAGNAVOX Co.,
ALFRED R. MCCAULEY,
JOHN E.. BAKER,
Attor,meys for the Majjnavoa~ Co.
Of Counsel: Graubard, Moskovitz & McCauley.
September 13, 1967.
(The following statement and letters were received by the
committee:)
STATEMENT OF FRANK L. RANDALL, JR., PRESIDENT, AMPEREX ELECTRONIC
CORPORATION
I am Frank L. Randall, Jr., President of the Amperex Electronic Corporation.
Amperex welcomes this opportunity of expressing its views on trade and tariff
proposals before this Committee, as they affect the electronics industry.
Amperex Electronic Corporation is a manufacturer of electronic tubes, semi-
conductors, integrated circuits, passive components and electronic circuit mod-
ules. It has seven factories in three states and investments in two companies
with factories in two other states. Total employment is 1500.
Manufacturing locations are:
(1) Hicksville, New York (electronic tubes)
(2) Hauppague, New York (passive components)
(3) Patchogue, New York (electronic circuit modules)
(4) Slatersville, Rhode Island (semiconductors)
(5) Slatersville, Rhode Island (electro-optical devices)
(6) Cranston, Rhode Island (integrated circuits)
(7) Hoboken, New Jersey (warehouse, packing and branding)
Investments include:
(1) Reeve Electronics, Inc., Chicago, Illinois
(2) Science Accessories Corp., Southport, Connecticut
PAGENO="0070"
3506
Amperex Electronic Corporation is opposed to any legislation which would
hamper international trade, for the following reasons:
1. International trade creates industry for the United States. Amperex in
the early 1950's embarked on a program of importing European components,
creating a market and establishing manufacturing facilities for these products
to serve this market place. Its growth from a small factory in Brooklyn to its
present seven locations is concrete evidence of imported products creating jobs
and opportunities for local citizens as well as serving industry as a component
supplier.
2. International trade makes available to the United States the research and
development from abroad which assists our domestic industry in staying at the
forefront of industrial progress. Amperex has introduced products from the
research laboratories of Free Europe which have assisted our customers in main-
taining their leadership in their particular field and has served industry by mak-
ing available the most advanced technologies. Two outstanding examples are now
being manufactured in our electro-optical device factory in Slatersville, Rhode
Island. These are the Plumbicon Camera Pickup Tube now used by all manu-
facturers of Studio Quality Color T.V. Cameras. Another is the Image Intensi-
fier X-Ray Tube which is used by all manufacturers of radiological instruments.
3. The balance of trade is outstandingly favorable to the Electronics Indus-
try. Statistics have already been presented to this Committee showing the favor-
able balance of trade in the total Electronics Industry, Industrial and Military
Equipment and Components. Only in the consumer products area do imports
exceed exports.
4. Low priced consumer electronics products serve a market place which can-
not be served by domestic industry because of our higher costs of manufacture.
Millions of low income citizens of our country are exposed to entertainment and
educational opportunities that would be unavailable to them because of price
if they were not supplied from overseas production.
5. Domestic industry is stimulated and afforded the opportunity to expand
in local markets which were developed initially by low priced imported products.
6. The export market provides a fertile field for expansion of our domestic
economy by supplying foreign market places. Restrictive action on our part would
most certainly provide retaliatory measures by nations in our important overseas
markets.
7. The robust health and growth of the United States Electronic Industry cer-
tainly attests to the fact that we can thrive in restriction free world trade.
We strongly recommend that the Ways and Means Committee not taken any
action which would endanger the position of the United States Electronic In-
dustry and its position in the World Market Place.
* * *
Resolution passed at the General Membership Meeting of the Tube Division,
Electronic Industries Association, June 5, 1968, at Chicago, Illinois, inserted in
this record by Frank L. Randall, Jr., President, Amperex Electronic Corporation.
"Whereas: It is an unassailable economic fact that free and equal Interna-
tional Trade is desirable and;
"Whereas: Import quotas, dumping and other non-tariff barriers are restrictive
and tend to stifle International Trade,
"Therefore, be it resolved: The Tube Division of the Electronic Industries
Association is opposed to dumping, non-tariff barriers, and the establishment of
import quotas or any restrictive devices and supports all effort to eliminate im-
port quotas and other measures which restrict imports, as presently imposed
by other nations and;
"Be it further resolved: The Tube Division of the Electronic Industries Asso-
ciation reserves judgment on the use of restrictive devices as a defensive measure
against nations who employ import quotas or other restrictive devices as a deter-
rent to International Trade and;
"Be it further resolved: The Tube Division of the Electronic Industries Asso-
ciation supports equity in foreign trade and that it is the proper function of
this organization, all Member Firms and the Federal Government to actively
promote and work to assure the establishment and maintenance of such equity in
foreign trade."
PAGENO="0071"
3507
ELECTRONIC INDUSTRIES ASSOCIATION,
Washington, D.C., July 12, 1968.
Hon. WILBUR D. MILLS,
Chairman, House of Representatives,
Committee on Ways and Means,
Washington, D.C.
DEAR. MR. CHAIRMAN: The Government Products Division of the Electronic
Industries Association represents United States manufacturers of special elec-
tronic systems and equipment required by the Government.
I have been directed to inform you that this Division, at its recent annual
meeting, voted to associate itself with ETA's Consumer Products Division in
opposing any import quotas on electronic articles.
Sincerely,
WM. H. MOORE,
Staff Vice President, Government Products Division.
ELECTRONIC INDUSTRIES ASSoCIATIoN,
Washington, D.C., July 10, 1968.
Hon. WILBUR D. MILLS,
Chairman, Committee on Ways and Means,
U.S. House of Representatives,
Washington, D.C.
DEAR Mn. MILLS: The Semi-Conductor Division of the Electronic Industries
Association, representing the United States manufacturers of semi-conductor
devices supports the position of the Consumer Products Division of the Elec-
tronic Industries Association, as stated before your Committee on June 25, 1968,
as opposing the imosition of import quotas on all electronic articles.
Sincerely,
F. E. JAUMOT, Jr.,
Chairman, Semi-Conductor Division.
The CHAIRMAN. Mr. Hobbs, we are glad to have you with us this
morning and if you will identify yourself for our record we will be
glad to recognize you, sir.
STATEMENT OP CLAUDE E. HOBBS, CHAIRMAN, FOREIGN TRADE
COMMITTEE, NATIONAL ELECTRICAL MANTJTACTU1tEI~S ASSO-
CIATION; ACCOMPANIED BY BERNARD PALK, VICE PRESIDENT
Mr. HOBBS. Mr. Chairman, thank you. My name is Claude E. Hobbs.
With me is Mr. Bernard Falk, vice president of the National Electri-
cal Manufacturers Association.
I am director of government relations, Westinghouse Electric Corp.
I am here today as chairman of the Foreign Trade Committee of the
National Electrical Manufacturers Association, which we abbreviate
as NEMA. Westinghouse is a member of that association. NEMA's
membership consists of approximately 475 manufacturing firms, the
principal U.S. manufacturers of electrical and allied pro4ucts. Prod-
ucts covered by the association are used in the generation, transmission,
distribution, and utilization of electrical energy. A list of our member-
ship and the product sections has been supplied to the committee staff.
The CHAIRMAN. Mr. Hobbs, if you omit any part of your statement
do so with the knowledge that the entire statement will appear in the
record.
Mr. HOBBS. We have culled the statement down to where it will
be just about as brief to read it, Mr. Chairman, without inserting
any voluminous material in the record.
PAGENO="0072"
3508
The CHAIRMAN. All right. Go right ahead.
Mr. HOBBS. NEMA suports the international trade policies of the
United States as set forth in section 102 of the Trade Expansion Act
of 1962, as follows:
"The purposes of this act are, through trade agreements affording
mutual trade benefits-(1) to stimulate the economic growth of the
United States and maintain and enlarge foreign markets for the
products of U.S. agriculture, industry, mining, and commerce; and
(2) to strengthen economic relations with foreign countries through
the development of open and nondiscriminatory trading in the free
world . . ."
Our views on the conduct of U.S. foreign trade policy are essentially
the same as they were prior to the Kennedy round. In preparation
for that round of tariff negotiations in 1964, NEMA. testified before
the trade information committee that, in general, we were basically
a free-trade industry, that we supported the Government's efforts to
reduce virtually all barriers to world trade in electrical products and
that, with rare exceptions, we would not request that the products of
our industry be reserved from negotiations.
We pointed out that there were a limited number of electrical
products which were deserving of special consideration in the nego-
tiations.
One group of products we felt then and still believe to be particu-
larly deserving of separate attention is what we call heavy electrical
equipment-the large, high-technology turbine generators, power
transformers and power circuit breakers used by electric utilities for
the generation and transmission of electric energy. This is because
there is not free and open international trade in this equipment.
Foreign manufacturers can and do sell it in the United States. But
we cannot sell such equipment in their markets because it is excluded
by nationalistic buying policies. Simply stated, here is one-way trade
in a large industry in which the United States has always excelled.
Therefore, in 1964, we requested that U.S. tariffs on these products
not be reduced unless the nontariff barriers of other countries were
also reduced in a manner which would provide U.S. manufacturers
access to foreign markets for such products equal to the access of
similar foreign equipment to U.S. markets. Nevertheless, U.S. duties
on this equipment were cut the full 50 percent in the Kennedy round,
without any foreign country concessions to open up their protected
home markets to U.S. competition.
We are confident that a more favorable trade balance can be achieved
if U.S. manufacturers of electrical equipment used by electric utilities*
are given a fair opportunity to compete in Europe and Japan, which
could also improve certain competitive conditions in the U.S. market.
American purchasers of utility equipment from foreign manufac-
turers reached new levels in 1967, when orders placed with foreign
supplies by U.S. utilities exceeded the cumulative total of all such
purchases during the preceding 75 years. Nearly $250 million of such
equipment was ordered from abroad last year by both Government-
owned and investor-owned utilities.
In determining proper future trade policy of the United States,
ci~itical questions for American manufacturers of large electrical
equipment are whether they are to be given a genuine opportunity to
PAGENO="0073"
3~~O9
compete abroad on fair terms, and what appropriate steps our Govern-
ment should take to bring this about.
To understand this problem it is necessary to know some of the
facts about electric utilities in the principal countries of the free world
which have industry capable of manufacturing large generating and
transmission equipment used in electric utility systems. These nations,
other than the United States and Canada, are principally the coun-
tries which are members of the European Common Market, the Eu-
ropean Free Trade Association, and Japan.
In varying extent the electric utility systems in most of these coun-
tries are owned, operated, or controlled by government agencies. Their
purchases of large electrical equipment are either controlled by, or
are fully responsive to the policies of their governments. None of
them will buy large electrical equipment from American manufac-
turers, with the limited exception of equipment of advanced design
which their home manufacturers cannot yet make. In the unusual case
where a utility in one of these countries buys an advanced, larger and
more efficient steam turbine generator or a nuclear plant from a U.S.
manufacturer, they are usually buying a prototype with a tie-in licens-
ing arrangement making the designs and detailed manufacturing in-
structions available to one of their home manufacturers.
Many of these countries have plants and personnel capable of manu-
facturing large electric generating and transmission equipment. Usu-
ally they have the capacity to make more equipment than their home
country utilities need year after year. For example, while all, or most,
of the capacity of British manufacturers of large power transformers
is used for supplying the British home market in some years, in other
years they have excess capacity available for export sales. This is true
with respect to manufacturers of a whole range of other electrical
equipment in Britain and also in other industrialized countries. They
often seek export sales in the United States at prices lower than they
obtain in their home country markets. Realizing high profits in their
protected home markets, they thus obtain the wherewithal to capture
sales in the United States at greatly reduced prices.
During the past 10 or 15 years, the principal U.S. purchasers of
large electrical equipment from foreign suppliers have been agencies
of the U.S. Government-TVA, Bonneville Power Administration,
Bureau of Reclamation, and the Corps of Engineers. Many of these
purchasers were at prices considerably below those then being received
by the foreign manufacturers for similar equipment in their home
markets.
U.S. Government policies of long standing have encouraged this
one-way trade in electrical equipment despite recommendations for
reciprocity in Government purchasing.
In 1954, the report of the Randall Commission on Foreign Eco-
nomic Policy stated as follows (p. 45)
The Buy American Act and legislative provisions of other acts containing the
Buy American principle should be amended to give authority to the President to
exempt from the provisions of such legislation the bidders from other nations
that treat our bidders on an equal basis with their own nationals. Pending such
amendment, the President by Executive Order should direct procurement agen-
cies in the public interest to consider foreign bids which satisfy all other con-
siderations on substantially the same price basis as domestic bids.
PAGENO="0074"
3510
That same year, an Executive order put part of this recommenda-
tion into effect, but not all. It established the principle that American
bids to Government agencies which exceeded foreign bids by more
than 6 percent were to be deemed unreasonable, and that foreign bids
should be accepted in such cases. But the Executive order did not re-
quire that this policy relate only to the bidders from other nations
that treat American bidders on an equal basis with their own
nationals.
While U.S. Government procurement policy is not the responsibility
of this committee, we believe it should be of interest to this committee
when Government procurement has a significant impact on our bal-
ance of foreign trade and our balance of payments.
The dramatic increase in orders for electrical equipment placed
abroad last year, especially in the light of the one-sided results of the
Kennedy round with respect to the heavy electrical equipment indus-
try, lead us to some observations concerning future trade policy.
Ambassador Roth and other important officials have said that from
now on tariffs will become relatively unimportant as a deterrent to
international trade. We believe this is correct, and that nontariff bar-
riers which now and in the future obstruct the flow of trade are the
most significant matters for the attention of Congress and our trade
policy officials.
We believe that linear, or across-the-board reduction of tariffs or
other trade barriers will not be appropriate for the future. The volume
of trade in given product lines or industries should no longer be the
principal criterion for swapping concessions respecting other, unre-
lated products. From now on, in our judgment, more specific and in-
formed attention must be given to the economics of any industry whose
trade is affected by concessions, and to the impact of such concessions
on the affected industry.
The industry we are discussing is a good example. Electricity is
electricity wherever it is used. There are substantial similarities in the
machinery that generates it and transmits it to locations where it does
its work. While there are differences in designs and efficiencies, British
generators can produce electricity in the United States or in France,
and American equipment could serve British or Italian needs. Techni-
cal reciprocity in electrical equipment can be universal. But the eco-
nomics are far from universal unless trade barriers or lack of barriers
are at least reciprocal.
Electrical generation and transmission equipment is fundamental to
maintenance and improvement of living standards throughout the
world. The markets for these products in the United States and other
industrialized countries are of substantial magnitude. Because of the
importance of this equipment, both in terms of foreign trade and
human comfort and convenience, and in view of the unusual govern-
mental character of potential foreign buyers of these products, we be-
lieve it is essential that the U.S. (xovernment utilize every available
tool to eliminate promptly those discriminatory procurement practices
which close major foreign markets to our electrical equipment manu-
facturers. An adjustment of U.S. Government procurement policies
could well be part of such an effort.
If this committee and the Congress decide to enact a renewal of the
trade policies and provisions set forth in the Trade Expansion Act of
PAGENO="0075"
3511
1962, we hope you will emphasize the essentiality of obtaining mutual
trade benefits for the products of this industry which are sold to
utilities, as well as for industrial products in general. Such a congres-
sional mandate should apply to any future round of negotiations to
reduce trade barriers, and also to any less significant negotiations prior
to a new large-scale effort.
We appreciate the opportunity of presenting these views to you.
The CHAIRMAN. We thank you, Mr. Hobbs, for bringing to us your
views.
Are there any questions? Mr. Curtis.
Mr. CunTIs. Mr. Chairman, I think in this paper, which I think is
excellent, we have what I would say is a classic example of the disman-
tling of tariffs and then the emergence of the importance of these non-
tariff trade barriers.
It also points up this very difficult problem of state ownership and
as you point out, the difficulty of American enterprise which is not
state-owned in competing with it. The state-owned enterprises fre-
quently don't even have good cost accounting so they don't even know
themselves what it costs to produce a unit. You have built in therefore
just by its very nature tremendous government subsidies.
I am leading up to this following question. Do you think that the
countervailing duty laws that we presently have might be utilized to
dig into this subsidy aspect, which I think you implied is part of the
difficulty you have?
Mr. HOBBS. I think so, Mr. Curtis, although this has to be a matter
of judgment because you have to fit the facts to the statute. The statute
says whenever any foreign country or business organization, "shall
pay or bestow directly or indirectly any bounty or grant" on the ex-
port of any article produced within the foreign country then the Sec-
retary of the Treasury can assess countervailing duties.
Well, in the British case, for example, the principal buyer of elec-
trical equipment in Great Britain is the entirely government-owned
Central Electricity Generating Board which is like our TVA, except
it is much larger and covers a much greater proportion of the United
Kingdom. It covers most of it. The CEGB has written agreements
with British manufacturers of electrical equipment whereby they
guarantee the manufacturers a profit rate of approximately 15 per-
cent or greater on their domestic business, and the agreements permit
loading into the prices of domestic business the research and develop-
ment expenses for all business, including exports, and for overseas
selling expenses.
That is a subsidy. Whether you want to call it government directly
or indirectly, or a bounty, it is certainly calculated to help and does
help British manufacturers of electrical equipment to sell it abroad,
into the United States specifically, at prices which are much lower
than those at which they sell in their home country. It seems to me
that this ought to be a classic case for the imposition of countervailing
duties.
Another section would be, section 252 of the Trade Expansion Act
of 1962. I think it clearly ought to fit this situation.
Mr. CuRTIS. I agree with you and I think it is most important that
we start moving in this area. There is an argument beyond the very
valid argument you are making. If we want reciprocity, then if we
PAGENO="0076"
3512
do not apply a rigid buy-American rule they should not be applying
their buy-national acts.
In fact they don't even have to do this buying by law. It is the
structure that permits them in effect to buy national. That is about
the only way they could do it.
Well, one other detail, because this has been a problem before this
committee ever since I have been on the committee. You relate it back
to 1954. At one time you were pointing out that you felt our own
governmental agencies, such as TVA, were not purchasing on the
basis of procuring the most efficient product and that they were only
looking-if I am in error in stating this I want to be corrected-at
the sale price of, say, a big generating unit and were not counting the
downtime of that particular unit. One of the competitive advantages
for American production of generators is that the instance of down-
time is considerably less.
Is this still a factor in this area?
Mr. HOBBS. Well, Mr. Curtis, I think the TVA certainly counts
all factors in the cost of operating the equipment, including the
capital cost and depreciation, and the fuel cost.
Mr. CURTIS. You say they do now.
Mr. HOBBS. I think they always have.
Mr. CURTIS. The argument was that they didn't. That is why I
raised it.
Mr. HOBBS. I think rather than characterize what TVA does, let
me state certainly what Westinghouse Electric believes. We believe
that our equipment has a better record of downtime than most of the
foreign equipment. I think we can prove that by carefully kept records
which have been made available to us by utilities that have both
types of equipment, and that is a significant consideration in the
value of the equipment that they are using.
Mr. CURTIS. You are not commenting on whether my statement
was correct or not, but at least now TVA, to use an example, does
consider downtime in purchasing formulas?
Mr. HOBBS. They certainly say that they do, and I have to assume
that they are correct, Mr. Chairman.
Mr. CURTIS. OK. Thank you.
The CHAIRMAN. Mr. Schneebeli.
Mr. SCHNEEBELI. Mr. Hobbs, you say that none of our trading
partners buy any large electrical equipment from us. You mention
the instance of the United Kingdom where the Government agency
more or less precludes anybody else.
What form of restriction do some of these other nations have?
Is it usually decided by the government body or are there other forms
of restrictions which they use in not buying from us?
Mr. HOBBS. They are very subtle. I think you have to take each
country separately.
Mr. SCHNEEBELI. There isn't any general pattern?
Mr. HOBBS. In France, for example, the whole electric system is
owned by the government. They simply won't buy from you, period.
We send salesmen to talk to them. They say, "That is very nice but we
only buy from French manufacturers."
As far as I know there is no law or specific regulation that they
point to. They just say "That is the way we do business in France."
PAGENO="0077"
3513
Mr. SOHNEEBELI. This seems to be the general pattern then, doesn't
it?
Mr. HOBBS. It is true in Italy where the system is government-owned.
In Switzerland the system is owned I believe by the cantons, which are
regional governmental bodies. They would not think of buying any-
thing except; of Swiss manufacture.
The Italians occasionally have bought turbines and large equipment,
but Italian purchases are good examples of what I referred to as pro-
totype purchases. I know that at least on one occasion the Italians
bought a steam turbine generator from Westinghouse and one of their
manufacturing companies received from us a license to copy that ma-
chine in the future. In effect, they bought the first one of that size and
efficiency but no more.
This is a general pattern. It applies to the countries of northern
Europe. The Japanese systems I believe are investor-owned, but they
are very responsive to tight government controls on where they buy
their equipment.
Mr. SCHNEEBELI. This restriction not only applies to the United
States; it; applies to importing from any other nation?
Mr. HOBBS. That is right. The French won't buy a British machine,
and the British will not buy a French machine.
Mr. SCHNEEBELI. So it is not applied to us particularly.
Mr. HOBBS. The only reason it particularly applies to us is while
they can't sell in any other developed country markets, they can sell
in our market, but we can't sell in theirs.
Mr. SCHNEEBEUI. In that connection my next question is have you
gone the route of the antidumping provisions in trying to protect
yourselves against; this?
Mr. Hoims. We are now intensively making studies to see if we can
present an antidumping action. The trouble is that none of the pur-
chasing data in the foreign countries is published. It is all done by
private negotiations. The bids are not opened publicly, and you prac-
tically have to get a detective to find out the prices at which they sell
this equipment in their own countries.
We are accumulating some of that information. We have had people
over there for the past year or so trying to do just what you are saying.
We think we have evidence of dumping at least from one of the coun-
tries, but this will present us a problem because our industry in the
last; couple of years has been at the peak of a buying cycle.
Our plants are well loaded so we may have difficulty this year, last
year, maybe next year, in establishing that we were injured by this
dumping. It will depend on the legal standard of what constitutes
injury in our case.
Mr. SCHNEEBELI. I notice that Farranti in England has been getting
a lot of our business. Is the United Kingdom responsible for most of
the purchases of that company in 1967?
Mr. HOBBS. I won't say most of them. They were responsible for a
large share of these purchases.
Mr. SCHNEEBELI. What percentage of our market in 1967 was for-
eign purchases?
Mr. HOBBS. It varies by type of equipment. We are only talking here
specifically about three basic types-large turbine generators, large
power transformers, and the large power circuit breakers. American
PAGENO="0078"
3514
manufacturers lost approximately-this is on the basis of orders
placed in 1967 by U.S. utilities, both investor-owned and Government-
owned-16 to 17 percent of the turbine generator business to foreign
suppliers last year.
The power transformer orders placed abroad were a smaller percent-
age, 7 percent perhaps, and the power circuit breakers maybe 5 percent.
You see, this is not published information as yet and these articles
require long leadtime so that some of them are shipped in different
years than when the orders are placed.
Mr. SOHNEEBELI. So it would show up more the next couple of years.
Mr. HOBBS. In later years, when the import shipments are received
in this country.
Mr. SCHNEEBELI. And you imply that the buy American provisions
are very ineffectual?
Mr. HOBBS. They have been almost totally ineffectual, and, remem-
ber, they apply only to Government agencies.
Mr. SCHNEEBELI. Yes, I realize that, but even so TVA is buying lots
of large generating equipment.
Mr. HOBBS. The foreign prices on power transformers during some
of the past 7 oi~ 8 years have averaged as much as 40 percent below
the level in the exporting countries, so a 6 percent differential applied
here, plus import duty, has not been enough to stop them.
Mr. SCHNEEBELI. That is all, Mr. Chairman.
The CHAIRMAN. Mr. Betts.
Mr. BETTS. Mr. Hobbs, on page 3 you mention this request that your
company made that there be no reduction in tariffs unless the nontariff
barriers on the part of other countries were also reduced and appar-
ently you didn't win on that score and in the Kennedy round the
tariffs on these particular products were reduced 50 percent.
Do you know whether or not these nontariff barriers that you asked
to be removed are in the agreement to be removed if we removed the
American selling price?
Mr. HOBBS. No, they are not part of that arrangement, Mr. Betts.
Mr~ Bm'rs. So if we remove the American selling price these barriers
will still exist?
Mr. HOBBS. That would have no bearing on this problem. As a matter
of fact, we are dealing principally with Government procurement
here, at least procurement by publicly owned bodies, and under the
GATT I believe Government procurement is not part of the negoti-
ating procedure.
Nonetheless, is is trade, but, in any case, the answer to your question
is "No," nothing that is pending before Congress in the present legis-
lation would specifically affect these nontariff barriers.
Mr. BETTS. I just wanted to make sure whether there was anything
in the offing that could help remove these barriers if we did something
here, but apparently there is not. Is that correct?
Mr. HOBBS. There is nothing in the bill before you now that would
specifically affect them.
Mr. BErrS. Now, then, also from your statement on page 3 at the
bottom of the page, I would assume that you feel that the 50-percent
reduction in tariffs is causing most of your trouble here. Is that
correct?
PAGENO="0079"
3515
Mr. HOBBS. These imports were coming in before the 50 percent went
into effect, but this is a matter of opinion.
Really we have no direct evidence, but many of the orders which
were placed last year will not be delivered until 2 or 3 years from now
when at least several of the five stages of reduction will have come into
effect.
I don't think those reductions alone are of sufficient magnitude to
make a major difference, but it all adds up to a difference in the cost of
entry in bringing these items into this country.
Mr. BETTS. Thank you.
The CHAIRMAN. Mr. Collier.
Mr. COLLIER. The previous witness suggested that it would be
preferable to prevail upon our foreign trade partners to remove their
nontariff barriers rather than for us to impose reciprocal policies of
this nature in our trade relations.
Now you said to us, Mr. Hobbs, in answer to a question that there
is nothing in this legislation that would deal directly with the removal
of these nontariff barriers.
Mr. HOBBS. Nothing specific, Mr. Collier.
Mr. COLLIER. Well, I would simply submit that there is, and I might
say, being realistic, that we are not going to impose nontariff barriers
similar to those that have been imposed by foreign countries, would it
not make good sense then to adopt a flexible quota ceiling type of pro-
posal that would at least give us a wedge from which we could nego-
tiate a removal of nontariff barriers?
Otherwise we have no wedge with which to deal with nontariff bar-
riers and certainly the quota provisions in the bill which I introduced
would place us in a far more favorable position to put pressure, if
you please, upon our foreign trade partners to remove nontariff
barriers.
Mr. HOBBS. I am speaking for a group which has not endorsed a
quota principle, Mr. Collier, but we as a group have recommended to
the Treasury Department and to an interagency group that the U.S.
Government at least put itself in the best possible negotiating position
in trying to remove these barriers.
We think in our particular case that at least we could say "We are
going to review U.S. Government purchasing policy and we would
like to talk to you about yours."
Now, at what stage we ought to impose restrictions against pur-
chasing foreign equipment, I don't think we are quite ready to say.
But we would certainly like to see the U.S. Government take a firm
stand in insisting that foreigners either open up their markets to this
equipment or that possibly in the future the U.S. Government agen-
cies are going to stop buying foreign equipment.
But this industry has not yet, and I don't think they will advocate
the quota route unless conditions change a great deal for us.
Mr. COLLIER. I am not suggesting, Mr. Hobbs, that they do and I
am not suggesting that this is in and of itself a solution to the prob-
lem of nontariff barriers. But I think we all recognize that in order
to negotiate and if it is our intent to eliminate some of these prac-
tices we have to have a wedge ourselves in order to provide the pres-
sure necessary to remove these nontariff barriers, and it just seems to
me that one of the things we can do is to establish a flexible quota
PAGENO="0080"
3516
ceiling if for no other reason than to, for instance, during this interim
period have some lever in our negotiations.
That is all I have, Mr. Chairman.
The CHAIRMAN. Mr. Burke.
Mr. BURKE. Mr. Hobbs, I was wondering if you could inform the
committee what percentage of increase in exports for heavy electrical
equipment took place between the years of 1961 and 1967?
In other words, how do the figures on exports compare for the year
1967 with the year of 1961? Has it increased, or decreased, or what?
Mr. HOBBS. On imports into the United States?
Mr. BURKE. No, exports.
Mr. HOBBS. Exports from the United States?
Mr. BURKE. From the United States.
Mr. HOBBS. They have gone up slightly, Mr. Burke. We do not have
the precise figures. We can supply those for the record if that would
be helpful.
Mr. BURKE. What I am trying to find out is if your figures on ex-
ports compare favorably to the figures on imports coming in?
Mr. HOBBS. The figures on exports of this particular type of equip-
ments have over the years, including the years up through last year, ex-
ceeded the import figures, I believe, but the exports are at least 70 per-
cent financed by U.S. dollar assistance, either AID funds, or Export-
Import Bank loans.
In other words, the exports are related to dollar financing and are
predominantly to the underdeveloped areas. Without U.S. Govern-
ment dollar assistance in making those exports they would be cut
by at least 75 percent, in my judgment. We are complaining prin-
cipally about the countries that have the money to buy but won't
buy from us.
Mr. BURKE. In other words, the developed countries that manu-
facture their own heavy equipment are not buying from us.
Mr. HOBBS. They are not. They refuse to buy from us; that is correct.
Mr. BURKE. Thank you.
The CHAIRMAN. Mr. Curtis.
Mr. CURTIS. Mr. Chairman, this discussion is moving into a very
important area. Itis true in the Kennedy round that practically noth-
ing was done about these nontariff barriers and the "buy National"
provisions of all the countries.
In my judgment this is certainly an area in which there needs to be
some work done. I would like for the record to point out article III,
section 8(a) of GATT:
The provisions of this article-
This provides for, in effect, fair trade-
shall not apply to laws, regulations, or requirements governing the procurement
by governmental agencies of products purchased for governmental purposes and
not with a view to commercial resale or with a view to use in the production
of goods for commercial sale.
In other words, all of our Buy American Acts, as well as buy British,
and buy French, and so forth, are exempted from the GATT pro-
visions. There are two ways we could go.
PAGENO="0081"
3517
One, we could just put up more of these nontariff trade barriers our-
selves and, indeed, this is what is going on. Our States now are engaged
in putting into effect Buy American Acts.
Whether it is constitutional or not is another question, but that is
an internal matter. Or we could go the way that I think you are recom-
mending of knocking down other countries' barriers, and I certainly
am in accord.
We can try to persuade these foreign countries to cut back on their
barriers. We have plenty of buy American provisions ourselves. I
pointed out one when the textile people were here the other day. We
put in the defense appropriation bill a few years ago at their request
that our military can only buy American textiles. That is a complete
buy American.
I would observe, and I hope our committee staff will study this
and possibly witnesses will bring us material in this area, that the Buy
American Acts of this variety nowhere compare to the buy French,
buy British restrictions, and so forth, imposed by our trading partners.
So again, to add to Mr. Byrnes' observation, let's not get our own sins
out here in the open without at the same time pointing up that in con-
text of what other nations do in this area, our barriers aren't as ex-
cessive as theirs.
And then this added factor that I pointed out. In nations that are
more socialistic, more and more industry is owned by the government,
and Buy National Acts are much more effective because there are more
governmental agencies involved.
I just wanted to put that in the record.
The CHAIRMAN. Mr. Schneebeli.
Mr. SCHNEEBELI. Has your industry ever considered going the route
of the OEP? Would you qualify as a strategic industry under the
Office of Emergency Planning?
Mr. HOBBS. We submitted a petition under section 8 of the Trade
Agreements Act, I believe it was the act of 1958 which had the pro-
vision in it that you are referring to, Mr. Schneebeli, and were turned
down.
Mr. SCHNEEBELI. For what reason?
Mr. HOBBS. Well, our basis was that the electrical equipment, the
large steam turbine generators, and large power transformers, the key
elements in the generation and transmission systems, were essential to
national security, that the difficulty of repairs to foreign equipment if
they were sabotaged or broke down in effect, was such that only Ameri-
can equipment should be bought for the key elements of the U.S. sys-
tem, and this was rejected.
Mr. SOHNEEBEIJ. You didn't qualify.
Mr. HOBBS. Our petition was turned down. They said they would
continue to look at it. This was about 1959 or 1960 as I recall.
Mr. SCHNEEBELI. Thank you.
The CHAIRMAN. Again we thank you, Mr. Hobbs, for bringing to
the committee your views.
Mr. HOBBS. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
The CHAIRMAN. Mr. Stewart. Mr. Stewart, again we ask you to
identify yourself for the record and those at the table with you.
95-159 O-68-pt. 8-6
PAGENO="0082"
3518
STATEMENT OP EUGENE L. STEWART, COUNSEL, PARTS AND DIS-
TRIBUTOR PRODUCTS DIVISIONS, ELECTRONIC INDUSTRIES ASSO-
CIATION, AND AMERICAN LOUDSPEAKER MANIJTACTURERS
ASSOCIATION; ACCOMPANIED BY W. L. LARSON, VICE CHAIRMAN,
PARTS DIVISION; R. W. WOODBURY, VICE CHAIRMAN, DISTRIB-
UTOR PRODUCTS DIVISION; TYLER NOURSE, STAPP VICE PRESI-
DENT, PARTS AND DISTRIBUTOR PRODUCTS DIVISIONS; AND
HERBERT ROWE, MEMBER, WORLD TRADE COMMIT1~EE, PARTS
DIVISION, AND VICE PRESIDENT, AMERICAN LOUDSPEAKER
MANUFACTURERS ASSOCIATION
Mr. STEWART. Mr. Chairman, I am Eugene L. Stewart. I appear
here as special counsel for the Parts Division of the Electronic Indus-
tries Association, the Distributor Products Division of that associa-
tion, and the American Loudspeaker Manufacturers Association.
With me at the table are Mr. Herbert Rowe, president of the Muter
Co., who is a member, who is vice president of the American
Loudspeaker Manufacturers Association; Mr. W. L. Larson, president
of Switchcraft, who is vice chairman of the ETA Parts Division: Mr.
R. W. Woodbury, who is vice chairman of the ETA Distributor Prod-
ucts Division; and Mr. Tyler Nourse, who is the staff vice president
of the Parts and Distributor Products Divisions.
There is listed on the cover of my testimony the names of other
industry representatives who are here. Each of them represents an im-
portant segment of the components industry, and they will assist if
needed in answering questions.
The CHAIRMAN. Mr. Stewart, you will want your entire statement
made a part of the record. Without objection, it will be made a part of
the record and you are recognized, sir.
Mr. STEWART. Thank you, Mr. `Chairman. In the interest of time I
shall summarize our testimony; I hope concisely.
The CHAIRMAN. You may be seated if you desire or stand, either way.
Mr. STEWART. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Let me say at the outset
that there is no single industry known as the electronics industry.
There are 25 industries in the standard industrial classification at the
four-digit level which manufacture articles which have an electronic
circuit.
It is impossible, due to the great range of these products to classify
them from a marketing or production point of view into a single
industry.
Electronic products cover an enormously wide spectrum of hard-
ware in consumer, and industrial, defense and space areas, from tran-
sistor radios to airborne computers, from electronic organs to measur-
ing instruments for assembly lines.
Let us make one thing clear on this record. The position that we
support is opposed by the Consumer Products Division of the Elec-
tronic Industries Association. But let us understand their position.
That position is based upon the vote of companies which account
for less than a majority of the IlLS, production of such products and
that vote was heavily weighted by companies that are primarily im-
porters of either consumer electronic products or electronic compo-
nents.
PAGENO="0083"
3519
There is nothing wrong with this, but so that the positions may be
clear they are the importers. We are the domestic industry, the domes-
tic producers. They want to be unrestricted in the importation of their
products. We want to see some part of the American market enjoyed
by American producers with American workingmen.
Our economic interests are opposed, ours and theirs. They want to
protect their investment in foreign plants. We want to protect our
investment in American plants. They are protectionists just as we,
but they wrap their protectionism in the semantics of free trade.
To show the relative stake of each of these two industries, consumer
products and components, in employment in the United States, please
look at the following table:
TABLE 1.-Employment in selected electronic industries, April1968
[In thousands]
Consumer electronic products (Standard Industrial Classification 365)____ 133. 8
Electronic components and accessories (Standard Industrial Classification
367) 350.4
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Employment and
Earnings, May 1968.
Here we find for the month of April 1968 the employment in each
industry. You will note that we have nearly three times the number
of employees as the consumer electronic products division.
Further, take note of this fact. Since November of 1966 the consumer
electronic products industry suffered an absolute loss of 45,000 jobs
and since October of 1966 our industry, the electronic components in-
dustry, suffered an absolute loss of 46,000 jobs. Together we lost 91,000
jobs for our American workingmen in the last 18 months.
Now, imports are not the sole cause of this but they are one of the
contributing causes. Let us look first at consumer electronic products,
and by this term I mean, and if you will look at the following table
concerning television sets, radios, phonographs, and tape recorders.
TABLE 2.-U.S. IMPORTS OF CONSUMER ELECTRONIC PRODUCTS
(In thousands of unitsi
1964
1966
1967
Percent of
change
1st quarter,
1967
1st quarter,
1968
Percent of
1964-67
TV
Radios
Phonographs
Tape recorders
Value of above (dollars in
millions)
715
13,739
2,363
3,075
$212. 6
1,524
24, 950
4,223
2, 807
$390. 2
1,614
24,201
4,134
3, 780
$458. 8
+125.7
+76. 1
+74.9
+22. 9
+115. 8
369
4,865
503
`1,043
.
$92.3
308
5,454
407
1,282
$104. 6
-16.5
+12. 1
-19.1
+22. 9
+13.3
1 Estimated at the ratio of change in value, based on units published for 1st quarter, 1968 (not available in 1967).
Source: Marketing Services Department, Electronic Industries Association; U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of
the Census.
You will note from this table that from 1964 to 1967 there was a very
large increase in imports in units in each one of these product areas.
Later I shall show you the balance of trade in dollars on these and the
other products I talk about.
Look at table 3, and note the share of the domestic market aëcounted
for by imports. In TV sets it doubled from 7 percent to 14 percent in
1967, is a little bit off in the first quarter of this year.
PAGENO="0084"
3520
TABLE 3.-IMPORTS OF CONSUMER ELECTRONIC PRODUCTS AS SHARE OF U.S. MARKET
[In percent)
1964 1966 1967 1st quarter,
1968
TV 7.3 12.0 14.0 11.0
Radios (home) 58. 3 71. 7 74. 4 77. 8
Phonographs 31.4 40.1 43.3 30.0
Tape recorders 86. 4 76. 4 82. 5 85. 3
Source: Derived from import and market data compiled by marketing services department, Electronic Industries
Association.
Radios, 74 percent of the market was supplied by foreign produced
radios in 1967 and you see the ratio for the other products. Why
are we interested in the imports of consumer electronic products since
we do not manufacture them?
Because they consist merely of an assembly of components, of tubes
and transistors, and resistors and capacitors and inductors, and
loudspeakers.
The importation of sets is a very major part of the importation of
the components. One of the gentlemen asked the first witness today
what has happened to the production of radios in the last 20 years?
Gentlemen, in 1947 the American market consisted of 20 million
sets, all of which were made in America; in 1967, 20 years later, 40
million sets, only 8 million of which were made in America. The
components industry 20 years ago supplied all of the components for
20 million sets. Twenty years later we supplied part of the components
for 8 million sets.
All of the growth in the radio market has gone to imports and most
of the market that was held in 1947 has gone to imports.
Look please if you would at table 4. In textiles you are familiar
with the fact that the ratio of imports to domestic consumption is
calculated by determining the square yard equivalent of fabric that
comes in in the form of shirts and garments as well as the fabric
imported as fabric.
TABLE 4.-TOTAL U.S. IMPORTS (DIRECT AND INDIRECT) OF ELECTRONIC COMPONENTS, 1964-67
[in million
s of units)
Class of component
1964
1966
1967
Percent of
change
1964-67
Active components:
Receiving tubes
TV picture tubes
Transistors
Rectifiers and diodes
Passive components:
Capacitors, electrolytic
Capacitors, fixed
Resistors, fixed
Inductors and transformers
Other components:
Controls
Loudspeakers
Record changers
67.7
0. 8
149. 9
105. 6
199. 8
785. 6
1,019.3
259.7
55.6
25. 3
2.3
111.8
1. 6
681. 6
383. 8
617. 3
1,616. 1
2,377.6
551.7
169.9
55. 5
4.6
85.0
2. 0
532. 8
484. 6
473. 8
1,692. 6
2,238.8
506.1
90.3
48.0
4.1
+25. 5
+147. 2
+255. 4
+358. 8
+137. 1
+115. 4
+119.6
+94.9
+62.5
+89. 5
+79.3
Source: Appendix table 1.
In similar fashion the marketing services department of ETA, which
is a division that serves all the other divisions statistically, has calcu-
PAGENO="0085"
3521
lated the quantity of components imported as part of sets and from
the Commerce Department the quantity imported as components.
The total U.S. imports of components, direct and indirect, is shown
in table 4. Note, and this is in millions of units, the astounding rate
of increase since 1964.
Now, let your glance fall on table 5, where we show what the ratio
of these imports to U.S. commercial sales of components in units is
for the same years. Notice the very astounding import penetration
ratio. In some cases imports account for twice or greater the volume
of commercial sales of domestically produced components.
TABLE 5.-RATIO OF IMPORTS TO U.S. COMMERCIAL SALES OF SELECTED
ELECTRONIC COMPONENTS, 1964-67
Class of component
Percent
1964
1966
1967
Active components:
Receiving tubes
TV picture tubes
Transistors
Rectifiers and diodes
20. 1
8. 5
102.7
17. 6
27.6
12. 1
227.3
31. 9
29.2
18. 7
242.3
43. 0
Passive components:
Capacitors, electrolytic
Capacitors, fixed
Resistors, fixed
Inductors and transformers
92. 6
45.6
35.2
479.6
171. 4
62.5
52.2
581. 0
169. 9
92.7
112.7
532.6
Other components:
Controls
Loudspeakers
Record changers
(1)
50.0
(1)
66.4
82.4
51.7
(1)
109.1
(1)
1 Not available.
Source: Appendix table II.
This rate of import penetration vastly exceeds that which exists in
textiles, petroleum, meat products, any other industry that has been
before you with a serious import problem.
Now let us look at table 6. Here we are setting forth the balance
of trade in both consumer electronic products and components. A
more specific breakout of each of the products is shown in an appendix
table where the detailed statistics are offered.
* TABLE 6.-U.S. BALANCE OF TRADE IN CONSUMER ELECTRONIC PRODUCTS AND COMPONENTS, 1964-67
[In millions of dollarsj
1964
1966
1967
Exports:
Consumer electronic products 64. 2
Active components 72.2
Passive and other components 1 39. 2
Total 1175.6
Imports:
Consumer electronic products 212. 6
Active components 21. 5
Passive and other components 58. 4
Total 292.5
Balance of trade:
Consumer electronic products -148. 4
Active components +50. 7
P~ssive and other components 1 -37~ 8
Total 1-116.9
76. 8
87. 0
1131. 3
76.6
79. 1
1145. 0
1 295. 1
404.3
68.9
181.0
1 300. 7
469. 8
64. 4
159. 0
654.2
-327. 5
+18. 1
1 -63. 1
693.2
-393. 2
+14. 7
1 -19. 9
1 -359.1
1_392.5
1 Exportdara for narphones and headsets notavailable, 1964-67; 1964 export data notavailable for microphones and, for
parts for radio and TV appacatus, phonographs, active and passive components, ~nd other components.
Source: Appendix table III.
PAGENO="0086"
3522
It is sufficient to notice here that we do export these products, and
the exports increased from $175 million in 1964 to $300 million in 1967,
a decent performance, but note that imports increased from $292 mil-
lion in 1964 to nearly $700 million in 1967.
Our balance-of-trade deficit went from a little over $100 million to
nearly $400 million in the space of these 3 years.
In the long-term cotton textile arrangement the GATT countries by
agreement without retaliation adopted the principle that because tex-
tiles are highly labor-intensive products that were being manufactured
predominantly in low-wage countries for export to the developed coun-
tries, a system of negotiated import rates for the developed countries
was n~cessary to avoid market disruption and to contribute to the
economic betterment of both the exporters and importers.
Please look at table 7 where I show you the labor-intensive ratio of
electronic components manufacture compared with cotton broadwoven
fabrics, and the average of all manufacturing and apparel.
TABLE 7.-COMPARATIVE LABOR INTENSIVENESS OF ELECTRONIC COMPONENTS MANUFACTURE IN THE
UNITED STATES
Payroll as a percent of-
Value of Value added
shipments by manufacture
All manufacturing establishments
Cotton broadwoven fabrics, SIC 2211
Apparel and related products, SIC 23
Electronic components, SIC 367
Receiving tubes, SIC 3671
Semiconductors,1 SIC 3674
Capacitors,1 SIC 36792
Resistors,1 SIC 36793
Coils, transformers, reactors, and chokes, SIC 36794
22.2
24.8
25.9
39.6
42.6
~ ~
38.5
40. 5
39.0
48.7
61.4
56.3
62. 0
54.6
~` 0
56.5
54.4
70. 1
1 Establishments with 90 percent or more specialization.
Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, "1963 Census of Manufactures."
You will notice that whereas cotton textiles have a ratio of total
payroll cost to value of shipments of 24.8 percent and apparel 25.9 per-
cent, all components on the average had a ratio of labor intensiveness
of nearly 40 percent and some of the individual components exceed
40 percent.
We are nearly twice as labor intensive as the average of all manu-
facturing and vastly more labor intensive than textiles, but notice
the difference in the policy of our Government in regard to our in-
dustry, which I should remind you does employ nearly 400,000
workers.
For textiles there is a long-term arrangement that provides a sys-
tem of quotas, and very properly there is widespread interest in the
Congress in extending those to other textile articles. The textile mill
products and apparel industries were spared deep cuts in the Ken-
nedy round.
Now, gentlemen, every one of our products in the consumer elec-
tronic product line and the component line but two were reduced by
50 percent in the Kennedy round, and we are in a situation where the
level of our duties is lower for most products than every other nation,
including Japan.
PAGENO="0087"
3523
First, to show you that this is primarily an Asian problem turn
to table 8. Here I have shown the origin of U.S. imports of these
consumer electronic products and components by country and area
of origin, showing what the situation is in dollars for each product.
If you look at the column on the far right, the percent which each
area is of the total, you will notice that Japan supplied 66 percent of
the imports in 1966 of these products and "other Asia," which is pri-
marily Hong Kong, 9.3 percent.
TABLE 8.-ORIGIN OF U.S. IMPORTS OF CONSUMER ELECTRONIC PRODUCTS AND SELECTED COMPONENTS, 1966
lIn t
housands of dollarsj
Tele-
vision
Country of origin receiving
sets
Phono-
Radio graphs,
receiving sound
sets recorders,
and parts
Active
compo-
nents
Passive
compo-
nents
Total
Percent
which
each
area is
of total
Canada $9,543
Latin America
Total, Western Europe 160
$11,111 $371
210
11, 390 51, 790
$5,077
345
41,696
$1,990
127
10, 055
$28,092
682
115, 091
4.8
. 1
19.9
EEC 135
EFTA
Other Western Europe
8,451 17, 128
898 33, 807
2,042 855
24,651
8,860
8, 186
6,967
2,444
644
57,332
46, 009
11,727
9.9
7.9
2. 0
Japan 106,754
Other Asia
Other Countries, NES
135,239 78,947
32, 779
374 322
35,712
19,474
229
24,503
1,499
425
380,615
53,752
1, 340
65.7
9. 3
0.2
Total of above 116,457
191,103 131,430
101,983
38,599
579,572
100.0
Source: United Nations, "Commodity Trade Statistic," Statistical papers series D, vols. XII, XIV, and XVI; U.S. Depart.
ment of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, FT 246.
Together these two Asian countries account for 75 percent of the
imports of these products.
Thus, it is labor intensive. It is low wage Asian in its nature.
Now, let us turn to what transpired in the Kennedy round. Mem-
bers of this committee have asked other witnesses what kind of a job
was done in regard to your industry in the Kennedy round.
In my prepared statement I have set forth three paragraphs from a
statement submitted by the president of the entire Electronic Indus-
tries Association, not just a spokesman for one division, the spokesman
for the entire organization, to the Trade Information Committee.
The full text of that statement is attached as exhibit 1 to my state-
ment. Let me just read the last paragraph.
In the Kennedy Round the U.S. electronics industry entered the negotiations
with generally the lowest tariffs, and after, in most instances a 50 percent cut of
U.S. tariffs we made the greatest concessions and emerged with an even more
unbalanced tariff rate structure than we had before.
If the electronic industries were viewed by the Government as an
industry with export potential why didn't they secure reciprocal con-
cessions from other countries to help our exports?
Now, I have submitted as an exhibit the full text, exhibit 2, of an ex-
tremely important analysis by the Marketing Services Division of
Electronic Industries Association in detail of the tariff concessions
granted on electronic products by every major country in the Kennedy
round, followed by a very precise analysis of the impact of the border
tax on electronic exports going into these countries.
PAGENO="0088"
3524
You gentlemen want chapter and verse. Here it is in electronic
products.
In my prepared testimony I summarize from that rather massive
study these important points: The first point set out is that the Com-
mon Market granted no tariff reductions in five product categories-
computers, semiconductors, TV picture tubes, electronic test and meas-
uring instruments and parts. These are areas where we had export
potential and we got no reductions. Second, starting at lower base
rates than the common external tariff of the Common Market, the
United States reduced duties up to 50 percent on products that ac-
counted for 95.7 percent of imports from the Common Market. Vir-
tually everything they ship here they got a concession on.
Point 3, the product categories in which the Common Market
granted less than 50 percent reductions equaled 34 percent of our ex-
ports; and point 4, the Common Market made 50 percent reductions
on categories accounting for only 17 percent.
Look at table 9. Here is the discouraging record laid out for you
to see. This table takes each of the products we are talking about,
shows you what the tariff rate is for the United States after the Ken-
nedy round, what it is for Japan, what it is for the Common Market
and United Kingdom.
TABLE 9.-IMPORT DUTY RATES OF THE UNITED STATES, JAPAN, AND EUROPEAN PRODUCERS OF CONSUMER
ELECTRONIC PRODUCTS AND COMPONENTS (POST-KENNEDY ROUND) (PERCENT)
United States Japan EEC United
Kingdom
Television receiving sets 5. 0 10 14. 0 15. 0
215
Radio receiving sets 6.0 9. 0 14. 0 15. 0
`10.4 117.5
Radio-phonographs 6. 5 17. 5 14. 0 15. 0
Phonographs, sound recorders, and parts 5. 5 15. 0 9. 5 10. 0
Receiving tubes 6. 0 10. 0 8. 0 20. 0
Transistors 6. 0 15. 0 17. 0 20. U
37.5
Capacitors 10. 0 7. 5 7. 0 12. 5
Resistors 6.0 7.5 8.0 17.0
Inductors 7.5 7.5 5.5,7.0 10.0
Other radio parts 6. 0 10. 0 9, 13, 17. 0 15. 0
Other TV parts 5. 0 10. 0 9, 13, 17. 0 15. 0
1 Transistor.
2 Not over 10 in. screen.
3 Germanium.
Source: Office of the special representative for trade negotiations, "Re~port on U.S. Negotiations, General Agreement on
Tariffs and Trade, 1964-67 trade conference," Geneva, Switzerland; GATT, "Legal Instruments Embodying the Results of
he 1964-67 Trade Conference."
You will notice in virtually every instance we are lower than all
of the rest, and notice that most of our duties are now at the level of
5 or 6 percent, and none of them exceeds 10 percent.
One final thing. The AFL-CIO in testimony here endorsed negotia-
tion of import restrictions similar to the long-term cotton textile
arrangement, and I am quoting from its testimony: "Affecting trade
in industries that are sensitive to disruption by rapidly rising imports
and unfair competition."
In my prepared statement I have also set out two excerpts from the
testimony of the president of the International Union of Electrical
Workers submitted to the Trade Information Committee.
PAGENO="0089"
3525
I will not read it, but the first quoted paragraph describes the im-
port problem in a manner entirely consistent with the way we have
identified it.
The second quoted paragraph says that this problem has been aggra-
vated by American companies that have transferred their plants
abroad, closed out their jobs in the United States, and created jobs in
low-wage nations.
Gentlemen, it is such companies who are represented by the Con-
sumer Products Division in their testimony here today. They have
caused and contributed to this import problem and they are here now
defending that position by resisting import quotas.
Now, I say finally that the Collier bill which we advocate is designed
to do exactly what the president of the International Union of Electri-
cal Workers wants to have done to create a negotiating climate so that
a harmonious solution can be achieved by the President through
negotiations.
Finally, I will merely refer to my final exhibit, exhibit 3, which is
a very extensive treatment of the ills of our Antidumping Act and its
administration. This industry has filed antidumping complaints on
virtually every electronic product that we are talking about, and they
have been filed over a period extending from July of 1967 to March
of 1968.
Investigations have been started on a few of these products. We
already know enough from working with the Treasury Department
on these products that the result seems to us to be foreordained. The
problems inherent in the way the Antidumping Act is administered
are set out in detail in exhibit 3, but I can summarize it, I think, in
two sentences.
The amendments that were made in the Antidumping Act in 1958
and in the antidumping regulations together accomplished this im-
proper result. They allowed other countries to export to the United
States on the basis of incremental pricing, prices that recover only their
direct costs, and do not recover overhead and profit, and allow the for-
eigners to explain away the difference between those prices and their
home market prices on the basis of uncorroborated, unsworn testimony
by saying that "The conditions of sale in our home country are different
from those in the export trade, and we assign a certain monetary value
to those differences," and this explains away the dumping.
Under the present Antidumping Act and regulations it will never be
possible for any American industry victimized by incremental price
dumping to secure anything significant, really, by way of relief. So we
are an industry which, if we are to survive, must have some method of
import regulation apart from the duties, because now our duties have
been destroyed.
We want the solution to our import problem to be negotiated, a har-
monious solution, and we say that you must create a negotiating situa-
tion by legislation that confronts the foreign producers and their gov-
ernments with the situation that "either you take the statutory quotas
or benchmarks, or you negotiate a more favorable but still reasonable
position."
As to the administration's trade bill, this group recommends that the
reform that would be carried out by amendment of the adjustment as-
PAGENO="0090"
3526
sistance provisions by supplying a more liberal test, an easier test to
meet, also be carried out in regard to escape clause applications by do-
mestic industries seeking tariff relief.
There is absolutely no justification for a double standard of economic
morality in the relief provisions of the Trade Expansion Act.
Gentleman, thank you and Mr. Chairman, thank you for your suf-
ferance in allowing me to go overtime.
(Mr. Stewart's prepared statement and exhibits follow:)
STATEMENT OF EUGENE L. STEWART, COUNSEL, PARTS DIvIsION, AND DISTRIBUTOR
PRODUCTS DIvISION, ELECTRONIC INDUSTRIES ASSOCIATION; AND AMERICAN
LOUDSPEAKER MANUFACTURERS ASSOCIATION
Mr. Chairman and Members of the Co~nmittee, I am Eugene L. Stewart, Special
Counsel for the Parts Division, Electronic Industries Association. I have with
me today:
W. L. Larson, President, Switchcraft, Inc., and Vice Chairman, EIA Parts
Division;
R. W. Woodbury, President, Sprague Products Company, and Vice Ohair~
man, EIA Distributor Products Division;
Herbert Rowe, President, The Muter Company; Vice President, American,
Loudspeaker Manufacturers Association; and Member, World Trade Com-
mittee, MA Parts Division;
Tyler Nourse, Staff Vice President, EIA Parts Division and Distributor
Products Division;
Noel Baird, Executive Vice President, Heppner Manufacturing Company;
Barry Brennan, President, Fiber Form Corporation;
C. G. Kilen, Vice President, Marketing and Sales, Sprague Electric
Company;
Walter Peek, Vice President, Customer Relations, Centralab, Electronics
Division of Globe-Union, Inc.;
W. L. Rollins, President, Oaktron Industries, Inc.; and
H. A. Williams, Vice President and General Manager, Electronic Com-
ponents Division, Stackpole Carbon Company, and Member, World Trade
Committee, EIA Parts Division.
PAGENO="0091"
3527
INTRODUCTION
This testimony is on behalf of U. S. manufacturers of
electronic parts and components, which are members of the Parts Division,
and on behalf of the members of the Distributor Products Division of
the Electronic Industries Association, and the American Loudspeaker
Manufacturers Association.
Electronic parts and components are the building blocks
from which finished electronic products, such as radios and televisions,
are assembled.
There is no single "industry" known as the electronics
industry. Instead, a group of distinct industries is referred to as
the "electronic industries" because the articles they manufacture have
one thing in common - the utilization of an electronic circuit.
Thus electronic products are scattered among an enormous
spectrum of consumer, industrial, defense, and space hardware: from
transistor radios to airborne computers; from electronic organs to
measuring instruments on an assembly line. Neither the production
nor the marketing of these, widely differing products lends itself to
PAGENO="0092"
3528
the grouping of establishments which use electronic circuits in the
products they make into a homogeneous industry. There are more than
25 classifications of the Standard Industrial Classification at the
1+-digit level which embrace electronic products within their product
definition.
You need to know this in order to evaluate some of the
statistics which our opponents like to use in their efforts to defeat
the imposition of any regulation on imports of electronic articles.
II. THE IMPACT OF ADVERSE FOREIGN TRADE BALANCES AND TRENDS
ON THE IMPORT-SENSITIVE MANUFACTURE OF CONSLR~IER ELECTRONIC
PRODUCTS AND COMPONENTS SHOULD BE CONSIDERED ON ITS
fr'ERITS WIThOUT BEING CONFUSED WITH ]1-IE MORE FAVORABLE
FOREIGN TRADE POSITION OF LESS IMPORT-SENSITIVE SECTORS
OF THE "ELECTRONIC" INDUSTRIES.
The group I represent is concerned solely with the damaging
imports of consumer electronic products and the classes of electronic
components used in the manufacture of such products. In other words,
we are centering our attention solely on radios, televisions, phonographs,
and tape recorders, and components such as capacitors, resistors,
inductors, loudspeakers, record changers, fractional horsepower motors,
and other parts used in the assembly of such consumer products.
We definitely are not now seeking your attention to the
regulation of imports of nonconsumer electronic products such as
computers; instruments; or commercial, industrial, or governmental
commun i cat ions systems.
PAGENO="0093"
3529
Perhaps an analogy to other industries would help you under-
stand this point. The steel industry is commonly understood to consist
of those establishments engaged in making basic steel mill products.
No one suggests that it can be studied only by sweeping into the data
every type of article made in this country which contains steel. Auto-
mobiles, for example, are not included in the statistics of the steel
industry. Nor should computers or missile guidance systems be included
in the data of the electronic industries whose problems we are asking
you to consider in these hearings.
So much for terminology. Before summarizing the pertinent
facts concerning the import problem in consumer electronic products
and the types of electronic components used in such products, wish
to clear up another possible matter of confusion. I speak only for
the Parts Division of the Electronic Industries Association, which
represents components manufacturers, the Distributor Products Division
of EtA which represents American manufacturers of components and equipment
sold through electronic parts distributors, and the American Loudspeaker
Manufacturers Association which represents domestic manufacturers of
loudspeakers and their suppliilrs.
The position we advocate is opposed by the Consumer Products
Division of the Electronic Industries Association, which represents
importers and some manufacturers of products such as radios, televisions,
tape recorders, and phonographs. That Division's position is based
on the vote of companies which account for less than a majority of the
U. S. production of such products, and is heavily weighted by companies
PAGENO="0094"
3530
which are primarily importers of either consumer electronic products
or the electronic components used in their assembly.
They are the importers; we are the domestic producers.
They want to be unrestricted in the importation of components - and
of the finished radio and television sets. We want to see some participa-
tion of domestic manufacturers in supplying the U. S. market. Our
economic interests appear to be opposed. They want to protect their
investment in foreign plants; we want to protect our investment in
American plants, and in the employment which our U. S. investment has
created. We are both `protectionists" in this sense; but they wrap
their protectionism in the appealing semantics of free trade.
If opposition meant that you should not consider the merits
of the problem, we are finished before we start. We doubt that this
great Committee will refuse to consider our problem merely because
spokesmen for consumer products manufacturers, importers, and distributors
are opposed to our position.
III. DUE IN PART TO RISING IMPORTS, THE CONSUMER ELECTRONIC
PRODUCTS AND COMPONENTS INDUSTRIES HAVE SUFFERED A 16%
LOSS OF EMPLOYMENT SINCE Ti-IE FALL OF 1966; THE STAKE
OF THE COMPONENTS INDUSTRY IN EMPLOYMENT AND THE THREAT
OF JOB LOSS FROM IMPORTS ARE 2½ TIMES THAT OF THE
CONSUMER PRODUCTS INDUSTRY.
It is essential that you understand that the interest of
our country in investment in plants in the United States, and in the
jobs such plants generate, lies in a fair consideration of the problem
of the components manufacturers. Let me illustrate this by citing the
PAGENO="0095"
3531
relative employment figures for consumer electronic product manufacture
versus electronic component manufacture in the United States.
TABLE 1
EMPL0Yt~ENT IN SELECTED ELECTRONIC INDUSTRIES, APRIL 1968
(in thousands)
Consumer electronic products 133.8
(Standard Industrial Classification 365)
Electronic components and accessories 350.4
(Standard Industrial Classification 367)
SOURCE: U. S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor
Statistics, Enrployrnent and Earnings, May 1968.
Obviously, the United States has nearly three times the
stake in jobs in the electronic components industry as it does in
consumer electronic products.
Both groups have reason to be concerned with the sharp
loss of jobs in U. S. plants. From its peak employment in November
1966 of 178.8 thousand workers, the consumer electronic products industry
lost 45 thousand jobs by April 1968. From its peak in October 1966
of 396.3 thousand employees, the electronic components industry lost
45.9 thousand jobs by April 1968. Together these two interdependent
industries lost 91 thousand jobs in the space of 18 months - and the
loss shows every indication of continuing.
One of the reasons for this loss, though not the sole reason,
is the swift rise in imports of both consumer electronic products and
of electronic components.
PAGENO="0096"
3532
IV. RISING IMPORTS OF CONSU~IER ELECTRONIC PRODUCTS AND OF
COMPONENTS USED IN THE MANUFACTURE OF SUCH PRODUCTS HAVE
CAPTURED A MAJOR AND STILL-RISING SHARE OF THE DOMESTIC
MARKET, FAR BEYOND THE MARKET-DISRUPTIVE LEVELS AT WriICH
POSITIVE IMPORT-REGULATING MEASURES HAVE BEEN RECOGNIZED
AS A NECESSITY IN SUCH FIELDS AS TEXTILES, PETROLELZ~I
PRODUCTS, MEAT PRODUCTS, AND DAIRY PRODUCTS.
Imports of consumer products have a double effect: they
displace radios, televisions, and phonographs produced here at home;
they also cut down the U. S. market for components by the amount of
set manufacture which they displace.
Let's look at the facts.
TABLE 2
U. S. IMPORTS OF CONSUMER ELECTRONIC PRODUCTS
(in thousands of units)
1st 1st
Quarter Quarter %
_______ _______ _________ 1967 1968 ~g~g4
TV 715 369 308 -l6.5°/~
Radios 13,739 L~,865 5,~514 +l2.l~
Phonographs 2,363 503 1i07 -l9.l~
Tape Recorders 3,075 l,o~+3e 1,282 +22.9~
Value of above $212.6
% Change
1966 1967 1964-67
l,52~+ 1,6l~~ +l25.75~
21+,950 2~,20l +76.1i~
1+,223 i+,131i +714.9°/C
2,807 3,780 +22.9°~
(in millions of dollars)
$390.2 $1i58.8 ÷ll5.8?~
$92.3 $1014.6 +13.3°/a
e - estimated at the ratio of change in value, based on units published
for 1st Quarter 1968 (n.a. in 1967).
SOURCE: Marketing Services Department, Electronic Industries Association;
U. S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. -
PAGENO="0097"
3533
These swiftly rising imports have taken a very large share
of the U. S. market for consumer electronic products. When you look
at the following table, bear in mind that imports of textiles are now
about lO~ of the domestic market.
TABLE 3
IMPORTS OF CONSUIVER ELECTRONIC PRODUCTS AS SHARE OF U. S. MARKET
(in per cent)
let Quarter
1964 1966 1967 1968
TV 7.3~ l2.O~ l14.O9~ ll.O~
Radios (Home) 58.3°~ 7l.7?~ 71~.1~2~ 77.8~
Phonographs 31.k2 1iO.l5~ 143.3~ 3O.O~
Tape Recorders 86.Li~ 76.4~ 82.55~ 85.3~
SOURCE: Derived from import and market data compiled by Marketing
Services Department, Electronic Industries Association.
These consumer electronic products are assemblies composed
of electronic components such as tubes, transistors, capacitors, resistors,
inductors, loudspeakers, etc. The quantity of components imported in
the form of sets is very great. These must be counted in any definitive
determination of total import penetration of the U. S. components market,
just as thesquare yard equivalent of fabric contained in imported apparel
is counted in the efforts directed to restraint of cotton textile imports.
The combined direct (as components) and indirect (as consumer products)
imports of electronic components are shown in the following table.
95-159 0-68-pt. 8-7
PAGENO="0098"
SOURCE: Appendix Table
The rate of increase in imports of theseelectronic products
is obviously so high that they cannot be received into the American
market without causing severe dislocation to American production. The
volume of imports of these components represents a major penetration
of the U. S. market. The extent of this capture of our domestic market
by foreign production is shown in the following table.
3534
TABLE 1~
TOTAL U. S. IMPORTS (DIRECT AND INDIRECT) OF
ELECTRONIC COMPONENTS~ 196'+-1967
(in mil,iions of units)
CLASS OF COMPONENI
l96~+
1966
1967
CHANGE
l96ft~7~
ACTIVE C0t4'ONENTS -
Receiving Tubes
TV Picture Tubes
Transistors
Rectifiers and Diodes
67.7
0.8
149.9
105.6
111.8
1.6
681.6
383.8
85.0
2.0
532.8
`+84.6
+25.5°~~
+lk7.2~
+255.14°/b
+358.82~
PASSIVE COMPONENTS -
Capacitors, Electrolytic
Capacitors, Fixed
Resistors, Fixed
Inductors and Transformers
199.8
785.6
1,019.3
259.7
617.3
1,616.1
2,377.6
551.7
473.8
1,692.6
2,238.8
506.1
+137.1°/b
+ll5.4°/~
+119.6~
+9L+.9~
OThER COMPONENTS -
Controls
Loudspeakers
Record Changers
55.6
25.3
2.3
169.9
55.5
4.6
90.3
48.0
4.1
÷62.5~
+89.5i~
+79.3i~
PAGENO="0099"
3535
TABLE 5
RATIO OF IMPORTS TO U. S. C0frT~1ERCIAL SALES OF
SELECTED ELECTRONIC COMPONENTS, lY6Lf_1967
CLASS OF COMPONENT _______ _______ _______
ACTIVE COMPONENTS -
Receiving Tubes
TV Picture Tubes
Transistors
Rectifiers and Diodes
PASSIVE COMPONENTS -
Capacitors, Electrolytic
Capacitors, Fixed
Resistors, Fixed
Inductors and Transformers
OTHER COMPONENTS -
Con trols
Loudspeakers
Record Changers
SOURCE: Appendix Table II
From the data in this table it is obvious that imported
electronic components have achieved a major and steadily rising penetration
of the U. S. market. It is this very high volume, rapid increase in
imports and the very large and rising share of the U. S. market accounted
for by foreign-produced components which are contributing to the absolute
loss of employment in this once dynamic industry to which referred
a moment ago.
l96~i
~j366
~967
2O.l~
27.6~
29.2~
8.5~«=
l2.l~
l8.7?~
lO2.7°~
227.3?~
2L+2.3?~
l7.6~
3l.9?~
~i3.O?~
92.6?«=
l7l.L~
l69.9~
45.6~c
62.5~«=
92.7~
35.21~«=
52.2~
ll2.7~
479 .6~«=
58l.O~c
532.6~
n.a.
66.4~
n.a.
5O.O~
82.4~
lO9.l0~
n.a.
5l.7~
n.a.
PAGENO="0100"
3536
We ask this Committee to report legislation which will
bring this very destructive import situation under some measure of
reasonable control. We are not asking for a substantial rollback
in imports. Instead, we ask that the future growth of imports be
brought into some reasonable relationship to the total growth of the
U. S. market.
Neither the electronic components industry nor any other
American industry should be subjected to such uncontrolled and massive
attacks upon its domestic market in so short a space of time as is
indicated by the data which have presented. Obviously, the electronic
components industry is much more severely affected by imports than
those few industries which have been the recipient of some means of
positive import control, such as textiles and petroleum products.
V. THE U. S. BALANCE OF PAYfrENTS HAS BEEN SERIOUSLY
AFFECTED BY A SEVERE IMBALANCE IN U. S. FOREIGN TRADE
IN CONSU~1ER ELECTRONIC PRODUCTS AND COMPONENTS.
Aside from the welfare of the domestic industry producing
electronic components and of its employees, there is also an urgent need
for the Congress to provide positive control over the foreign trade
in consumer electronic products and components for balance of payments
reasons. The size and growth of our Nation's balance of trade deficit
in these import-sensitive electronic products are shown in the following
table.
PAGENO="0101"
3537
TABLE 6
U. S. BALANCE OF TRADE IN CONSUMER ELECTRONIC PRODUCTS
AND CCMPONENTSJ 196~+_1967
(in millions of dollars)
1961+ 1966 1967
EXPORTS
Consumer Electronic Products $ 614.2 $ 76.8 $ 76.6
Active Components 72.2 87.0 79.1
Passive and Other' Components 39.2;~ 131.3~ 1L+5.O~
Total r175.6~ j295.1~ $ 300.7"
IMPORTS
Consumer Electronic Products $ 212.6 $1,01+.3 $ 1+69.8
Active Components 21.5 68.9 61+.14
Passive and "Other" Components 58.1+ 181.0 159.0
Total $ 292.5 $654.2 $ 693.2
BALANCE OF TRADE
Consumer Electronic Products -$l1+8.1+ -$327.5 -$393.2
Active Components +50.7 +18.1 +114.7
Passive and "Other" Components -37.8~' -63.l;~ -19.9"
Total -$116.9" -$359.1" -$392.5"
Export data for Earphones and Head Sets not available, 19614-1967;
1961+ export data not available for Microphones and for Parts for
radio and TV apparatus, phonographs, active and passive components,
and other components.
SOURCE: Appendix Table III
PAGENO="0102"
3538
The balance of trade deficit in these import-sensitive
categories of consumer electronic products and electronic components
of nearly $1i00 million is a serious matter. The fact that this deficit
more than trebled in three years' time is a serious matter.
Thus, the severe impact of these swiftly rising imports
of consumer electronic products and components is harmful not only
to the private sector (that is, to employment in electronic plants
around the country), but also to the public sector by making worse
our Nation's difficult balance of payments situation.
VI. THE MANUFACTURE OF ELECTRONIC COMPONENTS IS HIGHLY
LABOR INTENSIVE - MORE SO THAN MOST MANUFACTURING
INDUSTRIES AND, HENCE, CORRESPONDINGLY MORE
VULNERABLE TO LOW-WAGE IMDORT INJURY.
It is now recognized by the U. S. Government and by other
governments who are signatories to the Long-Term Cotton Textile Arrangement
that the manufacture of cotton textiles is so labor intensive that the
concentration of production for export in row-wage Asian countries results
in market disruption in developed countries. This calls for import
regulation by agreement backed up by quotas, as provided in the Long-Term
Cotton Textile Arrangement, in order to provide for an orderly expansion
of trade that is in the interests of both supplying and recipient countries.
The same principles apply, but with even greater emphasis,
to foreign trade in electronic components. This is shown by. the data
in the following table.
PAGENO="0103"
3539
TABLE 7
COt'FARATIVE LABOR INTENSIVENESS OF ELECTRONIC COMPONENTS
MANUFACTURE IN THE UNITED STATES
PAYROLL AS A % OF -
Value of Value Added
Shi~prnentc by Ma,i~facture
22.22~ 48.fl
21~.8~ 61.1i~
25.92~ 56.3°~
39.6~ 62.O~
42.62~ 5l4.6~
66.O~
38.5~ 56.5?~
14O.5?~ ~
39.O~ 7O.l?~
The above data show that the manufacture of electronic
components is nearly twice as labor intensive as that of the average
of all manufacturing in the United States when judged by the ratio of
payroll costs to the value of shipments. The production of electronic
components is also clearly far more labor intensive than the manufacture
of cotton broadwoven fabrics or of apparel, the central areas of concern
in the import regulation system established in the Long-Term Cotton
Textile Arrangement.
All Manufacturing Establishments
Cotton Broadwoven Fabrics, SIC 2211
Apparel and Related Products, SIC 23
Electronic Components, SIC 367
- Receiving tubes, SIC 3671
- Semiconductors,;'~ SIC 367~~
- Capacitors,* SIC 36792
- Resistors,* SIC 36793
- Coils, transformers, reactors,
and chokes, SIC 3679k
* Establishments with 9O~ or more specialization.
SOURCE: U. S. Department of Commerce, 1963 Census
of Monufactures
PAGENO="0104"
3540
The current ratio of imports of electronic components to
domestic sales (previously shown in Table 5 as ranging from l8.7~ to
532 .6°/b for the broad range of electronic components) vastly exceeds
the similar ratio of lO?~ applicable to cotton textiles.
On a market penetration basis, therefore, imports of electronic
components, because of the greater labor intensiveness of their manufacture,
have been more seriously affected than cotton textiles. Unlike the
special concern shown by the Government for the cotton textile industry
(as evidenced by the negotiation of the Long-Term Cotton Textile Arrange-
ment and the restraint shown in duty reductions in the Kennedy Round),
the electronic components industry has received no assistance in the
form of import regulation from the Government and all but one of its
products was reduced by 5O~ in the Kennedy Round.
As in the case of cotton textiles, the principal source
of U. S. imports of consumer electronic products and components is
Japan and the other low-wage Asian countries. This is shown by the
data in the following table.
PAGENO="0105"
CANADA
LATIN AMERICA
TOTAL WESTERN EUROPE
EEC
EFTA
Other Western Europe
JAPAN
OTHER ASIA
Radio
Rece i vi ng
____________ Sets _______________
$ 11,111 $ 371
210 -
11,390 51,790
8,451 17,128
898 33,807
2,042 855
135,239 78,947
32,779 -
_________ 374 322
$116,457 $191,103 $131,430
Passive
___________ Components
$ 1,990
345 127
41,696 10,055
24,651 6,967
8,860 2,444
8,186 644
35,172 24,503
19,474 1,499
229 425
°~ Which
Each
Area Is
of Total
1+. 8°'~
O.l~
19. 9°~
9.9%
7.9%
2.0%
65.7?~
9.3°'~
0. 22~
TABLE 8
ORIGIN OF U. S._IMPORTS OF CONSWER ELECTRONIC PRODUCTS AND SELECTED CONPONENTS, 1966
(In thousands of dollars)
Country of Oriain
Phonographs,
Sound
Recorders, Active
and Parts Compppents
Televi 5 ion
Receiving
Sets
$ 9,543
160
135
106,754
$ 5,077
OTHER COUNTRIES, NES
TOTAL OF ABOVE
TOTAL
$ 28,092
682
115,091
57,332
46,009
11,727
380,615
53,752
1 ,340
CJ~
:~
$101,983 $ 38,599 * $579,572 lOO.O~
SOURCE: United Nations, Conrinodity Trade Statistics, Statistical Papers Series 0, Volumes XII , XIV, and XVI;
U. S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, FT 246.
PAGENO="0106"
3542
Japan and the other nations of Asia together account for
75°/b of the total U. S. imports of the products covered by the above
table.
The electronic products import problem is an Asian problem.
It is compounded by the highly labor-intensive nature of electronic
component manufacturing in the United States, on the one hand, and
the low wages prevailing in the electronic manufacturing industries
of Japan, Hong Kong, and Taiwan, on the other han.d.
The remaining factor of significance which contributes
to the dimensions of the problem is the very low level of duties which
remain after repeated reductions in U. S. duties, and the further
virtually 5O2~ reduction in duties which the United States has agreed
to in the Kennedy Round.
VII. U. S. IMPORT DUTIES HAVE BEEN DESTROYED BY SEVERE TARIFF
REDUCTIONS AS AN IMPORT-REGULATING MEANS; OThER MEASURES
ARE REQUIRED IF U. S. MANUFACTURE AND EMPLOYMENT IN
THESE. ELECTRONIC INDUSTRIES ARE TO BE PRESERVED.
As a result of repeated tariff reductions in the past,
which were carried forward in virtually all cases by a 5O~ reduction
in the Kennedy Round, the present and post-Kennedy Round level of
U. S. import duties on consumer electronic products and the import-
sensitive classes of components identified in this testimony are below
the level of duties applicable to the other principal markets for such
products.
PAGENO="0107"
3543
The results of the tariff bargaining in the electronics
sector in the Kennedy Round were so unfair to the U. S. producers of
electronic articles that the following assessment was made on behalf
of all of the U. S. electronic industries in a statement filed on
behalf of the Electronic Industries Association by its President with
the Trade Information Committee:1
"While it may be too early to determine the full
effects of the Kennedy Round it appears, on the basis of
information available, that the Uni.ted States delegation
gave more than it received so far as tariffs on electronic
products are concerned, especially to the European Economic
Community. Continuing nontariff barriers, added to higher
tariffs in both the Common Market and Japan, aggravate
the problem of U. S. exporters who strive to increase
their exports.
It does seem to us that American trade representa-
tives may not have recognized the opportunities for further
expansion of U. S. exports of electronic products and the
consequent beneficial effect on our balance of payment.
Had the tariff reductions agreed to in Geneva been fully
reciprocal, both our industry and our nation would have
benefi tted.
"In the Kennedy Round the U. S. electronics industry
entered the negotiations with generally the lowest tariffs,
and after, in most instances, a 50 per cent cut of U. S.
tariffs we made the greatest concessions and emerged with
an even more unbalanced tariff rate structure than we had
before." (p. 2)
The unfairness implicit in the comparative level of import
duties on electronic products, the United States versus Japan and the EEC,
is aggravated by the border taxes and export rebates practiced by the EEC
1 Full text of the statement is attached as Exhibit 1.
PAGENO="0108"
3544
nations. Members of the Ways and Means Committee have manifested
a keen interest in these hearings in receiving specific information
concerning the quality of the Kennedy Round negotiations affecting
U. S. industries. Fortunately, an incisive analysis of the Kennedy
Round tariff concessions on electronic products has been prepared and
published by the Marketing Services Department, Electronic Industries
Association, in its authoritative publication Electronic Trends Inter-
national (issue of May 1968). This analysis is set forth in full text
in Exhibit 2 to this statement. The following points are based upon
that analysis:
1. The E. E. C. granted no tariff reductions in five
product categories: Computers, Semiconductors, TV
Picture Tubes, Electronic Test and Measuring Instru-
ments, and Parts for Instruments. These categories
accounted for 48.6~ of U. S. electronic exports to
the E. E. C. in 1967.
2. Starting at lower base rates than the l3.O?~ Common
External Tariff of the E. E. C., the U. S. reduced
duties up to 5O2~ on products which accounted for
95.7~ of imports from the E. E. C.
3. The product categories in which the E. E. c. granted
less than 5O.O~ reductions equaled 31.5~ of total
U. S. electronic exports to the E. E. C. in 1967.
14* The E. E. C. made 5O.O~ reductions on categories
accounting for only l6.9~ of total U. S. electronic
exports to the E. E. C. in 1967.
The effect of the EEC border taxes on the total landed cost
of U. S. exports to EEC countries in comparison with the much lower
PAGENO="0109"
3545
landed costs of comparably factory-priced goods entering the United
States is shown at pages 21+a-25b of Exhibit 2. To illustrate the burden
of these border taxes, that analysis shows that the landed cost of
U. S.-produced television receiving sets exported to EEC countries
with factory invoice prices identical to those produced in the EEC
ranged from ll5~ to l42?~ of the landed cost of EEC-produced television
sets imported into the United States.
For semiconductors, the comparison shown by the same analysis
is a range for the landed cost of U. S. exports to EEC from ll2~ to
l28~ of the landed cost of EEC-produced semiconductors imported into
the United States.
For capacitors, the similar comparison is a landed cost
for U. S.-produced articles exported to Europe ranging from lO5°/~ to
l2O2~ of the landed cost of similar products produced in Europe imported
into the United States.
Because of the labor-intensive character of electronic
components manufacture and the higher wage levels which prevail in
the United States in comparison with other producers, our costs of
production exceed those in other countries. This is not a new or
surprising fact, but it needs to be taken into account in considering
the relative level to which U. S. duties on our products have been reduced
in trade agreement negotiations. It is especially noteworthy that other
countries, including Japan, have resisted such extravagant reductions
in their duties. The situation is summarized in the following table.
PAGENO="0110"
TABLE 9
IMPORT DUTY RATES OF THE U. S., JAPAN, AND EUROPEAN PRODUCERS OF
CONSUMER ELECTRONIC PRODUCTS AND COMPONENTS (POST-KENNEDY ROUND)
UN lIED
UNITED STATES JAPAN EEC KINGDOM
Television Receiving Sets 5% 10% 1L% 15%
15% (not over 10" screen)
Radio Receiving Sets 6% 9% 15%
10.4% (transistor) 17.5% (transistor)
Radio-Phonographs 6.5% 17.5% 1L,% 15%
Phonographs, Sound
Recorders, and Parts 5.5% 15% 9.5% 10%
Receiving Tubes 6% , 10% 8% 20%
Transistors 6% 15% 17% 20%
7.5% (germanium)
Capacitors 10% 7.5% 7% 12.5%
Resistors 6% 7.5% 8% 17%
Inductors 7.5% 7.5% 5.5% and 7% 10%
Other Radio Parts 6% 10% 9%, 13%, 17% 15%
Other TV Parts 5% 10% 9%, 13%, 17% 15%
SOURCE: Office of the Special Representative for Trade Negotiations, Report on United States Negotiations~
GENERAL AGREEMENT ON TARIFFS AND TRADE 1964-67 TRADE CONFEREINCE, Geneva, Switzerland; GAIT, Legal
Instruments Embodying the Results of the 1964-67 Trade Conference.
PAGENO="0111"
3547
In view of the high rate of increase of imports already
established under the pre-Kennedy Round rates of duty, as shown by
the data for l961,-l967, previously discussed, both the 5O~ reductions
in duty in the Kennedy Round and the resulting level of U. S. duties -
generally below those of the other nations producing electronic products -
hold ominous implications for the electronic components industry.
The Kennedy Round reductions can only serve to stimulate
further the rapid increase of imports; the comparative lack of success
in exporting in the past will not be changed by the situation left in
the aftermath of the unequal tariff bargaining in the Kennedy Round
in which the U. S. electronic industries confront higher levels of duties
abroad than their foreign competitors will enjoy in the U. S. market.
In these circumstances, the Parts Division of the Electronic
Industries -Association, on behalf of its own members and those of the
Distributor Products Division, EtA, and the American Loudspeaker Manu-
facturers Association, urges the Committee to give favorable consideration
to the electronic products import quota bills (H. R. 11f597 and similar
bills).
The electronic products bill has been described by a free-
trade organization, the Canadian-American Committee, National Planning
Association (U. S. A.), in its analysis of the pending quota proposals
as a type which would bring no immediate cut in imports and cause the
least impairment thereafter."2
2 Canadian-American Committee, National Planning Association (U. S. A.),
Constructive Alternatives to Proposals for U. S. Import Quotas, p. 26
(February 1968). -
PAGENO="0112"
3548
We also support the Collier bill, H. R. 17671,, which provides
for similar liberal treatment and flexible administration of rising
import quotas in the future for the basic steel, footwear, flat glass,
meat products, and electronic products industries, with a general
procedure under which other industries which become similarly over-
burdened by excessive and market-disruptive imports in the future
could seek similar relief through a Tariff Commission investigation.
The electronic products import quota bill, like the Collier
bill, is constructive in its delegation of plenary trade agreement
authority to the President to adjust the statutory quotas through nego-
tiation with affected countries to seek amicable solutions to the import
problem, much in the way that the Long-Term Cotton Textile Arrangement
was negotiated amicably and without retaliation by the United States
and many other nations under the auspices of GATT.
We believe it of major importance that the AFL-CIO in its
testimony before this Committee reversed its prior position of unqualified
opposition to trade restrictions and urged that international agreements
similar to the Long-Term Cotton Textile Arrangement be concluded "affecting
trade in industries that are sensitive to disruption by rapidly rising
imports and unfair competition." The AFL-CIO recognized in its testimony
that labor-intensive operations in electronics manufacture have become
the object of runaway shops in foreign-based plants which lead to the
loss of actual and potential jobs for U. S. workers.
PAGENO="0113"
3549
The International Union of Electrical Workers, which repre-
sents workers in some electronic plants, also recently recognized in
its testimony before the Trade Information Committee that,3
"The major problem area [in foreign trade in electronic
productsj is the large growth of imports, chiefly from
Japan in the fields of small radio receivers, small TV
receivers, cheap tape recorders and a number of components.
In addition, imports of these products are growing in
some of the low wage areas of the Far East, such as Hong
Kong, Formosa, Korea, etc." (p. 21)
The IUE also correctly identified runaway American plants
as one cause of this major problem. It stated -
"Unfortunately, what has been happening is that
many American companies have been moving from country
to country in search of places where they can get the
cheapest wage rates. As a matter of fact, a great many
of the products that come into this country sold under
the names of our large corporations are made abroad and
the consumer does not know that." (p. 22)
Nevertheless, the IUE opposed enactment of the electronic
products import quota bill. Instead, it proposed that "our government
initiate a conference of nations principally involved in trade in
electronics to work out harmonious solutions." The President of the
UE stated that he will be going to Japan this month where he intends
to discuss these problems.
Unfortunately, the IUE executive appears not to have had
called to his attention the fact that the principal purpose of the
~ Statement of Paul Jennings, President, before the Trade Information
Committee, Office of Special Representative, April 11, 1968, pp. 21, 22.
95-159 0 - 66 - pt. 8- 8
PAGENO="0114"
3550
electronic products import quota bill is to achieve "harmonious solu-
tions" to the import problem through governmental action. It is for
this reason that the bill, and the Collier bill, would grant plenary
authority to the President to enter into trade agreements with countries
supplying electronic products to the United States to achieve mutually
agreeable solutions to the problem.
Harmonious solutions depend upon negoti ations. Negoti at ions
require for their success that each of the parties possess a negotiating
position. The electronic products import quota bills, and the Collier
bill, are designed to create a negotiating position for the President
by setting up a system of statutory quotas - liberal in themselves -
which can be liberalized through negotiations.
We cite this Union testimony to you because of its importance
in recognizing specifically the dimensions of the electronic products
import problem as we recognize it, and in calling upon the Government
to utilize negotiations in the manner of the Cotton Textile Arrangement
to achieve a solution to the problem. Negotiations cannot take place
simply by virtue of the wish of one side. Some definite act must set
the stage for the negotiations. The bills are designed upon their enact-
ment to set the stage and to move the forces into action which can bring
about negotiations.
PAGENO="0115"
3551
VIII. THE ELECTRONIC COMPONENTS INDUSTRY IS BEING HARMED
BY WIDESPREAD DUV1PING OF ELECTRONIC PRODUCTS /~ND
IMPROPER ADMINISTRATION OF ThE ANTIDU4PING ACT
BY THE TREASURY DEPARTMENT.
U. S. producers of electronic components are alarmed by
the widespread dumping of a wide range of electronic components and
by consumer electronic products incorporating these components. Anti-
dumping complaints have been filed in regard to the following electronic
products: black and white and color television receiving sets, color
television picture tubes, electron receiving tubes, resistors, capacitors,
inductors (transformers), loudspeakers, deflection yokes, tuners, and
ferrite cores.
These complaints have been filed over a period of time
extending from July 1, 1967, through March22, 1968. Thus far formal
antidumping investigations have been announced by the Treasury Department
in the case of black and white and color television receiving sets,
electron receiving tubes, and resistors. An announcement by'Treasury
of the formal initiation of antidumping investigations in the other
cases is hopefully and anxiously awaited.
Experience thus far in the recent administration of the
Antidumping Act offers little encouragement for prompt or effective
action by the Treasury in checking the widespread, unfair trade practices
which characterize the import trade in consumer electronic products
and components.
In these hearings, members of the Committee have expressed
a çLefinite interest in receiving specific information concerning problems
PAGENO="0116"
3552
encountered by domestic industry in the administration of the Antidumping
Act. As a service to the Committee and in the hope that discussion of
these problems will lead to some administrative reform if not positive
legislation, we offer as Exhibit 3 to this statement a detailed d~iscussion
of the many problems which currently exist in the administration of the
Anti dumping Act. The help of the Committee in achieving a correction
of these problems is earnestly solicited.
IX. CONCLUSION AND RECO11VIENDATIONS.
The manufacture of consumer electronic products and of
electronic components is carried on in 1f2 of the 50 States of the Union.
(See Appendix Table IV ranking the States in order of importance by
size of employment in the manufacture of these electronic products.)
The loss of employment in these electronic industries has a widespread
effect on workers and their communities throughout the United States.
The degree of market penetration by imports and the rate
of increase of imports are so great that prompt remedial action is
required.by direction of the Congress. We urge that this action be
in the form of the enactment of equitable import controls affording
fair access to both domestic and foreign-produced electronic products
commensurate with the future growth of the American market, in the
manner set forth in H. R. 14597 and similar bills, or, the Collier bill,
H. R~ 17674.
In addition, the widespread dumping of electronic products
in the United States market calls for prompt reform of ineffective
PAGENO="0117"
3553
and improper administration of the Antidumping Act by the Treasury
Department. The enactment of H. R. 16332 and similar bills, and legis-
lative oversight of the administration of the Antidumping Act by this
Committee are needed in order to accomplish this reform.
We urge that these legislative actions be taken by way
of amendment to the Administration's trade bill, and that in addition
the following amendment be made to the present language of that bill:
Amendment of Section 301 (b) (1) and (3) of the Trade
Expansion Act of 1962 in accordance with the substance
of the amendments proposed by the Administration to
Section 30l(c)(l), (2), and (3).
This would complete a reform of the so-called "escape clause"
[tariff adjustment] procedure of the Trade Expansion Act by extending
to petitions filed by domestic industries for tariff relief the same
reform in procedure which the Administration now proposes for the
consideration of petitions by firms and groups of workers for nontariff
relief.
This concludes our statement. Thank you.
PAGENO="0118"
3554
EXHIBIT 1
STATEMENT OF THE ELECTRONIC INDUSTRIES ASSOCIATION
TO THE
TRADE INFORMATION COMMITTEE
WASHINGTON, D. C.
PRESENTED BY
ROBERT W. GALVIN, PRESIDENT
ELECTRONIC INDUSTRIES ASSOCIATION
2001 EYE STREET, .N. W., WASHINGTON, D. C.
This statement is submitted on behalf of members of the Electronic
Industries Association (ETA) which is the national organization of electronic
manufacturers representing all major product categories. Our membership of more
than 300 companies includes large, medium, and small manufacturers. It includes
manufacturers who export and/or import as well as others who do neither.
Understandingly, there are different opinions among our members as to
what the United States foreign policy with respect to imports should be. But there
is no difference of opinion with respect to our national policy on exports. We
are unanimous in the belief that our Government should do everything possible to
improve our export opportunities and the United States balance of payments.
The electronics industry is a relatively new industry, and consequently
it may be that its importance to the American economy has not been fully recognized
in past international trade negotiations. It appears this may have been true in
the recent Kennedy Round of the GATT conferences in Geneva.
EIA was established 44 years ago as the Radio Manufacturers Association.
The industry was still small when the first tariff reductions were effected in the
1930's. Employment probably did not exceed 5,000 or sales $150 million in 1924.
This year electronic factory sales are expected to exceed $23 billion and employ-
ment is well over 1,000,000. U.S. electronic manufacturers now produce an
estimated two-thirds of the world's electronic equipment, based on dollar volume,
,outside the Communist nations. Our industry ranks fifth among U.S. manufacturing
industries.
PAGENO="0119"
3555
EXHIBIT 1
Our electronic exports have grown in recent years to reach $1.75 billion
in 1967, according tq EIA's Marketing Services Department, but the increase has
been largely in the military-industrial area. Imports have increased even more
rapidly to reach $806 million in 1967, and these have been heavily in the consumer
or home entertainment market. They have been in both consumer equipment and in
components. American investments abroad in electronic manufacturing facilities
az~e rising and already amount to several billion dollars.
EIA has cooperated with Government agencies over the years in promoting
international trade among Free World nations. In 1964 we were awarded an
certificate by the Secretary of Commerce for our efforts in this field.
While it may be too early to determine the full effects of the Kennedy
Round it appears, on the basis of information available, that the United States
delegation gave more than it received so far as tariffs on electronic products
are concerned, especially to the European Economic Community. Continuing non-
tariff barriers, added to higher tariffs in both the Common Market and Japan,
aggravate the problem of U.S. exporters who strive to increase their exports.
It does seem to us that American trade representatives may not have
recognized the opportunities for further expansion of U.S. exports of electronic
products and the consequent beneficial effect on our balance of payment. Had the
tariff reductions agreed to in Geneva been fully reciprocal, both our industry
and our nation would have benefitted.
In the Kennedy Round the U.S. electronics industry entered the negotiations
with generally the lowest tariffs, and after, in most instances, a 50 per cent cut
of U.S. tariffs we made the greatest concessions and emerged with an even more
unbalanced tariff rate structure than we had before.
The following examples are illustrative:
PAGENO="0120"
3556
EXHIBIT 1
Electronic products in which the United States is preeminent were
granted little or no concessions by the European Economic Community.
The United States reduced its tariff on computers from 11.5 to 5.5 per
cent, while no concessions were made by the Common Market which has a rate of 14
per cent. The U.S. cut its tariffs on all electronic and measuring equipment
50 per cent as did Japan. The Common Market made a general reduction of 50 per
cent but omitted electronic test and measuring equipment.
The tariffs on transistor radios, on the other hand, were cut sub-
stantially by both Europe and Japan, while the U.S. rate was reduced only from
12.5 to 10.4 per cent. Yet this country imports such radios heavily, chiefly
from Japan, and does little exporting.
U.S. tariffs on electron tubes were cut from 12.5 to 6 per cent; and,
while corresponding reductions were made byEurope and Japan, the American rate
remains less than half that of Japan and under the rates of the Common Market.
Perhaps more striking examples of imbalance in Genevf agreements on
electronic products were tariffs on transistors and semiconductors which American
industry developed and produces in the largest volume. While the U.S. rate was
reduced from 12.5 to 6 per cent, no concessions were made by the Common Market.
Japan limited its reduction to germanium transistors, cutting the rate from 15
to 7~ per cent.
These changes do not appear logical to our industry; they have seriously
impeded our potential to export and increased the U.S. trend to import.
A number of American businessmen, including members of our Association,
are concerned that not enough was done in the Kennedy Round to strike down artificia:
non-tariff barriers to trade. There are extant throughout the world uncalled for
restraints on trade which shackle the flow of goods between nations. This is a
prime area for consideration in the development of U.S. trade policy. Mutual
removal of these barriers to trade will put trade on a fair basis and eliminate
discriminatory, unfair advantages which these barriers create.
PAGENO="0121"
3557
EXHIBIT 1
The U.S. electronics industry as a whole is prosperous today and its
annual sales continue to rise, but more than half of our sales are to Government
agencies and the military services. If and when a Vietnam peace is negotiated -
which we strongly support - a sharp reduction in military requirements may occur.
The need for greater exports then will be accentuated.
Meanwhile, our world competitors, often with direct Government support,
are growing stronger. The United States has helped rebuild their wartorn
industries. We welcome competition in the world market, but we ask that the
rules be the same for all participants and that the American electronics industry
not be handicapped by higher tariffs and non-tariff barriers and licensing limitations
in our rivalry for foreign business.
The U.S electronics industry in some instances has been able to
counter higher tariffs and non-tariff barriers by rapid technological advances.
Much of this research has been an outgrowth of our military programs and has been
heaviest in military and industrial products. But this advantage is likely to
diminish when our defense expenditures are reduced. Meanwhile, our international
competitors are rapidly catching up, often with American licenses.
A good deal of attention should be paid to the emergence of new
taxing systems abroad which will, when in full swing, disadvantage U.S. exports
and simultaneously give an advantage to foreign producers. The rules of the
GATT which set up a dichotomy between direct and indirect taxes should be changed
so as to permit countries such as ours to remedy these disadvantages and to off-
set these advantages.
While recognizing the U.S. Government's concern with its unfavorable
balance of payments position, and the necessity for action to adjust the situation,
we believe that stringent restrictions on foreign investments by U.S. companies
is self-defeating of these objectives. Although curtailment of foreign invest-
ments would decrease the outflow of capital for the short-term, the long-term
impairment of overseas trade would more than outweigh any advantage gained.
PAGENO="0122"
3558
EXHIBIT 1
The expansion of U.S. industry in overseas areas during the past ten
years has been one of the dynamic factors in the growth of the Gross National
Product, and the dollars returned to the United States from overseas operations
of manufacturers have more than compensated for the original investments. Apart
from the purely financial considerations the psychological effect of stringent
restrictions would be immeasurable. We feel that effective alternatives should
be the subject of highest priority to the U.S. Government.
We point out also that the restrictions place an unfair burden on
newer manufacturers while causing few problems to large international companies
that have been manufacturing overseas for many years. Moreover, they are unfair
to companies that participated in the voluntary programs. These companies, as
a consequence of their cooperation, have a smaller base on which to calculate
the amounts which they may reinvest abroad.
These are just a few of the substantive areas which we believe need
close attention during this Committee's current study.
Turning now to the administrative or procedural side of this question,
we believe that all the diversified elements of the U.S. Government concerned
with foreign trade should be centralized in a single agency of cabinet level.
This recommendation is based on the experience and advice of manufacturers who
form our International Department.
At present, in addition to the Office of the Special Representative
for Trade Negotiations, there are elements of the Department of Commerce, Depart-
ment of State, Department of Defense, and many other agencies directly concerned
with aspects of foreign trade. For a company to obtain a major decision it is
often necessary to deal with all these agencies, and frequently several offices
in each, with a consequent loss of time and money. We believe that a single
agency, comparable to the Ministry of Foreign Trade in many other countries,
would go far toward eliminating present confusion and duplication of effort.
PAGENO="0123"
3559
EXHIBIT 1
The Electronic Industries Association would strongly support and
give full cooperation to any governmental effort aimed at simplifying procedures
involved in exporting. As an example, a normal export shipment now requires
completion and presentation to Government agencies of a minimum of eight
documents. We believe that a reduction in this quantity of documentation could
be accomplished at great saving in time and money to both exporters and the
Government.
In view of the recognized importance of international trade we believe
the U.S. Government should undertake an aggressive program of trade development
comparable to that of other countries. In this connection, we support the
efforts of the U.S. Department of Commerce and other agencies to encourage exports
by making information on overseas markets readily available to the business
conssunity, and in the program of trade fairs, trade centers, and trade missions.
We submit the following specific suggestions for your consideration:
(a) It is recommended that the Government place greater
emphasis on assembling information on non-tariff barriers
and making it available to industry, as well as provide
leadership in initiating negotiations for their removal.
(b) We recommend greater participation on the part
of the U.S. Government in international standards. deliberations.
In this we concur with the testimony presented by the U.S.
Standards Institute. Restrictive practices in standards are
notable examples of non-tariff barriers used by other
countries to bar U.S. exports.
(c) We recommend that the Government intensify efforts
to provide business-trained personnel in U.S. embassies as
commercial attaches with the capability and desire to assist
U.S businessmen abroad.
PAGENO="0124"
3560
EXHIBIT 1
The Electronic Industries Association appreciates this opportunity
to present its views on this important matter and stands ready to assist the
efforts of this office in any way proper to achieve the national goal of a
sound U.S. foreign trade policy.
PAGENO="0125"
3561
EXHIBIT 2
ANALYSIS OF THE KENNEDY ROUND TARIFF CONCESSIONS ON ELECTRONIC PRODUCTS
(Reproduced from ELECTRONIC TRENDS INTERNATIONAL, May 1968, pages ?-25b~ prepared
and published bp Marketinq Services Department, Electronic Industries Associ.ats.on)
PART I
1967 E.E.C. - U.S. Trade Flow
and Comparative Tariff Structures
The following narrative and data are not intended as a general commentary
on the results of the Kennedy Round negotiations.
This economic report limits itself to one industrial sector of the U.S.
economy, more precisely defined as the sector which manufactures or distributes
the products and product categories featured as "Selected Electronic Products and
Related Items" in the monthly studies of the International.
Part I discusses the U.S. and E.E.C. trade and tariff structure. To
present a factual and composite picture of total import costs, Part II then relates
the tariff rates to other import charges.
This is a ~ duct oriented marketing study limited to present and future
tariff structures and trade patterns between the U.S. and the E.E.C. References
to tariff rates in the context of this study concern actual reductions, increases
or no concessions --- after the individual member countries of the E.E.C. had
established a common base rate fer negotiations.
The rather liberal interpretation of a tariff concession' as defined by
the General Agreements on Tariff and Trade (G.A.T.T.) has been purposefully Us-
regarded.
"Concession - A commitment undertaken by a participant in the
Kennedy Round, usually with respect to the tariff treatment
of imports of a given product. In such a case, a concession
may be either: (1) a commitment to make a specified reduction
in the rate of duty on a product, or (2) a commitment that the
rate of duty will not be increased or, if the product is duty-
free, that a duty will not be imposed on it. A concession of
the types described in (2) is termed a binding."
By the quoted definition, a frozen tariff rate of 17% applicable through
1972 on semiconductor imports into the E.E.C. is considered a concession.
(a) Report on U.S. Negotiations, Volume I, page 181.
PAGENO="0126"
3562
EXHIBIT 2
A marketing analyst must, however, make a realistic appraisal of the
situation. He is obligated to correlate the `frozen" E.E.C. rate with a further,
economic reality. During a comparable period of time, the tariff rate on semi-
conductor imports into the U.S. will be reduced from 12.5% to 6.0%.
The present analysis further acknowledges and comments on another basic
international marketing principle. The analyst, acting as an agent for a supplier
or one seeking a source of supply, must relate the tariff rate on his' product
category interest to the sum of the intra-industry tariff structure. This is
particularly true of the electronics industry, which is characterized by rapid
technological developments.
During 1967, U. S. exports of "Selected Electronic Products and Related
Items" to the E.E.C. totaled $502.3 million, while counterpart imports from the
E.E.C. ran $128.5 million.
The E.E.C. granted no tariff reductions in five product categories;
Computers, Semiconductors, TV. Picture Tubes, Electronic Test and Measuring
Instruments and Parts for Instruments. These categories are defined as critical,
because they totaled $2141~.l million or L~8.6% of U.S. electronic exports to the
E.E.C. in 1967. (See Table I, pages l0a - lob).
In two categories, Computers and Semiconductors, the U.S. started at
an overall lower tariff rate and granted 50% reductions. The pre Kennedy Round
tariff rate on Computers ran 11.5% and will be reduced to 5,5% by 1972. Semi-
conductors rates were cut from 12.5% to 6.0% over the same period of time.
The E.E.C.'s Common External Tariff (C.X.T.) for Computers was set at
110.0%; for Semiconductors at 17.0% and no reductions were made. These no
reduction rates will be applied against two product categories, which at $155.0
million accounted for 310.5% of total 1967 U.S. electronic exports to the E.E.C. ~.
In TV. Picture Tubes, the trade balance stood slightly in favor of the
E.E.C. The C.X.T. was set and held at 15.0%; while the U.S with a higher pre
Kennedy-Round rate on Monochrome and lower on Color Tubes will equal out at the
set E.E.C. level of 15.0% by 1972.
1967 U.S. exports of Electronic Test and Measuring Instruments to the
E.E.C. totaled $72.2 million. The C.X.T. rate was frozen at 13.0%. During the
same year imports from the E.E.C. ran $11.6 million.
* As of July 1, 1968, the six member countries of the European Economic Community
(E.E.C.) will put into effect.a Common External Tariff (C.X.T.); that is a
product imported into any of the E.E.C. countries will be dutiable at the
same tariff rate applicable to that particular product.
PAGENO="0127"
3563
EXHIBIT 2
Starting at lower base rates than the 13.0% C.X.T. and running up to
50.0% in reductions, the U.S. liberalized rates are applicable to products which
comprised $11.1 million of the $11.6 imported from the E.E.C. (See detailed U.S.
Tariff Structure, Table I, pages lOa - lOb).
As with the finished products, the C.X.T. for Paris of Electronic Test
and Measuring Instruments was set and held at 13.0%. The U.S. reductions equalled
those of the finished products, since the same tariff rates apply to parts.
The product categories in which the E.E.C. granted less than 50.0%
reductions equalled 34.5% of total U.S. electronic exports to the E.E.C. in 1967.
On January 1, 1972, the date when the final Kennedy Round rates are in
effect, the U.S. tariff rates will be lower than the C.X.T. in 14 of the 16 listed
gq~ggories; those in which the E.E.C. reduced less than 50.0%. (See Table II,
pages ha - 12b).
The total extent of the U.S. concessions in this area becomes more
evident when placed in a ratio of reduction perspective.
In 11 of the 16 categories the U.S. started at lower rates than the
E.E.C. and made reductions of
The sixteen categories under discussion have been "basketed' for
facility of presentation. In fact, they include thousands of separate products,
Viewed in the individual product context, disproportionate decreases in several
product categories become extremely significant.
The pre Kennedy Round U.S. tariff rate on all Parts for Electronic O~ta
Processing Machines was 11.0%. The 1972 rate will be 5.5%, a 50.0% reduction.
The E.E.C. will decrease from 11.0% to 10.5% during the same period of time,
A comparable situation is applicable to any product in the Telecommuni-
cations Equipment categories. The U.S. reduced from 12.5% to 6.0%, while the
1.X.T. cut went from 16.0% to 11.0%.
The E.E.C made 50.0% reductions on categories amounting to $84.9 million
or 16.9% of total U.S. electronic exports to the E.E.C. in 1967. (See Table III,
pages 13a - l4b)
As in the E.E.C. no reduction and less than 50% reduction groupings, there
was no change in pattern, In 15 of the 19 categories, the U.S. also made 50% reduc-
tions, with one important qualification; the pre Kennedy Round base rates of these
15 categories were lower than those of the pre Kennedy Round C.X.T.
PAGENO="0128"
U.S. EXPORT CLASSIFICATIONS
Electronic
Computers
Television Picture Tubes
U.S. IMPORT CLASSIFICATIONT
01
cr5
-1
"5
Accounting, Computing, & other
2,78k Dais Processing Machines
19k B.& W.Television Picture Tubes
7,612 Color Television Picture Tubes
12,5 6 3,270 Semiconductors
Measuring, Checking, Pre? ~sing
or Automatically Controlling
Instruments & Apparatus,
~( ~ 11,618 °~ Electronic & Electrical
Parts for Measuring, Checking,
Analyzing, or Automatically
Controlling Instruments &
Apparatus: (3)
Parts of Ship's Logs &
Depth-Sounding Instru-
ments A Apparatus
Parts of Anemometers
The U.S.Tariff Rates A
Import for products in
this category are broken
out as follows:
TABLE I
NO E.E.C. REDUCTION GRANTED
(Add 000)
E.E.C. U.S.
TARIFF RATES TARIFF RATES
U.S. EXPORTS PRE FINAL PRE FINAL U.S. IMPORTS
TO E.E.C. KENNEDY RATE KENNEDY RATE FROM E.E.C.
__ ROUND 7~ ROUND ~ 1967
1l8,2k1 1k 1k 11.5 5.5
30 15
6,977 15 15 ( 12 15
Semiconductors 36,737 17 17
Measuring, Checking,
Analysing or Automatically
Controlling Instruments &
Apparatus, Electronic 72,163 (2) 13 13
Parts for Measuring, Checking,
Analyzing, or Automatically
Controlling Instruments &
Apparatus, Electronic (2) 13 13
50 25
k5 22.5
PAGENO="0129"
Automatic Voltage &
Voltage Current Regulators,
with or without Cut-out
Relays, designed for use
in a 6-volt, 12-volt, or
8,5 4 1,379 24-volt system, and Parts
Automatic Voltage & Voltage-
Current Regulators, with
or without cut-out relays
15 7.5 101 & Parts thereof, N.E.C.
Optical Instruments or Appa-
50 25 62 ratus & Pai'ts thereof
Ship's Logs & Depth-sounding
92% ea, 46% ea, Instruments & Apparatus
+14% +7% 89
Instruments & Apparatus for
Measuring or Detecting
Alpha, Beta, Gamma, X-Ray,
Cosmic or similar Radiations
14 7 217 & Parts
15.5 7.5 2 Seismographs & Parts
$2.25 ea, $1.12 ea, 2 Anemometers
+ 35% + 17.5%
Automatic Flight Control
Instruments & Apparatus
designed for use in Aircraft
12 6 ( and Parts thereof
Electrical Measuring, Checkini
9,761 ( Analyzing or Automatically
Controlling Instruments &
12 10 C Parts, N.E.C.
(1) Under a special provision the Tariff Rate for color picture tubes will remain at 12% through August 31, 1969. After that time,
they will come in under the duty for B & N Television picture tubes,
(2) Electronic instruments, apparatus, & parts were estimated at 75% of total measuring, checking, analyzing or automatically
controlling instruments & parts.
(3) Check U.S. Tariff Rates of parts classified with finished (conmiete) product.
PAGENO="0130"
U.S. EXPORT CLASSIFICATIONS
Parts for
Electronic Data
Processing
Machines
Television Receivers,
including Combinations(2)
Radios, including
Combinations (2)
Transceivers
Television & Radio
Broadcast Audio
Equipment
Television Broadcast Studio
Equipment, Other than VTR's
Radio Communication Systems,
except Mobile & Microwave
Microwave Communication
Systems & Eiuipment
Mobile Communication
Equipment, N.E.C.
TABLE II
ni
>(
LESS THAN 50% E.E.C. REDUCTION GRANTED
(Add 000)
E.E.C. U.S.
TARIFF RATES TARIFF RATES
U.S. EXPORTS PRE FINAL PRE FINAL U.S. IMPORTS
TO E.E.C. KENNEDY RATE KENNEDY RATE FROM E.E.C.
1967 ROUND ~ ROUND ~ 1967 U.S. IMPORT CLA2SlFICATIC~!.
(Included iri a basket cat ~
676.5200 - Parts ti 1iice
Machines, excludirg
57,581 11 10.5 11 5.5 NA. Typewritrr Partu)
10 5 90 Television fluceivert (2)
3815 22 115
13 7.5 7 Television - Ralia - Phono.Comb.
12.5 10.15 3,501 Solid State Radios (2)
1,370 22 115 ) 12.5 6 1,716 Radios, N.E.C. (2)
13.75 6.5 3,166 Combination Radio - Phonograph
1,229 16 11 12.5 6 13 Transceivers
(md. 685,20150 - TV. Apparatus
10 5 NA. & Parts, N.E.C.)
211 16 11 ) (mci. in 685.2060 - Radio Appa-
12.5 6 NA. ratus & Parts, N.E.C.)
(md. in 685.20L10 - TV.
849 (l) 10 5 N.A. Apparatus & Parts, N.E.C.)
1,827 16 11
1,01515 16 11
15,426 16 11
C)
C)
PAGENO="0131"
Communication Equipment
& Parts, N.E.C.
Inter-communication
Equipment (other than
wire telephone &
telegraph)
Transmitters & Radio Frequency
Power Amplifiers, other than
broadcast
* Transmitters
Other
Electronic Telecommunications
Equipment, N E.C.
Parts & Accessories for
Telecommunications
Equipment, N.E.C.
Meteorological & Navigation
Instruments, Electric or
Electronic
Electronic Navigational Aids
Electronic Search & Detection
Apparatus, Including Radar (3) 21,248
(1) See page
8,975 i6 11
Radio Navigational Aid Appa-
ratus, Radar Apparatus &
Radio Remote Control
15 7.5 596 Apparatus, & Parts
(2) Complete Kits are classified with finished product; incomplete Kits are classified under their respective parts - (i.e. a
receiving tube in an incomplete Kit would be classified under receiver tubes).
(3) Meteorological Instruments & Sonar Apparatus (including echo-sounding) would fall into BTN heading 90.28; Measuring, Checking,
Analyzing or Automatically Controlling Instruments & Apparatus.
12.5 6
1,520 Radio Apparatus & Parts, N.E.C.
327 16 11 )
3,955 * *
14 7 )
(1)
841
7,385 i8 13
7,442 13 10
19,382 13 10
13 10
rn
>(
I
-4
PAGENO="0132"
TABLE II
Communication Wire & Cable,
Insulated
Insulatdd Appliance Wire &
Cord & Flexible Cord Sets,
other than Ignition
Harnesses and Cable Sets
Power Wire & Cable, Insulated,
under 601 Volts
Power Wire & Cable, Insulated,
601 Volts & over
Magnetic Wire
Insulated
Insulated Electrical Cable,
Cord, & Wire, N.E.C.
* Lead-sheathed cables
Other
Resistors & Parts
Parts & Accessories, N.E.C.
for Electron Pubes
Parts & Accessories, for Diodes,
Rectifiers, Transistors, &
Semiconductor Devices, N.E.C.
l4or )
859 17 * 11 )
i4or
528 17 * 11
l4or
505 17 * 11
l4or
31 17 * 11
l4or
282 17 * 11
l4or
1,191 17 * 11
17
14
8,275 13 8
17
15
17
rn
cX3
Insulated Electrical
Conductors, without fittings,
(Included in basket category
with Photocells, & Piezo-
Electric Crystals)
Tees IWAN c0~ EEC. REDUCTION GRANTED - (Cont.)'
U.S. EXPORTS
TO E.E.C.
U.S. EXPORT CLASSIFICATIONS 1967
(Add coo)
E.E.C. U.S.
TARIFF RATES TARIFF RATES
PRE FINAL PEE FINAL U.S. IMPORTS
KENNEDY RATE KENNEDY RATE FROM E.E.C.
ROUND ~9J~j ~Q)(((~, ~7j l967~
U.S. IMPORT CLASSIFICATICOS
Insulated Electrical Conductors,
without fittings, containing
(exclusive of insulation u
sheating) over 10% by the
8.5 4,054 weight of metal copper
7.5 32 N.E.C.
Insulated Electrical
Conductors, with fitting,
8.5 451 N.E.C.
2,594 Resistors & Parts
12.5 6
2,886 12 9
6,639 12 9
12.5 6 NA.
PAGENO="0133"
Microscopes & Diffraction
Apparatus, Electron
& Proton
Electro-Medical &
Electro-Therapeut ic
Apparatus, other than
X-Ray Apparatus 6,!~98
Video Tape Recorders
Recorders, Tape, Wire &
Disc, except office
Recording Machines &
Recording Mechanisms (i)
Dictation Transcribing
Machines (1)
Combination Dictation
Machines (1)
** Estimated
Phonographs, Coin-operated,
New
Phonographs, except Coin-
operated, New
Phonograph & Record
Players, Used
Electro-Surgical Apparatus
203 & Parts
Electro-medical Apparatus
1,035 & Parts
(Included grouped together in
a basket category with all
Tape Recorders & Dictation
Machines & Parts)
(Included in basket category
6,610 15 9.5 17 8.5 NA, with Musical Instrumerits,N.E.C.
Record Players, Record Changers
& Phonographs, with or without
Speakers
(1) See page
>(
-1
Electron, Proton & Similar
Microscopes & Diffraction
150 12 9 22 11 785 Apparatus
36
12
13 8
2,80k 10 8
5,7L~9 13 8,5)
160 ** 15 9.5)
1,100 ** 13 8,5)
11.5 5.5 NA.
2~9
297
15 9.5 )
15 9,5 )
C;'
11.5 5.5 3,391
PAGENO="0134"
U.S. EXPORTS
TO E.E.C.
US. EXPORT CLASSIFICATIONS 1967
Telephone Switchboards
Telephone Switching Devices
Telephone Carrier Equipment
Telephone Instruments
Telephone Repeater Equipment
Telephone Apparatus &
Equipment, NEC. &
Parts, N.E.C
Teleprinter Units
(Wire)
Telegraph (Wire) Apparatus
& Equipment, N.E.C.
U.S.
TARIFF RATES
PRE FINAL U.S. IMPORTS
KENNEDY RATE FROME.E.C.
ROUND i2:Li~. 1967
Telephonic Apparatus. &
Instruments and Ports
thereof'
Telegraph Apparatus &
Instruments & Parts, N.E.C.
Measuring, Checking, Analyzing
or Automatically Controlling
Instruments & Apparatus,
Electrical
Parts C or Measuring, Checking,
Analyzing, or Automatically
Controlling Instruments &
Apparatus, Electrical
rn
Us
-1
TABLE III
50% E.E.C. REDUCTION GRANTED
(Add 000)
E.E.C.
TARIFF RATES
PEE FINAL
KENNEDY RATE
ROUND 12E _
15 7.5 )
15 7.5 )
36 13 6.5 )
115 15 7.5
56 15 7.5 )
910 15 7.5
626 15 7.5 14
1,403 15 7.5 14
US, IMPORT CLASSIFICATIOU~
17.5 8.~ 4,271
Cl'
Teleprinting & Teletypewriter
974 Machines & Parts
18,040(2) 13
6,896
6.5
(3)
3,332 (2) 13 6.5
(3)
PAGENO="0135"
Radio Broadcast
Transmitters
T.V. Broadcast
Transmitters
Railway Signals &
Attachments
Electric Traffic Control
Equipment & Parts, N,E.C,
Electric Lighting Sign~l
Apparatus, Marine Markers,
Beacons, & Similar Lighting
Signal Equipment, N.E.C.
Electric & Electronic Alarm
& Signal Systems
Electric Gongs, Buzzers, Bells,
& similar Sound Signal
Equipment
Bells, Sirens, Indicator
Panels, Burglar & Fire
Alarms, & other Sound or
Visual Signalling Apparatus
924 & Parts
Loudspeakers & Parts
Microphones & Parts, N.E.C.
Audio-Frequency Amplifiers
& Parts, N.E.C.
Public Address
Systems
1,404
478
2,292
171
14 7
14 7 )
14 7)~
))
14 7))
15 7.5 636 Loudspeakers
15 7.5 912 Microphones
Audio-Frequency Electric
15 7.5 380' Amplifiers
Headphones, Electric Sound
15 7.5 236 Amplifier Sets
Parts f or Loudspeakers,
15 7.5 321 Microphones, Amplifiers,etc.
Included in Radio Apparatus &
12.5 6 N.A. Parts, N.E.C.
Included in T.V. Apparatus &
10 5 N.A. Parts. N.E.C.
115 14 7
1 14 7
1.144 12 6
581 12 6 )
130 12 6 )
688 12 6 )
8.5 4
32 12 6
(2) Electrical Instruments and Apparatus were estimated at 25% of total category: Measuring. Checking, Analyzing or Automatically
Controlling Instruments & Apparatus.
(3) Check "No Reduction Granted" section for U.S. Tariff Rates and U.S. Imports from E.E.C.
PAGENO="0136"
TABLE III
50~ E.E.C. REDUCTION GRANTED - (Cont.)
(Add 000)
E.E.C. u.s. -I
TARIFF RATES TARIFF RATES
U.S. ED(PORTS PRE FINAL PRE FINAL U.S. IMPORTS
TO E.E.C. KENNEDY RATE KENNEDY RATE FROM E.E.C.
U.S. ~CPORT CLASSIFICATIONS 1967 ROUND (.21?.._ ROUND ~ 1967 U.S. IMPORT CLASSIiflATI
Capacitors 7,669 14 7 12.5 10 4,494 Capacitors
Electrical Apparatus for Naking,
Switches, N.E.C. 9,944 13 6.5 ( Breaking, or for protection
of Electrical Circuits;
Current Carrying Wiring ( Switchboards (except Telephone
Devices, N.E.C. 10,551 13 6.5 ( Switchboards) and Control
30 15 14,347 Panels & Pas'ts
Electronic Type Receiving Electronic Receiving Tubes
Tubes 2,152 15 7.5 12.5 6 4,929 (excl, Cathode Ray)
Cathode Ray TV, Camera
Tubes 268 14 7
12.5 6 51 Cathode Ray Tubes, N.E.C.
Cathode Ray Tubes, N.E.C.
(excl. TV, Picture Tubes) 162 15 7.5
Electron Tubes, N.E.C.,
Transmitting, Industrial &
Special Purpose 6.020 * *
12.5 6 5,705 Electronic Tubes, N.E.C.
Gas & Vapor Electron Tubes 755 * *
* If a Rectifying Tube . 16 8 )
Other 15 7.5
X-Ray Tubes, Valves, & Parts, X-Ray Tubes
N.E.C. Medical & Industrial 410 13 6,5 6.5 3 1,108 & Parts
PAGENO="0137"
Medical & Dental X-Ray &
Gamma Ray Equipment &
Parts, N.E.C.
Industrial & Scientific
X-Ray Equipment, &
Parts, N.E.C.
Electronic & Electric Organs
Dictation
Recording
Machines (1)
X-Ray Apparatus
& Parts,
5.5 2.5 10,878 N.E.C.
Apparatus based on the use of
Radiation from Radioactive
6 50 Substances & Parts
34 17 4,792 Electronic Organs
(Included in a basket category
with all Tape Recorders &
NA. Dictation Machines & Parts)
Phonograph Records, Record
Blanks, & Pre-Recorded Tapes
~ Blank Records
Recorded Records
Pre-Recorded Tape
(not for film)
Recording Magnetic Tape
& Wire
(1) See page
1,979 ***
14 7
17 8.~
15 7.5 )
10,414 15 7.5
10 5
2~ l~
~~** Sq. ft. of
recording surface
12 6
1,230 Phonograph Records
Recorded Magnetic Tape &
231 Media other than Wire
Blank Magnetic Recording
Media
ni
-1
660 13 6.~ ) (
627 13 6.~ ) ( 12
1,317 19 9.5
** Estimated
440 ** 15 7.5 11.5 5.5
PAGENO="0138"
P1
as
(i) Note: Parts for 85.15, Radiotelegraphic & Racliotelephonic Transmission and Reception Apparatus; Radio-Broadcasting I
T.V. Transmission & Reception Apparatus, and T.V. Cameras, Radio Navigational Aid Apparatus, Radar Apparatus
& Radio Remote Control Apparatus are classified in following manner by E.E.C. countries:
PRE FINAL
KENNEDY RATE
._~- i~__
Cases & Cabinets of Wood 13 6.5
Cases & Cabinets, N.E.C. 16 8
Microstructures 18 17 01
Parts cut from the bar, of base
metal, the greatest diameter of
which does not exceed 25mm 18 9
Parts, N.E.C. 18 13
Parts for Sound Recorders & Reproducers are classified in the following manner:
Sound-heads and pick-ups;
including parts 16 10.5
Needles 10 5
Other
Parts cut from the bar, of base
metal, the greatest diameter
of which does not exceed 25mm 14 7
Parts, N.E.C. 14 9
PAGENO="0139"
3575
EXHIBIT 2
PART II
TOTAL E.E.C. IMPORT CHARGES
PAGENO="0140"
3576
EXHIBIT 2
Tariffs are one form of cash charges levied against imports into the
member countries of the E.E.C. Among other charges are non-cumulative and
neutral turnover taxes and a variety of excise duties.
These indirect taxes are operated on the "country of destination
principle;" that is, the taxes are refunded on exports but imports are subject
to payment.
As explained by Mr. Johannes Jansen, head of the Indirect Taxation
Division, Commission of the European Communities:
"Turnover taxes are taxes on consumption: they are added to
the price of taxable products. They are levied according
to the "country of destination principle." This means that
exported goods are exempted from turnover tax and the tax
already paid is reimbursed. On the other hand, imported
commodities have to be taxed in the same way as similar
domestic products." *
"Because the "country-of-destination principle" also appli4s
to excise duties, there is, as with turnover taxes, a duty
refund on exports and a duty on imports." **
In addition to the taxes, there are a variety of fees, varying from
country to country, which are applicable against U.S. imports. Among these fees
are statistical charges, stamp taxes, administrative payments and import taxes.
Table IV, page 23, illustrates the taxes and other fees levied against
U.S. imports by the individual countries comprising the E.E.C.
A study of Table IV shows the wide range and disparity of these cash
charges within and between the different ccuntries. Readers are particularly
urged to note that with the exception of Luxembourg's 3.0% import tax, all other
"frontier" taxes are levied against the Cost, Insurance, Freight (C.I.F.) duty
paid total of an imported product.
In the case of imports into the U.S., there is only one cash charge; the
duty on the F.O.B. value.
* (1) Johannes Jansen, Tax Harmonization in the Community in European Community,
January, 1968.
**(2) Johannes Jansen, Introducing a Uniform A.V.T. Rate, in European Community,
March, 1968.
PAGENO="0141"
3577
EXHIBIT 2
Table V relates the total disparity between the lower U.S. and the
higher landed costs in the member countries of the E.E.C.
Five random products representing different sectors of the electronics
industry are presented. The point in time for the landed costs in the E.E.C. is
July 1, 1968. the date the Cormson External Tariff goes into effect. The presented
cost of imports into the U.S. has been effective as of January 1, 1968, the date
the U.S. made the first of the Kennedy Round 5 stage - 5 year reductions. (See
Table V. pages 2'~-25.) *
The differentials shown in Table V between the landed costs in the U.S.
and the E.E.C. are, of course, substantial and significant.
There are a variety of reasons for these landed cost differentials which
favor the E.E.C.
1. In the "Selective Electronic Products and Related Items"
area, present individual country tariff rates and the
future C.X.T. are and will continue for a five year period
to be generally higher than those of the U.S.
2. The U.S. duty is levied against the cost of the product
(F.O.Bj; the E.E.C. against the product, insurance, freight
(C.I.Fj. -
3. Each of the member countries of the E.E.C. applies its
turnover taxes against the C.I.F. duty paid total.
L~. With the exception of Germany and Luxembourg the incidence
of the "turnover" taxes varies according to the nature of
the product. The pattern followed is almost constant,
The incidence of the "turnover" rises on consumer type and
those products subject to rapid technological innovation
and development, Turnover in the above statement was put
in gratis to qualify Italy's approach for adhering to the
mentioned pattern, Italy holds the turnover tax at `~.O%
and then "adjusts" with a varied rate structure of an
additional compensatory import tax and in the case of
consumer products with additional taxes levied against the
C,I.F., Duty, Thrnover Tax and Compensatory Import Tax
p5j4~talJ
5. Luxembourg, France and Italy impose further taxes or
other charges. (Table IV).
* See Marketing Guide Sheets, pages 28 through 111 for detailed country by
country tariff and taxes for individual products.
PAGENO="0142"
3578
EXHIBIT 2
The question immediately occurs as to whether the various indirect taxes
are used as discriminatory measures against foreign competition.
Mr. Johannes Jansen, a spokesman for the Community answers the question
for U.S. exporters in the context of intra-E.E.C. trade:
"Accordingly, when the customs union in the Oommunity is achieved
on July 1, 1968, trade between the member countries will be free
of customs duties, but will nevertheless still come up against
tax frontiers at which indirect taxes will be levied and be reim-
bursed, and physical controls carried out.
It is not surprising therefore that the Treaty gives prime
consideration to the compensatory measures for indirect taxes
applied at the frontier to intra-Community trade in goods.
For export-drawbacks and import-equalization taxes can easily
be used for purposes incompatible with one of the main objectives
of the Common Market, namely free, undistorted competition. For
instance, if the compensatory tax levied on imports is higher
than the tax on comparable home-produced goods, the difference
has the same protective effect as the customs duties that are
being abolished. On the other hand, if the drawback on exports
is too high, then the difference is tantamount to an export
subsidy, which is prohibited.
In order to guard against these forbidden forms of discrimination,
Articles 95 and 96 stipulate that the indirect tax on imports
must not be higher than that which would be charged on similar
domestic goods, and that the drawback on exports must not exceed
the amount of tax actually paid. This sounds very simple. But
experience has shown that these prohibitions are very difficult
to enforce properly in the Common Market, at least as far as
turnover taxes are concerned." *
The E.E.C. turnover taxes, which afford a wide variety of discriminatory
practices in foreign trade, are presently in a transitional stage.
On February 9, 1967, the E.E.C. Council of Ministers adopted a unified
turnover tax called the value added tax (T.V.A.).
* ibid (1) page
Articles 95-96, reference to Rome Treaty.
PAGENO="0143"
3579
EXHIBIT 2
The value added tax cay be described as an overall and nonrecurrent tax
on consumption, the levy of which is made by partial payments in each state of
production and distribution on the basis of the value which is added to the product
in each stage.
The T.V.A. will replace the cumulative turnover tax system previously used
by the E.E.C. member countries, T.V.A. will be applied by all member countries of
the E.E.C. not later than January 1, 1970. Germany and France (modified form) are
presently operat;~g under this new tax system, The Netherlands and Belgium will
introduce the change on January 1, 1969; Italy and Luxembourg probably not before
January. 1970.
Will the T.V.A. offer some relief from the discriminatory practices
against imports possible under the old turnover tax systems?
In the opinion of the M.S.D. International Data staff, the possibility
of such relief is remote. The "why" of this opinion may be adjudged by an exam-
ination of a written commentary by the previously quoted Mr. Jansen.
"T.V.A., the European Community's common turnover tax system,
will be in force throughout the six member countries by January 1,
1970; but tax harmonization will not be finished, because the
common system still leaves many choices in the hands of the
individual governments.
The first two Community T.V.A. directives require the member
governments to apply T.V A. to only a small part of the service
sector. Depending on each country's own possibilities for col-
lectirig `T.V.A.. it may work out its own provisions for small
business and may decide for itself whether or not to apply the
tax to retail trade and to the many services not connected with
production and distribution of goods, such as banking, physicians'
fees, and other services normally supplied to private individuals.
Only a few services that have a direct bearing on production and
distribution must become subject to the common T.V.A., among them,
the transfer of patents and trade marks, advertising and the
transport and storage of goods.
Of all the choices left to the member governments, however,
the selection of tax rates and the granting of exemptions give
the most room for disparities in the first phase of turnover
tax harmonization.
Even after January 1, 1970, considerable differences will persist
between the six countries in both the standard rates and the
higher or lower rates levied on specific goods or services. It
is too early to make precise forecasts of what the normal rate
will be in any of the Six on January 1, 1970, but I would guess
they would be roughly 20 per cent in France and Belgium, between
10 per cent and 12 per cent in the Netherlands, Italy, and the
Federal Republic of Germany, and 9 per cent in Luxembourg.
PAGENO="0144"
3580
EXHIBIT 2
In areas where harmonization need not yet be applied, the
member countries are entitled to provide their own national
regulations. After consulting the Commission and the other
five countries, one member country may decide, for instance,
to disallow some or all tax deductions for expenditures on
capital goods or to allow deductions on this equipment by
annual installments only, when economic considerations
warrant such action. During a transitional period after
the introduction of T.V.A., even without prior consultations,
member countries may restrict deductions for capital goods.
Germany has already done so in its new T.V.A. law that came
into force on January 1 this year, on budgetary grounds.
The German restrictions were also intended to prevent a
temporary halt of investments prior to the introduction of
the T.V.A." *
The special rates, exemptions and options, which still leave room for
disparities are more than adequately stated.
"Under the new T.V.A. system, as long as each Community
member applies a different rate, set at a level that main-
tains the total incidence of the preceding cumulative turn-
over tax, U.S. exports to these countries will be taxed
at exactly the same amount as similar goods produced in
those countries. In cascade system countries where com-
pensatory taxes on imports were too low imports will
lose their unwarranted competitive advantage upon the
introduction of T.V.A. Conversely, exports from those
E.E.C. countries to the United States and other non-
member countries will lose the competitive disadvantage
from which they may have suffered because the cascade
system gave them an inadequate rebate. Competitive con-
ditions will also be equalized in trade between the E.E.C.
countries themselves." *
The idea of U.S. exports being taxed a exactly the same amount as similar
goods produced in the E.E.C. under the old turnover tax system or under the new
T.V.A. has been and remains an economic myth consistently perpetuated by the E.E.C.
As an example:
If the T.V.A. rate is 15.0%, the total tax paid on a domestically
produced goods worth $1,000 is $150.
If the same 15.0% T.V.A. is applied against an import worth $1,000 -
shipped and insured at $60 - and enters at a 15.0% duty rate, the
T.V.A. is $182.50.
* Johannes Janzen, T.V.A. 1970 and Beyond, in European Community, April, 1968.
PAGENO="0145"
3581
E)Q-IIBIT 2
Sometime after January 1, 1970 - at a date as yet unannounced - the
E.E.C. will harmonize at a common rate. Mr. Jansen makes this comment:
"Nothing yet is definite, of course, on the level of the
common rate, but it could conceivably be fixed at around
15.0%." *
This conceivable rate of 15.0% warrants an examination. By averaging out
the total imports -osts of the E.E.C. countries as of July 1, 1968 and theoretically
exporting to the Six at a common rate, the total landed cost on a $1,000 worth of
semiconductors would be $1,369.61.
If the same shipment were made after January 1, 1972 against a common
15.0% T.V.A., the total landed cost would be $1,426.23.
* Johanries Janse, T,V.A. 1970 and Beyond, in ~7ppean Community, April, 1968.
95-159 0 - e8 - pt. 8 - 10
PAGENO="0146"
TABLE IV
COMPARATIVE E.E.C. IMPORT TAXES
BELGIUM
Transmission Tax of
from 7 - 30% on
C,I,F. duty paid
value,
LUXEMBOURG
3% Import Tax on all 1% Statistical
products on FOB, Charge on all
Luxembourg value, products on C.I.P,
value.
2% Stamp Tax on all
products on the
amount of duty paid.
T.V.A. Tax of from
16.66 to 20% on
C.I,P. duty & tax-
paid value.
Administrative Fee
of 0.5% on all
products on C.I.F.
value.
4% Turnover Tax
on all products(1)
on C,I,F, duty
& Administrative
Pee paid.
Compensatory Import
Tax, of from L~.8 -
7.8% on CI.?, Duty
Administrative Pee
paid.
Additional taxes of
5% on CI,?. Duty
Tax paid total on
Radios, TV's &
Combinations.
And 10% C,I.P. Duty-
tax Paid Total on
Phonograph Records
and other Sound
Recording Media.
GERMANY
11% T.V.A, Tax on
all products on
CI.?, duty paid.
3% Turnover Tax on
all products on the
duty & tax..paid
value.
NETHERLANDS
Turnover Tax of from
9.t4 - 28.14%on ci.?.
Duty paid value.
(1) The Turnover Tax on items under 85.01 which
are used for Agricultural purposes is 3,3%.
PAGENO="0147"
EXHIBIT 2
3583
T A B L E V - C 0 M P A B A T I V t
(EFFECTIVE AS
(including
combinations)
FOB. $1,000.00
Duty 90.00
C.I.F.
Duty
$1,060.00
199.28
C.I.F.
Duty
$1,060.00
199.29
Insurance
& Freight 60.00
Total
Tax
Total
377.78
Taxes
Total
68.68
Landed
Cost $1,150.00
Landed
Cost
$1,637.06
Landed
Cost
$1,327.96
Tape
Recorders
F.0.B. $1,000.00
Duty 100.00
Insurance
& Freight 60.00
Total
Landed
Cost $1,160.00
C,I.F. $1,060.00
Duty 118.72
Taxes 66.26
Total
Landed
Cost $1,244.98
Home:
C.I.F. $1,060.00
Duty 118.72
Tax 341.83
Total
Landed
Cost $1,520.55
Industrial
(including
Dictation
Machines):
C.I.F. $1,060.00
Duty 118.72
Tax 153.23
Total
Landed
Cost $1,331.95
Radio Remote
F.0.B.
$1,000.00
C.I.F.
$1,060.00
C.I.F.
$1,060.00
Control
Duty
130.00
Duty
125.08
Duty
125.08
Apparatus;
Insurance
Radio
& Freight
60.00
Tax
82.96
Taxes
66.45
Navigational
Total
Total
Total
Aid Apparatus:
Landed
Landed
Landed
& Radar
Cost
$1,190.00
Coot
$1,268.04
(1) See following page.
PAGENO="0148"
Non-electrical:
C.I.F. $1,060.00
Duty 118.72
Tax iio.8o
Total
Landed
Coot $1,289.52
3584
IMPORT c,osTs(1)
OF JULY 1, ~
FRANCE
GERMANY
ITALY
C.I.F. $1,060.00
Duty 199.28
C.I.F. $1,060.00
Duty 199.28
C.I.F.
Duty
$1,060.00
199.28
Taxes 257.92
Total
Landed
Cost $1,517.20
Tax 138.52
Total
Landed
Cost $1,397.80
Taxes 209.27
Total
Landed
Cost $1,468.55
EXHIBIT 2
NETHERLANDS
C.I.F. $1,060.00
Duty 199.28
Tax 357.64
Total
Landed
Cost $1,616.92
Industrial:
C.I.F. $1,060.00
Duty 199.28
Tax 118.37
Total
Landed
Cost $1,377.65
C.I.F.
Duty
$1,060.00
118.72
.
C.I.F. $1,060.00
Duty 118.72
C.I.F.
Duty
$1,060.00
118.72
Electrical:
C.I.F. $1,060.00
Duty 118.72
Taxes
Total
Landed
Cost
239.86
$1,418.58
Tax
Total
Landed
Cost
129.66
$1,308.38
Taxes
Total
Landed
Cost
130,81
$1,309.53
Tax
Total
Landed
Cost
252.25
$1,430.97
C.I.F.
Duty
$1,060.00
125.08
C.I.F.
Duty
$1,060.00
125.08
C.I.F.
Duty
$1,060.00
125.08
C.I.F.
Duty
$1,060.00
125.08
Taxes
Total
Landed
Cost
201.59
$1,386.67
Taxes
Total
Landed
Cost
130.36
$1,315.44
Taxes
Total
Landed
Cost
131.49
$1,316.57
Tax
Total
Landed
111,40
$1,296.48
PAGENO="0149"
EXNIBIT 2
3585
TABLE V-COMPARATIVE
(EFFECTIVE AS
Semiconductors
FOB. $1,000.00
Duty 110.00
Insurance
& Freight. 60.00
Total
Landed
Coat $1,170.00
C.I.F. $1,060.00
Duty 180.20
Tax 86.8i
Total
Landed
Cost $1,327.01
C.I.F. $1,060.00
Duty 180,20
Taxes 68.11
Total
Landed
Cost $1,308.31
(1) `Costs are figured on a shipment value of $1,000.00, on which insurance and freight amount to
$60.00. The combined freight and insurance cost was calculated at 6% of value as estimated
in a report by the Tariff Commission on "C.I.F. Value of U.S. Imports."
Fixed
Capacitors
UNITED STATES
BELGIUM
LUXEMBOURG
F.O.B. $1,000.00
C,I.F,
$1,060.00
Duty 120.00
Duty
118.72
$i,o6o,oo
Insurance
Duty
118.72
& Freight 60,00
Tax
l65~~
Taxes
66.26
Total
Total
Landed
Landed
Total
Cost $1,180.00
Landed
PAGENO="0150"
C.I.F. $1,060.00
Duty 180.20
Taxes 253.63
Total
Landed
Cost $11493.83
C.I.F. $1,060.00
Duty 180.20
Tax 136.142
Total
Landed
Cost $1,376.62
C.I.F. $1,060.00
Duty 180.20
Taxes 1114,90
Total
Landed
Cost $1,355.10
C.I.F. $1,060.00
Duty 180.20
Tax 116.58
Total
Landed
Cost $1,356.78
3586
EXHIBIT 2
INFO R T C 0 S T S
(i)_ (Con~j
OF JULY 1, 1968)
FRANCE
GERMANY
ITALY
NETHERLANDS
C.I.F. $1,060.00
C.I.F. $1,060.00
C.I.F.
$1,060.00
C.I.F. $1,060.00
Duty 118.72
Duty 118.72
Duty
118.72
Duty 118.72
Taxes 239.86
Taxes 129.66
Taxes
130.81
Tax 1214~93
Total
Total
Total
Total
Landed
Landed
Landed
Landed
Cost $l,14l8.58
Cost $1,308.38
Cost
$1,309.53
Cost $1,303.65
PAGENO="0151"
3587
EXHIBIT 3
THE NEED FOR REFORM IN THE ANTIDUMPING ACT TO PREVENT
UNFAIR PRACTICES IN THE IMPORT TRADE
The Antidumping Act, in its administration, has been
substantially ineffective in checking unfair practices in the
pricing of foreign merchandise for export to the United States.
The Congress has, we believe, in the enactment of the
Antidumping Act, granted sufficient authority to the Bureau of
Custons to enforce the rules for fair trade practices in our import
trade. Due, in part, however, to the pervasive influence of the
concept of a total foreign economic policy fostered within the
Executive Branch of the Government, our antidumping laws have suf-
fered in their administration to a degree that has made them inefficient
instruments for suppressing the development of unfair trade practices
in the import trade of the United States.
The principal problem areas requiring attention are as
hereinafter described.
Disclosure of information filed by foreign
exporters in antidum-ping investigations i~s now
being significantly iimnunized from disclosure
through the arbitrary use by foreign exporters
of the "confidential" classification.
The Customs Regulations provide at Sec. 14.6a(a) that in
general all information obtained by the Bureau of Customs in an anti-
dumping proceeding will be available for inspection or copying by any
PAGENO="0152"
3588
EXHIBIT 3
interested person. Sec. 14.6a(b) permits persons submitting information
to request that it, or part of it, be kept confidential. But Sec. 14a(c)
of the Regulations states at paragraph (2) that information relating
to price information, allowances for quantity purchases, and to claimed
differences in circumstances of sale `will ordinarily be regarded as
appropriate for disclosure."
In practice, however, the foreign manufacturers of imported
merchandise subject to investigation under the Antidumping Act label all
information submitted to the Bureau of Customs in an antidumping
proceeding as "confidential.' The Bureau, in administering this
provision of the Act, then "negotiates" with the foreign manufacturers
to obtain their compliance with this provision of our laws. Such a
practice is hardly conducive to a fair and effective administration of
the Act which Congress intended as an instrument for the removal of
unfair practices in our import trade.
Failure of the Treasury Department to base its "fair
value" determinations in antidunrping proceedings upon
the "foreign value" of the imported merchandise as
defined in the Tariff Act of 1930 is contrary to the
intent of Congress.
The Antidumping Act [Sec. 160(a)] specifies that the basic
finding to be made by the Secretary of the Treasury (based on information
submitted to him by the Bureau of Customs) is whether the imported
merchandise "is being, or is likely to be, sold in the United States
PAGENO="0153"
3589
EXHIBIT 3
or elsewhere, at less than its fair value." The term "fair value" itself
is not defined in the Antidumping Act. Prior to the 1958 amendment
of the Antidumping Act, and the resulting amendment of the Customs
Regulations for antidumping investigations, the Secretary of the
Treasury, with subsequent court approval, had by regulation defined
"fair value" as equivalent to."foreign market value." Kleberg & Co.
Inc. v. United States, 21 C.C.P.A. 110 (Court of Customs and Patent
Appeals, 1933).
Legislative actions related to the Antidumping Act and
the above-mentioned definition of fair value strongly indicate that
Congress understood that "fair value" and "foreign value" in the Tariff
Act and "foreign market value" as defined in the Antidumping Act for
purposes of measuring the amount of dumping duties to be imposed after
other precedent determinations were made, were to all intents and
purposes identical.
The first evidence of this is offered by the report of
the Senate Finance Committee on the Customs Simplification Act of
1954. It quoted a letter from the Assistant Secretary of the Treasury
stating, among other things, that
"There is great difficulty, under the existing statute
and decisions construing it, in giving proper effect to
the law in cases where the home market of the country in
which the dumping originates is to any extent restricted
in the way in which the commodity is offered for sale."
(S. Rep. 2326, 83d Cong., p. 4)
PAGENO="0154"
3590
EXHIBIT 3
Restrictions on sale refer to foreign value for customs purposes, which
cannot be based upon other than prices which are freely offered to all
purchasers at wholesale. This comment by the Treasury Department,
reported by the Committee, ties "fair value" to "foreign value" for
customs purposes.
Next, the report of the Ways and Means Committee of the
House of Representatives on the Customs Simplification Act of 1955
directs attention to fears expressed that the repeal of foreign value
as a primary customs valuation base would, by eliminating up-to-date
information as to foreign values, weaken the enforcement of the
Antiduinping Act.
The significance of these expressed fears, referred to by
the Committee, lies in the identification of foreign value for customs
purposes as the measure of fair value. The Committee stated:
"Your committee considered carefully the effect of the
adoption of this bill on the enforcement of the Antidunping
Act, 1921. The committee has been assured by the Treasury
Department that there will be no weakening in the enforce-
ment of that act. The Secretary of the Treasury has written
to the committee stating the intention of the Bureau of
Customs and the Department of the Treasury to continue
to obtain the information on customs invoices necessary for
such enforcement." (H. Rep. 858, 84th Cong., p. 5)
PAGENO="0155"
3591
EXHIBIT 3
The Committee quoted the Secretary's letter, which included the statement:
"it is the firm intention of the Bureau of Customs and
the Treasury Departnent to continue to require foreign
value information as part of the information contained
in customs invoices. Consequently, the Treasury Depart-
ment will continue to have available to it foreign value
information upon which to initiate investigation of
possible sales at a dumping price wherever the discrepancy
between invoice price and foreign value appears to warrant
it." (Emphasis added) (H. Rep. 858, 84th Cong., p. 5)
The Senate Finance Committee in subsequently reporting
the Customs Simplification Act of 1956 took up the same topic, and
stated in its report:
"The Secretary of the Treasury has indicated that foreign
value information would continue to be required on customs
invoices made out by exporters. The Treasury would
thereby continue to have available the information needed
to initiate full-scale investigations whenever dumping was
indicated." (S. Rep. 2560, 84th Cong., p. 4)
At this point, there could be little doubt that both Treasury
and the cognizant committees of Congress understood that "foreign value"
as defined for customs valuation purposes was the touchstone of fair
value.
At that time, i.e., prior to the 1958 amendments to the
Antidumping Act, both "foreign market value" as defined in the Antidunping
Act and "foreign value" as defined in the Tariff Act of 1930 included
the requirement that the prices used to establish value in the home
market be those prices at which the merchandise was "sold or freely
offered for sale to all purchasers" in wholesale quantities.
PAGENO="0156"
3592
EXHIBIT 3
The courts had held that prices on transactions which
restricted the use or territory in which the merchandise could be
resold, or resale of the merchandise, were not `freely offered to
all purchasers" and, hence, could not be used as a basis for home
market value dtermination. Further, a price that was available to
some purchasers, but not to all purchasers (as, e.g., a price restricted
to manufacturers who used the merchandise in their manufacturing
operations but who did not resell it), was not "freely offered to
all purchasers."
Under the Antidumping Act, if freely offered home market
prices were not available, freely offered prices in sales to third
country purchasers were required to be used. These might have been
lower than the restricted home market sales. Foreign producers could
thus immunize their home market prices from use for dumping comparisons,
and set their third market prices at the same level as sales to the
United States.
Congress had dealt with a similar problem in regard to
"foreign value" for customs purposes in the Customs Simplification
Act of 1956. It eliminated the use of "foreign vaaue" as the primary
customs valuation base for all articles except those named on the
Final List (articles where the Secretary of the Treasury found that
change of the value rules would have the effect of reducing duties by
5% or more). It also defined the phrase "freely sold or, in the absence
PAGENO="0157"
3593
EXHIBIT 3
of sales, offered for sale' as either the price at which the merchandise
was sold to all purchasers at wholesale, or "in the ordinary course of
trade to one or more selected purchasers at wholesale at a price which
fairly reflects the market value of the merchandise without restrictions
as to the disposition or use of the merchandise by the purchaser" except
such restrictions as do not `substantially affect the value of the
merchandise to usual purchasers at wholesale." (Emphasis added.)
In 1958, Congress amended the Antidumping Act by redefining
"foreign market value" to substitute the words "sold or, in the absence
of sales, offered for sale" for "sold or freely offered for sale to
all purchasers." It also defined the phrase "sold or, in the absence
of sales, offered for sale in virtually the identical words it had used
in defining "freely sold, or, in the absence of sales, offered for sale"
in the Customs Simplification Act of 1956.
The definition in the Antidumping Act emphasized, however,
that if the price used for home market value was accompanied by restrictions
which affected the value of the merchandise, the Secretary was to make an
adjustment in value to eliminate the-effect of the restriction. Thus,
the definition states:
"The term `sold or, in the absence of sales, offered
for sale' means sold or, in the absence of sales, offered -
(A) to all purchasers at wholesale,.or
(B) in the ordinary course of trade to one or
more selected purchasers at wholesale at a price
which fairly reflects the market value of the
merchandise,
PAGENO="0158"
3594
EXHIBIT 3
without regard to restrictions as to the disposition or
`~ use of the merchandise by the purchaser except that, where
such restrictions are found to affect the market value
of the merchandise, adjustment shall be made there for
in calculating the price at which the merchandise is sold
or offered for sale." (19 U.S.C. 170a(l)) (Emphasis
added.)
It is important to remember that the 1958 amendments to
the Antidumping Act were submitted to congress by the Secretary of the
Treasury in obedience to a directive contained in the customs simplifica-
tion Act of 1956 to recommend any amendments "which he considers desir-
able or necessary to provide for greater certainty, speed, and efficiency
in the enforcement of such Antidumping Act." (Sec. 5, P.L. 927, 83d
Congress)
One must recall also that Congress placed that directive
in the 1956 Act to allay the fears that had been expressed that the
elimination of "foreign value" as the primary customs valuation base
would weaken the enforcement of the Antidumping Act because "foreign
value" was essentially the same as "fair value" which would stillbe
the base of comparison of home market and export prices to determine
if a margin of dumping exists.
The purpose of the 1958 amendments to the Antidumping Act
was, as stated by the Assistant Secretary of the Treasury in explaining
them to the Senate Finance Committee, to materially strengthen the power
of Treasury to move against dumping (Hearings on H. R. 6006, March 1958,
PAGENO="0159"
3595
EXHIBIT 3
p. 37) by, among other things, putting an end to the situation where
the inability to use home market sales prices because of restrictions
prevented findings of dumping and the imposition of dumping duties.
(Thid., pp. 23, 24.)
It certainly would be contrary to the origin and purpose
of the 1958 amendments to administer the Antidumping Act in a way which
eliminated higher "foreign value" prices, in fact available for use
under the meaning of that term in customs law, and to use in their stead
selected lower home market prices not available to all purchasers without
making adjustments in the price which would fairly reflect the market
value of the merchandise without the restrictions, and so eliminate
dumping margins. This interpretation of the 1958 amendments is borne
out by the following remark included in the testimony of the Assistant
Secretary of the Treasury before the Senate Finance Committee:
"Going back to the 1921 law, we have said that the
standard for calculating dumping duties was typically the
exporter's home price. If that price was higher than the
price to the United States, the difference was the dumping
duty. Now, the effect of a restriction such as limiting
resale to a geographic area is, if anything, to reduce
the value of the article in the purchaser's hands. Does
it make sense to say that when such a restriction is
placed on home sales, the standard for dumping duty should
instead be an even lower third country price? We do not
think it does. We do not think that such would have been
the intention of Congress when it enacted the 1921 legisla-
tion." (Ibid., p. 23)
PAGENO="0160"
3596
EXHIBIT 3
The Congress took the Treasury Department at its word in
approving the Antidumping Act amendments. In reporting the bill which
became law, the Senate Finance Committee stated:
"A principal change in the Antidumping Act of 1921
as amended which would be made by H. R. 6006 involves
amendment of the definition of `foreign market value'
in section 205 of the act so as to permit the use of prices
in `restricted' sales in the determination of foreign
market value. This amendment would bring the definition
of `foreign market value' into conformity with the defini-
tion of `fair value' in the Treasury regulations. The
amendment would be advantageous to the administration of
the act because, with the disparity in the definitions
of `foreign market value' and `fair value' that now exists,
imported merchandise may be found to be sold below fair
value to the injury of domestic industries but no anti-
dumping duties may be chargeable. Such a situation can
arise, for example, where the exclusion of a higher home
market price as a basis for foreign market value requires
reference to third country prices and where such prices
are the sane as or lower than the prices at which such or.
similar merchandise is sold to the United States."
(S. Rep. 1619, 85th Cong., May 21, 1958) (Emphasis added.)
There is no basis in the legislative history for believing
that Congress understood or intended that the 1958 amendments would be
used as a basis for ignoring freely offered home market prices, acceptable
as a basis for customs valuation under the definition of foreign value,
which are higher than the export prices to the United States, and
selecting restricted prices which are lower, and which eliminate the
margin of dumping. Congress understood that the amendments were protective.
The Senate Finance Committee stated:
PAGENO="0161"
3597
EXHIBIT 3
`The antidumping feature of our Tariff Act is of
considerable importance in protecting domestic industries
from inroads of foreign goods or offered for sale at less
than fair value. Not only will the improvements made by
this bill assist in speeding up the operating procedure,
they will strengthen the deterrent effect of the law and
in that respect help to prevent dumping." (Ibid.)
(Emphasis added.)
The practice of the Treasury Department in
adjusting the horns market price used as a basis
for "fair value" by differences in circumstances
of sale is of questionable validity.
There appears to be no authority in the Antidumping Act
for the Bureau of Customs to make adjustments in the home market
price for differences in the circumstances of sale. The Act, at
Sec. 202(a) [19 U.S.C. 161(a)], authorizes adjustments in price for
differences in quantity or other differences in circumstances of sale
only in the calculation of the amount of dumping duties to be imposed
in respect to each importation after there has been a determination
of dumping by the Secretary of the Treasury (and of injury by the
Tariff Commission). It seems significant that this authority is not
incorporated specifically or by reference in the definition of foreign
market value, purchase price, or exporter's sales price.
The Treasury Department has assumed the power to transfer
the authority to make such adjustments from the final stage of calculating
dumping duties on imports to the first stage of the investigation, where
it serves principally as a means of explaining awaymargins of dumping
which are otherwise shown by the data to exist. Thus the provision
95-159 0 - 68 - pt. 8 - 11
PAGENO="0162"
3598
EXHIBIT 3
in the Customs Regulations [Sec. 14.7(b)] specifying that in comparing
the prices on which a determination of sales below fair value is
being considered, "reasonable allowances will be made for bona fide
differences in circumstances of sale," has no basis in the Antidumping
Act itself.
Congress certainly did not understand that the Secretary's
authority to make adjustments for differences in quantity or in circum-
stances of sale applied to anything but the calculation of dumping
duties. The Senate Finance Committee conveyed its understanding by
stating in its report on the bill which was enacted into law that:
"Another amendment in the definitions relating to
assessment of dumping duties is designed to make appro-
priate comparisons between the price at which imported
merchandise is sold to American purchasers and the price
at which such or similar merchandise is sold by the
foreign producers or exporters elsewhere despite minor
dissimilarities between the merchandise and the differ-
ences in the terms or circumstances of the sale."
(S. Rep. 1619, 85th Cong., May 21, 1958) (Emphasis
added)
Accordingly, it is submitted that the Bureau of Customs is
proceeding improperly if it fails or refuses to make a determination
of dumping on the basis that differences in the circumstances of sale
call for adjustments which eliminate the margin of dumping disclosed
by a comparison of the home market and export prices.
PAGENO="0163"
3599
EXHIBIT 3
The Treasury Department Should At Least Limit These
Questionable Adjustments In The Home Market Price
Used As A Basis For "Fair Value" To Those Established
By Credible Evidence To Be Due To Differences in
Circumstances Of Sale.
The Bureau of Customs, in its administration of the
questionable provisions of the Customs Regulations permitting allow-
ances for differences in circumstances of sale, has made adjustments
in the home market price in its antidumping investigations for a
number of alleged differences in circumstances of sale. Typical of
these are (1) costs of warranty on home market sales; (2) differences
in credit costs; (3) differences in the cost of technical services;
(4) differences in branding costs; and (5) selling commiss~ons on
home market sales. An examination of the manner in which these
adjustments have been made discloses a real need for reform in the
procedures followed by the Bureau in making these determinations if
the intent of Congress expressed in the Antidumping Act to prevent
unfair practices in our import trade is to be carried out.
Adjustments To Reflect Cost of
Warranty on Home Market Sales
In making adjustments to the home market price to reflect
the cost of warranty on home market sales, the Bureau of Customs, we
have been informed, relies primarily upon information supplied by the
foreign manufacturers of the merchandise in question as to the
PAGENO="0164"
3600
EXHIBIT 3
existence of a warranty on home market sales, the cost of such
warranty and the nonexistence of a comparable warranty on export
sales to the United States.
Furthermore, we understand that Customs takes no steps
to inquire of the U. S. importers of the merchandise (whose identity
is, of course, known to the Bureau of Customs and whose response must
be truthful under pain of criminal liability) whether their purchases
were on terms, written or implied, which include the right to make
returns for credit of defective merchandise or to be given credit for
defective merchandise whether or not returns are made.
Apparently, the only "independent" investigation made is
that of the Treasury agents in the field, which consists simply of
the Treasury representatives' asking questions and recording the
answers of the foreign manufacturers which, of course, are not under
oath.
Such an investigation is not an investigation at all, but
merely a mechanism to formalize the self-serving statements of foreign
producers who are under absolutely no penal inhibitions in explaining
away dumping margins by using a variety of fictional or incompletely
stated responses to questions put to them by a few Treasury representa-
tives whose duties permit only limited attention to their preparation
for and conduct of the field interviews.
PAGENO="0165"
3601
EXHIBIT 3
There is still another aspect of the handling of this
type of adjustment by Customs which seems contrary to the intention
of Congress. We are informed that, after calculating an average
cost per unit of the warranty in the home market, Customs
automatically deducts that amount from the home market price for
purposes of comparison with the export price. This is done under
a claim of authority in the regulations to do so, where, under
Sec. 14.7(b) (2), "warranties' are mentioned as an example of
differences in circumstances of sale for which "such allowances"
will be made in calculating the "fair value" of merchandise.
The "such" in "such allowances" refers, however, to the
lead sentence of the subsection, which states that "reasonable
allowances will be made for bona fide differences in circumstances of
sale if it is established to the satisfaction of the Secretary that
the amount of any price differential is wholly or partly due to such
differences." (Emphasis added.)
The words in italics impose two requirements before an
adjustment in price may be made: the adjustment must be reasonable,
which certainly implies that an allowance is not automatically or
necessarily to be made by the full arithmetical difference of the
so-called warranty (the volume of returns in the home market on which
the allowance was calculated might have been due to defective manu-
facturing procedures on certain lots which were not involved in the
PAGENO="0166"
3602
EXHIBIT 3
production for export, for example); and, more importantly, an
adjustment is to be made only if the Secretary determines that the
amount of price differential was due, at least in part, to the
difference in warranty policy on home market sales versus those
for export.
Customs personnel have no right to assume the existence
of any fact, the proof of which is required as a condition precedent
to the making of an allowance which would excuse or explain away the
margin of dumping revealed by a comparisoA of the actual prices
themselves.
We believe that the practice of making adjustments in the
hone market price because of a claimed difference in warranty at the
stage where the Commissioner of Customs is making his initial
determination of whether reasonable grounds exist to believe or suspect
that the merchandise is being, or likely to be, sold at less than its
foreign market value, is contrary to the Antidumping Act which authorizes
such adjustments only at the time dumping duties are being assessed,
after the findings of dumping and injury have b~en made.
But even if authority to make such adjustments is deemed
to exist at the stage of the determination that reasonable grounds
exist to believe or suspect that the merchandise is being dumped, the
words of the statute control the nature and extent of such authority.
PAGENO="0167"
3603
EXHIBIT 3
They clearly limit the adjustments to those where it is established
to the satisfaction of the Secretary or his delegate that the amount
of any difference between the export price and the home market price
is wholly or partly due to differences in circumstances of sale, at
which point, as stated in the statute, due allowance shall be made
therefor. Sec. 202, Antidumping Act, 19 U.S.C. 161. There is simply
no basis whatever for Customs to assume what the statute requires to
be proven to the satisfaction of the Secretary or his delegate, nor
for adjustments to be made which exceed a `due allowance" under the
circumstances.
Adjus~nents To Reflect
Differences in Credit Costs
We have been informed that the Bureau of Customs makes
adjustments to reflect differences in credit costs when sales for
export to the United States are on a cash (letter of credit prior to
shipment) basis and home market sales are on credit terms. Apparently,
a calculation is made of the credit cost per day to the foreign manu-
facturer and an adjustment is made in the home market price by applying
this factor to the full amount of the invoice price on the volume of
merchandise sold in the home market.
It is well known that most foreign manufacturing economies
operate to a large degree on credit; not only is the manufacturer
extending credit to his customers in the form of extended payment terms,
PAGENO="0168"
3604
EXHIBIT 3
but also he is receiving credit from his suppliers in equal degree.
He certainly incurs no credit costs on the materials purchases. The
¼
selling price also includes an element for profit, and there can
obviously be no cost to the manufacturer in respect of the delayed
receipt of the profit increment of the selling price.
At most, the cost of the credit extended to the home market
would be the wage increment of manufacturing costs included in the
price. Customs has no data establishing what this portion is, nor that
the manufacturer incurs an interest cost equal to the going rate of
interest applied to the full selling price of the home market sales.
Once again, Customs appears to have assumed the existence of proof
which the law and regulations contemplate the foreign producer is
required to supply.
The procedure being followed on this adjustment is subject
to all the vices of that discussed above for warranties. No proof has
been developed to support a determination by Customs that the difference
in price is due in whole or part to differences in credit terms. No
proof has been developed upon which a determination could be based as to
the amount of a "due allowance" in price comparison in respect of credit
differences, even assuming such an allowance in some amount is proper.
The making of such an allowance, in any event, at this stage of the
investigation is improper, since the Antidumping Act provides for such
an allowance only at the time dumping duties are being assessed.
PAGENO="0169"
3605
EXHIBIT 3
Adjustments To Reflect
Differences in Branding Costs
Apparently, the Bureau of Customs makes adjustments in
the hone market price for the difference in cost represented by
branding of merchandise sold in the home market where the foreign
manufacturer claims that its merchandise sold in the home market is
branded, whereas its merchandise for export is unbranded.
The making of an allowance for branding is subject to all
of the vices discussed in the preceding sections: the Bureau has no
evidence that the difference in price between home market and export
sales is due in any degree to the alleged difference in branding;
nor does it possess information to support a determination of what
a `due allowance" (as distinguished from the automatic full credit
given for the claimed difference in cost) would be for such difference.
The allowance is made improperly at a stage not authorized by the
statute.
There is a further defect in the Bureau's procedure on
this allowance, and that is that the Bureau's own regulations do not
permit or contemplate such an allowance. Sec. 14.7(b) (2) (ii) states
that "allowances generally will not be made for differences in * * *
production costs" and the cost of branding would seem clearly to be
a production cost.
PAGENO="0170"
3606
EXHIBIT 3
It might be claimed that the branding cost is not a differ-
ence in the "circumstances of sale" (to which the cited subsection
pertains), but rather refers to differences in the merchandise which
make the imported merchandise "similar" rather than "such" merchandise
as that sold in the home market.
The same section of the Antidumping Act, as amended in
1958, which permits "due allowance" for differences in circumstances
of sale in the assessment of dumping duties (after the findings of
dumping and of injury have been made) found by the Secretary or his
delegate to be wholly or partly the cause of the difference in price
in home market versus export sales, also permits "due allowance" for
the fact that the merchandise exported is "similar" rather than "such"
merchandise as that sold in the home market if the Secretary or his
delegate have proof which establishes to his satisfaction that the
difference in price is wholly or partly due to the difference in the
merchandise.
The Customs Regulations at Sec. 14.7(b) (3) are quite
specific that in making "due allowance" for differences in the merchan-
dise, the Secretary "will be guided primarily by the effect of such
differences upon the market value of the merchandise but, when appro-
priate, he may also consider differences in cost of manufacture if
it is established to his satisfaction that the amount of any price
differential is wholly or partly due to such differences."
PAGENO="0171"
3607
EXHIBIT 3
Here the Bureau's people assume that the existence of
differences in cost of branding ipso facto resulted in a difference
in market value, or that the difference in price between home market
and export sales of the merchandise is due cent for cent to the
alleged difference in branding cost. The procedure being followed
in this respect is not only opposed to the applicable provision of
the law; it is also contrary to the letter and spirit of the regulations
which purportedly guide Customs personnel in their investigation of
dumping. Furthermore, no effort is being made to require the submis-
sion of information from the importer as to the manner in which, and
the considerations relating to which the price was set for unbranded
merchandise, or if such were indeed imported on a regular basis.
Adjustments To Reflect
Differences in The Cost
of Technical Services
Here, again, we understand that the Bureau of Customs
makes an adjustment in the home market price to reflect differences
in the cost of technical services in reliance upon a claim by the
foreign manufacturer that he renders technical services in connection
with his sales of merchandise in the home market which he does not
extend to purchasers of exported merchandise.
Even though such an uncorroborated claim were found to
be valid, it would still be necessary for the Bureau to be in
possession of evidence which establishes that the difference in price
PAGENO="0172"
3608
EXHIBIT 3
is due at least in part to the cost of technical service in the home
market, and which would support a determination of the particular
amount proper as a "due allowance" for such difference. Information
of this type, we understand, is not obtained and once again it appears
that the Bureau assumes the existence of a fact which the exporter
is supposed to prove.
Adjustments for
Selling Commissions
We are informed that Customs, in making adjustments to the
home market price for selling commission, does so in reliance upon a
claim by the foreign manufacturer that he sells through a commission
agent in the home market. Further, although selling commissions may
be incurred by the foreign manufacturer in his export sales, the Bureau
does not seem to regard such selling expenses as "other circumstances
of sale" for which allowances may be given.
An allowance cannot be made upon the basis of an assumption
that the difference in price is due to the difference in commission paid
in one market versus the other; proof establishing that the price
difference was due at least in part to the absence of a commission paid
on export sales is required. Further, the allowance is not automatically
equal to the amount of the commission; rather, proof establishing what
a "due allowance" is under the circumstances is required.
PAGENO="0173"
3609
EXHIBIT 3
Apart from these fundamental deficiencies, it is not
enough merely to take note of the selling commission. The Customs
Regulations at Sec. 14.7(b) (2) (ii) state that -
"reasonable allowances for selling expenses generally
will be made in cases where a reasonable allowance is
made for commissions in one of the markets under con-
sideration and no commission is paid in the other market
under consideration, the amount of such allowance being
limited to the actual selling expense incurred in the
one market or the total amount of the commission allowed
in such other market, whichever is less."
These words mean that if the selling commission is deducted from home
market price, the amount of the selling expense or commission, whichever
is less, must be deducted from the export price. This, we understand,
is not done by the Bureau.
The Practice of the Bureau of Customs in Averaging
Prices Over an Extended Period of Time in Such a
Manner as to Lower the Home Market Price in Effect
at or About the Time the Merchandise Under
Investigation was Exported to the United States so
as to Eliminate or Reduce the Margin of Dumping is
Clearly Improper.
The Bureau of Customs appears to have adopted a practice of
averaging prices over an extended period of time in such a manner as to
lower the home market price in effect at or about the time the merchandise
under investigation was exported to the United States so as to eliminate
or reduce the margin of dumping which may be found to exist after all of
the adjustments to the home market price described above have been made.
PAGENO="0174"
3610
EXHIBIT 3
There is absolutely no justification for averaging all
of the prices of foreign manufacturers over extended tine periods
as we understand is done. The Antidumping Act requires a finding
by the Secretary (or his delegate) of whether imported merchandise
is being, or is likely to be, sold in the United States at less
than its fair value. The averaging of prices over an extended past
period seems obviously contrary to a consideration of prices at
which the merchandise is being, or is likely to be, sold.
The Customs Regulations also require the focus to be on
sales at the time the merchandise complained about was exported to
the United States. Thus Sec. 14.7(a) (1) states,
"Merchandise imported into the United States will ordin- ~
arily be considered to have been sold, or to be likely to
be sold, at less than fair value if the purchase price or
exporter's sales price * * * is, or is likely to be, less
than the price * * * at which such or similar merchandise
* * * is sold for consumption in the country of exporta-
tion on or about the date of purchase or agreement to
purchase, of the merchandise imported into the United
States if purchase price applies, or on or about the date
of exportation thereof if exporter `s sales price applies."
(Emphasis added)
A footnote to this section of the regulations adds stress to the require-
ment that the price comparison be made in regard to sales made at the
time of exportation, as follows:
"Fair value is computed on the basis of sales for con-
sumption in the country of exportation * * * at or about
the date of the purchase or agreement to purchase of the
merchandise to be imported into the United States, or
the date of exportation."
PAGENO="0175"
3611
EXHIBIT 3
This footnote refers to a further, limited purpose, examination of
prices over a longer span, but in terms which provide no permission
for the averaging of prices, as follows:
However, in cases where it may be important to determine
either the stability of the market or its trend, as
well as to determine whether there has been a fictitious
sale * * *, it will be helpful to the Secretary to have
information as to sales made for consumption in the
country of exportation * * * over a significant period
of time immediately preceding the date of purchase or
agreement to purchase, or exportation."
Reporting price information for a time span to the Secretary
as a basis for him to consider the presence or absence of "stability
of the market or its trend" is quite a different matter than the
averaging of these prices to eliminate a margin of dumping plainly
established. Once a margin of dumping is found to exist, the Secretary's
duty is to make a determination of dumping. Price fluctuations may
result in a zero assessment of dumping duties on particular importa-
tions, but cannot properly be used as a basis for explaining away
the fact of dumping. We submit that the procedure being followed in
this respect is improper and unlawful.
CONCLUS ION
The chief difficulty with the administration of the
Antidumping Act is the evident willingness on the part of the Secretary
of the Treausry and his delegates to accept at face value the self-serving
PAGENO="0176"
3612
EXHIBIT 3
explanations of foreign exporters of the apparent margin of dumping
in their export sales to the United States. Current procedure
seemingly involves little or no objective corroboration of unsworn
statements of foreign producers.
Amendments to the Antidumping Act and a reform of its
administration somewhat along the lines contemplated by H. R. 16332,
and similar bills, which have been referred to your Committee, or
the exercise of the legislative oversight functions of your Committee
to this end will be required if the dumping aspect of unfair trade
practices in our foreign trade is to be effectively brought under
control.
PAGENO="0177"
CLASS OF COMPONENT
ACTIVE COMPONENTS -
RECEIVING TUBES
As end items
As tubes
Total
TV PICTURE TUBES
As end items
As tubes
Total
TRLESISTORS
As end items
As transistors
Total
RECTIFIERS AND DIODES
As end items
As rectifiers and diodes
Total
19,162 30,218 32,278 +68.'il
1,8,553 81,572 52,730 +8.6?~
67,715 111,790 85,008 +25.5%
715 1,524 1,614 +125.72~
95 103 388 +308.41
810 1,627 2,002 +147.2%
108,004 419,693 236,160 ÷118.61
_41,918 261,945 296,658 ÷607.71
149,922 681 38 532,818 +255.4%
70,685 124,098 126,856 +79.5?~
34,91~3 259,658 357,750 +924.01
105,628 383,756 484,606 +358.8%
PASSIVE COMPONENTS -
CAPACITORS, ELECTROLYTIC
As end items
As capacitors
Total
CAPACITORS, FIRED
As end items
As capacitors
Total
RESISTORS, FIXED
As end items
As resistors
Total
169,810 352,271 317,974 +87.21
30,000 265,000 155,837 +419.01
199,~dTO 617,271 473,811 +137.1%
538,148 1,081,756 1,018,554 ÷89.31
247,484 534,341 674,090 +172.41
3 2,616,097 1,692,644 +115.4%
713,430 1,475,525 1,361,893 +90.91
305,884 902,073 876,953 +186.71
1,019,314 2,377,598 2,238,846 +119.6%
(continued)
3613
EXHIBIT L~
APPENDIX TABLE I
U. S. DIRECT AND INDIRECT IMPORTS OF
ELECTRONIC COMPONENTS, 196N-1967
(in thousands of units)
1964 1966
I CHANGE
1967 1964-67
95-159 0 - 68 - pt. 8 - 12
PAGENO="0178"
3614
EXHIBIT L1
APPENDIX TABLE I - page 2
(in thousands of units)
CLASS OF COMPONENT 19611 1966
PASSIVE COMPONENTS (continued) -
INDUCTORS
As end items 213,2118 1i37,811
As inductors n.a. n.a.
TR4NSFOPMERS
As end items 28,0311 57,922
As transformers J~~j 56,013
Total 46,501 113,935
?~ CHANGE
1967 - 1961i-67
1,03,855 +89.1,?~
n.a.
55,152 +96.7?~
~7~jO7 +155.1~
102,259 19.9%
OTHER COMPONENTS -
CONTROLS
As end i tems
As controls
Total
LOUDSPEAKERS
As end items
As loudspeakers
Total
RECORD CHANGERS
As end items
As record changers
Total
32,538 68,823 611,008 +96.7?~
23,023 101,027 26,300 +11i.2~
55,561 169,850 90,308 +62.5%
17,169 35,907 32,1i29 +88.9%
8,161, 19,593 15,586 +90.9%
25,333 55,500 48,015 +89.5%
1,61, 1,523 1,9611 +323.3%
1,8112 ~ ~.~J2! +17.9%
2,306 4,578 4,135 +79.3%
SOURCE: Marketing Services Department, Electronic Industries Association.
PAGENO="0179"
CLASS OF COMPONENT
ACTIVE COMPONENTS -
Receiving Tubes:
1964
1966
1967
TV Picture Tubes:
1964
1966
1967
Transistors:
1964
1966
1967
Rectifiers & Diodes
1964
1966
1967
PASSIVE COMPONENTS -
Capacitors, Electrolytic:
1964
1966
1967
Capacitors, Fixed:
1964
1966
1967
5.6% 14.5% 20.1%
7.4% 20.2% 27.6%
11.0% 18.2% 29.2%
7.5% 1.0% 8.5%
11.3% 0.8% 12.1%
15.1% 3.6% 18.7%
74.0% 28.8% 102.7%
140.0% 87.3% 227.3%
107.3% 135.0% 242.3%
11.8% 5.8% 17.6%
10.3% 21.6% 31.9%
11.3% 31.7% 43.0%
3615
EXHIBIT L~
APPENDIX TABLE II
RATIO OF IMPORTS TO U. S. CONfrERCIAL SALES OF
SELECTED ELECTRONIC COMPONENTS, 1g6'4-1967
(Sales cmd Import Data in Millions of Units)
IMPORTS RATIQ, IMPORTS/SALES
As the As the
As End Compo- As End Compo-
SALES Items nent Total Items nent Total
3371
4O6~
29l~
9,513
13,450
10,682
1462
3002
2202
604
I ,204
1,128
19 49 68
30 82 112
32 53 85
715 95 810
1,524 103 1,627
1,614 388 2,002
108 42 150
420 262 682
236 297 533
71 35 106
124 260 384
127 358 485
216
360
279
1,723
2,584
1 ,826
170 30 200
352 265 617
318 156 474
538 248 786
1,082 534 1,616
1,019 674 1,693
78.7% 13.9% 92.6%
97.8% 73.6% 171.4%
114.0% 55.9% 169.9%
31.2% 14.4% 45.6%
41.9% 20.7% 62.5%
55.8% 36.9% 92.7%
(continued)
PAGENO="0180"
3616
EXHIBIT Lf
APPENDIX TABLE II - page 2
(Sales and Inrport Data in Millions of Units)
IMPORTS RATIO, IMPORTS/SALES
As the As the
As End Compo- As End Compo-
CLASS OF COMPONENT SALES Items nent Total Items nent Total
PASSIVE COMPONENTS (cont'd)
Resistors, Fixed:
1964 2,894 713 306 1,019 24.6% 10.6% 35.2%
1966 4,555 1,476 902 2,378 32.4% 19.8% 52.2%
1967 1,986 1,362 877 2,239 68.6% 44.2% 112.7%
Inductors & Transformers:
1964 54 241 18 259 446.3% 33.3% 479.6%
1966 95 496 56 552 522.1% 58.9% 581.0%
1967 95 459 47 506 483.2% 49.5% 532.6%
OThER COMPONENTS -
Controls:
1964
1966
1967
n.a.
256~
n.a.
33
69
64
23
101
26
56
170
90
n.a.
27.0%
n.a.
n.a.
39.5%
n.a.
n.a.
66.4%
n.a.
Loudspeakers:
1964
1966
1967
50
68
443
17
36
32
8
20
16
25
56
48
34.0%
52.9%
72.7%
16.0%
29.4%
36.4%
50.0%
82.4%
109.1%
Record Changers:
1964
1966
1967
n.a.
8.9
n.a.
0.5
1.5
2.0
1.8
3.1
2.2
2.3
4.6
4.2
n.a.
16.9%
n.a.
n.a.
34.8%
n.a.
n.a.
51.7%
n.a.
Sales in OEM and renewal markets.
2 Sales (consumer OEM).
Production.
SOURCE: Marketing Services Division, Electronic Industries Association; U. S. Department
of Commerce, BDSA, "Estimated Shipments of Selected Electronic Components,"
annual series (1967 annualized on the basis of first 3 quarters); Bureau of the
Census and BDSA, "Selected Electronic and Associated Products," annual series;
BDSA, "United States Imports of Selected Electronic Products"; Bureau of the
Census, official foreign trade statistics.
PAGENO="0181"
APPENDIX TABLE III*
C1~ss of Comonn~nt
U. S. BALANCE OF TRADE IN CONSUMER ELECTRONIC PRODUCTS AND C(}IPONENTS, 1964-1967
(In millions of dollars)
CONSUfrER ELECTRONIC PRODUCTS
1964
1966
1967
% Change
1964-67
EXPORTS
TV
$ 29.5
$ 35.5
$ 31.8
+7.8%
Radio
8.1
10.3
12.0
+48.1%
*
Phonographs (new)1
Tape Recorders
2.1
24.5
2.6
21.4
2.8
21.7
+33.3%
-11.4%
Other
n.a.
7.0
8.3
n.a.
Total
$ 64.2
$ 76.8
76.6
+19.3%
IMPORTS
TV
$ 36.3
$ 115.7
$ 125.5
+245.7%
Radio
101.1
160.9
197.9
+95.7%
Phonographs
20.5
38.8
30.7
+49.8%
Tape Recorders
54.7
74.8
104.7
+91.4%
Other
n.a.
14.1
11.0
Total
212.6
~44O4.3
$ 46~J~
n.a.
+121.0%
BALANCE OF TRADE
TV
-6.8
-80.2
-93.7
-1277.9%
Radio
-93.0
-150.6
-185.9
-99.9%
Phonographs
-18.4
-36.2
-27.9
-51.6%
Tape Recorders
-30.2
-53.4
-83.0
-174.8%
Other
n.a.
-7.1
-2.7
n.a.
Total
$ -148.4
$ -327.5
~~-393.2
-1 65.0%
1st
Quarter
1967
$ 7.5
2.6
0.6
5.2
1.8
17.7
$ 30.4
34.6
2.8
24.6
2.8
$~ 95.2
-22.9
-32.0
-2.2
-19.4
-1.0
~ -77.5
1st
Quarter
1968
$ 7.4
2.8
0.6
5.7
1.7
$ 18.2
$ 24.6
47.6
2.1
27.9
1 .9
$ 104.1
-17.2
-44.8
-1.5
-22.2
-0.2
$ -85.9
% Change
1st Qtr.
1967-68
-1 .3%
+7.7%
m
+9.6% ~
+2.8% ~
-19.1%
+37.6%
-25.0%
+13.4%
-32.1%
+9. 3%
+24.9%
-40.0%
+31.8%
-14.4%
+80.0%
-10.8%
(continued)
PAGENO="0182"
3618
EXHIBIT 4
a)
L. 03 U-U ~`Q ~U 8-U
C 4-~ `.0 c-4 0 ~3i LA 0'i ~`I0) (`4 0 -~ 0)
`tiC'' * * * *L.
~c N- N-, r('i C 0~ - o~T0~ ((`tO 0~ N
L) 4-~ `.0 `.0 I C~ C') 0~ IU\IN -~ LA r~\
U) 0~ I + + I + N
8-U-'-
a) -4. coI~o LA LA1-i .- 0 r'tlco
`I' `I. * .1.
U) I- `.0 (`\ c~ (`-413-) LA N-0) IN C'~ ~
(0 0t - IN IN I + I I
4-/U-
- r-~ c'.jlo o~ N- `-lao N-C ~-l'U
4-'4-'N- . *1. * `I. .1.
U) 1.. `.0 -3- LA `(`~I~() N- C('t'.0 IC- C~U ~) N-ItO
-IN I-i
3'-
C' --
a) 6-U 6-U 8-U U't a-U 6-U 8-U N 8-U 6-U 8-U N
D) N- LA ri C') to 0'03 tO 0-30 0
C'.0 * *
O N- N 0 0) 0 C') `~0 0) 0 (`4 (`4 N
C -3- N- I -1- -3- -o- N- 0) 0 N- LA t'~
L) `~0 + + C') (`t N C') I
c~+4
8-U-- ÷ I
N LA C~t r(')IN C~' -3- N-LU) ~ `.~
a) -~ N- C('t3-t'.0IO) -`.o'.oki N.c'J0±l1
(:a~ U) `.0 - -3-IC'. C') C'4I~0 + `IN
U) U, 0~ I 1 +14
-
4/U- 4/U- 4/U-
(U)
N c-, a-to ~-fo c~-~ 0) N-~0) -1~ - -3-h'
0 `.o'.o.o-IC-- e~t~.ocoIco t40)LAl3-)
.J Co `.0 LAIto I~t C'.41tO + ("uN
I I `~I~
U-- `c~ I I 1 0
~ tC'~ 4-/U- r-~
x
N
E `.0 C~4 -~-I~ (`4 N-'.0~t0 `.0 LA
~ 3--'.0Ic.4 LAOLAkI ~cck
- -3-IC'. IN I -1~ItO
+8-4
.0 .0 .0
3 3 3
4-' 1- U-- F-
C
C) C) C) C)
C C C C
o `-U) `-U) `-U)
0. >0.) >0 >0
E `-.0 *-.0 ~U)'-.0
0 (1) 03 03
C..) 1- 0 1- t'-1 0 I-C-I `)~ 0 I- ~4
Z a) U) (3) U) ~Q) U)
4- CLI t~ a) I~ 0 (3) i- 0.-i ~ a) I~
0 Z LO 1-0 1-0
0 C 3 4. C 3 -` - C'. c 3
U) ü. 0 4-' U) 0 4- U) 0 0 -` U)
~ ~ ~ Lu.- LU.-
(0 0 Cl) 4-j.- U) C--) Cl) 4.I*- fl C') E~) 4-' U) C'-)
U E-jUci.CU) U0..CU) L)UC3.CU)
C-) CC~ 0.) 0 +~ (3) 0 -4) ~ ~) 0 -4~)
Lii 0->-'-O 0'->LO ~,.>L-0
> PwF-I-E ~wI-I-E-, ~LtiI-I--E
C,) U--I
PAGENO="0183"
APPENDIX TABLE III - page 3
PASSIVE CC1~1P0NENTS
(In millions of dollars)
Class of Component
1964
1966
1967
1964-67
EXPORTS
Capacitors
Resistors
$
16.3 $ 21.1 $ 20.2
15.7 29.5~ 3l.l~
+23.9%
+98.1%
Inductors and Transformers
5.1
12.2k
1l.7~
+129.4%
Total
j
37.1 $ 62.8 $ .63.0
IMPORTS
Capacitors
Resistors
$
8.3 $ 24.4 $ 23.3
4*35 12.9~ 12.4~
+180.7%
+188.4%
Inductors and Transformers
5.9
12.1
21.4
+262.7%
Total
$
18.5 $ 49.4 $ 57.1
+208.6%
BALARCE OF TRADE
Capacitors
$
+8.0 $ -3.3 $ -3.1
-78.2%
Resistors
+11.4
+16.6
+18.7
+64.0%
Inductors and Transformers
-0.8
+0.1
-9.7
-1112.5%
Total
+18.6 $ +13.4 $ +5.9
-68.3%
Quarter
Quarter
1st Qtr.
1967
1968
1967-68
$
5.6
8.i~
$ 5.2
8.1~
-7.1%
-
$
3.0k
16.7
2.9+
$ 16.2
-3.3%
~T7~
$
6.8
$ 6.3
-7.4%
3.6
3.6
-
2.0
1.8
-10.0%
$
12.4
$ 11.7
-5.6%
$
-1.2
$ -1.1
-8.3%
+4.5
+4.5
-
+1.0
+1.1
+10.0%
$
+4.3
$ +4.5
+4.7%
>(
:i:
w
(continued)
PAGENO="0184"
APPENDIX TABLE III - page 4
OThER COMPONENTS
(In millions of doilca's)
1st
Quarter
1967
1st
Quarter
1968
% Change
1st Qtr.
1967-68
EXPORTS
Loudspeakers
Earphones and Head Sets
Microphones
Parts for Consumer
Electronic Products
and for Components
Total
IMPORTS
Loudspeakers
Earphones and Head Sets
Microphones
Parts for Consumer
Electronic Products
and for Components
Total
BALANCE OF TRADE
Loudspeakers
Earphones and Head Sets
Microphones
Parts for Consumer
Electronic Products
and for Components
$ 2.1 $ 4.4 $ 5.3 +152.4~4
n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a.
n.a. 2.3 2.6 n.a.
n.a. 61.8 74.1 n.a.
~ $ 82.0
$ 4.7 $ 10.4 $ 10.6 +125.5%
2.7 3.5 3.3 +22.2%
2.1 4.1 4.1 +95.2°4
16.2 21.4 +32.1%
~ $ 23.4 +29.3%
19.4 23.5
$ 23.8 ~28.1
-1.3 $ -1.6
n.a. n.a.
-0.4 -0.2
-3.2 -2.1 -34.4%
Class of Component
% Change
1964 1966 1967 1964-67
$ 1.2 $ 1.3
n.a. n.a.
0.7 0.7
+8.3%
n.a.
ni
I
I
-~
30.4 113.6 83.9 +176.0%
~ $ 131.6 ~1O9 +155.4%
$ 2.5 $ 2.9 +16.0%
0.8 0.8 -
1.1 0.9 -18.2%
$ -2.6 $ -6.0 $ -5.3
n.a. n.a. n.a.
n.a. -1.8 -1.5
-103.8%
n .a.
n.a.
+21 . 1%
+18.1%
-23.1%
n.a.
-50.0%
n.a. -51.8 -9.8 n.e.
1 Excluding coin-operated.
2 Import data for rectifiers and diodes are not separately stated in U. S. foreign trade statistics. The
classification "other semiconductors" in the import statistics includes, in addition to rectifiers and
diodes, other types of semiconductors which are not primarily used in consumer electronic products. Hence,
(continued)
PAGENO="0185"
APPENDIX TABLE III - page 5
NOTES (continued)
2 (continued)
the only directly comparable foreign trade data for the type of semiconductor used in consumer
electronic products is limited to transistors.
Effective January 1, 1966, data for electronic parts, n.e.c." are included with exports of resistors
and parts thereof, making the data not comparable to import data for resistors.
~ Classification changed effective January 1, 1965, from inductors (including transformers and coils) to
include coils, transformers, reactors, chokes, and parts.
Includes potentiometers and parts of resistors.
SOURCE: Marketing Services Department, Electronic Industries Association; U. S. Department of Commerce, -~
BDSA, "United States Imports and Domestic Exports of Selected Electronic Products," annual data;
Bureau of the Census, official foreign trade statistics.
PAGENO="0186"
3622
EXHIBIT 4
APPENDIX TABLE IV
EMPLOYMENT AND ESTABLISHMENTS IN THE U. S. CONSOMER ELECTRONIC PRODUCTS
AND ELECTRONIC COMPONENTS INDUSTRIES, 1967 (MID MARCH)
CONSUMER ELECTRONIC ELECTRONIC COMPONENTS
PRODUCTS (SIC 3651 (SIC 367) TOTAL
No. of No. of No. of
Employ- Establish- Employ- Establish- Employ- Establish-
ment cents cent cents cent ments~_
43,504 79 39,690 204 83,194 283
9,440 113 57,981 459 67,421 572
18,920 153 47,295 263 66,215 416
31,108 16 18,061 63 49,169 79
4,885 27 41,747 147 46,632 174
9,436 50 28,675 245 38,111 295
2,625 19 31,917 182 314,51+2 201
297 13 13,975 80 14,272 93
1,222 21 12,931 64 14,153 85
116* 5 10,761 18 10,877 23
8,223 23 1,729 15 9,952 38
7,860 9 7,860 9
2,360 7 5,336 17 7,696 24
1,535 2 5,470 23 7,005 25
6,834 19 6,834 19
837* 7 5,971 39 6,808 46
1,537* 3 5,237 21 6,774 24
1,883* 4 3,872* 10 5,755 14
925 22 4,638* 56 5,563 78
1,876 20 2,932 45 4,808 65
807 8 3,421 34 4,228 42
4,032 56 4,032 56
1,504* 3 1,881* 3 3,385 6
3,348* 9 3,348 9
3,000* 2 3,000 2
6 2,784 6
3 2,300 5
2,264 6
30 2,027 33
12 1,710 12
Illinois
California
New York
Indiana
Pennsyl van i a
New Jersey
Mas sachusetts
Connecti cut
Oh i o
Arizona
Tennessee
South Carolina
Iowa
North Carolina
New Hampshire
Minnesota
Virginia
Kentucky
Texas
Michigan
Wisconsin
Florida
Alabama
Nebraska
Vermont
Maine
Mississippi
Arkansas
Ma ryland
Rhode Island
350* 2
2,264 6
83 3
2,784
1,950*
1 ,944
1,710
(continued)
PAGENO="0187"
3623
EXHIBIT L~
APPENDIX TABLE IV - pcige 2
CONSUMER
PRODUCTS
ELECTRONIC
(sic 365)
No. of
ELECTRONIC
(sic
COMPONENTS
367)
TOTAL
No. of
-
No. of
Empl-oy-
Establish-
Employ-
Establish-
Employ-
Establish-
ment
- men ts
men t
men ts
ment
men ts
Kansas
.
.
1,598
15
1,598
15
Hawaii
.
.
1,500*
1
1,500
1
West Virginia
.
.
1,205
7
1,205
7
Missouri
98*
5
1,077
19
1,175
24
Colorado
815*
7
313
10
1,128
17
South Dakota
927*
4
927
4
Utah
556*
3
556
3
Oklahoma
229
6
229
6
New Mexico
198
9
198
9
Idaho
181*
2
181
2
Washington
.
.
117
13
117
13
Delaware
.
.
111+
5
111+
5
TOTAL, 42 STATES
11+6,650
618
384,997
2,228
531,61+7
2,846
UNITED STATES
TOTAL 144,998 656 401,916 2,247 546,914 2,903
* Estimated.
NOTE: The difference between the numerical total shown at the foot of each column
and the "United States Total" shown below it is accounted for by the necessity
of estimating employment in those States in which employment data are marked
with an asterisk. To avoid disclosure in certain instances, the source of
the data omits reporting actual employment figures.
SOURCE: U. 5. Department *of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, 1967 County Business
Patterns.
PAGENO="0188"
3624
The CHAIRMAN. We thank you, Mr. Stewart, for your very fine
presentation of your po~nt of view and that of your clients. Any ques-
tions? Mr. Curtis.
Mr. CURTIS. I want to again commend Mr. Stewart for the fine
research he has done in presenting his material. It certainly does move
forward the dialog.
Let me ask you, because you have testified in others areas too-here
I begin to see possibly a glimmering of guidelines for qoutas-if you
would argue that you apply quotas in those areas which prove to be
labor int.ensive, am I correct?
Is that where you might distinguish between those industries to
which Congress would apply quotas and those that we wouldn't ?
Mr. STEWART. Mr. Curtis, it is certainly true that in the industries
that are highly labor intensive you find problems of this comparable
magnitude though I must say that it is very extreme in the electronic
case, more advanced than any I have seen.
Mr. CURTIS. What I am seeking is some guidance. You very properly
are representing the proponents of American industry, and agriculture,
and services, but in your zeal to represent the proponents I know you
recognize the need to put that in the context of the whole.
Let me ask it this way. Would you advocate our going over com-
pletely to the quota license system for regulating international trade in
all areas?
Mr. STEWART. This group that I represent does not advocate a
total embracing of quotas for the regulation of all imports. We say this
industry certainly requires that assistance and we support a bill
introduced by Mr. Collier-
Mr. CURTIS. Yes, I understand all that.
Mr. STEWART (continuing). That includes other industries that
are labor-intensive that appear to us to be similarly affected
Mr. CURTIS. That is why I asked the question. Is one of your guide-
lines that you are suggesting the Congress consider in determining
whether to apply the quota approach th~s labor-intensive factor?
Mr. STEWART. Yes, I would concede that that should be a guideline.
Mr. CURTIS. Are there any other guidelines, and there need not be
necessarily-that is a pretty important one. I am just wondering if
there are any other guidelines that you would suggest.
Mr. STEWART. The guidelines such as those set forth in the Collier
bill contemplate a relatively high level of market penetration by
imports. In the case of the electronic industries you would abstract the
guideline of a very much higher rate of imports than of exports and an
absolute deficit in the affected products in our balance of trade..
If you combine labor-intensiveness, high rate of increase of imports
in relation to exports, and absolute trade deficit you are describing a
situation in which there are significant losses of jobs in the American
economy and an industry whose further growth is stunted by market
disruption.
In those instance identified by those criteria there should be import
relief.
Mr. CURTIS. And is the quota in the Collier bill a flexible one, as we
have in the meat bill and others? Is it triggered at a certain level of
imports?
PAGENO="0189"
3625
Mr. STEWART. It is not on the basis of a trigger point but it is
flexible in that a recent period is selected as a base period, for the
statutory quotas and their annual adjustment in the level of the
quotas as the market grows.
The President, however, Mr. Curtis, and this is most important in
the Collier bill, is given plenary power to enter into negotiations with
the affected countries under gmdelines to work out amicable solutions,
and this is the crux of the matter.
If it can be done in cotton textiles amicably, as it was, it can be
done in other major sectors of American industry that are labor
intensive and are similarly affected such as electronic components.
Mr. Cuirns. But, Mr. Stewart, the cotton textile people have been
in here saying that this approach hasn't worked and that they are
still in trouble. The rest of the textile industry, especially the man-
made fiber area, with I think considerable justification, is pointing out
that while this has been done in cotton textiles it doesn't apply to
them. So the question arises, if the cotton textile approach, the quota
approach, was good why hasn't it worked?
I don't want you to have the wrong remedy.
Mr. STEWART. As I learned from listening to the testimony of the
domestic textile industry witnesses, one of the problems with the
cotton textile arrangement was that it did not include a proper scope
of articles, so that it could be avoided by transferring from one area
to another.
Secondly, it did not seem to them that it was being administered
as much in the spirit of what was intended, though they are not willing
to give it up and this means that the quality of administration is bet-
ter than what the situation would be otherwise.
Now, in the case of electronic components if you were to draw the
bill so as to include some of these affected components and not others
or to leave out the summation of the components as assemblies, the
consumer products, then you would have problems similar to the cot-
ton textile arrangement in which quotas could be evaded, but if you
include, as the Collier bill does, both the consumer electronic products
and components used therein you would not have those problems.
Mr. Cuirns. Except for one thing. Thank goodness for the great
innovation in our society, but in textiles, as well as certainly in elec-
tronic components what is the pattern today is not the pattern tomor-
row. This is one of the reasons I worry about this kind of approach
where you are dealing with past markets. What we are really seeking
to solve is problems of anticipation and what future markets are going
to be.
Maybe this can be done within the context of quotas, but I suggest
that the difficulties that the cotton textile people have experienced are
almost intrinsically the result of the quota system and I think what-
ever you do you are going to run into this same trouble in other indus-
tries. You always have problems of circumvention of the quota and
you always have the question of how you administer the laws.
The only way I know to operate is to abide by the laws we have,
rather than subvert them by administrative action. Change laws when
they become outmoded but once you go to this business, which I think
we have today, of the administration picking and choosing what laws
it wants to enforce and not paying any attention to the laws it doesn't
PAGENO="0190"
3626
want to enforce, that is a destruction of orderly society per se. Your
criticism of the antidumping administration was very instructive in
this regard.
I think I share a lot of that criticism with you which leads me to
this question.
Why not develop the antidumping laws, rewrite those, to try to hit
at these problems? I think you are making excellent points. Cost
accounting now has advanced to the point where we can start looking
into the real practices of these countries abroad and particularly in
the area of Government subsidy. We need cost accounting to find out
where there has been subsidization.
Why isn't this a channel that your industry might pursue here?
Mr. STEWART. For this reason, and it is an important reason. We
offered our comments on the Antidumping Act in an effort to be of
service to the committee which had expressed an interest in the subject.
In industries that are affected by imports that are launched against
this country on the basis of incremental pricing and where that is the
margin of advantage, effective enforcement of the Antidumping Act
would help but in industries such as electronics where the full home
market price in Japan and in Hong Kong is so far below the domestic
price that we cannot compete without some import regulation the
Antidumping Act itself does not redress that problem so you need to
have an array of trade regulating mechanisms, some which prevent
unfair trade, which is what dumping is, and others which recognize
the difference in the cost of living abroad and in the United States
and the impact of that difference on labor-intensive industries.
Mr. Ctrwns. We have talked about this before. There is no disagree-
ment between you and me on this score. Back in 1957, as you know,
I sought to identify as an unfair trade practice which I wanted to see
us move to correct wage differentials related to productivity. This is
a difficult thing to try to measure, but very few people showed any in-
terest in it.
I still have an interest in trying to do it. I would do it frankly
through the tariff approach just as the countervailing duty seeks to
use the tariff approach in correcting government subsidies. We could
use this approach to correct other practices.
Well, I just worry about whether the quota is the correct approach.
Do you view this quota approach as something that would be perma-
nent? Is this something that you think is to meet immediate need, or iS
this something that we would have from now on?
Would there be a terminus to this approach?
Mr. STEWART. The same process of legislative review that this com-
mittee has performed on the many extensions of the Trade Agree-
ments Act over time and a refinement of the provisions of that act
would be carried out in connection with any type of legislation that
involved the use of quotas as an additional trade regulating means.
The fact that you adopted quota machinery here and now as a suf-
ficient solution for the present type of problems that we have doesn't
mean that you are committing future Congresses forevermore to that
approach.
Mr. Cuirns. That is true. In some legislation we try to adont a base
and set a fundamental theory that hopefully might last 20 or 30 years.
The cotton textile agreement quota was put on as if it were temporary.
PAGENO="0191"
3627
In fact, it was only said to be, but it of course turns out~ not to be
temporary.
Let me ask a couple of more questions on this job situation. What
was the employment in 1948 in this particular segment of industry
you are representing?
Mr. STEWART. I would have to submit that for the record.
Mr. CURTIS. Do you have any figures? The reason I picked 1948 was
because in your testimony you referred to the industry 20 years ago,
but any figure, for instance 1950, would be adequate.
Mr. STEWART. I can go back to 1959, Mr. Curtis.
Mr. Cumns. At least give me that. That will give me something.
Mr. STEWART. The electronic components industry, standard indus-
trial classification 367, in the year 1959 had 213,300 employees.
Mr. CtmTIs. You just gave us a figure in your other testimony that
they are now employing 500,000 in 1968.
Mr. STEWART. I believe that that was a combined total for that in-
dustry and consumer electronic products.
Mr. CURTIS. Can you give me the comparable figure which relates
to the same industry for 1968?
Mr. STEWART. I can give it to you for April of 1968, Mr. Curtis.
That figure is 350,400.
Mr. CURTIS. I am going to quarrel with you a little bit, as I have
with other witnesses when you put so much emphasis on loss of jobs.
Of course what you are really talking about isn't real jobs where peo-
ple are or were employed. You are talking about potentials. Here your
industry has gone in 1959 from a 213,000 employment figure to 350,000
in 1968, not a loss of jobs at all. That doesn't mean you haven't got
problems though.
I have been misquoted so often on the issue of jobs that I am sick
of it. I am concerned about jobs, but here we are trying to look at
jobs in the context of a very dynamic society.
We have an unemployment rate right now which is well below
4 percent. We have more jobs going begging than there are unem-
ployed. We have a very serious problem of utilizing these unemployed
in jobs or hopefully in this economic system which we could do with
adequate training and retraining. We just haven't been doing that,
but we have, as we always have had in the United States, a shortage
of labor. This is one reason these labor-intensive industries become
less labor-intensive as we automate by necessity for lack of workers.
Some workers are displaced from a particular job by automation
but it doesn't mean that human beings are not being employed. It
may mean they are not being employed in your particular industry
and that the labor unions that are in that industry are not getting
dues, but this doesn't mean these men and women aren't being gain-
fully employed. If in fact it is a labor-intensive industry the workers
are now probably being employed in an industry that is not so labor
intensive and therefore their wages are higher.
I just want this issue of jobs in context. If anyone can complain
about loss of jobs look at American agriculture where employment
now is about 6 percent of our society from a much higher level, and
coal, which was three times the employment which it is, and yet our
coal industry has in effect driven out the coal industry of Western
Europe by its efficiency.
PAGENO="0192"
3628
Incidentally, in this instance I think we did a miserable job-by
"we" I mean our labor leaders, and our coal industry-in the manner
in which the coal miners lost their jobs. There were no programs for
training and retraining, but there is no question about what the net
result has been.
The telephone people say, "If we were to provide the telephone
services that are provided in our society today, which is possible
through the dial system, if we were doing that through the old switch-
board system we would be employing every woman in the United
States". So I hope that the testimony of the various industries that
are pointing out their problems, and I know they have some real ones,
will direct their attention to this employment factor in a little different
way.
Yours is an emotional appeal and it is proper appeal if it is soundly
based, but it certainly isn't in light of your own figures you gave me.
Mr. STEWART. Mr. Curtis, I respectfully suggest that to look at the
total increase in employment of any industry from 1959 to 1968, and
to note that there was an increase and t.hen to draw the conclusion
there therefore can be no problems-
Mr. CURTIS. I didn't draw that conclusion. Did I draw that conclu-
sion? I said there are problems.
Mr. STEWART. That is the inference that I got.
Mr. CURTIS. Well, I said they are not of the nature that you describe
as being lost jobs.
Mr. STEWART. Well, merely allow me to complete my statement.
Mr. CURTIS. I just want you to quote me accurately.
Mr. STEWART. I apologize if I appeared to misquote you, sir. We
have not in this testimony complained about the increase in imports
from 1959. We have come before you at a moment of time when the
rate of increase in imports from 1964 to 1967 has risen so exceptionally
and the market penetration has risen to such levels that now companies
in the industry are experiencing a loss of jobs due to imports, and it
seems to us that it is always appropriate for the Congress to consider
the present situation and the composition of forces that influence this.
Mr. CURTIS. There is no question that we will consider the present
situation but, Mr. Stewart, the reason I asked you for figures for 20
years ago was that you were pointing out the impact of imports of
20 years ago. That was the point, so I wanted to see the figures for 20
years ago and you didn't have them.
I wasn't the one that picked 1959 out. You couldn't give me the fig-
ures for 1948 and I said, well, give me whatever you can. You had
directed your complaint to this committee with respect to imports by
going back 20 years.
Mr. STEWART. Not so, Mr. Curtis.
Mr. CURTIS. I think my cross examination was very much in context
with what you are saying.
Mr. STEWART. I had no objection to it. I was attempting to respond
to a question that had been asked by Mr. Collier or one of your other
colleagues of the prior witness that was not answered.
Mr. CURTIS. I am trying to look at these issues in the proper light
and I know you are, and I want to close my interrogation again on a
note of compliment. If only others would do as well as you do in dig-
ging into the details and the facts we would have this dialog moving
PAGENO="0193"
3629
along so much better. I hope we are all interested in getting at the
problems and my criticism here, and I will repeat it, is this quoting of
jobs that have disappeared.
You are talking about potential jobs. I had the same argument
from the steel people. They were talking about 80,000 jobs lost and
actually there was an increase in employment in the steel industry
at the time they said 80,000 jobs were lost. That doesn't mean there
isn't any problem. There is, but there is still a different kind of prob-
lem than those kinds of statements would indicate to the public.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
The CHAIRMAN. Did you have anything further?
Mr. STEWART. Merely to call to Mr. Curtis' attention and that of
the other members of the committee exhibit 4, appendix table 4 of
our testimony, which shows the employment by State in each of the
42 States that have these industries present and to make the point
which my colleagues here have emphasized to me just by looking at
those States you will recognize that a great deal of the employment
in this industry, and this table is the last table in the document, is
located away from metropolitan areas where it provides employment
for people who live in rural and suburban communities, which is espe-
cially important in view of our social problems at this particular time.
Thank you again, Mr. Chairman.
The CHAIRMAN. There is one weakness in this table, Mr. Stewart.
Mr. STEWART. What is that, Mr. Chairman?
The CHAIRMAN. I don't see the State represented by the chairman
on this with very many people employed.
Mr. STEWART. That is true, but it is like Dartmouth College. It is
small but there are those of us who love it.
The CHAIRMAN. I knew there was an explanation. Mr. Betts.
Mr. BETTS. Mr. Stewart, I was of course interested in your tables
on imports of component parts where you referred to TV picture
tubes. I think we were pretty deep in that subject once before in
this committee, and somewhere along the line the color tubes got
separated from the black and white.
I was wondering what the status is on that. I think that was a
real problem in the industry, wasn't it, at that time?
Mr. STEWART. It still is a problem. It is a problem, however, which
is the province of another division of the Electronic Industries As-
sociation and I am not an authorized spokesman of that division.
Essentially what occurred was that first this committee and the
Congress very properly corrected an error that had been made by the
Tariff Commission in the rate of duty on picture tubes from 121/2. to
30 percent and in the Tariff Schedules Technical Amendment Act as
it passed this committee that error was corrected.
It was then represented to the Finance Committee that there was
a shortage of color television picture tubes on the American market
and this would penalize American companies.
On the basis of those representations this committee and the Finance
Committee imposed a moratorium on the collection of the proper duty
until September 1, 1969.
The fact of the matter is that there was then no shortage and there
is now a considerable amount of excess capacity in this country for
producing color TV picture tubes.
95-159-68-pt. 8-13
PAGENO="0194"
3630
In 1967, as an example, the capacity for production of tubes was
10.4 million. The actual production was only 8.4. This was a capacity
of 2 million out of 10 million or 20 percent of the capacity was un-
used, and this is contributing to the distress that has been experienced
in the tube industry and there are bills pending before this commit-
tee, cosponsored by Members on both sides of the aisle, to cancel out
that moratorium so that the proper duty may now be collected, and I
respectfully submit that, as this committee has done in the past when
it legislated on the basis of a mistake in fact, it ought promptly now
to correct that mistake and to repeal the moratorium on the proper
duty on color television picture tubes.
Mr. BETTS. Then that is the overall picture even though it might
not be on this particular subject?
~ Mr. STEWART. Correct.
Mr. BETTS. I think this question was asked before. But I will ask
it again. I am not sure whether you got into it or not in your presenta-
tion but do you have a comparison between Japanese wage scales,
and American wage scales?
Mr. STEWART. Is there a difference?
Mr. BETTS. Yes.
Mr. STEWART. Not in our statement. I would be glad to submit that
for the record.
Mr. BETTS. I would like it. Do you recall offhand what it is?
Mr. STEWART. Yes; I do generally. It is difficult to generalize it about
Japan because people begin entering the work force in Japan, young
girls in their teens, who live in company dormitories and who receive
lower wage rates than adults, for example, but the general level of
wages in Japan in the electronic industries as I understand it is in
the approximate order of 50 to 60 cents an hour, in Hong Kong in
the approximate order of 16 cents an hour, in South Korea in the ap-
proximate order of 14 cents an hour, and in Taiwan, about 12 cents
an hour.
In the United States in the electronic components industry for 196T
the average hourly earnings were $2.40 an hour, on the average for
the whole industry in components, and our leaders have made the
point frequently we can be very efficient, we can be more efficient even
than the Japanese, let us say, but we can't be that much more efficient
in producing products in a labor-intensive industry to overcome that
amount of. wage difference.
Mr. BETTS. Were you going to submit it?
Mr. STEWART. I will submit the actual statistics that I can develop
on that subject, Mr. Betts.
(The following letter was received by the committee:)
LINCOLN & STEWART,
ATTORNEYS AT LAW,
Washington, D.C., July 3, 1968.
Hon. JACKSON E. Barrs,
House of Representatives,
Washington, D.C.
DEAR Mn. Bnrrs: During my appearance before the Committee on Ways and
Means on June 25, 1968, on behalf of the Parts and Distributor Products
Divisions of the Electronic Industries Association and the American Loud-
speakers Manufactures Association, you asked if I could submit for the record
information pertaining to wage rates in electronic manufacturing in Japan and
other Asian nations which are supplying electronic imports to the United States~
PAGENO="0195"
3631
We have been able to secure such information, and supply it in the form of
the attached table. The table sets forth the wages being paid by typical elec-
tronic manufacturers in Hong Kong, Taiwan, Korea, and Japan. All of them
are engaged in high labor content light electronic assembly work. The wage
figures are given in dollars per hour and include all fringes and benefits such
as holidays, vacations, annual bonuses, and other fringes. They are applicable
to the average payroll at the time indicated for each of the companies inter-
viewed and, therefore, include the average of new workers and workers with
considerable seniority.
For comparison purposes, the average hourly earnings of workers in the
U.S. electronic components and accessories industry (Standard Industrial
Classification 367) in the spring of 1968 was $2.51 per hour, in the fall of 1967,
$2.45, and in the summer of 1967, $2.41, as reported by the U.S. Department
of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, in Employment and Earnings Statistics
for the United States. These average hourly earnings exclude such "fringe
benefits" as irregular bonuses, retroactive items, payments of various welfare
benefits, and payroll taxes paid by employers.
We thank you for your interest in this matter.
Sincerely yours,
EUGENE L. STEWART.
FAR EAST COMPARATIVE WAGES
Dollar per hour Time period
Hong Kongl 0.165 Spring 1968.
Koreas 0.l2OtoO.140 Fall1967.
Taiwans 0.122 Fall 1967.
Japan4 0.60 Summer 1967.
1 Based on actual experience of our specific company.
2 Based on interviews with selected American manufacturers engaged in high labor content, light assembly operations
(3 companies).
3 Based on interviews with selected American manufacturers engaged in high labor content, light assembly operations.
4 Based on report of interviews with selected Japanese manufacturers engaged in light assembly operations.
Mr. BETTS. I want a copy of it and I want to compliment you for
your presentation today.
Mr. STEWART. Thank you, Mr. Betts.
The CHAIRMAN. Mr. Schneebeli.
Mr. SOHNEEBELI. Mr. Stewart, I also want to congratulate you on a
very comprehensive and factual statement. I think it is excellent. I
plan to study it with great interest. I think you have so many facts in
here that we should all study it further.
In the interest of time I have no questions to ask you but I do agree
with your statement on Dartmouth College. I think it was an appro-
priate statement.
Thank you.
The CHAIRMAN. Mr. Broyhill.
Mr. BROYHILL. I should like to associate myself with the remarks of
my colleagues in commending you. It was a very effective presentation,
Mr. Stewart. I can see why you appear before the committee on several
occasions representing several different clients. You make a most clear
and persuasive presentation. I regret that you aren't sitting at the con-
ference table when we negotiate some of these trade agreements.
What was the amount of the average wage rate that you gave to
Mr. Betts a moment ago in the United States in 1967?
Mr. STEWART. In the components industry, $2.40.
Mr. BROYHILL. That is 1967?
Mr. STEWART. Yes, sir.
Mr. BROYHILL. And it has gone up some since then, hasn't it?
Mr. STEWART. Yes, sir.
PAGENO="0196"
3632
Mr. BROYIIILL. In one of your tables here you point out the differ-
ence in the tariff rates between the United States, Japan and the Euro-
pean market. Are we exporting any of these goods to Japan? You
showed on one of these charts we got about 65 percent of the imports
from Japan. Here Japan has an average of about 100 percent more
tariff rate than we have.
Are any of these places that have high tariff rates, the Common
Market and United Kingdom, to which we have sent about $300 million
in exports as of 1967?
Mr. STEWART. Let us take a few categories. On television receivers,
in 1966 we exported television receivers to Japan of the value of
$264,000 and imported television receivers from Japan of a value of
$106,754,000. Let us take radio broadcast receivers. In 1966 the official
statistics of the United Nations, which is the source of these answers,
shows zero exports from the United States to Japan and imports of
$135,239,000.
On sound recorders, phonographs, and parts in 1966 the United
States exported $5,331,000 worth of those products to Japan while im-
porting $78,947,000.
Does that give you the kind of information you want?
Mr. BR0YHILL. Yes. In fact these duty rates imposed by Japan are
somewhat meaningless even though they are three or four times as
high as the duty we impose. If Japan reduced her duties we could not
increase our trade with Japan, or could we?
Mr. STEWART. The fact of the matter is that apart from the rate of
duty there are structural reasons why it is impossible to export a com-
petitive electronic product to Japan. Business there is done on the basis
of trading companies. The trading companies are already locked in
contractually with the Japanese manufacturers.
It is difficult for an American manufacturer to get the attention of
a trading company because if he has any substantial business or dis-
tribution in electronic products based on his Japanese business he will
lose it.
Also if you could find an importer who wants to brave all of those
difficulties he cannot get an allocation of foreign exchange from his
bank for products that are directly competitive with Japanese indus-
try. This is a matter of practice, not formal Government regulation.
Mr. BROYHILL. Thank you.
The CHAIRMAN. We thank you, Mr. Stewart, and those at the table
with you for your testimony.
Mr. STEWART. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
(The following telegrams were received, for the record, by the com-
mittee:)
NEW YORK, N.Y.
JnZy 12, 1968.
Hon. WILBUR P. MILLS,
Chairman, House Committee on Ways and Means,
Washington, D.C.
As a member company of the parts division of the Electronics Industries As-
sociation, we hereby disassociate, repeat disassociate, ourselves from the state-
ment of Eugene F. Stewart in behalf of the parts division of EIA in support of
quotas on imports of electronic articles made to your committee on June 25, 1068,
during the hearings on HR. 17551. Please insert this telegram in the record of
these hearings immediately following Mr. Stewart's statement.
MICHAEL BLUMENTHAL,
President, Bendico Internationa~, T1~e Bendico Corp.
PAGENO="0197"
3633
ERIE, PA.,
July 11, 196g.
Hon. WILBUR D. MILLS,
Chairman, House Comnvtttee on Ways and Means,
Washington, D.C.
As a member company of the parts division of the Electronic Industries Assoc.
we hereby disassociate, repeat disassociate, ourselves from the statement of Eu-
gene F. Stewart in behalf of the parts division of EIA in support of quotas on
imports of electronic articles made to your committee on June 25, 1968, during the
hearings on H.R. 17551. Please insert this telegram in the record of these hear-
ings immediately following Mr. Stewart's statement.
GEORGE P. FBYLING,
President, Erie Technical Products, Inc., Erie, Pac
July 11, 1968.
Hon. WILBUR D. MILLS, Chairman
House Committee on Ways and Means,
Washington, D.C.
As a member company of the parts division of the Electronic Industries As-
sociation, we hereby diassociate, repeat disassociate, ourselves from the state-
ment of Eugene F. Stewart in Behalf of the parts division of EIA in support
of quotas on imports of electronic articles made to your committee on June 25,
1968, during the hearings on H.R. 17551. Please insert this telegram in the record
of these hearings immediately following Mr. Stewart's statement.
JOHN J. GRAHAM,
Gi'oup Vice President, General Dynamics Corp.
SANTA MONIC4, CALIF.
July 12, 196&
Hon. WILBUR D. MILLS,
Chairman, Honse Committee on Ways and Means,
Washington, D.C.
As a member company of the parts division of the Electronic Industries As--
sociation we hereby disassociate, repeat disassociate, ourselves from the state-
ment of Eugene F. Stewart in behalf of the parts division of EIA in support of
quotas on imports of electronic articles made to your committee on June 25,
1968, during the hearings on H.R. 17551. Please insert this telegram in the~
Record of these hearings immediately following Mr. Stewart's statement.
JOHN C. BROOK,
______ Chairman, Lear Siegler, Inc~.
SUNNYVALE, CAliF.,
July 11, 1968.
Hon. WILBUR D. MILLS,
Chairman, Hoase Com'inittee on Ways and Means,
Washington, D.C.:
As a member company of the parts division as well as government products
division of the Electronic Industries Association we hereby disassociate repeat
disassociate ourselves from the statement of Eugene F. Stewart in behalf of the
parts division of EIA in support of quantities on imports of electronic articles
made to the committee on June 25, 1968, during the hearing on H.R. 17551. Please
insert this telegram in the records immediately following Stewarts statement.
D. J. HAUGHTON,
Chairman of the Board, Lockheed Aircraft Corp.
NEW YoRK, N.Y.,
July 10, 1968.
Hon. WILBUR D. MilLs,
Choirman, Committee on Ways and Means,
Washington, D.C.:
As a member company of the parts division of the Electronic Industries
Association we hereby disassociate, repeat disassociate, ourselves from the state
PAGENO="0198"
3634
ment of Eugene F. Stewart in behalf of the parts division of ETA in support of
quotas on imports of electronic articles made to your committee on June 25, 1968
during the hearings on HR 17551. Please insert this telegram in the records of
these hearings immediately following Mr. Stewart's statement.
GEORGE H. FEZELL,
President, Magnavox Consumer Electronics Co.
FRANKLIN PARK, ILL.,
July 12, 1968.
Hon. WILBUR D. MILLS,
Chairman, House Committee on Ways and Means,
Washington, D.C.:
As a member company of the parts division of the Electronic Industries As-
sociation, we hereby disassociate, repeat disassociate, ourselves from the state-
ment of Eugene F. Stewart in behalf of the parts division of ETA in support of
quotas on imports of electronic articles made to your committee on June 25,
1968, during the hearings on H.R. 17551. Please insert this telegram in the record
of these hearings immediately following Mr. Stewart's statement.
ROBERT W. GALvIN,
Motorola, Inc.
WALTHAM, MASS.,
July 12, 1968.
Hon. WILBUR D. MILLS,
Chairman, House Committee on Ways and Means,
Washington, D.C.:
Raytheon Company is a member company of the parts division of the Elec-
tronic Industries Association, we hereby disassociate, repeat disassociate, our-
selves from the statement of Eugene Stewart in behalf of the parts division of
ETA in support of quotas on imports of electronic articles made to your com-
mittee on June 25, 1968, during the hearings on H.R. 17551. Please insert this
telegram in the record of these hearings immediately following Mr. Stewart's
statement.
CHARLES F. ADAMS,
Chairman of the Board, Raytheon Co.
DALLAS, TEX.,
July11, 1968.
Hon. WILBUR D. MILLS,
Chairman, House Committee on Ways and Means,
Washington, D.C.
Texas Tnstruments is already on record as opposing any form of import quotas
or other restrictive import law. As a member company of the parts division of
the electronics industries association we hereby disassociate, repeat disassociate
ourselves from the statement of Eugene F. Stewart in behalf of the world trade
committee of the parts division of ETA in support of quotas on imports of elec-
tronic articles made to your committee on June 25, 1968 during the hearings
on H.R. 17551.
Please insert this telegram in the record of these hearings immediately follow-
ing Mr. Stewart's statement.
J. FRED BUOY.
Group Vice President, Texas Instruments Inc.
The CHAIRMAN. Mr. Tanaka. If you will identify yourself for our
record we will be glad to recognize you, sir.
STATE1VIENT OP H. WILLIAM TANAKA, ATTORNEY, IN BLHALP OP
PAUL H. DAVIDSON, PRESIDENT, INTERNATIONAL IMPORTERS,
INC.
Mr. TANAKA. Mr. Chairman, for the record my name is H. William
Tanaka. I am an attorney for International Importers, Inc. I received
a call late last night that Mr. Davidson regrets that he won't be able
PAGENO="0199"
3635
to appear. However, he asked that I read his short statement for the
record and with your permission I would like to summarize his state-
ment and then have the full statement incorporated in the record.
The CHAIRMAN. Without objection the entire statement will be made
a part of the record and you are recognized to proceed.
Mr. TANAKA. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
"Mr. Chairman, members of the committee, my name is Paul M.
Davidson. I am president of International Importers Inc., and im-
porter and distributor of electronic products and components located
in Chicago. I appreciate the opportunity to present the views of my
company on the important legislation before your committee."~
Inasmuch as the trade issue relating to imports of electronic prod-
ucts has been discussed at length here I will not deal with the trade
policy issue but I would like to direct your attention to what I as an
importer would experience in the event that any quota restrictions
should be imposed on electronic imports.
"Our company was established about 15 years ago in Chicago. We
are a relatively small company specializing in the importation and
sale. of finished electronic products and components."
Some of our products include television receiving tubes, and other
electronic subassemblies. Our total sales amount to about $6 million a
year. Our exports amount to about 5 or 6 percent of that figure.
"1 feel that companies like ours serve an important function for both
the industry and the American consumer. We are an important supple-
mentary source of electronic components for American subassembly
set manufacturers. Imports have been vitally important in times of
short supply and their availability at reasonable prices has helped
many smaller manufacturers to compete with the larger integrated
producers who have in-house capability to manufacture components.
The importance of imported components to American producers of
consumer electronic products is illustrated by their efforts to obtain
reasonable rates of duty for products such as color TV picture tubes
and receiving tubes."
* The American manufacturers and importers and the American con-
sumers have all benefited from the trade in electronics, but the quotas
iiow being considered by the Congress threaten the continuation of
these benefits.
"As you know, import quotas are the most stringent and onerous
i~orm of trade restriction. Unlike tariffs which are simply another ele-
ment in the cost of doing business, quotas completely disrupt the
normal factors of supply and demand, and make it nearly impossible
to conduct business in an orderly manner. The electronic quota bill and
the so-called omnibus quota proposals would place absolute limits on
the volume of imports.
"The advocates of this legislation state that they are only asking for
a reasonable regulation of trade. They say that they are not seeking
a rollback in imports and point to provisions which would permit im-
ports to share in the market growth. While these proposals might seem
*to be reasonable and even liberal when viewed in the abstract, I ask
you gentlemen to step in my shoes and think about their impact on
the businesses which are engaged in the importation and sale of elec-
tronic products. In my view, the practical application of import quotas
to businesses such as ours would totally disrupt normal operations and
ivould jeopardize the existence of many small businessmen.
PAGENO="0200"
3636
"To begin with, I cannot see how one can do business when
supply of his stock in trade is totally uncertain due to arbitrary re-
strictions. Once the annual quotas are filled, all additional imports
would be totally barred from this country until the new quota opens.
"Even if the overall quota is known in advance, no individual im-
porter can be sure that his own shipment will be entered before the
quota is ifiled. If the gates are closed while the shipment is on the
way, the importer must bear warehousing costs until the quota re-
opens. How can we make commitments to our customers and suppliers,
and how can we obtain the necessary financing under such circum-
stances?
"Secondly, absolute limitations on imports imposed by the Ijnited
States must necessarily result in controls on exports by the supplier
nations. In the case of Japan, for example, the variously mandatory
and so-called voluntary restrictions on other products have required
the Japanese Government and industry to divide up the quotas among
manufacturers, exporters, and importers to avoid a chaotic scramble
among competitors for the largest possible share of the quota. Similar
arrangements probably would have to be worked out if U.S. quotas
were imposed on imports of electronic products. This could have a
damaging effect on small business in the United States.
"If the @xperience under other quotas is any guide, the foreign
supplier nations would have to allocate the quotas among manufac-
turers, exporters and importers according to their past historical share
of the market. This would freeze the competitive position of individ-
ual U.S. companies. The large importers would remain large and the
small importers small, and there would be little if any opportunity
for growth. Companies such as ours would have no chance to expand
their business because their relative position in the industry would
be frozen.
"Aside from these serious impediments to the management and
growth of individual businesses, quotas would create an administra-
tive nightmare. To give you one example, it is proposed that the over-
all quota on electronic products and components will be divided among
supplying countries by category of product according to market
shares during a base period. But electronics is a dynamic industry,
and new products are constantly being introduced. The Government
will certainly not want to discourage innovation by freezing the
product mix according to the situation existing in the past. But how
are we to open the market to new products to meet the needs of the
consumer? The Government would have to maintain continuing sur-
veillance over the import quotas to review the categories and sub-
categories of products so as to maintain at least some room for innova-
tion. Furthermore, some administrative means must be provided to
relieve short supply situations. All of this means a proliferation of
bureaucracy and regulation. I believe that even those who are clamor-
ing today for quota `protection' would eventually discover that the
price they would have to pay in terms of Government interference in
normal business activity is simply not worth the benefits they receive.
"In conclusion, I urgently request the members of this committee
to give serious consideration to the practical effect of quotas on the
everyday operation of business. I submit that there is no need for
import quotas in any segment of the electronics industry, and that
PAGENO="0201"
3637
there is no justification for the disruption of normal marketing, the
restriction on competition, and the proliferation of Government inter-
ference which would inevitably result from enactment of the quota
legislation. Thank you."
Mr. Chairman, I would like to point out that in the case of tran-
sistor radios and small screen or micro TV sets these were essentially
innovations which were developed abroad and which moved into the
market in the interstices which existed at the time.
A previous witness testified that in 1947 there were 20 million U.S.
manufactured radios sold in that year. I daresaye that there was not a
single transistorized set sold for the consumer market in 1947. They
were all tube-type sets.
Also, in 1947 Bell Lab came out with the invention known as tran-
sistors which revolutionized the industry, and it was the application of
this transistor technology to consumer goods that resulted in the tran-
sistor radio which, in fact, revitalized the radio market which was
stea.dily going downward from the impact of the introduction of a
black and white TV set so that after the transistor radios were intro-
duced the radio market climbed very sharply.
Likewise with respect to the TV sets here again the imports came
into a market interstice created as a result of the fault on the part of
the U.S. manufacturer to go into the design and development of a
personalized set. Heretofore both radio and television were con-
sidered as a part of household furniture. This concept was revolu-
tionized as a result of the application of transistor technology to
diminish the size of these units, and these are some of the things which
might have been withheld from the American consumer were quotas to
have been in existence at the time.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
(The statement of Paul M. Davidson follows:)
STATEMENT OF PAUL M. DAVIDSON, PRESIDENT, INTERNATIONAL IMPORTERS, INC.
Mr. Chairman, members of the Committee, my name is Paul M. Davidson. I
am President of International Importers Inc., an importer and distributor of
electronic products and components located in Chicago. I appreciate the op-
portunity to present the views of my company on the important legislation before
your Committee.
You have heard opinions from industry leaders on both sides of the question
of quotas for electronics. You have heard statistics on exports, imports, em-
ployment, and the balance of trade. The witnesses have discussed foreign rela-
tions implications, the possibility of retaliation, and its impact on the world
economy. I will not deal with the broad issues of international competition in
electronics. Although I have my own opinions on these issues, I doubt there is
much I could add to what you have already heard.
But by speaking from my own experience I think that I can give you some
idea of the impact which the quota legislation can have on the many small
businessmen like myself who are engaged in the sale and distribution of elec-
tronic products.
Our company was established 15 years ago in Chicago. We are a relatively
small company specializing in the importation and sale of finished electronic
products and components. Sales to American manufacturers constitute a substan-
tial part of our business.
I feel that companies like ours serve an important function for both the
Industry and the American consumer. We are an important supplementary source
of electronic components for American sub-assembly set manufacturers. I know
that these companies have a vital interest in a continued supply of products such
as receiving tubes, semiconductors, and TV picture tubes from abroad. These
Imports have been vitally important in times of short supply, and their avail-
PAGENO="0202"
3638
ability at reasonable prices has helped many smaller manufacturers to compete
with integrated producers. The importance of imported components to American
producers of consumer electronic products is illustrated by their efforts to obtain
reasonable rates of duty for products such as color TV picture tubes and receiving
tubes.
I know that some component manufacturers are claiming that imports threaten
to destroy their business. These complaints are certainly difficult to understand
in view of the published figures on the sales and profits of the major components
producers. Certainly their substantial exports do not indicate their inability to
compete in the world market. As for the claims of loss of employment due to
imports, I was interested to note the press reports on the testimony presented
to your committee last week by the Emergency Committee for American Trade.
I understand that the ECAT presented an analysis of the statements by Trade
Relations Council that employment in the electronic tube industry in 1964 was
down 16.7% from the 1958-60 average. The ECAT analysis shows that auto-
mation, not imports, was by far the biggest factor in this job loss. In fact, importa
were only a 3% factor in job displacement in the electronic tube industry.
Our company imports a number of finished products including TV sets, radios,.
and tape recorders. My best source of information as to the impact of such
imports on the domestic industry comes from the American producers themselves.
They are certainly in the best position to determine their need for protection
against import competition, and their views should definitely be given close
attention. The Consumer Products Division of the Electronic Industries Asso-
ciation has opposed import quotas and other forms of trade restrictions. They
have emphasized the important role which imports play in the consumer market
by providing home entertainment equipment which is priced within the reach
of Americans who would otherwise be unable to buy these products. Further-
more, from my experience in this business, I know that imports, particularly
for Japan, have introduced innovations such as the pocket-sized transistor radio
and the small screen portable TV set which have made an important contribu-
tion toward expanding the entire U.S. market for electronic products.
Thus American manufacturing importers and the American consumer have all
benefited from the trade in electronics. But this trade is now threatened by the
import quota bills pending before your committee. You have been told about
the world-wide repercussions which are bound to come if the largest single
trading nation retreats behind a wall of quota protection. But I would like to
discuss the effect of quotas on the many small businesses in this country which
derive their livelihood from foreign trade.
As you know, import quotas are the most stringent and onerous form of trade
restriction. Unlike tariffs which are simply another element in the cost of do-
ing business, quotas completely disrupt the normal factors of supply and de-
mand, and make it nearly impossible to conduct business in an orderly manner.
The electronic quota bill and the so-called "omnibus" quota proposals would
place absolute limits on the volume of imports.
The advocates of this legislation state that they are only asking for a reason-
able regulation of trade. They say that they are not seeking a rollback in im-
ports, and point to provisions which would permit imports to share in the
market growth. While these proposals might seem to be reasonable and even
liberal when viewed in the abstract, I ask you gentlemen to step in my shoes
and think about their impact on the businesses which are engaged in the impor-
tation and sale of electronic products. In my view, the practical application of
import quotas to businesses such as ours would totally disrupt normal opera-
tions and would jeopardize the existence of many small businessmen.
To begin with, I cannot see how one can do business when supply of his stock
in trade is totally uncertain due to arbitrary restrictions. Once the annual
quotas are filled, all additional imports would be totally barred from this country
until the new quota opens. Even if the over-all quota is known in advance, no
individual importer can be sure that his own shipment will be entered before
the quota is filled. If the gates are closed while the shipment is on the way, the
importer must bear warehousing costs until the quota reopens. How can we
make commitments to our customers and suppliers, and how can we obtain
the necessary financing under such circumstances?
Secondly, absolute limitations on imports imposed by the United States must
necessarily result in controls on exports by the supplier nations. In the case of
Japan for example, the various mandatory and so-called "voluntary" restrictions
on other products have required the Japanese Government and industry to divide
PAGENO="0203"
3639
up the quotas among manufacturers, exporter, and importers to avoid a chaotic
scramble among competitors for the largest possible share of the quota. Similar
arrangements probably would have to be worked out if U.S. quotas were imposed
on imports of electronic products. This could have a damaging effect on small
business in the United States.
If the experience under other quotas is any guide, the foreign supplier nations
would have to allocate the quotas among manufacturers, exporters and importers
according to their past historical share of the market. This would freeze the
competitive position of individual U.S. companies. The large importers would
remain large and the small importers small, and there would be little if any
opportunity for growth. Companies such as ours would have no chance to expand
their business because their relative position in the industry would be frozen.
To say the least, such a situation is hardly compatible with our traditional
philosophy of free competition.
Aside from these serious impediments to the management and growth of indi-
vidual businesses, quotas would create an administrative nightmare. To give you
one example, it is proposed that the over-all quota on electronic products and
components will be divided among supplying countries by category of product ac-
cording to market shares during a base period. But electronics is a dynamic
industry, and new products are constantly being introduced. The government will
certainly not want to discourage innovation by freezing the product mix accord-
ing to the situation existing in the past. But how are we to open the market to
new products to meet the needs of the consumer? The government would have to
maintain continuing surveillance over the import quotas to revise the categories
and sub-categories of products so as to maintain at least some room for innova-
tion. Furthermore, some administrative means must be provided to relieve short
supply situations. All of this means a proliferation of bureaucracy and regula-
tion. I believe that even those who are clamoring today for quota "protection"
would eventually discover that the price they would have to pay in terms Of gov-
ernment interference in normal business activity is simply not worth the benefits
they receive.
In conclusion, I urgently request the members of this Committee to give serious
consideration to the practical effect of quotas on the every day operation of
business. I submit that there is no need for import quotas in any segment of the
electronics industry, and that there is no justification for the disruption of normal
marketing, the restriction on competition, and the proliferation of government
interference which would inevitably result from enactment of the quota legisla-
tion. Thank you.
The CHAIRMAN. We thank you for appearing for Mr. Davidson and
presenting his statement to us. We appreciate it.
Any questions?
If not, the committee will recess until 2 o'clock this afternoon. Mr.
Adams will be the first witness.
(Whereupon, at 12:25 p.m., the committee recessed to reconvene at
2 p.m., the same day.)
AFTER RECESS
(The committee reconvened at 2 p.m., Hon. Al IJilman, presiding.)
Mr. ULLMAN. The committee will be in order.
Our next witness is Mr. Adams. I would like to recognize Mr. Burke.
Mr. Biimwn. Mr. Chairman, it gives me a great deal of pleasure to
present to the committee Mr. Charles F. Adams whose company has
many divisions in my State. Mr. Adams with a proud family history
has made a great contribution not only in an industrial way but his
firm has recognized the great problems about the unemployed and the
unemployable. We in Massachusetts are proud of his accomplishments.
Mr. TJLLMAN. Mr. Adams, you come highly recommended by our
distinguished member from Massachusetts. We are very happy to have
you before the committee. With the understanding your testimony
will appear in full in the record you may proceed as you see fit.
PAGENO="0204"
3640
STATEMENT OP CHARLES P. ADAMS, CHAIRMAN OP THE BOARD,
RAYTIrEON CO.
Mr. ADAMS. Thank you, sir. Mr. Chairman and members of the
committee, my name is Charles F. Adams. I am chairman of the board
of Raytheon Co.
We are a diversified, international, science-based company, employ-
ing more than 50,000 persons. Our headquarters is in Lexington, Mass.
We operate plants, laboratories and other facilities in that State and
also in 12 others-New Hampshire, Indiana, Rhode Island, Okla-
homa, Iowa, Pennsylvania, Connecticut, New Jersey, Tennessee, New
Mexico, Virginia, and California.
We have subsidiaries and affiliates in many countries abroad includ-
ing England, Italy, Switzerland, Holland, Canada, West Germany,
India, and Japan.
Our sales volume for 1967 was $1.1 billion, reasonably well balanced
between government and commercial marketing activity. At the core
of this business volume is our electronics technology, providing for the
development, engineering, and manufacturing of components, equip-
ments, and systems.
IMPOSITION OF QUOTAS ON NAMED COMMODITIES
I wish to address myself to only one aspect of this hearing on the
general subject of trade balance between the United States and foreign
nations. I am concerned specifically with proposals relative to the
imposition of quotas, either on an across-the-board basis or on named
items or commodities.
Where such proposals call for import quotas to be imposed on elec-
tronic products and components, as is proposed, for example, in the
electronic import bill 5. 2539, I wish to register our company's belief
that the Congress should not pass such legislation. This belief, I might
add, is shaped by many representatives of top management in the
electronics mdustry.
The United States is an exporting nation, not an importing nation.
This is made clear in figures issued by the U.S. Department of Com-
merce, showing that export sales in 1967 were more than $4 billion
higher than imports-$31 billion in exports, $26.7 billion in imports.
The introduction of import quotas in the United States on partic-
ular products such as electronic commodities and against particular
countries abroad, can only lead to retaliatory measures which, in the
final analysis, will be more detrimental than helpful to our industry's
overall business.
BALANCE-OF-PAYMENTS DEFICITS
The import protectionists who seek to establish such quotas are
claiming that their action will protect American industry from for-
eign competition and will so help to reduce the balance-of-payments
deficit.
That claim is certainly open to argument. The current deficit in
the balance of payments did not result from an export-import relation-
ship but was caused by other factors, such as the cost of military
operations in Vietnam, a decrease in business activity in foreign coun-
PAGENO="0205"
3641
tries, lending by United States banks to foreign outlets, and-to some
degree-the currency devaluation abroad.
It is scarcely logical, therefore, to seek a restriction of trade m the
field of electronics, where the United States today enjoys a favorable
balance of trade and where the steady trend is toward improvmg the
balance of payments.
DOMESTIC MARKET IN ELECTRONICS
The electronics business in the United States has successfully met;
foreign competition in many products during past years, and is quite
capable of maintaining and even increasing its competitive edge with-
out import restrictions. With our vast resources in research and devel-
opment, we in this country hold a strong technological superiority'
over our foreign competitors. With such leadership, we neither need
nor seek the protection of a quota law. Such a law would harm us
rather than help us.
Today's electronic imports amount to less than 5 percent of the
domestic market. They serve an advantageous purpose by helping to
counter inflationary pressures in their field. In many instances, they
provide American industry and consumers with an opportunity to
take advantage of low prices.
The electronics industry in this country is young, dynamic, healthy,
and progressive. Factory sales of electronic products amount to sOme
$23 billion annually, only a small percentage of which can be attri-
buted to imports.
The domestic industry is not experiencing today, nor does it expect
to experience tomorrow, any economic difficulties traceable to foreign
competition.
HARMFUL EFFECTS OP RESTRICTIONS
In short, there would be no justification for imposing a quota re-
striction on this particular field of imports. Such an imposition, we
believe would produce an inflationary impact by decreasing the forces
of competition and would quickly produce a counteraction abroad
which would have a harmful effect upon our trade relations with the~
rest of the world.
We believe firmly that free trade between nations is desirable andl
necessary, and that the United States cannot afford to take a position
of economic isolation. Our economy cannot flourish without our mar-
kets abroad; but to sell our goods and services among foreign nations,
we must be willing to buy there on a mutually equitable basis. We must.
remain competitive worldwide, or we won't be competitive at all.
For these reasons, we respectively request that the 90th Congress:
reject any proposal which would impose import quotas on any elec-
tronic product or component.
Mr. ULLMAN. Does that complete your testimony, Mr. Adams?
Mr. ADAMS. Yes, sir.
Mr. ULLMAN. Are there any questions? Mr. Burke.
Mr. Buiuu~. Mr. Adams, do you believe that our export trade could
be increased by many of our American industries if they would take a
real good, hard look at the foreign markets that are open to their
products?
PAGENO="0206"
3642
Mr. ADAMS. I think that an increasingly hard look has been taken in
recent years but I do feel that this could be carried further. The
United States has an advantage in the more complex and more sophis-
ticated aspects of electronics and of the systems kinds of approach
and I think in fields like the educational system and things of this
kind, even in the developing nations, there are all kinds of opportuni-
ties that lie ahead for us and I do feel that we can expand our ac-
tivities by a greater effort.
Mr. BURKE. Do you agree with me that many times you visit some
large cities in the foreign countries, and you are rather surprised not
-to find many of our well-known products being sold in some of the
niarkets, popular items over here that apparently have never reached
the foreign markets?
Mr. ADAMS. I am not sure that I quite heard that, sir.
Mr. BURKE. I say are you surprised when you visit a foreign coun-
try and you find many of the products that are sold in this country
~and are looked upon as everyday articles that are in great demand-
to find a lack of these articles in these foreign markets.
Mr. ADAMS. I think this is true. I think you have to look very
carefully at the disposable income in some of these foreign coun-
tries and see how far up the scale they can go.
We regard color television here as a product wherein a large pro-
portion of our homes in this country have television; but if you try
to fit color television into the disposable income even in some of the
more prosperous Western European countries, they are not ready
for it yet.
It won't fit their budget situation very well; so that I think there
are things of this kind that we consider commonplace here that
you don't see over there, but many of the things that we see in this
country, my observation has been, we see in a somewhat cruder,
simpler, less expensive form there.
Many of the products that are tailored to our market are a little
too rich for some of the markets abroad.
Mr. BURKE. Thank you.
Mr. TILLMAN. Mr. Schneebeli.
Mr. SCHNEEBELI. Mr. Adams, what suggested approach would you
give to this Congress relative to eliminating some of these artificial
barriers or indirect restrictions that we meet in some of the foreign
countries? We heard testimony this morning about government re-
strictions in regard to the entry of power equipment. We heard dis-
cussion about residual quotas. We heard discussion about some of these
artificial barriers which some of our trading partners have created.
What suggested approach would you give to this committee to meet
this competition?
Mr. ADAMS. Well, I think this is a question on which I haven't the
familiarity that somebody would have who had been present at the
Kennedy round negotiations and at various GATT meetings and so
on; but I have the quite strong feeling that if we start imposing quotas
we begin to get sort of an across-the-board escalation of this kind of
thing.
Mr. SOHNEEBELI. I will agree with you there, but disregarding quotas
what other approaches have we? If we meet the same competition or
if we have the same rules for international trade that they have, is this
being unfair?
PAGENO="0207"
3643
Mr. ADAMS. I don't think it is unfair, but in a sense we are a very
rich nation in terms of the amount of exports we have versus imports.
I think most of the foreign countries looking just at our export-im-
port situation regard us with great envy, and their economies are weak-
er, their trade balances are more difficult, and I think if we start asking
for too much in the overall balance between nations that we may come
off worse.
Now, I think we have to continue to try to trade this out but I think
we always have to, in viewing this, 190k at the economic posture of
some, of these foreign countries, the problems that beset them, and
therefore proceed with some patience.
For example, if we attempt to set import quotas against the TJnited
Kingdom, which is in severe economic difficulties-
Mr. SCHNEEBELI. Let's take Japan.
Mr. ArAM5. If you take Japan you are dealing with a very-
Mr. SOHNEEBELI. Aggressive.
Mr. ADAMS (continuing). Strong nation both in technology and pro-
ductivity, its work force and all the rest of it, and I would hope that as
relationships between Japan and the United States are developed that
they will be more open. They have enormous markets in the Far East
open to them.
The U.S. market is very important to them of course, but they have
other markets and other opportunities and I would hope that their
situation would open up gradually to allow us to import more to
Japan.
Mr. SOHNEEBELI. Our conversations with them up to this point have
been rather negative and when we asked them when they were going
to eliminate some of these restrictions they told me personally possibly
they might think about it in the next 5 years.
Are we going to wait 5 years to be outtraded and do you think it is
unfair for us to raise the same artificial barriers as they have against
us during this 5-year interval?
Mr. ADAMS. In the case of Japan I tend to agree with you to a greater
extent. I am a firm advocator of the greatest amount of free trade pos-
sible. I believe everybody gains by this and I think there are lots of
exarnples to point it up, but in the case of Japan they have an extra-
ordinarily effective economy in many areas outside of electronics and
we don't have to have the same reservations that we may with respect
to the English, or the French, or others who are having difficulty.
Mr. SCHNEEBELI. Mr. Adams, some of the members of this committee
believe that in being tolerant and liberal and cooperative with some of
our trading partners we are being taken over and we want to know
what we can do to equalize this situation.
Mr. ADAMS. I am not really familiar enough with the give and take
on the diplomatic battlefront to be able to make specific suggestions
that I would like to be able to.
In my own company we have had considerable experience with
selling highly sophisticated pieces of equipment where the technology
of this country was superior to that available in the other country
and it was on that basis that we were able to make sales.
These things were, if not in military areas, in areas such as airline
operations, which are offshoots of the government in some of these
countries, where they were open to accepting American equipment.
PAGENO="0208"
3644
This has been true in Japan and in those circumstances we have had
no difficulty, but they certainly do regulate what we can do there with
great care and I think some possible threat in the case of Japan more
than in any other place, not threat exactly, but some sort of a trading
posture, might be useful.
Mr. SOHNEEBELI. I am glad you agree with our dilemma.
Mr. ADAMS. I am sure there is a dilemma.
Mr. SOHNEEBELI. Thank you.
Mr. BtTRKE (presiding). Are there any further questions?
Thank you very much, Mr. Adams. Your testimony has been very
helpful.
Mr. BURKE. Our next witness is Mr. Richard Hodgson.
Mr. FULTON (presiding). Mr. Hodgson, the committee is very glad
to have you today and for the benefit of the record will you please
identify yourself?
STATEMENT OF RICHARD HODGSON, VICE CHAIRMAN, BOARD OF
DIRECTORS, FAIRCflILD CAMERA & INSTRUMENT CORP.
Mr. }IODGSON. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I am Richard Hodgson,
vice chairman of the board of directors of the Fairchild Camera &
Instrument Corp. I appreciate the opportunity to be able to come and
talk before this committee today because we feel very strongly on this
subject.
Fairchild is primarily a manufacturer of electronic products and it
not only makes various types of electronic components but also pro-
duces specialized instruments such as automatic test systems and
digital voltmeters and graphic equipment such as electronic photo
composition devices and color scanners, all of which we do a fine export
business with.
In my prepared statement which I will submit for the record I have
dealt with the economic and political problems posed not only by
import quotas and import ceilings but by import surcharges and
rebates and by direct investment controls.
The fact that this committee has acted favorably on the 10-percent
tax surcharge and budget reductions I think has been a major step
forward in meeting some of the basic problems which this hearing,
as I understand, is being aimed toward. Because of the limited time
I have to talk about some things we are basically interested in in Fair-
child I would just like to offer my views on the effects which import
quotas and ceilings would have on an American industry in general
and particularly on the electronics industry.
It is the judgment of Fairchild Camera & Instrument Corp. that
these various import-restricting proposals run strongly counter to our
best interests as the world's foremost trading Nation. Their thrust is
inconsistent with the basic principle that expanded trade with a con-
comitant increase in U.S. exports is not only a fundamental premise
on which our international economic position must rest but an essen-
tial foundation for the political and economic stability of our various
trading partners.
You have already heard a great deal about the electronics industry,
its makeup and size, so I will not take up your time with a detailed
description of it. I would like to add only a few comments in addition
to those you have already received.
PAGENO="0209"
3645
The electronics industry is certainly one of this country's most
dynamic and growing industries. Between 1956 and 1967, electronic
sales increased by more than $15 billion. Imports do not have any
significant share of the U.S. electronics market. In 1963, imports com-
prised 2 percent of our market by value-in 1967, they amounted to
3.5 percent of the market. During these same years, electronic exports
have been growing. In a period of 4 years, they increased by almost
$900 million. The result has been an increasingly favorable balance
of trade, which amounted to $541 million in 1963 and climbed to $945
million in 1967.
The primary reason for this growth in electronics exports has been
that American manufacturers enjoy a substantial measure of tech-
nological superiority over foreign competitors. Virtually all of the re-
cent creative breakthroughs in electronics have been made by domestic
firms.
If any of you happened to read any of the trade journals in the
electronics industry you will recall the fact that every week there
probably are at least 150 new products introduced on the market, not
only the domestic market but the world market, today because of the
innovation and technological superiority of the American electronics
industry.
We hear something about the problems of the transistor radio and
the impact it has had on our own domestic economy. I think this is
a passing situation and the technological development in integrated
circuits today is going to permit the American industry to produce a
solid state integrated circuit pocket-size radio without this labor-
intensive component which has been talked about and that will dilute
materially the problems that are facing some of the industry and some
of the companies today in this business.
The growth of Fairchild is typical of the expansion of this
country's electronics industry. Through extensive research and the
application of new technological developments, Fairchild has more
than doubled its size during the last 5 years. In 1962, this company
had some $101 million worth of sales and employed 7,369 persons in
the United States. By 1965, sales were over $181 million; and by 1967,
they had grown to over $228 million. Domestic employment had in-
creased to 11,552 in 1965 and to 14,678 by the end of 1967.
Moreover, this same rapid domestic growth has marked Fairchild's
activities in the production of semiconductors and integrated circuits.
This fact should be of great interest to this committee for it is in the
semiconductor field that Fairchild has also opened several assembly
plants abroad. But these foreign plants have not meant fewer sales
for or domestic operations or fewer jobs in the United States. Instead,
the result of increased foreign assembly operations has been new
foreign sales and the opening of untapped markets in the United
States for Fairchild's goods. Inevitably, this has meant an upsurge in
sales and the creation of new employment opportunities in this coun-
try. Thus in 1962, employment semiconductor plants in the United
States had less than $50 million in sales and employed some 2,900
workers. By the end of 1967, semiconductor sales had increased by
over 200 percent and employment was up to 8,883 workers.
At the same time, Fairchild's operations abroad were opening up
new foreign markets and putting our sales force into contact with a
95-159-68-pt. 8-14
PAGENO="0210"
3646
broader range of customers for products that were made in this coun-
try. As a consequence, the company's foreign sales from its domestic
plants soared and this in turn was reflected in an increasingly favor-
able balance of trade. In 1964, Fairchild's Semiconductor Division ex-
ported $1.4 million worth of goods and had a favorabletrade balance
of $550,000. By 1967, this division was exporting almost $28 million
worth of goods and its favorable trade balance had risen to over $11
million. In fact, during that year, the exports of all the divisions of
Fairchild had risen to $39 million and its favorable balance of trade
was over $21 million.
You might ask the question why has Fairchild been able to grow
this rapidly. This point has been touched upon in some of the other
testimony. It has been because of the superior position which the semi-
conductor industry and other component manufacturers have had in
technology. We have been able to open foreign plants while doubling
employment at home. Why has it increased its favorable balance of
trade by over $14 million in 3 years?
In addition to having superior technology to the foreign competitor
we have been a company which has integrated its domestic and for-
eign questions. This is a lesson that I think a lot of companies that
worry about the qoutas should learn.
Its skilled jobs we have kept in this country; its most simple and
tedious production functions are performed abroad. It freely exports
and imports a variety of electronic parts and components. The end
result of this integrated manufacturing process is a lower priced prod-
uct which can compete more effectively both at home and abroad. New
markets are opened and sales increase. More employment opportuni-
ties are created both here and abroad, and, because the goods being
exported are more sophisticated and expensive than those being im-
ported, the favorable balance of trade constantly increases
This process which I have just described is no pipedream. It is the
way in which the manufacturing operations of Fairchild and many
other American companies operate. Fairchild continues to grow be-
cause its production processes and markets are both international. It
takes pride in its domestic and foreign plants and in the opportunity to
import and export goods freely precisely because these various inter-
national operations are serving this Nation's best interests. Not only
can Fairchild state that it is helping to increase the U.S. favorable
balance of trade and thereby decrease this country's unfavorable bal-
ance of payments, but it is also opening a growing number of export-
import related jobs. We estimate that from 1964 to 1967, the increased
international sales of just our semiconductor division created over
2,100 new jobs at that division's plants in the United States alone.
This represents approximately 25 percent of the employment in these
plants.
With this background in mind, it is now possible to examine the
problems which would arise for the electronics industry if quotas
or import ceilings were to be adopted by this Congress. In short, I
would like to put much of the general discussion about import quotas
and ceilings which you have heard over the past few weeks into the
context of the one industry with which I am famihar-electronics.
First, quotas as well as import ceilings are both inflationary and
discriminatory. They will normally cause sharp decreases in supply
PAGENO="0211"
3647
and concurrent increases in prices-and thus impose hidden taxes on
consumers while subsidizing favored domestic industries. In the elec-
tronics field, quotas would raise the price of various electronic prod-
ucts, thereby squeezing low-income purchasers out of the market. In
the case of Fairchild, this process would come about in two stages.
First, quotas on semiconductors or integrated circuits would drive
up our price to end-use producers. The resulting increase in the price
of such products as radio and TV sets would ultimately reduce end-
use sales and then the sales of Fairchild to these consumer goods
producers.
Second, countries whose products are subject to our quotas will
normally retaliate by raising their own trade barriers against goods
from the quota-imposing nations. This result would be particularly
true if quotas should be established for electronic products. Foreign
countries will never understand why this country should impose quotas
for an American industry which is healthy, growing, and maintaining
a favorable balance of trade~ Tinder those circumstances, if this Nation
should limit the import of variOus electronic commodities, our trading
partners will be exceedingly tempted to limit our export of other
electronic commodities.
It is my impression that in the last Kennedy round one of the
reasons why people have been concerned about the fact that the elec-
tronics industry in this country was not well treated was the fact that
in the negotiations, in the give-and-take which went on at those meet-
ings of the industries which were involved, the electronics industry
in this country perhaps was the strongest and needed less protection
and aid was given to some of the less, you might say, technologically
prominent industries in this country.
Third, quotas would also produce great administrative difficulties
and resist moderation or removal once enacted. In the electronics field,
technology is changing so rapidly that it would be an administrative
nightmare in my opinion, to determine which products should be sub-
ject to quotas or ceilings and which should not.
Finally, and most importantly, import quotas are simply not needed
for the electronics industry. On the whole, our industry is prosperous
and capable of meeting the challenge of foreign competition both at
home and abroad. In fact, I think that a majority of the electronics
industry realize this fact. At recent meetings of the Electronic In-
dustries Association, some of whom you have heard from today, four
divisions of that association-Consumer Products, Government Prod-
ucts, Semiconductors and Tube-have gone on record as being em-
phatically opposed to import quotas; while, to the best of my knowl-
edge, only one division-Parts-has gone on record as favoring them.
Mr. Chairman, it is the judgment of the Fairchild Camera & Instru-
ment Corp. that this Nation's current balance-of-trade and balance-
of-payments problems are solvable. But it is also the judgment of my
corporation that these problems must be treated within a framework
of multinational cooperation and through an international effort to
reach agreements and common goals. For the United States will only
exacerbate its difficulties if it should now embark upon a unilateral,
trade-restricting program in which national boundaries are trans-
formed into national barriers and the private enterprise quest for new
markets is replaced by governmental regulation of the movement of
goods and capital.
PAGENO="0212"
C)
0
Fairchild urges that the committee reject the various proposals in-
volving quotas that are before you today.
(Mr. Hodgson's prepared statement follows:)
STATEMENT OF RICHARD HODGSON, VICE CHAIRMAN, BOARD OF DIRECTORS,
FAIRCHILD CAMERA & INSTRUMENT CORP.
Mr. Chairman and members of the committee, I am Richard Hodgson, Vice-
Chairman of the Board of Directors of the Fairchild Camera and Instrument
Corporation.
During the past three and one-half `decades, this Nation has followed the prin-
ciple that expanding international trade means more economic prosperity both
for the United States and for the rest of the free world. We have been com-
mitted to the concept that the breaking down of national barriers to the free
movement of goods and capital is one of the keys to a more inter-related and
peaceful world.
Now we appear to be in danger of losing sight of these basic guidelines. The
emphasis of too many people-both inside and outside of the Federal govern-
ment-is to turn away from increased world trade and capital movement and to
support instead the idea of an America whose industries are sheltered from
foreign competition and whose private investments abroad are carefully regu-
lated.
Evidence of this trend is all too easy to find. The Kennedy Round of Trade
Negotiations had barely been completed when literally hundreds of import quota
bills were introduced in Congress. Since then, various proposals have been made
that the United States unilaterally adopt various surcharges, or surcharges and
rebates, to' compensate for the existence of foreign non-tariff barriers or, even
more drastically, that this country impose a system of import ceilings for any
products or articles which have penetrated our market beyond a specified level.
These proposals have been coincident with the adoption of regulations by the
Executive branch to impose direct controls on foreign investment.
It is the judgment of the Fairchild Camera and Instrument Corporation that
these various proposed and existing measures run strongly counter to our best
interests as the world's foremost trading Nation. Their thrust is inconsistent
with the basic principle that expanded trade, with a concomitant increase in
U.S. exports, is not only a fundamental premise on which our international eco-
nomic position must rest but an essential foundation for the political and eco-
nomic stability of our various trading partners.
To illustrate the potentially deleterious effects of these trade restricting pro-
grams, I would like to turn briefly to an examination of the electronics industry
in general and to the Fairchild Camera and Instrument Corporation in particular.
I would then like to deal with the problems which would be caused by this
country's utilization of import quotas as well as other trade and capital restrict-
ing measures. Finally, I would like to offer a few suggestions as to the steps
which this Nation might take in order to improve its balance of trade and thereby
strengthen its balance of payments position.
I. THE ELECTRONICS INDUSTRY AND THE FAIRCHILD CAMERA & INSTRUMENT CORP.
Electronics is one of this country's most dynamic and growing industries.
In 1956, factory sales of all electronic products amounted to $6.7 billion. Ten
years later, sales had trebled to $20.2 billion. And this rising sales curve shows
no signs of slackening, since the preliminary figures for 1967 reveal an increase
to some $22.1 billion.
Imports do not have any significant share of the U.S. electronics market. In
1963, they comprised 2 percent of the market by value-in 1967, they amounted
to 3.5 percent of it. During these same years, exports of U.S. electronic products
have been growing rapidly `and at a faster pace than overall U.S. exports. In
1963, electronic exports amounted to $846,000,000 ; by 1967 they had soared to
over $1.7 billion. The result has been an increasingly favorable balance of trade
in electronic products which more than `doubled between 1961 and 1967.
The primary reason for this growth in electronic exports has been that Amer-
ican manufacturers enjoy a substantial measure of technological superiority
over foreign competitors. Virtually all of the recent creative breakthroughs in
electronics have `been made by doni~estic firms. In all markets-whether in the
United States or in foreign countries-American firms dominate the produc-
tion and sale of sophisticated electronic products.
PAGENO="0213"
3649
To a large extent, the chief beneficiary of this growth in domestic production
and in international trade has been the American public. Employment in the
electronics industry has grown from some 650,000 in 1958 to 1,163,000 in 1967. At
the same time, consumer prices for electronic products have reflected the bene-
fits of heavy and unrestrained competition and a willingness on the part of do-
mestic manufacturers to leave the production of certain low-cost and unsophis-
ticated electronic commodities to foreign manufacturers-a choice which has
resulted in every American being able to enjoy the fruits of technological prog-
ress in electronics. Thus, the Bureau of Labor `Statistics Consumer `Price Index~
for December 1967 shows all consumer items to be at 118.3 (1957-~59 *base of
100). Yet for electronic consumer products, `the same index shows that the con-
`surner price is some 5 to 20 points below the base period figure.
The growth of the Fairchild Camera and Instrument Corporation is typical
of the expansion of this country's electronics industry. Fairchild is primarily an
electronics company; it not only makes various types of electronic components
but also produces specialized instruments such as automatic test systems and
digital voltmeters and graphic equipment such as electronic photo composition
devices and color scanners. Through extensive research and the application of
new technological developments, Fairchild has more than doubled its size during
the last five years. In 1962, this company had some $101 million worth of sales
and employed 7,369 persons in the United States. By 1965, sales were over $181
million and by 1967, they had grown to over $228 million. Domestic employment
had increased to 11,552 in 1965 and to 14,678 by the end of 1967.
Moreover, this same rapid domestic growth has marked Fairchild's imaginative
activities in the production of semiconductors and integrated circuits. This fact
should be of great interest to this Committee for it is in the semiconductor field
that Fairchild has also opened several assembly plants abroad. But these
foreign plants have not meant fewer sales for our domestic operations or
fewer jobs in the United States. On the contrary, the result of increased
foreign assembly operations has been new foreign *sales and the opening of
untapped `markets in the United States for Fairchild's goods. Inevitably, this
has meant an upsurge in sales and the creation of new employment opportunities
in this country. Thus in 1062, our semiconductor plants in the United States
had less than $50 million in sales and employed some 2,900 workers. In that
same year. Fairchild opened its first foreign assembly plant. By 1965, domestic
sales had more than doubled and employment was up to 6,141 workers. By the
end of 1967, semiconductor sales had more than trebled from 1962 and employ-
ment was up to 8,883 workers-an increase in our labor force of over 200
percent from 1962.
At the same time, Fairchild's operations abroad were opening up new foreign
markets and putting our sales force into contact with `a broader range of
customers. As a consequence, the company's foreign sales from its domestic
plants soared and this in turn was reflected in an increasingly favorable balance
of trade. In 1964, Fairchild's `Semiconductor Division exported $1.4 million
worth of goods and had a favorable trade balance of $550,000. By 1967, this
Division was exporting almost $28 million worth of goods and its favorable
trade balance had risen to over $11 million. In fact, during that year, the exports
of all the Divisions of Fairchild h'ad risen to $39 million-an increase of over
300 percent from 1964-and its favorable balance of trade was over $21 million.
Why has Fairchild been able to grow `this rapidly? Why has it been able to
open foreign plants while still doubling its employment at home? Why has It
increased its favorable balance of `trade `by over $14 million in `a period of
three years? The answer is simple. Fairchild is a company which integrates its
domestic and foreign operations. Its skilled jobs are kept in this country; its
most simple and tedious production functions are performed a'broad. It freely
exports an'd imports a variety `of electronic parts and components. The end
result of this in'tegrated manufacturing process is a lower priced product which
can compete more effectively both at home and abroad. New markets are opened
and sales increase. More employment opportunities are created `both `here and
abroad, and because the goods being exported are more sophisticated and
expensive than those being imported, the favorable balance of trade con-
stantly increases.
This process which I have just described is no pipe dream. It is the way in
which the manufacturing operations of Fairchild and many other American
companies operate. Fairchild continues to grow because its production processes
an'd markets are both international. It takes pride in its domestic and foreign
PAGENO="0214"
3650
plants and in the opportunity to import and export goods freely precisely be-
cause these various international operations are serving this Nation's best iiiter-
ests. Not only can Fairchild state that it is helping to increase the United
States' favorable balance of trade and thereby decrease this country's unfavor-
able `balance of payments, but it is also opening a growing number of export-
import related jobs. We estimate that from. 1964 to 1967, the increased interna-
tional sales of just our Semiconductor Division created over 2,100 new jobs at
that Division's plants in the United States.
With this background in mind, it is now possible to examine the problems
which might arise for a variety of American industries, and for the electronics
industry in particular, if quotas or various other types of import restrictions
were to be ad'opted by this Congress and if the present controls on direct in-
vestment were to be continue'd indefinitely.
II. THE EFFECT OF UNILATERALLY-IMPOSED TRADE AND CAPITAL-RESTRICTING
MEASURES
A. Import Quotas
In general, the imposition of import quotas for a wide variety of industrial
products would have the following disadvantageous features for this country:
First, quotas are both inflationary and discriminatory. They will normally
cause sharp decreases in supply and concurrent increases in prices, and thus
impose hidden taxes on consumers while subsidizng favored domestic industries.
Second, quotas will not, in the long run, aid the industries for whose `benefit
they are adopted. They will make technologically innovative companies lazy and
will provide little incentive for backward companies to modernize rapidly.
Third, quotas produce great administrative difficulties and resist moderation
or removal `once enacted.
Fourth, countries whose products are subject to new quotas will normally
retaliate by raising their own trade barriers against goods from the quota-
imposing nation. Since such retaliation could not be expected to be at a carefully
measured level of reciprocity, a spiraling trade-restricting process would begin
in which no country could emerge as the winner and the United States, with
so much at stake, would be the biggest loser.
Fifth, adopting import quotas places this country in the position of threatening
the results of the Kennedy Round of tariff reductions. As the Canadian-American
Committee has recently noted, such a step would be taken as' a "signal" of a `re-
treat from leadership in world affairs into economic nationalism." T'he result
would be an impairment of this country's bargaining position in its delicate nego-
tiations to obtain international cooperation in dealing with its balance of pay-
ment problem.
All of these disadvantageous features are highlighted if we turn to the pro-
posals which have been made in Congress to place quotas on electronic products.
First, quotas would raise the price of various consumer electronic products
thereby squeezing low-income purchasers out of the market. In the case of Fair-
child, this process would come about in two stages. Quotas on semiconductors or
integrated circuits would drive up our price to end use producers. The resultimig
increase in the prices of such products as radio and TV sets would ultimately
reduce end use sales and then the sales of Fairchild to these consumer goods
producers.
Second, the electronics industry-like many other industries for which im-
port quotas have been proposed-is prosperous and capable of meeting the chal-
lenge of foreign competition both at home and abroad. In general, the industry
does not need protection since it is not being injured by imports which in fact
hold a relatively insignificant share of the domestic market. Those companies
which feel threatened by imports must undergo a process of improving their
technology. Import quotas will not induce them to undertake this necessary mod-
ernization process but will merely reward their past failures.
Third, the changing technology of electronics leads to a constantly changing
range of products. Under such circumstances, the administrative difficulties in
determining specific quotas for individual items would be almost overwhelming.
Fourth and fifth, import quotas for electronic pro'ducts could only have a
damaging effect on our trade relations with the rest of the world-and inevitably
on our balance of payments problem. For if the rest of the trading nations of
the world should bear witness to this Congress' act of imposing quotas on elec-
tronic products-and on other products similarly situated-they will be driven to
retaliatory action. There will be no way of jus'tifying protectionist policies to
PAGENO="0215"
3651
these countries when they can see that the industry affected is healthy, growing,
and maintaining a favorable balance of trade, and when they know that a sub-
stantial segment of that industry does not favor such quotas.
In fact, I think it is fair to say that a majority of the electronics industry is
opposed to import quotas. At recent meetings of the Electronic Industries Associa-
tion, four Divisions of that Association-Consumer Products, Govermuent Prod-
ucts, Semiconductors, and Tube-have gone on record as being emphatically
opposed to import quotas, while, to the~ best of my knowledge, only one Di-
vision-Parts--has gone on record as favoring them.
B. Import ceilings
It has also been suggested that in place of import quotas, this Nation should
adopt a more flexible system of import ceilings with automatic trigger points
for certain articles or products. This type of measure is subject to the same
criticisms as are import quotas. Not only would it lead to a freezing of current
patterns of trade-which is not in this country's best interests-but it would
inevitably lead to enormous inequities. For example, let us turn to the electronics
industry again. While this country's electronics firms maintain a large and
increasingly favorable balance of trade, there are some electronic articles which
are largely imported. Are we therefore to set ceilings for transistors or certain
types of capacitors because imports have a substantial share of the domestic
market? Are we to lose sight completely of overriding trade balances and foreign
policy considerations in order to protect certain narrowly specified commodities?
If we are, then I think this country should be prepared to see a worldwide reac-
tion against the free movement of its favorite exports-of which electronic
products is a prime example. For once this Nation begins to pick and choose
those goods which it will protect from competition, then all nations will be
entitled to decide that such a narrow and restrictive policy is justified. And in
this reciprocal destruction of the open channels of trade, the United States, as
both the world's leading trading Nation and the repository of the most advanced
technology, must inevitably wind up the greatest loser.
U. Other unilateral restrictions on trade with our allies
In order to improve our balance of trade, other proposals have been put for-
ward to impose high border taxes on foreign goods or to impose such surtaxes.
with equivalent rebates on our exports. The most disturbing facet of those
various proposals is that they imply unilateral action on the part of the United
States.
For this country to take any individual action outside of the GAPT would be
a mistake. The effect would be to re-establish a precedent of unilateral action-
and once this is done, the abilities of this Nation to oppose similar unilateral
action by its trading partners would be significantly reduced. In the long run,
the cause of multilateral decision-making to reduce trade barriers would have
suffered a severe setback.
For industries such as electronics--which consistently maintain a favorable
balance of trade-the possibility that various foreign countries might begin tak-
ing independent steps to redetermine their own trade barriers raises very trou-
bling problems. It would be logical for these barriers to protect against highly
sophisticated products in which advanced technology and production efficiency
play a great part-and these are the very types of exports in which the electronic
industry specializes.
D. Limitations on direct investment
On January 1, 1968, the President-through an executive order-imposed
direct controls on foreign investments by U.S. corporations and citizens
and established repatriation requirements on the foreign earnings of do-
mestic companies. These were drastic and unprecedented steps to control the
flow of capital abroad and force profits to be brought back to the United States.
If, in the long run, one of the keys to a viable balance of payments picture for
this country is a growing surplus of foreign earnings, and another key is an
expansion of the direct investment in foreign corporations which is reportedly
generating approximately one-fourth of all U.S. exports, then the recent invest-
ment controls are indeed open to serious question concerning their wisdom.
Should these controls be continued over a period of several years. companies
such as Fairchild will simply not be able to expand those foreign facilities which
are producing the favorable trade balances these companies now maintain. And
if this should happen, the direct investment controls will have produced very few
positive gains indeed for our balance of payments.
PAGENO="0216"
3652
III. POSITIVE STEPS TOWARD IMPROVING THE 11.5. BAI~ANOE OF TRADE
It is clear that for this Nation to maintain a favorable balance of payments
picture, it must expand its favorable balance of trade. To do this, the Executive
Branch as well as the Congress must be willing to take some new steps here
at home. For example, we must begin to explore the possibility of expanding
the guarantee and direct loan powers of the Export-Import Bank. We should
also carefully examine the possibility of a lower tax treatment for export
corporations and of a coordinated system of trade shows and fairs in this
country to attract both foreign travelers and foreign purchases. During the
past few years, increased foreign attendance and orders have marked the trade
shows of the electronics industry. If the Federal Government can encourage
more industries to undertake these types of shows, we will have taken a major
step forward in our effort to increase our sales abroad.
But over and above any internal change that this Nation may make to im-
prove its trade position, it should also accept the proposition that multinational
rather than unilateral action must be our touchstone in dealing with all inter-
national trade problems and the fact that import quotas and ceilings and
surcharges are totally inconsistent with this proposition.
In the place of these unilateral acts, this Nation should continue its efforts
to obtain cooperation from its allies-cooperation which hopefully will lead
them to increase the pace of their Kennedy Round tariff reductions, to reduce
their border taxes so as to reflect more accurately those indirect levies which
are actually built into the price of their goods, and to adopt monetary and
fiscal policies which may further increase the demand for our products. More-
over, it is this same type of cooperation which can lead to a~ broad acceptance
of rules for international competition and ultimately to the creation of minimum
labor standards to be observed by all industrial nations. Finally, it is this
same spirit of cooperation which could lead to a coordinated policy of trade
with Eastern Europe and the Soviet Union-one in which United States in-
dustries would be enabled to obtain a fair share of what will hopefully become
a growing East-West trade in non-strategic goods.
Mr. Chairman, it is the judgment of the Fairchild Camera and Instrument
Corporation that this Nation's current balance of trade and balance of payments
problems are solvable. But it is also the judgment of my corporation that these
problems must be treated within a framework of multi-national cooperation
and through an international effort to reach common goals. For the United
States will only exacerbate its difficulties if it should now embark upon a
unilateral, trade- and investment-restricting program in which national bound-
aries are transformed into national barriers and the private enterprise quest
for new markets is replaced by governmental regulation of the movement of
goods and capital.
Mr. FULTON. Thank you. Mr. Conable.
Mr. GONABLE. Mr. Hodgson, I understand your point of v~iew about
your industry. I am also somewhat concerned as a member of this com-
mittee looking at the overall testimony that is coming before us and I
wonder if it is necessary for this country to be either free trade or
protectionist.
Is it possible for us to strike a balance somewhere where we will be
able to provide a degree of protection for the low skill, low tech-
nology, industries that provide jobs for so many of our disadvantaged
and comparatively unskilled people and still avoid this course of
retaliation that seems to be such a bugaboo to people in high skill
industries like yours.
Is it possible to walk that narrow path do you think to find a
compromise somehow?
Mr. HODOSON. It isn't going to happen in a very short time. I think
it is possible to walk this kind of a path. We have had extremely good
luck and fortune in training low-skilled people into the difficulties of
making semiconductors and instruments. We happen to be the largest
PAGENO="0217"
3653
employer of American Indians in this country. We have a plant in the
Navajo Reservation in New Mexico, with 500 girls working there who
have never seen a transistor before.
Their productivity equals the output we have from our factory in
Portland, Maine, in Mountainview, or in Europe.
I think they need the opportunity and the legislative acts that are
going on in this country today to bring opportunity to unskilled people
is certainly working in this direction.
We are looking at a bit here and a bit there, but I don't think you
are ever going to upgrade the working capacity of people by putting
up an umbrella and protecting them and saying, look, we are going
to keep you employed at $1.60 an hour doing the job which can be done
much better either by automation or certainly by bringing in com-~
petitive products from abroad.
Mr. CONABLE. Now let's look at this from a different angle. Isn't
completely free trade going to end with total dependence on foreign
supplier~s for some types of products?
For instance, isn't it likely that some vital industries will be either
moved abroad by our own producers or supplanted by foreign compe-
tition?
Mr. HoDosoN. I think this could happen, yes, and I think some of
the statistics that were given earlier today don't necessarily mean a
reduction in employment in these specific industries that one is talking
about.
We have moved abroad operations which were labor-intensive, low
skilled. In many cases we weren't even able to man the plants, you
might say, for this type of an operation.
People were not interested in this work. We moved them abroad..
This is a period of time where certainly I agree our industry is
perhaps special in that sense. It is highly technology oriented and
new processes, new techniques, are going to bring a lot of that work
back into this country but that doesn't mean that we are going to be
laying off people abroad either. There are other opportunities for
them now that have come out of our investments in plants abroad.
I think it is a continual series of movements. I think one has to
look at the trade business as being an international business and not
look at it specifically by countries or boundaries or industries.
Mr. CONABLE. Apparently one has to be an optimist in this field.
Mr. HoDosoN. You have to be a believer, but I don't think you have to
be an optimist.
Mr. CONABLE. I have no other questions.
Mr. FULTON. How many foreign countries does Fairchild have
plants in?
Mr. HODGSON. Well, I would roughly guess about 10.
Mr. FULTON. Could you name those countries?
Mr. HoDosoN. Yes; England, Sweden, France, Germany, Italy,.
Holland, Hong Kong, Korea, Australia, Canada, and Mexico.
Mr. FtrriroN. On behalf of the committee I want to thank you for
your excellent presentation and contribution you have made to the
committee in its deliberations.
Mr. HoDosoN. Thank you.
(The following statements were received, for the record, by the
committee :`~
PAGENO="0218"
3654
STATEMENT OF H. WILLIAM TANAKA, COURSEL, ON BEHALF OF CERTAIN IMPORTERS
OF ELECTRONIC PRODUCTS, A&A TRADING COMPANY, ET AL.
This statement is submitted on behalf of 13 U.S. corporations which import
and distribute electronic products~ We wish to register our opposition to the
various bills now pending before the Committee which would impose quotas on
imports of electronic products and components. We submit that there is no need
for quota restrictions and that quotas would restrict the consumer's choice of
products, would disrupt normal business operations, and would lead to an ex-
pansion of Government controls.
A description of the role which imports have played in the market might con-
tribute to the Committee's understanding of the electronic industry. While it
is true that imports have grown substantially, the bare statistics alone do not
give an accurate picture of the actual extent of competition between imported
and domestically produced electronic products. A substantial portion of the
total imports represents products not produced in the United States. Innovations
by foreign producers, particularly the Japanese, have served to fill the gaps in the
product lines produced in this country, and have offered the consumer a full
range of home entertainment products at reasonable prices.
The tremendous post-war expansion of the consumer electronics industry has
been spurred by development of new products. Many items which are in wide use
today were not available twenty years ago. Innovations by Japanese producers
have played an important role in this expansion. Much of the original technology
in miniaturization of electronic components and parts was developed in the
United States for use in the military, space and industrial fields. This tech-
nology was licensed to Japanese producers who realized its vast potential in the
consumer market. Their application of this technology in the production of new
consumer products has made a substantial contribution towards expanding the
range of items available to the American consumer today.
The development of the small pocket-size transistor radio is a prime example.
The transistor was an American invention, but no U.S. company considered
transistors ready for use in consumer products in 1954 when Sony Corporation
obtained a license from Western Electric to make transistors in Japan. A single
transistor cost $6 at the time and there was no hope of competing with tube
radios costing as little as $6.95. (Business Week, May 25, 1968, page 80). But
Sony executives realized that transistor costs could be substantially reduced to
the point where small transistor radios could be sold at competitive prices.
Within one year after acquiring the technology, Sony produced its first pocket-
size transistor radio. It was shortly followed by other Japanese producers, and
the transistor radio was an immediate success in the market.
The initial reaction of a major U.S. manufacturer was described in the report
of an annual national business conference held at Harvard:
"Engineers and marketing personnel in GE's radio receiver department had
studied the market for compact portable radios as early as 1956. Marketers had
favored the addition of small sets to the company's line but believed that per-
formance standards in such sets should be good. Engineering personnel did not
believe that it was possible to have good performance in small radios. Because
of the tiny speakers and cabinets that would be used, good tone would be impos-
sible to achieve. Furthermore, such sets would have to have small antennas and
their receiving sensitivity would necessarily be limited. Finally, small batteries
could last only fifteen to twenty hours as compared to seventy-five to one hundred
hours for batteries in conventional portable radios.
"The rapid acceptance of Japanese radios, however, had indicated the strong
demand existing in the United States for subminiature sets, in spite of the fact
that by GE standards these sets did not have good performance. It became ap-
parent, then, to the management of the radio receiver department that GE should
be represented in this new segment of the radio market." 1
The quality of transistor radios was substantially improved through Japanese
developments in the field of miniature components. Mitsumi Electric invented
the polyvaricon, a miniature tuning capacitor; while Toko invented the miniature
intermediate frequency transformer. Many Japanese companies contributed to
the development of improved speakers for transistor radios.
Some American producers decided to compete by using foreign components
in sets assembled in the United States. Other companies imported completed
sets produced to their specifications and sold under their own brand names.
l"Managing America's Economic Explosion", edited by Dan H. Fenn Jr. and published
by McGraw Hill Book Company, Inc., New York, 1961, page 145.
PAGENO="0219"
3655
Recently, the large Japanese companies have concentrated on the more expensive
multi-band transistor radios while much of the production of 6-transistor AM
radios has shifted to smaller Japanese companies as well as producers in Hong
Kong and Taiwan.
It is important to note that Japanese producers such as Sony, Matsushita,
Toshiba and Hitachi were the first to exploit the vast potential of transistors
in home entertainment products. These imports stimulated the growth of the
entire consumer electronic market.
The Japanese producers were also the leading innovators in developing tape
recorders for home entertainment use. Before the advent of imports, the only
tape recorders available in the United States were large expensive units be-
yond the reach of the average consumer. Sony Corporation was the first to in-
troduce battery operated portable tape recorders suitable for the mass market.
Tape recorder sales were expanded through Japanese development of improved
tape beads and motors. This product innovation created a new market dimen-
sion which would not have come into being at the time were it not for im-
ports. Japanese producers are now developing a new mass market for tape re-
corders with the cassette tape cartridge system originated by Phillips of Hol-
land. Another new dimension is being added by Japanese companies such as
Crown which have coupled the cassette to telephone answering systems.
The imported micro TV set is another example. At a time when major U.S.
manufacturers were advertising their 19-inch sets weighing 30 or 40 pounds
or more as "portable," merely by adding a luggage handle, the imports came
into this market with a truly portable 8-inch and 5-inch television receiver.
Matsushita has recently introduced a 1l/2-inch black and white set powered
by flashlight batteries. These imports have opened an entirely new market. In
addition to the large living room console, the average family can now afford a
second or third television set for other rooms or for outdoor use.
Japanese companies were also the leaders in small screen color TV sets.
Toshiba was the first to offer a 14-inch color set. On the other hand, domestic
producers have generally concentrated on the larger screen sizes.
The latest development in this field is the new 7-inch color TV set recently
introduced by Sony. The set is the first commercial application of the chromatron
picture tube invented in 1951 by Dr. E. 0. Lawrence, a physicist at the Uni-
versity of California. Next year, Sony will introduce a new small screen color
TV set with the trinitron color tube-a new departure in picture tube design
which provides substantial improvements in brightness and clarity.
Japanese companies have also played a leading role in the development of home
video tape recorders. Through new technological improvements the cOst is
being steadily reduced and complete video tape recorder systems are now com-
ing on the market at a price within the reach of the average consumer. They
will undoubtedly open new marketing opportunities in the consumer electronic
industry.
These Japanese innovations have not displaced domestic production since, in
general, comparable products are not produced in this country. Thus it is incor-
rect to assume that every imported transistor radio, portable tape recorder, or
small screen TV set, means one less item produced in the United States with a
corresponding loss of employment. Were it not for imports, these products
w-ould not have been available to the American consumer since U.S. companies
have generally concentrated in the larger and higher profit items.
In fact, the innovations of Japanese electronic producers have benefited the
American economy. They have opened up new markets and generated demand
for new products. The American ëonsumer has benefited through the variety and
range of choice available today. And these innovations have provided employ-
ment for thousands of Americans engaged in importing, distributing, merchan-
dising and servicing of consumer electronic products from abroad. The vitality
of this industry would be jeopardized by the quota legislation pending before
your Committee.
It is evident that the domestic electronic industry does not require special pro-
tection from imports. The United States is the world leader in electronics. The
industry has experienced a fantastic rate of growth since World War II. Total
factory sales rose from $1.7 billion in 1947 to $22.1 billion in 1967. Between 1958
and 1967, total employment jumped from 650,000 to nearly 1.2 million workers.
The United States has a substantially favorable balance of trade in electronic
products. Total exports in 1967 amounted to nearly $1.8 billion with imports of
about $830 million. Total exports increased by 22.7% between 1966 and 1967,
PAGENO="0220"
3656
compared to an increase of imports of 11.5%. (Electronic Industries Association,
Elect rowic Industries Year Book, 1968).
The U.S. producers of consumer electronic products do not need quota pro-
tection; in fact, they strongly oppose the electronics quota bills. Sales of con-
sumer electronic products increased 25% in 1966 over 1965-from $3.7 billion
to $4.5 billion. 1967 sales were ~4.3 billion, almost equal to the sales level attained
in the record year of 1966. (Ibid).
The consumer products producers have good reason to oppose import quotas.
No manufacturer can efficiently and economically produce every one of the great
variety of consumer electronic products on the market today. The American pro-
ducers concentrate on those products which they can manufacture efficiently in
volume, while relying on imports to round out their product lines. Major domestic
manufacturers such as RCA, General Electric, Motorola, and Philco-Ford are
going "international" by purchasing components and finished products wherever
they can be produced at satisfactory quality and economical costs. Broadening
the base for sourcing as well as marketing has served to improve the overall
competitive posture of these companies. Moreover, many American producers of
finished products who do not manufacture their own components have found that
imported components help them to compete with integrated producers.
The U.S. manufacturers of industrial and military electronic equipment have
not sought protection from imports. Companies such as IBM, Ratheon, and Fair-
child Camera `and Instrument Corporation are strong advocates of a liberal trade
policy, and they have played an important role in the fight against quotas.
The request for quotas comes from only one segment of the U.S. industry-
the producers of components and parts. But the facts show that this segment
of the industry is thriving, and is in no need of special protection.
U.S. factory sales of electronic components totaled about $5.5 billion in 1967,
off slightly from the record $5.7 billion in 1966, but higher than any other year.
Industry estimates point to a rise in component sales in 1968. The ability of
U.S. component manufacturers to compete in world markets is illustrated by
their record exports in 1967 of $486 million, up 10.5% over the previous year.
(Electronic Industries Association, Electronic Industries Year Book, 1968).
The claim that imports have caused a loss of employment in the component
segment of the industry is refuted by official Government statistics. Total em-
ployment in 1967 exceeded 360,000 workers; down from the peak year of 1966,
but higher than any other year on record. The latest information shows that
employment this year has moved up sharply. Total employment in electronic
components and accessories reached 376,000 workers in May 1968. (U.S. Depart-
ment of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, En~plo~jment and Earnings, June
1968). At this rate, employment for 1968 could reach an all-time high, exceeding
even the record 1966 employment of 374,000 workers.
Thus there is no need or justification for imposition of quotas on imports of
electronic products and components.
The economic and political repercussions of quota restrictions have been
emphasized in the testimony of both Government and industry witnesses. All
nations would suffer from the inevitable chain reaction of retaliation and counter-
retaliation.
In addition, quotas would totally disrupt normal business operations by
placing arbitrary limitations on supply. Competition would be restricted, prices
would rise, and Government control of business activities would increase.
Finally, quotas would stifle the innovative efforts of foreign producers which
have contributed so much to the growth, variety, and vitality of the consumer
electronics market. The American consumer and industry as well, would suffer
as a result.
We therefore respectfully urge the Ways and Means Committee to reject
the proposals for quotas on electronic products and components, and to reaffirm
its support for a liberal trade policy.
This statement made in behalf of the following:
A & A Trading Company, 23-25 East 26th Street, New York, New York.
Craig Panorama, Inc., 2302 Fast 15th Street, Los Angeles. Calif. 90021.
Hitachi Sales Corporation, 48-50 34th Street, Long Island City, N.Y. 11101.
Lloyd's Electronics rnternational, 6651 East 26th Street, Los Angeles, Calif. 90022.
Matsushita Electric Corporation of America, 200 Park Avenue, New York, N.Y.
10017.
Mitsumi Electronics Corporation, 11 Broadway, New York, N.Y. I 000f.
Murata Corp. of America, 160 Broadway, New York, N.Y. 10038.
PAGENO="0221"
3657
Pioneer Electronics USA Corp., 140 Smith Street, Farmingdale, Long Island, New
York 11735.
Sharp Electronics Corp., 178 Commerce Road, Carlstadt, New Jersey 07072.
Sony Corp. of America, 47-47 Ban Dan Street, Long Island City, N.Y. 11101.
TDK Electronics Corp., 82 Wall Street, New York, N.Y. 10005.
Topp Import and Export, Inc., 4201 Northwest 77th Avenue, Miami, Fla. 33106.
Toshiba America, Inc., 477 Madison Avenue, New York, N.Y. 10022.
STATEMENT OF GENERAL ELECTRIC COMPANY
General Electric Company, 570 Lexington Avenue, New York, New York 10022,
submits this statement to the Committee on Ways and Means in support of certain
provisions of H.R. 17551, the Trade Expansion Act of 19138.
Specifically, General Electric supports the following two provisions of the
pending legislation:
1. Extension through June 30, 1970 of the President's authority to nego-
tiate tariff reductions;
2. Authorization of funds for the expenses of U.S. participation in the
General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT).
And, in overall terms, General Electric supports the principles and objectives
set forth in the President's May 28 message to the Congress on U.S. trade policy,
which the pending legislation seeks to implement. We agree with the President
that "when trade barriers fall, the American people and the American economy
benefit" and that "even as we consolidate our past gains, we must look to the
future."
Above all, General Electric endorses, and in this statement seeks to bring into
particular commercial focus, two key sentences in the President's message:
"Other nations must join with us to put an end to non-tariff barriers. Trade
is a two-way street. A successful trade policy must be bailt on reciprocity. Our
own trade initiatives will founder unless our trading partners join with us to
put an end to non-tariff barrier." (Emphasis added.)
There still exist today, 20 years after GATT was established and one year
after the Kennedy Round was concluded, two major European non-tariff bar-
riers which create one-way streets in international trade among the industrial
nations of the free world: (1) nationalistic procurement policies and practices;
and (2) the border tax system which permits remission of taxes for export and
imposition of equalization charges on imports.
Both these barriers are ingrained into the economic structure and commer-
cial self-interest of the European trading nations, and both have a significant
effect on U.S. ability to compete in world markets. They are, therefore, of
great concern to General Electric as a multi-national company which already
exports $500 million annually but must continue to seek widening markets for
the export of its high-technology products.
First, the nationalistic public procurement policies of foreign governments.
The electric utility systems of Europe are substantially owned or controlled
by their national governments. As a matter of national economic policy these
utilities buy electrical equipment only from their domestic manufacturers. Where
domestic capability exists, no outside competition is permitted on these procure-
ments, regardless of whether it offers a low-er price or superior quality. Yet
these same manufacturers, while enjoying the insulation of their protected home
markets, can export to the United States and are doing so increasingly in sub-
stantial volumes.
What we are talking about here are hundreds of millions of dollars of trade
in high-technology equipment among the industrial nations-the big turbine
generators and power transformers and power circuit breakers that are the
backbone of modern electric power systems. This is an industry in which the
U.S. has always excelled-in innovation and technological advance, in engineer-
ing excellence and in manufacturing productivity. It is an industry whose major
markets are the 115.8. and industrialized Europe. Yet, U.S. manufacturers are
foreclosed from the European markets, and their satellite markets as well, by
procurement policies that give total preference to domestic manufacturers.
Here is protectionism of the most radical sort, for it denies entirely the concept
of reciprocity and a two-way street which the President laid down as a corner-
stone of U.S. trade policy.
PAGENO="0222"
3658
The commercial consequences of this one-way street in government procure-
ment are set forth in detail in a technical brief and supplementary letter which
General Electric recently submitted to the Trade Information Committee (TIC)
in connection with the TIC's current study of U.S. trade policy. We are attach-
ing the brief and supplementary letter to this statement for inclusion in the
record of hearings on H.R. 17551, should the Committee consider it appropri-
ate. * Suffice it here to summarize briefly the trade consequences of these ex-
clusionary procurement practices of foreign governments in heavy electrical
equipment:
(a) U.S.-made equipment is denied access to large and potentially profitable
markets, to the detriment of the U.S. industry, its employees and the national
trade account.
(b) Because their home markets are totally insulated from the discipline
of outside competition, European manufacturers, in close cooperation with their
customers, the nationalized power authorities, obtain all domestic orders at
high profitable prices-prices which are generally higher than U.S. manu-
facturers obtain from U.S. utilities.
(c) With the assurance of steady home market orders at high prices, Euro-
pean manufacturers sell into this country, to both public and private utilities,
at prices substantially below what they charge at home-20 to 50 per cent lower.
Sometimes the foreign price in the U.S. market is at or below cost, as shown
in our brief to the TIC. This is more than sporadic "incremental" pricing to get rid
of excess capacity. It is a calculated long-term strategy of dual-pricing to cap-
ture, hold and enlarge the largest single market in the world for high-voltage
electrical equipment which is at the very forefront of today's technology.
(d) An artificial competitive imbalance has fastened itself on the interna-
tional trade of this equipment to the point that such international trade is a
one-way street. Let us continue the U.S. commitment to open markets in this
country. Let us also realize that the competitive imbalance, inequitable on its
face and commercially disadvantageous to U.S. trade, will continue as long as
the one-way street is permitted.
Second, the tax structures of most of the European trading nations, which
impose equalization charges on imports (border taxes) and provide for remis-
sion of internal taxes on exports, confer a major trade advantage on those
nations. Their indirect border tax system is not trade-neutral in its effect on the
U.S. competitor who is operating under a direct tax structure.
The attached General Electric brief and supplementary letter to the Trade
Information Committee, referred to earlier, also contain specific detail with re-
spect to some of the trade consequences of the so-called border tax system. In
this statement we would only emphasize our belief that the theory of tax shift-
ing, direct taxes versus indirect taxes, which underlies the GATT rules with
respect to imposition of equalization charges and remission of internal taxes
for exports, should be re-examined and empirically tested for soundness, par-
ticularly the relationship of tax shifting to elasticity of demand. Until this is.
done, U.S. trade cannot be expected willingly to accept the trade disadvantages
which flow from a theoretical rationale which has been allowed to stand untested.
for too many years.
Here, then, in bare outline, are the dimensions of two non-tariff barriers
which have significant impact on U.S. trade and our competitive position in
world markets.
We suggest that U.S. trade policy, as enunciated by statute, regulation and
administrative practice, can and should seek to eliminate or at least reduce
these barriers in two ways: (1) by international negotiation, and (2) by
review and amendment of those U.S. laws and regulations which are intended
to protect against unfair foreign competition.
First, continuing international negotiations to remove these barriers must
be given priority. This is why we specifically support the provisions of H.R.
17551 which would extend the President's tariff negotiating authority and
authorize funds for U.S. participation in the GATT. Such participation, on
the strongest and most enduring basis possible, is an essential element of U.S.
trade policy because it is in this international forum, as supplemented by
*The General Electric brief submitted to the Trade Information Committee included, as a
separate attachment, a number of confidential exhibits which set forth cost and price infor-
mation about foreign-made equipment. Should the Committee or the Committee staff wish~
to examine these exhibits they can be made available on a confidential basis.
PAGENO="0223"
3659
proceedings in the Organization for Economic Development (OECD), that long-
term solutions to basic trade restrictions and imbalances will be worked out.
Our underlying commitment to liberalized reciprocal trade depends for its suc-
cess in large measure on multi-lateral negotiations under the procedural safe-
guards of the GATT. The record of the past 20 years shows that GATT is the
appropriate forum in which negotiations can be had to improve the basic rules
of international trade and commerce that go far to bind the trading nations
to fair trade and competitive equity.
In fact, the two non-tariff barriers we have cited in this statement are under
consideration in the GATT right now. We have been so advised by U.S. trade
officials; and in his testimony of June 4 before the Ways and Means Committee,
Ambassador Roth said:
"We have also made a good start (in the GATT) toward reaching an agreed
solution to the problem of the rules governing border taxes and are working
in a special GATT group on the many problems that remain in other non tariff
barriers."
The momentum of the Kennedy Round should be exploited to proceed now
to this next and more difficult stage of negotiations on the real barriers to
trade. U.S. trade policy, and the legislative base on which it rests, must accept
the U.S. commitment to international negotiations to accomplish these ends.
Accordingly, General Electric urges the Congress to give the Executive the
legislative support needed to go forward in the GATT. And beyond this, we
believe that the Congress should make clear its legislative intent that U.S.
trade policy, in the GATT and all related international proceedings, must be
conducted in such a way as to create genuine two-way streets and insure
competitive equity for American industry.
Second, U.S. trade policy must have at hand and effectively employ an array
of self-help remedies and legal recourse with which to discipline unfair com-
petition in international trade. Our ability to negotiate successfully in the
GATT and other international forums and to maintain a strong bargaining
position depends in large part on the statutory authority of U.S. government
and U.S. business to retaliate against trade discrimination and restrictive
practices. This is particularly important with respect to short-term solutions
for specific trade abuses, because international negotiations are necessarily
long in their resolution and general in the agreements they reach.
It is appropriate, we believe, in the course of the Committee's consideration
of H.R. 17551 that existing statutory remedies be reviewed carefully to deter-
mine if they are accomplishing the purpose intended and, if not, whether new
legislation or new statements of Congressional intent are necessary. In his June
testimony, Ambassador Roth said the following:
"I agree that the practices of other countries are not always what we would
like them to be. Where I do not agree is that we are helpless before them. Both
under our international commitments and our domestic law, we have remedies
for many of them. We have the power to impose antidumping duties and counter-
vailing duties to offset unfair pricing practices and subsidies. And we have
authority to protect domestic producers seriously injured by imports even where
foreign practices are perfectly fair. This includes the authority to increase tariffs
under the escape clause and to impose quotas to protect domestically supported
farm prices."
We suggest, however, that despite Ambassador Roth's statement, the existing
array of apparently applicable self-help remedies now on the books is inadequate,
either as written or as interpreted and implemented by Executive Departments
and administrative regulations. We recommend that Congress review existing
remedies in the light of unfair foreign competition; that is, those governmental
and commercial policies and practices that give an artifical trade advantage to
industries in competition with U.S. industry, whether in the U.S., their own
home country or third country markets. In particular, we believe that the fol-
lowing three U.S. laws as they have been interpreted and executed should be re-
examined in terms of their reach to prevent unfair methods of competition:
1. The Antidumping Act of 1921 (19 USC 160)
2. Countervailing Duties-Tariff Act of 1930 (19 USC 303)
3. Trade Expansion Act of 1962, Section 252 (19 USC 1882)
The Antidumping Act is not intended to reach unfair competition itself, but
only the injurious consequences of such dumping. As such, it is not a relevant
statutory remedy for an industry, or a company, which cannot meet the tests
of material injury, as laid down by regulation and previous Tariff Commission
PAGENO="0224"
3660
decisions. Unless the definition of "injury" under the Act were broadened to in-
clude certain kinds of dump pricing-from protected home niarkets, for ex-
ample-as injurious (per se or presumptively) by reason of their effect on do-
mestic price levels and share of market, the dual pricing strategies of foreign
exporters of heavy electrical equipment cannot be disciplined under the Act by
a healthy or relatively still healthy U.S. industry.
Countervailing duties provide an effective way to discipline export subsidies.
Used sparingly in the past, they have recently been applied in a few instances
involving both industrial and agricultural products. We suggest it is now time
for an in-depth analysis of the more subtle forms of foreign government assist-
ance to exporters to see if they are not in fact an improper bounty or grant
under the statute. Thus, for example, restrictive government procurement prac-
tices which exclude U.S. competition, assure protected home markets, and thereby
permit dual pricing-high at home, low into the U.S.-could well be held to con-
stitute an export subsidy. So, perhaps, could government-financed research and
development for high technology equipment going into export. Absent legislative
direction to this effect, the Treasury Department probably and understandably
would be reluctant to extend the reach of their authority to cases such as these.
Finally, Section 252 of the Trade Expansion Act, which appears to give the
Executive broad authority to move against foreign protectionism and restrictive
trade practices, has yet to be used. Admittedly, this is relatively new legislation.
And, as a practical matter, it should be regarded and applied as a complementary
part of overall trade policy, so as not to impair the outcome of int~rnational
negotiations. But international negotiations should not replace Section 252 or
render it inoperative. We would therefore urge that the Congress give more
explicit legislative direction to the Executive in the purpose of Section 252 and
specify the sorts of restrictive trade practices it was intended to protect against.
In conclusion, we would suggest two other steps which the Congress might
consider to bring international competition into closer balance:
First, further study should be given to the idea that the U.S. adopt, in substi-
tution for all or a part of the corporation income tax, a value-added tax which
would have the trade effect of encouraging exports (by tax rebates) and impos-
ing modest equalization charges on imports. The Committee for Economic Devel-
oprnent has advanced this idea, and we believe it has sufficient merit to warrant
serious consideration in the Congress. While it is preferable that there be inter-
national agreement that border taxes are not trade-neutral in their effect, with
consequent revision of the GATT rules as to their application, nevertheless it is
realistic for the U.S. to consider the alternative of adopting for ourselves, at
least on a limited basis, the European indirect tax system.
Second, U.S. procurement policy could be changed to take into accouat the
fact that certain foreign government markets are foreclosed from U.S. competi-
tion. In our brief to the TIC we suggested that U.S. procurement agencies could
require certification by foreign bidders that they are not bidding in the U.S.
at prices lower than they bid equivalent equipment in their own home markets.
This suggestion is the obverse of a recommendation of the 1954 Report of the
Randall Commission on Foreign Economic Policy. The Randall Commission
recommended that where other nations treat U.S. bidders "on an equal basis with
their own nationals" on government procurements, the Buy American preference
should not be applied against suppliers of those nations bidding in the U.S.
market. Equally valid, it seems to us, would be a U.S. requirement that where
other nations do not permit U.S. suppliers to bid in their government markets,
then at least some approximately equivalent deterrent should be applied against
the suppliers of those nations. Such requirement might well be the means for
creating two-way streets.
ATTACHMENT
Bainr OF GENERAL ELECTRIC COMPANY, NEW YORK, N.Y., BEFORE THE OFFICE OF
THE SPECIAL REPRESENTATIVE FOR TRADE NEGOTIATIONS, TRADE INFORMATION
COMMITTEE, WASHINGTON, D.C., DOCKET No. 67-4
~S'ome Non-Tariff Barriers to World Trade
INTRODUCTION
Present and future U.S. trade policy must be based on recognition of the fact
that, in terms of expanding free world trade, the tariff-cutting phase of interna-
tional trade relations has run its course, and a new phase has begun-the pains-
PAGENO="0225"
3661
taking work of eliminating or reducing those nontariff trade restrictions and
advantages which are rooted in national and regional economic policy.
The series of post-war multilateral tariff negotiations confirmed the trading
nations' general commitment to expanded trade and rejection of out-and-out
protectionism. But, precisely as these obvious evidences of pre-war protection-
ism have been stripped away, so the underlying imbalances and restrictions have
emerged. These are the real inhibitors of expanded trade on a fair and competi-
tive basis. The GATT is 20 years old; trade patterns and monetary flows reflect
the deep changes that have occurred during this period; and protectionism has.
new faces. U.S. trade policy must adjust to the realities of commercial competi-
tion in the world today.
The General Electric Company is particularly concerned with two of these
underlying imbalances and restrictions:
1. Nationalistic procurement policies and practices of foreign government-
owned or controlled electric utilities which (a) exclude U.S. electric utility
equipment from competing in their markets; (b) allow and encourage high non-
competitive prices from their domestic suppliers in these insulated markets;
and thus (c) permit and encourage those same domestic suppliers to export to
the United States and third countries at prices which, in a true commercial
sense, are at less than fair value. The competitive disadvantage to the U.S.
industry, thus, is two-fold: exclusion from potentially profitable European mar-
kets; unfair pricing in the U.S. market.
2. The tax structures of most of the European trading nations, which impose
equalization charges on imports (border taxes) and provide for remission of
internal taxes on exports, confer a major trade advantage on those nations. Their
indirect border tax system is not trade-neutral in its effect on the U.S. competitor
who is operating under a direct tax structure.
General Electric views the foregoing two imbalances and restrictions in the
following context of international competition:
First, General Electric has long been heavily engaged in international trade.
It has manufacturing and distribution facilities in many parts of the world.
It exports annually some $500 million from the U.S. and imports some $100 mil-
lion. Accordingly, General Electric's overall objective in international markets
is fair, freetrade with the fewest possible restrictions against the movement of
goods across national borders so that customers everywhere have freedom of
choice in making purchases anywhere in the world on a fair and equitable basis.
General Electric does not believe in closed markets, whether they be achieved
by high costs of entry or exclusionary public procurement policies.
second, a substantial portion of General Electric's business is in high-tech-
nology products. The Company contributes significantly to this nation's technolog-
ical world leadership. But with respect to electric utility equipment a disturbing
situation is developing. A significant amount of competence in certain high-tech-
nology equipment is gained through sales in this country to the Federal power
agencies. Sales to these Federal agencies are enormously important to the de-
velopment of technology because they operate large systems that require high
engineering sophistication. These agencies rank among the leaders in moving up
to the larger sizes and voltage levels which require new advances in technology.
Their influence on U.S. and world electric utility technology cannot be under-
estimated. Thus, to the extent that U.S. public procurement policy permits foreign
manufacturers virtually full access to the Federal market-at prices substan-
tially below their home market prices-while U.S. technology is denied access to
foreign markets, there is technological unilateralism. The question must be asked,
how much does this unilateralism impede or discourage U.S. manufacturers from
developing new technology? One possibly relevant answer may lie in the declining
number of U.S. bidders to the Federal power agencies on high-technology equip-
ment in recent years and the increasing number of foreign bidders.
Third, the statistics of trade in heavy electrical equipment among the producer
nations indicate a rapidly worsening competitive position for the U.S. industry:
(a) In high-voltage power circuit breakers and transformers, where manu-
facturing capability exists in seven European nations, for the period 1963-
1907 orders placed by U.S. utilities in these seven countries totaled
$97,185,000. Orders of U.S. equipment by the seven countries totaled $59,000.
(b) In large steam turbine generators, 10,000 KW and above, where
manufacturing capability exists in seven European nations, orders placed by
U.S. utilities in those seven countries totaled $146,000,000. Orders of U.S.
equipment by the seven countries totaled $0.
95-159 0-68-pt. 8-15
PAGENO="0226"
3662
Fo'urth, while the emergence of regional trade blocs such as the European
Economic Community and the European Free Trade Association are welcome
developments, they pose trade questions which have disturbing implications. To
the extent that national preferences, restrictions and advantages in tax struc-
ture, and protective public procurement policy expand into regional arrange-
ments, the U.S. and other outsiders will incur even greater competitive disadvan-
tages. Moreover, General Electric can reasonably anticipate that the larger
enterprises that emerge out of industrial realignment and rationalization within
these regions will be strengthened by uniform and widened public procurement
inside the sheltered markets, continuing high costs of import entry, and tax
incentives to export.
Pifth, it must be recognized that the procurement and tax policies of these
European countries are nationalistic instruments to encourage their manufac-
turers to help execute government policy designed (among other things) to
protect their balance of payments and thus their currencies.
I
A. THE PUBLIC PROCUREMENT POLICIES AND PRACTICES OF THE EUROPEAN PRODUCER
NATIONS OF HEAVY ELECTRICAL EQUIPMENT EXCLUDE U.S. COMPETITION IN EURO-
PEAN MARKETS
B. TOTALLY PROTECTED HOME MARKETS ENABLE EUROPEAN MANUFACTURERS TO
PURSUE A STRATEGY OF "DUAL PRICING": HIGH HOME MARKET PRICEs; LOW EXPORT
PRICES
A. European Public Procurement Policies and Practices
1. Most electric utilities are government owned or controlled public au-
tltorities.'-In the United Kingdom, France, Italy, Sweden and Austria electric
utilities are almost entirely nationalized. The few regional public authorities,
Scotland and Northern Ireland in the U.K., Electricité de Strasbourg and
Compagnie Nationale du Rhone in France, adhere to the policies of their respec-
tive national authorities, the Central Electricity Generating Board (CEGB) and
Electricité de France (EDF). In West Germany there is a mix of regional public
utilities and private utilities, but the Federal Government is a dominant par-
ticipant and influence in procurement policy by reason of its financing of utility
expansion.
Thus the public procurement policies of all these countries, which implement
underlying national economic planning, directly control purchases of utility
equipment by public auhorities.
2. European electric utilities pursue strict buy-national policies.-Where a
European nation has domestic capability in electrical equipment it buys from its
domestic industry.~ This is a fiat rule almost without exception. Sometimes the
authority of such policies is contained in law, administrative regulation or
executive order; sometimes it is simply a tacit or informal practice deeply rooted
in a modern day economic nationalism. The specific procedures by which these
policies are carried out are:
(a) Requests for bids are not formally advertised or otherwise given public
notice. Instead, private discussions and negotiations are held between the utility
and its potential suppliers whereby designs and specifications are spelled out and
terms and conditions of sale agreed upon. Thus, there is scant opportunity for
other qualified suppliers to respond to a bid or present their particular capabil-
ities for consideration.
lExhjbit 1.
2 See Organization for Economic Corporation and Development, Government Purchasing
in Europe, North America, and Japan: Regulation, and Procedures (Paris, 1966); also
Exhibit II.
PAGENO="0227"
3663
(b) Sole sourcing is permitted even though there may be other qualified sup-
pliers. The Utility can negotiate with a given supplier without notification to any
other. This practice is frequently used when one supplier has established its
competence in a particular rating or design.
(c) The utility may make a bulk allocation whereby it commits itself to
quantity requirements for the expected life of a particular design at a particular
rating. Production schedules may be spread over a term of years and prices sub-
ject to later agreement between buyer and seller. This arrangement has the
advantages of completing a single, early procurement at which no firm orders are
placed and no prices quoted; enabling the utility to distribute its purchases in a
series of large commitments to a predetermined group of suppliers, or to only
one; and, excluding potential competitors from bidding at a later date, even if
they might offer superior designs or lower prices, because the selection decision
will not be reopened at the time a firm order is placed.
3. Design competitions and development programs for new classes of equip-
ment are restricted to domestic manufacturers.-The utility will disclose to
selected suppliers its advanced plans and engineering requirements. Lead time
in research and development is thereby assured, perhaps as much as ten years.
Moreover, the public authority will frequently fund design competitions and
development programs which are restricted to domestic manufacturers. Par-
ticipating manufacturers are given extensive use of test facilities operated by
the public authority, as well as use of the system itself. CEGB operates the
U.K.'s biggest test facility in Leatherhead at its own cost, making results known
only to specified manufacturers. EDF has a similar facility outside Paris. In
Sweden, the development of high-voltage direct current techniques was conducted
by a Swedish manufacturer, ASEA, on the State Power Board's transmission
lines.
Compare these publicly financed programs with the U.S. system of research
and development on a risk-basis. General Electric, for example, developed, at its
own expense and with no purchase commitment of any sort involved, a 500 KY-
class power transformer in 1948 (no orders were placed for this equipment until
1962) and a 765 KV transformer in 1958 (no orders placed until 1966).
4. Utilities and domestic suppliers agree in advance on prices, quantities and
contract terms.-There is no doubt that this practice exists in the United King-
dom,3 and, General Electric believes, it exists also in France, Sweden, Switzer-
land and Germany. If so, the purpose is obvious: to forego competition in favor
of limitation to a single supplier or a closed association of manufacturers.
5. Outside solicitations or bids are deliberately discouraged or ignored.-U.S.
manufacturers do not receive notice of or a request to bid on a European public
authority requirement where domestic capability exists. Moreover, on the oc-
casions that General Electric Company has, on its own motion, sought to bid on
or initiate preliminary discussions, it has been ignored or discouraged from
pursuing the matter.
One critical point must be made here. General Electric cannot submit to the
Trade Information Committee a comprehensive list of specific instances when
it has unsuccessfully attempted to bid or be considered for an offering to a
European public authority. Such a list would, of course, be helpful to the Com-
mittee and to U.S. trade officials. The fact is, however, that the preparation of
a bid on heavy electrical equipment-a large steam turbine generator or a power
circuit breaker procurement, for example-costs many thousands of dollars, and
3Exhiblt III: G. B. Richardson~ "The Pricing of Heavy Electrical Equipment: Competi-
tion or Agreement?", Bulletin of the Oxford University Institute of Economics and ytatis-
tics (May, 1966), pp. 73-92; and Exhibit IV; Agreement between Central Electricity Gee-
erating Board and the Grid Switchgear Manufacturers, 1967. See also, Model Conditions
of Contract for TuCbo-Gener.ators and Associated Plant of CEGB/BEAMA for 1963, plus
Extended Form and Supplementary Clauses and Formulae Governing Contract Price Ad-
justments, and CEGB contract with English Electric Company, Ltd. General Electric has
not reproduced these documents because of bulk but will make them available on request.
PAGENO="0228"
3664
even preliminary discussions are expensive and time consuming. In view of past
experience and some recent confirmatory efforts, General Electric believes that
the time, expense, and frustration involved in a continuing course of bid submis-
sions would be wasted; the Company is convinced that it will simply not be
allowed to suply those markets. As specific substantiation of the U.S. industry's
inability to compete in European producer nation markets reference is made to
the following:
Confidential Exhibits A-J: Correspondence with Central Electricity Gen-
erating Board, 1965-1968;
Exhibit II: Affidavit regarding visit of General Electric official to Elec
tricite de France, 1967.
Transcript of Private Conference with General Electric Company, Office
of the Special Representative for Trade Negotiations, May 5, 1964.
Testimony of Robert L. Jeans, Westinghouse Electric International Com-
pany, before the Trade Information Committee, March 5, 1964.
Testimony of G. C. Hurlbert, Westinghouse Electric Corporation, before
the Trade Information Committee, March 5, 1964.
B. European pricing strategies in the U.S. market
1. Dual pricing-In selecting terminology for discussing the disparity be-
tween home market and export prices for European-made heavy electrical
equipment, the lower export pricing might be variously described as "incre-
mental," "dumped," or "predatory." For present purposes it is sufficient to use
the term "dual pricing" to record that there are two distince ex-factory prices
for essentially the same equipment and, further, that there is every indication
that the lower prices offered to time U.S. are the result of a deliberate course of
conduct made possible by the artificial conditions of world competition in this
equipment. If U.S. electrical equipment of the type herein discussed cannot com-
pete in Europe~n mirkets, then, obviously, the pricing options and market
strategies are predominantly with the Europeans who are permitted to sell here.
The disparity in price levels is composed of two elements: (1) remission of
European taxes on electrical equipment going into export; and (2) cost or below-
cost pricing on exports, which is made up for by profitable prices obtained in pro-
tected honle markets.
When quoted for U.S. delivery, European ex-factory prices range from 20%
to 50% below home market prices for equivalent equipment. About 20% to 35%
of this differential is attributable to absorption by the manufacturers of fixed
costs; and about 5% to 20% represents tax rebates and waivers and/or export
incentive payments. Normal profit, or indeed, any profit, is foregone in such
export pricing.
Such are the essentials in the establishment of a dual pricing system.
2. Price compa~risons.-Comparisons of European power transformers and
power circuit breakers, home market price versus U.S. market price, show Euro-
pean quotations in the U.S. to be at or near the lowest levels found in the world.
Annexed hereto are confidential exhibits pertaining to market price disparities
in power transformers made in the United Kingdom, France, Italy, and Sweden4
and power circuit breaks made in France and the United Kingdom.5
Inasmuch as these disparities cannot be explained by quantity discounts or
other legitimate pricing justifications a clear presumption of sales at less than
fair value is raised,° under either U.S. law or Article VI of GATT. What is more,
See Confidential Exhibits K-N.
~ See Confidential Exhibits 0, P.
6 See Confidential Exhibits Q.
PAGENO="0229"
3665
a course of regular conduct as opposed to sporadic incremental pricing in its
commonly understood sense, must also be presumed.
3. European m~anufaotwrers selectively price in the U.s. at or below cost.
Annexed hereto are exhibits pertaining to the full mainufacturing costs of
power transformers manufactured in France, Italy, Sweden, and the United
Kingdom.7
Protected home market sales in those countries are deliberately assigned higher
fixed overhead costs than export sales, regardless of the capacity level at which
a factory might operate-levels which today, incidentally, are significantly
below optimum capacity. As the exhibits show, British export quotations are at
or below incremental cost levels; Swedish export quotations are at levels that
cannot recover commercial and administrative expense; and Italian exports must
depend on export incentive payments to come close to or meet the break-even
level.
Detailed cost analysis of four large single-phase power transformers awarded
to English Electric Co., Ltd. in 1966 by TVA (Exhibit V above) indicate a pre-
tax loss to the manufacturer of $631,400, or failure to recover about 22% of real
costs on the delivered equipment. By reference back to Exhibit R, above, it can
be understood that such sacrificial export pricing is directly related to and
dependent on the high, profitable margins the same manufacturer receives on
sales to the CEGB in the protected British market.
There is no indication that European manufacturers of such equipment enjoy
cost advantages over U.S. manufacturers. Annexed is an analysis of compara-
tive costs for a particular type of transformer made in Italy, the United King-
dom and the U.S.8 This analysis, which uses index numbers (General Electric
delivered cost in the U.S. equal to 100) shows General Eelectric costs below
both Italian costs of 104.7 and British costs of 130.6. In short, General Electric
is cost competitive-in materials, direct labor costs, and overhead.
Finally, consider French power circuit breakers. The annexed exhibit ° com-
pares costs, on an index basis, for a typical rating which a French manu-
facturer sells in quantity in this country. Overall, on delivered costs into the
U.S. the French are at a slight disadvantage, 110.4 to General Electric's 100. Yet,
as shown by Exhibit V above, the French are selling this breaker in the U.S. at
an outright loss. Nevertheless the French manufacturer can sustain this loss
very well because the below-cost prices of three of these breakers in the U.S.
are counterbalanced by the margins achieved in a single high profit sale in
the protected French home market.
General Electric must conclude, then, that it can, if permitted, deliver power
transformers and power circuit breakers into European markets at lower cost
than domestic manufacturers can deliver equivalent equipment into their home
markets. And, what is more, the Company can do so without dual, or incre-
mental, pricing below prevailing U.S. market prices.
General Electric is confronted, then, by closed markets in the European pro-
ducers countries and the consequent working of a dual pricing strategy. That
strategy is, for the most part, pursued by companies which are among Europe's
largest aggregations of economic power. In their hands, it places American
heavy electrical manufacturers at a serious disadvantage right here in the
United States. It is a strategy almost impossible to defend against, for it pre-
cludes the disciplinary effects of fair and open competition in all the markets
of the producer countries of the free world.
~ Confidential Exhibits R-V.
8 Confidential Exhibit W.
9Confidential Exhibit X.
PAGENO="0230"
ExHIBIT I
EXTENT OF GOVERNMENT OWNERSHIP AND OPERATION OF ELECTRIC POWER SYSTEMS
Country
Percent of
National Government'
-
Other Government
Remarks
Generation Transmission Distribution
Generation
Transmission Distribution Percent of
system
system
United Kingdom 89 Yes Yes Yes 11 Yes Yes Yes Auto production equals 7 percent of total power
supply.
France 100 Yes Yes Yes Auto production equals 18 percent of total power
supply.
West Germany 6 Yes Yes 76 Yes Yes Yes Balance partly or wholly private ownership; auto
production equals 33 percent of total power supply.
Italy 80 Yes Yes Yes (2) Yes Yes Yes Auto production equals 19 percent of total power
supply.
Sweden 50 Yes Yes Yes Balance in private ownership; auto production equals
18 percent of total power supply.
Switzerland (3) Yes Yes Yes Balance in private ownership; auto production equals
14 percent of total power supply.
1 Includes regional agencies. Greater than 90 percent.
2 Greater than 15 percent.
PAGENO="0231"
3667
EXHIBIT II
STATE OF NEW YOBK,
Coui~ty of New York, ss:
Afilant, being duly sworn, deposes and says as follows:
On June 1, 1967, accompanied by Mr. I. M. Mourad, IGE, Paris, I visited the
subject customer located in Clamart, France just outside of Paris. The subject
customer is Electricite de France.
The purpose of this visit was to present a description of our Power Circuit
Breaker products for this customer's consideration and approval with the ob-
jective of becoming acceptable suppliers for their breaker requirements.
The customer was represented by:
Mr. Michaca, Directuer de Eludes de Recherche, E.D.F.
Mr. J. A. Duverny, Chief du Service Material, direction de l'Equipement
du Riseau de Transport
Mr. P. M. Jouclar, Service du Material Electrique, Direction des Etudes
and Recherche (also Assistant to Mr. Michaca)
Upon completion of my product descriptions, Mr. Michaca stated that there
was no problem in applying our equipment to the E.D.F. system, in almost every
voltage class, we have an excess of interrupting capability versus the breakers
they were now buying.
At this point, they asked about prices and I gave them prices for five ratings
of power circuit breakers. The prices given were essentially at the same price
levels quoted to domestic U.S.A. utilities for those ratings considering the prod-
uct modifications which apply.
To these prices we then added 17.6% tariff and then an additiopal 25% use
tax. Mr. J. A. Duverny then said that all the prices with the exception of the
115 KY were competitive and "in the same range as domestic prices". At 115
KY, they buy a 2500 MYA unit which has a rather low price because it can
be made as a single break device. I had no doubt that the prices given to E.D.F.,
except for the 115 KY, were lower than they now pay for this equipment supplied
by French manufacturers.
I then asked, "Can I be allowed to tender quotations for this breaker request?"
He replied, "At this time, I am not in the market for any breakers, however, if
I was, I could not buy from you because it is our policy to buy only domestic
products." He further stated that this has been their policy for about ten years
and he expected it would continue so with the Government that now exists in
France. I asked if this policy to buy only domestic products was an E.D.F. or
Government policy and he replied that since E.D.F. was a Goyernment owned
utility, the policy he was speaking about was influenced by the same body.
The meeting then concluded with a tour of their testing laboratory and a
luncheon.
Further deponent saith not.
Subscribed and sworn before this 25 day of April, 1968.
RIcHABD E. BEDNABEK,
IRENE E. MORCHAND,
Notary Public.
PAGENO="0232"
3668
Exhibit III
Bulletin of the Oxford University Institute
of Economics and Statistics
May 1966, pp. 73 ff.
THE PRICING OF HEAVY ELECTRICAL EQUIPMENT:
COMPETITION OR AGREE~1ENT?
By G. B. RICHARDSON -
1. Inlroduclior..
This paper deals with three types of heavy electrical equipment, the markets
for which have important features in common. The questions I try to answer are
these. Should the prices at which the equipment is sold be determined by
competitive tendering or by agreements? And, if agreements are judged appro-
priate, what form should they take, who should be party to them and to what
controls, if any, should they be subject?'
Although our concern is with the way in which prices ought to be set, it is
instructive to consider how they have in fact been set in the past. In the United
Kingdom, the prices of the equipment that concerns us have been regulated, for
the greater part of this century, by agreements between the manufacturers;
although these agreements broke down from time to time, we can regard their
operation as the normal state of affairs. In recent years, however, this tradition
has been broken After an adverse decision, in 1961, by the Restrictive Practices
Court, the agreements relating to one type of equipment -transformers-were
abandoned. The others have been referred to the Court by the Registrar of
Restrictive Trading Agreements but the hearings have been held up pending
discussions between the manufacturers and their chief customer-the national-
ised electricity authorities.
It is difficult to determine, with confidence, the extent to which the tradition
of agreed prices has held sway in countries other than the United Kingdom.
Restrictive agreements have for long been illegal in the United States, but the
Philadelphia Anti-Trust Cases of 1960 produced evidence of elaborate arrange-
ments to fix prices and share markets that were in effect, covertly, for at least one
period in the recent history of the electrical machinery industry. Accounts of
this famous `conspiracy', and of other anti-trust cases involving the industry,2
leave one with the impression that violations, despite the shocked indignation
which they provoke, have been by no means infrequent since the turn of the
century. This is not to deny that price competition has been severe at some times,
as during the so-called `white sales' of 1955;~ collusion, always illegal appears to
have been intermittent and often ineffective. Whether the situation is better
described as price competition tempered by collusion, or as collusion undermined
by rivalries and the enforcement of the laws, I cannot judge. In Continental
1 This article is an expanded version of a paper which I submitted to the Economic Develop-
ment Committee for the Electrical Engineering Industry. I am a member of this committee
and have benefitted from its discussions. My education has also been advanced through talks
with representatives of the industry, but neither the EDC nor the industry bears any responsi-
biiity for the views I express.
`For an account of these see Corwin D. Edwards, Big Business and the Policy of Competition,
1956, pp. 137-41 and 163-64.
When price cutting is believed to have got out of hand it is termed `white sale'. In 1955
orders for equipment were being accepted at prices up to 50 per cent below normal levels.
PAGENO="0233"
3669
Europe price agreements were generally legal, and often officially approved, until
after the Second \Vorld War, hut there, as in Britain, public opinion and the
statute books have recently undergone much change. Whether this has brought
to an end the practice of agreeing prices, however, is another matter and one on
which an outsider cannot easily form an opinion.
It is safe to conclude, even on this most cursory review of past experience,
that the circumstances of the heavy electrical industry must be such as put firms
under pressures towards price agreements, pressures strong enough to overcome
the reluctance of managers both to accept restrictions on their commercial
freedom and (in the United States) to run the risk of criminal prosecution. One
of our tasks must `be to enquire how these pressures are generated. We should
also note, at this point, the great difficulty in arguing either for or against price
competition merely by reference to the way in which it has in fact worked. Such
an appraisal of price competition would need to examine its effects when sustained
over a long period without the degree of mitigation that agreements, of varying
legality and effectiveness, have always exercised in the past. In this respect the
protagonists as well as the opponents of competitive pricing are in the same boat:
they must endeavour to predict; with the help of theory and limited experience,
what would happen in a hypothetical situation.
The pricing of heavy electrical equipment, in this country, has already
received the attention of the Monopolies Commission, the Restrictive Practices
Court and the Select Committee on Nationalised Industries.
The Monopolies Commission took the view that prices, in the markets we
shall be considering, ought to be determined by competitive tendering.' It saw
no merit whatever in agreements or arrangements between the manufacturers,
who were urged `to refrain from any kind of collaboration in matters of price and
tendering'. Nor were they prepared to give any support to the manufacturers'
suggestion that agreements might be operated with safeguards designed to
ensure that prices and profits were reasonable; free competition, they insisted,
was the proper regulator for these markets. Price notification agreements, in
so far as they would apply to the home market, were also condemned, on the
ground that understandings on prices might follow them.
The Restrictive Practices Court was called upon to declare whether a parti-
cular price agreement, operated by the transformer manufacturers at the time of
the hearing, was contrary to the public interest; it did not have to give an opinion
on the wider issue of the appropriateness of competitive tendering for all three
types of equipment. Nevertheless, the judgment of the Court may be regarded
as in line with the views of the Commission,2
The Select Committee, reporting six years later than the Commission, does
not show the same enthusiasm for competitive tendering.3
While maintaining that `competition is still realistic between firms making
smaller equipment', it clearly h~s doubts as to its appropriateness for markets in
which `both the Board and the (nanufacturers of larger equipment at higher
`Report on the Supply and Exports of Electrical and Allied Machinery and Plant, 1957.
2 In re Associated Transformer Manufacturers' Agreement, LR, 2 RP, 295.
Report from the Select Committee on Nationalised Industries; the Electricity Supply
industry, Vol. 1 Report and Proceedings. Chapter 16.
PAGENO="0234"
3670
voltages are becoming more and more prisoners to size'. It recommended that an
independent arbitrator, acceptable to both the manufacturers and the Central
Electricity Generating Board, be asked to inquire into the arrangements for
placing contracts and fixing prices.
It is not my purpose to review the arguments and the conclusions of the
Commission, the Court and the Select Committee, but the reader will find in their
reports a wealth of useful background material for which space could not be found
in this article. My excuse for setting out, by myself, on this well-trodden ground
is twofold. First, I wish to focus more narrowly on the relevant economic analysis
than did these reports. Secondly, I find myself in disagreement with the con-
clusions of the Monopolies Commission and with part of the Judgement of the
Court. One hesitates to question the findings of these bodies, which, quite rightly,
have great authority, but some comfort may perhaps be found in the fact that
these are matters on which informed opinion has, in the past, suffered a good deal
of fluctuation.
I shall be dealing with three quite specific types of electrical equipment, these
being turbo-alternators with ratings of 30 megawatts or above, Grid switchgear
and Transmission and Generator transformers all for 132 kilovolts or above.1 I
shall refer to these, for brevity, simply as `turbines', `switchgear' and `trans-
formers', or, collectively as `heavy electrical equipment', but the readers will have
to bear in mind that we are dealing with restricted types of equipment under these
heads. (Roughly speaking, we are concerned only with the largest or `heaviest'
categories of each of the three kinds of equipment). The justification for grouping
them for discussion is the fact that they are sold under similar conditions.
2. The Structure of the Markets.
Let us begin by listing the common features of the three markets that are
relevant to pricing policy.
(i) The first of these is the predominance, in the home trade, of the nationalised
Electricity Supply Authorities. Turbines, switchgear and the larger transformers
are bought, in England, only by the Central Electricity Board, and, in Scotland
~ind Northern Ireland, by corresponding bodies. On the manufacturing side, we
find three firms in turbines, four in switchgear, and about a dozen in trans-
formers.2
`Electricity is generated by boiling water to produce steam, which, when applied to a
turbine, strikes metal blades fixed to wheels, thus causing the wheels and connecting ahaft to
move at a high speed. This mechanical energy is then converted into electricity by a generator.
The various bits of equipment other than the boiler necessary to do these things are referred to
as a `turbo-alternator set' and are usually ordered together. It is efficient to distribute electri-
city at a voltage higher than that at which it is generated and much higher than that at which
it is ultimately used by consumers. The equipment which steps up the voltage when electrical
energy leaves a generating station, or lowers it as the current passes to the consumer, is a trans-
former. Switchgear is used at the points where electricity is stepped up to voltages suitable forthe
main transmission lines and where it is stepped down. Its functions are to connect or disconnect
a line as required or to act as a safety device cutting off a current when there has been a fault.
Thus it acts like domestic switches or fuses, though the Hgh voltages with which it deals
require it to be much more complicated.
`The turbine makers are Associated Electrical Industries, the English Electric Company.
and C. A. Parsons. Switchgear is made by the first two of these companies, by the General Electric
Company and by Reyrolle. Of the dozen or so firms making larger transformeri~ none has a
share of the total markets as large as twenty per cent.
PAGENO="0235"
3671
(ii) Of key significance for our analysis is the fact that the total home demand
for each category of equipment is in effect totally inelastic with respect to price.
This is certainly the case in the short run, as it is unlikely that the electricity
authorities would alter their construction programmes in response to fluctuations
in the price of this equipment. In the longer run, the price of the equipment, by
influencing the cost of these programmes, might affect their scale, but the circum-
stance will have no bearing on the price that a manufacturer quotes for a
particular order at a particular time. Although the total demand for each type of
equipment is inelastic, however, the demand for that offered by any single seller
will be highly sensitive to the level of his price compared to those of rivals. This
very high cross-elasticity is the result of the fact that each item of equipment is
produced by the different manufacturers to the same specifications, as laid down
by the buyer.
(iii) Of related significance is the size of individual orders. Either because of
the scale of particular items of equipment (as with turbines) or because of the
inclusion of several items in one order (as with transformers), success or failure
in obtaining a particular contract nay have a very large effect on the total
business obtained by a firm within a year. In the case of turbines, there are only
about two orders, on average, per year, worth (in 1965) some £20 million each. A
single order for transformers may represent a quarter of a firm's annual turnover
in this equipment. The business in switchgear is in effect allocated in bulk by the
Generating Board, rather than split up and put out to tender; but it is safe to
say that were competitive tendering to be introduced, the size of an individual
order could be very large.
(iv) Excess capacity, from time to time, is inevitable in this industry~ There
are several reasons for this. It is obvious, first, that if productive capacity is to be
sufficient to meet the electricity authorities' demands when these are at their
peak, then it will necessarily exceed them at other times. The demand for each
type of equipment is on a steadily rising trend, but subject to fluctuation. The
`stop-go' policies, so much discussed in recent years, have a clear enough impact
on this industry, in that they give rise to sudden modifications in the electricity
investment programme. A greater stahilisation of public investment would
permit a better adjustment of capacity to demand, though imbalances would
never be wholly prevented. Export orders may help to fill the gap left by the
falling off of home demand for a particular category of equipment, but they
cannot be depended upon to become available in sufficient quantity at remuner-
ative prices.
Excess capacity may also arise through technical advance. In the case of
turbines, which form the heart of a generating plant, recent improvements have
been very striking. Increases in the size of the turbine and devices that enable it
to deal with higher steam temperatures and pressures have markedly reduced
cost per kilowatt. The first 30 megawatts set was installed in 1930; by 1956 a
100-MW set had been commissioned and orders for 120-MW, 200-MW and
275-MW sets had been placed. The first 500-MW set was ordered in 1960. The
cost per megawatt of turbine plant over these thirty years fell by more than half.
(The rate of progress has been so rapid, in fact, that firms find themselves design-
PAGENO="0236"
3672
ing plant with higher ratings before they have had operational experience of plant
with lower ratings.) The fall in turbine cost per megawatt is associated with a
reduction in the real resources required; excess capacity, in terms of skilled men as
wcll as equipment, can be prevented only by a sufficiently great increase in the
volume of orders.
The fact that the investment plans of the independent manufacturers are
not co-ordinated can also result in excess capacity. This has happened, notably,
in transformer production, where the number of firms concerned is relatively
large. Given fairly large numbers, there is nothing to ensure that each firm, in
the hope of realising scale economies, does not count on enlarging its share of the
market, with the inevitable result that total capacity becomes excessive. This
tendency, I have argued elsewhere' is endemic in precisely those markets with large
numbers of producers acting independently that often feature as the textbook ideal.
(v) We have already noted, in the case of turbines, that the industry's product
is subject to continuous change. The same may be said cf switchgear and trans
formers, which have to be adapted to deal with higher voltages. As a result, the
firms concerned deploy large resources in research, development and design. There
is some inter-firm co-operation in this field, particularly in the development of
certain kinds of switchgear, but the Generating Board took the view that there
ought to be more of it.~ This is an important matter lying, for the most part, outside
the scope of this article; its relevance to pricing will be discussed later.
(vi) Finally, we must bear in mind the export trade, which represents a signifi-
cant, but diminishing, proportion of the total sales of the equipment with which
we are concerned. In 1965 exports of heavyelectrical equipment represented about
16.5 per cent of the value of home deliveries, which were some £100 million in
value. In 1961, the value of exports was almost one-third of home deliveries. I am
concerned in this paper with the pricing of equipment sold at home to the elec-
tricity authorities, but it will be necessary to consider whether this has any
hearing on the exports that firms are able to make.
3. The Criteria of an Efficient System of Pricing.
How are we to assess the relative merits of the alternative ways in which the
prices of heavy electrical equipment may be determined? Let me now endeavour
to set out, very briefly, the criteria that I shall apply.
First, and most obviously, the procedure adopted should be such as sets Pl~~
at levels that are appropriate relative to demand and cost conditions. Appropriate-
ness, in this sense, has two aspects. It would be generally agreed the rate of profit
in this line of production, taking one year with another, should neither exceed nor
fall short of the rate in other industries subject to an equivalent degree of risk.
Considerations of equity might be regarded as sufficient justification of this equality,
hut the economist sees it as a condition for the proper allocation of resources in
diffierent employments. We have to consider, that is to say, whether the prices set
are likely to cause the right amount of productive capacity to be installed and to
ensure that the right amount of output is being produced from this capacity.
`Informalion and Investment, Oxford University Press, 1960.
Report from the Select Committee, pp. 167-8.
PAGENO="0237"
3673
The indirect effects of alternative pricing systems must also be taken into
account. Would they permit the more efficient firms to grow at the expense of their
higher. cost rivals? Would they put such pressure on producers as would induce
them to exploit all available economies of scale? Would they be consistent with
whatever forms of co-operation between firms in matters other than price, are
held to be desirable? \Vould they be likely to facilitate, or to hamper, the forward
planning of production? How, if at all, would they affect the ability and willingness
of firms to export? These are some of the ways in which alternative methods of
pricing might influence the efficiency and structure of the industries that adopted
them.
The simplest solution to the problem of determing prices is that recommended
by the Monopolies Commission and, by implication, in the Judgment of the Restric-
tive PracticesCourt. It consists in proscribing any inter-firm agreement or arrange-
ment and leaving prices to be determined by free competition, each producer setting
his own price in independence of his rivals. The genuine merits of this solution are
readily apparent. The operation of price agreements, and their public control,
requires an administrative machinery which, in terms of the services of lawyers,
accountants, economists and the like, represents a genuine social cost. Price
agreements, if not subject to public control, may be used to further the interests of
those who make them, to the disadvantage of the community as a whole; but
public control may itself be abused, either to protect vested interests or to court
political popularity. By relying on free price competition, we can avoid these costs
and difficulties. This is a substantial advantage to which I give full weight. I shall
argue, nevertheless, that price competition is not appropriate to the special con-
ditions of the markets with which we are concerned.
4. Transfori~sers.
(i) Alternative Effects of Abrograting Agree~senis.
Let us first consider transformers. First, we have to decide whether the pro-
scription of agreements would be likely to lead firms to compete actively in terms of
price. It will be recalled that the agreement between the manufacturers of trans-
formers was held by the Restrictive Practices Court, in 1961, to be contrary to the
public interest. The Report from the Select Committee, however, quotes the
Generating Board to the effect that `while the manufacturers have observed the
letter of this decision, they have flouted its spirit by adopting a system of price
leadership'. Acting under this conviction the Board ordered two large transformers
from Canada at prices appreciably below these ruling in this country. The manu-
facturers objected strongly to this decision; they maintained that the transformer
market in Canada was very depressed and saw the Boards' action as an attempt to
bring British. prices down to similar levels. At the same time, they claimed that the
system of price notification that finns had adopted was not equivalent to price
agreement, in that it permitted firms to quote low prices if they believed themselves
to be competitive.
No fully adequate information is available to me about the present level of
prices and profits in transformer production or about the extent of the changes that
have taken place. since abrogation of the agreement. It is possible, nevertheless, to
PAGENO="0238"
3674
sketch out the general picture. The prices of the smaller transformers have fallen
markedly and continue to fall; all or almost all the manufacturers appear to sell
these transformers at a loss.1 The prices of the large transformers-those which~
directly concern us-held up better, at least in the years immediately following
abrogation.
These developments are very much what one would expect. In the first place,
there is excess capacity in transformer production. A reliable measure of a firm's
capacity is difficult to make, chiefly because the maximum volume of output that
can be put through the works depends on the `product-mix', this being the propor-
tions of the total output formed by different sizes of transformers. Not all firms,
moreover, make estimates of the capacity they have available. (All the members
of the `Power Transformer Conference' make returns on capacity but not all trans-
former manufacturers are members). Despite these difficulties it seems safe to say
that the demands of the electricity authorities, together with any likely export
demand, will leave a substantial margin of capacity unemployed.
In these circumstances, firms are continuously subject to the risk of getting
little or no work. The magnitude of this risk varies with the number of firms
making each type of transformer, being great for those making the smallest types
and less for those making the larger types with which we are primarily concerned.
An excess of capacity over demand of even one per cent would make it possible,
in principle, for some of the smallest firms making the smaller transformers to
be left without work. A 10 percent excess would make it possible for even large
firms to have no orders. Given the electricity supply authorities' system of
tendering-which is such that a single order can make a great difference to a
finn's annual tutnover-it is clear that each manufacturer is under strong~
pressure to quote a price low enough to obtain some business. It is also clear
that firms have an incentive to resist this pressure, because they realise that the
total business available to the industry as a whole will not be increased by price
reductions.
What we have, therefore, is a familiar oligopoly situation where the outcome
depends on the relative strength of two opposing considerations. The larger the
number of fIrms, the greater is the chance that one of them may he left without
work; the more likely therefore is that prices will be driven down by the com-
petitive struggle, a limit being set, in the last resort, about the level of variable
costs. In the case of the smaller transformers, this is what has happened. With
the larger transformers, which are made by fewer firms, prices are more likely
to be sustained, if only precariously. Although the business available is insuffi~
dent to fill all ihe works, each producer may expect to get some of it. A sense of
common interest may be sufficient to prevent price-cutting, especially if firms
keep one another informed as to the terms on which contracts with them are
actually placed.
In appraising the effects of proscribing agreements, therefore, it is important
to distinguish between two situations, the first in which excess capacity will
1 These smaller or `distribution' transformers are made by about fifty firms and sold to
Area Electricity Boards. The characteristics of their market create special problems distinct
from those associated with the pricing of large transformers and it seemed appropriate to
exclude them from discussion here.
B
PAGENO="0239"
3675
result in competitive price-cutting, the second in which it may not. Very broadly,
these alternative outcomes can be associated in this case with the markets for
the smaller and for the larger transformers respectively, though it would be
misleading to draw a sharp line. In the case of the so-called distribution
transformers, which are sold by some fifty firms to a dozen Area Electricity
Boards, conditions bear some resemblance to the text-book model of perfect
competition, and prices have clearly fallen in response to the excess of capacity
over demand. In the cas~ of the larger transformers, sold to the Generating
Board by a smaller number of firms, there has been a more obvious reluctance
to `spoil the market', but, given excess capacity and the practice of tendering for
very large orders, more active price competition can readily develop.
(ii) Prices Responsive to Excess Capacity.
Let us take first the situation in which the abrogation of a price agreement
does produce active competition in tendering. On the face of it, this may seem
precisely what is required; the more efficient firms will be able to undercut their
high cost rivals and the general level of profits will be kept low. Given excess
capacity, it will be conceded, prices will fall to uneconomic levels, but, in doing
so, they will help to bring about the contraction required and thus restore
profits to a normal level. This, at any rate, is what the more elementary text
book models would lead us to expect; a more careful examination of the situation
points to conclusions less simple and less satisfactory.
In the first place, excess capacity is likely to be chronic. Each firm may see
its salvation in expansion, which will enable it to reap more of the economies of
scale. The fact that the demand for transformers is on a rising trend may give
further countenance to this policy, with the result that the industry's total
capacity may become even more excessive. Lest the reader consider this
situation too pervei~se, let him bear in mind that the excess capacity with which
the industry is at present afflicted, and which so far has shown no tendency to
disappear, did in fact develop over a period of steadily rising demand. Never-
theless, it is reasonable to suppose that firms will not for ever persist in such
unprofitable courses, that some will leave the industry and others cease to expand
with the consequence that capacity will come to equal, or even fall short of
demand. What chance is there that these developments would lead, in the long
run, to a steady growth of capacity in balance with demand?
To my mind, very little. Losses are indeed likely to check investment and
thus bring capacity, for a time, into rough equality with demand; but, given the
continuing presence of a large number of competing firms, there would seem to be
every reason to expect further bouts of excessive investment. EconomistS with
faith in some kind of tendency to equilibrium may envisage a fluctuating balance
between demand and capacity, firms gaining on the swings of excess demand
what they lost on the roundabouts of excess capacity. But, in the special
circumstances of this market, these conditions need not result in normal profits.
Firms would certainly lose, through price competition, in times of slack, but it
seems to mc unlikely that they would be able to gain very high profits at other
times. In the first place, supply conditions are likely to be fairly elastic, firms
being able to take on extra work without much rise in marginal costs. But even
PAGENO="0240"
3676
although there were bottlenecks, it is difficult to envisage the Generating Board
or even the Area Boards deliberately bidding up prices against themselves. No
one has yet seen a one-man auction. Normal profits would be compatible with
the conditions we are postulating only if excess capacity could be avoided at all
times. This is unlikely to be assured and it is undesirable that it should be; the
public interest requires that the investment programmes of the electricity
authorities are not held up through bottlenecks in the capacity to supply equip-
ment. If peak requirements are to be met, excess capacity must develop at
normal times and must be tolerable to the industry.
There is a further circumstance that would make active price competition
often incompatible with normal profits even in the absence of unused capacity.
Part of the output of the larger transformers is exported and at prices below
those ruling at home. It seems to be very generally the case that heavy electrical
equipment is sold abroad by all the main manufacturing countries, at prices that
approximate more to marginal than to full unit costs of production. The gap
between home and export prices is of course evidence that price competition
within the home markets of the manufacturing counties is somewhat attenuated.
If producers were to fight for domestic contracts in the same way as they fight
for foreign contracts, home prices would move down towards the export levels
and the profitability of the total output would fail. Many see the differential
between home and export prices as proof of our fallen state and would welcome
its erosion under the stress of more active competition. But, as far as British
manufacturers are concerned, the low level of the export prices of these capital
goods is simply a fact of life which neither our industry nor our government has
by itself the power to alter. Were our export quotations to move up to the level
of home prices, we should fail to export; if our home prices were to move down to
the level of export prices, the total business would not be remunerative. This is a
conclusion that those most eager to promote price competition in the home
market are rarely seen to draw; -
Let us now return to the main course of our argument. Given fairly numerous
independent manufacturers, faced with a totally inelastic home demand and in
active price competition for orders, there will be chronic tendency to excess
capacity and low returns. This tendency is unlikely, in the nature of things, to
continue indefinitely, but an end to it could be brought, it seems to me, only as a
result of change in the structure of the market. The logic of the situation is
likely, sooner or later, to lead producers to concentrate production, in the hope
that this will both limit the extent of excess capacity and reduce the likelihood
that excess capacity will induce firms to cut prices. There is no telling how long
this change would take to come about and no assurance that, once it had come
about, it wOuld not subsequently be reversed.'
`Of key importance in this connection is the magnitude of scale economies in the production
of transformers. If these economies are insignificant then concentration within the industry
might prove short lived; small firms would be attracted by the prospects of entering the
business in the hope of prospering under the umbrella of the larger producers. Given, that is to
say, the maintainence of relatively stable prices by the established firms, even in the face of
some excess capacity, there would be a living to be made by the outsider willing to.charge a
slightly lower price in order to get a full load on this works. Assuming free entry therefore, the
viability of a regime of concentrated production and stable prices would depend on the existence
of significant scale economies.
PAGENO="0241"
3677
(iii) Prices Unresponsive to Excess Capacity.
We have now, in effect, moved on to the second of the alternative situations
that we proposed to analyse. We have been assuming that, in the absence of a
price agreement, active competition would cause prices to be flexible and to fall
in response to excess capacity. N~w we assume that the producers, chiefly
because they are less numerous, succeed in maintaining stable prices in the face
of a changing balance between demand and capacity. This of course is the
situation in the generality of manufacturing industry. When the demand for
cars suffers temporary decline, their prices do not fall to the level of variable
costs; the total burden of adjustment is usually met by a fall in output. For
adjustment to take this form, there is no need for manufacturers to make an
* agreement; each of them takes it for granted that price 1-eductions would without
delay be noted and matched by competitors with the result (given the prevailing
* elasticity of demand for cars) that all would stand to lose. The circumstances~
of the markets for heavy electrical equipment, however, are vastly different.
The size of individual orders relative to a firm's turnover puts management
under very strong pressure to cut prices in order to be sure of getting work.
Where the largest and most advanced types of equipment are concerned, to miss
an order does not only produce unemployment of men and machines; it may also
cause firms to fall out of the race in technical development. In order to be able
to tender for the most advanced type of equipment, firms require experience to
draw upon and this experience cannot be acquired if they fail to get orders. The
willingness of firms to cut prices at the risk of `spoiling the market' would also
he in.fluenced by the fact that competitive prices, instead of being `posted' as
with cars, would be quoted in closed bids. Firms would not normally know what
prices their rivals were quoting and might be tempted to reduce their quotations
substantially in order to make sure that they were not undercut. It is of course
open to firms to exchange information about prices at which contracts have
actually been placed, so that it would be possible for them to know, after the
event, whether rivals were in fact reducing their bids below some normal level.
This arrangement might go some way in inhibiting firms, eager to increase their
share of a fixed market, from starting a price war.
These considerations suggest that price stability, based on the wish not to
spoil the market, is possible b~it by no means assured in the circumstances we are
considering. Let us now ask whether it would be in the public interest.
If prices can be maintained, in the face of temporary falls in demand, then
producers certainly enjoy a more stable prospect than they would have other-
wise and will he more willing to create facilities large enough to meet their
customer's peak requirements ip the knowledge that the associated excess
capacity, in normal times, will not bring them heavy losses. Only very grudging
recognition, if any, is usually given, in this context, to the benefits that society
as a whole can derive from a more predictable business environment. If the
context is economic planning, and the need for a more stable rate of investment,
then most people are prepared to see virtue in arrangements that enable firms
better to insulate their expansion plans from short-run fluctuations in the balance
between demand and capacity. ~ut there is a strange reluctance to perceive
95-159 0 - 68 - pt. 8 - 16
PAGENO="0242"
3678
that arrangements or conventions leading to short-run price stability fulfil just
this shock-absorbing function.
But there is another side to this matter. Can one reasonably assume that
price competition between firms, in these circumstances, will be suspended only
in conditions of excess capacity? Is it not possible for mutual tolerance to be so
developed that firms will refrain from use of the price weapon to compete for
larger market shares even when demand rises above capacity? The force of
rivalry might or might not be strong enough to ensure that abnormally high
profits were rapidly removed by competition. In the case of large transformers,
where there are a dozen producers, it may seem unlikely that a struggle for
market shares could for long be in abeyance; but where there are only three or
four companies-as with turbines and switchgear-mutual accommodation is less
unlikely. Abnormally high profits might, in the long run, induce entry by new
suppliers, but entry in these fields is not sufficiently easy for this to be an
adequate discipline. My own view is that neither theory nor experience enables
us to say, with certainty, whether the producers of heavy electrical equipment
would or would not, in the absence of agreements between them, have the power
consistently to maintain prices such as yielded abnormally high profits. What one
can say is that the proscription of agreements cannot be relied upon always to
give either the electricity authorities or the public at large the assurance of
reasonable prices.
Here then we have a dilemma that those who advocate merely the abolition
of agreements have to face. Either the abandonment of the agreements results
in active price competition and flexibility of prices in response to the changing
balance of demand and capacity, or it does not do so. In the former eventuality,
prices are likely to be chronically depressed, thus leading to an undesirable
shrinkage of capacity or to a movement towards further concentration. In the
latter case, the purchasers and the public lack sufficient assurance that profits
will not be unduly high. These are the considerations that lead me to conclude
that the mere abolition of inter-firm agreements, whether or not it results in
prices flexible in response to supply and demand, does not ensure suitable
regulation of the markets for transformers. But before examining the available
alternatives, let us turn to consider the working, in the absence of price agree-
ments, of the markets for turbines and switchgear.
5. Turbines.
(i) Special features of the market.
Those features of the transformer market that made price competition
unsuitable are to be found also in the market for turbines and in a much more
marked degree.'
The manufacture of turbines has of necessity to be on a very large scale. Very
large investments are required in terms of research, design an~ training as well as
1At the time of writing, there were three producers of turbines, each with ~ts own design.
But there has been talk of a desire, on behalf of the Generating Board, to have only two designs.
This desire could achieve fulfilment only through structural change in the industry, but I lack
the information required to discuss this matter. Whatever changes might be promoted seem
likely to weaken the case for price competition yet further.
PAGENO="0243"
3679
fixed equipment. The rate of technical advance in the industry has, as remarked
earlier, been particularly rapid and the firms operate continuously at the frontiers
of new development. Overheads (taken to include the teams of designers and
other skilled staff) are high relative to turnover, and are, in effect, completely
specific to manufacture of turbines. The firms concerned do all the research
and development relating to the equipment they produce and bear the costs of
rectifying it when it fails to work.
Of central significance, for our purposes, is the magnitude of individual
contracts in this industry, the value of which, at f20 mill. or more, exceeds the
average annual turnover in turbo-alternators of any one of the firms.' The size of
order is to be explained, in this case, not in terms of the buyer's preference for
inviting firms to tender for a bunch of different items, but by the remarkably
rapid increase in the scale on which it proves possible and economical to build
single turbo-alternator sets. This development, moreover, is not yet complete and
we may envisage even larger sets, and therefore larger,' and to that extent fewer,
orders in the future.
A nice balance between demand and capacity is no more possible to maintain
in this market than in the market for transformers. The electricity authorities
cannot avoid some fluctuation in their requirements, nor can the producers hope
to expand their total capacity at a continuously appropriate rate. In addition,
excess capacity is likely to develop, in the absence of a strong upward movement
in demand, simply because rapid technical advance has made it possible to
generate the same amount of electricity, from larger sets, with reduced inputs of
capital and labour in turbine construction.
These special circumstances, taken in combination, are very unfavourable to
effective regulation by price competition. Failure to obtain a contract will
certainly burden a firm with heavy financial losses and may indeed threaten its
survival as a producer of turbines. Given that an interval of four years may
elapse between the ordering and final commissioning of a turbo-alternator set,
it is apparent that management will be obliged to attend, not to the current load
on the works, but to the chances of getting work in the future. Each firm will be
well aware of the disastrous effect on profits of competition, in terths of price,
for a share in the total business; at the same time, it cannot fail to realise that
failure to obtain an order may put it out of the race.
The buyer also will be faced with its own dilemma. Presumably, according
to the advocates of regulation by price competition, the Central Electricity
Generating Board will award a contract to the firm that makes the lowest bid,
allowing for differences in performance between rival equipments. But is it
really conceivable that it could thus ignore the effects of its actions on the
structure of the industry? It is perfectly possible for the distribution of its
orders to cause a firm to be starved of technical experience or to be obliged to
give up production for good. To place contracts blindly, in these exceptional
circumstances, merely according to the lowest bid, would be to credit market
forces with quite magical authority.
I Twelve years ago, orders rarely exceeded £2 millions in value, it is worth observing that
circumstances have therefore changed in this respect since the Monopolies Commission studied
the industry-changed moreover in a way less favourable to the suitability of price competition.
PAGENO="0244"
3680
I find it very difficult to predict what the effects of abrogating the price
agreement between the turbine makers might be. It is worth while, as with
transformers, to distinguish between two possible outcomes, the one in which
prices fall in response to excess capacity and the other in which they do not.
(ii) Alternative effects of ending an agreement
Prices could fall sharply, given the threat of some excess capacity, if the
firms strove, by endeavouring to under-cut their rivals, to get work. The export
trade, it should be noticed, could not be called upon to redress the balance
caused by a falling off of demand at home, for the prices at which it is conducted
are below full cost. Inevitably, if this were to happen, firms would suffer losses;
investment would be checked and, if the situation Were sufficiently grave, the
currently available productive facilities might be contracted with an associated
dispersal of design teams and other specially trained staff. Expenditure on
research and development seems to me one of the forms of investment that would
suffer a check or an absolute reduction, although the Restrictive Practices Court
denied, in their judgment on the transformer case, that this kind of result would
be likely to happen. The Court apparently took the view that, if conditions were
to become more competitive, firms would be obliged to spend more rather than
less on research. The superficial plausibility of this argument rests on an ambigu-
ity in the term `competitive'. The market for turbines, even with agreed prices,
is already highly competitive, in that firms have to strive hard, with the help of
sustained investment in res~arch arid development, to stay in the technological
race. Were the price agreement to be given up, the market would not become
more competitive in this sense; the chief effect would be for receipts to fluctuate
more widely (given periods of excess capacity) at a lower level. The decision as
to how much to invest in research and development (never easy) will rationally
depend upon the magnitude of the expected yield. If the general profitability
of turbine business is to fall, then the yield from investment in research, aimed at
securing for the firm a larger share of this business, will fall likewise. The
Restrictive Trade Practices Court, in arguing as they did, would seem to believe
that a man could be induced to increase his stake in a lottery provided only the
value of the prizes were lowered.
It is theoretically conceivable that the check to investment, occasioned by
poor returns, could ultimately so reduce the volume of capacity relative to
demand as to restore profitability. But, for reasons given in the discussion of
transformers, this result, even if it could be assured, would not be in the public
interest.
Let us now assume, alternatively, that the producers would not make com-
petitive price reductions when capacity came to exceed demand. Their resistance
to the temptation to use the price weapon might find strength merely in a keen
sense of common interest, but might be further re-infoi~~ed by the belief that the
buyer would in any case choose to allocate business tn s~cli a way as ensured the
survival of all three firms. In this case the disturbances ~ up by price instability
would be avoided, but it is still necessary to ask, as with transformers, whether
the public interest would he sufficiently safe-guarded. The fact that we have here
PAGENO="0245"
3681
only three producers, rather than the dozen found in transformer production,
strengthens the chances that mutual accommodation might serve not merely to
stop prices falling to an unduly low level but to keep them permanently higher
than they should be. We need not take a view as to whether firms would in fact
choose to exercise any joint monopoly power; the point to be noted is that there
would be no automatic competitive force sufficiently strong to ensure that they
did not.
These considerations seem to me to suggest that competition would fail to be
an efficient regulator of prices in this market irrespective of the alternative
assumptions one may prefer to make as to the outcome of abandoning the prac-
tice of agreement.
6. Swiichgear.
The market I or switchgear differs little, in basic structure, from that for
turbines, but it is marked by a more developed system of co-operation between
the four producers and between them and the Central Electricity Generating
Board.
Let us begin by noting that the cost of supplying electricity must depend upon
the rapidity with which potential gains from improved technology can be realised
through their embodiment in equipment actually in use. There are in fact
substantial gains to be had in particular from increasing the power load with
which a transmission system can deal, and the rate at which this can take place
depends on the time taken to get the more advanced types of switchgear into
service. This circumstance creates in itself the need for close co-ordination
between the investment plans of the Generating Board and its suppliers.1
Under the current arrangements, the plans of the two sides are cO-ordinated
at several stages. A forecast of the Board's switchgear requirements is made
known about a decade in advance, thus enabling the manufacturers to take
certain steps--such as acquiring factory space-that are an essential preliminary
to future production plans. The second and most important stage is reached
when the Board makes a bulk allocation of work between the manufacturers
and thereby enables them to make their own production plans as well as to
inform their own suppliers (the makers of porcelain and bushing) of their pro-
jected needs. The point to note here is that the arrangement permits firms to go
ahead with their programmes without having to wait for the Board's require-
ments to be articulated in detail. Binding contracts are entered into only later
and on the basis of prices listed or; a schedule agreed between the manufacturers.
I find it hard to conceive that this procedure, or any other procedure equally
able to save time, would be fully compatible with competitive price tendering.
lithe allocation of work were to be determined by competing bids, then the
Board would have to be in a position to specify its needs in appropriate detail.
The producers would then take longer to learn of the amount of work for which
they had to prepare, with a resultant delay in dates of commissioning. It may be
1 The reader will recall that Scotland and Northern Ireland have their own separate electri-
city generating authorities. What is said, for brevity, about the Central Electricity Generating
Board should be taken as applying to these bodies also.
PAGENO="0246"
3682
iflL 1'1(it~1r'~I., U1~ flk.AVY ~LJ~.Ci1UCAL EQUiPMENT
asked why the same degree of expedition could not be achieved by the Board's
making its plans earlier, but, were this to be done, ~hesc plans would be based on
less information about future demand and on a less advanced technology. Also
relevant is the fact that detailed specifications are at present decided upon, not
by the Board alone, but by the Board and the appropriate manufacturer after
the bulk allocation of work.
It is worth noting that the systeni of bulk allocation enables the Board, if it
chooses, to distribute work among the firms in accordance with their relative
advantages in capacity, skills, e~perience and the like. Competitive bidding, of
course, is itself a system of allocation which, ideally, ensures that orders go to the
firms able to execute them most cheaply. It seems doubtful to me, however,
that it could in practice promote as efficient a distribution of work as it is possible
to achieve directly, with only one buyer and four sellers. Different finns have
different methods of costing and may have different ideas about the bids that
others will submit, so that the prices quoted for particular jobs need not closely
reflect the relative ability of firms to undertake them.
Work has, in the past, been distributed between the firms in such a way that
intertrading has had to take place on a fairly considerable scale. Up to 40 per
cent of the value of a particular contract obtained by one of the firms may be
represented by components bought from the others, the prices paid being those
listed in the agreed schedules subject to a handling discount. Wbere there are
significant economies of scale in the production of particular components, this
arrangement has much to commend it, but I cannot believe that it would for long
endure under a regime of competitive pricing. In the absence of the agreement,
firms would be free to vary bOth the prices they quote to the Board, for main
contracts, and the prices they quote to each other for the supply of components.
Thus a firm competing for a main contract could demand prohibitive prices for
the supply of essential components required by its rivals. If all four firms had
given hostages to each other in this way, then one might hope that they would
refrain from any attempt thus to hold each other up to ransom. But at present
there is one firm nearly self-sufficient and therefore in a stronger position for
this type of warfare than the others. It seems to me, therefore, that the present
measure of rationalisation, let alone further extension of it, would clearly be
prejudiced by the introduction of price competition. Each firm would be likely
to strive for self-sufficiency, as far as its rivals are concerned, or run the risk of
being put out of business. This consequence of price competition, as most of the
others, cannot be predicted with certainty; it would be foolish to imagine that
we are able to identify simple and dependable links between cause and effect in
affairs of this kind; new or unperceived circumstances can easily upset one's
speculations. The pOint I make is that, on the face of it, price competition is
incompatible with rationalisation of the kind described; it is up to the protagon-
ists of such competition to show either that this incompatibility .~ illusory or that
the rationalisation achieved, or capable of achievement, is not ~vorth preserving.
Further co-operation takes place, between the buyer and the producers, and
between the prodocers themselves, in the development of standardised equip-
ment. The aim is to provide components that are. interchangeable, thereby
PAGENO="0247"
3683
reducing the average quantities that have to be held in stotk, and at the same
time incorporate the best ideas of the four design teams. I am unable to estimate
the gains from collaboration of this kind, but there seems little reason to doubt
that the Generating Board, which took the chief initiative in this matter, regards
them as valuable. What concerns us here is the compatibility between this
exchange of ideas and the practice of price competition. Although it would be
perfectly possible for firms to compete in terms of price while co-operating in
development, I cannot believe that they would be likely to do so for long. There
are hound to be times at which some firm is convinced that it has less to get from
an exchange of ideas than it has to give and succumbs to the temptation to make
use of this advantage in the competitive struggle. The temptation exists, of
course, even under the price agreement, but abrogation, by obliging the com-
panies to struggle for their share of the market, would greatly strengthen it. It is
likely, moreover, that firms would seek some shelter from the full vigour of price
competition by developing nonstandard products which, by the very fact of
being incapable of substitution, have a low cross-elasticity of demand.
7. The Summary case againsi Price Competition.
The unsuitability of price competition, for the three markets under dis-
cussion, seems to me the consequence of several quite particular circumstances
taken in conjunction. It is certainly not my intention in this paper to offer a
general apology for restrictive agreements; circumstances alter cases and, in
this field, can do so decisively.
To sum up, the policy of promoting price competition, in the sale of heavy
electrical equipment, is inappropriate for two main reasons.
In the first place, it will fail to attain its own objective. The size of single
orders, the inelasticity of demand, the gap between marginal and average costs
and the predominance of one buyer, all taken together, make it impossible to
combine normal profitability with price flexibility and periodic excess of capacity
over demand. Something has to give. Normal profitability must be assured, if
the firms concerned are to stay in the business. Excess capacity could be com-
pletely avoided, if indeed at all, only at great social cost. Price flexibility is
avoidable only if firms make an agreement or are able to refrain from active price
competition even without one; in this latter eventuality, however, there will no
longer be any guarantee that prices are not kept unduly high.
Secondly, price competition would prejudice the attainment of other objec.
tives important in this context. It requires only a very limited faith in the prin-
ciple of planning as such to recognise that the particular character of the markets
which concern us offers a special opportunity for the deliberate co-ordination of
plans. Such co-ordination is made difficult, in the generality of industry, by the
number of firms on both sides of the market; but the domestic requirements for
turbines, transformers and switchgear depend on programmes made by a single
nationalised electricity authority and framed several years in advance. Co-
operation between the suppliers and the Generating Board has developed
furthest, I believe, in switchgear, where, as we have seen, there is a system of
bulk allocation. The utility of such co-operation, in matters of design and devel-
PAGENO="0248"
3684
opment as well as the planning of investment, seems to me something no reason-
able man could deny; in the nature of things, it would seem appropriate for the
manufacturers and the Generating Board to work together as a team. I am
indeed inclined to think, as an outsider, that co-operation might be closer, but
even its maintenance would be threatened by the practice of price competition.
Thus the real problem before us is to devise arrangements that permit the manu-
facturers and their customer to work together as a team without sacrificing the
objectives for the attainment of which price competition, in other circumstances,
is a useful device.
8. The Alternative ~o Price Com~eii~ion.
The alternative to price competition is agreement, but I do not wish to suggest
that we should be satisfied with agreements such as have been in force during the
last few decades. The electricity supply authorities have surely a right-indeed,~
a duty-to insist that the price they pay for equipment is not such as provide the
manufacturers either with abnormally high profits or with a shelter for ineffici-
ency. The agreements in operation hitherto have not given this guarantee; quite
apart from whether they did promote high prices and costs-and on this we need
not express an opinion-they offered the buyer no assurance that they did not do
so. Neither, I have argued, would price competition provide this guarantee;
some other way has to be found of providing the purchaser and the public with
the assurances to which they are entitled.
It might at first be supposed that the pricing policy of the firms operating an
agreement would be subject to two forms of check or sanction, the first provided
by the threat of new producers entering the market, the second by foreign
competition. In fact, however, it is very difficult for new firms to enter the heavy
end of the industry, in which much capital and experience is required. Nor would
it be expedient for the Generating Board to purchase equipment from abroad.
Obviously the balance of paymen~:s would suffer, and, in any case, the prices
quoted by foreign suppliers would not provide a standard for home producers, as
export prices seem generally to be below the level of. full costs. We have to
conclude, therefore, that there are no natural checks such as would prevent a
price ring from abusing its power.
The need is clearly to devise an agreement to which both the Generating
Board and the manufacturers are party and into which appropriate safeguards
have been built. This could be done in a variety of ways, the details of which
ought to be the subject of another paper. Clearly the level of price must be
related to production costs, these being calculated as a weighted average for the
firms concerned and set so as to provide a rate of return on capital comparable to
that obtained in industry generally and not less than is required to finance
expansion and provide a normal yield to shareholders. A fairly loose form of
control would seem preferable, prices being set for a period of ----say-three years
and revised subsequently if they did not provide the agreed rate of return on
capital. The firms would be obliged to employ the same accounting techniques
and their calculations would have to be submitted to some independent body,
neither the producers nor the purchaser being left as judge in their own cause.
PAGENO="0249"
3685
Negotiations along these lines have in fact, I believe, been under way between
the parties concerned, but 1 am not informed as to their progress. Needless to
say, there are important issues of principle and of practical administration that
require to be resolved. One of these is the appropriate allocation of costs between
home and export sales.
First, in the production of heavy electrical equipment there are important
overhead costs the allocation of which, between home and export sales, is essen-
tially arbitrary. Capacity installed to make switchgear for the CEGB for example
may be used at a later state of its life to produce for export. The development
work done to produce ever larger turbo-generators will likewise serve both the
home and export markets. In so far as these costs are concerned, any net
contribution to them that the manufacturers can obtain from exports will
reduce the level of home prices necessary to secure a reasonable return ovei all.
Even if almost the whole of these overheads were attributed to the cost of
producing equipment for the home market, it could not be said that the home
customer was subsidisiiig exports; without the exports he would have to pay
more.
Secondly, it appears to be the case, throughout the world generally, that the
domestic price of heavy electrical equipment exceeds the export price. Foreign
manufacturers, that is to say, rely on their home markets for recouping the
greater part of their overheads. Whether or not we approve of these arrange-
ments, they are a fact of life and the British industry cannot hope to compete
overseas unless it operates similarly.
Thirdly, there are no statistics known to me that can provide us with the
return earned on capital, in industry generally, on home sales alone. The avail-
able figures relate to the return on capital on total business. This is important in
that the permitted rate of return on the production of heavy electrical equipment
-assuming that this were to be employed in fixing prices-would have to be
related to the returns in other industries. If like were to be compared with like,
then it is the manufacturers' return on their total sales of the electrical equip-
ment in question that must be considered.
For these three reasons, it seems to me that the prices fixed in any agreement
between the industry and the supply authorities ought to be such as afford a
normal rate of return to a firm of normal efficiency on its total business, home and
export, subject to the condition that export prices are not actually below
marginal costs.
A further problem concerns the computation of the capital employed by the
firms concerned and, more generally, the structure of production in the industry.
The prices set ought to be such as to compensate producers for having installed
an amount of capacity sufficient to meet the buyer's needswhen at their peak
even although that capacity is not currently in full use. But it is possible for
excess capacity to exist to an extent greater than that required to meet peak
requirements, through lack of co-ordination between the firms' investment
plans, technological change, a falling off in export orders or for some other
reason. The Generating Board has no obvious obligation to take thisparticular
burden off the firms' shoulders, and yet it may in practice be difficult to measure
PAGENO="0250"
3686
the quantity of excess capacity attributable to one circumstance rather than
another. I can see no hope of precise solutions to this problem, but it should not
he so difficult for reasonable men to reach a compromise appropriate to the
particular circumstances of each case.
These considerations lead us to the question of the structural efficiency of an
industry as a whole. Let us assume for example that it could be established,
beyond reasonable doubt, that the number of, say, transformer makers was too
great to permit full exploitation of all the available economies of scale. \Vere
this the case, the firms would hav~ an incentive to form larger units in order to
reduce costs, but it could be thatthis incentive was not strong enough to counter
the effect of inertia and the desire to maintain independence. In these circum-
stances price competition does offer some remedy. Firms that did merge would
strive, by price reductions, to enlarge their share of the market and would thereby
force rivalsto follow their example; even the threat that this might happen might
encourage firms to exploit such scale economies as became available. A general
fall in prices, produced by competition in conditions of excess capacity, would at
least help to concentrate the minds of manufacturers on the need to improve
their position.
Under these conditions, it would be hard to justify any agreement that left
firms, on average, with a normal return on capital employed and thereby pre-
vented an unsatisfactory structure from registering itself in the way most likely
to lead to its improvement. It ought to be understood that an industry is not
entitled to enjoy the legal right to operate a restrictive agreement that serves to
perpetuate inefficiency. But it would be wrong to turn to price competition as
the sure way of bringing about desired rationa.lisation. No doubt poor returns,
in the long run, will reduce an excessive number of producers, but they may also
weaken the incentive and the ability, even for the most efficient firms, to invest
in the development and installation of up-to-date productive equipment. It is
conceivable that general impoverishment might prove the only way, in practice,
of forcing the required changes, but I should hope that a less costly and more
rapid method might be found in cooperative action in which both the manu-
facturers and the electricity supply authorities would take part.
A policy of agreed prices, based on a weighted average of the finns' costs, is
`pen to the further objection that it ensures only that a company's profits are
.ommensurate with its efficiency relative to rival producers as contrasted with its
efficiency relative to industry as a whole. And the point could be made, in this
connection, that three or four producers, as in both turbines and switchgear,
represented a very small sample. The most obvious reply to an argument
along these lines is that, given the difficulty of entering these markets and
the objections to buying from abroad, competition would do no better; each
firm woul(1 fare according to its efficiency relative to its t'~'o rivals irrespective
of the level of efficiency of three firms as a whole. It is conceivable that, in
fixing agreed prices, one might even do better, in that the buyer might be `sble
to produce evidence of costs in other countries or to make his own estimates of
what costs, employing the latest equipment and techniques, ought to he.'
`Sir Robert Shone, in a comment on an earlier version of this article, pointed to the stee)
industrvs experience of price control based on calculations of this kind.
PAGENO="0251"
3687
Whether such developments would eventually be feasible, I cannot readily
judge, but it would be wrong to rule them out of consideration. In a similar way,
the buyer could claim that any very marked spread between the costs of the
firms concerned was prima fade evidence of structural inefficiency or of the
use of different accounting techniques.
Some readers, dismayed by the number and difficulty of the problems bound
up with the choice of an agreed level of prices, may feel that their sympathy for
the policy of price competition is now being re-kindied. But reliance on such a
policy, although it might encourage us to forget about these problems, would
not ensure their solution. It would not, I have argued, guarantee that profits
were neither persistently above nor persistently below those earned generally;
it would not automatically correct any structural inefficiency, and it would
not ensure that firms were in a position to compete, by differential pricing at
home and abroad, in the international market as it currently exists.
Other readers may blame me for not following, to their proper conclusion,
the logic of m-y own arguments. They may see the plurality of producers as a
permanent obstacle to the co-ordination of investment plans, the importance of
which I conceded, and recommend that not only the generation and distribution
of electricity, but also the manufacture of the equipment used in these processes,
should be put under the control of a state monopoly. Such a proposal can appear
reasonable, however, only if we focus on some of the requirements of economic
efficiency'to the exclusion of others no less important. Given that we cannot
hope to know, in advance, the forms of research and development that will
prove the most fruitful, the designs that will be most effective, the techniques of
organisation and management that will show themselves superior, the decentral-
isation of decision-making provided by a plurality of firms is a sound strategy.
Nor must we imagine that, price competition being appropriate, all forms of
inter-firm rivalry serve no useful social purpose. We should see ourselves not as
obliged to choose between competition and monopoly but as confronted with the
problem (an economic problem quite strictly) of devising arrangements that
provide, even approximately, an optimum balance between competition and
planning, freedom and order. We should aim at getting (as far as is possible) the
best of both worlds.
SI. John's C~l1ege,
Oxford.
PAGENO="0252"
3688
EXHIBIT IV
AGREEMENT BETWEEN THE CENTRAL ELECTRICITY GENERATING BOARD AND
THE GRID SWITCHGEAR MANUFACTURERS
Partie8 to the Agreement
1. The parties to this Agreement are the Central Electricity Generating Board
and the Manufacturers of Grid Switchgear comprising Associated Electrical
Industries Limited, The English Electric Company Limited, The General Electric
Company Limited and A. Reyrolle and Company Limited (hereinafter referred
to as "C.E.G.B." and "G.S.M." respectively).
,S~cope of Agreement
2. (a) The agreement covers the manufacture and installation by the four
G.S.M. firms for C.E.G.B. of 400 kV, 275 kV and 132 kV switchgear.
(b) In the manufacture of grid switchgear, the G.S.M. accounts disclose that
the turnover :capital employed ratio has been in recent years about 1 :1 so that
profit on sales is broadly equivalent to profit on capital employed.
(c) The agreement will run for an initial period of five years from 1st january
1966 prov~dect that:
(1) the operation of the pricing mechanism of the agreement shall be
reviewed after two years to ascertain whether so far as the actual (as dis-
tinct from notional) average profit earned by the two lowest cost producers
at each voltage exceeds 161/2% on sales it is likely to be reduced to that level
over a reasonable period, and also whether the average annual return over
the five year period of the four G.S.M. firms on their grid switchgear busi-
ness with the C.E.G.B. is likely, as expected by the parties to the agreement,
to be below 161/2%.
(2) if following the review referred to in (1) above the C.E.G.B. on the
one hand or the G.S.M. on the other are not satisfied that the agreement is
operating or is likely to operate in accordance with the intentions of the
parties, either party may give notice to terminate the agreement with effect
from 1st January 1969.
(3) if notice to terminate the Agreement is so given it shall continue
to apply in respect of contracts already placed but not to any future
oontracts.
Determination of Prices
3~ A uniform method of ascertaining costs, proposed by Cooper Brothers &
Co., hereinafter referred to as "the independent accountant" is annexed to this
Agreement (Annex I) and has been approved by the parties.
4. Until such time as adjustments are determined under Clauses 5 to 9 below,
all new contracts will be placed at the net selling prices ruling at 31st December
1965 and incorporated in the agreed Schedule of Prices subject only to modifica-
tion of such individual prices as may be agreed between the parties.
5. (i) At the end of each calendar year, each manufacturer will submit to the
independent accountant a certified statement showing the total Grid Switchgear
invoiced by him during that year for C.E.G.B. contracts together with the re-
sultant profit. This return will show separate figures for 132 kV, 275 kV and
400 kV contracts and initially for the year 1964 as well as 1965 for 132 kV and
275 kV switchgear.
For the purpose of this clause the term "invoiced during that year" is to be
interpreted as relating to contracts for gear which during the year concerned
have reached the point at which invoices for 95% of the contract price have been
submitted (i.e. excluding retention money) and the invoice prices shall be in-
creased in the ratio 100/95.
Where major items of equipment have been sub-contracted between members
of the G.S.M. the following procedure shall apply in preparing the above returns:
(a) The subcontractor will include in his costs the cost to him of the
sub-contracted items and in his invoiced price the price he obtained from
the main contractor.
(b) The main contractor will include in his cost return the cost of han-
dling and engineering. In his contract price return he will include the differ-
ence between the price he received from the C.E.G.B. and the price he pai(l
to the sub-contractor.
The term "major items of equipment" comprises circuit breakers, current
transformers, voltage transformers, isolating and earthing switches and line
traps.
PAGENO="0253"
3689
The certified statement referred to above will show not only the actual invoice
values, ascertained costs and resulting profits or losses but also the notional sales
values, ascertained costs and corresponding adjusted profits or losses which
would have resulted on these contracts if the contracts had been invoiced at the
schedule price level ruling for tenders during the year. 5. (ii) When the inde-
pendent accountant has received the returns under (i) above he will proceedin
accordance with the annexed terms of reference (Annex 2). He will aggregate
the sales and also the profits of each manufacturer over a three year period to
which the return under 5(i) relates and the two previous years. For this purpose
the sales and corresponding profits will be those which would have resulted if the
invoices relating to the contracts for all three years had been invoiced at the
schedule price level ruling during the third year. The independent accountant
will then identify the two manufacturers (not necessarily the same for each of
the three voltages) who, on this basis of computation of the profits, would have
earned over the latest available three years the greatest percentage profit margin
in respect of each of the three voltages. He will then summate the returns of
these two manufacturers for the three years and ascertain the percentage profit
margin for the three years on their combined sales to the C.E.G.B. at each of
the voltages concerned. The returns of the two manufacturers with the lowest
percentage profit margins for the three years will be ignored but they will never-
theless be subjected to the price adjustment set out in Clauses 6 and 7 below.
However, the first calculation to be made under this sub-clause shall be in
accordance with Clause 9.
A. similar calculation will be made using actual invoice values and resulting
profits or losses and the percentage profit margins both actual and notional as
ascertained for each of the three voltages will be advised to the O.E.B.G. and
the G.S.M.
5. (iii) The G.S.M. agree to give the independent accountant such information
and explanations as he may require.
6. (A) Unless otherwise agreed between the parties, prices in the agreed sched-
ule of prices used for the preparation of tenders and for contracts placed during
the calendar year following the year to which the returns under Clause 5(i)
relates will be reduced by half the percentage, if any, by which the notional
profit margin ascertained under Clause 5(u) for the particular voltage for the
average of the three previous calendar years has exceeded the agreed profit
margin of 16'/2 %, the schedule of prices so modified becoming the agreed sched-
ule of prices.
Provided that if the notional percentage profit margin of one of the two pro-~
ducers showing the highest notional rate of return under Clause 5 (ii) shall be
lower than the agreed profit margin, then no reduction will be made in the sched-
ule of prices. Any such reduction shall, in any case, be limited to the difference
between-
(a) the notional rate of return of the lower of the two highest margins
identified under Clause 5(u) and
(b) the agreed profit margin.
Any limitation in price reduction arising from the proviso in the previous two
sentences will be advised by the independent accountant to the C.E.G.B. and
G.S.M.
6. (B) For the purposes of the calculations to be made under Clauses 5, 6 and~
7 of this Agreement there shall be eliminated from the contract and invoice
prices any amount arising from the operation of the contract price adjustment
clause referred to in Clause 11 of this Agreement and the same amount shall be
eliminated from the relevant costs. Any percentage adjustment made to the
prices under the provisions of Clause 7 below shall not be made to that part of
the price which represents the contract price adjustment referred to above.
6. (C) The agreed Schedule of Prices shall be expressed as an index and the
price level at 31st December 1965 shall represent 100. Adjustments to the index
shall only be made by reference to adjustments arising under Clause 6(A).
Any adjustments made to the Schedule of Prices under the provisions of Clause
10 of this Agreement shall not affect the index. For the purposes of making any
actual or notional adjustments to contract or invoice prices under Clauses 5,
6 and 7 by reference to the level of the agreed Schedule of Prices the adjust-
ment shall be made by way of a percentage reduction based on the movement
in this index of schedule prices.
7. The prices for all invoices, in respect of contracts covered by this Agree-
ment, rendered to the C.E.G.B. by the G.S.M. for the particular voltage during
PAGENO="0254"
3690
the calendar year following the year to which the return under Clause 5(i) re-
lates shall be reduced to the schedule price level used for the preparations of
tenders during that calendar year.
8. In addition to the review provided for under Clause 2(o) (1), the C.E.G.B.
and G.S.M. will also review the operation of the Agreement from time to time
with the intention of making appropriate changes in the event of :-
(a) any material change of circumstances (e.g. merger of two or more
manufacturers or the development of basically new types of switchgear)
(b) the actual (as distinct from notional) average profit of the two most
profitable manufacturers at any voltage failing to exceed 161/2% in three
successive years;
(c) there being a significant variation in three successive years in the
relationship of capital employed to turnover from the ratio of 1 :1 which
has pertained in recent years so that profit on sales ceases to be broadly
equivalent to profit on capital employed.
9. The first cost returns will be in respect of the calendar years:
1964 and 1965 for 132kV and 275kV (early in 1966)
1965 and 1966 for 400kV (early in 1967)
and the first adjustments to prices based on such returns will be as follows
132kV and 275kV: 1966 for all invoices and schedule prices used for tenders
and new contracts.
400kV: 1966 and 1967 for all invoices, 1967 for schedule prices used for
tenders and new contracts.
10. Schedule Prices will also be adjusted for variations in labour rates, mate-
rials, etc. as agreed between the C.E.G.B. and G.S.M.
Other Conditien~
11. All contracts will be placed in accordance with standard Conditions of
Contract agreed between the C.E.G.B. and B.E.A.M.A. The C.E.G.B. and the
G.S.M. agree to negotiate a contract price adjustment formula consistent with
this Agreement for application to contracts completed after 31st December 1966.
Meanwhile the existing formula will apply.
12. If requested by the C.E.G.B. the G.S.M. will quote competitively as between
themselves for 15% of C.E.G.B. requirements for 132kV switchgear taking one
year with another. Any orders placed as a result of such competition will be
excluded from the other provisions of this Agreement.
13. The C.E.G.B. do not undertake to order Grid Switchgear exclusively from
the G.S.M.
ANNEX I
GElD SWITCUGEAR
Compilation and Presentation of Comparable Costs of Grid Switcbgear
1. The following paragraphs set out the basis on which costs of grid switch-
gear should be compiled and presented.
I. COMPILATIQN OF COSTS
Mat en ais
2. The quantity of material used in manufacture should include manufactur-
ing scrap where identifiable with individual contracts, and would be obtained
from the job cost account which would be compiled from material requisitions
issued and charged to the job. Scrap, arising during the course of manufacture,
not identifiable with individual contracts should be charged to works over-
heads. In order to verify that all requisitions have been charged, the job costs
should be compared with the material specifications. The material requisitions
should be priced at cost and there should be no addition for handling charges.
Where castings are produced in the member's own foundry, the cost charged
as materials should include the direct labour and overhead costs of the foundry.
3. Where material is purchased in a rough machined state from outside sup-
pliers the char~re to materials will include the labour and overhead charges for
the rough machining.
4. The realised value of scrap should he credited to the material cost of the
job where practicable or alternatively to general works overhead charges.
5. Any excess material issued for the job should be returned to stores and
credited to the material cost of the job.
6. Where items are manufactured in other departments or by subsidiary
companies the transfer value thereof should be included as part of the cost of
PAGENO="0255"
3691
materials. The transfer value of such items should be cost unless the depart-
ment or subsidiary company concerned supplies to third parties in the normal
course of business in which case the transfer prices should be equivalent to the
prices charged to third parties.
7. Any trade discounts or rebates directly applicable to the materials used
in the product should be credited to the material cost. Any other discounts
received should be credited to administration and selling expenses.
Direct Labour
8. Direct labour may be defined as the work engaged in altering the form
or shape of materials in fabricating or processing. The direct labour cost should
be based on whichever of the following bases is appropriate:
(a) The piece work prices paid plus the national award or cost of living
bonus, and any incentive or production bonus paid to direct operatives.
(b) The piece work times allowed evaluated at the budgeted labour cost
per hour, plus the national award or cost of living bonus related to the hours
worked, and time saved at the bonus rate per hour and any incentive or
production bonus paid to direct operatives.
(c) Where day work rates are paid the costs should be based on the day
work rate, which would consist of the basic rate per hour plus national
award and the lieu bonus rate. This consolidated rate should be applied to
the hours charged to the job. Any incentive or production bonus paid to
direct operatives should be included in the direct labour cost.
9. Where piece work prices or times allowed include the cost or time for
setting by the operative this should be included in the direct labour cost. Where
setting is performed by a setter the cost should be charged to the job where pos-
sible but otherwise should be included in the general works overheads. All
other labour engaged in supervision, servicing, transporting materials including
crane men and slingers, and general labouring should be included in the general
works overhead charges.
Overhead Ea,pen~ses
10. The overhead expenses should be based on budgets for the period of pro-
duction and where necessary should be adjusted to reflect normal activity i.e.
80% of single shift working plus normal overtime plus double shifting of some
key machine tools. If Budgets are not used then the latest available financial
accounts shiuld be used and adjustments made for any fluctuations in prices
and wage rates between the period of production and the period of the financial
accounts and should reflect normal activity.
11. The overhead expenses should be segregated between-
(a) General Works Expenses (paragraphs 12-17).
(b) Administration and Selling Expenses (paragraphs 18-21).
(c) Packing Expenses (paragraph 29).
(d) Site (paragraphs 22 and 23).
(e) The Selective Employment Tax should be regarded as an overhead
expense and should be segregated between the classes of overhead expense
as set out above. Any refunds or premiums received should be regarded as
a reduction of the overhead expenses.
The type of expenses normally shown under groupings (a) (b) and (c) is shown
in appendix A attached.
Goueral Works E~rpenses
12. The general works expenses should be allocated between departments,
shops or cost centres. Where possible, expenses should be directly allocated to
the department, shop or cost centre and where that is not possible reasonable
arbitrary bases of apportionment should be used for example-
Type of expenses Basis of apportionment
Rent, rates Floor space occupied
Lighting Wattage of lamps
Heating Cubic area of floor space
Power Metered consumption or horse power of
Maintenance of buildings motors in use
Depreciation of plant Floor space occupied
Gas Capital value of plant
General labouring Technical estimate base on the
number of jets used
Direct labour
PAGENO="0256"
3692
The works overhead expenses should be recovered in costs by machine hour rates
related to the cost centres, or by the productive hourly rate related to the de-
partment, shop or cost centre, or by percentage of direct labour cost applicable
to the department, shop or cost centre.
13. Where budgeted overhead recovery rates are used these should be ad-
justed by any over or under absorbed expenses to the extent that is necessary
to reflect normal activity as defined in paragraph 10. Recoveries as a percentage
of the material cost for material handling should not be used.
14. Overhead expenses should be collected for ancillary departments, i.e. tools
and patterns, research and development etc. These expenses would be directly
charged, where possible, to the products (see paragraphs 25 to 29).
15. Departmental accounts should be maintained for the direct cost of service
departments, i.e. power ho~use, maintenance etc. The total cost of such service
departments to which general overheads should not be charged would be ap-
portioned to the production departments, shops or cost centres according to the
service performed.
16. Notional charges, such as rent where buildings are owned, should not be
included in the overhead expenses.
17. The depreciation included in costs should be calculated on the bases adopted
by manufacturers in their accounts and should be based on the historical cost
of the fixed assets. Investment and similar cash grants received should be de-
ducted from the cost of the relevant fixed assets and depreciation should be
calculated on the resulting net cost of those assets.
Administration and selling Expenses
18. Administration and selling expenses which are attributable to the admin-
istration and selling of the products manufactured are those set out in appendix
A. Where applicable a due proportion of head office expenses should be included.
19. These expenses which will rate to both home and export trades combined
should be segregated as between product divisions but not as between depart-
ments, shops or cost centres in view of the arbitrary bases of apportionment
which would have to be used and which may direct the costs.
20. The expenses should be recovered in costs as a percentage of the works
cost and recoveries as a percentage of the material cost for handling should
not be used.
21. Where budgeted recovery rates are used these rates should, if necessary,
be adjusted so as to reflect normal activity as defined in paragraph 10, in the
period of production.
Erection and Installation on site
22. Any direct materials used should be charged to the job at cost. Direct
labour employed at the site should also be charged to the job at the rates paid.
The labour should be confined to the erection, installation and testing on the
site. Work normally done in the works but for expediency done on the site,
should be included in the works cost.
23. The overhead expenses would be those incurred at the site plus any other
overheads directly attributable to the erection organization. The total of the
materials, labour and overhead expenses would be a direct charge to the job.
Design and Drawing Office Expenses
24. Design and drawing office time applicable to the job should be charged
direct, based on time occupied at hourly rates. These rates should be set to in-
clude the overhead expenses of the engineering and drawing offices, or alterna-
tively an addition should be made to the direct costs to cover the overhead ex-
penses concerned.
Tools and Patterns
25. Tools and patterns purchased specifically for the job should be charged
direct to the job at cost.
26. Tools and patterns made for the job by the member's own tools and pat-
terns department should be charged to the job at the departmental works cost.
The expenses of the department not chargeable direct should be recovered in
costs as a percentage of works cost and should be added to the direct costs
giving a total cost of tools and patterns applicable to the job.
PAGENO="0257"
3693
Research and Development
27. The charge for general research to the product divisions concerned should
be recovered in costs as a percentage of works cost. Materials, labour and over-
head expenses incurred by the product divisions in developing and proving new
or improved standard designs prior to putting such new or improved standard
designs into production should be recovered in costs as a percentage of works
cost. All research and development expenses referred to in this paragraph should
be charged to home trade business only.
28. Special development should be charged direct to the contract under the ap-
propriate headings design and drawing office expenses, tools and patterns or
research and development. This expenditure includes special engineering and
drawing office work, patterns and tools for a specific contract together with
special modifications.
Packing
29. Packing materials used should be charged to the job at cost where sepa-
rately identifiable. Packing labour employed on the job should be charged at the
rates paid. Overhead expenses of the department should be collected in a de-
partmental account and recovered as a percentage of the labour cost of the
department.
Delivery
30. The cost of hired transport, or charges for own transport, for delivery
should be charged direct to the job.
Post Construction Maintenance Ecepenses
31. The charge in the product costs to cover post construction maintenance
should be a provision based on past experience and anticipated future trends,
and should be a percentage of the works cost. The provision relates to all main-
tenance expenses incurred after the ~1ate of commissioning.
IL PRESENTATION OF COSTS
Cost Retii~rn
32. Attached at `appendix B is a cost schedule setting out the form `in which
the costs of the grid switchgear, compiled in accordance with paragraphs 2
to 31 of this memorandum, should be presented.
33. The cost schedule sets out the elements of cost under which the costs
should be analysed. For guidance, definitions of the elements of cost are set out
in paragraphs 34 to 38.
Materials
34. Materials represent items purchased or requisitioned from stores in ac-
cordance with the contract specification, other than those items coming within
the definition of sub-contracted work (see paragraph 35).
Sub-Contracted Work
35. Sub-contracted work consists of processing, by outside firms, on material
supplied by the main contractor. Where practicable, the cost of the material
supplied should be included under "materials" and the charge for processing
included under "sub-contracted work."
Direct Labour
36. Direct labour may be defined as the work engaged in altering the form or
shape of materials in fabricating or processing.
Overhead Ea~pe'nses
37. The works overhead expenses are those indirect costs applicable to the
manufacturer of the product, or expended in ancillary and service departments,
as set out on appendix A.
38. Administration and selling expenses are those expenses incurred in the
management and administration of the Company, and the sale of its products,
as set out on appendix A.
95-159 0-68-pt. 8-17
PAGENO="0258"
3694
APPENDIX A
GRID SWITCHGEAR
Classification of Overhead Ea,penses
I. GENERAL WORKS EXPENSES
Indirect Labour:
Tool setting
Rectification
`~\Taiting time f Or direct operatives
Collecting and feeding materials for productive operations
Moving work in progress between operations
Moving finished materials from manufacturing departments or shops
Unloading outside transport
Internal transport labour
Overtime and shift extras
Extra allowances to direct operatives
General labouring shopwork not specified
Foreman, chargehands and supervisors
Managers and staff of productive departments
Inspection and testing of incoming materials
Inspection and testing-production
Planning and progressing
Method, time study and ratefixing
Timekeeping
Works security
Training, teaching and learning
Storekeeping
Stocktaking
Plant equipment and layout staff
Personnel
Works Clerks
Bonus to works staff
Holiday pay
National Insurance-Company contribution
Selective Employment Tax
Free Transport-works employees
Pension scheme contributions and ex gratia pensions
Retrospective wage adjustments
Plant relayout
Production replacement and repajrs (material and labour)
Consumable materials
Rejects and losses
Redundant stores
Protective clothing
Works internal transport running expenses and depreciation
Coal, coke, gas and fuel oil for works and works offices
Employer's liability insurance
Printing and stationery
Power, light and heating of works and works offices
Plant maintenance and reconditioning
Water for works and works offices
Rents and rates of works buildings
Works Insurance
Building maintenance
Depreciation of works buildings, plant, machinery and equipment
Carriage inwards when goods are not purchased at delivered prices
Canteen and welfare
Miscellaneous expenses
PAGENO="0259"
8695
IT. ADMINISTRATION AND SELLING EXPENSES
Management
Accounting staff
Secretarial staff
Central typing staff
Sales department staff
Representative staff
Agents' commission
Drawing office and design (sales)
National Insurance-company contribution
Selective Employment Tax
Bonuses
Pension scheme contributions and ex gratia pensions
Rents and rates of buildings
Repairs and maintenance
Depreciation of office furniture, fittings and equipment
Management expense
Light and heat
Telephone and postage
Office services
Printing, stationery and duplicating
Motor vehicles (administrative and sales) expenses, including depreciation
General insurances, other than works
Canteen and welfare
Travelling expenses
Bank charges (excluding bank interest)
Patent renewal and license fees
Donations and subscriptions
Advertising
General publicity, including catalogues and brochures
Exhibitions
Expenses of branch Offices and sales depots
Consultants' fees
Audit fees
Legal charges
Debt collecting expenses
Bad debts
Miscellaneous expenses
Group tendering and associated expenses
Note: Cash discounts received are to be deducted
IlL PACKING EXPENSES
Transport maintenance
National insurance company contribution
Selective Employment Tax
Bonus
Pension scheme contribution and ex gratia pensions
Miscellaneous packing expenses
Rent and rates of buildings
Repairs and maintenance
Light and heat
Telephone and postage
Printing and ntationery and duplicating
PAGENO="0260"
3696
APPENDIX B
COST SCHEDULE FOR GiuD SWITCHGEAE
Description of Plant
Period of production (from commencement of machining to despatch from
works) from to
Total
(pounds)
Materials (paragraphs 2-7 and 34)
Sub-contracted work (paragraph 35)
Direct labour (paragraph 8-9) -
Works overhead expenses (paragraphs 10-17)
Works cost
Administration and selling expenses (paragraph 18-21)
Erection and installation on site (paragraphs 22 and 23)
Material
Labour
Site overhead expenses
Design and drawing office expenses (paragraph 24)
Tools and patterns (paragraphs 25 and 26)
Research and development (paragraphs 27 and 28)
Packing and delivery (paragraphs 29 and 30)
Post construction maintenance expenses (paragraph 31)
ANNEX 2
GRID SWITCHGEAR
Terms of Reference to the independent accountant Cooper Brothers & Co. in
connection with Clause 5 of the Agreement
It being the wish of both parties to the Agreement that their joint and several
financial interests thereunder shall be subject to the examination aDd judgement
of a single independent accountant: Cooper Brothers & Co. are hereby authorised
and instructed as follows:
(1) To prescribe the form of a return to be compiled and certified by each
manufacturer in respect of each calendar year showing particulars relating
to all grid switchgear invoiced by him during the year for C.E.G.B. contracts
and distinguishing between business for 132kV, 275kV and 400kV.
(2) To be available at all reasonable times to advise accountants con-
cerned in producing the returns and also the Central Electricity Generating
Board.
(3) To receive the certified returns and to scrutinise and appraise them
with the financial interests of all parties to the Agreement in mind and to
pursue any enquiries necessary to ensure that the costs shown therein have
been arrived at in accordance with the costing principles detailed in Annex I
to this Agreement and with any modifications, interpretations and techniques
developed to give effect to these principles.
(4) Having completed his examination of the returns and having made
any necessary adjustments arising from his scrutiny and appraisal, to
summate the returns in accordance with Clause 5 (ii) of the Agreement and
advise the Central Electricity Generating Board and the Grid Switchgear
Manufacturers of the percentage profit margins ascertained in accordance
with Clause 5 (ii) of the Agreement.
As witness the hands of Joseph Latham on behalf of Associated Electrical
Industries Limited Gerald Noel Cabell on behalf of The English Electric Com-
pany Limited Kenneth Gladstone Smith on behalf of The General Electric Com-
pany Limited James Bennett on behalf of Reyrolle and Company Limited and
PAGENO="0261"
3697
Leslie Frederick Miller on behalf of the Central Electricity Generating Board this
23d day of March 1967.
Signed by the said Joseph Latham in the presence of:
J. LATHAM.
Signed by the said Gerald Noel Gabell in the presence of:
G. N. GABELL.
Signed by the said Kenneth Gladstone Smith in the presence of:
K. G. SMITH.
Signed by the said James Bennett in the presence of:
JAMEs BENNETT.
Signed by the said Leslie Frederick Miller in the presence of:
A. B. HACKETT.
L. F. MILLER.
EXHIBIT V
COMPARISON OF MARGINS ON FRENCH-MANUFACTURED POWER CIRCUIT BREAKERS
[GE-PCBD costs=100J
Home market Export to
sale United States
Delivered price
Total delivered costs
Indicated pretax margin
184. 0
1118. 6
86. 8
110. 4
65. 4
(23.6)
1 Includes tax on value-added.
Note: Parentheses denotes loss.
II. EUROPEAN MANUFACTURERS DERIVE TWO TRADE ADVANTAGES FROM THE "BORDER
TAX" SYSTEM: INCREASED COST5 OF IMPORTS AND TAX REMISSIONS ON EXPORTS
A. EMropean reliance on indirect taxes for revenues
Indirect taxes are the major source of revenue for most European countries.
In contrast the United States derives most of its revenue from direct taxes. Al-
though some European countries have corporate income tax rates nominally as
high as in the U.S., effective tax revenues from them are substantially less
because of generous depreciation practices, allowance of special reserves and
lower tax rates on distributed income. In General Electric's case we estimated
that our corporate income tax would have been reduced by about one third if
we had been subject to the German corporate income tax.
European indirect tax rates-for sales, turnover and value added taxes-are
high: 20% in France, 11% in Germany (as of July, 1968), and, probably a future
harmonized rate of 17% for the entire European Economic Community in the
19TOs. In contrast, the average indirect tax in the U.S. (state sales taxes) is
3.7%.
B. The trade effects of an indirect tax system competing with a direct tax system
Because of GATT rules regarding imposition of import equalization charges
and remission of taxes on exported goods, there are significant trade effects
than can be achieved by one nation's use of high-level indirect taxes, coupled
with lower direct taxes, against a competitor trading nation that depends almost
entirely on direct taxes.
PAGENO="0262"
3698
To the extent that an upward change in an indirect tax rate (either by initial
imposition or by a rate rise), is not passed along in full to the purchaser, the
residual amount must be absorbed by the manufacturer, becoming, in effect, a
direct tax on corporate earnings.
If, following such an increase in tax, a country raises its import equalization
charges (border taxes) and export remissions by the full upward change in in-
direct taxes, to the extent that the increase in the domestic tax is not fully
shifted `to purchasers, imports are penalized by paying a higher burden than the
equivalent product sold domestically, and exports are favored by a remission
rate higher than the indirect tax being charged within the border.
C. The need for analysis of the theory of tacv shifting
If the situation outlined in Section B, above, does or can occur, then underly-
ing tax theory regarding the shifting of direct and indirect taxes needs new
analysis and empirical testing. The GATT provisions governing tax impositions
and remissions seem to have assumed that indirect taxes are always shifted
100% forward, while direct taxes are not shifted at all. From that assumption
trade advantages `and disadvantages are derived, in that U.S. products going into
Europe face added costs of entry in the form of border taxes which overcompen-
sate for the internal indirect taxes, while the European products going into ex-
port receive substantial tax remissions that sometimes can make the difference
between winning an order and losing it.
The practical trade consequences of the GATT-endorsed theory of tax shifting
are evident to General Electric as it competes in world markets: added costs
of entry on its exports and import competition sharpened by tax remissions
whose rates run as high as 20%. When these tax remissions are added to
dual pricing disparities, they become a particularly significant and adverse
factor in international competition. It is important, then, that the theoretical
rationale on which the GATT provisions rest be re-examined and realistically
tested for its soundness. Competitive equity demands no less.
D. Additional inequities
Two other aspects of the European administration of high rate sales taxes
should be noted.
The first of these arises from the fact that European countries compute im-
port equalization taxes on a base that includes transportation, insurance and
duties, in addition to the factory price of the goods. The U.S., in applying its
few import equalization levies, does not include transportation. Two arguments
can, therefore, be advanced: (a) since inclusion of transportation, insurance
and duties unfairly raises the import equalization charge above the internal
sales tax, the equalization charge should be based on the price f.o.b. country
of origin, and (b) in any event, transportation charges should not be included
in the base.
Exhibit VI shows General Electric's experience with European border taxes
that are levied on landed cost instead of on the price f.o.b. factory. The rates
shown are those in effect ~1uring 1967. It will be noted that in the case of the
Netherlands and France, the domestic sales tax rate and the rate of the import
tax were the same. Yet, because these countries include transportation, insur-
ance and duty in the tax base, the border tax was much higher than the tax
paid by the European manufacturer.
Exhibit VI also shows the effect of a second administrative practice on
imports and exports where the turnover tax is of the "cascade" variety. Because
of the total tax borne by an article is a function of the number of turnovers
that brought it to market, the amount of import tax necessary to equalize sales
tax burdens is imposed at a rate higher than that applicable to a single turn-
over. For example, 11.5% as opposed to 7% in the case of tungsten carbide
to Belgium. There is little evidence avsilabh' about the degree of vertical inte-
gration among European industries. However, it is fairly clear that where
the border tax is equivalent to the average integration of a European industry,
the leaders of that industry who are more integrated than the smaller firms,
bear a tax burden well below that of the American exporter.
As the Kennedy round of tariff reductions takes effect, and the European
Economic Community adopts a uniform t.v.a. system of taxation, the barrier
effect will actually worsen in some countries, as demonstrated in the specific
example of Exhibit VII.
Assume that a U.S. manufacturer is exporting electric knives to West Ger-
many, and the value of his product at the port of New York is 100-an index
PAGENO="0263"
3699
value of 100. In 1967, at the German border, there was an import duty of 13%,
adding 13.6 points to the price. A 6% import tax adds 7.1 points to the index.
So the landed price of the U.S. product at the West German port is 125.2 index
points in 1967.
By 1973, the import duty will be cut in half (6.5%) but the import or border
tax will match the expected t.v.a. rate of 17%. So the landed value goes up to
130.2 points under the new t.v.a. tax system, in spite of Kennedy Round tariff
reductions.
A system of tax rebates works to subsidize exports of integrated European
firms in the cascade tax countries. Exhibit VIII shows data derived from exports
of General Electric subsidiaries in Common Market countries. The "waived" tax
simply shows the extent to which exports are exempt from sales taxes. The in-
termediate line shows the additional rebate which the government pays the ex-
porter and which supposedly is a function of the average number of turnovers in
a given industry. To the extent that a European exporter is highly integrated,
the rebate tends to exceed the actual tax burden. It represents an outright export
subsidy.
The specific manner in which the excess rebate system operates as an export
subsidy is shown in Exhibit IX. Our West German subsidiary manufactures an
electric alarm clock which has an f.o.b. plant price in West Germany of $3.86.
When this clock is exported to the United Kingdom, the West German govern-
ment waives 18 cents of inland sales tax and turnover tax. It also pays the Ger-
man manufacturer an excess rebate of 11 cents. Thus, the clock leaves the
German plant for its destination in the United Kingdom at a price of $3.57-or
29 cents less than its price in the German market.
Tax rebates to manufacturers in Europe thus affect competitive positions in
third markets. Exhibit X demonstrates the effect on refrigerators going to the
United Kingdom, from U.S. and Italian plants. In each case, the price for home
markets equals 100 index points. Going to export markets, the manufacturer in
Italy gets tax waivers and rebates amounting to 25 points, reducing his export
price to 75 points. By the time both have paid duties, customs, and transporta-
tion, the total landed value at Liverpool is 125 points for the U.S. product, and
99 points for the Italian product. This gives the manufacturer in Italy such
an advantage that, in the case investigated, he decided to take 10 points in extra
profit, and sold at 109.
It is conceded that these built-in trade advantages of high-rate sales taxes will
diminish in the future as the EEC switches from the cascade to the t.v.a. system.
But as long as the EEC countries base their import taxes on landed cost, and as
long as their rates exceed U.S. sales taxes by a factor of four, EEC countries
will continue to benefit from the current border tax practices.
Uo'nclusioii,s
A realistic interpretation of these data suggests that nations which rely pri-
marily on direct taxes face a chronic problem in international trade, when they
compete with industrialized nations whose tax structure is more heavily oriented
toward indirect revenues. This in turn raises the question of whether the United
States will be capable of correcting its balance of payments problems without
either adapting its own tax structure along the lines of its key competitors, or
obtaining GATT revisions that treat direct and indirect taxes more equitably for
purposes of international trade.
ExEnaIT VI
EUROPEAN TRANSACTION TAXES, 1967
[In percentj
U.S. export of-
National
turnover
tax rate
Import equal
ization taxes
~
Official
rate
Eflective rate
(percent of
U.S. f.o.b.)
Tungsten carbide to Belgium
Refrigerator to West Germany
Molding compound to Netherlands
7
4
6
11. 5
6
6
13. 5
5. 4
7. 3
X-ray equipment to France (t.v.a.)
25
25
35. 1
PAGENO="0264"
3700
EXHIBIT VII
U.S. EXPORT OF ELECTRIC KNIFE TO WEST GERMANY
1967 1973 with unifor
m t.v.a. rate
Rate Index Rate
(percent) (percent)
Index
F.o.b., U.S. price 100.0
Ocean freight and insurance 4. 5
100.0
4. 5
Subtotal 104. 5
Importtariff 13.0 13.6 6.5
Import equal. tax 6.0 7.1 17.0
104. 5
6.8
18.9
Landed price 125.2
130.2
EXHIBIT VIII
EUROPEAN TAX WAIVERS AND REBATES-EXPORTING COUNTRY AND PRODUCT
[Effective rate as percent of fob. pricel
West Nertherlands,
Germany, chemical
houseware
Italy,
refrigerator
Waived nationalindirecttaxes 4.6 5.5
Rebates national indirect taxes 2. 8 3. 8
11.4
9. 8
Total, waiver/rebate 7.4 9. 3
21. 2
EXHIBIT IX
EUROPEAN TAX REBATES SUBSIDIZE EXPORTS
[Case: Electric alarm clock made in West Germany; destination: United Kingdomj
Amount
West Germany fob. plant price
Taxes included in fob. price:
(1) Inland sales tax at 1 percent of export price
(2) Turnover tax at 4 percent of export price
Export rebate:
(1) Above 2 taxes are exempt (waived) on exports
(2) Excess rebate at 3 percent of export price
West German f.o.b. price less tax adjustment
$3.86
.04
14
(.18)
(.11)
3.57
EXHIBIT X
EUROPEAN TAX REBATES AFFECT COMPETITIVE POSITIONS IN 3D COUNTRIES
[Case: Refrigerator. Destination: United Kingdom.J
From United
States
From Italy
Home market price 100
Less tax waivers and rebates 0
100
25
Home market price less tax adjustment 100
Duties, customs, and transportation 25
75
24
Total, landed value 125
Actual selling price 125
99
109
PAGENO="0265"
3701
CONCYLUSION
A. The need for continuing convmitnvent to international negotiations
Since World War II multilateral negotiations in the GATT and consultations
in the OECD have been established as the principal means whereby the trading
nations agree to uniform and non-discriminatory rules of trade. As such, they
provide the essential foundation for orderly progression toward expanded inter-
national trade and elimination of devices and restrictions by which nations seek
either to protect their domestic economies from outside competition or to gain
an unfair advantage in foreign markets. General Electric believes that the long-
standing U.S. commitment to multilateral discussion and negotiation is desirable,
necessary and productive. It is the foundation on which viable rules of inter-
national law can be built.
Part of these negotiations, in OECD or in the GAPT, could well be directed
toward an agreement on uniform, publicly disclosed, non-discriminatory procure-
ment rules which would open the European government owned or controlled
markets to United States competition. The desirability of such an agreement has
been well stated by The Brookings Institution to the Senate Finance Committee
in connection with its review of U.S. trade policies:
"Government procurement policy seems to be one of the more promising areas
for progress in reducing nontariff barriers. The basic approach that has been
suggested by U.S. officials is to obtain an agreement among governments to pro-
vide foreign producers with the same opportunity to bid on Government contracts
as domestic producers. This would involve such matters as establishing uniform
procedures regarding the announcement of proposed purchases, publicizing re-
quired standards, and publishing the bids that are accepted. Any preference
granted to domestic producers would be explicitly expressed and put in percent-
age terms."
(Compendium .of Papers on Legislative Oversight, Feb. 7, 1968, vol. I, p. 340.)
Thus, with respect to heavy electrical equipment, such suggested agreement
would contain explicit provisions and definitive safeguards followed by all Gov-
ernment authorities for the, purpose of assuring U.S.-manufactured electrical
utility equipment the same access to European governmental markets that Euro-
pean equipment producers now enjoy in selling to the United States Government
procurement authorities.
Certainly too, these ongoing negotiations should focus specifically on the trade
effects of border tax adjustments which are presently export-promoting and
import-restricting for the indirect tax countries. The basic assumptions under-
lying the GATT provisions are open to substantial question, as has been previ-
ously discussed. The full border tax adjustments provided for with respect to
indirect taxes can constitute both an export subsidy and an import surcharge.
Adjustments for indirect taxes should at least be reduced under carefully circum-
scribed conditions, or some comparable advantage granted to countries who do
not enjoy the international trade benefits of the indirect tax system.
B. The inadeqnacy of existing 8tatutory remedies
But proceedings in the GATT and OECD are not enough. An effective and
comprehensive U.S. trade policy requires more: for example, determined and
resourceful utilization of statutory and administrative procedures to cope with
the many facets of international competition and provide timely remedies which
can be invoked to discipline unfair competition on a case-by-case basis. As a
practical matter, however, the available procedures discussed below have not
provided effective relief against the consequences of exclusionary procurement
practices of foreign governments and the dual pricing by foreign suppliers when
selling to governmental agencies in the U.S.
1. Trade Expansion Act of 1962
On its face, Section 252 of this Act (19 USC Section 882) would appear to
give the President broad discretionary authority to take a variety of retaliatory
steps in order to end "unreasonable" or "unjustifiable" foreign import restric-
tions, discriminatory acts and non-tariff barriers. Yet, thus far this statutory
authority has not been invoked nor, so far as we are aware, have U.S. trade
officials encouraged U.S. industries to provide specific information that would
bring its provisions into play. This appears to he a missed opportunity, because
the apparent legislative intent of this Section was to provide a means for execu-
PAGENO="0266"
3702
tive action against precisely the sorts of non-tariff barriers and unfair competi-
tion practices we have faced for many years. Until rules or regulations are pre-
scribed for this statutory authority and initiative taken by the Executive Branch
to exercise the responsibilities vested in the President, Section 252 of the Act
will not accomplish its legislative purpose.
2. Couatervailing Duties
The provision for countervailing duties, Title 19 USC Section 303, recites
that whenever any foreign country or business organization thereof "shall pay
or bestow, directly or indirectly, any bounty or grant" upon the export of any
article produced within a foreign country, and the article is dutiable under the
U.S. Tariff laws, an additional duty shall be levied upon its importation into
the United States "equal to the net amount of such bounty or grant, as esti-
mated by the Secretary of the Treasury."
General Electric suggests the statute be re-examined in the light of the two
types of trade imbalances previously discussed in this brief: dual pricing and
the existing trade advantages of the European tax system.
Admittedly, in none of the reported cases brought under the present Act, or
its earlier counterpart, has evidence of the alleged "bounty" or "grant" been
predicated upon the subsidization of low prices for exports through payment to
the exporter by government owned or controlled purchasers of significantly
higher prices in the home market for the same goods.
In considering whether Section 303 of the current Act could not be interpreted
to cover such a method of subsidizing exports, it is stressed: (1) the statute
proscribes the payment of "any" type of bounty or grant, and covers those made
"directly or indirectly," (2) the bestowal of the pecuniary benefit need not be
made by the government, but by a corporation, partnership, association, or
"any . . . person . . ." Indirect subsidy payments in the form of higher prices
paid by a quasi-governmental body or a government owned utility would ap-
pear to come within the literal scope of the language.
In three early cases, remission of taxes at the border on account of the
exportation of goods was held to be a bounty. U.. v. Passavant, 169 US 16
1897); Downs v. U.s., 187 US496, 47 L. Ed. 275 (1903); Nicholas ~ Co. v. U.s.,
249 US 34 (1919). In the Nicholas case, the Court was strikingly clear on this
point and treated as irrelevant the fact that the goods were sold in the United
States for the same amount as they would have been sold in the United Kingdom
if the latter had imposed no domestic tax.
In spite of the Nicholas case, supra, the position of the United States Treasury
has been that remission of indirect taxes on exports does not constitute a
bounty. Hearings on HR. 1535, Customs Simplification Act of 1951, before the
House Committee on Ways and Means 16 (1951) ; see also The Contracting
Parties to tli e General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, Antidumping and Count-
errailing Duties, 9-10 (1958).
The Treasury's position is undoubtedly influenced by the fact that Section 303
is not literally consistent with GATT Article VI, which specifies that counter-
vailing duties should be imposed only under the following conditions:
1. The purpose of the duty is to offset a bounty or grant bestowed directly
or indirectly upon the manufacture, production or export of merchandise;
(Sec. 3)
2. There is a showing of material injury to an established domestic in-
dustry, or retardation of the establishment of a domestic industry; (Sec.
6(a))
3. The importation is not also subject to an antidumping duty; (Sec.
5) and
4. Provided that: "No product of the territory of any contracting party
imported inito the territory of any other contracting party shall be subject
to antidumping or countervailing duty by reson of the exemption of such
product from duties or taxes borne by the like product when destined for
consumj)tion in the country of origin or exportation, or by reason of the
refund of such duties or taxes." (Sec. 4)
U.S. law as expressed in Section 303, Title 19, USC, contains only the first
condition; i.e., it does not require any showing of material injury, does not
make antidumping and countervailing duties mutually exclusive remedies, and
does not exclude from the bounty or grant category rebates or exemptions of
indirect taxes. Legislation to conform Section 303 to the material injury require-
ment of GATT was introduced but failed to pass the Congress (H.R. 1535, 82nd
Congress, 1st Session).
PAGENO="0267"
3703
At the request of the Contracting Parties, a group of experts has examined
whether remission of indirect taxes upon exportation can be a subsidy or bounty
under GATT. Their report, Antidumping and Countervailing Duties, (GATT/
1961-2) was adopted by the Contracting Parties. They concluded as follows (at
p. 20, supra):
"Eremption from ta~ration does not constitute subsidization
"The Group considered that it was perfectly justified that in conformity with
the procedures of paragraph 4 of Article VI, countervailing duties should not
be imposed on a product by reason of the exemption of such product from
duties or taxes imposed on the like product when destined for consumption in
the country of origin or exportation, or by reason of the refund of such duties
or taxes. If, however, it were established that the exemption or the reimburse-
ment exceeded the real charge which the product would have to pay in the
exporting country, the difference could be considered as constituting a subsidy."
Since the unshifted portion of an indirect tax is by the definition borne by
the producer and not the product, the language of the last sentence of the para-
graph would leave the United States free to treat as an export subsidy a rebate
of either (1) an amount exceeding a. ta.x aetually paid, or (2) an amount repre-
senting the unshifted increment of a TVA tax.
3. Antidumping Act
With the previously described electrical utility equipment being sold in the
United States at less than fair value, an action would ostensibly lie under the
Antidumping Act of 1921 (19 USC 160 et seq). Here, it would seem, is precisely
the sort of self-help remedy that the heavy electrical equipment industry, or any
of its members, should pursue. The statute and regulations, however, require a
finding of material injury or the likelihood of material injury to the domestic
industry. Historically, this requirement has been so interpreted by the Tariff
Commission that the U.S. electrical industry, which has relatively full employ-
ment, increasing production volumes and overall profitability, probably has not
sustained injury within the meaning of the Act.
This observation does not mean General Electric believes the Antidumping Act
should be used as a shield for domestic industry against inroads from fair foreign
competition. To the extent a foreign manufacturer, exploiting advantages in
costs, produ~tivity or innovation, can produce and sell on a non-discriminatory
basis, a product in this country at a price lower than the equivalent U.S.-made
product, U.S. manufacturers must look to the economics of the situation-even
to the extent of shifting production facilities to offshore locations and exporting
to the United States.
General Electric suggests, however, that on the facts developed in this brief the
concept of material injury could be broadened to permit the Tariff Commis-
sion to draw persuasive inference of injury where the dumped sales are in signif-
icant volume and such sales depend upon or are linked to the demonstrable
exclusion of equivalent U.S. products from the home market of the foreign
exporter.
C. Certification
The Brookings Institution proposal described at the outset of our concluding
remarks, has considerable merit and should be considered as one of the methods
for dealing with the dual pricing of heavy electrical equipment. The gravity of
the situation, however, is such that government-to-government negotiation may
not be concluded in time to make such an arrangement an effective remedy~
On a short-range basis, the serious trade imbalance caused by dual pricing
might well be relieved by appropriate governmental action changing existing U.S.
Government Procurement Regulations (e.g., 41CFR, Subtitle A, Chapter 1) to
require foreign suppliers to certify specifically and in a prescribed manner, that
the prices they are quoting are no lower than the comparable prices for like prod-
ucts sold in their respective domestic markets. If the foreign supplier has not
sold such products in his home market, appropriate alternative procurement cer-
tifications could deal with either the supplier's prices to third countries, or the
constructed value of the products as would be defined in the proposed new Pro-
curement Regulations (compare provisions set forth in 19 CFR 14. 7). In view
of the existing U~S. balance of payments problem and the consequent threat to
the national interest from the current price discrimination practices of foreign
suppliers, it seems clear there is ample authority to make such changes in the
PAGENO="0268"
3704
U.S. Government Procurement Regulations. (See for example, Executive Order
No. 10,582; Armed Services Procurement Regulations 32 CFR Sections 6.102,
6.104-4 (1967))
D. UJ~. tao, on value added
The difficulty of determining the quantum of trade advantage that is con-
ferred by a high rate indirect tax with border adjustments is the chief obstacle
to effective international negotiation or acceptable U.S. counteraction. As long
as opinion is widely divided on whether and by how much the United States is
disadvantaged by its primary reliance on the direct net income tax, any U.S. bor-
der adjustments designed to offset such disadvantage can be alleged to be un-
unwarranted and in violation of the GATT. Unless justification for a border
levy can be convincingly shown, retaliatory action by foreign nations can be
expected.
Of the available alternatives, the only border levy clearly exempt from this
consideration would be a border tax and export rebate in support of a U.S. in-
direct tax of the TVA variety. Should the European Common Market adopt a
uniform TVA with a 17% rate, they could not complain if the United States
were to replace a portion of its corporate net income tax with an appropriate
TVA levy and the import equalization taxes and export rebates similar to those
contained in the European TVA laws. A description and analysis of a value-
added tax as part of the U.S. tax structure is contained in a statement by the
Research and Policy Committee of the Committee for Economic Development,
A Better Balance in Federal Taa~es on Business, April 1966, at Page 25 et seq.
As an interim measure until a TVA system can be carefully studied and
worked into the United States tax system, present international agreements
would appear to justify a border tax and export rebate system with a rate equal
to the calculated level of indirect taxes borne by goods produced in the United
States and not now adjusted for at the border. Informal estimates have placed
such a rate at 2-3%. A higher rate, 5% for example, would also be justifiable
under Article XII of GATT if imposed as a temporary measure designed to
alleviate current U.S. balance of payments difficulties.
STATEMENT OF DON A. ELLIs, TREASURER, TEKTRONIX, INC.
Tektronix, Inc., Beaverton, Oregon, is a fairly young, rapidly growing company
in the technology-based field. Tektronix is the world's largest manufacturer of
cathode-ray oscilloscopes, the basic electronic measuring instrument, used by
all electronics companies and many others. Tektronix cathode-ray oscilloscopes
are the preferred measuring instruments, not only in the United States but in
the entire world.
Because Tektronix has been able to manufacture oscilloscopes in the United
States at a cost that would allow them to be sold competitively throughout the
world if there were not trade barriers, the company is a strong advocate for
free trade. It therefore strongly opposes the protectionist tendencies which are
cropping up so frequently lately, and the program to restrict direct foreign in-
vestment.
We are sure you have heard all the arguments favoring free trade and opposing
trade barriers. We see nothing to be gained by attempting to reword and expound
these arguments. We would merely like to point out the obvious: That reduction
or elimination of protective trade barriers will hurt those companies or industries
that are uneconomic and survive only because they are protected. Obviously, also,
the resources used in these industries would better contribute to the prosperity
of this country if applied in a more economic use. Therefore, continuing or in-
creasing protectionism because some company might otherwise be hurt is unwise,
and its logic fallacious.
If there had been free trade in the world the last 10 years, we firmly believe
Tektronix would be supplying a larger share of the world market than at present,
simply by exporting from the United States. Since there were trade barriers,
Tektronix has found it necessary to manufacture outside the United States to
overcome advantages enjoyed by competitors and potential competitors, advan-
tages created by their countries' protective barriers.
Tektronix products are now manufactured within the Common Market, the
European Free Trade Area and Japan. Much of this output results from assembly
PAGENO="0269"
3705
of components manufactured by Tektronix in the United States and exported
to the manufacturing subsidiary.
The following information shows the growth of Tektronix sales; how much of
that was international; and how, even though an increasing porton of the prod-
ucts sold internationally must be manufactured outside the United States, exports
from the U. S. still have continued to increase. It also shows the amount invested
outside the United States to keep Tektronix competitive-including receivables
from customers and retained earnings of subsidiaries.
Year ended May
Net sales
International
sales
Percent
international
Exported
from
United States
Investment
outside
United States
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
j965
1966
1967
1968
44,762,255
50,282,197
60,139,148
70,450,810
75, 502, 572
81,099,088
101,759,192
129,030,753
133,656,005
9,685, 133
12,209,493
14,260,093
18,255,864
22,335,008
25,870,467
30,061,655
35,082, 518
43,487,800
21.6
24.3
23.7
25.9
29.6
31.9
29.5
27.2
32.6
9,095,662
12,567,509
14,636,883
12,199,439
18,271,493
18,212,263
20,475,465
23,477,101
25,844,410
1,722,708
6,711,527
8,014,590
6,694,806
10,095,534
10,754, 121
12,675,550
15,520, 157
19,363,471
We regret we are unable to find reliable information on the total world sale of
oscilloscopes, or even on the total United States sale. Most other manufacturers
are large companies, with oscilloscopes only a small part of their output. If they
announce what portion of their sales are oscilloscopes, we are unaware of it.
Although it is not explicit in the figures, we firmly believe Tektronix exports
would not be nearly so large had we not protected our competitive position around
the world by manufacturing outside the United States. That is, a larger share of
the world market would have gone to unchallenged competItors. We would much
prefer to concentrate all our manufacturing within the United States. We are
convinced that further elimination of trade barriers will increase the proportion
of Tektronix manufacturing that is done within the United States.
If trade barriers were eliminated, and Tektronix manufacturing expanded
within the United States rather than outside it, the company would not be
hampered by the program restricting foreign direct investments. As it is, invest-
ment restriction considerably retards our ability to compete.
We strongly urge that every attempt be made to resist trends toward trade
protectionism, and that all efforts seek to rapidly approach free trade among all
countries.
Mr. FULTON. Our next witness is Mr. Lowe.
Mr. Lowe, we welcome you to the committee and ask that you
identify yourself for the benefit of the record.
STATEMENT OP BERTRAM LOWE, CHAIRMAN, CUSTOMS COMMIT-
TEE, AMERICAN WATCH ASSOCIATION; ACCOMPANIED BYSTAN-
LEY L. TEMKO, COUNSEL
- Mr. LOWE. Mr. Chairman and gentlemen, my name is Bertram
Lowe. I am vice president and secretary of the Longines-Wittnauer
Watch Co. and chairman of the Customs Committee of the American
Walxth Association, on whose behalf I appear.
Unfortunately, Mr. Julian Lazrus, president of the AWA and also
the president of Benrus Watch Co., who was to be with me, was
called away.
Mr. Stanley L. Temko of Covington & Burling is counsel to the
AWA, and he is here with me on my left.
I have a brief statement which I -would like to make at this time,
and a longer statement that I should like to submit for the record,
to be included as part of my testimony.
Mr. FULTON. It will be included.
PAGENO="0270"
3706
Mr. LOWE. The AWA is an association of approximately 50 U.S.
firms which import watch movements and assemble them, utilizing
U.S. and foreign-made cases and other components, into complete
watches for sale in the United States and world markets.
We are here to oppose legislation that would restrict importation of
watch movements either by raising the current rats of duty or by
imposing quotas. In particular, we oppose H.R. 11738, which seeks
to reimpose the escape clause tariff rates on watch movements in effect
for 121/2 years-from July 27, 1954, until January 11, 1967, when
they were terminated by the President. We are also opposed to H.R.
16936 and similar bills, lmown as the Fair International Trade Act
of 1968. We believe that serious economic injury is the appropriate
test for relief from import competition, not share of the market.
Our testimony will show that the decision to rescind the escape
clause rates was made only after a most careful economic study by
the U.S. Government disclosed that the domestic producers have made
a successful adjustment to import competition. It will further show
that the domestic producers are today enjoying alltime record sales
and profits. Significantly, it will show that domestic watch production
increased following the tariff reduction, whereas the number of watches
entering the United States from offshore sources declined sightly. Al-
though we will be able to cover only a part of this material in our oral
presentation, the longer statement we have submitted for the record
provides detailed information on the performance of the domestic
producers and on developments in U.S. watch trade. We believe that
the evidence demonstrates that the domestic producers are competing
successfully, and that they can continue to do so without additional
protection from imports.
PRESIDENT'S DECISION FOLLOWED PAINSTAKING INVESTIGATION
The President's decision of January 11, 1967, to rescind the escape
clause rates of duty on watch movements followed an exhaustive re-
view begun by the U.S. Tariff Commission, on its own motion, on
December 5, 1963. During the more than 3 years that this matter was
under study, the companies which engage in the domestic production of
watch movements had every opportunity to present their case, and
they did so by resort to several administrative procedures established
by Congress as part of the trade agreements program.
First of all, there was the opportunity afforded by the basic escape
clause review itself, under section 351 (d) (2) of the Trade Expansion
Act.
Secondly, in April 1964, some domestic producers petitioned for
additional escape clause relief under section 301 (b) of the Trade
Expansion Act.
Thirdly, in a complaint originally filed in April 1964, and amended
in December 1964, the domestic producers also brought an action
alleging unfair import competition under section 337 of the Tariff
Act of 1930.
Finally, at the request of the President, an investigation was begun
in April 1965, under section 232 of the Trade Expansion Act, into the
issue of whether imports of watch products were threatening to injure
the national security.
PAGENO="0271"
3707
Thus, there were four separate proceedings and four separate in-
vestigations, lasting for a period in excess of 3 years. Had the views
of the domestic manufacturers prevailed in any one of these four
proceedings, it is highly unlikely that the escape clause tariff rates
would have been rescinded. Certainly no one can properly state that
the domestic producers lacked adequate opportunity to present their
views, or that those views received less than thorough consideration.
The President's decision, which was taken only after all four of
these proceedings had been completed, resulted in the restoration of
watch tariffs to the levels established under the United States-Swiss
Trade Agreement of 1936-that is to say, the rates existing before
the escape clause was invoked in 1954. The reductions amounted to
331/3 percent, as compared to the 50-percent reductions agreed to on a
broad range of products in the Kennedy round negotiations. In com-
pensation for the restoration of the 1936 rates, the United States
received equivalent concessions from Switzerland, to the benefit of
U.S. exporters.
It should be noted that despite the restoration of the 1936 rates,
U.S. watch tariffs remain among the highest levied on any imported
product, averaging approximately 40 percent ad valorem equivalent.
It is easy to look at watch tariff disputes as a traditional battle
between the importers and domestic producers. But the structure of
the U.S. watch industry differs from that of other U.S. industries.
All major firms in the industry have substantial facilities abroad and
in the United States, and all add substantial value to their products
here as well as overseas. My company, Longines-Wittnauer, and the
other members of the AWA are importers of watch movements, but
AWA members do not sell watch movements. We sell complete watches.
The value of the imported watch movement represents only a small
percentage of the total cost of the watch.
As the Tariff Commission pointed out in a comprehensive study
of the industry issued in 1947: "The cost of the movement, the only
imported element, accounted for about 36 percent of the total cost
of the importer-assembler, 25 percent of the cost to the retailer, and
12 percent of the price to the consumer."
At the time of that study, in other words, about 88 cents of every
dollar paid by a customer for a so-called imported watch remained
in the United States to pay for goods and services and for the U.S.
duty.
The essential point we want to make today is that the domestic
watch producers have already enjoyed more substantial tariff pro-
tection for a longer period of time than any other American industry
of which we are aware. During this extended period, the domestic
producers successfully made their adjustment to import competition.
In the interest of brevity, I shall skip over most of the detail
appearing in our written statement, but I do want to emphasize
certain key facts:
(1) Domestic watch production was at an alltime high in 1967.
As shown in table 1, consumption of U.S.-made watch movements
rose from 7.2 million in 1954, the year the escape clause increases were
imposed, to 16.6 million in 1967, an increase of 130.6 precent.
As shown in table 2, manufacturers' sales in U.S. durable goods
industries increased 95.6 percent in that span, and manufacturers'
sales in nondurable goods industries increased 87.6 percent.
PAGENO="0272"
3708
Thus, the domestic watch manufacturers have substantially out-
performed U.S. industry in general over the 13-year period.
Watch imports have also increased. Yet, based on the report to
the President issued by the Tariff Commission following its compre-
hensive review of the watch escape clause, action, imports by importer-
assembler firms in 1963 were 10 percent below their 1953 level. On
the other hand, imports of watches and watch movements by the
domestic manufacturers themselves had increased more than 95 per-
cent. The trend is shown in table 3. The Tariff Commission has not
made figures of this type available for years after 1963.
(2) Sales and profits of the U.S. manufacturers were at an alltime
high in 1967. Since the escape clause action of 1954, the watch industry
li as undergone a series of changes which have markedly strengthened
the competitive capability of the firms which produce watch move-
ments domestically. chief among these changes is the growth of U.S.
Time, or Timex, from a relatively unimportant company into the
giant of the industry.
By its own proud boast, U.S. Time is the world's largest watch
company, marketing more than 40 percent of all the watches sold
in the United States. Its sales last year amounted to $201 million,
representing, incidentally, a 40-percent increase over 1966, and a 169-.
percent increase since 1962. Please note that this latest increase of
40 percent came after the tariff reduction, which occurred in January
1967. Forbes magazine recently estimate4-June 1, 1~68-that U.S.
Time last year earned a return on stockholders' equity of 25 percent.
The most recent Fortune 500, reporting on 1967 results, showed only
11 of the 500 largest industrial companies in the United States with
a higher earnings rate on invested capital. U.S. Time is a privately
held company. If it were a public company, it would, of course, be
represented on the Fortune 500. It is ironic that this company-which
sells five or six times as many watches as its closest competitor, and
is substantially more profitable than any other firm in the industry-
should come before Congress and ask to be protected from competition.
The other principal domestic producers are also enjoying unpre-
cedented prosperity, as shown in table 4. Bulova's sales in the year
ended March 31, 1968, were $139.8 miflion, up 13 percent from $123.9
million a year ago. Profits were $4.5 million, an increase of 15% per-
cent from $3.9 million a year ago. The results in the year ended
March 31, 1968, represented an all-time record for the company, the
previous records having been established in the year ended March 31,
1967. Since 1962, Bulova's sales have increased approximately 122
percent.
Hamilton increased its sales during the year ending January 31,
1968, to $68.4 million, a new high, and an increase of 81.9 percent since
1962. Hamilton's earnings were below the record level achieved in 1966
because of-and I quote here from the most recent annual report:
~ * * difficulties with a major military contract involving heavy
training expenses, difficulty in obtaining parts from certain vendors,
and high investment in inventories." First quarter results for 1968
showed an increase of more t.han 45 percent in sales and of about 75
percent in profits from the first ~uart.er of 1967. Hamilton's president,
Richard J. Blakinger. said: "We look for continuing improvement
for Hamilton through the balance of the year. Based on incoming
PAGENO="0273"
3709
orders and operating performance so far, we expect all divisions to
complete the year ahead of 1967 in both sales and profits."
A second major development in recent years has been the marked
trend toward the internationalization of watch production. This trend
has affected the domestic manufacturers as well as it has affected most
other watch producers in the world.
In testimony before the U.S. Tariff Commission in March 1964, a
U.S. Time executive asserted that "the importation of parts keeps our
labor force at work here." He was saying, in other words, the U.S.
Time has taken advantage of international specialization, based on
production of certain parts in its foreign factories, production of cer-
tain other parts in its U.S. factories, and assembly of completed move-
ments for the U.S. market in Puerto Rico, the Virgin Islands, and in
the continental United States. This formula enabled U.S. Time to
achieve the lowest possible unit cost of production, and is one very
important reason for U.S. Time's fantastic success, which has led to a
manifold increase in the company's U.S. employment.
Certainly there is no basis in fact for the subterranean argument
encountered again and again, that U.S. Time could do better by shut-
ting up its U.S. factories and supplying the American market entirely
from abroad. On the pin-lever watches which continue to be the main-
stay of U.S. Time's business, the protection which the company con-
tinues to enjoy since the tariff reduction amounts to approximately 75
cents per unit, which is considerably in excess of anything U.S. Time
could possibly save by producing movements abroad instead of in the
United States.
The simple fact is that today the watch industry has become a
truly international industry. Even though Switzerland remains by far
the largest producer, Swiss and other foreign-based companies, like
those in the United States, are using facilities in a number of nations
to make watthes with components from a variety of sources. I believe
we will see more of this in the future. I also believe firmly that there
will continue to be a large and growing role for the American watch
industry in this picture.
(3) Developments in 1967 confirm that the domestic producers are
capable of competing effectively at current rates of duty. As reflected
iii table 1, domestic production in 1961 reached 16,599,000 units, an
increase of 9.2 percent from the 1966 level. Dutiable imports amounted
to 22,913,000 units, an increase of only 6 percent. Shipments from U.S.
insular possessions, which are entered free of duty under a special tariff
provision, dropped 30.6 percent, to 3,182,000 units, largely because of a
quota imposed by Congress, but also partly because the tariff reduction
reduced the edge enjoyed by insular watch shipments over dutiable
imports.
Thus, in spite of the tariff rollback, which might have been expected
to stimulate imports relative to domestic production, the total number
of watches and watch movements entering the United States from. off-
shore sources-that is, dutiable imports plus shipments from the U.S.
Virgin Islands and Guam-actually declined 1.3 percent last year.
This development substantiated the prediction which the AWA made
in 1954 in its testimony before the U.S. Tariff Commission. We said
at that time that the principal result of restoring the 1936 tariffs
would be to limit production in the Virgin Islands and Guam, and that
95-158 0-68--pt. 8-18
PAGENO="0274"
3710
the domestic companies particularly U.S. Time, would pick up a sub-
stantial share of the market vacated by merchandise from the islands.
Experience has demonstrated that we were correct.
PROPOSED BILL ATTACKS THE BASIC PROCEDtTRES ESTABLISHED BY
CONGRESS
The real issue posed by }LR. 11738 to this committee, it seems to us,
is the integrity of the procedures and guidelines which the Congress
has enacted over the years for the conduct of U.S. trade policy. Surely,
after 1~½ years under the escape clause, and a careful economic review
which documented the successful adjustment of the domestic procluc-
ers, Congress will not arbitrarily put aside the procedures which it
has established, and which have been fully utilized in this case, thus
confirming confidence in them on the part of the trading community.
The existence of fair and dependable procedures is essential to the
reciprocal trade program and to orderly trade relations with the rest
of the world.
Thank you for giving us this opportunity to present our views.
(Mr. Lowe's prepared statement follows:)
STATEMENT OF BERTRAM LOWE, CHAIRMAN, CUSTOMS COMMITTEE, AMERICAN
WATCH ASSOCIATION
My name is Bertram Lowe. I am Vice President and Secretary of the
Longines-Wittnauer Watch Company and Chairman of the Customs Committee
of the American Watch Association, on whose behalf I appear. With me is Mr.
Julian Lazrus, President of the AWA and also President of the Benrus Watch
Company.
The AWA is an association of approximately 50 U.S. firms which import watch
movements and which assemble them, utilizing U.S. and foreign-made cases and
other components, into complete watches for sale in the U.S. and world markets.
Many of our members also import watches. In addition to Longines-Wittnauer,
members of the AWA include the firms which market such well-known brands as
Audemars Piguet, Benrus, Girard Perregaux, Gruen, Lucien Piccard, Louvic,
Movado, Omega, Rolex, Waltham, Wyler and Zodiac.
We are here to oppose legislation that would restrict the importation of watch
movements either by raising the current rates of duty or by imposing quotas.
In particular, we oppose H.R. 11738, which seeks to reimpose the escape clause
tariff rates on watch movements in effect for 121/2 years-from July 27, 1954,
until January 11, 1967, when they were terminated by the President. We are
also opposed to H.R. 16936 and similar bills, known as the Fair International
Trade Act of 1968. We `believe that serious economic injury is the appropriate
text for relief from import competition, not share-of-the-market
Our testimony will show that the decision to rescind the escape clause rates
was made only after a most careful economic study by the U.S. Government
disclosed that the domestic producers have made a successful adjustment to
import competition. It will show further that the domestic producers are today
enjoying alltiine record sales and profits. Significantly, it will show that domestic
watch production increased following the tariff reduction, whereas the number
of watches entering the U.S. from offshore sources declined slightly. It provides
detailed information on the performance of the domestic producers and on
developments in U.S. watch trade. We believe that the evidence demonstrates
that the domestic producers are competing successfully and that they can con-
tinue to do so without additional protection from imports.
THE WATCH TARIFF ROLLBACK FOLLOWED PAINSTAKING ECONOMIC REVIEW
On January 11, 1967, President Johnson rescinded the escape clause rates
of duty on watch movements following an exhaustive review begun by the
U.S. Tariff Commission, on its own motion, on December 5, 1963. During the
more than three years that this matter was under study, the companies engaged
in the domestic production of watch movements had every opportunity, under
PAGENO="0275"
3711
procedures established by Congress as part of the trade agreements programs,
to present their case, not only on the economic issues but also on the subject of
their alleged essentiality to the national defense.
I think it is safe to say that no other industry in the entire history of the
trade agreements program has been subjected to such a painstaking and definitive
exsmination.
First of all, there was the basic escape clause review itself under Section
351(d) (2) of the Trade Expansion Act. Secondly, in April 1964, some domestic
producers petitioned for additional escape clause relief under Section 301(b)
of the Trade Expansion Act. Thirdly, in a complaint originally filed in April 1964
and amended in December 1964, the domestic producers also brought an action
alleging unfair import competition under Section 337 of the Tariff Act of 1930.
Finally, at the request of the President, an investigation was begun in April
1965, under Section 232 of the Trade Expansion Act, into the issue of whether
imports of watch products were threatening to injure the national security.
Thus, there were four separate investigations made, involving three entirely
separate sets of hearings and four separate sets of briefs, rebuttal briefs, in-
formational memoranda, etc. Had the views of the domestic manufacturers
prevailed in any one of these four proceedings, it is highly unlikely that the escape
clause tariff rates would have been rescinded. The application for additional
escape clause protection was unanimously rejected by the Tariff Commission
in October 1964. The complaint of unfair import competition was unanimously
rejected in June 1966. The Tariff Commission completed its work on the basic
escape clause review in March 1965, at which time the Conrndssion's report
became the basis for further studies by the departments and agencies charged
with responsibility for advising the President. This review and the national
security investigation, which also involved extensive inquiry by several depart-
ments and agencies, were completed simultaneously in January 1967. The na-
tional security investigation resulted in a finding that imports of watch products
were not threatening to impair the national security, and the escape clause
review disclosed that the domestic producers had made a successful adjustment
to import competition, as contemplated in the Trade Expansion Act of 1962, and
would not be injured by restoration to the trade agreement rates.
Certainly no one can successfully assert that the domestic producers lacked
an adequate opportunity to present their views or that those views received less-
than-thorough consideration.
The President's action of a year ago January, based on the Tariff Commis-
sion's investigation and upon the advice of the Commerce Department, the Labor
Department, and other government agencies, resulted in the restoration of watch
tariffs to the levels established under the U.S.-Swiss Trade Agreement of 1936-
that is to say, the rates existing before the escape clause was invoked in 1954.
The reduction amounted to 3314k percent as compared to the 50 percent reduc-
tions agreed to on a broad range of products in the Kennedy Round negotiations.
In compensation for the restoration of the 1936 rates, the United States received
equivalent concessions from Switzerland to the benefit of United States exporters.
It should be noted that, despite the restoration of the 1936 rates, U.S. watch
tariffs remain among the highest levied on any imported product, averaging
approximately 40 percent ad valorem equivalent.
Parenthetically, I should explain that watch duties are assessed at so many
dollars and cents per unit, ranging from 750 on a pin-lever movement to $2.70 for
a small, 17-jewel ladies' movement. Additional charges are levied if a movement
is self-winding or adjusted to position and temperature. Watches containing in
excess of 17-jewels were not subject to the escape clause increitses; they are cur-
rently dutiable at $9.67 and are scheduled to be reduced eventually to $5.37~/2
under the agreements reached in the Kennedy Round.
The essential point we want to make today is that the domestic watch pro-
ducers have already ehjoyed more substantial tariff protection for a longer period
of time than any other American industry of which we are aware. The domestic
producers have made their adjustment to import competition. The decision which
the President made in January 1967 was entirely just and proper and should not
be reversed by an act of Congress.
THE EVIDENCE SHOWS DOMESTIC PRODUCERS ARE ENJOYING RECORD PROSPERITY
Turning now to the condition of the industry, at the outset let me emphasize
these key facts; they will be discussed in greater detail later on.
(1) Domestic watch production was at an all-time high in 1967.
PAGENO="0276"
3712
(2) Sales of the domestic manufacturers were at an all-time high in 1967.
Profits of the domestic manufacturers were undoubtedly also at an all-time high
in 1967. The largest domestic manufacturer, Timex, is a closely-held corporation
and is not required to report its earnings publicly. But since Time~r sales have
nearly trebled since 1960 and went up 40 percent last year alone, we think the
assumption is entirely safe. Indeed, Forbes magazine recently estimated that
U.S. Time last year earned 25 percent on stockholders' equity.
(3) Especially striking is the fact that, as indicated, domestic watch produc-
tion increased in 1967 to an all-time high, despite the restoration of trade agree-
ment rates on watch imports. Conversely, the number of watch movements enter-
ing the U.S. from off-shore sources actually declined. A slight increase in dutiable
imports was more than offset by a sharp decline in duty-free shipments from U.S.
insular possessions.
WATCH TARIFF BATTLES ARE BETWEEN COMPETING SEGMENTS OF U.S. INDUSTRY
It is easy to look at watch tariff disputes as a traditional battle between im-
porters and domestic producers. But the structure of the U.S. watch industry
differs from that of other industries. All firms in the industry have substantial
facilities abroad and in the TJ.S., and all add substantial values to their products
here as well as overseas.
My company, Longines-Wittnauer, and the other members of the AWA, are
importers of watch movements. But we do not sell watch movements; we sell
complete watches. The value of the imported watch movement represents only a
small percentage of the total cost of the watch.
As the Tariff Commission pointed out in a comprehensive study of the in-
dustry issued in 1947, "the cost of the movement, the only imported element,
accounted for about 36 percent of the total cost of the importer-assembler, 25
percent of the cost to the retailer, and 12 percent of the price to the consumer."
At the time of the study, in other words, about 88 cents of every dollar paid by
a customer for a so-called imported watch remained in the United States to pay
for goods and services and for the U.S. duty.
While these figures may have changed somewhat in the intervening years,
it continues to be a fact that the operations of watch importer-assembler com-
panies contribute heavily to the Arerican economy. Conversely, the so-called
domestic watch manufacturers are heavily internationalized. Each of theni owns
substantial productive facilities overseas and imports a very large number of
watches, movements, and parts into this country.
Bulova is the largest single U.S. importer. Hamilton is the largest pro-
ducer of watch movements in the U.S. Virgin Islands as well as a very substan-
tial importer of dutiable merchandise. And U.S. Time imports large quantities
of watch parts which it utilizes, together with U.S.-made parts, to assemble
the watch movements its manufactures domestically.
What the controversy over watch import duties involves is a commercial
struggle within the total U.S. watch industry. H.R. 11738 would intervene on
the side of ~ few companies which are prospering by every conceivable measure-
ment of economic performance and which are well able to take care of themselves.
The domestic producers are fond of saying that they could make more money as
importers, implying that they are responding to a higher motive in campaigning
against imports. But what they really want is the best of both worlds. When
Edward T. Carmody of U.S. Time testified before the Tariff Commission in March
1964 in favor of lower duties on imports of watch parts in the pre-Kennedy Round
hearings, he acknowledged that be found himself "in a rather unexpected posi-
tion, that is historically unexpected," and that his request for lower tariffs on
watch parts "might appear at first blush to be a somewhat unusual approach."
Re hastened to assure the Commission that when the escape clause hearings
began on duties for watch movements as opposed to watch parts, "we will be
heard, I hope effectively, in crying against any disturbance of the present tariff
structure in any downward form."
The question that is raised by the proposal to restore the escape clause rates
is whether, with respect to this one industry, ignoring the growth and present
prosperity of the domestic manufacturers, ignoring also the proofs of injury
required under the escape clause. Congress will impose permanently what are
essentially the Smoot-Hawley rates on these products-alone or almost alone
among products in the Tariff Schedules of the U.S. I hasten to add that imposi-
tion of quotas on watch imports would be equally unfair.
PAGENO="0277"
3713
DOMESTIC COMPANIES DOMINATE U.S. MARKET AND SEEK EXCLUSIVE PRESERVE
Such protection is surely unwarranted. We do not know the current figure,
but the domestic watch manufacturers were responsible for approximately (10
percent of U.S. watch sales at the time the Tariff Commission issued its report
to President Johnson in March 1965. In other words, a small handful of firms
accounted for three-fifths of all watches sold in the United States conipared
to two-flfth~ for the hundreds of firms comprising the importer-assembler
segment of the industry. Each of the major domestic companies is larger than
the largest of the importer-assemblers. There are certainly few consumer indus-
tries in which a small group of companies dominates so large a segment of the
market.
In a nutshell, this dispute is about how large a guaranteed market companies
like Timex ought to have. The various studies conducted by the Administration
between 1963 and 1967 demonstrated to the satisfaction of any objective observer
that Timex and the other domestic companies can compete successfully at the
pre-escape clause rates. The Administration was obviously convinced that the
threat to pick up and move overseas is an empty threat. What these companies
are asking for is, very simply, an exclusive preserve.
DOMESTIC WATCH PRODUcYJI'ION HAS INCREASED 130 PERCENT SINCE 1954
We turn now to a more detailed examination of watch industry trends. Even
so, we have-only touched the high points here of a very complicated situation.
As previously indicated, during the 121/2 years while the escape clause tariff
rates were in effect, the domestic watch industry, made a substantial and succes&-
ful adjustment to import competition. A.s shown in Table 1 (attached), apparent
consumption of U.S.-made watch movements rose from 7.2 million units in 1954,
the year the escape' clause increases were imposed, to 16.6 million in 1967, an
increase of 130.6 percent.
I am sorry that dollar figures are unavailable, but it is nevertheless instructive
to compare the 130.6 percent increase in the volume of U.S. watch production
from 1954 to 1967 with increases in sales recorded by other U.S. manufacturing
industries during the same period. As shown in Table 2, manufacturers sales in
U.S. durable goods industries increased 95.6 percent in that span, and manu-
facturers sales in non-durable goods industries increased 87.6 percent. Among
the major subcategories of manufacture, there are only three in which the rate
of increase exceeded 130 percent-instruments, plastics, and electrical machinery
which includes the electronics industry. These three subcategories encompass
most of the real "high flyers" in American industry during the past decade-
and-a-half.
"DOMESTIC" COMPANIES ACCOUNT FOR LARGE PROPORTION OF INCREASED IMPORTS
SINCE 1954
Watch imports have also increased. Yet, based on the report to the President
issued by the Tariff Commission following its comprehensive review of the
watch escape clause action, imports by importer-assembler firms in 1963 were
10 percent below their 1953 level; on `the other hand, imports of watches and
watch movements by the domestic manufacturers themselves had increased
more than 95 percent. The trend is shown in Table 3. No figures of this' type are
available for years after 1963, though imports by importer-assemblers have
probably increased faster than those of the domestic producers in the last couple
of years.
One reason for the decline in imports by importer-assemblers registered during
1963 was the sharp expansion which occurred in that year in shipments of watch
movements entering the United States duty-free from the U.S. Virgin Islands.
The first firm to assemble movements in the U.S. Virgin Islands was Standard
Time Corporation, now a subsidiary of the Hamilton Watch Company. U.S. Time
and Bulova also own subsidiaries in the Virgin Islands, as do General Thne,
Benrus, and Sheffield, among Other mainland companies. Hamilton, Bulova, and
U.S. Time together have quotas to ship about 1.3 million units in 1968 or approxi-
mately 25 percent of the total allotted to the V.1.'
In the last couple of years, dutiable watch imports have increased substan-
tially, primarily as the result of the spectacular growth in the market for ladies'
fashion watches, including pendant watches worn on a chain around the neck and,
more recently, wrist watches in the so-called "mod" or "go-go" styles. As the U.S.
PAGENO="0278"
3714
Tariff Commission has pointed out, imported fashion watches satisfied a new
demand and thus did not compete to any significant extent with domestic produc-
tion. Initially an inexpensive vogue item for teen-agers, fashion watches sub-
sequently caught on as a medium-priced or relatively expensive item of jewelry
for older women. Domestic producers began to compete in this market only after
it was carved out by the importers. The recent increase in watch imports has
certainly not come at the expense of the domestic industry. On the contrary, im-
ports helped to establish an important new watch market in which the domestic
manufacturers themselves are now competing.
DOMESTIC EMPLOYMENT HAS PROBABLY INCREASED SINCE 1954
Employment in watch production fluctuated within a relatively narrow range
from 1954 through 1965 and, at the end ~ the period, was down slightly from the
1954 leveL In 1966 and 1967, domestic watch production increased a total of ap-
proximately 3 million units. Bulova reported in 1967 that its employment was at
an all-time high. Hamilton reported earlier that it had hired 500 new workers in
1965 and anticipated hiring an additional 500 in 196(1. U.S. Time's domestic em-
ployment has trebled over the years. While these increases are certainly not
attributable entirely to watch production, neither are they consistent with the
picture of an aging work force that is being driven to the wall by import
competition.
Statistics recently reported by the Department of Commerce indicated that
employment of production workers in the watch and clock industry rose from
18,308 in 1958 to 22,832 in 1966, up about 25 percent. Much of this increase was
undoubtedly in clock assembly, but it must also reflect increased employment by
watch-importer asselnl)lerS, as well as the stable trend in employment in watch
movement production. In addition, production employment in the watch case
industry rose from 2,227 in 1958 to 3,591 in 1966, an increase of more than 60
percent.
In summary, while we do not have complete figures at our disposal, we believe
that total employment in the U.S. watch industry and its supplier industries has
risen since 1954, probably by a couple of thousand or 10-15 percent
DOMESTIC COMPANIES HAVE STRENGTHENED THEIR COMPETITIVE POSITION SINCE 1954
Since the escape clause action of 1954, the watch industry has undergone a series
of changes which markedly strengthened the competitive capability of the firms
which produce watch movements domestically. Chief among these changes is the
growth of U.S. Time, or Timex, from a relatively unimportant company into the
giant of the industry.
By its own proud boast, U.S. Time is the world's largest watch company,
marketing more than 40 percent of the watches sold in the United States. Its
sales last year amounted to $201 million, representing incidentally a 40 percent
increase over 1966 and a 169 percent increase since 1962. I would remind you
that this latest increase~ of 40 percent came after the tariff reduction which
occurred in January 1967. Forbes magazine recently estimated (June 1, 1968)
that U.S. Time last year earned a return on stockholders' equity of 25 percent.
The most recent Fortvne 500, reporting on 1967 results, showed just 11 of the
500 largest industrial companies in the U.S. with a higher earnings rate on
invested capital. Xerox, to use a familiar bench mark, earned 24.0 percent
and stood 13th on the earnings rate list Among those who trailed Timex: Gen-
eral Motors (17.6%), IBM (17.4%), RCA (17.4%), Litton Industries (16.4%),
Coca-Cola (22.5%), Pfiser (13.9%), Texas Instruments (9.5%), LTV (13.9%),
and Eli Lilly (19.2%), all regarded as exceptionally profitable companies. Ac-
cording to Forbes, U.S. Time's earnings per share have increased 200 percent
since 1962. U.S. Time is a privately-held company. If it were a public company,
it would, of course, be represented in the Fortwne 500.
Forbes recently quoted U.S Times Vice President Robert E. Mohr as saying:
"Labor may be cheaper in Switzerland, but through automation we can keep our
costs down." In view of U.S. Time's growth, its obvious profitability, and its
remarkable dominance of the low price market, no one can seriously question
this company's ability to take care of itself competitively. In fact, it is ironic that
this company-which sells five or six times as many watches as its closest com-
petitor and is substantially more profitable than any other firm in the industry-
should come before Congress and ask to be protected from competition.
PAGENO="0279"
3715
The other principal domestic producers are also enjoying unprecedented pros-
perity, as shown in Table 4. Bulova's sales in the year ended March 31, 1968, were
$139.8 million, up 13 percent from $123.9 million a year ago. Profits were $4.5
million, an increase of 15'/2 percent from $3.9 million a year ago. The results in
the year ended March 31, 1968, represented an all-time record for the company,
the previous records having been established in the year ended March 31, 1967.
Since 1962, Bulova's sales have increased approximately 122 percent. Bulova
officials have stated flatly that the reduction in the escape clause rates "imposed
no economic penalty on the company." The Long Island Newsday last year quoted
Bulova President Harry B. Henshel as saying that Bulova is working at peak
capacity, "particularly at its Long Island plants," where the phenomenally suc-
cessful Accutron is produced for the U.S. market. Bulova officials told stockhold-
ers on June 13, 1967, "in the next two years we will continue to expand our
manufacturing facilities for both watch cases and movements." More recently,
in March of this year, Bulova's national sales manager, Michael D. Roman, fore-
cast that Accutron would be the "leading selling watch brand in the United
States in dollar volume within three years."
Hamilton increased its sales during the year ending January 31, 1968, to $68.4
million, a new high, and an increase of 81.9 percent since 1962. Hamilton's earn-
ings were below the record level achieved in 1966 because of-and I quote ht~r~~
from the most recent annual report-difficulties with a major military contract
involving heavy training expenses, difficulty in obtaining parts from certain
vendors, and high investment in inventories." The annual report forecast "a good
year ~n i~,& anu predicted that ~industry-wide sales of watches probably will
reach new highs." Arthur B. Sinkler, now the firm's chairman, said in 1967 that
Hamilton's factory in Lancaster, Pa., was operating "at near-capacity levels."
First quarter results for 1968 showed an increase of more than 45 percent in
sales and of about 75 percent in profits ($19,240,000 and $414,000 in the quarter
ended April 30, 1968, compared to $13,050,000 and $237,000 in the first quarter
of the previous fiscal year).
General Time, which is a relatively small factor in the watch business though a
major producer of clocks, also achieved record sales of $129.5 million in 1967
and, according to Forbes, boosted sales during the most recent 12-month period
to $132.8 million, a gain of 92 percent since 1962.
Spokesmen for the domestic companies have been extremely optimistic about
the future. Harry B. Henshel of Bulova, in December of 1967, forecast "an
all-time record watch market in the United States in 1968," with an increase in
unit sales of "at least 10 percent during the next 12 months." We have already
mentioned the forecast by Mr. Roman of Bulova regarding his expectation for the
Acoutron. Hamilton's President Richard J. Blakinger, also in December 1967,
predicted that watch sales "should reach a new high of 46 million units and
exceed $1 billion in 1968." He said that "the pace is accelerating as we enter
1968." In announcing his firm's first quarter results for 1968, Mr. Blakinger said:
"We look for continuing improvement for Hamilton through the balance of the
year. Based on incoming orders and operating performance so far, we expect all
divisions to complete the year ahead of 1967 in both sales and profits."
A second major development in recent years has been the marked trend toward
the internationalization of watch production. This trend has affected the domestic
manufacturers as well as it has affected most other watch producers in the
world.
U.S. Time and its affiliates now have factories in England, Scotland, France,
West Germany, Canada, Puerto Rico, and the U.S. Virgin Islands, as well as in
the continental U.S. In addition to producing watches for marketing abroad-
and I would note that, according to U.S. News c~ World Report of August 21,
1.967, Timex now accounts for one-third of the watches sold in Britain, 20 percent
in France, and about 10 percent in West Germany-these factories also produce
parts for incorporation in the watch movements which U.S. Time manufactures
domestically. -.
In testimony before the U.S. Tariff Commission in March 1964, a U.S. Time
executive asserted that "the importation of parts keeps our labor force at work
here." He was saying, in other words, that U.S. Time has taken advantage of
international specialization to achieve the lowest possible unit cost of produc-
tion on the millions of watch movements it produces in the United States. This
technique is one very important reason for U.S. Time's fantastic success and
has led to a many-fold increase in the company's U.S. employment.
PAGENO="0280"
3716
In light of U.S. Time's current position on watch tariffs, it is extremely
interesting that this statement was made by the U.S. Time spokesman at hear-
ings in advance of the Kennedy Round negotiations and was designed to per-
suade U.S. negotiators to grant a full 50 percent reduction in U.S. tariffs on
watch parts, the maximum permitted under the Trade Expansion Act of 1962.
U.S. negotiators did, in fact, agree to a full 50 percent reduction in tariffs cm
watch parts-as contrasted to a 33% percent reduction from the 1930 level
in the tariffs on most watch movements after the rollback. We believe that
U.S~ Time continues to enjoy the advantages of international specialization based
on production of certain parts in its foreign factories, production of other parts
in its U.S. factories, and assembly of completed movements for the U.S. market
in Puerto Rico, the Virgin Island's, and in the continental United States.
Certainly there is no basis in fact for the subterranean argument encountered
again and again that U.S. Time could do better by shutting up its U.S. factories
and supplying the American market entirely from abroad. On the pin-lever
watches which continue to be the mainstay of U.S. Time's business, the pro-
tection which the company con~tinue8 to enjoy since the tariff reduction amounts
to approximately 75 cents per unit, which is considerably in excess of anything
U.S. Time could possibly save by producing movements abroad instead of in the
United States.
The other major domestic manufacturers are also substantial importer-assem-
blers. Bulova has foreign facilities in Toronto, Canada, and in Bienne and
Neuchatel, Switzerland. In 19(30, it acquired majority control of the Recta Watch
Company of Bienne. Also in 1960, Bulova established a new subsidiary, Bulova
International Ltd., in Bermuda to import jeweled-lever watches from the Citi-
zen Watch Company of Japan. Bulova's Caravelle line, utilizing principally
Japanese movements, has become one of the market's major brands in recent
years. In 1967, Bulova acquired Universal Geneve, one of Switzerland's most
prestigious watchmakers. Today Bulova is the largest single manufacturer in
Switzerland and the largest U.S. importer. It also operates a substantial facility
in the U.S. Virgin Islands.
Hamilton established a Swiss manufacturing subsidiary, Ha~mill S.. A., in
1969, and subsequently purchased all the outstanding stock of A. Huguenin Fils,
S.A., of Bienne, which had been Hamilton's major supplier of imported watch
movements since 1952. A Japanese affiliate, the Hamilton-Ricoh Watch Company,
which is 60 percent owned by Hamilton, was established in 1962. In 19643,
Hamilton acquired the Buren Watch Company, a leading Swiss manufacturer.
In addition, in October 1967, Hamilton purchased the Semca Watch Company and
organized a `new subsidiary, Vantage International G.m.b.H. in Pforzheim, West
Germany, to provide watch movements for Hamilton's Vantage line. Additionally,
Hamilton owns and operates Standard Time Corp., the oldest and largest of the
watch firms in the U.S. Virgin Islands.
General Time has subsidiaries in Mexico, Oanada, Brazil, Scotland, and
Hong Kong, as well as in the U.S. Virgin Islands.
In brief, each of the domestic manufacturers has become a major international
company, with world-wide production and marketing facilities. Each is a major
importer for the U.S. market. This trend toward internationalization took place
for the most part after the tariff increase of 1954. It came about, in part, because
higher tariffs shut out inexpensive jeweled-lever watches and opened the way for
Timex to grab the lion's share of the low price market. Timex found a formula
for manufacturing some parts overseas and some parts in the U.S. that enabled
it to take advantage of scale economies in both places. U.S. Time's example, and,
equally important, its challenge in the marketplace forced the other companies,
like Hamilton, to revise their traditional marketing strategy and to broaden
their base of supply. The sudden and spectacular growth of watch operations
in the Virgin Islands added to the ferment, affecting everyone in the industry-
both those who went `to the Virgin Islands and those who did not.
The simple fact is that today the watch industry has become a truly inter-
national industry. Even though Switzerland remains by far the largest producer,
Swiss and other foreign-based companies, like those in the United States. are
using facilities in a number of nation's to make watches with components from
a variety of sources. Already watch movements are made from parts produced
in several countries, assembled in cases manufactured in yet another country.
and completed with bracelets or watch bands made in still another country. I
believe we will see more of this in the future. I also believe firmly that there will
PAGENO="0281"
3717
continue to be a large and growing role for the American watch industry in this
P]cture.
Developments in 1967 confirm that the domestic producers are perfectly capa-
ble of competing effectively at current rates of duty. As reflected in Table 1,
domestic production in 1967 reached 16,599,000 units, an all-time high and an
increase of 9.2 percent from the 1966 level. Dutiable imports amounted to
22,913,000 units, only an increase of 6 percent. Shipments from U.S. insular
possessions, which are entered free of duty under a special tariff provision,
dropped 30.6 percent to 3,782,000 units.
As the Committee knows, shipments from TJ.S. possessions are controlled
under a system of quotas enacted by Congress in 1966. It is important to note,
however, that the decline last year was greater than that required by the quota
system. Because watch movements produced in the islands must be able, in order
to qualify for duty-free treatment, to sell on the mainland for more than twice
the value of their foreign components, the rollback in the tariff on dutiable watch
movements had a substantial impact on insular production. Many watch com-
panies in the Virgin Islands and Guam failed to produce up to their quotas in
1967. In fact, most observers are convinced that if it had not been for the desire
of operators in the islands to keep their production as high as possible in order
to retain their quotas for 1968, insular watch production would have been even
lower in 1967.
Thus, in spite of the tariff rollback, which might naturally have been expected
to stimulate imports relative to domestic production, the total number of watches
and watch movements entering the United States from offshore sources-i.e.,
dutiable imports plus shipments from the U.S. Virgin Islands and Guam-actu-
ally declined 1.3 percent last year. As I pointed out a moment ago, domestic
production in contrast rose 9.2 percent. This development substantiated the pre-
diction which the AWA made in 1964 in its testimony before the U.S. Tariff
Commission. We said at that time that the principal result of restoring the 1936
tariffs would be to limit production in the Virgin Islands and Guam and that
the domestic companies, particulariy U.S. Time, would pick up a substantial
share of the market vacated by merchandise from the islands. Experience has
demonstrated that we were éorrect.
I have dwelt on this point at some length because developments in 1967, fol-
lowing the rollback, tend to prove that the President was entirely right in his
assessment of the industry's situation. That the domestic producers have made a
successful adjustment during the 121/2 years while the escape clause was in effect
is shown by their resilience in dealing with the consequences of the rollback.
Spokesmen for the domestic producers respond by pointing out that there are
fewer domestic watch producers today than there were in 1950. They call atten-
tion to the recent decision of the Elgin National Watch Company to quit domestic
production as evidence that the prosperity of the domestic industry is a false
glow. On the surface, the argument is a highly plausible one. But only on the
surface. The fact that there are only four surviving U.S. automobile manufac-
turers is scarcely a sign that the automobile industry is failing. Nor does the
dominance of General Electric and Westinghouse foreshadow the decline of the
electrical industry.
Elgin got into difficulty because of bad management decisions. Elgin's domestic
production was highly inefficient, utilizing old-fashioned methods and obsolete
machinery. For example, Elgin had cutting machines which cut one tooth at a
time without using automatic feeders. A worker could produce 1,800 parts a day
on these machines. On the modern cutting and milling equipment employed by
Elgin's competitors, a worker can produce 10 to 15 times as many parts. Many
other examples of inefficient production practices could be cited.
In the early 1960's, Elgin also experienced serious financial difficulty because of
what were described as substantial "cost overruns" on defense contracts. The
company lost $13.9 million in the 1962-66 period, and shareholders' equity-that
is, net worth-dropped from $19.7 million in 1963 to $8.9 million in fiscal 1965.
The company's troubles, resulting from an ill-advised attempt at diversification,
sparked a bitter proxy fight leading to the ouster of Elgin's previous management
and the company's complete reorganization. The company abandoned its defense
operation entirely and cut back its sales from a high of $66.2 million in the year
ended February 29, 1964 to $38.7 million in the year ended February 29, 1968.
Indeed, Elgin's sales in fiscal 1968 were 11 percent below fiscal 1962.
With the company in a weakened position financially, the new management
decided that instead of investing in a costly modernization program it would
PAGENO="0282"
3718
shift production to its other plants in the U.S. Virgin Islands and abroad. Elgin's
failure, in short, was a management failure. We see no basis in the Elgin example
for concern about Bulova, Hamilton, or U.S. Time.
PROPOSED BILL ATTACKS THE BASIC PROCEDURES ESTABLISHED BY CONGRESS
Gentlemen, it seems to us that fundamental trade policy questions are raised
by these proposals to limit watch imports, whether by restoring the escape clause
tariff rates or by imposing a ceiling on imports as a prelude to a possible quota.
Last year, American consumers purchased about 43.3 million watches. Of this
total about 16.6 million were U.S.-made, 22.9 million contained imported move-
ments, and 3.8 million contained movements entered free of duty through the
U.S. Virgin Islands and Guam.
The real issue posed by H.R. 11738 to this Committee, it seems to us, is the
integrity of the procedures and guidelines which the Congress has enacted over
the years for the conduct of United States trade policy. Surely, after 12% years
under the escape clause and a careful economic review which documented the
successful adjusted of the domestic producers, Congress will not arMtrarily put
aside the procedures which it has established-and which have been fully utilized
in this case, thus confirming confidence in them on the part of the trading com-
munity. The existence of fair and dependable procedures is essential to the
reciprocal trade program and to orderly trade relations with the rest of the
world.
From the standpoint of the watch industry, I must add that the Herlong bill
would be no less damaging than the proposal to restore the escape clause tariff
rates. Section 5(d) (3) of that bill would require the certification of a ceiling
on imports which supply more than 40 percent of domestic consumption and
have incerased 15 percent since 1960. Since 1960. U.S. watch consumption has
increased more than 90 percent; imports have increased about 75 percent. Al-
though watch imports today supply a smaller portion of the domestic market
than they did in 1960, a ceiling would be imposed by this legislation requiring
a cutback of approximately 1.5 million units from present import levels. In
addition, we are opposed to H.R. 16926 and similar bills because of the admin-
istrative difficulties and inequities which inevitably accompany a quota system.
Thank you for giving us this opportunity to present our views.
Table 1.-Apparent consumption of Uf~.-produced watch mo'vements
[In units]
Year: Volume
1954 7, 183,000
1955 8,358,000
1956 9,286,000
1957 7, 782,000
1958 9,448,000
1959 11,282, 000
1960 9,475,000
1961 9,668,000
1962 11,919,000
1963 12,135,000
1964 11,970,000
1965 13, 609,000
1966 15, 192,000
1967 16,599, 000
~oTE.-Apparent consumption of domestic watch movements represents domestic pro-
duction of watch movements in the U.S. minus U.S. exports of watches containing such
movements.
Source: U.S. Tariff Commission.
PAGENO="0283"
3719
TABLE 2.-U.S. MANUFACTURERS SALES
[Dollar amounts in billionsj
1954 1967 Percent
increase
Durable goods industries $141.9 $277. 5 95.6
Nondurable goods industries 138.3 259. 5 87. 6
Stone, clay, and glass products 7.4 11. 8 59. 5
Primary metals 23.9 42.6 78.2
(Blast furnaces, steel mills) (13. 2) (22. 2) (68. 2)
Fabricated metal products 15.4 25. 7 66. 9
Machinery, except electrical 18. 8 43. 1 129. 3
Electrical machinery 16. 2 40. 9 152. 5
Transportation equipment 37.2 73. 0 96. 2
(Motor vehicles and parts) (21. 8) (42. 2) (93. 6)
Instruments and related products 3. 6 10. 7 197. 2
Food and kindred products 50.6 92.4 82.6
Tobacco products 3.4 5.1 50.0
Textile mill products 11.6 19.2 65. 5
Paper and allied products 10. 5 22. 5 114. 3
Chemicals and allied products 17.9 40. 1 124. 0
Petroleum and coal products 13. 1 21.3 65. 6
Rubber and plastics products 5. 1 13. 3 160. 8
Source: Statistics for 1954 from Business Statistics: 1967, 16th Biennial Edition, U.S. Department of Commerce,Office
of Business Economics, pp. 24-45. Statistics for 1967 from Survey of Current Business, May 1968, p. S-5.
TABLE 3.-IMPORTS BY DOMESTIC WATCH MANUFACTURERS VERSUS IMPORTS BY OTHER IMPORTER-ASSEMBLERS
[In unitsj
Dutiable imports Duitable imports
by U.S. watch by other importer-
manufacturers assemblers
1953 1,925,000 9,950,000
1954 1,911,000 7,106,000
1955 1,903,000 7,452,000
1956 2,070, 000 10, 192, 000
1957 2,246, 000 9,997, 000
1958 1,976,000 8,411,000
1959 2,738, 000 10,734,000
1960 2,804, 000 10,354, 000
1961 2,458,000 10,169,000
1962 3,231,000 10,567,000
1963 13,774,000 `8,971,000
1964 (2) (2)
1 Only the 1963 statistics reflect all imports by U.S. producers. If statistics for 1953-62 were available on the same basis
the effect would be to increase the quantity of imports credited to U.S. watch manufacturers and to decrease the quantity
credited to importer-assemblers by an unknown amount. Undoubtedly, this amount was near zero in 1953 but fairly
sizable during 1962.
2 In 1964, according to the U.S. Tariff Commission, U.S. proucers brought in 4,200,000 units, including both dutiable
imports and shipments from the U.S. Virgin Islands; however, the Tariff Commission did not specify how many were
dutiable imports.
Source: Statistics for 1953-62 based on table 3, sales of products by U.S. establishments in which watch movements are
produced, and table 7, U.S. imports for consumption, U.S. Tariff Commission, Watch Movements, Preliminary Statistical
Data for Use in Connection with Investigation No. TEA-lA-2 (Apr. 28, 1964). Statistics for 1963 from table 7 estimated
U.S. consumption by supplier, origin, and type, 1963, U.S. Tariff Commission, Watch Movements, Report to the President
on Investigation No. TEA-lA-2 Under sec. 351(d)(2) of the Trade Expansion Act of 1962.
PAGENO="0284"
3720
TABLE 4.-DOMESTIC WATCH MOVEMENT MANUFACTURERS FINANCIAL SUMMARY
LIn millions of dollarsj
1968
1967
1966
1965
1964
Bulova (years ended Mar. 31):
Net sales
Net income
$139.8
4. 5
$123.9
3. 9
$99.8
3. 2
$84.2
2. 8
$73.0
2.4
Current assets
Current liabilities
Stockholders' equity
(1)
(1)
(1)
99. 3
41.9
46.4
88.2
32.2
43. 4
74. 0
18.9
41. 3
62. 2
26.3
39. 4
1967
1966
1965
1964
1963
General Time:
Netsales
Net income
$129.5
3.8
$110.8
3.3
$91.6
2.5
$79.9
1.9
$73.6
1.4
Current assets
Current liabilities
Stockholders' equity
(1)
(1)
(1)
(`)
(1)
(1)
42. 4
16.6
32.3
40. 1
14.2
30.9
33. 1
10. 8
29.4
1968
1967
1966
1965
1964
Hamilton (years ended Jan. 31):
Net sales
Net income
$68.4
1.9
$61.9
2.6
- $44.8
2.0
$38.1
1.1
$37.1
.6
Current assets
50.7
40.4
26.8
23.4
23.3
Current liabilities
7.6
12.4
4.3
3.0
7. 5
Stockholders' equity
31. 9
27. 3
21. 4
18. 2
17. 7
1967
1966
1965
1964
1963
U.S. Time:
Net sales
Net income
Current assets
Current liabilities
Net worth
$201. 6
(3)
(1)
(1)
+40
$143. 0
(1)
(1)
(1)
(`)
(2)
(1)
(1)
(1)
(1)
$90.9
5. 4
30.9
13. 3
25.4
$83. 5
4. 0
(1)
(1)
23. 1
1 Not available.
2 U.S. Time Chairman and President Joakim L. Lehmkuhl said that the company's sales topped $100,000,000 in 1965,
according to Newsweek, Mar. 16, 1966.
3 "Well over $10,000,000" or 25 percent of stockholders' equity according to estimate by Forbes, June 1, 1968.
Mr. TJLLMAN (presiding). We thank you very much, Mr. Lowe.
Are there questions?
You have been very helpful to the committee. You have a very fine
paper.
We appreciate your appearance.
Mr. LOWE. Thank you, sir.
Mr. TJLLMAN. Mr. Carmody.
Mr. Carmody, we are very happy to have you before the committee.
STATEME~ OP EDWARD T. CARMODY, VICE ~XRAIRMAN AI~D DI~
RECTOR, TIMEX, THE U.S. TIME CORP.; ACCOMPANIED BY
RONALD MARiSOHING, SECRETARY AND GENERAL COUNSEL
Mr. CARMODY. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman.
Mr. TJLLMAN. For the record, would you please identify yourself
and your colleague and with the understanding your full statement
will appear in the record, proceed as you see fit, sir.
Mr. CARMODY. Thank you very much.
My name is Edward Carmody. I am a director and vice chairman of
the TJ.S. Time Corp., with headquarters in Middlebury, Conn.
PAGENO="0285"
3721
With me is Mr. Ronald Marsching, secretary and general counsel of
the U.S. Time Corp.
We will summarize here the brief we have filed with the committee.
Our company was established in 1857. We make the Timex watch,
and in this testimony I will refer to the Timex group of companies,
including our affiliated companies, as Timex.
Timex has watch factories in the mainland U.S.A., in Middlebury
and Watertown, Conn.; Little Rock, Ark.; and Abilene, Tex. We also
produce watches in Puerto Rico and the Virgin Islands; Toronto,
Canada; Dundee, Scotland; Feitham, England; Pforzheim, West
Germany; Besancon, France; and Hong Kong, and are in the process
of building a plant in Taiwan.
We have research laboratories in Middlebury, Irvington-on-Hudson,
N.Y., and in Scotland, France, and England.
We are the world's largest producer of watches. And from all I have
just enumerated, you might gather that there was not a cloud in our
sky, and wonder why we are here.
Specifically, we are here to support H.R. 11738, which would restore
tariffs on watch movements to the levels prevailing immediately prior
to the action of the President on January 11, 1967, which removed es-
cape clause rates for imported movements, and to oppOse H.R. 17551,
which among other things would permit the President further to re-
duce the tariffs on movements.
It is almost 20 years ago that we began to come to Washington to
plead for the survival of the horological industry in the Umted States,
and to prophesy its eventual extinction unless it was given tariff or
quota protection.
Eighty-five percent of the cost of a watch is labor, and it was ob-
vious to us that with the productivity of foreign labor being the equal
of ours here in the United States, and with foreign labor rates a fraction
of ours here in the United States, there was no place for our domestic
watch and clock industry to go but out.
For whatever consolation it gives us, we have been good prophets.
In 1957 the Waltham Watch Co., discontinued the production of
watches. In 1959, New Haven Clock and Watch Co., went out of busi-
ness. In the same year, Ingraham Co., gave up the production of wrist
watches. In 1963, Precision Time Co., went into bankruptcy. In 1964,
General Time Corp., gave up the production of wrist watches. In that
same year, Elgin Watch Co., which a year earlier had closed its Elgin,
Ill., plant and discontinued all domestic production of men's watches,
discontinued the manufacture of all watches in the United States.
And now Hamilton Watch Co., is planning further restrictions on
the number of calibers it makes in the United States.
So here we are, almost 20 years later, the only domestic manufacturer
of wrist watches which does not also manufacture watches in Switzer-
land. And the only reason we are still here is that our foreign plants
supply us with about half the parts that go into our Timex watches.
This state of affairs, of course, makes the Swiss watch cartel re-
joice-which cartel the U.S. District Court for the Southern District
of New York in 1962 found, in an opinion of over 100 pages, guilty
of violating the U.S. antitrust laws.
And the Tariff Commission reached the same conclusion in its June
1966 report to the President-also over 100 pages.
PAGENO="0286"
3722
And the free traders among us think that this attrition in the ranks
of our industry is a necessary step forward toward the Utopia they
envision, when all tariffs and trade barriers have been abolished.
We do not question the motives of the free traders, but we cannot
understand their lack of concern over who will supply our country-
speedily and in volume-with artillery fuzes and other small and in-
tricate armaments, when they are needed.
The Defense Department, at least the top echelon of the Defense
Department, was of the opinion in 1966 that as to other domestic in-
dustries not presently making such fuzes and armaments:
* * * as a result of the experience they were gaining in the current procure-
ment program to meet Vietnam needs, their capability for making the more
difficult mechanical timing devices used in fuzes and other ordnance items will
increase substaTitially.
Well, said capabilities do not seem to have increased substantially
enough, because, just as they did in World War II and the Korean
action, the Defense Department has had to come back to' what is now
left of the domestic horological industry for `mechanical time artillery
fuzes for Vietnam and this industry is the only industry supplying
them-critically as they have been needed.
In 1964, the Special Preparedness Investigating Subcommittee of
the Committee on Armed Services of the U.S. Senate looked carefully
into the importance of the horological industry to national security.
Their conclusion was forthright, to wit: that the watch industry was
involved in over 90 percent of our missile programs; that it was the
only industry capable of making timing devices for certain nuclear
weapons; that there is a definite need for the industry in the field of
miniature timing devices of many kinds, both for current and emer-
gency production; and t:hat Russia, Red China, Japan, France, and
Germany have been fostering their watch industries, while the United
States allows it to wither.
It would be a foolish prophet who does not heed his own prophecies.
We have, perforce, heeded ours.
For more than 10 years, seeing the apathy of Government toward
the plight of our industry, we have been making ready for the day
when we, too, will have to disappear from this country.
Timex has established the foreign plants I have mentioned above,
has examined the possibilities of establishing plants in six additional
countries, and has bought land in two of them.
We never forget that figure-that 85 percent of the cost of a watch
is labor. And we observe the labor rates not only in Europe, but espe-
cially in Japan, Russia, and Red China, and reflect at the same time
on the additional assistance all foreign watchmakers are offered here
by our descending tariffs.
It takes a long time to make a watch plant in a foreign country
self-contained and profitable. It takes many years just to train the
too1makers required. But we have been working at it. We have no other
choice. We know that, in time, unless we are given, with urgent speed,
help from our own Government, we will have gone the way so many
of our industry have been forced to follow-out.
Thank you.
(Mr. Carmody's prepared statement follows:)
PAGENO="0287"
3723
STATEMENT OF EDWARD T. CARMODY, VICE CHAIRMAN AND DIRECTOR,
TIMEX, THE UNITED STATES TIME CORPORATION
My name is Edward Carmody. I am a Director and Vice Chairman of The
United S~ates Time Corporation of Middlebury, Connecticut-manufacturers of
TIMEX watches. We were established in 1857. We are the world's largest
producer of watches. In this testimony I will refer to TIMEX, including our
affiliated companies, as TIMEX.
TIMEX has watch factories in the mainland U.S.A. in Middlebury and Water-
town, Connecticut, Lii,tle Rock, Arkansas and Abilene, Texas. We also produce
watches in Puerto Rico and the Virgin Islands, Toronto, Canada, Dundee, Scot-
land, Feltham, England, Pforzheim, West Germany, Besancon, France and Hong
Kong and are in the process of building a plant in Taiwan. We have research
laboratories in Middlebury, Irvington-on-Hudson, New York and in Scotland,
France and England.
Specifically, we are here to support H.R. 11738 which would restore tariffs on
watch movements to the levels prevailing immediately prior to the action of
the President on January 11, 1967 which removed Escape Clause rates for
imported movements and to oppose H.R. 17551 which among other things Would
permit the President further to reduce the tariffs on movements. Existing tariffs
on movements which were originally established in 1930 have over the years
been reduced approximately 38% by administrative action. But additional penalty
exists in these tariff rates because they are fixed in amount rather than ad
valorem so that they have in effect been reduced approximately 34% by inflation.
Consequently today's tariffs on movemeuts are approximately 72% lower than
the tariffs in effect in 1930. We will be glad to furnish to the Committee the
statistical data underlying these figures.
I want first to tell you something about our company, then briefly to picture
for you the chaotic condition of the watch industry in the United States, includ-
ing the extent to which it is controlled by the Swiss watch cartel, and finally
the effect upon the national security of depriving this nation of the capacity to
prn(l'~Pr~ n~ fr'nic'~I t~me artillery fuses for the military which are now supplied
only by the domestic horological industry-an industry that will cease to exist
unu~r die pre~ai~ing trenU ot tariffs.
THE BUSINESS OF TIMEX
From its inception in 1857 to the end of World War II, TIMEX had never
manufactured outside the United States.
During World War II, TIMEX was a principal producer for the United States
Government of mechanical time artillery and anti-aircraft fuses as well as such
aircraft instruments as screw jack actuators, hook retractors, shutter controls,
depth controlled gears and oil pressure gauges. At the time of the Korean conflict
TIMEX was the largest producer in the United States of mechanical time
artillery fuses, producing 25,000 fuses per day, in addition to safety devices for
proximity fuses. Today, artillery fuses are produced by TIMEX under govern-
ment contract and various types of timing mechanisms are produced for, among
others, Sandia Corporation, contractor for the Atomic Energy Commission.
TIMEX is now a very substantial supplier of the M-564 and M-565 mechanical
time fuses for the Army. Following World War II, TIMEX resumed the pro-
duction of civilian timepieces and in 1949 introduced TIMEX watches in the
United States. TIMEX at this time makes over 80% of the watches produced in
the United States because our competitors have been compelled to abandon
domestic production due to lower foreign production costs.
In the 1940's and 1950's TIMEX opened plants in Scotland, England and West
Germany, and in 1962 opened an additional plant in France. TIMEX supplies the
entire world deman~1 for TIMEX watches, outside the United States, from its
foreign plants. Domestic plants cannot compete abroad. About 50% of the parts
TIMEX uses in the domestic manufacture of watches are imported from its
plants abroad. The primary purpose of our building plants abroad has been to
insure a flow of parts and movements which would keep us competitive in the
domestic market.
TIMEX employs about 9,000 people in the United States and about 8,000 `abroad.
About 3,500 of these people are employed by us at Little Rock, where we have
received an award from the Urban League for our non-discriminatory employ-
PAGENO="0288"
3724
mont practices and our contributions to race relations. Unfortunately, most of
our negro employees have much less seniority than our white employees and
therefore under seniority requirements they would be the first to go if and when
that labor force is reduced. We are told by the Arkansas State Unemployment
Agencies that there is no employment available locally for those potentially
unemployed persons except domestic work.
THE DOMESTIC HOROLOGICAL INDUSTRY
Since before World War II the watch industry in the United States has been
dominated by the Swiss watch cartel. The nature, character and extent of the
Swiss watch cartel is described in detail first, in an opinion of the United States
District Court for the Southern District of New York, dated December 20, 1962,
United States v. The Watch Makers of Switzerland Information Center, et al.,
in which the Court found the Swiss watch cartel guilty of violating the United
States antitrust laws, and secondly, in a June 1966 Report to the President from
the Tariff Commission (T. C. 177). Each is more than 100 pages long.
Perhaps second only to the South African diamond cartel, the Swiss watch
cartel is probably the most powerful cartel in the world. Its influence is such
that it was able to persuade the Swiss Government to prevail upon the President
of the United States, on January 11, 1967, to withdraw the then existing Escape
Clause rates on watch tariffs of the United States as a pre-condition to the
Swiss Government's participating with the United States and other Governments
in the Kennedy Round tariff negotiations in the Spring of 1967.
Existing tariff rates for watch movements were established by paragraph
367(a) of the Tariff Act of 1930. These rates were very substantially reduced by
concessions in a Trade Agreement with Switzerland (T. D. 48093), effective
February 15, 1936, entered into under the Trade Agreement Extension Act of
1934. Following an Escape Clause investigation by the Tariff Commission, pur-
suant to the Trade Agreements Extension Act of 1951, and on the recommenda-
tion of the Tariff Commission, the President on January 27, 1954 increased the
duties on watch movements by Proclamation No. 3062 to roughly the levels estab-
lished by the Tariff Act of 1930. On January 11, 1967, the President by Proclama-
tion No. 3761 withdrew the Escape Clause tariff rates on watches provided for
by the 1954 Presidential Proclamation and reinstated the tariffs provided for
by the 1936 Trade Agreement with the Swiss.
At least 85% of the watches imported into the United States are from Switzer-
land. Excluding TIMEX's sales, approximately 70% of the U.S. consumption
of watches are watches produced in Switzerland. In the period 1958 through
1967 domestic consumption of watches increased from 19.8 million to 43.3 million,
an increase of approximately 23 million watches. Yet domestic production in-
creased by only 7 million watches (from 9.4 million to 16.6 million). Thus domestic
production accounted for less than one-third of the increased consumption during
that ten-year period. These data are all from official reports of the United States
Tariff Commission.
The specific results of Swiss imports are shown in the following. In 1957 Walt-
ham Watch Company, then a domestic manufacturer of watches, discontinued
the production of watches. In 1959 New Haven Clock and Watch Company, then a
domestic manufacturer of watches, went out of business. In 1959 Ingraham Com-
pany, then a domestic watch manufacturer, discontinued the production of wrist
watches and continued domestic production only of pocket watches. In 1963
Precision Time Company, a manufacturer of wrist watch movements, went into
bankruptcy, and its plant and equipment were sold in 1964. In 1964 General Time
Company discontinued the manufacture of wrist watches in the United States,
continuing the domestic manufacture of only pocket watches. In 1963 Elgin Na-
tional Watch Company closed its Elgin, Illinois plant and trhnsferred its watch-
making facilities to a new plant in Elgin, South Carolina, for the announced pur-
pose of reducing production costs. But in 1964 Elgin discontinued all domestic
production of men's watches and in 1967 Elgin discontinued the manufacture of
all watches in the United States-although its South Carolina plant was but four
years old.
The day following the President's January 11, 1967 reduction of tariffs on
watch movements, Hamilton Watch Company issued a press release stating:
"The action taken by the President yesterday will not benefit American con-
sumers for through this action the United States will be dependent on foreign
cartel-controlled sources for watches.
PAGENO="0289"
3725
"So far as the Hamilton Watch Company's future is concerned, Hamilton
fully protected for its sources of supply through both foreign and domestic manu~
facturing facilities. During the past eight years, we have had watch manufactur-
ing capacity in Switzerland, Japan, and the U. S. Virgin Islands. At the present
time, about 40% of the Hamilton watches sold in the United States are manu-
factured in our factories in Switzerland. We must, as a result of the President's
action, anticipate a gradual incr~ase in foreign manufacturing and a lessening of
our watchmaking activies in the United States."
As of this date Hamilton reports that it is planning further restrictions in the
numbers of calibres it makes domestically.
In the United States today there are but three manufacturers of wrist
watches-(1) TIMEX, (2) Hamilton and (3) Bulova-originally a Swiss watch
manufacturing company which came to the United States some years ago and
now manufactures watches both in Switzerland and in the United States. TIMEX
is the only domestic manufacturer of wrist watches that does not also manufac-
ture watches in Switzerland. In the last ten years TIMEX has been forced com-
petitively to make half the parts abroad which it uses in its domestic watch pro-
duction.
Neither Elgin, which gave up all domestic wrist watch production since the
President reduced watch tariffs on January 11, 1967:, nor Hamilton imported any
watches prior to 1950.
As early as July 1963 the Tariff Commission, apparently ignoring the effect on
domestic employment, unanimously found that the losses domestic companies
would incur by liquidating their domestic plants would "be partly or fully offset
by increased profits arising from increased import operations."
The United States District Court's 1954 decision in the Swiss Watchmakers
case found in part:
Since at least 1931 and continuing to date, the defendants (the Swiss cartel and
certain domestic importers of Swiss watches) have been engaged and are engaged
in a combination and conspiracy to restrain unreasonably the foreign and inter-
state trade and commerce of the United States in the manufacture, import, export
and sale of watches, watch parts and watch-making machines in violation of
Section 1 of the Sherman Act and Section 73 of the Wilson Tariff Act.
The Court further found:
The United States watch industry was the Swiss watch industry's biggest
competitor, and the restrictions of the Convention 1 have obviously had a crippling
effect in this country, and were so intended.
The Court cited examples of the cartel injury to the domestic watch industry
including an agreement under which Benrus Watch Company agreed to liquidate
certain of its United States watch making facilities which had been converted
to war production during World War II.
Despite the injunctions in the District Court's decree against the cartel, the
primary source of watches supplying the domestic market is still Switzerland-
excluding only that portion of the market supplied by TIMEX.
While TIMEX, Bulova and Hamilton are the only remaining domestic wrist
watch manufacturers, and Hamilton and Bulova also manufacture in Switzer-
land, the cartel continues to expand its control over firms distributing watches
in the United States. In recent years the cartel has acquired substantial shares
of stock in both Elgin and Gruen. In 1968 financial publications report on nego-
tiations by the cartel to acquire shares in Waltham Watch Company and Bulova
Watch Company. See in particular Forbes Magazine for June 1, 1908.
It is interesting to compare what has happened to the watch industries of the
w-orld since the end of World War II. In 1948 the United States produced 14.3
million watches, in 1963 12.3 million watches, while in 1967 it produced 16.6 mil-
lion watches. In 1948 the Soviet Union produced 4 million watches, while in
1963 it produced 27 million watches (and The New York Times says its 1967
production was 40 million watches). Switzerland increased its watch produc-
tion between 1948 and 1963 from 24 million to 45 million watches. Japan's
watch production was 0.6 million in 1948 and 12 million in 1963. Red China which
produced no watches prior to World War II (1948 figures are not available) pro-
duced 8 million watches in 1963. In the period 1948-1963 world production of
watches increased 250% from 49 million to 123.8 million while United States
production of watches declined 15%. These data are from hearings before a Sub-
committee of the Senate Armed Services Committee, on August 17, 1964, p. 285.
1 Which comprised the rules and regulations of the Swiss watch cartel.
O~i-159-6S-pt. S-19
PAGENO="0290"
3726
From the earliest days of mechanized warfare nations have recognized the~
importance of their horological industries to national defense. Only the UnitedL
States seems oblivious.
In commenting on the great growth of Soviet Russian watch production since-
World War II, a 675% increase between 1948 and 1963, it is pertinent to note
an article in the Sunday New York Times of February 18, 1968 which states that-
Russia sold 40 million watches in 1967 (up 50% from 1963, and 1000% from
1948). That article in The New York Times further reports that Russian-made-
watches are entering the United States duty free through the Virgin Islands,
under the tax loophole that permits the duty to be avoided when certain minimal
assembly operations take place in the Virgin Islands. It is true that Russian
watches are `thus being imported into the United States duty free. That article,.
however, er~oneously gives the impression that Russian watches are thus being:
imported into the United States and sold by TIMEX under the TIMEX trade-
mark. TIMEX is not importing and has not imported into the United States any
watches or watch movements, or watches or watch movements made from parts
originating in Soviet Russia, either through the Virgin Islands or otherwise..
NATIONAL SECuRITY INTERESTS
A Special Preparedness Investigating Subcommittee of the Committee on
Armed Services of the United States Senate reported on December 23, 1964, on
the importance of the horological industry to national security. The report.
addresses itself "to the relationship and importance of the domestic watch in-
dustry to our national defense and space programs." The report further states.
that "it is the conclusion of the Subcommittee that the domestic watch industry,.
now making a significant contribution to our missile, space and other military
programs, is important to the national security of the country."
The report showed: (a) that the watch industry was involved in over 90%
of our missile programs, (b) that it was the only industry capable of making:
timing devices for certain nuclear weapons, (c) that there is a definite need for
the industry in the field of miniature timing devices of many kinds, both for
current and emergency production, and (d) that Russia, Red China, Japan,.
France and Germany have been fostering `their watch industries while the
United States allows its to wither.
An investigation of a similar character today would show not only that which.
the Senate Committee found in 1964, as to the need for this industry for na-
tional security, but substantial deterioration since then in the health of the
industry and in its capacity to protect the national security in future times of need...
The vast majority of the critical machinery and `trained operators in the
United States needed for fuses and safety and arming devices are in the domestic
watch industry. Even today the United States is required to import from abroad'
a substantial part of its fuse requirements. As early as 1966 between 150 million
and 200 million small gears and pinions were being procured abroad because of
domestic shortages of special screw-machine capacity and deliveries of the
XM-92 mortar fuses were than being held up because of delays in the delivery
of Swiss parts. This situation has prevailed in spite of the fact that a very sub-
stantial part of the domestic watch industry is currently at work on the nation's.
defense needs.
In World War II the watch industry made very substantial contributions to
defense requirements. Following World War II, the skilled workmen who pro-
duced those military timing devices returned to the manufacture of watches
where their skills remained available to national security. In the Korean War'
again the watch industry made similar contributions and when that war ended
those skilled workmen were able to return to the production of civilian watches.
The industry has made and is making similar contributions to our military en--
gaged in Vietnam. But if there is no domestic watch industry, because domestic
manufacturers cannc~t compete with foreign producers, there will be no trained
pool of watch makers available to the nation in the event of a future need for~
timing devices to meet the security requirements of the country. Only by the
maintenance of a healthy domestic watch industry can these skilled craftsmen
be available when needed for the nation's security.
Three examples of emergency requirements of the nation being met by the'
watch industry are the safety and arming device for the proximity fuse used'
in Korea and the safety and arming device for the XM-423 and XM-427 fuse
for `the 2.75 inch rocket for helicopters and jet use in Vietnam. These were
PAGENO="0291"
3727
developments or modifications of stockpile items to meet new requirements and
specifications. In all three instances the watch industry met the emergency need.
Non-watch companies were brought in later-two years later-as to the XM423
and XM-427 fuses for additional production.
Even were the Federal Government to "mothball" plants for emergency tim-
ing device needs, there is no way to mothball the skilled work force needed
to produce such timing devices.
On February 26, 1966, then Secretary of Defense Robert McNamara wrote
the Acting Director of the Office of Emergency Planning with respect to the
national security aspects of the watch industry. Secretary McNamara concluded
that: "The United States watch industry has been an important and responsive
source for horological-type items used in rockets, missiles, and ammunition, as
well as a supplier of watches, chronometers, and other items." The Secretary
noted the domestic production of watches had declined in spite of "escape
clause" tariff rates and he predicted a further decline in domestic production,
thus proving, in our opinion, that even with the "escape clause" rates, watch
tariffs were too low to protect the domestic industry since that decline in domestic
production of watches was' in the face of a very substantialgain in domestic watch
consumption.
The Secretary commented that companies not now Involved in watch mak-
ing were a growing source of capability for horological-type items and that "as
a result of the experience they were gaining in the current procurement program
to meet Vietnam needs, their capability for making the more difficult mechanical
timing devices used in fuses and other ordnance items will increase substantially."
The Secretary was referring to the production of timing devices by non-watch
making firms which devices had been developed and initially produced by watch
making firms. Thus, while non-watch making firms during the six years since the
Vietnam action began have acquired a certain capability to produce these fuses,
they will return to the production of non-watch commodities at the cessation
of hostilities and if the domestic watch industry should cease to exist, then in
the event of a future emergency requiring these skills there will be no existing
pool of skilled workers or machinery possessing the capabilities necessary to fill
those security needs.
TIMEX `therefore vigorously urges the enactment of H.R. 11738 to protect
what is left of the domestic watch industry and vigorously opposes H.R. 17551
to the extent it can be used further to reduce watch tariffs not only because of the
bill's national security implications but in `the interest of keeping alive a domestic
watch manufacturing industry and in the interest of its employees.
For us, moving abroad will mean embarking upon hazardous ventures, for our
employees, loss of employment and for our national defense, a serious elimina-
tion of an important source of military mat~riel.
Mr. TJLLMAN. Does that complete your testimony?
Mr. CARMODY. That completes my testimony.
Mr. TJLLMAN. Are there questions?
Thank you very much, sir; for your appearance before our com-
mittee. We appreciate your testimony.
(The following letters and statement were received, for the record,
by the committee:)
AMERICAN WATCH ASSOCIATION, INC.,
New York, N.Y., July 11, 1968.
Hon. WILBUR D. MILLs,
Chairman, House Committee on Ways and Means,
Longworth House Office Building,
Washington, D.C.
DEAR MR. CHAIRMAN: The American Watch Association would like to comment
for the record on several issues raised by Edward Carmody of U.S. Time Corpo-
ration in his testimony of June 25, 1968, favoring an increase in tariffs on watch
movements:
1. Mr. Carmody's charges relating to alleged violations of U.S. antitrust laws
by the Swiss watch industry concern conditions and practices which date from
before 1954 and which no longer affect the U.S. watch market. Mr. Carmody
neglected to point out that a final judgment of the U.S. District Court in New
York, entered on February 3, 1965, dealt fully with these past violations of U.S.
antitrust law and precluded their repetition. The imposition of any future re-
PAGENO="0292"
3728
strictions on United States domestic or foreign commerce in watches, watch
movements, watch parts and watchmaking machinery was specifically prohibited.
The Court's authority to enforce this judgment under its contempt powers,
and the Justice Department's broad investigatory authority under the judg-
ment, assure that the Court's orders will continue to be carried out. Indeed, the
Department of Justice, in a memorandum to the Court dated December 4, 1964,
stated that this judgment effectively assures "free and open competition" in the
U.S. watch market, and achieves "the economic and basic antitrust objectives
sought by the Government in this action."
Mr. Carmody's references to the findings of the U.S. Tariff Commission in the
Section 337 case are simpiy incorrect. The Commission's June 1906 report stated
flatly:
"The record before the Commission does not disclose that time respondents (i.e.,
the importers and the Swiss industry) are engaged in a combination or con-
spiracy to restrain or monopolize trade and commerce in the United States. There
is no evidence of current application of the `cartel's' restraints to importations
into, or sales in, the United States. Nor is there evidence that the Swiss watch-
makiig industry, or any of its elements, have monopolized or are presently con-
spiring or otherwise attempting to monopolize United States trade and commerce
in watches, watch movements or watch parts. As a consequence, no basis exists
for a recommendation by the Commission that the President, pursuant to Section
337, order the exclusion of articles from entry into the United States." The Com-
mission's finding was unanimous.
Concerning the Court's decision in the antitrust case, the Commission observed
specifically that "the conditions found by the Commission currently to exist differ
materially from those determind by the Court to have prevailed in the past."
As indicative of the changed situation, the Commission pointed to "the steps
certain of the respondents in this investigation have taken at the instance of
the Court to remove restraints on U.S. trade and commerce from their agreements,
and the inhibitions placed upon them by the Court's final order."
In short, contrary to the views imputed to the Tariff Commission in Mr.
Carmody's statement, the Commission's report explicitly rejected the claims of
the domestic producers that U.S. antitrust laws are being violated by the Swiss
watch industry, and accordingly the petition of the domestic manufacturers for
relief under Section 337 of the 1930 Trade Act was unanimously denied.
2. Mr. Carmody's discussion of the role of the domestic watch manufacturers
in production of defense items is similarly misleading. Mr. Carmody failed even
to mention the fact that the domestic watch industry's national security argument
was rejected by the Office of Emergency Planning following a thorough investiga-
tion instituted in April 1965 at the request of the President. (The same con-
clusion incidentally, was reached following an earlier investigation by the Office
of Defense Mobilization begun in 1955 arid completed in 1958.)
Governor Farris Bryant, the Director of the O.E.P., wrote the President on
November 14. 1966: "I have concluded that watches, watch movements, and watch
parts are not being imported into the United States in such quantities or under
such circumstances as to threaten to impair the national security. I have also
concluded, based on the studies and judgments of the interested defense agencies,
that the domestic watch manufacturers will be likely to continue production of
defense materials for the foreseeable future, that the non-horological industry
now has and will continue to have a role in the production of essential military
timing devices, and that horological-type defense items will continue to be avail-
able from one source or another without regard to the level of imports of watches,
movemnents and parts."
Mr. Carmody did refer, however, to the report submitted to O.E.P. by Secre-
tary of Defense Robert MeNamara. He conveyed the impression that the Defense
Department agreed with the claims of the domestic producers. Mr. Carmody
quoted Secretary McNamara out of context, however. In point of fact, the De-
fense Department reached a conclusion precisely opposite to Mr. Carmody's.
Immediately following the statements quoted by Mr. Carmody, Secretary
MeNainara went on to say:
"Termination of domestic watch production, in whole or in part, if it occurs
at all, will not take place at a given moment in time but rather over a period
of time. During this period the Defense Department can make plans for dealing
with the developing situation. The Department considers it unlikely that all do-
mestic production of w-atch movements would cease.
"Defense requirements, while an uneven source of sales volume for the watch
companies, have nevertheless been a continuing source. These requirements will
PAGENO="0293"
3729
continue for the foreseeable future and should constitute an important source
of volume for the watch companies of particular interest to them should domestic
production of watches decline.
"In the interest of preserving both a quick reaction capability and a mobiliza-
tion base, the Defense Department can under Exception 16 to the Armed Services
Procurement Regulations confine contract awards for horological type items to
watch companies or other companies capable of making the needed items.
"The watch industry is currently up to capacity in military production which
necessitated a continuing introduction by the Department of non-watch com-
panies as producers of these items. Companies outside of the watch industry are
a growing source of capability for the horological-type items produced by the
watch industry and are currently able to meet the peak mobilization requirements
for safety and arming devices. As a result of the experience these companies are
gaining in the current procurement program to meet Vietnam needs, their
capability for making the more difficult timing devices used in fuzes and other
ordnance items is increasing su:bstantially, there is a basis for believing that
they would be able to meet peak mobilization requirements for mechanical timnmg
devices as well as safety and arming devices.
"If necessary, the Government could establish an in-house capability for mak-
ing critical components in the event that circumstances disclose that they cannot
be obtained from either the watch or non-watch companies. The Department does
not believe, however, that such an alternative is likely to become necessary in
view of the broad capability of American industry.
"Over the long run the current dependence upon mechanical timing devices for
rockets, missiles and ammunition in general may be reduced if mion-mechanical
devices based on chemical or electronic techniques prove to be feasible.
"In the area of research and development, the Department's principal use of
the industry has been in the developmental area, particularly in production engi-
neering. Fuze design philosophy, conception, engineering design and other phases
of invention are ordinarily done in the Department's own arsenals and labora-
tories. Although technical know-how and equipment is, to a minor degree, avail-
able in-house for prototype production, it is customary to use private industry for
this work. The watch industry relies on its production resources to support its
capabilities in developmental work. While these companies have contended that
loss of production facilities would result in an impairment of developmental
resources, the continued requirement for a defense production base should prevent
any diminution in these capabilities in the foreseeable future.
"In the light of the above, the Department cannot assert that the continued
importation of watch movements will threaten to impair the national security,
because action will be taken to assure a source of production with or outside the
watch industry."
It is worth noting also that the O.E.P. report expressed substantial doubt that
watch production and defense production are interdependent, as claimed. Gov-
ernor Bryant observed that U.S. Time's own non-watch capabilities "are of such
a nature and size as to be largely self-sustaining." In other words, it was O.E.P.'s
judgment that U.S. Time's own defense production was largely unrelated to
watch production. Similar observations about the separability of defense produc-
tion and watch production were made with respect to General Time and Ingra-
ham. Attached for the Committee's files is a copy of the entire O.E.P, report.
3. Mr. Carmody notes that several U.S. companies have discontinued domestic
watch production during the past 15 years, but he neglects to mention that com-
petition from U.S. Time, not imports, was the principal factor in the decision
of most of these companies to abandon domestic production. U.S. Time's rise
to dominance in the watch market came at the expense of many other firms,
just as General Motors' rapid growth was accompanied by the failure of many
of its competitors. The analogy to the automobile industry is carried through
in the sales and profits performance of the three domestic wrist watch producers,
As I testified, in spite of the restoration of the pre-1954 watch tariff rates, do-
mestic watch production is at all-time high; the sales of the domestic producers
are at an all-time high; the profits of the domestic producers are at an all-time
high. These are the incontestable facts which rebut Mr. Carmody's testinionv.
We would be grateful if you would include this letter in the record of the
June 25 hearings.
Very truly yours,
BERTRAM LOWE.
Attachment
PAGENO="0294"
3730
EXECUTIVE OFFICE OF THE PRESIDENT,
OFFICE OF EMERGENCY PLANNING,
Washington, D.C., November 14, 1966.
MEMOBANDUM FOR THE PRESIDENT
INTRODUCTION
In April 1965 the Director of the Office of Emergency Planning, at your request,
ordered an investigation under Section 232 of the Trade Expansion Act of 1962
to determine whether or not watches, movements and parts are being imported
into the United States in such quantities or under such circumstances as to
threaten to impair the national security.
Notice of the investigation was published in the Federal Register on April 8,
1965. A press release of the same date announcing the investigation invited all
interested parties and organizations to submit their comments and views within
the time prescribed by OEP Regulation 4.
Initial briefs, statements and rebuttal material were filed for the record of this
investigation by the Bulova Watch Company, Hamilton Watch Company, Elgin
National Watch Company and General Time Corporation on behalf of the domestic
watch manufacturers, and by the American Watch Association for the U.S.
watch importers.
Two other domestic watch manufacturers, the ilLS. Time Corporation and the
Irigrahain Company, did not submit their views for the record of this investi-
gation.
The import products encompassed in the investigation included watches and
watch movements of jeweled and pin-lever construction and watch parts.
The domestic watch' indvstrji
The domestic watch industry consists of the manufacturing segment produc-
ing watches and watch movements of both jeweled and pin-lever construction,
and of some 200 firms which import movements and assemble watches for sale
in the United States and world markets.
The manufacturing segment consists of six companies. Of these, Bulova, Elgin,
and Hamilton produce mainly jeweled-lever movements, and General Time, U.S.
Time, and Ingraham produce pin-lever movements. Since 1961 U.S. Time had also
been producing watches incorporating a 21 jeweled-lever movement differing
somewhat from a conventional jeweled-lever movement. The pin-lever movements
produced by U.S. Time are assembled domestically from an admixture of im-
ported and domestic parts.
General Time and Ingraham, at present, produce only pin-lever pocket watches
and clocks. Elgin's production is now limited to ladies jeweled-lever wrist
watches.
Currently, Bulova and Hamilton also produce watch movements powered by
miniature electric cells, and U.S. Time is marketing a watch incorporating an
imported movement powered by an electric cell.
All of the domestic watch manufacturing companies, with the exception of
Elgin. are engaged in varying degrees, in the production of components utilized
in military ordnance, missile and space programs. By May 1965, Elgin had com-
pleted or discontinued work on all Government contracts and had sold nearly
all of the machinery and equipment used in such production.
U.S. consumption, production, and imports
Apparent U.S. consumption of watches incorporating both jeweled and pin-
lever movements has increased substantially during the past decade, reaching an
annual average of over 26 million units in 1962-64, as compared with some 16
million in 1954. The 1965 consumption reached an all-time high of over 34 mil-
lion units, an increase of some 25 percent over 1964. Consumption figures are
understated by watches brought in by tourists or smuggled into the U.S. custom
territory. Of the 1965 consumption total, some 18 million units were sold by the
six domestic companies, and some 16 million by the more-than-200 firms in the
importer-assembler segment of the industry. The Tariff Commission in a report
to the Senate Finance Committee estimates that consumption during 1966 will
reach 42,000,000, up some 22 percent from 1965.
The increase in quantity consumed since the beginning of the last decade
was almost entirely of watches incorporating pin-lever movements. However,
since 1961 there was a significant upward trend in the consumption of jeweled-
PAGENO="0295"
3731
-lever watches, particularly in the lower price ranges imported from abroad and
the U.S. Virgin Islands.
U.S. production of all movements increased from 7.4 million in 1954 to
about 13.7 million in 1965. The trend, however, of U.S. production of jeweled-
lever movements declined from 1.7 million units in 1954 to 1.3 million in 1965.
During the past decade domestic jeweled-lever production has tended to become
concentrated on over-17-jewel movements. The demand for less expensive watches
-has been met by imports from the companies' overseas facilities or other sources.
The over-17-jewel movements have never accounted for a significant proportion
-of the imports, apparently because the high import duty in effect on such
movements substantially precludes import competition. In recent years two of
the major jeweled-lever producers, Hamilton and Bulova, have been concen-
trating on developing the production and marketing of electronic and electric
watch movements for which no competitive imported product is being marketed
in the U.S. to any substantial degree. Their production and sales of movements
-of this type are still a minor portion of their production and sales of conven-
tional type movements.
The aggregate imports in the period 1954-1964 (including shipments from
the Virgin Islands which began in 1959) did not show any appreciable upward
-or downward trend, accounting for an average of about 55 percent annually
of apparent domestic consumption. In 1965 the ratio was about 60 percent.
The major companies in the domestic watch manufacturing industry have
in recent years acquired or expanded facilities abroad and in the Virgin Islands
for producing movements. Bulova, Hamilton and Elgin, which also own or
control a number of foreign plants in Switzerland or Japan, have in recent
years accounted almost wholly for the increase in U.S. imports of jeweled-lever
movements. Each of these companies imports watch movements in quantities
exceeding several times its domestic production. In 1964 these three companies
accounted for about 46 percent of the total imports.
U.S. Time and its affiliates operate foreign plants in England, France, West
Germany, Scotland, Puerto Rico, Canada and Hong Kong. Its domestic output
-during the past decade increased very substantially and now accounts for prac-
tically the entire domestic production of pin-lever watches.
General Time in addition to its domestic plants owns or -controls a number
of foreign subsidiaries. The Ingraham Company has a fabricating and an assem-
bly plant in the United States and through a subsidiary operates a pocket watch
~assembly plant in Canada.
While some parts incorporated in domestically produced movements are im-
ported, such imports are not significant except for U.S. Time. The latter has
been importing since 1955 an increasing share of parts for use in the assembly
of its domestically produced movements. Some of the other jeweled-lever pro-
-ducers have been importing from time to time some parts for their domestic
production of movements. All domestic producers are importing jewel bearings.
Since 1959, the Virgin Islands became an important source for shipments to
the United States of 17-jewel movements. The movements are assembled from
foreign-made parts or subassemblies imported into the Islands at a very 1-ow rate
-of duty. The assembled movements or complete watches are shipped to the United
*States duty-free if they do not contain foreign materials having a landed cost
-of more than 50% of the appraised value of the movements. The 1965 shipments
from the Islands were almost three times the number of jeweled-lever move-
nients produced in the U.S. during that year. In 1966, sixteen companies were
assembling watches in the Islands. Five of the plants are owned by Bulova,
Elgin, Hamilton, General Time and U.S. Time, and at least five of the other
ten plants are owned by major U.S. watch importers. In August 1965, the Gov-
ernment of the Virgin Islands instituted a quota system through the imposition
of a production tax of $2.50 on each watch movement manufactured in the Islands
for shipment to the United States in excess of a stipulated quantity. Beginning
April 1, 1966, this tax applies to each movement in excess of annual quantity
equal to one-ninth of the U.S. consumption of watch movements. In 1966 the
Virgin Islands District Court invalidated the methods used for enforcing
this quota. -
Late in 1965 a watch movement assembly plant was established in Guam.
Duty-free shipments from that plant to the U.S. customs territory began in
November 1965.
In October, this year, Congress passed legislation limiting shipments from
U.S. insular possessions to ~th of the total U.S. watch consumption-7/s ths to
PAGENO="0296"
3732
be allocated to the Virgin Islands, while the remaining 1/~ to be divided in a two-
to-one ratio between Guam and American Samoa. On the basis of estimates for
1960, the Virgin Islands will be allowed to ship approximately 4.1 million units
in 1967, Guam about 400,000, and American Samoa about 200,000.
~8a7es, income, and employmeat
Total sales of all products of the six watch companies have been steadily in-
creasing during the last five years.
The following is a summary of available data conceri~ing total sales of all
products and net income of domestic watch manufacturers.
BU LU VA
[In millions of doilars[
Fiscal ye
as ending Mar
31-
1966
1965
1964
1963
1962
Net sales -
Net income
9
9. 8
3.2
84. 2
2.8
73. 0
2.4
6
3. 3
1.5
62. 8
1.3
Sales and net income for the quarter ended June 30, 1966 were $24.702,178
and $629,000, against $18,838,034 and $521,900, respectively, a year earlier.
HAMI LION
[In millions of dollarsi
Fiscal yea
r ending Jan. 31-
1966
1965
1964 1963
1962
Net sales
Net income
4
4.8
2.1
38. 1
1.1
37. 1
.6
37.6
.7
35
. 8
.025
During the first six months ended July 31, 1966, sales were reported as $24.9
million, an increase of nearly 40 percent over the same period a year ago.
GENERAL TIME
[In millions of dollars[
Fiscal yea
r ending Oec. 31-
1965
1964
1963
1962
1961
Netsales
Net income
9
1.6
2.5
79.9
1.9
73.6
1.4
69.2
1.1
65.6
.5
For the quarter ended March 31, 1960 sales and net income were substantially
ahead of the corresponding quarter a year ago.
U.S. TIME'
[In million dnllars[
Fiscal
year ending De
c. 31-
1964
1963
1962
1961
1960
Net sales
9
0.9
83.5
74.5
7
1.2
69.8
1.7
Net income
5.4
4. 0
3.2
2.9
1 The figures were obtained from investment reparting services. U.S. Time is a privately held corporation and is not
required to report its earnings publicly.
PAGENO="0297"
3733
Newsweek magazine on March 16, 1966 quoted the company's Chairman and
President as having reported that sales topped $100 million during 1965. No
profit figures for that year were cited.
ELG III
(In millions of dollarsj
,
.
Fiscal year e
nding Feb. 28
(or 29)
1966
1965
1964
1963
1962
Net sales
Net income (loss)
42
. 4
.6
54. 8
(8.4)
66. 2
(2.4)
46. 3
1. 1
40. 4
1.4
Elgin's net losses in the fiscal years ended February 28 (or 29) 1964 and 1965
were said to have been associated in large part with substantial "cost overruns"
in prior years on defense contracts. Net decrease in sales during fiscal 1966
reflected the company's elimination of all its Government business. Consumer
sales increased both in fiscal 165 and 1966 as defense sales declined.
INGRAHAM
The Ingrabam Company is a privately-owned firm and does not publish any
financial operating statements. However, information from reliable sources
indicates that sales in 1964 were more than two and one-half times the 1960 sales,
primarily as a result of defense w-ork. The Company's defense backlog on the last
day of 1965 was more than its total sales for 1964.
Employment
The Department of Labor has recently surveyed the employment of the four
domestic wrist watch producers (Bulova, Hamilton, Elgin and U.S. Time).
The total employed in 1965 by the four companies on all products was 9,880. The
figure includes clerical, managerial, technical, and professional workers.
In general, there was no discernible trend during the past decade in the em-
ployment of production workers on domestic watch movements. A decline of
workers in the jeweled-lever segment during the period was partially offset by a
gain in the pin-lever segment, and since 1958 the pin-lever segment has employed
more workers than the jeweled-lever segment.
THE INVESTIGATION
Following the formal announcement of the investigation on April 8, 1965, this
Office undertook an exhaustive study of the domestic watch industry's role in
national defense. As required by the statute, the study employed the resources
of a number of Government agencies having responsibilities or interest in the
matter under review. The agencies collaborating in the study, the Departments
of Defense, Commerce, Labor, the Atomic Energy Commission, and the National
Aeronautics and Space Administration made material available to this Office
as to pertinent aspects of this case which fell within their respective respon-
sibilities. In addition, advice was sought and received from the Department of
State and the Council of Econosnic Advisers. The views of these agencies in the
matter follow.
THE DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE
The Commerce report on this investigation dealt primarily with the question
as to whether there is enough machine capacity in the domestic watch industry
to meet total mobilization requirements for (1) military components planned
for the industry and (2) watches for essential civilian and war-supporting re-
quirements. The report did not address itself specifically to the overall problem
of the impact on the national security of imports of watches.
As part of its investigation, the Department undertook a survey ot the watch
industry to obtain information on the nature and variety of production equip-
ment, the character of current operations, usage of imported parts and move-
ments, production records and capacity potentials. Total mobilization require-
ments were then analyzed for critical parts which in turn were related to ma-
chine time and machine availability. Based on this information and* informal
PAGENO="0298"
3734
consultations with industry, an evaluation of the supply-requirements situation
was made.
In brief, the conclusions drawn were that:
1. Under present planning assumptions estimated mobilization requirements.
for horological items that could be placed on the watch industry could not be
met with currently available equipment. Thus, the report states, a precarious
situation would exist in the event of a conventional war.
2. Watchmaking equipment in the watch industry and elsewhere is inadequate
at this time to meet demand stemming from the Vietnam operations, and with-
out substantial imports of parts, production of fuzes and timing devices would
fall short of current requirements.
3. Present planning assumptions raise a question regarding reliance on im-
ports in a conventional war and such uncertainty of supply of foreign-made parts
could affect the national security.
The report concludes that the prospective deficit in production equipment in a
mobilization period is a serious matter and recommends measures which could
strengthen the defense posture, such as adopting programs to develop additional
capacity, stockpiling of watchmaking equipment and maintaining a watchmaking
complex capable of quick response to defense orders.
DEPAIiTMENT OF DEFENSE
The Department conducted a comprehensive study to determine the extent te
which overall military requirements for horological-type products could be met by
watch and non-watch producers.
In the course of the study, the Department solicited and obtained information
and comments from its component elements which have a significant interest in
the matter, and assembled data on the capabilities of the horological and non-
horological producers for meeting foreseeable defense needs.
The overall military requirements for horological-type products considered in
the study are based on the needs for meeting ammunition and other inventory
objectives for presently planned forces, amended wherever possible to reflect Viet-
nam demands; plus monthly production rates needed to meet anticipated require-
ments under mobilization conditions. The study encompassed jeweled and non-
jeweled watches, clocks and chronometers, timing mechanisms for ammunition,
guided missiles, fire control equipment, photographic equipment, miscellaneous
timing mechanisms, and safety and arming devices for missiles, rockets, and
bombs.
An evaluation of the study led the Department to the following conclusions:
The United States watch industry has been an important and responsive source
of horological-type items used in rockets, missiles and ammunition as well as a
supplier of watches, chronometers, and other items.
Despite the protection of the "escape clause" rates, domestic production of
jeweled watches declined, and further decline may be expected whether or not
the higher rates are extended beyond their terminal date of October 1967. The
Department therefore must anticipate the possibility of a further production re-
trenchment, or even complete termination of production, and has considered alter-
natives available to it should these possibilities occur. -
Termination of domestic watch production, in whole or in part, if it occurs
at all, will not take place at a given moment in time but rather over a period of
time. During this period the Defense Department can make plans for dealing with
the developing situation. The Department considers it unlikely that all domestic
production of watch movements would cease.
Defense requirements, while an uneven source of sales volume for the watch
companies, have nevertheless been a continuing source. These requirements will
continue for the foreseeable future and should constitute an important source of
volume for the watch companies of particular interest to them should domestic
production of watches decline. . . .
In the interest of preserving both a quick reaction capability and a mobiliza-
tion base, the Defense Department can under Exception 16 to the Armed Services
Procurement Regulation confine contract awards for horological-type items to
watch companies or other companies capable of making the needed items.
The watch industry is currently up to capacity in military production which
necessitated a continuing introduction by the Department of non-watch com-
panies as producers of these items. Companies outside of the watch industry
are a growing source of capability for the horological-type items produced by
the watch industry and are currently able to meet the peak mobilization require-
ments for safety and arming devices. As a result of the experience these com-
PAGENO="0299"
3735
panies are gaining in the current procurement program to meet Vietnam needs,
their capability for making the more difficult timing devices used in fuzes and
other ordnance items is increasing substantially. Accordingly, there is a basis for
believing that they would be able to meet peak mobilization requirements for
mechanical timing devices as well as safety and arming devices.
If necessary, the Government could establish an in-house capability for mak-
ing critical components in the event that circumstances disclose that they cannot
be obtained from either the watch or non-watch companies. The Department does
not believe, however, that such an alternative is likely to become necessary in
view of the broad capability of American industry.
Over the long run the current dependence upon mechanical timing devices for
rockets, missiles and ammunition in general may be reduced if non-mechanical
devices based on chemical or electronic techniques prove to be feasible.
In the area of research and development, the Department's principal use of
the industry has been in the developmental area, particularly in production
engineering. Fuze design philosophy, conception, engineering design and other
phases of invention are oridnarily done in the Department's own arsenals and
laboratories. Although technical know-how and equipment is, to a minor degree,
available in-house for prototype production, it is customary to use private in-
dustry for this work. The watch industry relies on its production resources to
support its capabilities in developmental work. While these companies have con-
tended that loss of production facilities would result in an impairment of devel-
opmental resources, the continued requirement for a defense production base
should prevent any diminution in these capabilities in the foreseeable future.
In the light of the above, the Department cannot assert that the continued
importation of watch movements will threaten to impair the national security,
because action will be taken to assure a source of production within or outside
the watch industry.
At the request of this Office, the Department reviewed the report on this in-
vestigation submitted by the Department of Commerce. On September 28, 1966,
Secretary McNamara advised as follows:
The Department finds the report informative and helpful as a document to
be used in maintaining continuing surveillance over the situation and for
planning to insure that both current and mobilization requirements for timing
devices will be met.
However, in the Department's opinion, there is nothing in the report to
cause it to alter or modify the conclusions stated in the previous DOD report
to this Office.
The Department further advises that it has made a detailed check of its in-
ventory of equipment of the type specified in the Commerce report. The results
show:
1. Sufficient DOD equipment is available to meet the alleged shortages men-
tioned in the Commerce report. The equipment is in very good condition and a
substantial portion of it is unused.
2. While the available equipment may not in all instances be the most modern
type, it is adequate and fully capable of meeting defense production require-
ments. Therefore, there is no need to be dependent upon imports to satisfy
these requirements in a mobilization period.
3. Should it ever be considered necessary, replacement of part of this equip-
ment is possible by importing Swiss-type machines which are available within
reasonable price levels and lead times. Furthermore, some American firms are
interestedin providing this type of equipment, if orders of sufficient magnitude
are involved. Lead time of such domestic equipment is about two years.
4. As a further consideration affecting equipment requirements, an intensive
product improvement program is now under way which includes the redesign of
fuzes to allow such parts as gears to be manufactured by stamping and die
casting the gear, pinion and pin as one piece, thus eliminating more costly
and time-consuming machinery processes.
The Department which has been continuously exploring potential replace-
ments for mechanical timers now advises that since its previous report to this
Office, many advances in integrated circuit techniques have been achieved by
industry which bring electronic timers closer to realization.
THE ATOMIC ENERGY COMMISSION
The AEC advised this Office that national security implications pertinent to
the investigation were found only in the ordnance segment of AEC's nuclear
weapons program, and that certain horological skills and experiences presently
found only in the jeweled-lever segment of the domestic watch industry "have
PAGENO="0300"
3736
been and are expected to continue to be of considerable importance to AEC's
weapons program." The AEC concluded however that:
"Though the jeweled lever segment of the domestic watch industry has played
an important role in AEC's past programs and its availability would be desir-
able in the future, it cannot be concluded that it is essential. If a domestic watch
industry were not available for future AEC work, the AEC programs would sur-
vive by the pursuit of new timing concepts, reverting to old ones with perhaps
some compromises, or developing a jeweled detached lever capability in a
precision company outside the horological industry. The latter alternative is
estimated as a three-year program costing several million dollars."
NATIONAL AERONAUTICS AND SPACE ADMINISTRATION
In reporting on this investigation, NASA advised that a survey of its Field
Centers indicates that although the watch industry has supplied items for the
space program, the major portion of timing devices used by NASA for all appli-
cations is essentially of the electronic rather than the mechanical type, furnished
by firms other than the watch industry. In some cases, however, the watch in-
dustry may be a subcontractor for some part of the subsystem which contains the
tiniing devices.
DEPARTMENT OF LABOR
In an investigation under Section 232 of the Trade Expansion Act of 1062, the
Director of the Office of Emergency Planning must, in the light of the require-
ments of national security, give consideration, among others, to ". . . existing
and anticipated availabilities of the human resources . . . essential to the
national defense . .
Accordingly, we requested the Department of Labor to furnish us information
on the manpower aspects of the watch industry.
To meet this request, the Department initiated manpower evaluation studies
based upon information obtained in field surveys of jeweled-lever and pin-lever
wrist watch firms and of 36 non-horological firms producing related products. A
job analysis study was made of 18 occupational skills agreed upon by represent-
atives of the domestic watch industry as being critical to their operations. These
key horological jobs were then compared with similar jobs found in the non-
horological companies in terms of training times required to reach proficiency,
dimensions of work pieces produced and assembled, and tolerances required.
The following findings from the I)epartment's study are considered relevant to
the question at issue:
Only the jeweled-lever watch industry now has the combination of skills and
procedures to produce precision jeweled-lever watch movements.
Management in many related product factories estimated that it would re-
quire about two years to establish from scratch a manufacturing capability to
produce precision watch movements on a mass basis.
Only three of the eighteen key skilled occupations in the industry did not have
approximate counterparts in other types of manufacturing. The three occupa-
tions are only needed to produce electric watches.
It is estimated that combined jeweled watch and pin-lever wrist watch in-
dustry would need 3,700 workers to manufacture products needed by the Depart-
ment of Defense in a peak mobilization period. This represents about three-
eighths of the 9,880 employed by the four wrist watch companies in 1965.
About 200 workers, approximately one-third of whom would be technical and
highly skilled workers, would be needed to manufacture precision time keeping
devices to meet military requirements under mobilization conditions. The other
3,500 would be working on a variety of defense-associated timing devices and
related products which do not require as much of the highly skilled work es-
sential in the production of precision watches and chronometers.
Few of time highly skilled specialized workers now engaged in precision watch
movement production would be needed in the manufacture of defense goods pro-
vided by this industry.
COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS
In his letter to this Office, Mr. Gardner Ackley, Chairman of the Council of
Economic Advisers, discussing the statutory requirement in Section 232 that
"the Director and the President shall further recognize the close relation of the
economic welfare of the Nation to our national security,..." concluded that
there is "no evidence to suggest that imports of watches, watch movements,
and parts are currently such as to threaten the welfare of the domestic watch
PAGENO="0301"
3737
manufacturing industry, much less the health of the economy as a whole." Mr.
Ackley continues with the statement that viewing the question on this narrow
ground alone, he does not conclude that watch imports are threatening to impair
the national security.
FOREIGN POLICY CONSIDERATIONS
United States foreign policy interests and objectives were considered in this
case. The comments of the Department of State, whose advice was sought in this
investigation, were directed broadly toward an evaluation of the importance of
watch imports to our foreign economic relations and the relevance of such rela-
tions to the overall national security and well being of the American people as
a whole.
SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
During 1950 and 1957 the Office of Defense Mobilization (0DM), a predecessor
agency of OEP, conducted an exhaustive investigation, under the "national se-
curity clause" then embodied in Section 7 of the Trade Agreements Extension
Act of 1955, to determine the effect on the national security of imports of horo-
logical products. The investigation led to a finding in February 1958 that the level
of imports of such products did not threaten to impair the national security.
The present investigation which lasted nearly a year and a half, while parallel
in scope to the Office of Defense Mobilization investigation, was conducted as a
new and independent examination of the problem in light of many new factors
that have arisen since 1958, such as changes in military concepts, new weapon
technology, and changed military requirements.
The investigation was carried out in accordance with the criteria contained
in the statute and OEP Regulation 4, giving consideration to the overall produc-
tion facilities and capabilities available within and outside the domestic watch
industry, in terms of the human resources, equipment and materials which are
necessary to meet present and projected defense requirements for horological-
type items, and giving recognition to certain other economic factors related to
the national security.
Without question, imports of watch movements have in the past decade consti-
tuted a substantial portion of the total domestic watch consumption. These im-
ports have had an economic impact on the domestic watch manufacturing indus-
try as a whole and have contributed to some extent to the demise of a few watch
manufacturing firms and to the curtailment of the activities of others in the
field. On the other hand, nearly all the remaining watch manufacturing com-
panies seem to have made far-reaching and fundamental adjustments to the
economic environment of import competition, and were able at the same time
not only to maintain but actually increase their related defense production
capability.
We have considered carefully the statements by spokesmen for the industry
that imports threaten the survival of unique watchmaking, managerial, and pro-
duction-line skills needed in the manufacture of military end products. We do
not believe that there would be any significant loss of skills and facilities im-
portant to national defense during emergency periods.
First, if the watch industry should find it advantageous from an economic
standpoint to turn more and more to imports and gradually curtail or even phase
out domestic watch production, it does not appear that it would abandon its
defense production activities so long as the military demand for their products
continues. In light of current military procurement plans involving an expanded
industrial production base to meet ammunition and other inventory objectives,
the defense capabilities of the watch industry should be in steady demand for
a number of years to come.
Second, even if some of the watch companies should decide to discontinue
their defense production along with that of watch manufacturing, there is
reason to expect that the skilled personnel, production facilities and equipment
now being utilized in production of defense items would be absorbed by or
continued as separate entities of other watch or non-watch companies. This has
happened in the not too distant past. For example, Waltham, Gruen, and Elgin,
upon complete or partial discontinuance of watch manufacturing sold their
defense production facilities to other companies engaged in the supply of defense
or industrial products.
Third, an increasing number of non-watch companies are showing a capability
to produce components requiring equally close or closer tolerances and to develop
complex weapons systems employing such components.
PAGENO="0302"
3738
Statements were made by representatives of the jeweled-lever watch industry
that there is an interdependence between watch production and defense produc-
tion, and that the latter could not be sustained economically unless watch produc-
tion at adequate levels is maintained. The facts, however, as to, three of the five
domestic watch manufacturers involved in defense production, do not appear
to support this contention. Two of these companies, General Time and Ingraham,
prQduce, in addition to clocks, only pocket watches of pin-lever construction
which are not significantly affected by import competition, if at alL Notwith-
standing this, these companies are very substantial producers of sophisticated
military components and their defense sales and defense backlogs have been
increasing at a rapid rate in the past several years. In the case of the third
company, the United States Time Corporation-the largest U.S. producer and
assembler of pin-lever wrist watches-the non-watch capabilities of that firm
are of such a nature and size as to be largely self-sustaining. As in the case of
General Time and Ingraham, the defense sales of U.S. Time account for a
significant proportion of its total sales, and the current defense backlog is the
highest in the firm's history.
The domestic watch industry with its long tradition of experiences in micro-
miniature precision skills required for defense production is an important seg-
ment of our mobilization base. The Department of Defense and the Atomic
Energy Commission are currently relying and will continue to rely for some
years to come on the watch industry to meet a good portion of the current and
projected requirements for certain types of timing devices, saIety and arming
devices, and timepieces. In many instances the industry has excelled in meeting
the need for both speed and quality in the procurement of horological-type
defense items.
However, the basic issue in this investigation is not a determination as to
whether or not the watch industry's facilities and skills are important to our
mobilizatio~i base. Virtually every industry in this country has a role to play
in our defense effort whether in peace or war. In times of a major emergency a
maximum logistic effort to save the nation will require the conversion and use
of all the machinery, skills and experience wherever found throughout the
economy.
We must ascertain whether the quantities or circumstances of continued im-
ports of watches, movements and parts threaten to impair the national security
by impairing, or inhibiting the creation o,r maintenance of, essential productive
capacity, specialized skills or other factors important in times of a national
emergency. Stated differently, (a) are watch imports having such a debilitating
effect on the domestic watchmaking operations as to impair the ability to meet
current and projected defense requirements, and (b) will an impairment of such
ability in turn impair or threaten to impair our national security?
In considering existing capability outside the watch industry, the issue with
which this investigation is primarily concerned is not whether non-horological
firms can produce wo~tches in an emergency, but whether such firms possess the
skills and facilities to produce the same types of components for military hard-
ware as the watch companies. We therefore considered carefully the existing ca-
pability in the total U.S. micro-minature precision industry. The conclusion ar-
rived at, supported by studies made by interested defense agencies, is that even
though the watch industry has valuable capacity and skills which are being and
will continue to be utilized in the defense effort, its abilities cannot be considered
unique outside the watchmaking field. The non-watch companies, even though
they encountered in many instances production difficulties with certain horo-
logical-type defense items, are mastering the prcthlems. If necessary, the defense
agencies can use the so-called "mobilization base" exception to confine contract
awards for horological-type items to particularly qualified non-watch companies
needed to maintain a production base should the watch companies not be
available.
As regards watches per se, accurate timepieces are important to the conduct
of war and essential civilian operations.
Military requirements for watches in a mobilization period are but a small
fraction of one percent of the amount currently consumed in the United States,
and the defense agencies are able, by stockpiling, to meet military needs in the
event they are cut off from fresh supplies.
With respect to essential civilian requirements, the estimate by the Depart-
ment of Commerce was based largely on the experience of World War II, ad-
justed upward for such factors as increase in the U.S. population and the in-
creased mechanization and urbanization of the economy. Civilian (including in-
PAGENO="0303"
3739
dustrial) requirements for watches, as computed by Commerce, actually exceed
the military requirements.
According to information obtained from both trade and Government sources,
the number of jeweled-lever and pin-lever watches currently in the hands of the
American public is estimated between 145 to 170 million units. This estimate is
based on domestic consumption figures for the past 10 years and the average serv-
ice life of the watches under normal maintenance conditions. In addition, the
total inventory of watches at the retail level is estimated at 17.5 million watches
at the end of 1965. Estimates of watches in the domestic producers and importer-
assemblers inventories ran to some 6 million units, making a total inventory in
1965 of over 23 million units. Thus, there appears to be a pool of about 165 to
190 million watches in consumers' hands and inventories, most of them being of
jeweled-lever construction. In addition, the number of clocks of all types in the
hands of consumers and in inventories exceed the number of watches above re-
ferred to. This available supply of timepieces should be more than enough to
meet all essential civilian needs even in a war lasting several years.
With respect to the repair and maintenance of watches in the hands of the
public, the Department of Labor publication, "Occupational Outlook Handbook"
1966-1967 edition, states, among other things, that there are over 25,000 watch-
makers in the United States outside of manufacturing facilities. A great num-
ber of these are employed in retail stores, only a few hundred being employed
either by the domestic watch manufacturers or importer-assembler firms. In
fact, about one-half of the total are self-employed. During World War II, most of
these watchmakers continued in the retail establishments.
It is likely that during a major emergency most of the watchmaking opera-
tions would be curtailed to an irreducible minimum and the facilities utilized to
fulfill higher priority needs. According to the study by the Department of Labor,
referred to in this report, only about 200 workers of the present nearly 10,000
workers employed in the four major watch companies would be needed to manu-
facture precision time keeping devices to meet defense requirements in a mobil-
ization period. Of these 200 workers, approximately only one-third would be tech-
nical and highly skilled workers.
The level of imports dealt with in "national security" investigations is related
to quantities which have been and are entering this country under existing rather
than prospective tariffs. However, we have taken account of the fact that the
higher "escape clause" rates of duties on watches imposed in 1954 are currently
in the process of review. Our findings in this national security investigation took
into consideration the alternatives considered by the defense agencies, referred
to earlier in this report, should further changes in domestic watch production take
place as a result~ of termination of the duty protection now enjoyed by the
industry.
I have made a careful analysis of the comprehensive record assembled in this
case and of the thorough and exhaustive studies by the Departments of Defense
and Commerce, the Atomic Energy Commission and the other agencies collaborat-
ing in this investigation. There is ample evidence that the military production
capability of the companies composing the domestic watch manufacturing in-
dustry has not only been unimpaired by substantial imports in the past decade
but is currently at its maximum and is expanding. In this connection, we have
taken note of the judgments of the defense agencies which rely on the watch
industry for the supply of a significant portion of horological-type defense items
that in the event any changes result in the impairment of this source, not now
foreseen, timely action can be taken by them to provide a source of production
within or outside the watch industry for meeting peacetime and mobilization
requirements for horological-type defense products.
Accordingly, I have concluded that watches, watch movements, and watch
parts are not being imported into the United States in such quantities or under
such circumstances as to threaten to impair the national security. I have also
concluded, based on the studies and judgments of the interested defense agencies,
that the domestic watch manufacturers will be likely to continue production of
defense materials for the foreseeable future, that the non-horological industry
now has and will continue to have a role in the production of essential military
timing devices, and that horological-type defense items will continue to be avail-
able from one source or another without regard to the level of imports of watches,
movements, and parts.
FARRIS BRYANT, Director.
PAGENO="0304"
3740
STATEMENT OF ANTONIO B. WON PAT, TERRITORY OF GUAM,
REPRESENTATIVE IN WASHINGTON, D.C.
Mr. Chairman and members of the Committee, I am Antonio B. Won Pat, the
elected Representative of the people of Guam in our Nation's Capital, and I am
presenting this statement on behalf of equity, fairness and justice `for the 100,000
American citizens of Guam with respect to the division of future increases in the
importation into the mainland of watches assembled in the insular possessions of
the United States. I might point out that as the incumbent of the only territory-
wide elective office in Guam, I in my official capacity am the authorized spokes-
man in Washington for the Guamanian people, all of whom, as you know, are
American citizens.
This Committee is well aware that Public Law 89-805 limits duty-free imports
of watches and watch movements containing foreign components, from the in-
sular possessions. These insular possessions consist of Guam, the Virgin Islands
and American `Samoa, although the status of the latter area has never been
clearly defined by the Congress. Under PL 89-805, which grew out of legislation
sponsored in this Committee, one-ninth of the total domestic consum~Ytion for the
previous year of watches and watch movements may enter the mainland from
all three insular areas. The formula set forth in the Act gives the Virgin Islands
seven-eighths of this one-ninth quota, with the remaining one-eighth divided,
two-thirds of it for Guam and one-third for American Samoa.
At the time of enactment of PL 85-805 the American citizens of Guam were at
a loss to understand this highly inequitable, highly unfair formula. The passage
of time since enactment has not made its logic any clearer nor its justice any
more apparent.
The effects of this inequitable formula for 1968 are shown, painfully for Guam,
by the recent determination of the United States Tariff Commission, published
in the Federal Register for March 27, 1968, as Document 68-3644. Under this de-
termination, during 1968, the Virgin Islands may enter 4,208,750 units, Guam only
400,673 units and American Samoa 200,577 units.
That is, the Virgin Islands are entitled to almost 10 times the number of units
to which Guam is entitled!
Yet by every reasonable standard, we merit treatment at least equal to that
accorded the Virgin Islands: Under Acts of Congress, both the Virgin Islands
and Guam are unincorporated territories of the United States; and the citizens
of each are American citizens. Our population is substantially greater than that
of the Virgin Islands-nearly twice, as a matter of fact. The economy of the
Virgin Islands was not destroyed by enemy capture, occupation and subsequent
liberation as was that of Guam, which is the only area now under the American
flag to suffer such devastation.
In terms of specific economic effect, prior to the imposition of this formula,
400 Guamanians were employed in eight separate watch assembly plants on
Guam. During the calendar year 1966, they produced over one million watches.
However, with the imposition of the highly inequitable quota, 370 of our people
lost their means of livelihood, five of the plants have been forced to close eu-
tirely, and quarterly salaries and withholding taxes associated with our watch
industry have fallen from $219,150.40 and $35,411.21 to $85,516.02 and $12,190.05,
respectively.
However inequitable and unfair this formula is as between the Virgin Islands
and Guam, we are not asking you to change it.
What we are asking is a fair division of future unit increases under the quota
you have established. As the consumption on the mainland of America grows,
so will the number of units coming under the one-ninth limitation increase. What
the people of Guam now propose and urge is that future increases over the 1967
quota level be divided equally among the three areas-Virgin Islands, Guam
and American Samoa.
A draft of proposed legislation to accomplish this purpose previously was sub-
mitted last fall to Chairman Mills; in the Senate it has been introduced as S
3124. A copy of S 3124 is attached and made a part of my presentation.
Mr. Chairman and members of the Committee, I want to thank you for allow-
ing the American citizens of Guam to present this petition to you, through
PAGENO="0305"
3741
me, their elected representative, and to urge your prompt and favorable
consideration.
[S. 3124, 90th Cong., second sess., introduced by Senator Metcalf on March 18, 1968]
A BILL To provide that annual Increases in the quota of watches and watch movements
which may be entered duty-free from the insular possessions shall be equally divided
among the Virgin Islands, Guam, and American Samoa
Be it enacted by the Senate and House of Representatives of the United States
of America in Congress assembled, That (a) headnote 6(b) of schedule 7, part
2, subpart E of the Tariff Schedules of the United States (19 U.S.C. 1202) is
amended by adding at the end thereof the following new sentence: "If such
total quantity for any calendar year after 1967 exceeds 4,693,000, then of such
total quantity-
"(iv) not to exceed 4,106,375, plus ½ of the number by which such total
quantity exceeds 4,693,000, shall `be the product of the Virgin Islands.
"(v) not to exceed 390,927, plus ½ of the number by which such total
quantity exceeds 4,693,000, shall be the product of Guam, and
"(vi) not to exceed 195,698, plus ½ of the number by which such total
quantity exceeds 4,693,000, shall be the product of American Samoa."
(b) The amendment made by subsection (a) shall apply with respect to
articles entered, or withdrawn from warehouse, for consumption on or after
January 1, 1968.
HAMILTON WATCH COMPANY,
Lancaster, Pa., July 12, 1968.
Hon. WILBUR MILLS,
Chairman, Committee on Ways and Means,
Hous~e of Representatives, Washington, D.C.
DEAR Mn. CHAIRMAN: As you know, few U.S. industries have been more deeply
affected by or more actively interested in U.S. trade policies and their adminis-
tration over the past thirty years than the producers of jeweled-lever watch
movements. This experience has shown rather conclusively that it is not possible
to produce watch movements in this country without a very substantial tariff
to equalize the difference between foreign and domestic labor rates. It has also
shown that such rates cannot be maintained, certainly not through adminis-
trative channels.
In 1950, when I first became active on the tariff problem for Hamilton Watch
Company, there were seven companies making complete wrist-watch move-
ments in the United States, three producers of non-jeweled or pin lever move-
ments and four producers of jeweled-lever movements. Today there are only
two companies which have the capability to produce complete movements in
this country. The total domestic production of these two companies is quite
limited, is substantially less than in 1950, and its continuation even at this
level is problematical.
Four of the other five companies have ceased all U.S. production of wrist-
watch movements (although two continue to make an inexpensive, large, pin
lever pocket watch of the type which once was known as the $1 watch). The
The fifth company, U.S. Time Corporation, has presented testimony to your
Committee. It produces more watches than any other company in the world,
but the greatest part of its production is from its plants in several foreign
countries. It now makes only one-half of the parts for its U.S. produtcion in
the United States. Irts more complicated operations, which require more labor,
are centered elsewhere.
The President's reduction of tariffs on watch movements in January, 1967,
by revocation of the escape clause rates established by President Eisenhower
in 1954, has already resulted in the further decline of U.S. watch-movement pro-
duction, and the full effects of his action will become more evident in the next
few years. In March, 1965, before the President acted, the Tariff Commission
had reported to him that the revocation of the escape clause rates would result
in "idling of productive facilities and a decrease in employment in the manu-
facture of U.S. watch movements. . ." That is precisely what has happened
95-159-68-pt. S-20
PAGENO="0306"
3742
and what will inevitably continue to happen to the industry under present cir-
cumstances.
As you know, all U.S. companies have long ago been forced to establish some
plants abroad. We, ourselves, now have facilities in Germany and Switzerland.
As it becomes necessary, the oniy two companies which make complete move-
ments in the United States must make further shifts abroad and U.S. Time niust
move the remaining portion of its U.S. production.
This process, apparently, is what the witness for importers of watch move-
ments referred to so euphoniously before your Committee as "a successful ad-
justment to import competition," or "taking advantage of international special-
ization." The witness' reference to increased sales and profits of the U.S. watch-
movement producers, including Hamilton, is wholly misleading.. I can tell you
categorically that our sales of watches with domestic movements have declined,
not increased, and that we are not profiting from the sale of such movements.
Under present circumstances, we must look to imported movements or to wholly
different products for the profits we report.
As we have said over the years, a shift to complete importation of watch move-
ments is not necessarily injurious to our profits. It is easy to see that any com-
pany can generate more profit by making movements in Switzerland rather than
in the United States because the Swiss wage rates are less than half the U.S.
rates for the same skills. But transferring jobs abroad is not helpful to our em-
ployees, and the loss of watchmaking skills in America is not in the interest of
our national security.
Subcommittees of the Senate Armed Services Committee reported in 1954 and
again in 1964, that the industry was important to our national security because
of its ability to shift its watchmaking skills to emergency production of precision
timing devices for missiles, rockets, shells and other weapons. As a preliminary
to the 1967 reduction of watch tariffs, the Secretary of Defense advised the
Director of the Office of Emergency Planning that the watch industry was im-
portant, but refused to advise that any steps should be taken-specifically, the
retention of the 1954 escape clause rates-in order to preserve the industry. I use
the word "refused" advisedly because the Secretary acted contrary to the advice
of the office of the Assistant Secretary for Installations and Logistics and that of
the Government arsenals and laboratories directly responsible for procurement
of precision mechanical timing devices. The Secretary's letter actually took the
position that there was adequate capacity for precision timing devices in other
less-skilled industries, although it was a known fact at the time that a shortage
of U.S. capability existed even with the watch industry fully involved in the fuse
program. At present, every one of the producers of one important new time fuse
is a watch company. The Secretary's reversal of the staff recommendations based
upon many months of study resulted from intervention of the office of the As-
sistant Secretary for International Security Affairs, which was activated by those
who believe that reduction of U.S. tariffs is of paramount importance.
Based npon this, and many similar experiences which I will not take time to
recount, it is our firm opinion that the present procedures for preservation of
industries which are seriously injured economically and those whose loss is not
in the national interest are wholly ineffective. The futility of escape clause pro-
cedures is demonstrated not only by the small number of escape clause actions
taken, but even more clearly by the recent determined and systematic revoca-
tion of those few which had been taken. The domination of trade policy over
national interests in preservation of an industrial base for emergency military
procurement has been made clear to us by the experience I have just described.
Those responsible for administration of the trade program seem firmly convinced
that no consideration should stand in the way of tariff reduction. The safeguard
procedures written into the Trade Expansion Act by the Congress are regarded
not as applicable principles of administration but as unwise obstacles to de-
velopment of free trade to be circumvented after appropriate lip service.
This attitude has now become so pervasive in the various Departments and
Agencies, largely through a program of strategic placement of personnel totally
indoctrinated in their free trade philosophy that there is no hope for a change
of administrative policy. Any meaningful restraints or remedial action must be
legislatively imposed.
Sincerely,
ARTHUR B. SINKLER,
Uha'irrnan 01 the Board.
PAGENO="0307"
3743
The next witness is Mr. Robert Ward.
Mr. TJLLMAN. Mr. Ward, I am particularly pleased to welcome you
before the committee. Members of the committee have a~lways enjoyed
Oregon strawberries.
Would you please identify yourself for the record.
Are you appearing alone?
STATEMENT OF ROBERT E. WARD, ON BEHALF OF NORTHWEST
CANNERS & FREEZERS ASSOCIATION, OREGON STRAWBERRY
COUNCIL, ANIJ CALIFORNIA STRAWBERRY ADVISORY BOARD
Mr. WARD. Yes.
Mr. TJLLMAN. Very good.
I want the members of the committee to know that we in the North-
west produce the finest fruits and vegetables in the country, and cer-
tainly the finest strawberries. You, sir; represent an outstanding orga-
nization with a fine record of public service, and I particularly am
pleased to see you here today.
You may proceed.
Mr. WARD. Thank you.
Representative TJllman, Mr. Chairman, and members of the com-
mittee, my name is Robert E. Ward. I am the assistant general man-
ager of United Flav-R-Pac Growers, a grower-owned processing co-
operative, with plants in Gresham, Newberg, and Salem, Oreg.
I am presenting this testimony in behalf of the California straw-
berry industry, including growers, processors, and shippers; North-
west Canners & Freezers Association, a trade association of fruit
and vegetable processing companies located in Oregon, Washington,
and Idaho; the Oregon Strawberry Council, representing the straw-
berry growers of the State of Oregon; and growers and packers in the
States of Michigan and Tennessee.
Mr. Chairman, with your permission, I would like to read a few
letters into the record, one from Michigan, and one from Tennessee.
Mr. ULLMAN. Will you proceed?
Mr. WARD. The letter from Michigan is from Mr. James Bryan,
president of Smeltzer Orchard Co., who is also vice president of the
National Association of Frozen Food Packers, and a member of that
organization's legislative committee:
DEAR BOB: We appreciate your efforts on the Mexican strawberry bill regard-
ing a 20-percent import quota. Michigan packers and strawberry growers are
definitely behind this bill, as we have met with Senator Hart and Senator Griffin
in connection with Mexican import quotas.
We are just beginning our 1968 pack with a substantially reduced acreage
in Northwestern Michigan. We are receiving extremely competitive prices from
imported strawberries in New York and Philadelphia markets.
To date we have been unable to obtain information as to the quality of the
fruit.
Sincerely.
The other letter is from Winter Garden Freezer Co., Inc., in Bells,
Tenn., from Mr. Clay Cosco, who is a member of the National Asso-
cmtion of Frozen Fruit Packers Legislative Committee:
Dear Bob: We will support you in your attempts to enact a 20-percent import
quota on Mexican strawberries. Please advise me concerning the date the corn-
PAGENO="0308"
3744
mittee presides. I will attempt to contact the appropriate legislators at the
time of the hearing to gain their support.
Very truly yours.
These growers and packers represent approximately 95 percent of
the national pack of frozen and canned strawberries.
In the three Pacific Coast States, where the largest percent of proc-
essed strawberries are handled, there are approximately 2,000 growers
whose primary market is provided by processors.
You will note in table I that strawberries are grown commercially
and are important to growers in 28 States.
This processing strawberry production represents approximately
a $35 million income to growers, and $3.8 million to workers in proc-
essing plants. It is a significant part of both afrrn and processing
diversification, which is already seasonal and marginal.
A major factor causing depression in these important industries is
the increasingly large imports of frozen strawberries, principally from
Mexico, and the potential for further growth in imports and disrup-
tion of domestic marketing.
U.S. strawberry growers and processors need your assistance in
limiting excessive imports, if they are to continue in this business.
During the most recent 5-year period, average total disappearance
was somewhat less than during the previous 5 years, which, when meas-
ured against the substantial increase in population, indicates a declin-
ing per capita consumption.
In the absence of market expansion potential, there is little or no
room in the domestic market for a large volume of imports of this
product, and any increase in such volume must be regarded as a re-
placement of domestic production, to the detriment of all segments of
the domestic industry.
The U.S. grower overproduced strawberries in the period of 1956 to
1959, and then adjusted his planting to correspond with the market
demand and a fair return.
The success of this self-help program of acreage reduction was short
lived, due to the beginning of a rapidly expanding strawberry indus-
try in Mexico. Imports from Mexico moved from 14.2 million pounds,
or 5.3 percent of U.S. disappearance, in 1959, to a high of 82.8 million
pounds, or 31.5 percent of U.S. disappearance, in 1966.
The 1966 imports of 82.8 million pounds was a 60-percent increase
over the previous year. This has upset a balance needed by U.S. growers
to keep producing strawberries economically.
The 82.8 million pounds of strawberry imports represents over $3.5
million to farm labor, $1.5 million to processing labor, and $10 million
to growers.
Many growers and processors are small operators who have been
able to compete effectively in normal domestic marketing, but are most
severely affected when the supply is inflated by imported product and
prices are depressed.
Strawberry growing and processing is really a small business gen-
erally carried on by small and medium sized processors.
We encourage the committee to consider the strawberry problem in
this perspective.
U.S. growers are unable to compete successfully in the domestic
market with frozen strawberries produced in Mexico. The reasons
PAGENO="0309"
3745
are simple. Strawberry growing and prOcessing has a very high re-
quirement for labor, ingredients, and supplies.
Labor costs in Mexico, both on the farm and in th~ plant, are less
than 10 percent of such costs in the United States, Mexican sugar
prices are about 53 percent, and30-pound containers are roughly 94
percent of current prices in the United States.
The direct result of these and other similar advantages has been
the extremely rapid growth of a fledgling industry in Mexico, based
almost entirely on an export market, principally the United States.
Canada has also become an important export outlet for this produc-
tion, and this export volume has almost completely replaced that
formerly enjoyed by U.S. exporters.
The U.S. strawberry industry is not subsidized, nor is it asking for a
subsidy. It has made every effortto help itself, bñt it cannot control
imports.
The import duty has been lowered from 35 to 14 percent, which en-
courages imports.
Representatives of U.S. processors and growers met with Mexican
processors and growers in 1963, and the Mexicans agreed to limit
imports to quantities that would not unduly upset the balance of the
TJ.S. market.
* However, this voluntary approach was not successful, and imports
continued to rise sharply.
* This situation has resulted in instability in the American market,
and uncertainty among growers.
This industry realizes that the U.S. must share its markets, but
proposes that this share be limited to a formula* based on a moving
5-year average of annual disappearance.
The average disappearance in the United States for the most
recent 5-year period, 1962-63 through 1967-68, is 273 million pounds.
During this same period, imports of frozen strawberries from Mexico
have averaged 56.3 million pounds.
In the light of these figures, an annual quota. of 20 percent for frozen
strawberry imports would be reasonable., including fruit pastes and
fruit puips.
We suggest that a quota of, say, 20 percent of annual domestic dis-
appearance of frozen strawberries be established for imports, based
upon the average disappearance for the last 5 marketing years.
This sort of formula would enable foreign exporters to take ad-
vantage of increasing markets in the United States, or conversely, it
would hold them to reasonable levels in a declining market. (See
tables II and III.)
The market prices of Mexican imports in table III also reflect the
crowing problems of the U.S. strawberry growers and producers.
These prices run 1 to 5 cents per pound below the U.S. market.
U.S. growers are faced with increasing demands for higher wages
and benefits for farm labor. The grower is generally in favor of these
increases, but grower returns are not sufficient to provide needed dol-
lars without a higher market price.
Low prices of uncontrolled imported strawberries are a major factor
in suppressing grower prices and the wages he can pay.
Strawberry growers and processors do provide a great many jobs
for young people, both in the field, and in the processing plants. The
PAGENO="0310"
3746
seasonal nature of this crop in most States makes its labor requirement
needs occur during summer vacation, and it is completed prior to the
start of school in the fail. This again fills a void in supplying a large
number of summer jobs asked for by the President.
U.S. growers are being squeezed by rising costs of equipment and
supplies as well as labor, plus demands from consumers for lower
prices. This system will not work. U.S. citizens can afford products
grown by U.S. growers.
We feel that ELR. 9071, using 20 percent of the 5-year average dis-
appearance of the U.S. market gives ample room for imports and a
healthy domestic market.
(Tables referred to follow:)
TABLE 1.-STRAWBERRIES-ACREAGE AND INDICATED PRODUCTION, BY SEASON AND STATE,
1968 WITH COMPARISONS
Acreage
Crop and State Harvested
-
1962-66 1967
Production (
in thousand
s of pounds)
For harvest,
1968
Average
1962-66
1967
Indicated,
1968
Strawberries: 1
Winter 2,380 2,000 1,800 20,906 17,600 14,400
Spring: California 9,080 8,000 8,500 212,978 208,800 238,000
Early spring 5,660 4,400 3,800 16,460 13,280 11,200
Mid-spring:
Illinois 1,700 1,500 1,500 4,136 4,050 3,600
Missouri 1,040 800 750 2, 567 2, 080 1, 950
Maryland 870 800 750 2,856 2,320 3,750
Virginia 2,000 1,400 1,300 5,408 4,200 3,900
North Carolina 2,040 2, 000 1,900 5,736 4, 200 6, 650
Kentucky 1,280 1,000 900 3,888 3,0)0 2,340
Tennessee 4,040 2,400 1,700 10,087 6,720 4,250
Alabama 730 650 600 1,662 1,300 1,140'
Arkansa~s 3,880 2,600 2,300 9,057 7 800 5 750
Oklahoma 1, 160 900 900 2,886 3,600 3,600
Grouptotal 19,120 14,050 12,600 48,880 39,270 36,930
Late Spring:
Maine 360 350 320 1,109 1,155 990
Massachusetts 370 370 250 1,385 1,591 1,330
Connecticut 360 350 300 1,079 1,050 990
New York 2,780 2,400 2, 100 9,660 6,480 6, 720
Newiersey 2,520 2,400 2,500 11,840 9,120 11,000
Pennsylvania 1,540 1,800 1,800 4,934 5 040 5,040
Ohio 1,760 1,500 1,600 4,894 4,800 3,840
Indiana 1,200 1,100 1,300 3,756 4,620 5,850
Michigan 7,560 6,800 5,900 33,098 29,240 23,600
Wisconsin 1,920 1,900 1,900 5,000 4,940 3,990
Washington 6, 180 5,600 5, 300 42, 004 35,840 34, 450
Oregon 13,400 14,000 12,300 83,740 95,200 81,180
Group total 40, 060 38, 570 35,670 202,914 199,076178,950
AllStates 76,300 67,020 62,370 502,138 478,026 479,480
1 Includes processing.
Source: U.S. Department of Agriculture Statistical Reporting Service, Sacramento, Calif.
PAGENO="0311"
3747
TABLE Il-STRAWBERRIES (FROZEN)-U.S. SUPPLY AND DISAPPEARANCE, SEASONS 1942-43 TO 1966-67
[Million pounds)
Mexico Average f.o.b monthly price quotations
imports (cents per pound)
(million
(pounds) California Northwest Mexico
Beginning Total Disappear- Ending
stocks Pack Imports supply ance stocks
(May 1) (Apr. 30)
Season (May-April)
1942-43 25. 9 63. 8
1943-44 15. 4 29. 8
1944-45 11.5 34.8
1945-46 12. 7 36. 9
1946-47 16.8 78.1
1947-48 17.7 109.0
1948-49 15.9 160.1
1949-50 36.4 107.6
1950-51 11.1 192.7
1951-52 50.6 157.7
1952-53 41.5 200.3
1953-54 45.4 226.0
1954-55 51.5 221.4
1955-56 40.6 273.0
1956-57 65.0 312.3
1957-58 102. 3 259. 3
1958-59 84.2 261.5
1959-60 88. 7 248. 2
1960-61 84.6 217.5
1961-62 89. 5 222. 7
1962-63 76. 6 234. 6
1963-64 79. 4 234. 4
1964-65 61.6 252.6
1965-66 84.7 191.6
1966-67 86.8 213.3
0.1 89.8 74.4 15.4
.1 45.3 33.8 11.5
.4 46.7 34.0 12.7
.2 49.8 33.0 16.8
.1 95.0 77.3 17.7
.2 126.9 111.0 15.9
8 176. 8 140. 4 36. 4
1.6 145.6 134.5 11.1
3.6 207.4 156.8 50.6
6. 6 214. 9 173.4 41. 5
5.4 247.2 201.8 45.4
7. 4 278. 8 227. 3 51. 5
8.9 281.8 241.2 40.6
12.0 325.6 260.6 65.11
12. 3 389. 6 287. 3 102. 3
13.7 375:3 291.1 84.2
16. 3 362. 0 273. 3 88. 7
15.0 351.9 267.3 84.6
33. 5 335. 6 246. 1 89. 5
29. 0 341. 2 264.6 76. 6
34. 5 345. 7 266. 3 79. 4
40. 7 354. 5 292. 9 61. 6
42. 9 357. 1 272. 4 84. 7
74. 6 350. 9 264. 1 86. 8
76. 5 376. 6 269.3 107.
Source: Annual reports of Foreign Agricultural Service, Agricultural Estimates Division, SRS, and National Association
of Frozen Food Packers.
TABLE 111.-STRAWBERRIES (FROZEN)-IMPORTS FROM MEXICO; AVERAGE PRICES, UNITED STATES AND
MEXICAN PRODUCT, YEARS 1957-67
Calendar year
1957 13.8 16.0 18.2 16.11
1958 14. 4 17. 0 18. 0 17. 0
1959 14.2 19.5 20.7 18.5
1960 24.9 20. 2 20. 5 19. 0
1961 29.9 18.0 20.5 17.0
1962 32.3 17.0 19.0 17. 0
1963 34.6 17. 7 19. 5 17. 7
1964 39. 7 20. 5 20. 7 19. 0
1965 51. 8 23. 2 24.2 23. 0
1966 82.8 23.7 25.0 20.0
1967 72. 7 23. 0 22. 5 18. 0
1968 1443
1 Preliminary, through June 2.
Sources: Mexico imports, U.S. Bureau of Census; California and Pacific Northwest price quotations, Quick Frozen
Foods (monthly); Mexico prices, New York Journal of Commerce.
Mr. ULLMAN. Thank you very much, Mr. Ward.
Are there questions?
Mr. Conable.
Mr.CONABLE. Mr. Ward, do you have any idea what percentage of
the strawberries coming in from Mexico are being produced there by
Americans?
Mr. W~iw. No, we don't have that figure.
Mr. CONABLE. My understanding is that there is a substantial out-
flow of American productive capacity from California to Mexico, as
a result of labor shortages in California.
PAGENO="0312"
3748
Mr. WARD. We in discussing this estimated the percent to be small,
not real large. I mean less than half.
Mr. CONABLE. I see.
Thank you.
That is all, Mr. Chairman.
Mr. ULLMAN. You are saying that it is not possible to compete in
the American market with Mexican strawberries? Is that right?
Mr. WARD. Correct.
Mr. ULLMAN. Are they able to produce a comparable berry there?
Mr. WARD. Their quality is improving. However, their quality has
not been as good a quality as you do have in certain strawberry-
producing areas.
However, for preserves versus a retail pack, they do a fair job.
Mr. ULLMAN. I am sure you have explored every possible avenue
of protecting your industry. Your industry has had to cut back in its
production, has it not?
Mr. WARD. Yes. We have cut back, from 1956 to 1959, since that
time, and it appears that we. are now starting on another decline in
our acreages throughout the several States producing strawberries.
Mr. ULLMAN. Is it your feeling that they can go on developing new
acreage in Mexico? Is there still a lot of land that can be used for
berries?
Mr. WARD. Yes. It is our feeling that in 10 years they could com-
pletely take over the processed strawberry market in the United States,
if they so desire, or were pushed ahead that fast.
Mr. ULLMAN. It is a heavy labor using commodity, and does this
account for most of the advantage they have down there?
Mr. WARD. Yes. Our recent figures, which were stated in a report
to the National Advisory Commission on Food and Fiber on January
11, 1967, stated that the Mexican field labor runs from $1 to $1.20 per
day, versus $1.40 an hour in California, and the cost of labor in Mexi-
can plants is $1.56 a day, versus $2.09 an hour in California.
Mr. ULLMAN. Thank you very much, Mr. Ward. I am sure that the
committee will take the matter under consideration.
Mr. WARD. Thank'you.
Mr. BuR1c1~. Without objection, Mr. Chairman, I think it would be
appropriate to place in the record a number of Tariff Commission
statistical tables and comments on strawberries, in connection with
Mr. Ward's testimony.
Mr. Uu~rAN. Without objection, the material will be placed in the
record at this point.
(The material referred to follows:)
PAGENO="0313"
3749
STRAWBERRIES
I. Tariff status, TSUS numbers, and rates of duty
TSUS No.
Rate of duty
Description
December 1967 Post KR.
U.S. imports,
1967 (thou-
sands of
pounds)
146.58
146, 60
146. 7520'
152. 7420~
Fresh, or in brine:
Entered during June 15-Sept. 15, in- 0.5 cent per poundl_ 0.2 cent per pound__
clusive, of any year.
Entered any other time 0.75 cent per pound 2_ 0.75 cent per pound - -
Frozen strawberries 14 percent 14 percent
Strawberry pulp and paste 15 percent 15 percent
1,216
20, 520
74, 659
6,042
1 Based on 1967 imports, virtually all from Canada, the AVE was 1.4 percent.
2 In 1967, the AVE ranged from 0.8 percent to 12.0 percent. The average AVE on imports from Mexico, which accounted
for the great bulk of the entries, was 4.8 percent.
3 Formerly 146.7220.
Formerly 152.70 (part).
Note: Import data include fresh and frozen strawberries and strawberry paste and pulp but exclude minor quantities
of strawberry jam; imports of strawberries in all other forms have been negligible.
II. U.S. production and trade
STRAWBERRIES: FRESH AND PREPARED OR PRESERVED 1 (TSUS 146.58, -.60, -.7520. AND 152.7420)
un millions of pounds, fresh weight equivalentJ
Year
Production
Imports
Exports 2
Apparent
consumption
Ratio of i
Production
(Percent)
mports to-
--
Consumption
(Percent)
1963
510
36
22
524
7.1
6.9
1964
1965
1966
557
459
464
43
55
87
22
15
14
578
499
537
7.7
12.0
18.8
7.
11.
16.2
1967
478
86
10
554
18. 0
15. 5
1963-67 average
494
61
17
538
12.3
11.3
I Data on production includes output for the fresh market and for processing. The fresh weight equivalent of imported
frozen strawberries and strawberry pulp is computed at 80 percent of the reported total weight of the imports to fake
account of the sugar content of the entries.
2 Data on exports, which are not separately available, are estimates based upon import statistics for Canada, which
accounts for the great bulk of U.S. foreign shipments.
Note: The data on production include small quantities of strawberries for canning. The combined output of fresh and
frozen strawberries shown on the succeeding tables do not add to the total shown above, primarilybecause the production
data for the following table on frozen strawberries is on a finished product basis, including the weight of added sugar.
Source: Production compiled from official statistics of the US. Department of Agriculture; imports compiled from
official statistics of the U.S. Department of Commerce.
PAGENO="0314"
3750
FRESH STRAWBERRIES (TSUS 146.58 AND 146. 60)
[Quantity in millions of poundsj
Year
Production 1
Imports
Exports
Apparent
consumption
Ratio of im
ports to-
Production
(percent)
Consumption
(percent)
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965 2
1966
1961-66 average -
:1967
285.9
290. 5
295. 1
297.3
249. 2
257. 4
0.7
1. 0
3. 6
5.2
6.4
13. 1
225.1
2 21. 3
2 20. 4
221.0
13. 0
12. 7
2261.5
2 270.2
2 278. 3
5281.5
242. 5
257. 8
0.2
.3
1.2
1.7
2.6
5. 1
0.3
. 4
1. 3
1.8
2. 6
5. 1
279. 2
5. 0
18. 9
265. 3
1. 8
1. 9
278. 4
21. 7
9. 8
290. 3
7. 8
7. 5
I Production for fresh market; includes small quantities for processing from some States.
2 Export data used in computing apparent consumption for the years 1961 to 1964 represent Canadian imports of
fresh strawberries from the United States as reported in the official statistics of the Dominion of Canada.
Excludes 22,100,000 pounds produced in 1965 but not marketed.
Source: Production compiled from official statistics of the U.S. Department of Agriculture; imports and exports compiled
from official statistics of the U.S. Department of Commerce, except as noted.
Note: The Fresh Fruits and Vegetables Market-Sharing Act of 1968 (HR. 16416) provides that quotas be base so-
called "import year" which includes the months of January through July plus December in any calendar year. It is
estimated that of the 1961-66 averages, approximately 99 percent of production, 88 percent of imports, 100 percent of
exports, and 99 percent of consumption occurred during this "import year." Based on this "import year" the estimated
ratios of imports to production and to consumption over the years 1961-66 would have been about 1.6 and 1.7 percent,
respectively
FROZEN STRAWBERRIES, AND STRAWBERRY PULP AND PASTE, (TSUS 146.7520 AND 152.7420)
[Quantity in thousands of poundsj
Apparent
Year Production Imports u Exports x consumption
Ratio of i
mports to-
Production
Consumption -
1961 222,694 33,817 2,978 262,745 15.2 12.9
1962 234,620 36,781 2,545 261,712 15.7 14.0
1963 234,440 40,146 2,414 299,202 17.1 13.4
1964 252,646 46,997 877 273,420 18.6 17.2
1965 191,613 60,366 2,588 283,552 31.5 21.3
1966 236,492 91,807 969 295,784 38.8 31.0
Average 1961-66.. 228,751 51, 652 2, 062 279, 402 22. 6 18. 5
1967 198, 940 80, 701 508 288, 258 40.6 28. 0
I Frozen strawberry imports were not separately reported prior to Aug. 31, 1963. Data used for years prior to 1964 are
for imports of frozen berries from Mexico; such entries are believed to have consisted almost enitrely of strawberries, and
Mexico was virtually the only supplier. Imports of strawberry paste and pulp, all of which are believed to have been
`frozen, were not separately reported prior to 1967. Data used for 1961-63 are estimates based on information obtained
from trade sources; the data for 1964-66 are based on an analysis of impart documents.
2 U.S. export statistics are not separately reported. Data shown are Canadian imports from the United States. Exports
to other countries are believed to have been negligible.
3 Consumption data have been adjusted to reflect carry-in and carry-out stocks.
Source: Production data are compiled from official statistics of the National Association of Frozen Food Packers. Im-
ports are from official statistics of the U.S. Department of Commerce, except as noted, and exports from official import
statistics of Canada.
PAGENO="0315"
3751
III. Principal sources of imports
FRESH STRAWBERRIES (TSUS 146.58 AND 146.60)
(Quantity in thousands of poundsj
Source 1965
1966
1967
Total, all countries:
Quantity 6,442
Value (1,000 dollars) 1, 023
Unit value (cents per pound) 15.9
Mexico:
Quantity 5,791
Value (1,000 dollars) 844
Unit value (cents per pound) 14. 6
*Canada:
Quantity 608
Value (1,000 dollars) 165
Unit value (cents per pound) 27. 1
13, 135
21, 736
2,404
3, 621
18. 3
16. 7
11,747
20,499
2, 048
3, 180
17. 4
15. 5
1,128
1,216
316
436
28. 0
35. 8
FROZEN STRAWBERRIES (TSUS 146.7520)
Source 1965
1966
1967
Total, all countries:
Quantity 53,866
Value (1,000 dollars) 8, 193
Unit value (cents per pound) 15. 2
Mexico:
Quantity 51,796
Value (1,000 dollars) 7, 805
Unit value (cents per pound) 15. 1
Poland:
Quantity 1,313
Value (1,000 dollars) 242
Unit value (cents per pound) 18. 5
Netherlands:
Quantity 757
Value (1,000 dollars) 146
Unit value (cents per pound) 19.3
85,707
15, 874
18. 4
82,826
15, 264
18. 4
2,523
449
17. 8
276
54
19. 6
74,659
10, 319
13. 8
72,693
9, 991
13.7
1,830
302
16. 5
128
24
18. 9
Source: Compiled from official statistics of the U.S. Department of Commerce.
COMMENTS
Imports
The great bulk of the U.S. imports of both fresh and frozen strawberries are
supplied by Mexico. Canada has supplied most of the remaining imports of fresh
strawberries; Poland and the Netherlands have in recent years exported small
amounts of frozen strawberries to the United States. Generally, the import
season for fresh Mexican strawberries begins in the fall (usually November),
peaks in winter months and declines sharply in the spring as the domestic crop
begins to enter the market in increasing volume (usually April).
PAGENO="0316"
3752
STRAWBERRIES, FRESH: U.S. IMPORTS FROM MEXICO1
[In thousands of pounds[
Month
1960
Year
beginning
November 1_
--
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
November
43
41
394
464
746
870
982
December 23
January 26
February 10
March 305
April 19
May 4
201
187
150
329
72
14
403
576
702
319
595
113
703
210
538
1,357
354
233
931
722
729
1,273
921
111
1,256
1,945
1,849
2,288
1, 519
176
3,080
2,730
4,741
4,741
2, 912
748
4,730
6,850
6,439
3,205
2, 390
Total 387
966
2, 449
3, 794
5, 151
9, 779
18, 715 -
--
I The Mexican season for fresh marketing begins in November of the year shown and ends in May of the following
year.
Source: U.S. Department of Agriculture.
All of the entries of fresh strawberries from Mexico enter at the "non-
seasonal" rate of duty of 0.75 cents per pound (about 4.8 percent AVE in 1907).
Most of the small imports from Canada enter at the seasonal (June 15-September
15) rate of 0.5 cents per pound-the equivalent of about 1.4 percent ad valorem
in 1907.
Mexican strawberry production began in significant commercial quantities in
1948. The first shipments to the United States were frozen strawberries, and the
sizeable shipments of fresh strawberries commenced in 1959. During the 1905
crop year Mexico produced about 110 million pounds of strawberries, more than
80 percent of which are estimated to have been exported to the United States,
particularly in the form of frozen strawberries.
In the Bajio-which is the principal growing area and which extends from
Leon and Irapuato on the north to Zamora on the west and Morelia on the east
and covers the major portion of the State of Guanajuato and of Michoacán-
strawberries have been the most important horticultural crop grown and proc-
essed.1 In recent years growers, as well as processors, have begun diversifying
production, and this area is becoming an important center for freezing vegetables
for export. Prior to a hugh crop in 1965-00, the area experienced a large expan-
sion in both acreage and production facilities. Subsequently, the emphasis was
placed upon .marketings geared to sales that could be made at profitable prices,
and efforts have been made to diversify by producing other commodities such as
fruit juices, nectar concentrates, and the like.
U.S. imports of frozen strawberries from Mexico reached a peak of 82.9 niil-
lion pounds in 1966. The resulting low prices, coupled w-ith adverse weather,
brought a reduction in imports the following year. Iniports of frozen berries
during January-March 1968 were about twice those of the comparable period
in 1967. However, imports during April were less than half as large as in April
1967, so that total imports through April were about the same as those of last
year. Processors and growers in the Bajio expect total 1967-68 exports to be no
larger than in the previous season. The freezers believe that under present con-
ditions exports should be in the neighborhood of 70 million pounds.
The frozen berries are trucked to the United States, with the bulk of the ship-
ments entering at Laredo. The 30-pound can of whole berries is the standard
pack although some berries are sliced upon order. Some processors are individ-
ually quick freezing (IQF) selected large berries, but IQF installations are
limited to a few processors. Almost all of the imports from Mexico are of large
(over 10 pound) packs for use by the manufacturers of preserves, janis, ice
cream, baking products, and the like. About 50 percent of the domestic output of
frozen strawberries has been put up in large containers in recent years for tile
food processing industries.
While the imports of the frozen pack from Mexico enter the United States
the year around, the bulk of the entries in recent years has occurred during the
spring and early summer season.
1 The following discussion of the Mexican industry is taken from the U.S.D.A. publication,
Mexico's Production of Horticultural Products for Export, FAS-M-199, ~Tune 1968.
PAGENO="0317"
3753
STRAWBERRIES, FROZEN: U.S. IMPORTS FROM MEXICO
[Million pounds[
Month
Average
1959-61
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967 1968
January
February
0.3
1.2
0.3
1.0
0.7
2.7
0.7
1.8
1.5
4.5
2.2
6.2
3.6 6.8
1.3 7.9
March
3.4
6.5
7.3
13.0
9.3
12.7
6.6 7.5
April
May
June
6.5
5. 7
2.9
8.7
5. 3
6.0
8.1
7. 0
3.4
9.6
5. 6
4.2
13.0
7. 0
5.9
22.1
15. 0
7.3
17.7 7.6
12. 3
9.6
July
1.4
1.4
2.3
2.8
3.1
5.2
5.0
August
Seotember
October -
.4
. 4
. 4
1.3
. 6
.6
1.0
. 6
. 5
.8
. 6
. 1
1.9
. 6
. 9
3.3
2. 5
1. 7
4.8
3. 8
3.9
November
. 1
. 4
. 4
. 2
1. 9
2. 5
1. 1
December
Total
. 3
. 2
. 6
. 3
2. 2
2. 2
3. 0
23. 0
32. 3
34. 6
39. 7
51. 8
92. 9
72. 7
Source: U.S. Department of Agriculture.
During the current year, excess berries have been shipped fresh. Fresh ship-
ments increased materially in the 1968 season, largely because of the voluntary
restrictions on frozen berries. Reports indicate that grower associations are
again discussing acreage restrictions for next season to enforce their orderly
marketing plans. Similar efforts in the past, however, have not been effective.
Shipments of fresh strawberries can be expected to continue to increase. The
growers ship their best size and quality berries to fresh markets and the balance
to the freezer. About 75 percent of the fresh berries coming to the United States
at McAllen, Texas, and most of the renoainder cross at Laredo in the same State.
Mexican fresh berries are also being airfreighted to Europe via the United States
and Mexico City.
U.~8. ca~ports
U.S. exports of fresh strawberries, which until 1966-67 were larger than im-
ports, traditionally have been to Canada. In recent years such exports have de-
clined somewhat as Canadian imports from Mexico have increased. U.S. exports
of fresh strawberries to Europe by air transport is a small but apparently grow-
ing trade. Exports of prepared strawberries, including frozen, are not separately
reported but are believed to be small and to have consisted chiefly of shipments
to Canada.
U.s. production
Strawberries are grown commercially in every State in the Union and consti-
tute a perennial crop which provides production from the same acreage for both
the fresh market and for processing. During 1961-66, about 55 percent of the
average annual domestic crop was sold fresh. In California, which in recent
years has accounted for about two-fifths of total U.S. production, from 65 per-
cent to 75 percent of the crop is usually sold on the fresh market. In 1967, Cali-
fornia's output totaled 209 million pounds (148 million for the fresh market)
compared with 213 million pounds annually during 1962-66. According to the U.S.
Department of Agriculture, California's 1968 harvest is estimated at 14 percent
above last year's crop. The other ranking producers of strawberries for the fresh
market are Florida, Michigan, Louisiana, New Jersey, and Arkansas. The bulk of
the production in those States is marketed fresh, although about a third of the
Michigan crop is normally processed. In contrast to California's gain in 1968,
production in the latter States in the 1968 season is expected to be substantially
below those of a year ago as a result of acreage reductions and a decline in
yields due in part to adverse weather.
PAGENO="0318"
3754
STRAWBERRIES: PRODUCTION BY GROUPS AND STATES, AVERAGE 1962-66, ANNUAL 1967 AND
INDICATED 1968'
[1,000 pounds[
Group and State Average
1962-66
1967
Indicated
1968
Winter: Florida 20, 906
Spring: California___ 212,978
Early spring:
Louisiana 14,076
Texas 2,384
17, 600
208,800
14, 400
238,000
11,780
1,500
10,200
1,001)
Grouptotal 16,460
Midspring:
Illinsis_ 4, 136
Missouri 2,567
Maryland 2,856
Virginia 5,408
North Carolina 5,736
Kentucky 3, 888
Tennessee 10,087
Alabama 1,662
Arkansas 9, 057
Oklahoma 2,886
Grouptotal 48,880
Late spring:
Maine 1,109
Massachusetts 1,385
Connecticut 1,079
NewYork 9,660
Newiersey 11,840
Pennsylvania 4, 934
Ohio 4,894
Indiana 3,756
Michigan 33, 090
Wiscons!n 5, 000
Washington 42, 004
Oregon 83,740
Grouptotal 202,914
All Stat3s 502,138
13,280
- 11,200
4,050
2,080
2,320
4,200
4,200
3, 000
7,720
1,300
7,801)
3,600
3,600
1,950
3,750
3,900
6,650
2, 340
4,250
1,140
5,750
3,600
39,270
36,330
1,155
1,591
1,050
6,480
9,120
5, 040
4,800
4,620
29,240
4, 940
35, 840
95,200
960
1,330
990
6,720
11,000
5, 040
3,840
5,850
23,60~
3, 990
34, 450
81,180
199,076
178,950
478,026
479,480
1 For fresh market and processing.
Source: U.S. Department of Agriculture.
Most of the strawberries for processing are grown in the Pacific Northwest.
Washington and Oregon together have accounted for from 25 percent to 3Q~
percent of total U.S. production for all uses in recent years, and for most (more
than two-thirds in 1967) of the U.S. frozen pack. Total production in those two
States is estimated at 116 million pounds for the 1968 season, compared with 131
million in 1967, and an average annual of 126 million during 1962-66. Through
June 15 of 1968, only about 17 million pounds of strawberries had been delivered
to processors in Oregon and Washington, compared with 25 million pounds a.
year ago. This decline in deliveries, was expected to be offset by an increase in
California's deliveries to freezers, which, through mid-June, were reported at
about 29 million pounds-or about 53 percent more than during the same period
last year.
PAGENO="0319"
3755
STRAWBERRIES FOR PROCESSING: PRODUCTION, VALUE PER POUND, AND TOTAL VALUE, AVERAGE 1961-65,
ANNUAL 1966 AND 1967
Production
Season and State
pounds)
Value
(thousand
Per p
ound (cents)
Total (tho
-
usand dollars)
Average,
1961-65
1966
1967
Average,
1961-65
1966
1967
Average,
1961-65
1966
1967
Spring: California 1 79, 760 60, 500 60, 700 13. 0 16. 5 14. 7 10, 112 9, 982 8, 923:
Early spring: Louisiana_ ...966 176 144 13. 0 15. 0 15. 0 123 26 22
Mid-spring:
Kentucky 1,208 1,240 380 14.6 18.0 13.5 172 223 51
Tennessee 7,512 3,500 704 14.2 17.8 14.9 1,031 623 105
Oklahoma 2, 480 2, 100 1, 300 15. 8 21. 0 18. 0 372 441 234
Total or average_ - - _11, 200 6,840 2, 384 14. 6 18. 8 16. 4 1, 574 1,287 390
Late spring:
New York 1 680 1 500 700 12.7 13.2 13.1 210 198 92
Michigan 11,748 11,160 11,100 15.3 15.3 15.6 1,842 1,707 1,732
Washington 39, 432 33,940 32, 340 14. 0 16.6 15. 0 5, 395 5, 634 4, 851
Oregon 1 74, 288 93, 000 1 92, 300 13. 3 17. 3 14. 1 9, 642 16, 089 12, 422
Total or average_ - - - 127, 148 139, 600 136, 440 13. 7 16. 9 14. 4 17. 090 23,628 19,097
United States 219, 074 207, 116 199, 668 13. 4 16. 9 14. 5 28, 899 34, 923 28. 432
some quantities not marketed and excluded in computing value: Late Spring, Oregon, 4,200,000 pounds in
Source: U.S. Department of Agriculture.
In 1963 (the latest year for which data are available) frozen strawberries.
were produced in 78 U.S. establishments compared with 94 in 1959. Two-thirds
of the establishments were located in Oregon, Washington, and California in
1963. The U.S. Department of Commerce indicates that in 1963, 20 of the largest
strawberry freezers accounted for 77 percent of the total production in that year.
Fifty of the largest accounted for 99 percent of total output. Most establishments.
freezing strawberries also process other fruits and/or vegetables; frozen straw-
berries provide a substantial portion of the total income of a number of these
producers. Data on the number of workers engaged in harvesting and processing
strawberries are not available. Because of the short season for the crop, much.
of the labor is recruited locally as temporary help. In the major producing areas,.
wages for strawberry harvests have been increased to insure sufficient labor.
Mr. TJLLMAN. Our next witness is Mr. Howard P. Chester.
Mr. `Chester, we are very happy to have you before the ~oniinittee.
For the record, will you please identify yourself, and also all of'
your colleagues, and with the understanding your full statement will
be in the record, proceed as you see fit.
PAGENO="0320"
3756
STATEMENTS OP HOWARD P. CHESTER, EXECUTIVE SECRETARY,
STONE, GLASS, AND CLAY COORDINATING COMMITTEE; APPEAR-
ING JOINTLY WITH RALPH REISER, INTERNATIONAL PRESI-
DENT, UNITED `GLASS & CERAMIC WORKERS OF NORTH AMERICA;
GEORGE BARBAREE, INTERNATIONAL SECRETARY-TREASURER,
INTERNATIONAL BROTHERHOOD OF OPERATIVE POTTERS; VIC-
TOR THOMAS, GENERAL VICE PRESIDENT, UNITED CEMENT,
LIME, & GYPSUM WORKERS; HOLLAN OORNETT, EXECUTIVE
BOARD MEMBER, UNITED STONE & ALLIED PRODUCTS WORKERS
OP AMERICA; AND ROBERT LORD, VICE PRESIDENT, INTERNA-
TIONAL BROTHERHOOD OF OPERATIVE POTTERS
Mr. CHESTER. We appreciate that, Mr. Chairman.
My name is Howard P. Chester. I am executive secretary of the
stone, glass, and clay coordinating committee. This is a committee
that consists of seven international unions, `and these are all union
officers here, and with your permission I would like to introduce them.
Mr. ULLMAN. Would you do that, please?
Mr. ChEsTER. Starting on my left, Mr. Hollan Cornett, executive
board member, United Stone & Allied Products Workers of America.
Next to him is Mr. Ralph Reiser, international president of the United
Glass & Ceramic Workers.
Starting on my far right is Mr. Robert Lord, vice president of the
International Brotherhood of Operative Potters. Next to him is Mr.
George Barbaree, secretary-treasurer, International Brotherhood of
Operative Potters; and next `to me, on my right, is Mr. Victor Thomas,
general vice president of the United Cement, Lime & Gypsum
Worker5
Mr. ULLMAx. We are pleased to have all you gentlemen before the
committee.
Mr. CHESTER. Mr. Chairman and members of the committee, we
have in all cases briefed our testimony, and, of course, `we will submit
more extensive documents for the record, with your permission.
I would first like to thank you for this opportunity to express
our views.
Our stone, glass, and clay coordinating committee represents
seven international AFL-CIO unions. We have a combined member-
ship of 250,000 workers, with active locals in almost all `of the 50
States.
The first subj ect covered in our brief is private foreign investments,
and points up the tremendous increase in private investment abroad,
from $19 billion in 1950 to $86.2 billion in 1966.
Turning to the distribution of direct private foreign investment,
which has risen from $11.7 billion in 1950 to $54.5 billion in 1966, we
find that contrary to the flow being to underdeveloped countries, where
the need had been emphasized in the 1958 hearings, the investment
flow has instead gone to developed countries, with Western Europe
showing a 14-percent increase over 1957 for a total of 30 percent, which
combined with Canada's 31 percent, shows that 61 percent of all private
direct investment abroad has been made in the two highly developed
areas.
PAGENO="0321"
3757
With regard to industry distribution, manufacturing leads with 40
percent of the total, or $22 billion, in all areas.
Many of these global corporations are showing their concern against
any restrictions to their access to the U.S. market. They recognize
that free access to U.S. markets is in their corporation interest.
They want to invest abroad, enjoy the markets and lower wage labor,
and they also want to enjoy the U.S. market from abroad, in some
cases in direct competition with their domestic operations, or other
domestic producers of the same product.
For example, in 1965, U.S. foreign affiliates exported back to the
United States $5.133 billion in products from manufacturing, mining,
and petroleum.
We certainly agree with the mandatory restrictions on foreign invest-
ment issued by President Johnson on January 1, 1968.
The second subject is the U.S. method of valuing imports on an
f.o.b. as opposed to the method used by most countries, or c.i.f.
Our f.o.b. method definitely undervalues our imports by at least
10 percent, and creates several serious disadvantages.
An unrealistics figure is released, which inflates our supposed sur-
plus in balance of trade. A realistic trade policy must be considered
on accurate.comparable statistics in order for Congress to make respon-
sible trade legislation.
For example, our quoted 1967 surplus in trade of $4.3 billion would
be reduced to $1.63 billion, if we added only 10 percent to our 1967 im-
port figure for insurance and freight.
Our third subject is the effect of Government subsidies on U.S.
trade statistics.
To reflect a true figure for calculating a surplus or deficit in trade,
subsidies must be considered.
Testimony on the Trade Expansion Act before the Senate Finance
Committee clearly shows that agricultural exports that are subsidized
were included in overall export figures.
Later testimony revealed that of the $5.1 billion of agriculture ex-
ports, $2 billion of such exports were subsidized under Public Law
480, and for proper reporting, should have been excluded from the $5.1
billion figure of agricultural exports.
Our trade statistics should truly show our position in trade, so that
trade policy decisions can be based on accurate figures, and not figures
that undervalue imports and overvalue exports.
The fourth subject is the useless portion of the Trade Expansion Act,
section 301, or adjustment assistance to workers or firms.
To date, not one case has been certified for assistance.
The words "in major part" should be stricken from this section, as
they were not in the bill when passed by the House.
I know there is recognition of this unworkable section, but I might
suggest deletion of the words "in major part." Then the section has
meaning.
Of course, I must point out that there is no substitute for a job, and
a productive place in society, and labor, as I know it, is not interested
in any dole, but by far prefers to work.
The fifth and concluding subject is the effect on labor of U.S. trade
policy.
95-159-OS-pt. S-21
PAGENO="0322"
3758
`We believe all working Americans are affected by U.S. trade policy.
Our Nation requires maximum employment, and healthy industries, to
maintain a healthy economy.
Most industries are willing to share in the growth of the U.S. mar-
ket with the foreign producers, but they are not willing to have this
growth completely absorbed by imports, or to have present productive
capacity and employment displaced by imports.
We believe that the tremendous rise in American investment and
technology abroad added to rising capacity of foreign firms results in
decreasing exports and increasing imports, and eliminates existing jobs
and job potential, and reduces domestic industry's capacity to operate
at a healthy level and properly share in our country's growth.
Our experience, borne out by statistics, shows that the products
produced by the employees who are members of our committee have
been and will continue to be faced with constantly rising imports, de-
clining employment, plants closing their doors, and no relief in sight.
In pottery, for example, the 60-percent increase in imports in 1966
over 1961 is called the adding of insult to injury.
Imports of china and earthenware, made in major part by the Jap-
anese, had already captured 48.4 percent and 33.6 percent of the do-
mestic market respectively.
Twenty pottery plants have closed their doors since 1954, unable to
compete with imports.
This is an almost unbelievable, but factual, account of what has
happened in the pottery industry.
Of the $55 million of total pottery imports in 1966, the Japanese
captured $33 million.
You will note the rising increases in imports of cement, lime, and
gypsum products, with a 90-percent increase; ceramic floor and wall
tile, 85-percent increase; flat glass, including sheet, plate, float, cast,
and rolled, tempered, laminated, and mirrors, 22-percent increase;
illuminating and table and arc glassware, a 67-percent increase.
These increases are based on a comparison of 1961 with 1966, and
like pottery, do not show the previous damage.
Exports in all of these industries are minimal, while imports have
displaced in excess of 50,000 workers.
Something must be done to prevent annihilation of these industries
and their workers.
On behalf of the Stone, Glass, and Clay Coordinating Committee,
we urge legislation to regulate foreign imports, U.S. foreign invest-
ment policy, and congressional consideration and approval before any
changes are made in our antidumping procedures.
We support the Fair International Trade Act first introduced by
Congressman Herlong on May 1, 1968, and subsequently introduced by
more than 30 Congressmen, expressing their concern on the serious
problem of uncontrolled imports.
As a closing comment, the United States has been warned by the
EEC that we are risking further deterioration of our balance of pay-
ments unless we take vigorous remedial action against rising imports
from the EEC.
This article was in the Washington Post May 21, 1968. We cer-
tainly should heed their timely warning.
Thank you very much.
PAGENO="0323"
3759
(Mr. Chester's prepared statement follows:)
STATEMENT OF HOWARD P. CHESTER, EXECUTIVE SECRETARY, STONE, GLASS, AND
CLAY COORDINATING COMMITTEE
MEMBERS OF COMMITTEE
Mr. George M. Parker, President, The American Flint Glass Workers Union of
North America
Mr. Lee W. Minton, President, The Glass Bottle Blowers Association of the United
States and Canada
Mr. E. L. Wheatley, President, The International Brotherhood of Operative
Potters
Mr. Paul Peifrey, President, The United Brick and Clay Workers of America
Mr. Felix C. Jones, President, The United Cement, Lime and Gypsum Workers
International Union
Mr. Ralph Reiser, President, The United Glass and Ceramic Workers of North
America
Mr. Harry Baughman, President, The Window Glass Cutters League of America
Mr. Chairman, my name is Howard P. Chester. I am the Executive Secretary
of the Stone, Glass and Clay Coordinating Committee. We are composed of seven
international unions, all affiliated with the AFL-CIO, who have joined together
to cooperate on mutual problems that affect any one of our seven affiliates. We
have a combined membership of 250,000 workers, with active locals in almost
all of the fifty states.
In this Hearing on U.S. trade policies we would like to make it clear from the
beginning that the Unions listed above represent employees in industries that
are already extremely import sensitive and we know that the Kennedy Round
of tariff cuts will serve to further accelerate the foreign low-wage imports in
these industries. They are presently faced with large shares of the domestic
market being captured by foreign imports, causing plants to close and workers to
suffer loss of their employment.
To list some of the industries we are concerned with that are now suffering
severe damage: pottery, ceramic tile, illuminating and table and art glassware,
hydraulic cement, lime, gypsum, and fiat glass. There are many other industries
also showing their concern. We submit that for these labor-intensive industries
to compete with the like product produced in foreign countries, who have willing-
ly accepted our technology and our mass production system but did not accept
our high wages, can only be destructive to our high wage, high purchasing power
economy.
Most industries are willing to share in the growth of U.S. markets with the
foreign producers, but they are not willing to have this growth completely ob-
sorbed by imports or to have present productive capacity and employment dis-
placed by imports.
The Congress is showing great concern with our foreign trade policies and
bills have been introduced; to establish import quotas on specified products; to
amend the Trade Expansion Act; to amend the Anti-Dumping Act; to provide for
orderly marketing, and to amend the Fair Labor Standards Act of 1938, to es-
tablish procedures to relieve domestic industries and w-orkers injured by in-
creased imports from low-wage areas. This last-described Bill, HR. 478, known
as the Dent Bill, resulted from years of research and testimony given before
Congressman Dent's Subcommittee of the Committee on Education and Labor on
"The Impact of Imports on American Labor." After thorough debate on Septem-
ber 28, 1907, the Bill passed the House by a strong majority of 340-29.
Senator Long, Chairman of the Senate Finance Committee, conducted Hear-
ings October 18, 19 & 20, 1907 on the import quota bills that had been introduced
in the Senate. Considerable interest was shown by the public, business, labor, Con-
gress and Cabinet Officers of the Administration. Senator Long also will be con-
ducting hearings on a legislative oversight review of U.S. trade policies, seeking
more data on our trade policies.
Certainly we in Labor who are vitally affected by imports and U.S. trade policy
should concentrate our efforts and battle for fair and just legislation. There
are several important deficiencies in our present foreign trade policies that work
in direct opposition to our national interest.
Private Foreigm Investment
U.S. foreign investment-and, as a substantial part of this category, U.S. pri-
vate foreign investment-must be given full consideration as an inseparable part
of our foreign trade policy. The following Chart "A" will serve to show the
PAGENO="0324"
3760
astounding increases in our U.S. foreign investments; Chart "B" the area dis-
tribution of U.S. direct private foreign investments; Chart "C" the industry dis-
tribution of U.S. direct private foreign Investments. (The sources of informa-
tion for Charts A, B and C were the 1958 Hearings by the Subcommittee on Pri-
vate Foreign Investment, and the Department of Commerce Survey of Current
Business, September, 1967.)
CHART A-U.S. INVESTMENTS ABROAD
(In millions of dollarsJ
1950 1957 1966
$32,844 $54,215 $111,874
19,004 36,812 86,235
17,488 33,588 75,565
11,788 25,252 54,562
5,700 8,336 21,0i3
1,516 3,224 10,670
13,840 17,403 25,639
13,518 15,548 21,182
322 1,855 4,457
In Chart "A" we find that total U.S. investment abroad in loGO has increased
by practically four times the 1950 figure of $32.8 billion. The large share of the
1966 total figure is made up of private investments, $86.2 billion of the $111.8
billion total for 1966.
The divisions of private investment are long-term meaning a period in excess
of one year, and short-term. The book value of our various short-term private
investments at the end of 1960 totaled .$10.6 billion.
Long-term private investments can be placed in two categories, portfolio and
direct. Portfolio investment largely entails private ownership of foreign govern-
ment bonds and business securities, with no implication iii management decisions.
Portfolio investment abroad in 1966 totaled $21 billion.
Direct foreign investment is ownership of 25 percent or more of a business and
usually important management participation. Private direct foreign investments
abroad in 1966 totaled $54.5 billion.
In all divisions of private foreign investment, comparing 1950-1957-1966, there
have been tremendous increases in the holdings of U.S. companies and private
investors abroad.
CHART "B"
AREA DISTRIBUTION OF
U.S. DIRECT PRIVATE FOREIGN INVESTNENTS
19~7 1966
Total U.S. investments abroad -
Private investments
Long term
Direct
Portfolio
Shortterm
U.S. Government credits and claims
Long term
Short term
BOOK VALUES, $2~.3 BILLION BOOK VALUES, $~Ii-.S BILLION
PAGENO="0325"
3761
In Chart "B" comparing the area distribution of direct private foreign invest-
ment for 1957 with 1966 we find that considerably more investment dollars went
into Western Europe, with a 14 percent increase, *so the investment flow is to
the developed countries, in Western Europe and to Canada, while the less devel-
oped and underdeveloped countries in Latin America, Africa and the Middle East
dropped considerably in investments to their areas. And this happened despite the
emphasis, stated in the 1958 Hearings, on the necessity of changing the private
investment pattern to encourage more flow to Latin America, Middle East and
Africa to deter the Soviet economic offensive in those areas.
CHART ~~CI?
INflUSTRY DISTRIBUTION OF
11.S~ DIRECT PRIVATE FOREIQN INVESTMENTS
1957 1966
Chart "C" compares the industry distribution of U.S. direct private foreign
investments in 1957 with 1966. You will note a strong upward thrust in manu-
facturing investment, a 9 percent increase over 1957, a decline in petroleum,
mining and public utilities. Manufacturing leads all other industry investment
with a 1906 foreign total of $22 billion in all areas, while petroleum is in second
place with $16 billion.
The three charts which show the increases in U.S. private foreign investment
bear out a prediction made by Mr. Robert M. Mitchell, Vice President of the
Whirlpool Corporation, in Hearings held on the subject of private foreign
investment by the Subcommittee on Foreign Trade Policy, December 1958. After
Mr. Mitchell's testimony, questions were asked by Congressman John W. Byrnes:
"Mr. BYRNES. As I gather the basis of your concern here, among other things,
is the fact that you foresee a necessity as far as American business is concerned
to shift from an export business to manufacturing abroad, an investing and going
through the manufacturing process abroad; is that right?
"Mr. MITCHELL. That is correct, Mr. Byrnes.
"Mr. BYRNES. Do you attribute that trend in part to this common market
trend, the European Common Market and the proposals for a common market in
other areas? Is there any other factor that gives rise to tha't?
"Mr. MITCHELL. Basically that is it, Mr. Byrnes. In many of the Latin Ameri-
can countries at the moment for practical purposes it is impossible to export
particularly consumer durable goods. There is a rising nationalism in many of
these countries, and they are trying to industrialize, and to raise their `standard of
living. So that American companies, if they are going to have a part of that mar-
ket at all, must invest in some form or other..
"Mr. BYRNES. You don't see a great future then as far as the export of finished
commodities from this country. You see that contracting, I gather, and an in-
crease in manufacturing abroad and with foreign labor?
BOOK VALUES~ $25~3 BILLI~N BOOK VALDES, $5L~.5 BILLION
PAGENO="0326"
3762
"Mr. MITCHELL. I think that is the way it will happen; yes, sir.
"Mr BYRNES. Great emphasis has been put on the fact of the importance of
the trade-agreements program and all of the rest of it, and the increase in our
exports, and .the developing of this freer trade. I gather that you would suggest
at least by your testimony that we may be getting into a period where that is
going to be reversed?
"Mr. MITCHELL. I think that that is quite right, sir.
"Mr. BYRNES. That is all."
This prediction of increasing investment abroad and the decrease in the ex-
port of finished commodities from this country has come to pass. This increased
foreign capacity can only serve to decrease our exports and increase our imports,
and since capital is mobile and labor is not, the result has been loss of American
jobs and loss to those American industries that do not choose to move or that do
not have the capital to make such a move.
Many U.S. corporations are becoming global in their makeup, with vast hold-
ings and assets in other nations. Consider that in 1950, in direct private foreign
investment the U.S. bad $11.8 billion invested around the world, this rose to $25.3
billion in 1957 and to $54.5 billion in 1966. Many of these global corporations are
showing their concern against any restriction to their access to the U.S. market.
They recognize that free `access to U.S. markets is in their corporation interest;
they want to invest abroad, enjoy the markets and low-wage labor; and they
also want to enjoy the U.S. market from `abroad, in some cases in direct compe-
tition with their domestic operation or other domestic producers of the same
product.
United States foreign manufacturing affiliates' sales in 1965 were $42.4 billion
compared to $18.3 billion in 1957, for an increase of 132 percent.
In 1965, $34.7 billion of such sales were within the area of plant location, how-
ever $7.7 billion represented export sales to other countries, including the United
States. The products shipped to the U.S. am9unted to 24 percent of total export
sales of manufacturing affiliates, or $1856 billion.
This figure does not include exports to the U.S. of foreign mining affiliates
of U.S. firms in the amount of $1.225 billion, nor does it include exports to the
U.S. of petroleum and petroleum products by U.S. foreign petroleum affiliates.
estimated at $2052 billion.
Combining manufacturing, mining and petroleum export sales to the U.S., `by
U.S. foreign affiliates in 1965, the total would be an astounding $5.133 billion.
The time has come for a re-evaluation of this expanded investment program in
terms of the U.S. economy, employment, outflow of capital. loss of revenue to
the United States and effect of imports' on U.S. industry and labor.
Our rising deficit in our balance of payments has brought this problem into
focus and President Johnson has wisely issued mandatory restrictions on pri-
vate foreign investment as of January 1, 1968. We heartily agree with his actions
designed to preserve our country's financial strength.
FOB versus CIF
The official valuation of U.S. imports is based on foreign value of the merchan-
dise abroad prior to shipment, and therefore excluding ocean freight and in-
surance charges. The major alternative method in use by most other countries
is referred to as CIF valuation; to the value of the goods in the country of
origin is `added the cost of ocean freight and inOurance involved in shipment
to the importing country. The resulting reported value of import's is thus higher
than the foreign value by the amount of ocean freight and insurance.
The United States method of foreign valuation of imports is completely out
of step with most of the world; of 154 countries that tabulate import statistics,
131 use the OIF method while only 23 use the FOB method. The United Nations
has recommended the use of the CIF method to promote international compara-
bility of foreign trade data.
There are many serious disadvantages in being out of step in valuing our
imports; the American public get an inflated, unrealistic figure with respect to
balance of trade overall and with respect to country by country comparisons; a
realistic trade `policy must `be considered on accurate, comparable *statistics in
order for Congress to `make responsible trade legislation; a `C'IF valuation is
estimated at the very least `to provide a 10 percent increase in the value of U.'S.
imports: C'IF values are far more accurate for analysis of imports in relation to
domestic consumption or production.
PAGENO="0327"
3763
Based on Department of Commerce figures (Washington Post, January 12,
1968) exports for 1967 were estimated $31 billion and imports $26.7 billion.
Adding 10 percent-a conservative figure-to imports for ;CIF valuation, this
figure becomes $29.37 billion, and our `balance of trade figure quoted at $4.3
billion drops to $1.63 billion, a sharp drop of $2.67 billion. Of course many coun-
tries use in excess of 20 percent to add the C~IF valuation. If we used their CIF
percentage in computation, we would have a deficit in our `trade account.
Effect of U.S. Go~vernment Subsidies
Government subsidies have a tremendous effect on U.S. trade statistics; to
reflect a true figure for calculating a surplus or deficit in trade, subsidies must
be considered. For example, in testimony before the Senate Finance Committee
in their consideration of the Trade Expansion Act, Secretary of Agriculture
Freeman, August 15, 1962, on a request `by Senator Bennett `to supply the record
with figures to show the percentage of total exports agriculture represented, the
following are the figures supplied:
Value of U.S. ewports, total and agricultural, in fiscal year 1961-62
Total exports $21, 216, 874, 000
Agricultural exports 5, 138, 837, 000
Percentage of agricultural to total exports 24
In order to find the true figures of our exports that move in commercial com-
petition or for dollar sales we must know the breakdown of the subsidized prod-
ucts and shipping `costs `paid for by the U.S. Government. In response to a request
by Senator `Curtis on the same day, for a breakdown on export subsidies, P.L. 480
subsidies shipping costs, trade mission costs, Secretary Freeman supplied the
following information:
Cost of financing agricultural exports under Food for Peace (Public Law
480) and export subsidy programs July 1, 1961 through May 31, 1962:
Public Law 480:
Gross cost to CCC of financing sales of agricultural commodities Millions
for foreign currency under title I 1 $1, 2.12. 7
Ocean transportation costs financed by CCC 88. 3
CCC cost of commodities granted under title II 165. 8
CCC cost of commodities donated under title III 194. 7
`Excess of CCC investment over exchange value of materials re-
ceived under title III barter program 3. 9
CCC cost of title IV sales in excess of anticipated dollar re-
payments 16. 9
Total, Public Law 480 1, 682.3
Cost to CCC of payment in kind and cash subsidies (excludes $249,-
800,000 P1K and cash subsidies included under gross cost of title
I sales, above) 322.1
Total cost of Public Law 480 and export subsidy programs_. 2, 004.4
1 In payment for commodities sold under this program, foreign governments are required
to deposit the equivalent of $907,000,000 in their local currency `to the account of the U.S.
Government. These currencies are used for various purposes authorized under sec. 104 of
Public Law 480, such as payment of U.S. obligations abroad, agricultural market develop-
ment, loans and grants for economic development, loans to U.S. and foreign private business,
and other mutually agreed purposes.
USDA expenditures for trade fairs and other market development projects abroad
amounted to $7,500,000 during fiscal year 1962.
This information points up that our method of reporting exports is misleading
and very unrealistic. In the above case agricultural exports of $5.1 billion, and
reported in the figure of total exports as such, should have been reported at
$3.1 `billion or the staggering figure of $2 billion less, and which immediately
reduces the total export figures from $21.2 billion to $19.2 billion.
Our trade statistics should truly show our position in trade, so that trade
policy decisions can be based on accurate figures, and not figures that under-
value imports `and overvalue exports.
Adjustment Assistance under TEA
As an important part of the Trade Expansion Act, provisions are made for
petitions to be filed with the Tariff Commission by workers or firm's for adjust-
ment assistance. The Tariff Commission makes an investigation and if their
PAGENO="0328"
3764
report to the President is in the affirmative, the President may take action to
provide tariff adjustment, provide that firms may request the Secretary of
Commerce for certification of eligibility to apply for adjustment assistance, pro-
vide that the workers of such industry may request the Secretary of Labor
for cert1fication of eligibility to apply for adjustment assistance, or the President
may take any combination of such actions.
This is what is provided in the law, but in actual practice since the enact-
ment of the law October 11, 1962, not one case has been, certified for adjustment
assistance, and this very important provision has been rendered useless by a
rigid interpretation by the Tariff Commission of Title III, Sec. 301, subsections
(b) and (c) and the damaging phrase repeatedly used (quote): "Whether, as
a result in major part of concessions granted under trade agreements, an article
is being imported into the United States in such increased quantities as to cause,
or threaten to cause, serious injury to the domestic industry producing an article
which is like or directly competitive with the imported article." (end of quote)
The words "in major part" were not in `the bill as passed by the House, it there
read "whether, as a result of concessions granted under trade agreements." This
is the wording under H.R. 11970 when it was being considered by the Senate
Finance Committee and as Senator Harry Byrd placed it in the record at the
outset of the Hearing, Monday, July 23, 1962.
The addition of the words "in major part," added by the Senate Finance
Committee, stripped the law of any meaning, and resulted in a rigid interpreta-
tion by the Tariff Commission, and prevented any intent to provide assistance to
workers and firms adversely affected by imports due to U.S. trade policy. A
workable and effective adjustment assistance program was vitally important to
Labor, in fact as AFL-CIO President Mr. George Meany testified, "It is indis-
pensable to our support of the trade program as a whole."
Secretary of Commerce Hodges testified that he estimated that this part of
the program would cost $122 million for finns and $45 million for workers over
the five-year period of the law, a total of $167 million.
To date not one case has had an affirmative finding for workers or firms.
In direct contrast the Automotive Products Trade Act of 1965, legislated after
the trade agreement reached with Canada by the United States on automotive
products, provides a more realistic approach to adjustment assistance. The Act
provides for petitions by workers and firms; it provides for investigation by
the Tariff Commission but contrary to the procedure under the Trade Expansion
Act, the Automotive Adjustment Assistance Board makes the final determina-
tion and not the Tariff Commission.
This Board, consisting of the Secretaries of Commerce, Labor and Treasury,
has been delegated authority by the President to carry out the provisions of Ad-
justment Assistance and in 12 of the first 16 cases filed, assistance has been pro-
vided and $3 million in benefits have been paid to workers in approximately a
two-year period. Of course there is no substitute for a job and a productive place
in our society.
Effect on Labor of 1J.2. Trade Policy
All working Americans are affected by United States trade policy; our Na-
tion requires maximum employment and healthy industries to maintain a healthy
economy, and without a healthy economy our position as a world power and
leader of the free world will quickly deteriorate, and just as quickly be replaced
by another country less generous than the United States.
The tremendous rise in American investment and technology abroad, added
to rising capacity of foreign firms-with the resulting decrease in exports and
increase in imports-eliminates existing jobs and job potential, and reduces
domestic industry's capacity to operate at a healthy level and properly share
in our country's growth.
With 40 percent of direct private foreign investment or $22 billion at the
end of 1966. invested in manufacturing abroad, what effect will this have on
U.S. imports and displacement of U.S. labor?
Manufactured products incorporate more steps of labor than do raw products.
A manufactured product may go through a number of processes and fabrica-
tions in each of which additional labor is applied. A raw product goes through
a minimum of steps, possibly only one or two exclusive of transportation. Semi-
manufactures fall into a halfway slot between raw products and finished
manufactures.
PAGENO="0329"
3765
U.S. IMPORTS
[Dollar amounts in billions[
1961
1966
Increase
(percent)
Crudefoodstuffs
Crude materials
$1.60
2.87
$2.12
3.85
32.4
33. 9
Semimanufactures
Manufactured goods, in
cluding food
3.38
6.68
5.59
13.99
65.3
109.5
Comparing the five-year period 1961-66, the chart above points up with great
clarity the large increases in imports of semimanufactures and manufactured
goods, 65 percent and 109 percent respectively. Since these two classes of prod-
ucts carry with them the greatest amount of labor expended, it results in a larger
displacement of LT.S. workers and job opportunities.
U.S. IMPORTS
[Dollar amounts in millions[
1961 1966 Increase
(percent)
Cement, lime and gypsum $18,759 $35,379 90
Ceramic floor and wail tile - 14,952 27,744 85
Pottery, earthenware and chinaware 33,643 55,222 60
Flat glass 47,449 57.712 22
Illuminating and table and art glassware 21,712 36,239 67
The above comparison of 1961 w'ith 1966, in the products produced by members
of the Stone, Glass and Clay Coordinating Committee bear out the previously
shown increases in imports of semimanufactures and manufactures of labor
intensive products. It does not show the many years of damage causing plant
closings, jobs eliminated and overall loss of potential jobs. These figures do
show the increasing penetration of imports and the dollar amounts are based
on FOB values and do not include ocean freight or marine insurance which
would increase the amounts by at least 10 percent.
In pottery for example, the 60 percent increase in imports in 1966 over 1961
is called the adding of "insult to injury." Imports of china and earthenware, led
in major part by the Japanese, had already captured 48.4 percent and 33.6 per-
cent of the domestic market, respectively. This is an almost unbelievable but
factual account of what has happened in the pottery industry. Of the $55 million
of total pottery imports in 1966 the Japanese captured $33 million. Something
must be done to prevent annihilation of this industry and its workers.
Note the rising increases in imports of cement, lime and gypsum pi~oducts,
with a 90 percent increase; ceramic floor and wall title 85 percent increase; flat
glass (includes sheet, plate and float, cast and rolled, tempered, laminated, and
mirrors) 22 percent increase; and illuminating and table and art glassware,
67 percent increase.
The officers and members of these International Unions are showing great
concern over the jobs that are continuing to be eliminated, by imports, and auto-
mation attempts to compete that have not slowed the tide, but acted as a deter-
rent to annihilation.
Immediate action to halt job losses due to our trade policies would be in our
Nation's interest, and corrective measures should be taken, in conjunction with
existing and proposed Government programs, to help our unemployed, and to
put a stop to the dangerous erosion of U.S. employment due to the rising tide
of foreign imports.
~umrnary
American jobs are being exported to other countries by the astounding in-
crease in private foreign investment. Increasing from a 1950 figure of $19004
billion to a 1966 figure of $86.235 billion or a 454 percent increase, using Amer-
ican investment plus foreig-n labor to produce products for sale within the for-
eign market and for export to the LTnited States, displacing American labor and
PAGENO="0330"
3766
yet expecting American workers to purchase products that are putting them out
of work and destroying job potential. U.S. foreign affiliates exported products
back to the U.S. totaling $5.133 billion, in manufactured products, mining prod-
ucts, and petroleum and petroleum products. These exports flow from private
direct foreign investment of $54.5 billion, as of the end of 1966, located primarily
in Canada and Western Europe.
The American people have for many years been misled, with regard to our
balance of trade figures, into believing the United States has been enjoying large
surpluses in our trade account, when in fact we are not~ If we valued our imports
as most countries do, on a CIF basis, our import valuations would increase by
ten to twenty percent.
Also, we overvalue our exports by including Government subsidies within our
export figures. As previously shown for fiscal 1961-62, $2 billion was included
in our agricultural export figure, that in reality represented the Government
paid subsidies and Public Law 480 subsidies.
Reporting imports on a CIF basis, withdrawing Government subsidies when
reporting agricultural exports, would give a true picture of our balance of trade,
and in many, many cases would have resulted in a deficit in our trade account.
Accurate and realistic trade statistics on our imports and exports would make
possible more responsible and responsive decisions on our Nation's foreign trade
policy. It is imperative for the Congress to have the accurate facts at their dis-
posal so they can regulate foreign commerce and preserve this Nation's economic
well-being.
The adjustment assistance section of the Trade Expansion Act, providing for
assistance to firms and workers has proven worthless, negated by the addition
of the words "in major part." As a result there has not been a single case with
an affirmative finding by the Tari~ Commission since enactment of the law
in 1962.
On behalf of the Stone, Glass and Clay Coordinating Committee, we urge
legislation to regulate foreign trade and investment policy to restore the economic
well-being of domestic industry and American workers.
I want to thank you for this opportunity to express our convictions before
this Committee.
Mr. TJLLMAN. Thank you, Mr. Chester.
Are there questions?
Mr. Collier.
Mr. COLLIER. May I ask, is the porcelain insulator business repre-
sented by your unions?
Mr. CHESTER. I would have to check.
Mr. REISER. We represent three plants in porcelain.
Mr. COLLIER. Is this business particularly affected by Japanese
importation?
Mr. REISER. The large insulators are, and of course in that area
of the smaller insulators, there are other products, like glass, and that,
which has affected the volume of porcelain products.
Mr. COLLIER. May I ask, is tile also in your union?
Mr. REISER. That is right.
Mr. CoLLIER. There has been some voluntary limitation of Japanese
ininortation of tile, hasn't there?
Mr. REISER. Yes, sir, that is correct.
Mr. COLLIER. In order to preserve some part of the market for
American producers?
Mr. REISER. Yes.
Mr. COLLIER. Do you know what percentage that is?
Mr. REISER. Well, no, I don't, because there seems to be not too
much said about it. Somebody is afraid of rocking the boat, I think
is what it is. Every time I seek some information, it is better not to say
anything about it.
Now, we lost approximately 4,000 tile workers~ that is, floor and
n-all tile, and it took 3 or 4 years to establish that they were dumping.
PAGENO="0331"
3767
I think the recession in the building industry is what the tipoff was
in the thinp.
Now, I understand that agreements were reached on a self-imposed
ceiling, and I don't know the increment, but as I understand it, it is
predicated on the iroiected production of tile in the coming year, and
this is a preestablished figure.
I understand a vulnerable part of that is that most~ of these pro-
jections are optimistic in their makeup, and this kind of gives a false
result, but it is a whole lot better than what it was.
Mr. COLLIER. I understand the ceramic tile people were going to
testify at these hearings, and they canceled. I wondered if you knew
the reason.
Mr. REISER. This is a very low paid industry, about $2.23 an hour,
and we put in a modified form of a Scanlon plan, which is a scheme
to reward the worker if he reduces his unit cost on labor.
We were continually increasing our production, but we couldn't get
any yield from this formula. But since this agreement has been
reached, we went up approximately 20 cents an hour in this Scanlon
plan, so that the reaction was nearly immediate.
But the tragedy of it is that, under this assistance feature, there was
no substance to it. Now, these some 4,000 workers are out and they
haven't been retrained. They have received nothing, and, being a low
paid industry, they have no pensions to speak of, because what money
we had negotiated we put in across the board rather than in the
fringes.
Mr. COLLIER. Thank you very much.
That is all, Mr. Chairman.
Mr. LLLMAN. Thank you very much.
Mr. CHESTER. Our whole panel, Mr. Chairman, will be testifying.
We have been allotted so muc.h time.
We had planned to start with Mr. Raiser, and then Mr. Thomas, and
then Mr. Cornett, and then Mr. Barbaree, assisted by Mr. Lord.
Mr. ULLMAN. You may introduce each one, and proceed as you see
fit. We will withhold questions until yOu are through.
Mr. CHESTER. Mr. Raiser will be first, of the United Glass & Ceramic
Workers, the international president.
STATEMENT OP RALPH REISER
Mr. REISER. We have 42,000 members in our organization, 35,000 in
the United States, and 7,000 in Canada. About 25,000 of our members
in the United States, or more than half, are what has been called over-
exposed to some type of trade agreement.
In fact, we have been overexposed so long you might say we are
pretty well done in the thing.
Of course, all these other side arrangements, agreements, and under-
standmgs result in loss of jobs to us. What we really want to talk
about, not downgrading the importance of this assistance feature, is
about our jobs, our own jobs, and we would like to see a type of tariff
that would be flexible enough to provide for special problems of differ-
ent industries. S
Now, also, we are in a position that, come this fall, Pittsburgh Plate
Glass-and I will address myself to the block glass industry_-and
Libbey-Owens~For~ Co. have built new plants in Canada, and they-
will be in full production in the fail.
PAGENO="0332"
3768
Now, that means that they will come underneath the Canadian-
American Automobile Act. Of course, this act did have an assistance
program. However, it expired this month, I believe, and, if it isn't
extended, we will get a zero on that one.
However, we are not too pessimistic about the Canadian situation,
because we got a chance there to do a little work of our own, in nego-
tiating equal pay, just as the United Automobile Workers have done.
However, in other phases of this, what we have been exposed to,
what we really want, is a time element. What we really want is our
jobs as glassworkers, and all we ask is a chance and time to adjust to
new methods and new processes.
We need time to adjust to new processes of manufacturing flat glass,
developed by foreign glass companies, because it so happens that in the
fiatglass industry, all the innovations, all the new methods, have been
developed by foreign glass companies, and licensed by foreign glass
companies..
We are willing to work our way out of this economic press, if we
are only given a chance to compete.
In 1962 we asked President Kennedy for time to meet the flood of
imports triggered by the new modern plants financed by the Marshall
plan.
President Kennedy increased duties effective June 1962. Did we
respond? We did.
Using the Federal Reserve Index, 1957-59 as 100, we increased our
productivity to 167 by 1966, while during the same period our wages
went up 17.5 percent, while the average earnings for all manufactur-
ing went up 28.8 percent.
A good performance? Yes, but not good enough; for, in the mean-
time, Pilkington Bros. of England developed a new method for
making glass. It is called float glass, that makes all the new plants
built since the war obsolete. So it is a new ball game.
With the advent of float glass throughout the world, and some 34
licenses have been granted, the imports reacted dramatically, rising
from 8.6 in 1966 to 13.6 in the first 6 months in 1967.
President Johnson, in October of last year, saw fit to keep into effect
the relief that was granted in 1962 on single and double strength.
Now, just last week I was at Charleston and Shreveport, and Libbey-
Owens-Ford has developed a new method called the air flotation proc-
ess, which they believe may compete with thin glass as far a.s float is
concerned.
Now, they gave the proposition to us that either we cut manpower,
or they could build this plant overseas. In fa.ct., I think I can say
without hesitation that most of the flat glass that is supplied to the
coastal cities is partly manufactured by Pittsburgh Plate or Libbey-
Owens-Ford in their plants overseas, because again we are in the un-
enviable position that when the trade is favorable to the United States
empty bottoms coming back, they put glass on, flat glass on as ballast,
and it is practically a premium of getting glass as a ballast in the thing.
So that, as trade is favorable, this gives us an unfavorable reaction
in the thing.
Now, we did cut off approximately 75 men in the process at Charles-
ton and Shreveport. Now, Charleston, W. Va., isn't what you call a
lush employment centerS Now, our average earnings are $3.65 an hour,
and when you cut a guy out of the glass plant, he has to go over and
work for $1.80 an hour, and you have a pre.tty sore guy on your hands.
PAGENO="0333"
3769
It took our local committees and our international representatives
about 2 weeks to work this out. I went down there last week to report
on it, and they said, "You guys weren't negotiating. You guys were
waiting for Congress to pass a stiff gun law before you come back here
to report," and in West Virginia, that is no outlandish statement.
Now, we believe that the fact that a new process has come into being,
and Ford Motor Co. is going to build two more floats, that these things
should be taken into consideration.
Now, we have pledged ourselves, and if I may, I will put in the
record two booklets that we are going to give at our convention, in
which we promise and in which we pledge ourselves to cooperate in
the installation of new methods, full utilization of the work force,
which is something new for our industry.
We are seeking through other organizations, like the coordinating
committee, fair labor standards, although the more you dig into it,
what fair labor standards are is pretty elusive in detail, but what they
seem to imply-and we are getting active in the ICF, which is the
trade secretariat that nearly all glass workers in the free part of the
world belong to, and we are feeding them information.
I have accepted a cochairmanship on a committee-we are feeding
them all the information, the imports, the prices that their manu-
facturers are receiving, to beef up their bargaining.
We are following the same type of our parallel organization, of the
IMF, which is the automobile version of it.
I am sure that the recent increases that the workers in France got
in the automobile factories came from some of the information and
some of the activities triggered by the IMF committee, so that we are
not looking on this in a defeatist attitude.
In principle, we believe in free trade, but we are asking for a break,
or an adjustment.
We think that something could be arranged, that if `the industry
lagged in its productivity, if the exporter, the importer, don't come
up in some of this fair labor or minimum wage deal, that these factors
should be taken into account, allowing some kind of a workable in-
centive for the right to go into these markets.
In closing, I would like to read a news item which I ran' across, and
it is an article in Glass Review Monthly, "Glass Around the World."
I am not going `to pronounce the companies, because I am not very
good on pronunciation if it isn't German or Irish.
Future competition between the capitalist and communist flat glass indus-
tries was projected at a recent conference in Belgrade. Organized by the Yugos-
Jar Glass Industries, Pancevo, the conference was attended by representatives of
exporting organizations of several countries, including Razno Export (Soviet
Union), Glas Export (Czechoslovakia), Mineks (Poland), Mineraliniportexport
(Rumania), Diaglass-Keramik (East Germany), Industrieimport (Bulgaria),
and Femunion (Hungary).
Officials of the Yugoslav glass factory at Paneevo, and sheet glass factories in
Lipik, Novo Mesto, and Zajeca, also attended the meeting. Representatives of
the Yugoslav trade firms in charge of exporting flat glass, Hemikalija, Zagreb,
and Kemijaimpex, Liubijana, were present, too.
Coordination of production and merchandising of flat glass in all of the
communist countries was long overdue. Domestic requirements of each coun-
try were evaluated and deliveries assigned to domestic facilities and neighbor-
ing countries.
In view of the ever-increasing exports of Eastern European flat glass to the
West, the question of selling prices has become paramount. Because Pilkington
95-159 O-68-~pt. 8-22
PAGENO="0334"
3770
has granted licenses to Russia and Czechoslovakia, the problem of how to over-
come the price disadvantage between the Fourcault drawn glass and the Puking-
ton process has to be solved.
In view of the concerted movement of the communist countries, it would
seem mandatory for the flat glass industries of the West to get together as soon
as possible in order to be better prepared for the coming battle for a share of
the world's markets.
So it looks like the comrades are pretty well organized in this thing.
Mr. ULLMAN. We would hope you could keep your remarks brief,
because we want to hear all the members, and you have already ex-
ceeded your time.
Mr. Rnisnn. Thank you for listening to me.
(The material referred to follows:)
GLASS ABOUND THE WORLD
Future competition between the capitalist and communist flat glass industries
was projected at a recent conference in Belgrad. Organized by the Yugoslav
Glass Industries, Pancevo, the conference was attended by representatives of
exporting organizations of several conutries, including Razno Export (Soviet
Union), Glas Export (Czechoslovakia), Mineks (Poland), Mineral-importexport
(Rumania), Diaglass-Keramik (East Germany), Industrieimport (Bulgaria),
and Ferunion (Hungary).
Officials of the Yugoslav glass factory at Pancevo, and sheet glass factories
in Lipik, Novo Mestro, and Zajeca, also attended the meeting. Representatives of
the Yugoslav trade firms in charge of exporting flat glass, Hemikalija, Zagreb,
and Kemijaimpex, Llubljana, were present, too.
Coordination of production and merchandising of flat glass in all of the com-
munist conutries was long overdue. Domestic requirements of each conutry were
evaluated and deliveries assigned to domestic facilities and neighboring countries.
In view of the ever-increasing exports of Eastern European flat glass to the
West, the question of selling prices has become paramount. Because Pilkington
has granted licenses to Russia and Czechoslovakia, the problem of how to over-
come the price disadvantage between the Fourcault drawn glass and the Pilking-
ton process has to be solved.
In view of the concerted movement of the communist conutries, it would seem
mandatory for the flat glass industries of the West to get together as soon as
possible in order to be better prepared for the coming battle for a share of the
world's markets.
AUSTRIA
Austria's glass industry is hard hit by increasing competition not only from sonic
Eastern European countries, but from Italy, one of its former main export out-
lets, as well. Shipments from the communist countries are usually sold at dump-
ing prices and Italian quotations are extremely low. Austria points out that she
considers the Italian quotations particularly damaging because Italian produc-
tion capacity has almost doubled in recent years and presently exceeds require-
ments of the domestic market by 50 per cent.
Austria recently started production of insulating glass. Up to the middle of 1967,
domestic factories could only supply one-third of Austrian requirements. Two-
thirds had to be imported, primarily from Belgium, Germany, and France. In
1966, 5.72 million pounds (2.6 million kilograms) of insulating glass, valued at
$1.68 million (42 million Austria schillings), was delivered by foreign countries.
Austria has continuously complained about the imports of window glass from
the communist countries at prices which are far below the existing Austrian
price level. Because Austria has to trade with her neighbors, it is understandable
that, in every new trade agreement, a certain amount of flat glass is included
by Austria reluctantly.
A short while ago, the new trade agreement between Austria and Czechoslo~
vakia, covering all of 1968, was signed. As usual, flat glass for special purposes
and signal lights, as well as insulating glass, amounting to $100,000, will be im-
ported by Austria.
Starting January 1, Austrian glass wholesalers increased prices for flat glass up
to 5/64-inch (2 millimeter) thick by a maximum of 3 per cent. All other thick-
nesses over 2 millimeter were upped by a maximum of 5 per cent.
PAGENO="0335"
GOLD
`~ AND THE
NATIONAL
ECONOMY
A PLAN TO REGULATE FOREIGN TRADE AND INVESTMENT
POLICIES TO RESTORE THE ECONOMIC WELL-BEING OF
DOMESTIC INDUSTRY AND LABOR*
:.~ 1
..4)
(3771)
PAGENO="0336"
3772
~FAIR INTERNATIONAL TRADE ACT
This is a bill that has now been introduced by 25
Congressmen to provide for regulation of imports in
all industries. The bill provides for investigationand
hearings by the Tariff Commission a ft e r filing of a
petition for an import ceiling, s u c h filing is open to
anationallabor union, industry, Senate Finance Com-
mittee, House Ways and Means, or r eq u e s t of the
President. After investigation by the Ta r if f Com-
mission if imports related to domestic consumption
meet the criteria of the bill they certify a ceiling on
imports to the President, the import ceiling is pro-
claimed by the President; if impo rts penetrate the
ceiling proclaimed in any six-month period, a quan-
tity limitation is invoked by the President.
There is considerable interest in this bill by in-
dustry, congressmen, and la.bo r unions.. We have
collabdrated.on the bill and been successful in getting
many introductions by congressmen who like the con-
cept of a broad-base bill as opposed to specific in-
dustry bills.~ This is a real opportunity to help ob-
tain passage of a bill which would prevent rising im-
ports from displacing our employment and employ-
ment potential. T h e Chairman of Ways and Means,
Wilbur Mills, is interested in this bill and suggested
we get Congressman Herlong to introduce it which he
did May 1, 1968. Following this introduction we have
been able to get multiple introductions by the follow-
ing Congressmen: Herlong, Fla. (16936), Utt, Calif.
Collier, Ill. , Perkins, Ky. , Staggers, W. Va., Hech-
ler, W. Va., Moore,, W. Va., Der~t~ Pa. (17043),
Whalley, Pa., Clark, Pa. , Saylor, Pa., Ashbrook,
Ohio, Thomson, Wis., Okonski, Wis., Fisher,
Texas, Philbin, Mass., Hunt, N. 3. , Langen, Mimi..
Pelley, Wash., Baring, Nev., Barry, S. Dak., Harri-
son, Wyo., Lennon, No. Car., Korm~gay, *~. Car.,
Keith, Mass.
PAGENO="0337"
ECONOMiC TRENDS IN THE U.S. FLAT GLASS INDUSTRY
TARIFF
%CHANGE
TARIFF
PEAK
REDUCTION
1958-80.
1965
~VERAGE
INCREASE
YEAR
1967
to
to
.
VALUE OF SHIPMENT.S, ALL FLAT GLASS
(in millions of dollars)
1958-60
1962
1965
(annual rate)
1967
1967
$490. 6
$490. 6
-
$676. 4
$585. 9
+19.4%
-13.4%
of which -
,
Sheet glass
Plate, float, rolled & wire glass
Laminated, specially tempered &
other flat ~lass
111. 1
157.1
222.4
126. 4
159.5
204.7
140. 6
213.7
322. 1
116. 5
190.4
279.0
+ 4.9%
+21.2%.
~
+25,4%
-17. 1%
-10.9%
-13.4%
EMPLOYMENT.r (in thousands)
AVERAGE WEEKLY HOURS, PROD, WKRS.
AVERAGE HOURLY EARNINGS, PROD. WKRS.
32.2
40.1
$ 3.09
30. 4
38. 3
$ 3. 29
32~3
42.5
$ 3. 52
30. 2
40. 8
$ 3. 63
+ 6. 2% -6. 5C7~
+ 1.7% -4.0%
+17. 5% +3. 1%
- Avg.. Hourly Earnings, AIl,Mfg,
DOMES TIC MA~ET ~$ millions)
IMPORTS, f.o.b. U.S. port .
($ millions)
EXPORTS, f. o. b, mill ($ millions)
of which, Canada ($ milliOns)
IMPORTS AS A % OF DOMESTIC MARKET
$ 2, 19
$538.6
$ 63. 4
$ 15. 5
$ 10. 1
11.8%
$ 2.39
$542. 9
.
$ 70. 6
$ 18. 3
$ 12. 0
130%
$ 2. 61
$720.6
$ 69. 4
$ 25. 2
$ 15. 8
9.6%
$ 2. 82
$636. 6
$ 86. 4
$ 35. 7
$ 23.6
13.6%
+28. 8%. +8.0%
+18. 2°Jo -11, .7%
,
+36. 3% +24. 5%
+ 130. 3% +41.7%
+ 133. 7% + 49. 4%
+15.3% +41.7%
~A D~TT~T/'C ~ ~
Ld~ L~.LNiLN `.30 ~&LSJtJLUV1I~ ~
Net Profit After Taxes as a
% of Sales (Sheet Glass)
Gross Earnings, *All Flat Glass,
as a % of Sales
4,9%
1,1%
4,8%
2,7%(1966)
44,9%
43.8%
35, 8%
31, 1%
38. 1%
33. 8%
5. 6%
.-11. 3%
* Sales less payroll and materials purchases, before payment of overhead, depreciation, and taxes,
PAGENO="0338"
GOLD AND ECONOMIC GROWTH
While Gold Supply Declined, The National Economy Grew
1947-1967
(In Billions of Dollars)
Source of data: Economic Report of the President: 1968.
PAGENO="0339"
37Th
The recent gold crisis was blafrned on eve rything
1,-n Vii'twi,u War and well heeled tourists to
I I i k () I. (~ 1)1(1 country - -
&-v- ()I1~( ~fl a \V 11 ii e SOIflCOflC mentioned U. S..
investments abroad to explain ou r deficit in the bal~-
ance of payments.
Further, they have claimed the only effect on the
a v e r a g e Joe would be that he would pay more for a
gold filling, or wedding ring.
T~tey, say all that glistens is not gold. Neither
can explanations hide the fact that private foreign in-
vestment results in the export of American jobs.
With the tremendous r i s e in private foreign in-
vestment of 454 percent between the years 1950 and
1966, this increased foreign capacity can only serve
to decrease our exports and increase our imports,
adding further distress to our b alan c e of payments
deficit.
The United States is importing products from
U.S. foreign subsidiaries and affiliates of U.S. com-
panies, in direct competition with their domestic
operation or o the r domestic producers of the same
product. In 1965 U. S. foreign affiliates exported pro-
ducts bacl~ to the U.S. totaling $5, 133 billion. Many
of these affiliates have more workers employed abroad
than they do in the U.S., and if not restricted this
trend of decreasing exports, increasing imports and
displacement of Am e r i c a n industry and labor will
continue.
PRIVATE FOREIGN INVESTMENTS
U. S. foreign investment - - and, as a substantial
partof this category, U.S. private foreigninvestment
-- must be given full consideration as an inseparable
part of our foreign trade policy. The following Chart
`A" will s e r v e to show the astounding increases
our U.S. foreign invesn-iients; Chart "B" the a~e.
PAGENO="0340"
3776
distribution of U.S. di~ect private foreign invest-
ments ; Chart "C" the industry distribution of U.S.
direct private foreign investments. (The sources of
information for Charts A, B and C were the 1958
Hearingsby the Subcommittee on Private Foreign In-
vestment, and the Department of Commerce Survey
of Current Business, September, 1967.)
CHART "A"
United States Investments Abroad
(Millions of Dollars)
1950 1957 1966
Total U.S. investments abroad $32,844 $54,215 $111,874
Prviate Investments 19,004 36,812 86,235
Long-term 17,488 33,588 75,565
Direct 11,788 25,252 54,562
Portfolio 5,700 8,336 21,003
Short-term 1,516 3,224 10,670
U.S. Government credits & claims 13,840 17,403 25,639
Long-term 13,518 15,548 21,182
Short.term 322 1,855 4,457
In Chart "A" we find that total U.S.. investment
abroad in 1966 has inc~reas ed by practically four times
the 1950 figure of $32.8 billion. The large share of
the 1966 total figure is made up of private invest-
ments, $86.2 billion of the $111.8 billion total for
1966.
The divisions of private investment are long-term
meaning a period in excess of one ye a r, and short-
term. The book value of our various short-term pri-
vate investments at the end of 1966 totaled ~i0.6
billion;
Long-term private investments can be placed in
two categories, portfolio and d i r e c t. Portfolio in-
vestment largely entails private ownership of foreign
government bonds and business securities, ~ no
implication i n management decisions. Portfolio in-
vestment abroad in 1966 totaled $21 billion.
PAGENO="0341"
3777
Direct foreign investment is ownership of 25. per-.
cent or more of a business and usually i m p o r t a n t
managementparticipation. Private direct foreign in-
vestments abroad in 1966 totaled $54. 5 billion.
In all divisions of private foreign investment,
comparing 1950-1957-1966, there have been tremen-
dous increases in the holdings of U.S. companies
and private investors abroad.
In Chart "B' comparing the area distribution o~f
direct private foreign investment for 1957 with 1966
we find that considerable went into Western Europe,
with a 14 percent increase, so the investment flow is
to the developed countries of Western Europe, while
the less developed and under developed countries in
Latin America, Africa a n d the Middle East dropped
considerably in investments to their areas. And this
happened despite the emphasis, stated in the 1958
hearings, on the necessity of changing the private in-
vestment pattern to e n c o u r a g e more flow to Latin
America, Middle East and Africa to deter. the Soviet
economic offensive in those areas.
CHART "B'
AREA DISTRIBUTION OF
U.S. DIRECT PRIVATE FOREIGN INVESTMENTS
]-9S7 1966
BOOK VALUES, $25.3 BILLION
BOOK VALUES, $51~.5 BILLION
PAGENO="0342"
3778
Chart "C" compares the industry distribution of
U.S. direct private foreign investments in 1957 with
1966. You willnote a strong upward thrustin manu-
facturing investment, a 9 percent increase over
1957, a decline in petroleum, mining and public uti-
lities. Manufacturing leads all o t h e r indüs try in-
vestment with a 1966 foreign total of $22 billion in
all areas, while petroleum is in second place with
$16 billion.
CHART "C"
INDUSTRY DISTRIBUTION OF
U.S. DIRECT PRIVATE FOREIGN INVESTMENTS
1957 1966
The three charts which show the increases in
U.. S. private foreign investmentbear out a prediction
made by Mr. Robert M. Mitchell, Vice President of
the Whirlpool Corporation, in Hearings held on the
subject of private foreign investmentby the Subcom-
mittee on Foreign Trade Policy, December 1958.
After Mr. Mitchell's testimony, questions were
asked by Congressman John W. Byrnes:
"Mr. Byrnes: As I gather th e b a s i s of your
concern here, among other things, is the fact that
youforesee a necessity as far as American business
is c o n c e r n e d to shift from an export business to
manufacturing abroad, an investing and going through
~N~(6% 7%
BOOK VALUES, $25.3 BILLION
BOOK VALUES, $SIi.5 BILLION
PAGENO="0343"
3779
the manufacturing process abroad; is that right?
Mr. Mitchell: That is correct, Mr. Byrnes.
Mr. Byrnes: Do you attribute that trend in part
to this common Market trend, the European Common
Market and the proposals fo r a common market in
other areas? Is there any other factor that gives
rise to that?
Mr. Mitchell: Basicallythatis it, Mr. Byrnes.
In many of the Latin American countries at the mo-
ment for practical purposes it is impos sible to. ex-
p o r t particularly consumer durable goods. There
is a rising nationalism in many of these countries,
and th~y are trying to industrialize, and to raise
their standard of living. So that American com-
panies, if theyare going to have a partof that market
at all, must invest in some form or other.
Mr. Byrnes: You don't see a great future then
a s far as the export o f finished commodities fror~
this country. You see that contracting, I g a t h e r,
and an increase in manufacturing abroad and with
foreign labor?
Mr. Mitchell: I t h i n k t h a t is the way it will
happen; yes, sir.
Mr. Byrnes: Great emphasis has been put on
the fact of the importance of the trade-agreements
program and all of the rest of it, and the increase
in our exports, and the developing ofthis freer trade.
I gather that you would suggest at least by your tes -
timony that we may be getting into a period where
that is going to be reversed?
Mr. Mitchell: I think that that is quite right,
sir.
Mr. Byrnes: That is all."
PAGENO="0344"
3780
This prediction of increasing investment abroad
and the decrease in the export of finished commod-
ities from this country has come to pass. This in-
creased foreign capacity can only serve to decrease
our exports and i n c r e a s e our imports, and since
capitalis mobil and labor is not, the result has been
loss of American jobs and 1 o s s to those American
industries that do not choose to move or that do not
have capital to make such a move.
Many U. S. corporations are becoming global in
their makeup, with vast holdings and assets in other
nations. Consider that in 1950, in direct private
foreign investment the U~ S. had $11.8 billion inves -
tedaround the world, this r o s e to $25. 3 billion in
1957 and to $54. 5 billion in 1966. Many of these
global corporations are showing their c o n c e r n a-
gainstanyrestrictionto their access to the Canadian
and U.S. markets. They recognize that free access
to Canadian and U. S. markets is in their corporation
interest; they want to invest abroad, enjoy the mar-
kets and low-wage labor; and they also want to enjoy
the Canadian and U.S. market from abroad, in some
cases in direct competition with their domestic oper -
ation or other domestic producers of the same pro-
duct.
United States foreign manufacturing affiliates
sales in 1965 were $42. 4 billion compared to $18. 3
billion in 1957, for an increase of 132 per cent.
In 1965, $34. 7 billion of such sales were with-
in the area of plant location, howeve~, $7. 7 billion
represented export sales to other countries, includ-
ing the United States. The products shipped to the
U. S. amounted to 24 `percent of to ta 1 export sales
of manufacturing affiliates, or $1. 856 billion.
This figuredoes notinNc~ude exports to the U.S.
of foreign mining affiliates o~f'U.S. firms in the a-
mount of $1. 225 billion, nor does it include exports
to the U. S. of petroleum and petroleum p r o d u c t s
PAGENO="0345"
3781
by U. S. foreign petroleum affiliates, estimated at
$2, 052 billion.
Combining manufacturing, mining and petroleum
export sales to the U. S., by U. S. foreign affiliates
in 1965, the total would be an astounding $5. 133
billion.
The tim.e has come for a re-evaluation of this
expanded investment program in terms of the U.S.
economy, employment, o ut flow of capital, loss of
revenue to the United States and effect of imports on
U. S. industry and labor.
Our rising deficit in our balance of payments has
broughtthis problem into focus and President Johnson
has wisely issued mandatory restrictions on private
foreign investmentas of January 1, 1968. We heartily
agree withhis actions designed to preserve our coun-
try's financial strength.
NTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
We've all seen and had Canadian coins in our
pocket change at one time or another and have en-
countered little or no trouble in spending the foreign
currency as though it were our own. The same is
true for U. S. coins in most of Canada.
Butimaginetryingto putour coins in a cigarette
or coffee machine in Japan, Sweden, France, Italy,
West Germany, Belgium or the Netherlands.
Yet these nations, along with the U. S. , Canada
and the united Kingdom are the Big 10 in foreign
trade and account for 56 per cent of the votingpower
in the International Monetary Fund which b o a s t s a
total membership of 106 nations.
And if you want to do business with these or any
of the other International Monetary Fund nations and
PAGENO="0346"
3782
make the Kennedy rounds (GATT) work, youhad better
have some form of payment or exchangable currency
acceptable by the individual n a t i o n s, backed up ~by
adequate reserves.
Right now, however, the F r e e World's trading
nations face the threat of running short of ready re-
serves of gold, U.S. dollars, other readily accepted
currencies and credit. Some economists fear that a
reserve shortage would put a severe crimp in world
trade.
The most recent example of this is the devalua-
tion of the pound sterling by Britain. Full effects of
the devaluation may not be known for months but world
governments began reacting instantly following Bri-
tain's decision. The same nations that have depended
upon the pound sterling as a solid fo rm of currency
and reserve have now been asked through the IMF to
loanthe British government $1.4 billion dollars in an
effort to s a v e the British economy, narrowing even
further the number of world currencies that generally
preserve and guarantee the others.
To remedy the reserve and credit shortage the
Big 10 leaders in world trade and manufacturing have
supported a contingency plan to create a new kind of
international money that was p r e s e n t e d to the 106
IMF nations at their i'ec~nt 22nd annual meeting.
The technical n a m e of the new money would be
special drawing rights (SDR) from the IMF. Some
experts loosely call it "Paper Gold." But what ever
the name, each nation would get some of the new kind
of money to add to its reserves.
If you t h i n k that t h e new "drawing rights" are
like creating money out of thin air, you a r e right to
a considerable extent.
But that doesn't mean that it is "funny money"
PAGENO="0347"
~783
because all of it will have the b a c k i n g of the total
resources of the 10 major nations a s well as every
other nation participating in its use.
The reason for creation of some new reserve
asset is simple: There is a growing shortage of gold
and dollars necessary to settle the trading balances
among nations.
What is not so well understood is the mechanics
of the new proposal. But this is not surprising: No-
body has tried to create mqney on this scale in the
hi s to r y of the world and many technical questions
are&t yet settled.
Such a pl an is crucial to the United States be-
cause for several years more dollars have been leav-
ing the country in trade, aid and military and tourist
spending than have been returning in expenditures by
foreigners in the United States. In other words, the
United States has a balance-of-payments deficit.
This means thatmanynations have built up huge
reserves of U.S. dollars, which the United States is
committed to redeem for gold upon demand. Thus,
these claims.
In recent years however, the U.S. Gold supply had
dwindled consistently as foreign central banks Lave
sought to r e d e em their American dollar reserves
for gold. The U.S. gold reserve stood at $26 billion
at the end of W o r 1 d W a r II, but it has been cut in
half since then. Durin.g July alone it dropped another
$33, 000, 000 to $13, 136, 000, 000.
In an effort to cope with its balance-of-payments
deficit, the United States has sought to slow it~ flow
of dollars into the world economy. The result has
been a reduction in Free World reserves, which are
composed predominently of U. S. dollars, as well as
g o I c a n d o t h e r convertible currencies. At the
PAGENO="0348"
3784
same time, the amount of gold i n national reserveâ
also has started to decline, largely because of pri-
vate hoarding in Europe.
Some economists argue that these reductions are
danger signals that could r e s ul t in a slow-down in
world trade. Thus they have argued that it's time to*
develop a contingency plan to add to world reserves.
Franceand some other nations, on the other hand
argued that the r e was no shortage of reserves and
that making it too easy for countries to continue hav-
ing payment deficits might encourage loose fiscal
practices and feed global inflation.
The debate continued for six years and was not
resolved until the Big 10 settled on the special draw-
ing rights formula.
Assuming approval by participating countries,
the IMF would ration SDRs to each member country
based roughly on economic size. In effect, each na-
tion would get a free bond.
Of a hypothetical $1 billion issue of SDRs the
United States would be entitled to $246, 000, 000.
The United States could spend them directly in pay-
ment fo r surplus dQllars held by another country if
that country would accept them. However, nothing
would prevent France, for example, from refusing
to ho no r the SDRs as redemption for U. 5. dollars;
it could still demand gold.
IfFrancedidn'taccept theSDRs the UnitedStates
could turn the SDRs back to the IMF whichwould be-
come a middleman and pick out another country with
a fast-growing supply of dollars. Such a country
would be obligated to take SDRs up to three times the
size of its own allocation of SDRs. In exchange the
United States would get a c u r r e n c y or currencies
acceptable to France. In this way the United States
PAGENO="0349"
3785
could redeem dollars without ha v i n g to give up its
gold.
If the 106 IMF nations approve the new money
the IMP' charter would have to be revis ed and ap-
proved through ratification by a `majority of the mem-
ber countries. It is doubted'this `can beàccomplished
before 1969.
Even though the new money is not as sured,
France has insisted on a weighted v o t e by the IMF
representatives that will require 85 percent appro-
val. The weighted vote g i v e s the Common Market,
countries a bloc vote that could veto any issuance of
the SDRs. Previously ~y the United States had e-
nough power in a single vote to block IMF action on
a large percentage vote, the United States being en-
titled to a weighted vote of 24. 59 percent.
And France, for one, ha's not indicated that its
convinced more reserves arenecessary. it has a-
greed only to the contingency plan.
In otherwords the IMF wouldbe unlikelyto pro-
pose the creation of new reserves unless the big
powers shared a unive~rsal feeling that there was a
need.
But for the U. S., Canada, Britain and :hose a-
mong the Continentals who agreed that the tin-ic has
come to provide a new reserve asset to rank along
with gold and dollars, the SDR agreement..appears
to be a great victory.
It seems to assure that those who speculated in
gold by hoarding or buying gold stock have met a
spectacular defeat. Thosewhohadhoped the existing
monetary system would fail, necessitating a big
hike in the price of gold, have ~-iade a bad' guess.
95-159 0 - 68 - pt. 8 - 23
PAGENO="0350"
3786
Mr. CHESTER. Mr. Victor Thomas, of the United Cement, Lime, &
Gypsum Workers.
STATEMENT `OP VICTOR TROMAS
Mr. THOMAS. Mr. Chairman and members of the committee, I am
Victor H. Thomas, fifth general vice president of the United Cement,
Lime, & Gypsum Workers, AFL-CIO.
I would like to thank the chairman and this coimuittee for giving
me the opportunity to express the views of my union on several pending
proposals relating to the International Antidumping Code, and the
Antidumping Act of 1921.
I have submitted a written statement with tables attached setting
forth these views in full. At this time I would like to present only a
brief summary of our position.
My union is concerned primarily with the particular unfair trade
practice which has been all too prevalent in the importation of
cement in the United States.
This is the unfair trade practice known as dumping, a practice under
which foreign manufacturers of cement dump their excess production
in the United States at prices greatly reduced below their own home
market prices.
Dumping is condemned by our domestic laws, most importantly by
the Antidumping Act of 1921. The effectiveness of this act, limited
as it is in protecting domestic industry and workers from the effects of
this unfair trade practice, would be seriously undermined by the
proposed International Antidumping Code negotiated during the
past year in Geneva, and by the regulations proposed by the Treasury
to implement this code.
There was no authority for the negotiation of this code in the 1962
Trade Expansion Act, and its promulgation as an executive agree-
ment would encroach and undermine the proper authority of the
Congress to determine our domestic laws by substantially amending
the provisions of the 1921 act.
Thus, I appear on behalf of my union to strongly urge this commit-
tee and the Congress to prevent the International Dumping Code from
becoming effective without congressional approval.
Specifically, we urge this committee to report favorably on House
Concurrent Resolution 447, and to support its passage by the Con-
gress prior to July 1, 1968, when the code is scheduled to become
effective.
The reason why the dumping of imports is of such concern to the
members of my union are fully set forth in my written statement, and
in the testimony of Mr. John Mundt on behalf of the cement industries
committee for tariff and antidumping, presented to this committee on
June 14, 1968.
During the last 10 years, workers in the domestic cement industries
have continually been seriously affected by the dumping of foreign
cement in the United States.
On two previous occasions, I have sought to bring this unfair and
illegal situation to the attention of those concerned here in the Con-
gress. The first time was during the August 1961, hearings before
the House Committee on Education and Labor, the General Suboom-
PAGENO="0351"
3787
mittee on Labor, on the impact of imports and, exports on ~rnemp1oy-
ment.
The second time was during the September and October 1966,
hearings of that same subcommittee on the effect of imports and
exports on American labor.
Such efforts were in support of legislation to strengthen the Anti-
dumping Act of 1921.
Representatives of the cement industries have also pursued the
currently available remedies in a series of proceedings under the art,
which have involved no less than 15 foreign countries over the `last
10 years.
It is most important that our ability to deal with these recurring
instances of. dumped imports, with substantial amounts of employ-
ment and unemployment caused thereby will not be undermined by
implementation of the International Antidumping Code.
`My union feels that the new code procedures for combating such
dumping would inevitably and substantially increase the exposure of
workers in general, and our members in particular, to `lost jobs in the
underemployment as a result of dumping.
This would be particularly true in the cement industry, which under
the new code provisions could hardly ever expect to qualify as a re-
gional industry, therefore exposing our members working along the
gulf coast, the east coast, and the Great Lakes to mect loss of jobs
without ever satisfying the new very difficult code standards for find-
ing injury to a domestic industry.
We also particularly object to the fact that the new proviskrns do
away with any effective interim relief while an investigation takes
place.
Our experience has been that such investigations take anywhere
from 6 to 18 months, a period of time during which domestic workers
can well be, and often have been, entirely thrown out of work.
Even though the eventual result of the legai jousting is to find that
injurious dumping has been taking place, once again, this is a highly
unfair, intolerable, vulnerable position into which to place American
workers.
The unrealistic standards and complex procedures of determining
injury under the International Anti-Dumping Code are unhappily
similar to the provisions for determining injury now contained in the
adjustment assistance section of the 1962 Trade Expansion Act.
As you know, no American worker has ever successfully petitioned
for relief under these provisions.
In his message of May 28, 1968, the President has recommended
that these sections be amended, `and that the relief be substantially
broadened, so that it would be available to all American workers
whenever imports are a substantial cause of injury.
It is difficult for `my union to understand why we should allow
standards for relief under the antidumping laws to become more lim-
ited and less available at the same time that we `are trying to liberalize
these adjustment assistance provisions.
Most important of all, such steps should never be taken without the
regular or due consideration of Congress.
Once again, we urgently request this committee to support House
Concurrent Resolution 447, and to oppose any weakening of our do-
mestic unfair trade practice laws.
PAGENO="0352"
3788
Thank you for your time and indulgence.
(Mr. Thomas' prepared statement follows:)
STATEMENT OF VICTOR H. THOMAS, GENERAL VICE PRESIDENT, UNITIm CEMENT,
LIME. AND GYPSUM WORKERS' INTERNATIONAL UNION, AFL-CIO
I am Victor H. Thomas, 5th General Vice President of the United Cement,
Lime & Gypsum Workers' International Union, AFL-CIO. I would like to thank
the Chairman and this Committee for giving me the opportunity to express the
views of my union on several pending proposals relating to the International
Antidumping Code and the Antidumping Act of 1921.
My union has long been concerned with the injury which American workers
have sustained as a result of the international unfair trade practice known as
"dumping", especially as it has affected those employed in the domestic cement
industry. On two previous occasions I have sought to bring this serious and
unfair situation to the attention of those concerned here in the Congress. The
first time was during the August, 1961 hearings before the House Committee
on Education and Labor, General Subcommittee on Labor, on the impact of
imports and exports on employment. The second time was during the Sep-
tember and October, 1966 hearings of that same Subcommittee on the impact
of imports and exports on American labor. On both of these occasions I filed
statements dealing at some length with recurring instances of dumped imports
of foreign cement and with the substantial amount of unemployment and under-
employment caused thereby to American workers and to members of my union.
I would like to incorporate by reference both my 1961 statement and my 1966
statement for consideration now by this Committee. I would also like to bring
this testimony up-to-date and to emphasize these problems again, as they con-
tinue unabated.
The dumping of cement into the domestic market is fully described and
thoroughly documented in the statement which was submitted to the Committee
in these hearings on June 14, 1968 by the Cement Industry Committee for Tariff
and Antidumping and in the statements previously presented by the Cement
Industry Committee and by its counsel, Covington & Burling, in the 1961 and
1966 hearings. My union feels that the extended and continual legal proceedings
in which the cement companies have engaged over the years in an attempt to
halt such dumping constitute a more than adequate effort by the industry to
keep it free of such unfair trade practices. If our domestic legislation were
adequate, these efforts would have been effective and the legitimate interests of
American workers in not losing jobs as the result of the unfair competitive
practices of foreign companies would have been protected. The record makes it
apparent, however, that such efforts were not effective, and both domestic in-
dustry and labor continue to suffer serious injury.
In order to bring borne the seriousness of the situation, I would like to refer
to a series of five tables presented in the 1966 hearings by Covington & Burling
as counsel to the Cement Industry Committee. For the convenience of the Com-
mittee I have attached to my testimony copies of these tables, revised to make
them current and to reflect the most recent import statistics of the Department
of Commerce, Bureau of International Commerce, U.S. Trade Section.
Table I is a list of the antidumping proceedings filed by the domestic industry
against imports from no less than 15 foreign countries during the years 1958-
1967. Table II records the `amount of foreign cement imported from these "dump-
ers" during the same period. Table III shows how much this unfair competition
has hurt our critical balance of payments position. These figures were computed
by adding to the F.O.B. value of the imports (as recorded by the Commerce De-
partment from U.S. Customs duty valuation certificates) an additional factor of
10% to cover freight and insurance, which is also uniformly purchased from
overseas firms. Addition of the 10% factor for these items is in accordance with
the report of the U.S. Tariff Commission, "C.I.F. Value of U.S. Imports", Feb-
ruary 7, 1967. Using the latest Bureau of Labor Statistics figures on productivity
in the domestic cement industry (5.l~7 barrels per man hour in 1966 and 6.27
barrels per man hour in 1967), Table IV translates these unfairly, lost sales into
man hours lost for domestic workers. Finally, using average domestic cement
industry wage rates ($3.97 per hour in 1966 and $4.27 per hour in 1967), Table V
shows the amounts of wages by which American labor has been unfairly de-
prived as a result of the dumped and tainted imports.
PAGENO="0353"
3789
I would like to call the Committee's attention particularly to the figures in
Tables IV and V. These tables show that American labor has lost well over 7
million man hours during the 1958-1967 period, an average of more than 700,000
man hours per year. Similarly, the equivalent wages lost have amounted to over
$24,000,000, an average of almost $2.5 million a year. Surely American labor
should not have tc sustain such drastic injury from an importing practice that-
has been condemned as an unfair method of competition not only by the United
States Congress but also by Article VI of GATT.
For these reasons my union strongly endorses and supports the position of the
Cement Industry Committee in these hearings that the relief from dumping prac-
tices now available under the Antiduinping Act of 1921, limited as it is, surely
should not be further restricted by implementation of the International Anti-
dumping Code and by the new implementing regulations issued by the Treasury
Department to become effective on July 1. My union feels that these new pro-
cedures for combating the dumping of foreign imports would inevitably and
substantially increase the exposure of American workers in general, and our
members in particular, to lost jobs and underemployment as a result of dumping.
This would be particularly true in the cement industry, which under the new
provisions could hardly ever expect to qualify as a regional industry, therefore
exposing our members working along the Gulf Ooast, the East Coast, and the
Great Lakes to complete less of jojs without ever satisfying the new, very difficult
Code standards for finding injury to a domestic industry. We also particularly
object to `the fact that the new provisions do away with `any effective interim
relief while an investigation of injury takes place. Our experience has been
that such investigations take anywhere from 6 to 18 months, a period of time
during which domestic workers can well `be, and often have been, entirely thrown
out of work, even though the eventual result of the legal jousting is to find that
injurious dumping has taken place. Once again, this is a highly unfair and in-
tolerably vulnerable position in which to place American workers.
The unrealistic standards and mixed procedures for determining injury under
the provisions of the International Antidumping Code are unhappily similar to the
provisions for determining injury now contained in the adjustment assistance
sections of the 1962 Trade Expansion Act. As you.know, no American workers have
TABLE I
Date of Treasury initial
Country of exportation formal finding of reason Nature of final determination by treasury department
complaint to believe or of Tariff Commission
suspect dumping
Belgium Oct. 2, 1959 Yes Treasury found dumping and Tariff found injury to
the domestic industry.
Canada May 28, 1959 Yes Treasury found dumping, but Tariff found no injury
to the domestic industry in part because continua.
tion of dumped sales seemed unlikely.
Colombia Sep. 25, 1959 No Treasury found no dumping.
Denmark Apr. 28, 1960 Yes Treasury found dumping but did not refer it to Tariff
partly because of cessation of shipments.
Dominican Republic Aug. 19, 1961 Yes Treasury found dumping, but Tariff found no injury
at the time to the domestic industry.
May 4, 1962 Yes Treasury found dumping and Tariff found injury to
the domestic industry.
Israel July 21,1959 Yes Treasury found no dumping partly because of a non-
cost-justified quantity discount allowance.
Italy June 7,1962 No Treasury found no dumping.
Japan Dec. 1, 1961 None Treasury found dumping but did not refer to Tariff
partly because of assurances by the producer that
dumping would not be resumed.
Feb. 5, 1963 Yes Treasury found dumping, but Tariff found no injury
to the domestic industry.
Aug. 26, 1965 No Treasury found no dumping.
Norway Sep. 15, 1958 Yes Treasury found no dumping solely because of a non-
cost-justified quantity discount allowance.
Dec. 27, 1961 Yes Do.
Poland Dec. 29,1960 Yes Treasury found no dumping, but used a 3d-country
- price and not Polish as home market price~
Portugal June 9, 1960 Yes Treasury found dumping and Tariff found injury to
the domestic industry.
Sweden Nov. 25, 1958 Yes Do.
Tunisia Sep. 13, 1960 No Treasury found dumping but did not refer it to Tariff
on assurances by the producers that dumping
would not be resumed.
West Germany Aug. 13, 1959 Yes Do.
Yugoslavia Aug. 28, 1961 Yes Do.
PAGENO="0354"
TABLE ll.-DUMPED OR "TAINTED" CEMENT IMPORTS, 1958-67 (BILLIONS OF BARRELS)'
West Dominican Japan
Year Canada Belgium Sweden Germany Colombia Norway Poland Israel Italy Yugoslavia Republic Tunisia (white Portugal Denmark Total
cement)
1958 657, 100 410, 800 339, 900 325, 100 473,900 335,600 68, 500 58,200 47, 500 7, 500 192, 800 2,916,900
1959 1,491,200 581,400 280,700 578,600 791,400 454,400 42,000 349,000 67,400 129,800 4,765,900
1960 868,700 326,200 289,600 51,400 537,000 310,200 243,700 58,800 111,100 85,400 290,800 3,172,900
1961 1 221, 800 89, 500 29, 000 17, 900 513, 300 721, 500 206,900 24,200 49, 100 439,600 58,900 3,371,700
1962 1,170,100 445,100 117,600 314,800 584,200 1,162,500 144,900 420,000 188,900 16,400 292,200 60,500 4,917,200
1963 1, 485,200 110, 800 254,000 28, 800 378, 500 919, 000 300, 000 20,600 29,600 52, 300 3, 578, 800
1964 1,399,300 41,400 51,200 17,400 540,000 949,700 23,100 54,900 3,077,100
1965 1,431,600 17,400 200 15,500 623,700 954,300 17,100 64,700 3,124,500
1966 2, 118,200 18,700 19,300 479, 400 1, 004,300 23,200 66, 500 43 3,729,643
1967 1,692,600 12,400 37,200 13,800 444,100 16,200 52,300 2,268,600
TotaL.... 13, 535, 800 2, 053, 700 1,399, 400 1,382,600 5,365, 500 6, 811, 500 706, 000 1, 127,200 213, 100 339,400 880,000 85, 400 410, 100 290, 800 322,643 34,923,243
1 Excludes clinker and white cement (except Japan).
TABLE 111.-DOLLAR OUTFLOW
West Dominican Japan
Year Canada Belgium Sweden Germany. Colombia Norway Poland Israel Italy Yugoslavia Republic Tunisia (white Portugal Denmark Total
cement)
1958 1 314,200 821,600 679,800 650,200 947,800 671,200 137,000 116,400 95,000 15,000 385,600 5,833,800
1959 2,982, 400 1, 162, 800 561, 400 1, 157, 200 1, 582, 800 908,800 84, 000 698, 000 134,800 259, 600 9, 531, 800
1960 1 737, 400 652, 400 579, 200 102, 800 1, 074, 000 620, 400 487,400 117, 600 222,200 1,218,614 414,844 6, 812, 014
1961 2, 443,600 179, 000 58, 000 35, 800 1, 026, 600 1,443, 000 413, 800 48, 400 98,200 879, 200 222, 455 6, 848, 055
1962 2,340,200 890,200 235,200 629,600 1, 168, 400 2,325, 000 289, 800 840, 000 377, 800 32,800 584, 400 207,705 10,335,989
1963 2,970,400 221, 600 508, 000 57, 600 757, 000 1,838, 000 600, 000 41,200 59, 200 175, 185 7 228, 185
1964 3 868 490 116 998 95 000 171.106 1,197,551 1 925 668 159 996 249 629 6,407 625
1965 3,810,544 46,251 3,948 139,489 1,327,246 2,140,715 99,417 393,872 6 488 689
1966 5,902,380 49,270 199,275 1, 052, 598 2, 178,829 177, 538 318, 586 3, 581 9 882, 057
1967 4,496, 148 32, 569 67,824 143,986 1, 031, 029 130,282 238, 836 12, 042, 522
TotaL... 31,865,762 4,172,688 278,372 3,287,056 11,165,024 14,052,612 1,412,000 2,254,400 426,200 1,086,833 1,760,000 1,218,614 1,716,268 414,844 648,781 81,410,736
PAGENO="0355"
TABLE IV.-MAN-HOURS LOST
Year Canada Belgium Sweden West Colombia Norway Poland Israel Italy Yugoslavia Dominican Tunisia Japan Portugal Denmark Total
Germany Republic
1958 169,356 105, 876 87,603 83,789 122, 139 86,495 17,655 15, 000 12,242 1,933 49,691 751,779
1959 344 388 134 273 64 827 133,626 182 771 104,942 9,700 80,601 15,566 29,977 1,100,671
1960 202 494 76,037 67 505 11 981 125 175 72,308 56,807 13,706 25,897 19,912 67,785 739,607
1961 290 214 21,259 6,888 4,252 121,924 171,378 49,145 5,748 11,663 104,418 13,991 800,880
1962 242 759 92,344 24,398 65,311 121,203 241,183 30,062 87,137 39,191 3,403 60,622 12,552 1,020,165
1963 290 078 21, 641 49, 609 5,625 73, 926 179,492 58, 594 4,023 5, 781 10,215 698, 984
1964 259,130 7,667 9,482 3,222 100,000 175,870 4,278 10,185 569,834
1965 251,158 3,053 35 2,719 109,421 167,421 3,000 11,351 548,158
1966 354,807 3, 132 3,233 80,302 168,224 3,886 11, 139 7 624, 730
1967 269,952 1,928 5,933 2,201 70,829 2,584 8,341 361,768
Total__ 2,879,293 467,210 316,280 315,859 1,107,710 1,367,313 163,369 241,332 44,939 74,351 198,651 19,912 77,774 67,785 79,675 7,148,811
TABLE V.-EQUIVALENT WAGES LOST
Year Canada Belgium Sweden West Colombia Norway Poland Israel Italy Yugoslavia Dominican Tunisia Japan Portugal Denmark Total
Germany Republic
1958 457,260 285, 866 236, 528 226,229 329, 775 233, 536 47,667 40, 500 33, 054 5,219 134, 165 2 029 791
1959 988,393 385,362 186,053 383,506 524,554 301,184 27,838 231,323 44,674 86,034 3 158 924
1960 619,632 232,674 206,567 36,663 383,034 221,261 173,827 41,941 79,246 609,307 207 422 2 811 579
1961 922,879 67,603 21,905 13,520 387,718 544,981 156,280 18,279 37,087 332,049 44,491 2 546 792
1962 803,533 305,659 80,758 216,180 401,182 798,314 99,505 288,423 129,721 11,262 200,660 41,541 3 376 738
1963 994,967 74, 227 170, 160 19,293 253, 565 615,658 200, 976 13, 800 19, 829 35, 037 2 397 512
1964 909,544 26,910 33,280 11,309 351,000 617,305 15,015 35 749 2 000 112
1965 929,284 11,294 129 10,061 404,857 619,457 11,100 41,999 2 028 181
1966 1,408,584 12,434 12,835 318,799 667,849 15,427 44,222 28 2 480 178
1967 1,152,695 8,233 25,334 9,398 302,440 11,034 35,616 1,544,750
TotaL... 9, 186,771 1,424, 157 960,714 938,994 3,656,924 4,619, 545 505, 117 761,222 148, 000 234,394 637, 003 609,307 278,655 207, 422 220,227 24, 167, 135
PAGENO="0356"
3792
ever suecessfully petitioned for relief under those provisions. In his message of
May 28, 1968, the President has recomineded that these sections ~e amended and
that relief be substantially broadened so that it would be available to American
workers whenever increased imports are a substantial cause of injury. It is
difficult for my union to understand why we should allow the standards for relief
under the antidumping laws to become more limited and less available at the same
time that we are trying to liberalize these adjustment assistance provisions.
For these reasons, on behalf of my union I strongly urge this Committee to
give immediate support to House Concurrent Resolution 447 and Senate Con-
current Resolution 38, which express the sense of Congress that the Code
should be submitted for legislative consideration prior to its becoming effective
in this Country. Surely the representatives of American workers should be
given the opportunity to express their views on such an important change in
our domestic fair trade laws, laws which so directly affect the welfare of these
workers, under the normal procedures of the legislative process. To allow the
new Oode provisions to take effect without careful deliberation under regular
legislative procedures would amount to an unfair and unlawful by-passing of
Congressional functions.
Mr. CHESTER. Mr. Hollan Cornett, of the United Stone & Allied
Products Workers.
STATEMENT OP HOLLAN CORNETT
Mr. CORNETr. Mr. Chairman and members of the committee, the
largest part of my job with this union consists of representing the
workers of the six operating companies with potash plants in the Carls-
bad, N. Mex., area.
I am here today to plead with you gentlemen to give these workers
some protection from the scourge of potash imports which is rapidly
changing them from workers making a decent living wage to recipients
of unemployment insurance and public welfare.
In the prepared written statement that I have submitted to you are
tables relating the facts on potash production and the increases of
imports into the United States, along with exhibits showing the actual
factors of what is `happening to the union members of our local unions,
as well as other unions made up of the workers of the domestic potash
industry, and what is happening to the economy of Carlsbad and the
State of New Mexico.
I am not going to belabor the facts and figures; they are all before
you, and I urge you to study them thoroughly.
What I really want to impress upon you is the human side of the
story, for I am convinced that we here in the United States have a
moral obligation to our own citizens that should take precedence over
the attitude and well-being of other countries.
This is not just a problem for Carlsbad, N. Mex., and members of our
union. Even though the majority of domestic potash production comes
from New Mexico, there are producers in California, Utah, `and Idatho.
They too, have suffered because of the increase in imports from Canada
and other countries.
The United States enjoys a generally high standard of living, with
high salaries and high taxes. These high taxes give all foreign potash
producers, especially Canada, `an artificial advantage over the domestic
producer.
Canada is by far the largest exporter of potash to the United States.
Mo~t of the U.S. producers of potash have established plants in Oanada,
and gain further advantage of a 5-year moratorium on taxes by estab-
lishing Canadian operations.
PAGENO="0357"
3793
This will change, once the domestic producers are eliminated.
As the tables will show you, a great deal of these imports come from
West Germany, France, and Spain. The operations in those countries
are controlled by a cartel, who have for years threatened the domestic
producers with price cuts.
They have, during the past couple of years, carried out this threat.
They have sold potash right here in the United States at a price much
lower than even they can produce the product.
I am sure the farmers are quite glad to be able to buy potash at
these temporarily reduced prices. The cartel and the foreign producers
will raise their prices after domestic production is eliminated, to a
point where they will be more than compensated for their temporary
losses.
The U.S. farmer will pay much more in the long run for this
fertilizer.
But what about the workers who are being forced out of work by
this cartel, and Canadian imports?
During the last 12 months, one Carlsbad producer has closed their
operation down completely, putting over 850 workers out of work.
IMCC has reduced their work force by over 50 percent, putting over
450 more workers out of work.
Duval Corp. closed down one mine and laid off 50 workers.
Potash Co. of America just laid off an additional 75 workers last
month.
All together, we have, during the last 12 months, had over 1,480
workers put out of work in the Carlsbad area, because of potash im-
ports.
Most of these now unemployed workers are over 50 years old, they
only know one trade, potash mining. It is very late in their life to re-
train them for other jobs. Even if it were possible to retrain them,
there are no jobs available for them in the Carlsbad area.
Gentlemen, in the western part of the United States, there are many
old mining industry ghost towns. Some are long forgotten, others are
used somewhat as a tourist attraction.
Oarlsbad, N. Mex., is rapidly becoming such a town. It will be a mod-
ern version of a ghost town, with real live ghosts being fed at the ex-
pense of the American taxpayer.
We will have a few tourists stopping in town to view the vacant
buildings and to talk to the citizens about the good old days when the
mines were operating, as they make their way to the Oarlsbad Caverns.
It does not have to be this way. Something can be done to protect
the life of the domestic potash industry, by putting a stop to the im-
ports of potash.
This is a vital, basic industry, one which the United States cannot
afford to lose, or to let foreign powers gain complete control of. This
is just what is going to happen, if we are not `successful in obtaining
reasonable quotas on the imports of potash.
You gentlemen are our only hope. You, the U.S. Congress, are the
only body that can give us the protection that we need.
I beg of you gentlemen not to put the high-sounding theory of free
world trade, or the friendship of foreign countries, above the welfare
of the U.S. citizens who work in our domestic potash industry.
I thank you.
PAGENO="0358"
3794
(Mr. Cornett's prepared statement follows:)
STATEMENT OF HOLLAN CORNIerr, ExEcuTivE Boaiw MEMBER, UNITED STONE AND
ALLIED PRODUCTS WORKERS OF AMERICA, AFL-CIO
The TJnited States potash industry has suffered disastrous setbacks in the last
several years. It faces virtual annihilation in the immediate future. The question
is not one of margin of profit as is faced in many other industries in the United
States but whether or not its very existence can be continued under the present
and foreseeable circumstances.
The following tables are attached as exhibits to this statement being the best
information available through the year 1906. The first table shows potash opera-
tions in Canada. Table 2 shows United States domestic consumption of potash.
Table 3 shows United States domestic production capacity. Table 4 shows
United States imports of potash from Canada and other countries. Table 5 shows
Canadian consumption of potash. Table 6 is world wide potash production
capability vs. consumption, estimated through the year 1971.
Present production of potash in the United States is roughly equal to the
consumption in the United States and the domestic potential is sufficient to pro-
vide for the estimated annual increased use of potash for many years to come.
Accurate figures are difficult to obtain covering United States consumption up to
date, however, it does appear apparent that potaSh will be in increased use in
the United States as well as in many foreign countries.
The cost of actual production in the United States is comparable to the cost
of production in other countries with the difference in competitive positions being
determined by cheaper labor and principally artificial tax advantages held by
foreign producers. There are no natural advantages held by foreign producers.
Potash shipped from West Germany, France and Spain is controlled by a cartel
who can fix prices regardless of costs and who have deliberately undercut, even
below their own costs, the price of potash being delivered to the United States
and for other economic reasons are able to sustain the loss suffered in potash
shipments. The Canadian producers were given approximately five years tax
moratorium as an inducement to expend huge sums of capital investment in
Canada. The Canadian mines are of much higher grade potash, however, being lo-
cated at a considerably greater depth than the potash in the Carlsbad area and
requiring several times the capital investment, do not have too great an advantage
excepting, as to taxes over the United States producers.
Canadian imports have risen from less than one percent domestic consumption
in 1960 and 1901 to over thirty two per cent of domestic consumption in 1966.
Total foreign imports have risen from nine percent of domestic consumption in
1960 to over thirty eight per cent in 1966. Nineteen sixty seven and 1968 figures
are not available, however the trend is certainly established and is continuing.
The loss of this industry in the Carlsbad area only, to the United States in em-
plOyment is shown by exhibits attached from several of the local unions and
the local employment service. The human cost is unmeasureable because many
of the men now in their fifties who have spent 25 years in this particular industry
have no place to go with their training. The city of Carlsbad has dropped in
population as shown by attached water and electric meter readings and mail
count. The depression created is further evidenced from the Credit Bureau's
reports on comparable periods of foreclosures filed.
The potash industry in the year 1966 paid total taxes in excess of $10,000,0(X).00.
It is respectfully submitted unless action is taken by this committee restrict-
ing foreign imports, especially Canadian, the industry in the United States will
disappear with terrific hardship on those immediately involved and the entire
country will suffer ultimately with control of this vital basic product being
delivered into the hands of foreign producers.
PAGENO="0359"
379.5
TABLE 1.-BOX SCORE OF POTASH
OPERATIONS IN
CANADA I
Output
(tons per
Capital
cost
Production start
Shafts
year)
Operating:
International M. & C., K-i 2, 000, 000 $65, 000, 000 September 1962
Kalium Chemicals 600, 000 50, 000, 000 September 1964 None
Potash Co. of America.. 600, 000 45, 000, 000 April 1965
Total, operating 3,200,000 160, 000 000
Under construction:
Allan Potash 1,500,000 70 000,000 Summer 1967 2
Aiwinsal Potash 1,000,000 50, 000, 000 Early 1968
Cominco Potash 1, 200,000 65, 000, 000 Late 1969 2
Duval Corp 1,000,000 63,000,000 Early 1969 .2
International M. & C., K-2 1, 500, 000 60,000,000 Early 1967
Noranda Potash 1,200,000 73,000 000 Early1969 2
Southwest Potash 1, 500,000 60, 000, 000 Early 1970 2
Total, under construction 8,900,000 441, 000, 000
Total 12, 100,000 601, 000, 000
1 The Northern Miner, July 14, 1966.
Note: Potash Co. of America is planning a second shaft on which work is to commence early next year. International
Minerals & Chemical Corp.'s K-i and K-2 shafts connect underground. Alwinsal Potash expects to start sinking a second
shaft shortly after production attained.
TABLE 2
-U.S. DOM
ESTIC CON
SUMPTION OF POTASH
Year
.
.
.
Product
(tons (KC1) 1)
K2O (tons) 2
Change over prior
year (percent)
1960 2,119,397 (3)
1961 3,911,896 2,054,097 -3.1
1962 4,248,931 2,342,876 +14.1
1963 4,293,141 2,645,040 +12.9
1964 4,820,741 2,935,989 +11.0
1965 4,692, 760 3, 141, 856 +7. 0
1966 4,931,686 3,810,531 +21.3
Total 26,898,155 19,049,786
1 Measured in terms of the mineral known as potassium chloride KC1. Source for figures is the Atchison, Topeka &
Santa Fe RR.
2 Measured in terms of the oxide content (l(~O). Pure sylvite, or pure muriate of potash, contains 63.2 percent of K2O.
Mining companies strive for a product containing a minimum of 95 percent sylvite(KC1) which then contains over60 percent
K2O equivalent, the usual minimum standard. Source for figures is the American Potash Institute.
Note: Average increase per year over base year of 1960 averages 13 percent per year.
S . TABLE 3.-U.S. domestic production capacity of potash1
Year: . KnO'ton~
1960-64 2, 800, 0(u)
1965 2,875, 000
1966 3,400, 000
`USDA publication "The Fertilizer Situation, 1963-64, 1964-65, 1965-66" (production
capacity for 1960 through 1963 assumed to have been the same as 1964). The published
flgure.s have been reduced by 200,000 K20 tons to reflect the net production capacity of KnO
as potassium chloride.
PAGENO="0360"
3796
TABLE 4.-U.S. IMPORTS OF POTASH 1
CANADA
Year
KCL (tons) 2
I(~O (tons) 3
Percent of
domestic
consumption
1960
1961
1962
6,717
3
76,395
563,344
837,357
1,485,148
2,015,838
4,030
2
45,819
338,006
502,414
891,089
1,209,503
(4)
(4)
2
13
17
28
32
1963
1964
1965
1966
OTHER IMPORTS
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
321,992
331,901
386,734
313,192
358,360
295,133
366,383
193, 195
199,141
232,040
187,915
215,016
177,080
219,830
9
10
10
7
7
6
6
TOTAL IMPORTS
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
328,709
331,904
463,129
876,536
1,195,717
1,780,281
2,382,221
197,225
199,143
277,859
525,921
717,430
1,068,169
1,429,333
9
10
11
20
24
34
38
Total
7,358,497
4,415,080
123
1 American Potash Institute.
2 Measured in terms of the mineral known as potassium chloride (KC1).
3 Measured in terms of the oxide content (K2O). Pure sylvite, or pure muriate of potash, contains 63.2 percent of K2O.
Mining companies strive for a product containing a minimum of 95 percent sylvite (KC1) which then contains over 60
percent K20 equivalent, the usual minimum standard.
4 Less than 1 percent.
5 Over the 7 years from 1960 to 1966, the total imports of K2O into the United States averaged approximately 23 percent
of our domestic consumption for those 7 years.
Year: KuO 2 tona
1960 100, 880
1961 105,951
1962 105,282
1963 121,909
1964 154, 663
1965 185, 021
1966 197, 162
1 Potash Institute.
2 Measured in terms of the oxide content (K20). Pure sylvite, or pure muriate of potash,
contaIns 63.2 percent of K20. Mining companies strive for a product containing a minimum
of 95 percent sylvite (KC1) which then contains over 60 percent KxO equivalent, the usual
minimum standard.
TABLE 5.-Canadian consumption of potash1
PAGENO="0361"
1960
1961
1962
1963_
1964_
1965_
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1 Chemical Week, July 2, 1966. Measured in terms of the mineral known as potassium chloride (KC1). Pure sylvite, or
pure muriate of potash, contains 63.2 percent of K20 the oxide content Mining companies strive for a product containing
a minimum of 95 percent sylvite (KC1) which then contains over 60 percent (K2) equivalent, the usual minimum standard.
2 Not available.
TOTAL NUMBER OF MEN REPRESENTED BY USAPWA, AFL-CIO AT THE FOLLOWING MINES IN THE CARLSBAD POT-
ASH BASIN FROM JANUARY 1965 TO JUNE 1968, MEMBERS AND NONMEMBERS INCLUDED
January 1965
Local
Plant Members
Nonmembers Total
177
PCA and NPC
473
8
179
U.S. Borax
271
10
181
SWP
359
0
183
Duval
249
8
188
IMCC
86
636
Total
1,438
662 2,098
June 1965
177
PCAandNPC
487
8
179
U.S. Borax
270
10
181
SWP
351
0
183
Duval
273
8
188
IMCC
Total
135
577
1,516
602 2,118
January 1966
177
PCAandNPC
498
8
179
U.S. Borax
270
10
181
SWP
348
0
183
Duval
278
8
188
IMCC
175
437
Total
1,569
463 2,032
June 1966
177
PCAandNPC
497
8
179
181
U.S. Borax
SWP
278
345
10
0
183
Duval
270
6
188
IMCC
166
436
Total
1,556
450 2,006
3797
TABLE 6.-WORLDWIDE POTASH PRODUCTION CAPABILITY VERSUS CONSUMPTION
World production
capability
Year (including
Carlsbad
production) 1
World
consumption 1
Excess capability
over consump-
tion 1
Carlsbad produc-
tion capability
(estimated)
8,500, 000 8, 500, 000 None 4, 200, 000
9,500, 000 9, 500, 000 None 4,200, 000
10, 000, 01)0 10, 000, 000 None 4, 200, 000
10,500,000 10,500,000 None 4,200,000
12,000, 000 12, 000, 000 None 4,200, 000
13,000,000 13,000,000 None 4,500,000
15, 000, 000 14, 000, 000 1, 000, 000 5, 100, 000
16, 000, 000 15, 000,000 1,000, 000 (2)
17,000,000 15,000,000 1,800,000 (2)
18, 800, 000 16, 000, 000 2, 500, 000 (2)
20, 500, 000 17, 000, 000 3, 500, 000 (2)
25,000, 000 18, 500, 000 6, 500, 000 6, 500, 000
PAGENO="0362"
3798
TOTAL NUMBER OF MEN REPRESENTED BY USAPWA, AFL-CIO AT THE FOLLOWING MINES IN THE CARLSBAD POT-
ASH BASIN FROM JANUARY 1965 TO JUNE 1968, MEMBERS AND NONMEMBERS INCLUDED-Continued
January 1967
Local
Plant
Members
Nonmembers Total
177
179
181
183
188
PCA and NPC
U.S. Borax
SWP
Duval
IMCC
500
278
352
280
161
8
10
20
6
427
Total
1,571
451 2,022
June1967
177
179
181
183
188
PCA and NPC
U.S. Borax
SWP
Duval
IMCC
501
281
348
282
163
8
10
0
6
459
Total
1, 575
483 2, 058
January 1968
177
178
179
181
183
188
PCA
NPC
U.S. Borax -
SWP
Duval
IMCC
308
185
7
370
243
81
8
0
0
0
6
325
Total
1,194
339 1,533
June 1968
177
178
179
181
183
188
PCA
NPC
U.S. Borax
SWP
Duval
IMCC
252
189
6
336
244
60
8
0
0
0
6
315
Total
1,087
329 1,416
JUNE 18, 1968.
Mr. HOLLAN CORNETT,
International Representative, United Fitone and Allied Products Workers of
America, Carlsbad, N. Me~v.
DEAR HOLLAN: In response to your request of how my membership at the local
potash mines has fluctuated, is as follows:
January 1967:
U.S. Borax 140
PCA 54
Duval
Total 228
June 1967:
U.S. Borax 140
POA 54
Duval ____ 34
Total 228
January 1968:
U.S. Borax 2
POA 54
Duval 30
Total 86
PAGENO="0363"
3799
June 1968:
U.S.. Borax - 2
PCA 54
Duval 24
Total 80
in 1967 we had 228 members working in the potash mines. Today we have 80
members working in the mines.
if I can be of any other help, please call on me.
Sincerely,
W. R. E&ns,
Business Manager, Local No. 703, I.B. of E.W.
CAVERN CITY LocAL 1124,
INTERNATIONAL ASSOCIATION OF MACHINISTS AND AEROSPACE WORKERS,
Carlsbad, N. Mew.
HOLLAN C0RNETT:
DEAR SIR: Active membership from 1965, 300 members; 1966, 295 members;
1967, 291 members; 1968, 13 members.
These members were working till Nov. 10 1967 when Company shut down
operations at refinery, The U.S. Borax & Chemical Co. Potash Division.
REX KEEN,
Financial f~ecretary.
JUNE 19, 1968.
#1912 I.A.M.
1965, 110 Members
1966, 108 Members
1967, 105 Members
1968, 1 Member
To whom it may concern:
Listed above is the active membership of International Association of Machin-
ists & Aerospace Workers Permian Basin Lodge #1912, located at Carlsbad,
New Mexico, on the given dates,
The above information is true to the best of my knowledge and belief.
H. A. GREEN, President.
EMPLOYMENT SECURITY COMMISSION,
NEW MEXICO EMPLOYMENT SREvICE,
Carlsbad, N. Mew.
To Whom It May Concern:
Due to the installation of highly mechanized and larger equipment in an et!ort
to become more competitive in the potash market, there were reductions in labor
forces for several years by the potash industries in the Carlsbad, New Mexico,
area. More recently, the potash companies have stated that they have been
having difficulty in competing with the foreign markets which resulted in the
closing of one of the major firms.
The area eventually became one of substantial unemployment and on September
21, 1967, it was classified as a "Redevelopment Area" under Section 401(a) (4) of
the Public Works and Economic Development Act of 1965. Criteria for a desig-
nated area is clearly specified in this Act. Statements used in determining the
designation of Carlsbad as a Redevelopment Area should be on file with the
Federal Government prior to the date of designation. Such documents describe
the conditions in this area at that time, which was prior to the closing of one
of the major potash industries in November of 1967.
HAROLD R. CONWAY,
Manager, Carlsbad Local Office.
PAGENO="0364"
3800
CITY OF CARLSBAD,
POTASH CAPITAL OF THE WORLD,
Carlsbad, N. Mex., June 18, 1968.
To Whom It May Concern:
Below is listed the number of water meters in service in the City of Carlsbad
by six months intervals since January 1, 1965. The information is directly re-
lated to the economic situation in Carlsbad that has resulted in a large number
of people leaving the area because of unemployment.
Numberof
Date operating
meters
Numberof
Date operating
meters
Jan. 1, 1965 7,451
Jan. 1, 1966 7,419
Jan. 1, 1967 7,321
Jan. 1, 1968 6,996
July 1, 1965 7,470
July 1, 1966 7,453
July 1, 1967 7,295
June 1, 1968 6,943
CHARLES R. GRIGO,
Wa4er and Sewer Superintendent.
SOUTHWESTERN PUBLIC SERVICE (Jo.,
Carlsbad, N. Mecv., June 19, 1968.
To Whom It May Concern:
A check of our records indicates the following meter count taken at six month
intervals for Carlsbad, New Mexico, beginning with January, 1960.
January 1966 10,633
June 1966 10,762
January 1967 10,531
June 1967 10, 639
January 1968 10,267
June 1968 10,066
W. K. ROTAN.
QREDIT BUREAU OF CARLSBAD,
Carlsbad, N. Mea'., June 18, 1968.
To Whom It May Concern:
Upon request, I have examined our records and find that the following number
of Mortgage Foreclosure Suits have been filed in Eddy County during the first
five months of each of the past three years, as listed below.
1966 27
1967 30
1908 70
W. R. MIDDLETON, Owner.
POTASH TAXES PAm ro STATE OF NEW MEXICO IN 1966
Local and State taxes and royalties borne by the potash industry total
more than 10 million dollars annually. For the calendar year 1966. the potash in-
dustry paid the following amounts:
Gross receipts tax (on sales) $802, 905
Sales Tax (on purchases) 758, 306
Oompensating tax (on purchases) 143,862
Ad Valorem tax 2,079, 476
Royalties 5,066, 891
Mineral lease 500, 821
Occupation tax ~` ~
State income tax 212,741
Severance tax 497,498
Total 10,088, 342
PAGENO="0365"
3801
Mr. CHESTER. Mr. George Barbaree, assisted by Mr. Lord.
STATEMENTS OP GEORGE R. BARBAREE AI~fl) ROBERT LORD
Mr. BARBAREE. Mr. Chairman and members of the committee, my
name is George R. Barbaree. I am international secretary-treasurer
of the International Brotherhood of Operative Potters, AFL-CIO.
On behalf of our union and its membership, I thank you for giving
of your time to listen to our views regarding the serious impact that
the present import policy has, and is having, on the pottery industry,
and more specifically the earthenware dinnerware potteries, where our
members are employed.
We have prepared some charts to emphasize to you the reduction
in shipments from the U.S. Pottery Association, and the cor-
responding unemployment that was a result of the reduction in man-
hours worked due to the continued increase in foreign imports dur-
ing the years from 1947 to 1967.
The black line on the chart shows that 27,293,281 dozen of earthen-
ware was shipped in 1947, and that with the exception of the years
1958 through 1962, there has been a steady decline, with only 7,737,549
dozen being shipped in 1967, or a reduction in dozens shipped of over
70 percent.
The blue line, representing man-hours worked during the same
period, reflects an almost parallel decline, dropping from 25,681,758
hours worked in 1947, to 5,297,424 hours worked in 1967, or a loss
of over 75 percent.
The red line depicts the continued rise in imports during this same
period, from approximately 2 million dozen in 1947 to approximately
25 million in 1967.
As a result of this invasion of the domestic market by unfair foreign
dinnerware imports, the next chart shows that our members employed
in the industry declined from approximately 12,000 in 1947 to 3,599
in 1967. or a loss in job opportunity of 70 percent.
From 1953 to 1967, 18 dinnerware potteries affiliated with the U.S.
Potters Association in various States have been forced out of business
because of being unable to compete with these foreign imports pro-
duced with low-wage rates.
Other plants under contract with our union, and not members of the
USPA, also have gone out of business.
The financial plight of our inudstry can in no way be attributed to
unreasonable wage or fringe demands by the union.
As a matter of fact, the union has had to recognize the import prob-
lem, and temper its demands accordingly.
The average hourly earnings in union potteries are approximately
60 cents per hour below the national averages for all manufacturers.
If our union members had not restrained their demands, there would
be no pottery manufacturers remaining today.
Not only has cheap foreign imports caused numerous losses of jobs
to American potters, but they are causing the standard of living of
the remaining pottery workers to be lowered substantially.
In view of the above facts, it therefore becomes imperative for Con-
gress to pass legislation to restrict this unfair foreign competition,
so that a vital domestic industry, providing jobs for American workers,
95-i59 0-68-pt. 8-24
PAGENO="0366"
3802
will not be completely destroyed by products made with unreasonably
low wages in foreign countries.
We therefore respectfully request that you support H.R. 16936,
entitled t.he Fair International Trade Act, introduced by Congress-
man Sydney Herlong of Florida.
Mr. FULTON (presiding). Thank you, sir.
Mr. CHESTER. That finishes our testimony, Mr. Chairman.
If there are any questions, we will stand ready to answer them.
Mr. BYRNES. Some of the witnesses emphasized adjustment assist-
ance. It is my impression that most of your workers are rather highly
skilled. Am I wrong in that, or not?
Mr. CHESTER. In some cases, Mr. Byrnes. In the flat glass industry,
it is probably the highest paid of all of our affiliates.
Mr. BYRNES. I am talking principally of the training that is re-
quired, and the fundamental skills that the normal worker has to
attain.
Mr. CHESTER. I think they could probably address themselves to
that question.
On flat glass, they have skills, and P. and M., production and main-
tenance workers.
Mr. REISER. In flat glass, most of that is mechanized equipment,
and during the war they stepped right into the ammunitions.
Mr. BYRNES. Then adjustment assistance can be of some help.
It seems to me that where you have higher skills-which I assume
you have in the pottery, chinaware production-trying to acquire
another skill through new training is not a very satisfactory solution to
the problem.
Mr. BARBAREE. And also the average age in the potteries is very
high. Because of the decline in job opportunities, we have not been
attracting young people.
Mr. BYRNES. That is true in flat glass?
Mr. REISER. Well, yes. It takes nearly 12 to 15 years to even hold
on to a labor job, because if it wasn't for our early retirement systems,
at age 62, we would be in real trouble.
Now, about the training, most of our plants are in small towns, and
the people at that age are hesitant to leave, if they do get the chance.
Mr. BYRNES. You have to move someplace else.
One of my colleagues made the remark that someone said that you
people want a break. We thought that that was a bad word to use if
you were in the glass business, so maybe we could find a little different
phrase.
Mr. RETSER. It is an ill wind that doesn't blow somebody some good.
When they break them, we make them.
Mr. BYRNES. Thank you very much.
Mr. FULTON. Congressman Burke?
Mr. BURKE. Do any of you gentlemen represent the workers em-
ployed in the stonecutting industry, the granite industry?
Mr. CHESTER. The Stone and Allied Products Workers represent
them.
Mr. CORNETT. I do.
Mr. BURKE. I know in Quincy, Mass., where they have the Quincy
granite, they find it very difficult to get new workers into this trade.
PAGENO="0367"
3803
Most of the oldtimers are immigrants from Italy, doing the polish
work and the sculpture work.
Mr. CORNErr. I think that is true all over the New England States,
in the granite and marble industry.
I am primarily concerned with the union in the western part of the
United States, in the potash, and don't know much about the New
England stone part.
I do know they are having problems getting people to go in and take
the training and learn the jobs. They are not interested in being quarry
men and stone polishers, as their forefathers were. In that part of the
industry, there again, in age bracket, the people are quite old, most
of them.
Mr. B1JRKE. I was wondering what the industry was doing about
developing workers to take the place of these older men.
Mr. CORNETT. They are setting up training programs under the
various Government programs that they get assistance through to
train people in that area.
Mr. Bu1iKE. I understand that in some of these buildings erected in
Washington in recent years, they had to import stonecutters and
stone masons to do some of the work.
Mr. FULTON. We certainly thank each of you gentlemen.
Our next witness is Mr. Golden.
Gentlemen, we welcome you to appear before the committee, and
will you identify yourselves for the record.
STATEMENT OP DAVID A. (+OLDEN, CUSTOMS AI~]) TARIFF COUN-
SEL, UIIITED STATES POTTERS ASSOCIATION; ACCOMPANIED BY
J~0SEPR M. WELLS, flt., AN]) J~OHN T. HALL
Mr. GOLDEN. Mr. Chairman and members of the committee, my name
is David A. Golden, and I am. the customs and tariff counsel for the
U.S. Potters Association.
At the outset, I would like to say that we wholly subscribe to and
endorse the remarks just made by Mr. Barbaree, who is the secretary-
treasurer of the International Brotherhood of Operative Potters, and
I may also state that it is refreshing, at least in this industry, to see
labor joining with management in seeking some sort of relief for this
industry.
Also, I would like to state that all the remarks made by me are
limited to earthenware dinnerware, which is manufactured by the
Potters Association members.
Now, on my left is Mr. Joseph M. Wells, Jr., vice president of the
Homer Laughlin China Co., of Newell, W. Va., and on my right is
Mr. John T. Hall, president of the Hall China Co., of East Liverpool,
Ohio.
I am not going to read my statement, Mr. Chairman and gentlemen.
However, I do request that it be printed in the record along with the
statement that we are making now.
Mr. FULTON. Without objection, it will be done.
Mr. GOLDEN. The first thing that I would like to talk about is the
tariff adjustment assistance program.
PAGENO="0368"
3804
Under the Trade Expansion Act of 1962, as you gentlemen well
know, the criteria for relief were changed by Congress from that
under the old Trade Expansion Act of 1951.
I was the first one who fell under the ax of the investigation `by the
Tariff Commission under the new criteria, as expounded in the 1962
act.
As a matter of fact, the Potters Association filed a petition for
relief in 1962, in August, and before the case was decided, the new
act went into effect, and we were caught under the new criteria.
Obviously, as you well know, we did not get the relief, and at the
time we felt pretty badly about it, although the Tariff Commission
found that we were injured, and imports were coming in, and we were
being injured by them, but since the other 20 applications that have
been filed subsequent to ours received the same treatment, we are in
pretty good company.
Now, it is the administration's proposal under the new act, the
Trade Expansion Act of 1968, to change the criteria as affecting mdi-
vidual firms and workers. It does not intend to change the criteria
affecting industries, and, gentlemen, I submit that to do that would
be a mere nullity.
What good would it do if you are going to give a worker increased
benefits, or retrain him, or relocate him, or give an individual firm
long-term loans at low interest, or reductions in taxes, or whatever
the case may be, if the industry goes out of business?
Now, you just asked the gentlemen that preceded me about the skill
of the workers, and the training of the workers, and so on. Fine. You
are going to give them the assistance, which is economic, but you are
not going to save the industry, and again, as the President in his
recommendations urged the Congress to do certain things, I strongly
urge that if you change the criteria under the trade adjustment
assistance program, to affect or to help individual firms and workers,
you do the same for the industry.
I may also pose this: It is possible, if you do not change the criteria
affecting industries, that an individual firm, an industry and workers
may come in and file petitions affecting the same industry.
Using the same evidence, the same facts, you will give relief to the.
firm and to the workers, and the industry will get no relief on the
same basis, facts, law, or whatever may be involved.
If you change it, whereby all of them will come under the same
criteria, and again I submit all I mean is the industry, the firm, and
the worker, then they will qualify under the criteria announced by
Congress, and relief will be given, if it so meets the criteria.
Again, I strongly urge that, if you change the criteria, you include
also the industry.
Another thing-and this I am firmly opposed to-is granting to
the President further authority to reduce duties on imports. And
I believe there the administration has put itself in an untenable po-
sition.
The administration wants the authority to further reduce duties,
or to use that unused portion under the Kennedy round, for the next 2
years, until 19W.
This industry is very, very vulnerable by that. By that I mean we
have received reduction under the Kennedy round, except in one in-
PAGENO="0369"
3805
stance, where the negotiators culled out a new category, which ap-
pears in the tariff schedules of the United States as though no re-
duction had been given to this particular cull-out of the odd sections
of the tariff schedules, so that at the present time they would be sus-
ceptible to a full 50 percent cut.
And for that category, we believe it is the category containing the
largest amount of imports, and where the industry is hurt to the
greatest extent.
Now, the untenable position of the administration is this: The Ad-
ministration says that-
We want that authority because-
And let me quote from page 2 of this committee's proposed Trade
Expansion Act of 1968:
For example, the United States may find it necessary to increase the duty
on a particular article as the result of an escape clause action or a statutory
change in tariff classification.
On the next page they say:
The escape clause action hasn't worked. We are going to change it.
Now, if it hasn't worked, why does the President need authority
to increase rates of duty because of the compensatory raites that we
may have to give another country under the escape clause actions?
They can't be on both sides. They cannot say the same thing.
Then he says "a statutory change in tariff classification."
If there is a statutory change in tariff classification, that means
Congress passes a statute.
If Congress sees fit in a particular statute to increase the rate of
duty on a particular item, in the same statute, they can decrease the
rate of duty on a particular item, why does the President at this time
need further authority to continue the unused portions of the Ken-
nedy round authority that was given to him in 1962?
Again, I repeat this industry is very, very vulnerable to anything
along those lines.
Furthermore, I am naive enough, and I believe that the reductions
made under the Kennedy round were based on the economics of this
country.
When Ambassador Roth's office and other negotiators to GATT sat
down and polled all the information, they came to the conclusion that
the maximum cut we can give on that article, this article, so on down
the line, were those reductions which the industry could stand.
I believe that. If that is the case, then why does the President want
at this time, or need at this time, authority to further reduce the rate
of duty?
I say that there should be anywhere from 3 to 5 years waiting period
to see the effect of the Kennedy round reductions before we go into
anything else.
Another area I would like to explore is the omnibus bill, or across-
the-board quotas.
Now, this committee -is very well aware, much more than I am, of
the number of quota bills that are thrown into the hopper. Some
come out, and some do not.
If there was an omnibus bill in which Congress had set out a stated
policy and criteria, any industry which met that criteria and is in-
PAGENO="0370"
3806
jured and makes the overt step of seeking relief should get relief
without coming in and filing t~ quota bill and having to appear before
the Ways and Means Committee and the Senate Finance Commit-
tee, and all the other governmental agencies before he is granted the
relief.
Again, whatever the announced criteria is, which Congress may im-
pose, if it is a fair one, and a workable one, I don't think anyone is
disadvantaged. No one is hurt.
Quotas in that sense is not a dirty word. The Congress can state
what kind of quotas they shall be, whether absolute, and I do not
favor absolute quotas, but it can be a limited quota whereby so much
can come in at a reduced rate, and not a complete cutoff, but so many
more hundreds or thousands or millions of dollars or commodities at
an increased rate of duty.
I think that is fair, workable, simple, and helps both industry,
knowing they can do it. and helps Congress, `by saying, "You qualify
under the quota," or, "You don't."
There is your relief, rather than the individual quota bills on which
the administration has come down here time after time and said,
"Don't do it. They are going to retaliate. Every time that anything
happens along those lines, there is going to be retaliation."
Maybe there will, and maybe there won't. I don't know, but that
gets to be worn a little thin, also.
Any questions that the committee may have along the lines of
the skill or the workers or the numbers or the amounts involved, Mr.
Wells and Mr. Hall will be more than happy to answer anything that
the committee may have.
Gentlemen, I want to thank you for the opportunity to appear
before you, and to state our position.
(Mr. Golden's prepared statement follows:)
Re: Trade Expansion Act of 1968, H.R. 17551
STATEMENT OF DAvm A. GOLDEN, CUSTOMS AND TARIFF COUNSEL, UNITED STATES
PorrEns ASS0cIArE0N
My name is David A. Golden `and I am an attorney associated with the firm of
Lamb & Lerch, located at 25 Broadway, New York, New York, 10004. I am Tariff
and Customs Counsel to the United States Potters Association, located in East
Liverpool, Ohio.
The United States Potters Association is one of the older trade associations
in the United States having its beginning in 1875. At the present time the Asso-
ciation having its beginning on 1875. At the present time the Association is com-
prised of six active members and approximately 25 associate members. All of
the active members are producers of earthenware dinnerware. These six plants
represent about 70% of the dollars and approximately 60% of the dozen of the
domestic production in this field. The six active members are: Canonsburg
Pottery Co., Canonsburg, Pa., 15317; The Hall China Co., East Liverpool, Ohio
43920; The Harker China Co., East Liverpool, Ohio, 43920; The Homer Laughlin
China Co., Newell, W. Va., 26050; Royal China, Inc., Sebring, Ohio, 44672; The
Taylor, Smith & Taylor Co., East Liverpool, Ohio, 43920.
TO LTBERALIZE ADJUSTMENT ASSISTANCE CRITERIA FOR FIRMS AND WORKERS WITHOUT
LIBERALIZING THE ESCAPE CLAUSE PROCEDURES FOR DOMESTIC INDUSTRIES WOULD BE
LESS THAN A NULLITY
A. History Of The Eseape Clat~se
From the beginning of the Trade Agreements Program there has been concern
that as a result ocf a decreuse in import restrictions there would be sudi an in-
crease in imports as to seriously injure or to threaten serious injury to domestic
PAGENO="0371"
3807
manufacturers. When the President was given authority in 1934 to reduce import
restrictions he committed himself to use the authority in such manner as not to
injure sound and important American industries. However, in administering
the Trade Agreements Act it soon became apparent that some domestic industries
would be seriously injured. An "escape clause" was, therefore, included in trade
agreements which periniitted the United States to withdraw a concession under
certain conditions.
The Trade Agreements Extension Act of 1951 for the first time had an "escape
clause" procedure provided for by statute (Sec. 7). This provision in substance
held that the Tariff Commission should investigate all escape clause applications;
impose a time limit for the investigation; and allowed an actual as well as a
relative increase in imports to satisfy the procedural critieria. The Tariff Com-
mission pursuant to the investigation then had to determine if as a result in
whole or in part of concessions granted, imports of the article under investiga-
tion were being imported into the United States in such increased quantities,
either actual or relative, as to cause, or threaten, serious injury to the domestic
industry producing like or directly competitive products. Section 7 of the Trade
Extension Act of 1951 was re-enacted in 1955 and 1958. It lasted until 19(32.
B. Application Of The Escape Clause
Under Section 7 of the Trade Extension Act of 1951 (and its re-enactment)
113 investigations were completed by the Tariff Oomimission. Of that number of
investigations the Tariff Commission found that in 33 investigations the criteria
for injury was met by the domestic industry and reconunended to the President
that relief be granted; in 8 investigations the Tariff Commissioners were divided
as to their findings and therefore, the cases had to be referred to the President
for disposition; and 72 cases were dismissed by the Tariff Commission on the
grounds that the domestic industries did not meet the criteria set up by Con-
gress for relief.
Of the 41 investigations referred to the President, 15 were granted relief pur-
suant to the statute and 2(3 were denied relief.
C. Changes Made in The Present Act (Trade Ea~pa~sion Act of 1~962). From
Section 7 Of The Trade Agreement Eo,tension Act of 11)51
In the Trade Expansion Act of 1962 Congress enacted a sweeping reorganiza-
tion of safeguard procedure which among other things made a form of relief
available to groups not covered by earlier acts, such as individual firms and
employees of injured industries. Under the 1962 Act the President could provide
relief in cases of injury to an industry, firm or workers by withdrawing, or
modifying the concession or he may grant trade adjustment assistance such as
loans, tax relief and technical assistance. During the debates in Congress on
the 1962 legislation it was held out to `labor as an inducement for the passage
of the Act that individual groups of workers, not provided for under previous
legislation could obtain trade adjustment assistance.
However, in addition to the attempted beneficial changes made by the 1962
Act, the criteria for "injury" was changed which change made it impossible
for domestic industries, firms or individuals to get any trade adjustment
assistance.
Before the Commission can make an affirmative finding under section 3(~1
(b) (1) of the Trade Expansion Act of 1962, it must determine (1) that the
imports in question are entering the United States in inéreased quantities;
(2) that the increased imports are a result in major part of trade agreement
concessions; and (3) that such increased imports have been the major factor
in causing or threatening to cause, serious injury to the domestic industry
concerned. If the Commission finds in the negative with respect to any one
of these three requisites, it is foreclosed from making an affirmative finding
for the industry.
D. Impossibility of Qualifying for Relief Under Present Criteria
Since the drastic change made by Congress in the Act of 1962 in determining
the criteria for injury to be found by the Tariff Commission before relief can
be secured by an industry, firm or individual, not one petition was found to
have met that criteria. From the enactment of the 1962 Trade Expansion Act
to date, domestic industries have filed 10 petition.s with the Tariff Commission
for investigation and trade `adjustment assistance; domestic firms have filed
6 petitions and workers have filed 5 petitions. In all, 21 petitions have been
filed and as previously stated the Tariff Commission has not made an af/irma-
tive finding in any.
PAGENO="0372"
3808
B. The United States Potters Association Was One of the Many Domestic Indus-
tries Denied Relief After an Escape Clanse Hearing by the Tariff Corn-
mission Under the Present Criteria
An excellent example of relief denied under the present escape clause criteria
is the petition filed by myself on behalf of the United States Potters Association.
It was the first case which came before the Tariff Commission for relief under
the Trade Expansion Act of 1962. As a matter of fact the petition was filed
under Section 7 of the Trade Agreement Extension Act of 1951 as amended,
and the hearings were also held under the provisions of the act. However, before
the Tariff Commission could render its findings the Trade Expansion Act of
1962 was passed and, therefore, this petition had to be adjudicated under the
new act with its changed criteria for "injury".
The Commission found that there was an upward trend of imports of earthen-
ware tableware and kitchen articles and that such earthenware "is being
imported * * * in * * * increased quantities" within the meaning of the Trade
Expansion Act (Page 4-Report to the President on Investigation No. 7-114-
TEA-1-2). They also found (in one category) that the significant increase
in imports occurred years after the duty reductions were made, hence the duty
reductions could not be the major cause of the increased imports.
The Tariff Commission stated that 15 domestic producers of earthenware had
ceased production, 8 of which terminated production in the period 1957-1961.
Production declined from 30 million dozen pieces in 1954 to 26.8 million dozen
pieces in 1957 and to 22.1 million pieces in 1958; production then increased
to 24.4 million dozen pieces in 1959 and declined to 21.6 million dozen pieces in
1961. In all of the yOars 1957 through 1961, dinnerware accounted for more
than 98 per cent of the total quantity of earthenware produced. Sales of house-
hold earthen dinnerware by domestic producers declined from 26.4 million dozen
pieces valued at $57.1 million in 1957, to 23.0 million dozen pieces valued at
$48.4 million in 1961. During 1958-60 the average annual imports were 17 per
cent greater than 1955-57, and in the 2 year period 1961-2, they were 11 per cent
greater than in 1958-60. Imports of earthenware amounted to 6.5 million dozen
pieces in 1957, increased to 9.2 million dozen pieces in 1960. Estimated imports
of earthenware dinnerware rose from 2.5 million dozen pieces in 1957 to 4.3
million dozen pieces in 1960, then to 3.4 million dozen pieces in 1961. These im-
ports were equivalent to 9 per cent of the apparent consumption of such din-
nerware in 1957 and to 13 per cent in 1961. (See report to the President on In-
vestigation No. 7-114 (TEA 1-2) under Section 301 (b) of the Trade Expan-
sion Act of 1962). The statistical information secured from the Labor Depart-
ment, Bureau of the Census, Customs Bureau, etc. can be found in the report
submitted to the President; the testimony adduced at the hearings nnd the
exhibits submitted can be seen at the Tariff Commission.
F. The Proposed Liberalization Of The Tariff Adjnstment Provisions Of The
Trade Expansion Act of 1962 By The Trade Expansion Act of 1968 (H.R.
17751) For The Benefit Of Firn~s And Workers Will Help Those Classes
Little If At All Unless There Is A Change In The Criteria For Injury
Applying To Domestic Industries
As above stated, when Congress changed the criteria for relief to domestic
industries injured as a result of increased imports due to a trade concession
from the escape clause provisions contained in the Section 7 of the Trade Exten-
sion Act of 1951 to the provisions contained in the present act (Trade Expan-
sion Act of 1962) and included also therein for the first time tariff assistance
to injured firms and workers, not one petition on behalf of domestic industries,
firms or workers qualified. The criteria for securing relief in the present law
(Trade Expansion Act of 1962) is the same for domestic industries, individual
firms or workers.
The Administration recognizing that whereas the escape clause provisions of
the Ti~ade Extension Act of 1951 were successfully applied by several domestic
industries which qualified thereunder, the changes made for securing relief by
injured industries, individual firms or workers under the Trade Expansion Act
of 1962, proved to be a complete nullity, is now suggesting amendments to the
latter Act through the proposed "Trade Expansion Act of 1968" (H.R. 17551).
However, the proposed changes in H.R. 17551 apply merely to individual firms
and workers and does not apply to domestic industries. In other words the pro-
posed new Act will make it easier for individual firms and workers to secure
relief from loss of jobs or loss of income due to increased ruinous imports, but
PAGENO="0373"
3809
the domestic industry which contains the individual firms and employs the
workers will still be handicapped by the criteria under the Trade Expansion
Act of 1962, which criteria has been impossible to meet up to the present time.
The President in requesting Congress to liberalize the previous impossible re-
strictions placed on those industries, firms and individuals seeking justifiable
relief from imports, very studiously limited the proposed changes to apply only
to firms and workers. He stated:
"Some firms, however, have difficulty in meeting foreign competition, and need
time and help to make the adjustment.
"Since international trade strengthens the nation as a whole, it is only fair
that the government assist those businessmen and workers who face serious prob-
lems as a result of increased imports.
"The Congress recongized this need-in the Trade Expansion Act of 1962-
by establishing a program of trade adjustment assistance to businessmen and
workers adversely affected by imports."
It is respectfully pointed out that to offer relief to firms and workers and not
to the domestic industry involved is absolutely worthless . . . What can it
possibly benefit a firm if it receive tax assistance or a loan or other adjustment,
if the industry is forced out of the business of producing the article because of
low cost foreign competition? What can it possibly benefit a worker in the long
run if he gets extra unemployment benefits or training or relocation, if the in-
dustry in which he was employed transfers its manufacturing ability and know-
how to low wage countries because of imports from similar low wage countries?
If the proposed "Trade Expansion Act of 1968" (HR. 17551) is passed in the
present form as relates to escape clause provisions for domestic industries; and
tariff adjustment provisions as relates to individual firms and workers, it is
possible that a firm or worker could qualify for relief under the new provisions
but the domestic industry could not qualify even though petitions could be filed
by all three categories at the same time and the same evidence adduced by the
Tariff Commission in its investigation.
It is strongly urged that the criteria for relief proposed by the new act (H.R.
17551) be changed so that it would be identical for domestic industries, individual
firms or workers.
THE PRESIDENT SHOULD NOT BE GIVEN FURTHER AUTHORITY TO REDUCE DUTIES
Under the proposed Trade Expansion Act of 1968 (H.R. 17551) the President
is seeking further authority to reduce duties. Under the Trade Expansion Act of
1962 the President was given authority to reduce the rates of duty on imported
merchandise tO 50 per cent of the rates which existed on July 1, 1962. The
authority expired on June 30,1967.
Under the auspices of the so-called Kennedy Round of negotiations most of
the authority granted to the President to reduce rates of duty was used. It is
believed that the reductions in the rate of duty applying to imports into the
United States were predicated not so much on the concession we received from
the negotiating parties under GATT but took into account the domestic industry
involved, its relation to the country, its relation to the community, the protection
needed (if any) from competitive imports, capital invested, number of employees,
etc. If it is a fact that those factors were taken into account, then the reductions
in duty under the Kennedy Round were probably the maximum reductions pos-
sible, even if less than the full 50 per cent permitted. Therefore, to permit the
President to have authority to further reduce duties for any reason in those
instances where the full 50 per cent reduction in duty was not used would be
imposing an undue hardship by the mere threat of further reductions on those
domestic industries.
The results of the Kennedy Round have hardly been realized and the mere
authority to further reduce duties could result in a mass exodus of domestic
industries to low wage countries. For example the rate of duty on all categories
of imported earthenware dinnerware was not reduced the full 50 per cent
authorized. Nevertheless, the categories which received a full per cent recluc-
tion in duty are dependent and inter-related with the categories which did not
receive the full 50 per cent reduction; so that a definite loss of over-all business
in the domestic earthenware dinnerware trade is anticipated as a result of the
Kennedy Round reductions. Before an additional authority be given to the
President to reduce the rate of duty on those categories of earthenware dinner-
ware which were not originally reduced the full 50 per cent, a waiting period
of at least 3 years be set up to determine the effect of the Kennedy Round.
PAGENO="0374"
3810
Also certain new categories of earthenware dinnerware were established for
customs treatment and duty application under the Kennedy Round. It appears
as though the duty on these new categories was not reduced under the Kennedy
Round. However, the duty was reduced under previous customs classifications
and under prior trade agreements and, therefore, to permit these categories to be
reduced at the present time a full 50 per cent of the rate of duty existing on
July 1, 1962 would be imposing an undue hardship on an already over bur-
dened industry.
No one is disadvantaged if the President is denied at the present the authority
to reduce duties to the full 50 per cent authorized under the Trade Expansion
Act of 1962. If in a specific instance for a specific purpose it is necessary, Con-
gress can authorize such authority. Blanket authority to the President at this
time can only be detrimental to domestic industries.
AN OMNIBUS QUOTA BILL SHOULD BE PASSED SO THAT ANY DOMESTIC INDUSTRY
WHICH IS INJURED AND QUALIFIES UNDER AN ANNOUNCED CRITERIA WOULD BE
ABLE TO GET RELIEF FROM RUINOUS IMPORTS
Congress is well aware of the many quota bills presently pending and cover-
ing many imported articles. There is no doubt that at least some are meritorious
and are deserving of Congressional action. Obviously some of them are merely
put into the hopper by Congressmen in order to appease constituents.
In order to reduce the work load of Congress in this connection and to remove
the doubt as to whether or not a domestic industry is entitled a relief from
imports by limiting the amount of imports, an omnibus quota bill should be
passed. The criteria for qualifying for relief under such a bill could be spelled
out by Congress and would require an overt act on the part of such industry to
seek relief. Therefore, even if a particular industry may be entitled to relief
under such a bill, the relief would not be forthcoming automatically, but it
would be necessary for `the industry to petition for the relief necessary.
Again using the domestic earthenware dinnerware industry as an example,
we find that since the Tariff Commission ruled under the criteria of the Trade
Expansion Act of 1962 that the industry was not entitled to relief, matters have
worsened. Furthermore, the duty reductions made under the Kennedy Round
have not yet been felt due to the shortness of time that they have been in exist-
ence (January 1, 1968). Attached hereto is Exhibit I which is a report of the
Bureau of Labor Statistics covering this industry and tells its own story. It
shows that from 1960 to 1965 employment decreased 26 per cent and imports
increased 42 per cent. Furthermore, and most important, is the fact that in
1960 imports was 18 per cent of total consumption and in 1965 it jumped to 27
per cent. An omnibus quota bill would probably have a percentage of imports
as related to domestic consumption as part of its qualifying criteria, and in all
probability, would not be as drastic as the jump in this industry from 18 per
cent in 1961) to 27 per cent in 1965.
Furthermore, attached hereto is Exhibit II which shows domestic shipments
in a steady decline from 1954 to 1966 and a steady increase in the value of im-
ports (based on foreign value) during the same period. During -the period the
ratio of imports to consumption jumped from 7.7 per cent to a whopping 32.5
per cent. See also Exhibit III, a report of the Bureau of the Oensus showing
the tremendous increase in imports of earthenware table and kitchen utensils
from 1954 to 1967 and the negligible amount of exports. As a result of such
increased imports against decreased domestic production, the number of pro-
duction workers decreased from 12,333 in 1954 to 5,626 in 1966 (Sec Exhibit
IV attached hereto). When combined with certain chinaware imports, Exhibit
V, a report from the Bureau of the Census, shows that earthenware table and
kitchen articles domestic shipments decreased from $67,029,000 in 1954 to
$47,599,000 in 1966 whereas imports increased from $5,522,000 to $22,332,000;
and when combined with chinaware imports, the ratio of total imports to do-
mestic shipments rose from 28.8 in 1954 to 116.6 in 1966.
No domestic industry can long survive with increases of that nature, especially
one like the earthenware dinnerware industry, where approximately 60 per cent
of the cost of production i's attributable to direct labor. .
PAGENO="0375"
3811
As has been previously stated an omnibus quota bill would probably cover
a situation presently encountered by the domestic earthenware dinnerware in-
dustry and permit it to qualify for relief under a defined criteria. It would not
then be necessary for this industry to seek Congressional relief.
BALANCE OF TRADE PAYMENTS
Our balance of trade payments are linked with and tied up with our trade
balances relative to imports and exports. For years it has been the theory that
we are a solvent country as reflected in at least one instance by our favorable
balance of trade. As a result of this fiction we were advised that in order to
keep up our favorable balance of trade, and in fact increase it, we would have
to reduce tariffs so that other nations could sell their exports to us before they
could buy our exports. This concept was stressed even if it meant the exter-
mination of some domestic industries which were economically operated and
turn over the production of that article to foreign countries.
As of several weeks ago we no longer have a favorable balance of trade. Our
exports, including government-financed exports, did not exceed our imports. As
recently as May 20, 19(18 there appeared in the New York Times a statement
made by a Vice President of the overseas division of a very large bank, who said:
"If Government-financed exports are left out of account, the commercial trade
balance this year may show a deficit of $1.5 to $2.5 billion, compared with a
small commercial surplus last year of $250 million."
Since our export statistics when stripped of government financed shipments
will show an unfavorable balance of trade it reduces considerably the argument
of those who claim that duties must be reduced at any cost in order to be able
to export. We now have an unfavorable balance of trade and practically free
trade. Perhaps it is time to take a hard look at the entire picture of world trade
with a view to domestic industries sharing in it.
EXHIBIT I
TABLE 1.-FINE EARTHENWARE TABLE AND KITCHEN ARTICLES, SIC 3263
Shipments Imports Total Imports Employment Imports
(millions) (millions) (supply) percent of Employment decrease increase
total (percent) (percent)
1960
1965
60.2
51.1
13.0
18.5
73.2
69.6
18
27
8,770
6,447 -26 +42
EXHIBIT II
EARTHENWARE TABLE AND KITCHEN ARTICLES-U.S. MANUFACTURERS' SHIPMENTS, IMPORTS FOR
CONSUMPTION, EXPORTS, AND APPARENT CONSUMPTION, 1954-66
IDollar amounts in thousandsj
Year
Manufacturers'
shipments
value
Imports
value
(foreign)
Exports
value
Apparent
consumption
Ratio of
imports!
consumption
1954
1955
1956
1957
1958
1959
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
$67,029
67,985
69, 307
63,212
50,230
58,215
58,326
46,446
48,383
59,046
62,242
52,334
47,599
$5,522
6,823
7,869
8,788
9,037
11,614
12,963
11,662
13,562
14,033
16,861
18,545
22,332
$1,358
1,435
1, 149
1,494
1,487
1,172
1,074
752
640
779
664
898
1,119
$71,193
73,373
76, 027
70,508
57,780
58,657
70,215
57,356
61,305
72,300
78,439
69,981
68,812
7.7
9.3
10. 4
12.5
12.3
16.5
18.4
20.3
22.1
19.4
21.4
26.5
32.5
Source: U.S. Bureau of the Census and Consumer Durables Division.
PAGENO="0376"
Cl,
C
Cl)
w
C)
Cl)
~
C)
C)
3
N) C~)
C)~4.JC)~CO OO~ ~4 ~ U~C~)
O)(C) ~J ~ ~N) ~~-J~O Co N)
4000
~ (4,0) (J1~ ~ (4) ())C4)0) 0)0)0)
CJ)CC) N) ~C~) ~Cl) 3N)N)o4 CO Co
dli.
2
3
-4
Co
-4
2
-4
Co
2
-Co
2
Cl) C)
Cl)>
R~
C)C)
~ w
DC')
4-4
~C) .~
~(fl(4)C)CYiC.3
~w0o-.4O,~
C,~.3C,)C~) ~ C) 0N3~C) ~ 00
(41(0 -J~ 0000 ~ N) 00C4100(43 -
4,
01(000 ~W Co N) ~ N) -4 ~ (0(3100
-4
>
Co
>
-4
2
>
-4
>
Co
>
2
Co
-4
- C)
Co
= 2
>~
F ~
Cl) ~
~
0
-4
Cl~
0
C)
0
2
Cl)
C
-a
-4
0
2
>
2
Co
C
~l)
-a
0
-4
C/)
a
a
PAGENO="0377"
3813
EXHIBIT V
HOUSEHOLD EARTHENWARE TABLE AND KITCHEN ARTICLES-DOMESTIC SHIPMENTS AND IMPORTS AND I MPORTS'
OF CHINAWARE TABLE AND KITCHEN ARTICLES 1954-66
(Value in thousands of dollarsj
Year
Earthenware
Chinaware
imports
Total chinaware
and
earthenware
imports
Ratio total
imports to
domestic
shipments
Domestic Imports
shipments
1954
1955
1956
1957
1958
1959
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
67,029 5,522
67,985 6, 823
69,307 7,869
63,212 8,788
50,230 9, 037
58,215 11,614
58,326 12,963
46,446 11,662
: 48,383 13,562
59, 046 14, 033
62,242 16,861
52, 334 18, 545
47,599 22,332
13,754
15,222
16,942
18,359
17,772
21,806
23,382
21,108
24,791
20, 757
27,690
30, 767
33,185
19,276
22,045
24,811
27,147
26,809
33,420
36,345
32,770
38,353
34,790
44,551
49, 312
55,517
28. 8
32. 4
35.8
42.9
53.4
57.4
62.3
70.6
79.3
58. 9
71.6
94. 2
116.6
Source: Bureau of theCensus.
Mr. FtriIroN. Thank you, Mr. Golden.
Mr. human?
Mr. ULLMAN. I have no questions.
Mr. FULTON. Mr. Byrnes.
Mr. BYRNES. I have no questions.
Mr. FtILTON. Mr. Conable.
Mr. CONABLE. I have no questions.
Mr. FULTON. There being no further questions, we certainly appre-
ciate your contribution.
Mr. GOLDEN. Thank you.
(The following statements were received, for the record, by the
committee:)
STATEMENT ON BEHALF OF THE EXPANDED SHALE, CLAY & SLATE INSTITUTE, THE
LIGHTWEIGHT AGGREGATE PRODUCERS AS500IATI0N, AND THE NATIONAL SLAG
ASSOCIATION
The Expanded Shale, Clay and Slate Institute is a trade association represent-
ing 32 United States producers of expanded shale, clay, and slate for use as a
lightweight concrete aggregate. Its members operate 46 plants in 28 states and
Puerto Rico, employ many hundreds of people, and annually produce 5,400,000
tons of lightweight aggregate worth $30,000,000.
PAGENO="0378"
3814
The Lightweight Aggregate Producers Association is a trade association repre-
senting 13 United States producers of sintered clay, shale, and fly ash for use as
a lightweight aggregate. Its members operate 14 plants in 9 states, employ several
hundred people, and annually produce 2,400,000 tons of lightweight aggregate
worth $13,200,000.
The National Slag Association is a trade association representing 9 sellers of
expanded slag for use as a lightweight aggregate. Its members operate 12 plants
in 9 states, employ several hundred more people, and annually market 2,450,000
tons of lightweight aggregate worth $7,250,000.
We are attaching to this statement a listing of our members and the locations
of their plants. Together they account for approximately 85 percent of domestic
production of expanded shale, clay, and slate aggregates, approximately 95
percent of domestic sales of slag aggregates, and roughly two-thirds of domestic
production of all light-weight aggregates.
The lightweight aggregate industry
Aggregate is the material that is added to cement or a similar adhesive to
make concrete. Sand, gravel, and crushed store are used as aggregate in the mak-
ing of heavier grades of concrete. Lighter grades of concrete require a light-
weight aggregate. These lighter grades enjoy obvious advantages in large-scale
construction projects and have achieved general acceptance for that use, partic-
ularly in the form of concrete blocks. The market for light aggregates derives
directly from the demand thus generated for lightweight concrete~
Lightweight aggregates are invariably low-priced bulk minerals. Expanded
shale, clay, and slate are produced by burning certain types of raw shale,
clay or slaite in rotary kilns or sintering them on traveling plates. The burned
or sintered raw material expands to as much as several times its original size
without any increase in weight and thus becomes suitable for use as lightweight
aggregate.
Slag is a byproduct of the iron blast furnace process. When molten slag is
expanded with controlled applications of water, it too is suitable for use as
lightweight aggregate. Other lightweight aggregates include coal cinders, vermic-
ulite, perlite, and pumice.
Pumice is a glass-like form of cooled volcanic lava which is light in weight
because it is full of minute cavities caused by expanding volcanic gases that
become entrapped when the lava suddenly cooled. Limited quantities of pumice
are mined in some of our own western states. Recently, however, floods of
imported pumice, primarily from Greece and Italy, have been pouring into our
eastern seaboard markets for lightweight aggregate. Impeded by no tariff
barrier at all-the pumice we are concerned with comes in dutv-free---this
imported pumice is making sudden and deep inroads in cities and localities near
several eastern ports.
Our member firms and the people who work for them find their businesses
and their jobs threatened. We come to seek relief from this threat.
The development of the pumice aggregate threat
During the 1950's and before, little pumice entered the United States from
abroad, and most of what did was intended for use as an abrasive. Some pumice
still is brought for this purpose, and to this day pumice is classified among the
abrasives in the Tariff Schedules of the United States. The Tariff Act of 1930
originally subjected the type of pumice which primarily concerns us to a duty of
0.1 cent per pound. By 1956, however, trade agreement concessions had lowered
the duty to 0.0425 cent per pound.
Meanwhile, in the late forties and early fifties, domestic pumice in small
quantities and imported pumice in even smaller quantities began to be employed
as a lightweight aggregate. The domestic pumice all comes from western mines
and processing plants. Then as now, transportation costs made it unavailable
east of the Mississippi. Then as now, all or almost all imported pumice entered
through the eastern seaboard and was marketed only in the East. Then, however,
most such pumice imports came to Florida ports for use within that state. They
were not a significant factor in any larger lightweight-aggregate market.
In 1959 a special law was enacted for the benefit of Florida importers and
concrete block producers eliminating the tariff on "pumice stone to be used in the
manufacture of masonry products such as building blocks, bricks, tiles and
similar rm' (Now Item 519.05, United States Tariff Schedules Annotated.)
1 PublIc Law 86-325, 73 Stat. 596 (1959).
PAGENO="0379"
3815
At that time our industry opposed this law because we foresaw that it would
inevitably allow the importation of pumice to spread to a much wider area on
the East Coast and to take on a much larger scale. Unfortunately, we were proved
right about that.
The only east coast area who~e imports of masonry pumice have not risen since
the duty was eliminated is Florida. The subsequent poor performance of the low-
quality pumice then being imported there temporarily eliminated the local market
for pumice. As we had feared, it temporarily damaged the local market
for other lightweight aggregates as well.
The rising swell of imports
Elsewhere the story was quite different, and it bore out our fears that elimina-
tion of the tariff would invite destructive competition all over the East Coast.
Imports, which were negligible outside of Florida in 1959, had by 1961 reached
24,000 tons. In 1962 they tripled to 76,000 tons. In 1963 they doubled again to
146,000 tons. Since then they have proceeded in an erratic but unmistakable
climb that last year brought them to 238,000 tons, ten times the level of 1961.
If unrestrained, these imports will undobtedly go higher.
The worst of it is that the full brunt of this asault on U.S. markets falls
on a few firms located at or near the East Coast. Almost all the pumice imports
are coming into the eastern seaboard ports between Boston and Norfolk and
are being marketed near those ports. Though local markets for lightweight aggre-
gate are growing as builders discover the advantages of these materials, they
remain limited, and as a result of this intense import competition individual
plants and even companies are in danger of being swamped and driven out of
business.
When low-priced pumice became available in the Norfolk area a year or so
ago, for example, it put domestic competitors at a sudden and severe competitive
disadvantage. Lured by lower prices, local concrete block makers turned to
pumice, and local construction firms turned to the correspondingly cheaper
pumice block. Whereas in 1966 no pumice at all had been sold in the Norfolk
area, last year pumice took up 21 percent of the lightweight aggregate market
there, and in the first six months of this year pumice has preempted a full
55 percent of that market. Perhaps coincidentally, a local block maker who had
been using another type of lightweight aggregate went into liquidation and has
left the business.
Similar, if less drastic, consequences have followed the import surge in other
areas. On up the east coast last year pumice imports chewed up an estimated
15 percent of the lightweight aggregate market in the Baltimore area; 60
percent of the market in Philadelphia; 47 percent of the market in Elizabeth,
New Jersey; 83 percent of the market in Milford, Connecticut; 71 percent in
New Haven, Connecticut; 69 percent in Providence, Rhode Island; and 41
percent in Boston. Evidence so far this year is that these percentages will rise
further. Naturally, the domestic firms in these areas are being hurt by the loss
of business. Workers in these areas are being hurt by the loss of jobs.
Meanwhile the pumice importers have promised to extend their marketing
efforts back down the remainder of the East Coast, around to the Gulf Coast,
and through the St. Lawrence Seaway to Great Lakes ports as well. When
and if they are able to carry out their promise, many more domestic producers
and their employees will be similarly threatened.
Causes and adverse effects of pumice imports
The price advantage imported pumice enjoys over competing domestic aggre-
gate stems from its distinct advantages in labor and materials costs. The wages
paid to Italian or Greek laborers are far below those we pay our workers here
in the United States. Moreover, the pumice is considerably less complicated to
mine and process than the expanded or sintered materials we market. It re-
quires nothing like the millions of dollars of plant and equipment in which our
firms must invest.
Even the costs of transporting the pumice across a thousand miles and more of
ocean adds no more to the dockside price than a rail journey of a few hundred
miles adds to the price of domestic aggregates. Ships whose holds would other-
wise be empty or filled with ballast on return trips to the U.S. give rock-bottom
rates to shipments of materials like pumice that can be transported in bulk.
We consider this invasion of our markets by cheap materials processed by
cheap labor and brought to the United States at cut rates a form of unfair corn-
PAGENO="0380"
3816
petition. United States customs offers no relief, since the pumice imports come
in duty-free-a fact which the importers are quick to point out to potential
customers.
The upshot is that dockside prices on the imported pumice generally are con-
siderably less than the best prices domestic competitors can offer.2
The s~irong and swelling surge of imports that results is threatening the growth
of an important domestic industry, costing American workers jobs, and contribut-
ing to the newly unfavorable trend in our balance of trade and the already
unfavorable condition of our balance of payments.
The lightweight aggregate industry was a relative newcomer in the postwar
period and expanded rapidly during that period. Recent years have seen some
leveling off of production and consumption. But as the advantages of lightweight
aggregate and of the lightweight masonry it makes possible become better known
and more widely appreciated, we anticipate a renewal of rapid growth in
the market as a whole. If the importation of pumice continues to grow even faster
than the overall market, however, the growth of our domestic industry and
in particular the growth of firms whose plants lie near ocean ports will be
stymied, if not reversed. By the same token, the employment of American
workers in the industry will be severely curtailed.
Meanwhile, increasing imports of pumice are helping to aggravate this na-
tion's already severe balance of trade difficulties. Because lightweight aggregates
are low-priced commodities for which transportation costs over great distances
at normal rates are generally prohibitive, they are not exported from the United
States except in very small quantities to nearby islands. Thus almost the entire
amount of pumice imports-over half a million dollars last year-is a net drain
on the balance of payments.
In this respect of course the experience of the lightweight aggregate industry
differs from that of other industries only in its complete one-sidedness. In indus-
try after imports are outpacing exports, to the point that in March and May even
the balance of trade, long the bright spot in the payments picture, turned against
the United States for the first time.
Something must be done, and Congress is the right place to start.
The need for Congressional Actioiv
Before this Committee now are several measures that will alleviate the current
general trade situation and the situation of industries being injured, as ours is,
by rising imports.
We support the President's move to make it easier for injured firms and work-
ers to qualify for adjustment assistance and to simplify the attendant procedures.
We support also bills like that introduced by Mr. Herlong (H.R. 16936) to im-
pose import quotas whenever imports threaten to overwhelm an industry before
it has time to react.
But because of the peculiar regional nature of the threat to our industry, we
are uncertain that these bills will meeet it. For this reason and for the protection
of our firms and their employees, we respectfully request that imports of ma-
sonry pumice (Tariff Item 519.05) be limited by law to an amount equal to the av-
erage of such imports over the past five years, 1963-1967. Such a limitation, while
not excluding imports altogether, would permit domestic lightweight aggregate
producers to maintain their just share of the now-threatened markets in our
seaboard cities and would reduce the drain from these imports on our balance
of payments. We further ask this Committee to give our problem careful consid-
eration in the formulation of more general legislation, and we add our voices to
the proposition that in the formulation of United States trade policy the needs of
U.S. business and U.S. workers should be placed first.
JOHN J. SAPIENZA,
CHARLES H. Hniiz,
_________ Of Counsel.
2Exact price figures are unfortunately unavailable, since prices vary with each
transaction.
PAGENO="0381"
3817
Attachment
Rosmx OF MEMBERS
EXPANDED SHALE, CLAY & SLATE INSTITUTE
Alabama:
Vulcan Materials Co.
P.O. Box 7324-A
Birmingham
Arkansas:
Arkansas Lightweight
Aggregate Corp.
P.O. Box 99
England
California:
Basalt Rock Co., Inc.
8th and River Streets
Napa
The McNear Co.
P.O. Box 1380, McNear Point
San Rafael
Lightweight Processing Co.
650 South Grand Avenue
Los Angeles (three plants in Los
Angeles area)
Port Costa Clay Products Co.
P.O. Box 5
Port Costa
Kaiser Industries Corporation
Sand and Gravel Division
300 Lakeside Drive
Oakland
Colorado:
The IDEALITE Co.
821 Seventeenth Street
Denver
Florida:
Florida Solite Co.
1114 SOL Building
Jacksonville
Georgia:
Georgia Lightweight Aggregate
Co.
P.O. Box 19781, Station "N"
Atlanta
Illinois:
Material Service
Division of General Dynamics
Corp.
300 W. Washington Street
Chicago
Indiana:
Hydraulic Press Brick Co.
Brooklyn
Iowa:
Carter-Waters Corp.
Centérville
Kansas:
Buildex, Inc.
P.O. Box 15
Ottawa
Buildex, Inc.
Marquette
Kentucky:
Kenlite
129 River Road
Louisville
95-159 O-68-pt. 8-25
Louisiana:
Louisiana Lightweight Aggregate Co.
P.O. Box 5472
Aiexandria
Big River Industries
P.O. Box 66377, Central City Station
Baton Rouge
Minnesota:
Acolite, Inc.
Springfield
Mississippi:
Jackson Ready-Mix Concrete
P.O. Box 1292
Jackson
Missouri:
Carter-Waters Corp.
2440 Pennway
Kansas City
Hydraulic Press Brick Co.
705 Olive Street
St. Louis
Montana:
Treasure State Industries, Inc.
P.O. Box 2750
Great Falls
Nehraska:
Western Aggregate & Brick Co.
P.O. Box 268
Lincoln
New York:
Buffalo Haydite Division of J. P. Bur-
roughs & Son
P.O. Box 29
West galls
Hudson Valley Lightweight Aggre-
gate Corp.
1967 Thrnbull Avenue
Bronx
Northern Lightweight Aggregate, Inc.
028 5. Saratoga Street
Cohoes
Nytralite Aggregate Division of Lone
Star Cement Corp.
162 Old Mill Road
West Nyack
North Carolina:
Carolina Solite Corp.
4425 Randolph Road
Charlotte
North Dakota:
Baukol-Noonan, Inc.
P.O. Box223
Mandan
Baukol-Noonan, Inc.
Noonan
Ohio:
Hydraulic Press Brick Co.
P.O. Box 7786
Cleveland
PAGENO="0382"
3818
ROSTER OF MEMBERS-Continued
EXPANDED SHALE, CLAY & SLATE INSTITUTE-continued
Oklahoma: Texas:
Ohandlei~ Materials Co. Dallas Lightweight Aggregate Co.
1723 South Boston P.O. Box 400
Tulsa Arlington
Chandler Materials Co. Texas Lightweight Aggregate Co.
Choctaw Division P.O. Box 400
P.O. Box 158 Arlington
Choctaw Texas Lightweight Aggregate Co.
Oregon: 3111 MeKinney Avenue
Empire Building Material Co. Houston
9255 N. E. Halsey Street Utah:
Portland Utelite Corp.
Puerto Rico: Goalville
Diaslite Inc.
Box 2588 G.P.O. Virginia:
`Clinchfiekl Goal Go.
San Juan
Dante
South Dakota:
Solite Corp.
Light Aggregates, Inc. P.O. Box 9138
P.O. Box 1922
Richmond
Rapid City Virginia Solite Go.
Tennessee:
P.O. Box 2015
Tennlite, Inc. Arlington
P.O. Box336
Greenbriar
LIGHTWEIGHT AGGREGATE PRODUCERS ASSOCIATION
PRODUCER MEMBERS
Illinois: New York:
Illinois Brick Co. Onondaga Lightweight
228 N. LaSalle St. Aggregate Corp.
Chicago, Ill. 60601 Peck Road
Waylite Co. Warners, N.Y.
20 N. Wacker Drive Pennsylvania:
Chicago, Ill. G. & W. H. Corson, Inc.
Massachusetts: Plymouth Meeting, Pa.
Freeport Brick Co.
Masslite, Inc.
Freeport, Pa. 16229
P.O. Box 1747
Plainville, Mass. 02762 Bylite Corporation
P.O. Box 1628
Michigan: North End Station
Light Weight Aggregate Corp. Wilkes-Barre, Pa.
12720 Farmington Road Tennessee:
Livonia, Mich. John A. Denie's Sons Co.
373 Adams Ave.
Minnesota:
Memphis, Tenn.
North Central Lightweight Shalite Corporation
Aggregate Company P.O. Box 441
4901 W. Medicine Lake Drive
Knoxville, Tenn. 37901
Minneapolis, Minn. Virginia:
New Jersey: Weblite Corporation
Sayre & Fisher Brick Co. P.O. Box 270
Sayreville, N.J. Roanoke, Va.
PAGENO="0383"
Alabama:
U.S. Pipe & Foundry Company
3300 First Avenue, North
Birmingham, Alabama 35202
Vulcan Materials Company
P.O. Box `7497
Birmingham, Alabama 35223
California:
Fontana Slag Division
Brown Bros. Contractors, Inc.
P.O. Box 1010
.Fontana, California 92335
Michigan:
Edw. C. Levy Company
8800 Dix Avenue
Detroit, Michigan 48209
Ohio:
American Materials Corporation
P.O. Box 291
Hamilton, Ohio 45012
The Standard Slag Company
1200 Stambaugh Building
Youngstown, Ohio 44501
Pennsylvania:
Bethlehem Steel Corporation
701 East Third Street
Bethlehem, Pennsylvania 18016
Duquesne Slag Products Co.
Frick Annex Bldg., 16th Floor
429 Forbes Avenue
Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania 15219
United States Steel Corporation
525 William Penn Place
Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania 15230
STATEMENT OF J. RAYMOND Paicu, EXECUTIVE SECRETARY OF GLASS CRAFTS OF
AMERICA, ON BEHALF OF THE AMERICAN HAND-MADE GLASSWARE INDUSTRY
GLASS CRAFTS OF AMERICA
MEMBERSHIP
1. Blenko Glass Company, Milton, West Virginia 25541.
2. Fenton Art Glass Company, Williamstown, West Virginia 26187.
3. Fostoria Glass Company, Moundsville, West Virginia 26041.
4. Imperial Glass Corporation, Bellaire, Ohio 43906.
5. Lenox Crystal, Inc., Mount Pleasant, Pennsylvania 15666.
6. Morgantown Glassware Guild, Morgantown, West Virginia 26505.
7. Pilgrim Glass Corporation, Ceredo, West Virginia 25507.
8. Rainbow Art Glass Company, Huntington, West Virginia 25704.
9. Seneca Glass Company, Morgantown, West Virginia 26505.
10. L. B. Smith Glass Company, Mount Pleasant, Pennsylvania 15666.
11. Tiffin Glass Company, Inc., Puffin, Ohio 44883.
12. Viking Glass Company, New Martinsville, West Virginia 26155.
13. Westmoreland Glass Company, Grapeville, Pennsylvania 15634.
14. West Virginia Glass Specialty Company, Weston, West Virginia 26452.
IDENTIFICATION AND QUALIFICATION OF THE WITNESS
Mr. Chairman and Gentlemen of the Committee, My name is J. Raymond Price.
I am Executive Secretary of GLASS CRAFTS OF AMERICA, an organization
comprised of fourteen U.S. companies engaged in the production of hand pressed
and hand blown glassware. I am also Executive Secretary of the Illuminating
and Allied Glassware Manufacturers Association, an organization of seven U.S.
companies engaged in the production of hand-made glassware products for
illuminating, industrial and allied purposes. In addition to these two Association
groups of glassware manufacturers I also represent, on an individual basis,
twelve additional companies producing a general line of hand-made glassware.
3819
ROSTER OF MEMBERS-Continued
MEMBER COMPANIES OF THE NATIONAL SLAG ASSOCIATION
PAGENO="0384"
3820
This presentation is made on behalf of all these companies who are desirous of
lending their support to H.R. 16936 as introduced in the House of Representatives
by Mr. Herlong, May 1, 1968. The companies that I represent maufacture approxi-
mately 90 to 95 percent of all the hand-made glassware made in the U.S.A. In
each of their respective locations they contribute substantially to the total inthis-
trial payroll and, in some instances, almost 100 percent of the total industrial
payroll in the community.
It is the earnest desire of the American Hand-Crafted Glassware industry to
cooperate with, and to assist in every way possible, this Committee in the
discharge of its responsibilities in conducting these trade legislation hearings.
We feel that we can best do this by conveying to the Committee some of the
problems experienced by this industry under past and present tariff policies. The
ever-increasing influx of imports and Hand-Made glassware over the past
twenty years has brought about a very serious erosion of the domestic industry.
The story of this industry, in this respect, has been ~x~ld many times before, but
it will bear repetition, in essence, here because there has been no change, except
for further and continuing deterioration.
To illustrate briefly the reasons for, and the intensity of, our interest, I should
like to point out that, in 1950, wage and employment surveys conducted for this
industry and through my office, covered 39 companies operating 40 plants. Those
39 companies included all of the major producers of hand-made glassware in
America. The surveys included the collection of such data as the number of
workers employed, total hours those employees worked, total earnings, average
rates per hour, etc.
Ten years later, in 1961, we reviewed the happenings of the 1950-1960 decade.
As of January 1, 1961, 15 of the companies which were operating in 1950 were
out of production. Those 15 companies alone, in 1950, had employed 3,080 workmen
as compared to the total employment of 4,644 hourly-paid workmen in the com-
panies which remained in operation when the 1961 survey was taken. The loss of
those companies represented a loss of approximately 41/2 million manhours of
work per year, and a loss of approximately 42 percent of America's oldest and
one of its most vital industries.
The primary reason for the loss of these companies was the inability of their
respective management to compete with low-wage products from abroad.
This same problem continues with greater intensity today. In 1965 we had 23
companies reporting a total of 4,690 employees who worked a total of 7,738,141
hours. This means that we have regained only 46 in the number employed during
these past five years. Moreover, those employees worked almost one-half million
fewer hours in 1965 than in 1961.
This is not too difficult to understand when we consider that imports of table
and art glassware have increased in each of the past five years, reaching record
levels in 1965 and indicating new higher levels in this current year. According
to a report issued by the Business and Defense Services Administration of the
U.S. Department of Commerce in February of 1966, it was estimated that im-
ports of table and art glassware alone would reach 20.5 million dollars in 1965
(imports were valued at 51/2 million dollars in 1950 and 111/2 million in 1960),
and this estimate is based on foreign value, country of origin, and does not
include U.S. import duties, ocean freight and marine insurance. The first six
months of 1966, according to the U.S.. Department of Commerce data on imports
of Table and Art Glassware, indicated that the trend continued upward with
a foreign value, country of origin, of 23.7 million as compared to 20.5 million
in 1965.
The first six months of 1967 compared to the first six months of 1966 show
the following gains:
Total imports $11,525,890, or a gain of 6.5 percent over the January to June
period of 1966.
Typical of the gains shown by the leading exporters to this country would
be Italy with a 10 percent gain in 1965, West Germany 25.4 percent, and Japan
30 percent.
Other countries indicating a sizeable increase (although somewhat lower
volume than the first three named above) are the United Kingdom up 45.2 per-
cent and Ireland up 46.4 percent.
Hand-made glassware was the principal 1965 glass import and supplied more
than 50 percent of the domestic market.
Imports from Soviet-bloc countries accounted for 11 percent of the total
(2.1 million dollars-an increase of 25 percent in the first eleven months of
1965).
PAGENO="0385"
3821
As of May 31, 1966, over fourteen countries have increased the value and
quantities of shipments of glassware to the United States. Korea, with a 330
percent increase, leads the parade followed by:
Percent Percent
Spain +94.7 Belgium 21.1
Ireland ~ 41. 5 Italy 10. 7
Denmark 28.0 East Germany 8. 8
Bulgaria 24.0 Czechoslovakia 8.5
Japan 22.1 Rumania 1.0
West Germany 21. 8
The above data, released by the Consumer Durable Goods Division of the
U.S. Department of Commerce, indicate a 10.4 percent increase in total value
of table and art glassware for the period ending May 31, 1966. Shipments were
valued at $8,892,023 or $835,891.00 more than for the same period in 1965.
Early in 1968 the industry was informed that it must gird for greater on-
slaughts, particularly from Japan which supplied 27.7 percent of the total
imports last year.
A glass industry publication recently reported:
"A sweeping invasion of 8000 units of glassware consisting primarily of
tumblers and brandy glasses valued at approximately $16,700 is now being spear-
headed at the American market. Nippon Toki Company, Ltd., producers of Non-
take China, has already started state-side export of its newly added crystal glass-
ware line. The firm began production of the line some five years ago, with this
being the first overseas shipment . . . ." (Note: This ware is already on the
American market.)
Since the preliminary work on this report was outlined in March of this year,
we have received the data for the first quarter of 1968 from the U.S. Department
of Commerce, Durable Goods Division. (See Exhibit 1 attached.)
As we have already indicated, the drastic decline of the domestic hand-made
glassware industry has been brought about primarily because it has been im-
possible for American manufacturers to compete in their own market with
similar products made in foreign countries which enjoy an overwhelming ad-
vantage in labor costs.
The average hourly rate paid to Skilled glassworkers in America today is
$3.39 per hour. Add to this figure current fringe benefits and the total cost to the
employer is somewhere around $3.93 per hour. To the supporting or so-called
Miscellaneous help in the Glass industry, the average rate is $2.43 per hour.
Add to this fringe benefits currently in effect and we come up with a wage of
$2.82 per hour. (Approximately sixty to seventy-five cents of every cost dollar
goes to labor).
The enormity of the task facing the American manufacturer of hand-crafted
glassware is well illustrated by a comparison with his Japanese competitor.
The domestic manufacturer using the same tools, techniques and equipment
must, in this case, overcome wage cost differentials of about twenty to thirty
times the wage cost of the Japanese manufacturer. For example: The average
monthly wage1 paid to a Middle School (equivalent to U.S. High School) gradu-
ate in Japan in 1967 was 13,820 yen (1 yen equals about three-tenths of one
U.S. cent). Thus, that Japanese worker's wage equals about $13.89 per month as
compared to approximately $467.00 now paid to a similar worker in the Hand-
Crafted Glassware industry in the U.S.A.
The Hand-Crafted Glassware industry is of vital importance to our national
defense in times of war or other national emergency, yet these factories cannot
be maintained nor can the irreplaceable skills of the men and women who work
in the industry be preserved on a war-time or emergency-need basis. Their
ability to rapidly convert to the production of such items as glass for ships,
planes, airports, ordnance use, signal glass, sonar, radar and television bulbs
has been fully dempnstrated in World Wars I and II and in the Korean situa-
tion, and there is no reliable source of supply outside our nation's borders to
replace them in time of war. This reservoir of facilities, technical personnel
and skilled craftsmen cannot be tossed into the discard. However, these com-
panies cannot exist unless we can find some way to preserve for them a fair
share of the domestic market for the ordinary household glassware, giftwares,
11J.S. Department of Labor, BLS.
PAGENO="0386"
3822
glass for household and business illumination purposes, etc.-their "Bread and
Butter" items as it were-in times of peace.
In order that there be no misunderstanding of our position, the American
manufacturer is fully cognizant of the necessity for maintaining trade with
foreign nations. We do not seek to create tariff barriers for the sole purpose
of eliminating competition. All we ask is that the American manufacturer be
given an opportunity, by whatever means may be found just and equitable, to
sell his wares, made by AMERICAN workmen at AMERICAN labor rates, equal
to the opportunies afforded foreign manufacturers whose employees are paid
much lower rates.
In his recent appearance before this (Jomniittee, Secretary of State, the
Honorable Mr. Dean Rusk, said that the position of the United States as the
largest single trading nation "underlines our special responsibility to insure
that our trade policy promotes a continued growth of our own2 and the world
economy."
We believe that H.R. 16936 undergirds this philosophy in that it specifically
allows for growth and in fact it does not propose, generally, any reduction in the
current level of imports. Quotas would come into being only if and when pre-
scribed "ceilings" have been penetrated. Moreover, it will allow imports to be
increased in equal proportion to the growth of the American market.
Section 5 of H.R. 16936 establishes certain criteria through which equitable
ceilings on imports may be imposed. We would not presume to say that in all
phases of their application these criteria are 100 percent accurate, but we do
hold that the principle is sound. We hold, further, that certainly it is more equit-
able, and the principle reasonably defensible, when, after an appraisal of all
factors set forth under this and related sections of H.R. 16936, reasonable
ground rules are thus enunciated for the implementation of our tariff policy.
For far too many years we, in the Hand-Crafted Glassware industry, have felt
that the interests of domestic manufacturers were being dealt with solely on
the whim or arbitrary judgment of persons who cared little about the preserva-
tion of the best interests of our own U.S. industries. This, we think, has been
justifiable in view of the fact that over the past score of years directly com-
petitive imports have taken, and now continue to hold, more than 50 percent
of the domestic market in hand-made glassware.
The writer can well recall an appearance before the Committee on Ways and
Means prior to the passage of the Tariff Revision Act of 1962. On that occasion,
we warned that the relief provisions of the then-pending legislation were cynical
and meaningless. The experience of those industrial firms which later sought
relief under the applicable provisions of the Act during these intervening years
has proven, beyond any question, the accuracy of that appraisaL According to
our best information, not one single measure of relief has ever been granted.
It is our hope that the members of this Committee will lend their support to a
re-direction of U.S. Foreign Trade Policy in order to bring about some measure
of equitable treatment for domestic industry. We believe that the enactment of
H.R. 16936 would extend the principle of quota limits under specific criteria-
2 Italic supplied.
PAGENO="0387"
w
o ~ ~
a: 3 3:
D ~
:~: ~` C,,
0 r) 3 0
~ 0,' -4 ~
::::::
0
0. ~ (/)
0
0 COC~
0
~
I -.
0
0
0
N) N) C,) N) N) - N) ~0) ~ - Q~ N) -~ r~ ~ 3 r~ W
0~- .JC,)~N)(O 0 0 ~
-~°: ` ~ !~. ~
~: 0 ()
Q 0 r~,
-~ ~ C/)
0) ~ ~ C/)
~ )Q OQ~ >
0
< -u o
C,) -- -- (flC,) ~ C
C0~-J~ )D 0 m
ON)' ON)0)~0N)
F -
Cu~C~00Ui~ 0 O(icu~0o0)C)o)o.~- ~U) :u D
- N) C,) C,) ~ U) -C) ~ -l
C.)
+1+
+ ,,``,,,`,`,,,`,,,,,(,,,,```` 100+0 -
~O(0C,)
N) ~ ON) U) ~ N) 0
PAGENO="0388"
3824
TABLE AND ART GLASSWARE: U.S. IMPORTS FOR CONSUMPTION, BY KIND, FOR JANUARY-MARCH 1967, AND
1968
[Quantity in number; foreign value in U.S. dollars]
1968
January-March
Quantity Value
Articles chiefly used for preparing, serving or storing
food or beverages; smokers' articles, art and orva-
mental:
Valued not over $1 each
Valued over $1, not over $3 each
Valued over $3 each
Glassware (Venetian type) valued not over $1 each:
Smokers' articles
Other
Valued over $1 each
Bubble glassware
Glassware pressed and toughened
Other glassware, smokers' articles:
Valued not over $1 each
Valued over $1, not over $3
Valued over $3 each:
Cut or engraved
Other
Perfume bottles fitted with ground glass stoppers:
Valued not over $1 each
Valued over $1, not over $3 each
Valued over $3 each:
Cut or engraved
Other
Other:
Valued not over 30 cents each 10, 020,892 2, 078,975
Valued over 30 cents, not over $1
Valued over $1, not over $3 each (1)
Valued over $3 each:
Cut or engraved
Other
1 Formerly No. 546.5300
2 Formerly No. 546.5500
3 Formerly No. 546.5700:
Total 15, 001, 889 5,969,472 15, 188, 303 6,251,919
Source: U.S. Department of Commerce official statistics prepared in Consumer Durables Division, May 1968.
STATEMENT OF HARRY W. BAUGUMAN, JR., NATIONAL PRESIDENT, WINDow GLASS
CUTTERS LEAGUE OF AMERICA
TSUSA
No. Description
1967
January-March
Quantity Value
546.11
546.13
546. 17
546.21
546.23
546.25
546.35
546.38
546.40
546.42
546.43
546. 44
546.46
546.48
546.49
546.50
546.52
546.54
546.56
546. 58
546.59
138,058 60,034 295,049 146,153
283,219 515,833 420,753 750,329
86, 067 479, 057 92,978 529, 690
58, 443 25, 345 36, 244 17,982
13,945 7,205 42,510 10,297
59, 689 95, 266 99, 390 147, 060
2,594,918 815,973 2,505,107 908,914
435, 969 47, 842 465, 382 59,700
411,825 136,381 578,022 146,416
(1) 32, 899 52,674
(2) 1,848 7,678
(3) 2,785 12,107
72, 887 22, 138 52,692 18,426
(1) 10,384 15,281
(2) 1,102 4,800
(3) 353 2,079
8, 145, 816 1, 079, 129
1,682,574 883,105
624,750 926,781
(2) 57,671 293,177
(3) 39,994 240,141
706, 595 1, 040, 168
83, 426 425,679
35,956 219, 576
Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee, My name is Harry W. Baugh-
man, Jr. I am National President of the Window Glass Cutters League of America,
a labor organization representing approximately 750 members employed in the
manufacturing of window glass. Our Union consists of twelve (12) locals
located in West Virginia, Pennsylvania, Ohio, Indiana, Arkansas, Oklahoma and
Louisiana. We have been chartered in the AFL-CIO since 1928 as:
The Window Glass Cutters League of America
1078 South High Street
Columbus, Ohio 43206
In this Hearing we are direcbly concerned with the manufacturing of window
glass or sheet glass, whichever you prefer. We strongly oppose the present low
tariff rates which allow the foreign producers the world over to further pene-
trate the already crippled industry.
We respectfully submit our reasons for strongly supporting the Herlong "Fair
International Trade" bill, H. R. 16936.
EFFECT ON APPALACHIA
Six of our twelve existing locals are located in the heart of Appalachia. Four
in West Virginia and two in western Pennsylvania. One local located in Arnold,
Pennsylvania, has been completely shut down since December, 1967 with no.
indication that it will ever be re-opened. This resulted in the loss of employment
PAGENO="0389"
3825
for 90 of our members. Since `the average age of our. members is 46.10 years,
you can readily see the almost impossible task of securing other employment.
The other five locals located within Appalachia are experiencing drastic loss of
wages caused by curtailed production brought on by the closing of melting fur-
naces. The locals where the existing facilities are in operation (three of the six
locals in Appalachia) have embarked on an almost complete stocking program
both in finished and unfinished ware because of non-existing customer orders.
Prior to 1960 the six aforementioned locals made up approximately 750, or
one-half of our then 1500 total membership. True, automation contributed par-
tially to these declining numbers. Presently there are approximately 450 mem-
bers that make up the six Appalachia locals. These remaining 450 members are
for the most part working on a curtailed or pro-rata basis as per negotiated
contract obligations. As late as May 7 I have reliable information that even
further cubacks in production is a reality within the six locals. The further
cutbacks as predicted in the already recognized depressed region can only worsen
the plight of workers and their families in Appalachia.
THE EFFECT OF FOREIGN IMPORTS IN OTHER AREAS
The May 20th issue of the Wall Street Journal reported that housing starts
for the month of April, 1968 reached a four year high. If this is a true statement,
and we have to assume it is, one would also assume that employment within the
window glass industry would also be at a higher level than it was four years
ago. However, this is not the case. Two window glass factories previously
referred to, one located in Okmulgee, Oklahoma and the other located in Shreve-
port, Louisiana, started drastic cutbacks in production during the month of
April. Despite housing starts at a four year high, not one of our laid off members
has been recalled, nor has any of the already idle facilities been started back into
production. One factory, located at Henryetta, Oklahoma, has been operating
at a 50% of capacity since March, 1967. At this plant alone, 36 of a total member-
ship of 96 were laid off 15 months ago. Those remaining 60 members have been
working at drastically reduced hours and wages for 15 months.
The over-all window glass industry is at the present time operating at only
57% of capacity. On May 7, 1968, Mr. Robert Wingerter, President of Libbey-
Owens-Ford Glass Company, stated to Special Representatives of the President
that his company facilities must operate at a minimum of 60% of capacity before
they could even hope to reach a break even point. The same should hold true
with all companies within the industry. By the same token, it is easily recognized
why employees also must work above a 57% of capacity so they, too, can reach
a break even point
During the month of April, I made an extended trip to the southwestern region
to visit with four locals located in that area. I had the opportunity to speak
with members of the Building and Construction Trades while in Oklahoma. As you
no doubt know, building and construction in the Southwest is also at an all time
high, particularly in Texas. In a three state area surrounding Texas, namely
Arkansas, Oklahoma and Louisiana, there are four window glass plants. Despite
this fact, members of the Building and Construction Trades stated to me that
almost without exception all window glass being used in these enormous projects
is of a foreign origin. Even with freight and shipping rates at a minimum in
such a confined area, the foreign producers have, as they have in the past,
demonstrated their ability to penetrate the United States market. Are we to
continue the exportation of our jobs to low wage foreign countries on such a
ridiculous basis? I don't believe so.
EFFECT ON EMPLOYMENT
In early 1960 our total membership was 1,500 members. At the present time
our membership is just half that figure-750 members. As of May 24, 1968, 212
employees, or a little above 25% of our membership, was on lay-off status. It
seems iromc that the ratio of imports to consumption is also 25%. At the Charles-
ton, West Virginia local, 39 of our members have been on lay-off status for eight
years without any hope of ever being recalled. This again amounted to approxi-
mately 25% of the local membership.
We become alarmed when we realize the number of employees being lost
through attrition. Prior to 1960 it was normal procedure to hire new employees
or replace those employees lost through death or retirements. Under normal
operating conditions this must be done to maintain a status quo, regardless of
PAGENO="0390"
3826
the product being manufactured. At the Charleston, West Virginia plant alone,
30 employees retired and 5 have died for a total of 35 employees lost through
attrition. The same would hold true on a comparable basis for all 12 locals. In the
two window glass plants of Libby-Owens-Ford, at Charleston, West Virginia,
and Shreveport, Louisiana, the youngest seniority date is February 10, 1956.
At the present time Libbey-Owens-Ford Glass Company has 162 employees
represented by the Window Glass Cutters League of America, employed in their
two platas. This figure, prior to 1960, was approximately 360 employees. If it
were not because of contractual obligations, the remaining 162 employees would
be reduced to less than 100.
Company officials have stated to me on numerous occasions that they would
invest enormous amounts of capital to modernize their existing facilities and
place back into operation their idle furnaces if there was any indication they
would be able to share in the growing window glass market in the United
States. However, with the present tariff structure and non-existing import
ceilings, they are not willing to make such investments.
I respectfully submit on behalf of the employees in the window glass industry
represented by the Window Glass Cutters League of America, that our employ-
ment within the already crippled industry be given great consideration and that
you will give full support to the Herlong "Fair International Trade" bill, HR.
16936.
Thank you for this opportunity to present our position.
STATEMENT OF HUBERTA M. PATTERSON, SECIuCTARY, WEsT VIRGINIA LEAGUE, IN
BEHALr OF WEST VIRGINIA, PENNSYLVANIA, OHIO, AND INDIANA GI~ASs WORKERS'
PROTECTIVE LEAGUES
The Glass Workers' Protective Leagues whose members are affiliated with the
American Flint Glass Workers Union, have over the years suffered severe
setbacks due to ever increasing imports of all types of glass.
While some people argue that the production of glass may not be as important
a segment of the national economy as some more basic industries, the great
variety of glass products and its multiplicity of uses give it a most important place
In our economy.
Lets look more closely at the relationship between protective tariffs and the
American glassware industry in general, but particularly the band-blown seg-
ment, offers a good example of the problems arising from increasing imports
into the United States. The burden of this importation falls heavily on the
workers and owners of `the American glass ware industry. As recently as 19643,
about 2 out of every 5 workers who produced tableware or artware or industrial
glass specialties or lighting fixtures was laid off his regular job.
It is important to consider not just the lost jobs, but the impact of this
unemployment on local communities. Since 1950 some fifteen (15) hand glass
plants have closed, plants which in the late 1940's provided more than 2,500
jobs. Most of these companies and the ones in production today are located in
communities of less than 25,000 population.
In areas of chronic unemployment where each lay-off compounds an already
great problem, these glass companies are usually the dominent and in many
cases the only manufacturing firms in the towns. The key factor in the failure of
glass plants was not poor management and inefficiency. Low wage foreign iniports
were. It has been said that the automatic machine segment of the industry
is the important factor in the closing of hand-made glass plants. Statistics show
that is not the main factor, for low wage imports are causing great concern to
the automatic machine plants as well.
The average hourly rate paid to skilled glassworkers in this Country today is
$3.93 per hour including fringe benefits. The rate for the supporting industrial
help in the glass industry is $2.82 per hour including fringe benefits. Approxi-
mately sixty (60) to seventy (70) percent of every cost dollar goes to labor.
If the hand-made glass industry in America is forced out of business due to
imports, there would be a loss of skilled workers who played such an important
role in producing wares for the national defense in past wars and other national
emergencies.
We hope that there is no misunderstanding of our position. The American
glassworker is aware of the necessity of maintaining trade with foreign coun-
tries. We are not asking for tariff barriers in order to eliminate competition.
PAGENO="0391"
3827
We want to see that our manufacturers are given the opportunity to sell the glass,
made by us, the American glassworker, receiving American labor wages, the
same a.s given foreign manufacturers, who pay such low wages.
We respectfully urge the Ways and Means Committee to give every considera-
tion to legislation that will preserve the glass industry, the first industry in
America.
STATEMENT OF CLINTON M. HESTER, ArPORNEY, ON BEHALF OF Cooas
PORCELAIN COMPANY
Coons PORCELAIN COMPANY, GOLDEN, COLORADO
CHEMICAL PORCELAIN
It is esthnated that 40% of Coors chemical porcelain production goes to edu-
cational institutions, 15% into Government laboratories and the remaining 45%
to industrial laboratories. In all perhaps 10%, or approximately $130,000 at Coors
sales value, is used directly for National Defense.
In the atomic energy field it is used in a great deal of analytical chemistry
including the preparation and analysis of special nuclear metals. A list of AEC
users includes:
Dow Ohemical Company, Rocky Flats, Colorado
Oak Ridge National Laboratories
Savannah River Laboratories
Hanford
Los Alamos
Sandia Oorporation
Argonne National Laboratories
Lawrence Radiation Laboratories
Brookhaven Laboratories
In the area of missiles and munitions it is used at the following places in ad-
dition to many not listed:
Redstone Arsenal
Water Arsenal
NASA Langley Research Center
Wright Patterson Air Force Base
Vandenberg Air Force Base
Naval Ordnance Laboratory
Air Force Missile Test Center, Patrick Air Force Base
Other Government laboratories include:
National Institutes of Health
National Center for Atmospheric Research
U.S. Navy, Army and Air Force Medical Services
Veterans Administration Hospitals
Bureau of Standards
Federal Bureau of Investigation Laboratories
U.S. Food and Drug Administration Laboratories
Bureau of Mines
U.S. Geological Survey
Department of Agriculture Laboratories
National Cancer Institute
Use of chemical porcelain in teaching of science
Under Title 3 of the National Defense Education Act a document was pre-
pared by the Board of Directors of the Council of Chief State School Officers en-
titled "Purchase Guide for Programs in Science, Mathmetics and Modern
Languages", Ginn .& Company, 1959 Rev. This Guide is for use in the purchase
of economical, modern and necessary apparatus and equipment for elementary
and secondary schools. Laboratory porcelain items are listed as basic items in:
Basic, Standard and Advanced Biology; Basic, Standard and Advanced Chem-
istry; Standard and Advanced Elementary Science; Basic and Standard General
Science; and Basic and Standard Physics.
The National Science Teachers Association of Washington, D.C. in 1947 pub-
lished a volume entitled "Science Course Content and Teaching Apparatus Used
in Schools and Colleges of the United States." This book was prepared at the re-
quest of the Department of State in 1946 particularly for the use of Ministers of
PAGENO="0392"
3828
Education of the devastated countries of the United Nations. In this listing,
chemical porcelain (specifically Coors) is specified for courses in Elementary
School Science; Secondary School Chemistry; College Botany; General Chemis-
try; Organic Chemistry; Qualitative Analysis; Quantitative Analysis; Physical
Chemistry; Biochemistry; General. Geology; Mineralogy; College Physics; and
College Zoology.
What is chemical porcelain?
Chemical porcelain is a ceramic product similar in appearance to chinaware
but of much higher quality. It is dead white impervious material, covered over
most of its surface with a hard white glaze. It is composed, formed and fired to
produce maximum resistance to the attack of many chemicals. These properties
are vital to the stringent use it receives and the rigorous treatment to which it
is subjected in the great variety of uses constantly performed in control and re-
search laboratories. As a product, chemical porcelain is highly specialized and
well known only to chemists and scientists who use it in all industrial and edu-
cational laboratories, hospitals and governmental laboratories of all kinds. There
is certainly not a laboratory in the United States which does not in some way use
Coors chemical and scientific porcelain ware. The photographs on the next pages
illustrate the type and wide variety of products which are included in this line.
In many essential control and research analyses there is no known substitute for
chemical porcelain and the work which uses this product could not be carried out
if these items were not available.
Chemical porcelain as it is made today is strictly utilitarian in design. These
designs are standard throughout the world, having originally been developed in
Germany before the time that Coors Porcelain Company started this business in
1915. Although a number of items have been added to the line, there have been
no basic changes in design of the fundamental items and actually there is a
strong resistance on the part of the chemists to any design changes that are
proposed.
Position of Coors in industry
Coors Porcelain Company is the only manufacturer of chemical porcelain in
the Western Hemisphere. This situation does not exist because of any patents
or restriccive agreemenls of any kind. This field is certainly open to anybody
who desires to get into it. The fact that Coors is the only manufacturer results
PAGENO="0393"
3829
CHEMICAL
PORCELAIN
COORS
U.S.A.
from the complexity of the line, the requirements for extremely high quality,
and the relatively limited sales volume. It evidently has not appeared to others
to be an attractive enough business to justify their making the necessary invest-
ment to get into it.
Location of Coors
The only factory of the Coors Porcelain Company is located in the city of
Golden, Colorado, which has an estimated population of 8,000. This company
along with its parent company, the Adolph Coors Company, manufacturer of
PAGENO="0394"
3830
beer, constitute the major industries in this locality. Golden is located twelve
miles due west of Denver.
Foreign m~anufacturers
There are a number of manufacturers of chemical porcelain throughout the
rest of the world. Those which have been indicated to us to be of the best quality
are Haldenwanger and Royal Berlin, both from Germany. Rosenthal in Germany
also produces this type of product as does a Czechoslovakian firm with whose
name we are not familiar; Weta in Holland; and several in England, includ-
ing K. L. G., Limited and Royal Worcester. There is also a Japanese firm known
to us as SPC, which has entered the field during the past five years, who offer
chemical porcelain but not of the highest quality at the present time. Except for
the mention of the Czechoslovakian product, we know nothing of the activities
in this area behind the Iron Curtain. At the present time, the sale of Coors porce-
lain are limited to the United States, Canada and Mexico with other manufac-
turers covering the remainder of the world. This situation exists because of price
and competitive situations which will be discussed later.
Distribntion
Our method of distribution of chemical porcelain is entirely through dealers.
These dealers are laboratory supply houses who carry a general line of scientific
apparatus which is required in research and control laboratories. They have
distribudon in all of the United States, plus Puerto Rico, Canada and Mexico.
These dealers actually have main offices or branches in 36 of the United States
plus the District of Columbia and Puerto Rico. A number of companies have
their own branches in Canada and we have one strictly Canadian owned dealer.
These dealers have our porcelain listed in their general catalogs and sell through
the use of these catalogs plus direct sales forces. A list of these dealers is attached
to this brief as Exhibit A.
~S'ales volume trends
The volume of sales of chemical porcelain by Coors Porcelain Company was
$1,600,000 in 1967. This was the net value to Coors and accordingly, with our
discount to dealers averaging approximately 47% of the list price, the sales
volume of our dealers was approximately $3,000,000. The total number of pieces
sold during 1967 was 2,557,000 and this is an increase of only 38% over the aver-
age number of 1,850,000 pieces sold during the period of 1940 to 1949. Although
there has been a gradual and continual growth in volume since the concept of
its manufacture in 1916, the actual usage has not increased anywhere nearly
as fast as the growth of scientific endeavor in this country. Over the past twenty
to thirty years there have been a number of competitive items of other materials
which have tended to displace the use of chemical porcelain. Some of these are
glassware which was particularly damaging with the advent of Pyrex; plastics
such as polyethylene; and some of the better stainless steels which have been
introduced and which are capable of replacing porcelain in some of its less
severe applications. There has also been the growth of the electronic analytical
equipment which has changed the methods in many laboratories over the past
fifteen years particularly and has antiquated some of the older techniques
which employed chemical porcelain. Since the unit costs of chemical porcelain
are necessarily rather high compared to materials such as glass and plastics,
and since the costs of chemists and chemical technicials are ever increasing,
it certanly can be concluded that there will be continual inroads into the usage
of chemical porelain from these other areas, and particularly from the more
modern automated electronic analytical devices.
Prieing trends
On the following page is a chart showing the prices which have been charged
for chemical porcelain by Coors Porcelain Company from the year 1916 through
1963. Although the actual prices for this product have increased significantly
since 1946, the real prices have only gone up 20% in 53 years of operation.
These real prices are the actual prices adjusted for the increase in the cost of
living as provided by the Consumer Price Index of the U.S. Bureau of Labor
Statistics. There has been practically no real price increase during the past
fifteen years. This performance has been possible because of technological im-
provements in methods of manufacture, but also has been forced to a certain
extent by the continual threat of foreign competition at lower prices.
PAGENO="0395"
PERCENT .
----- r~, ~ tx)- r~) r~, (~J
rs, .~ c~ ~ 0 r~) .~ o~ w o ~ ~ C) W 0
1916 . * ~ : :0~ 0 °.~: :0 ~ 0 , 0 ~ ~ 0 0* , 0 ~ 0 * 0 0 , 1c~ :
918
-- -I- ~2~° I- ~_ _ -
920 ~
~ ~
- . ,. . ~.I,
1922 . . . ~ ~ ... . ...
:: ~ ~:~*". ~ .
- - rT~mv) - -
.:: ;or?~
924 I ~ ~ . . . : ~ . * . ..~. ~ . . .
. .... :: . . *--1 ~ .: ,.*. ..-,
--- --,. (I) ~;...~:::: :-*~-----=-~
926
~ ~
928 ~
--- -
... ...~. . . .. ~ , ~ .. .:
I .~`j~*~1 . . --~, i.....: ,:
- ~:o - - - (~)O
932 ~
: j ~ :: ..: :~. :: . :~ ~ S... *:-~-- ; ~ : . :: ~ ~ ri-i ~
1934 ~ .. . . . .
..l ~ !. ~
. ... .
93E or-
0
93E
- -
940 ~t7S»=rri
-I~I ~
1942 ..~ ~ . .. .
....
I94~ ~ .
~ Jo
194E ~ . ~ .. . . . . .
- - - I
948
__f -- --
1950 ~ ~
I---r--~-~ ~ . ..:.~ . .._ -.-~
J952_~c* t~- ~ -~
~2 - --- c~ -- ~c1 --
. z ~ ~. . . . . Z~cz ...... ... .
I954-czc~ ~. ... .: I ..~. . ~~r- . . . ,
I c: . . ... I.
~r~' ~ ~ . ~
I956i--~~.: Iltil!):!
H.C(J) ~ ,. ;~-nI_ ~
1958'-~~ H*; ~ .~*-:T:I~L. ~ ii ~ ~
-;~ ~1~c)
:~___
T888
PAGENO="0396"
3832
Employment
The total number of employees at Coors Porcelain Company as of December
31, 1967, was 1,316. Of these, 105 are directly connected with the daily operations
of the chemiCal porcelain plant and a num'ber of others are indirectly involved
through staff functions. Many of these people have been working on chemical
porcelain for more than 25 years and they know no other skills. Their jobs
would be seriously endangered by any reduction in the protective tariff of
chemical porcelain.
Variety of product
Counting all of the shapes and sizes, there are 459 separate items of chemidal
porcelain in our catalog. In addition to those items which are listed in the
catalog and therefore stocked for immediate delivery, about 300 custom made
`specialties are also made. Some sixty to seventy of these are made for U.S.
Government agencies.
A listing of the total numbers of these 459 catalog items which were sold in
1967 is shown in Appendix B. it is of value to note the small numhers that
are said of many of the items. There were less than 10 pieces sold during the
year of eleven different items. The largest quantity was for a small crucible, our
Number 23005, which sold 265,736. A listing is given below of the number of
various items which were sold and the quantity breakdowns:
Number of items: Number of pieces of each item sold
12 0 to 9.
47 10 to 49.
45 50 to 99.
132 100 to 499.
40 500 to 999.
141 1,000 to 9,999.
36 10,000 to 99,999.
6 100,000 or more.
Consideration of mechanization aind automation
Because of the low volume of a large number of items which are produced,
automation is impractical in most cases. A great deal of development effort has
been spent in the past 22 years since World War II to mechanize as many of
the production lines as possible. New equipment ha's been installed and new
techniques tested out and put into use where feasible. Also, a tremendous
amount of improvement has been made in the area of efficiency as measured by
the percentage of losses of the various items which are made.
Losses which ranged from 30% to 50% fifteen years ago have been reduced
to the area of less thou 10% and in many cases only 3% to `5%. Because of this
situation there is very little room left for improvement in either the methods or
the efficiencies of operations although considerable effort is still being expended
in this direction.
For the above reasons there remains a great deal of hand labor involved in the
manufacture of chemical porcelain. Approximately 27% of our cost of manu-
facture is in direct labor and another 26% is involved in indirect payroll. In
other words, a total of 53% of all costs is paid out in wages. For this reason,
it is quite apparent that comparative wage rates with manufacturers in foreign
lands are of extreme importance in the analysi's of the competitive picture.
This factor will be dealt with in more detail later.
During the past several years our developmental work has produced a new
line of high purity alumina ceramic laboratory ware. This is a new laboratory
advuncement but is not a substitute `for chemical porcelain-it is rather a sup~
plement for a number of sepcialty uses. The ~colume of this line is still rather
small in comparison with the standard chemical porcelain.
Other Coors products
In addition to the manufacture of `chemical porcelain, the Coors Porcelain
Company is in the `business of making and selling a good num'ber of other prod-
ucts. The largest volume is alumina ceramics for electrical and electronic in-
dustries as `we'll as for many mechanical application's. Beryllia ceramics are
also produced, as are pyrometer and combustion tubes, grinding media and
brick linings for ball mill grinders, and other wear resist'ant products, ceramic
coatings, metal-to-ceramic assemblies, nuclear fuel elements and aluminum metal
PAGENO="0397"
3833
cans and lids. Our total volume of sales during 1967 was approximately $15,-
000,000 and accordingly, the chemical porcelain is slightly more than 10%.
This figure compares to our situation in 1946 just after the end of World War
II when our business was 90% in chemical porcelain.
Through extensive research and development efforts and the plowing back of
earnings into the business, new items have been added from time to time so that
even with its continual, slow growth, the percentage of chemical porcelain has
steadily declined over the years.
Profitability
Throughout this period of growth, however, the chemical porcelain phase of
the business has remained profitable and returns approximately 9% of its own
sales volume. Because of the continuing introduction of new products, the profit-
ability of the company as a whole has not been this good and although it varies
rather widely from year to year because of the developmental nature of some
of the projects which are undertaken, the average for the last ten years has been
less than 3% after taxes on over-all ~aleLs. This picture would certainly not allow
for any reductions in prices of chemical porcelain to meet foreign competition
in the case that protective tariffs were lowered.
Fiscal policies
The Coors Porcelain Company is a wholly-owned subsidiary of the Adolph
Coors Company, also of Golden, Colorado. The latter is a family owned and con-
trolled corporation which has met the cash needs of its stockholders and its own
expansion program from its own operation. Accordingly, it has not been the prac-
tice of the Coors Porcelain Company to declare dividends and none has been
declared during the past twenty years. Any earnings that have been made are put
back into the business in the way of expansion of facilities and research and
development effort. Our research and development expenditures are undoubtedly
as high or higher than any comparable type of operation, running at the present
time at a rate of almost $800,000 per year. This effort is aimed both at improving
the operations which we have at the present tme, including those of chemical
porcelain, as well as in finding new products and new processes which will be
of long range advantage to this company.
History
The Coors Porcelain Company was given its real start in life at the beginning
of World War I when the Allied blockade of Germany stopped the importation
into the United States of chemical porcelain along with all other kinds of scien-
tific apparatus. This occurred in 1915 and up until that time, all of the chemical
porcelain used in this country was imported from Germany. This importation
was stopped so completely that work in all chemical laboratories, governmental,
educational and industrial, was disastrously affected. The situation was so
serious that the United States Government made an appeal to any factories pro-
ducing chinaware at that time to undertake the manufacture of chemical porce-
lain. This company, along with approximately twenty-six others, started small
scale operations to attempt to learn how to produce these items. Sticking to the
goals of the highest quality standards, Coors soon established itself as one of
the outstanding manufacturers of chemical porcelain in the world, and as men-
tioned above, is at the present time the only manufacturer left in the Western
Hemisphere.
During the 1930's when German industry was again on the rise and imports
started to flow back into this country, it was only possible for this company to
survive as the result of the high protective tariffs. If they had not beeii in
existence at that time, the Coors Porcelain Company would undoubtedly have
been forced out of the manufacture of chemical porcelain and the United States
would have again been left at the beginning of World War II with no supply
of this valuable scientific product. The threat of imports is again becoming more
and more present as we see manufacturers in both Europe and Japan concen-
trating on this line of endeavor. Again tariffs will play an extremely important
part in keeping this operation alive to maintain a continuing supply of chemical
porcelain to the scientists of this country in case of some international conflict
in the future. In view of the previous two major wars and the world conditions
today, it would be difficult for any of us to assume with any degree of reality that
such a conflict could not possibly occur.
95-159 O-68--pt. 8-26
PAGENO="0398"
3834
Foreign sales
The sales of chemical porcelain to foreign countries direct from Coors Porcelain
Company were $126,000 in 1007, or slightly less than 8% of the total. In addi-
tion to this, it is estimated that our dealers sold approximately $70,000 to
foreign consumers directly. Of this amount, some 86% went into Canada and only
about $9,600 or some 14% of this total to Mexico. It is not possible for us to get
completely accurate figures from all of our dealers as to their shipments direct
to consumers in Canada and Mexico. Although the amount of Coors chemical
porcelain shipped into Canada is probably a fairly large percentage of their total
usage, the reason for our success in being able to penetrate this market despite
adverse foreign price situations is that all but one of the Canadian scientific
apparatus dealers are branches of U. S. owned companies. For this reason it is
more natural for them to purchase this type of item from the United States and
in many cases the purchasing arrangements are actually handled through offices
in the United States. The Canadian duty is 22% on the majority of chemical
porcelain items. The Mexican duties range from 12.7% to 41.6%, depending on
the nature of the item.
Competitive price picture
In order to evaluate the effect of tariffs on the marketing of chemical porce-
lain, it is important to look at the competitive price situation. The table which is
attached as Appendix C shows the prices of several German products a~ well as
the Japanese products and those of Coors Porcelain Company before the duty
was reduced from 60% to 54%. These figures indicate quite clearly that in some
of the more popular items, such as crucibles and evaporating dishes, which in
many cases were the only ones where foreign prices were available to us, the
Coors list price is often double that of the list price of the imports. The column
showing Labco is for Japanese ware delivered in the U.S. and duty paid. These
are the list prices for which this product is offered to the ultimate consumer and
compare with Coors list price. Even with the present 54% tariff, this material
is available at a price ranging from 25% to 40% less than ours. The only rea-
son that this has not made inroads into our business is that the ware is of
relatively poor quality and also is not supplied in all of the items which are re-
quired. It is this kind of pricing, however, which is made available by reduction
of our tariff to 30% and if used with the type of quality which is. available from
one or two of the top European producers, would provide such serious competi-
tion that it would be difficult to maintain our position as a supplier in this field.
Comparative wage rates
As mentioned previously, approximately 50% of the cost of our product comes
either from direct or indirect labor. For this reason then, it is also important to
compare competitive labor rates. The latest rates which we have for foreign coun-
tries are for the year 1961 and were compiled by the Business and Defense Serv-
ices Administration of the Department of Commerce. These `show that the average
wage rate in the pottery industry is 35~ per hour in Japan, 61~ per hour in West
Germany, and 480 per hour for women and 97~ per hour for men in the United
Kingdom. In our manufacture of chemical porcelain, approximately 75% of the
jobs are carried out by female operators and the remainder by male operators.
The average for these classifications in the jobs involved at the Coors Porcelain
Company is $1.93 for female operators and $2.51 for male operators at the pres-
ent time. In the case of Coors figures, fringe benefits which average in the neigh-
borhood of 50ç~ per hour are not included and it is presumed that fringe bene-
fits are not included in the figures for the `foreign countries either. In any case,
assuming a 10% increase per year in these foreign countries, it can easily be
seen that the average wage rates at Coors are two and one-half to three times
higher than those* in Europe and as much as five times higher than those in
Japan. Although wage rates are rising faster in these countries than they are
in the United States at the present time, the disparity is still a vast one and
cannot be compensated for to any large extent by productivity. Until wage rates
and the corresponding costs of living tend to equalize in the various countries of
the world, it will not be possible to manufacture high labor cost items such as
chemical porcelain in this country on a competitive basis with these foreign coun-
tries Protective tariffs are therefore absolutely necessary if this industiv is
gofng~to be preserved in the near future.
PAGENO="0399"
3835
Problems in foreign competition
To help substantiate the problems of competing with foreign products with
the extreme price differential, we are attaching as Exhibit D a letter from
a dealer in Holland and as Exhibit E a letter from a scientific ap-
paratus dealer in England. The significant factors in the letter from Holland are:
"We know from experience that your quality is the best of all to be obtained in
the world since at the end of the war we have sold your porcelain-but later
on we have been compelled to drop your porcelain as soon as the German factcries
were getting again at the market, supplying satisfactory qualities and much
cheaper than yours." The significant part of the English letter is: "We feel sure
you will appreciate that this makes the position of marketing your lines, partic-
ularly with regard to import duties, etc., extremely uncompetitive." In other
words, it has proven completely impossible to `sell in European markets even with
what is considered by many to be a superior product, with the wide disparity of
prices. This same situation would occur in the United States if the tariffs were
to be dropped to the point that the same competitive disadvantage existed for our
product.
Foreign imports
The large increase in imports under tariff item 535 2100 of 1965-66 indicates
that more serious inroads into the domestic market can be expected. Rising costs
in both labor and materials make competition even more difficult.
Vital to national defense
Although no mention has previously been made of this fact, chemical porcelain
plays an extremely important part in our over-all defense effort. This informa-
tion has been established so thoroughly over the past years that in the U.S. Tariff
Commission's "Summaries of Tariff Information", Volume II, Part 1, Para-
graph 212, Page 178, last published in 1948, the statement is made "Chemical
porcelain is vital in national defense."
In this same respect, there is attached as Exhibit F, copies of a letter from the
late Senator Eugene Millikeri of Colorado addressed to the Chairman of the
Interdepartmental Committee on Trade Agreements of the Department of State.
This letter was written in 1950 and states "I am utterly astonished that chemical
porcelain, which is widely recognized as absolutely essential to national defense
and which is produced by only one eompany in the United States, would be placed
on this list." He was referring at that time to the list of commodities on which
the United States was considering negotiating tariff reductions.
Effect of tariff reduction
There is little question that if the protective tariff against `the importation of
chemical porcelain were to be removed, this segment of our business at Coors
Porcelain `Company would be destroyed. Of great concern if this were to happen
is that the entire Western Hemisphere would be left without a single supplier
of chemical porcelain. This was distastrous to our budding young chemical in~
dustry in World War I. It certainly would have been disastrous to our entire
war effort if it had happened in World War II, and there is surely no one who
can claim that it would not be disastrous to the research and development effort
required if this country were to again face a worid conflict.
It was pointed out above that chemical porcelain of somewhat inferior quality
is already available in this country at more than 25% below Coors prices. We
have been able to retain our present market only because our consistent quality,
ready availability and progressive attitude have convinced the searching scien-
tists that the use `of this material would cost him more in unreliable results and
costly delays than he would gain by the price advantage. This would certainly
not be true if the quality differential did not exist or if the price `advantage was
such that it could be compensated for. It is quite certain that such a condition
would exist if the existing tariffs on chemical porcelain were cut in half.
In view `of all that has been presented above, it must certainly be conctuded
that it would be td the disadvantage of the United States to reduce the tariff on
chemical porcelain in such a way that it would destroy an industry which is vital
to all the chemical and physical laboratories of this country. Accordingly, we
strongly urge that there be no further reduction in the tariffs on chemical per-
celain, but on the contrary that import quotas be imposed or tariffs be increased
on chemical porcelain.
PAGENO="0400"
3836
This supplemental statement is submitt~d for the purpose of providing informa-
tion regarding the oon~petitive conditions in Canada and Mexico affecting the
Coors Porcelain Company.
CANADA
Laboratory porcelain is imported into Canada under two Canadian classifica-
tions. The first is Item No. 288A. which illcludes "chemical porcelain specially
compounded to resist acids." This class comprises laboratory chemical porcelain
as manufactured by the Coors Porcelain Company as well as chemical stoneware
used for laboratory sinks, chemical processing equipment, furnace combustion
tubes, jar mills for grinding and some other miscellaneous ceramic products.
Some of these items are supplied by a number of firms in the United States.
Canadian customs Item No. 300 encompasses "crucibles and covers" and in-
cludes laboratory chemical porcelain crucibles and covers and in addition, cm-
cibles and covers of refractory ceramics, assay crucibles of fire clay and miscel-
laneous ceramic compositions
The duty rate under Item 228A is 171/2% ad vaiorem to most favored nations,
United Kingdom free. Educational institutions and government agencies import
duty-free.
The duty rate under Item 300 is 15% ad valorem to most favored nations,
United Kingdom free. Educational institutions and government agencies import
duty-free.
It is customary to add about 5% to the price to the consumer in addition to the
duty to cover brokers costs on items imported from the United States.
The Canadian market for laboratory equipment is less than 10% of the United
States market. There are considerably fewer laboratories and relatively little
chemical industry.
At this time one Canadian laboratory supply dealer (The Johns Company) is
offering English laboratory porcelain (Royal Worcester). This dealer is not a
large company and does not handle Coors Canadian imports from England under
Item 288A and 300 amount about 8% of the imports from the United States
under the same custom items.
There are several reasons why Coors has successfully competed in Canada
against English porcelain available at a lower figure:
1. Coors has been able to supply the Canadian market without interruption
since 1917. Canadians have become accustomed to our product.
2. Prompt delivery is offered through ample stocks in Canada.
3. Of six major supply houses in Canada, five of which handle Coors, four
are American-owned. Three of these do over 70% of the volume in laboratory
porcelain and all are American-owned. One Canadian-owned company sells
Coors and one sells English porcelain.
4. The large laboratory dealer catalog, listing 12,000 to 18,000 laboratory
items, is a major selling tool in the United States and Canada. Five of these
catalogs list Coors and one lists Worcester (English). Several of the dealers
use the same catalog in both the United States and Canada.
5. Coors porcelain has been advertised in Canadian magazines and has been
exhibited at numerous trade shows in Canada.
6. Much of the Canadian market is in laboratories of American-owned
companies and many of the technicians have been trained in laboratories in
the United States or have been exposed to the U.S. product.
TABLE I
The following table shows the current comparison in consumer list prices in
Canada of. Royal Worcester and Coors porcelain. The items listed comprise a
typical assortment for a general laboratory. Twelve per cent has been added to
the English price for freight and five per cent for handling. Five per cent has been
added to the American price for handling.
PAGENO="0401"
3837
Coors catalog Description
No.
English
duty-free
price 1 laid
down
Canadian
Doty on Coors
porcelain
(percent)
Duty-free
Coors price2
plus 5 percent
plus 8 percent
Duty-paid
Coors price3
plus 5 percent
plus 8 percent
180 size 1 Casserole
180 size 2 do
180 size 3 do
180 size 5 do
230 size 0 Crucible
$0.75
1.25
1. 70
3. 81
.21
173/~
173/i
173/3
173/i
15
$1.71
1. 78
2. 01
6. 90
$1.93
2. 02
2. 27
7. 80
23Osizel do
.39
15
.49
23Osize2 do
53
15
.91
.80
240 size F Crucible cover
12
15
32
240 sizeG do
-
.12
15
.
. 36
24Osizel do
.19
15
.42
.32
270 size 3 Gooch crucible
66
15
1. 28
.45
430 size 005 Evaporating dish
430 size 2 do
.
- 43
70
173~
173/3
- 57
1. 07
1. 42
- 65
430 size 4A do
-
1. 15
173/~
1. 50
1.21
490 size 1 Buchner funnel
490 size 2A do
490 size 4 do
510 size 4/0 Hirsch funnel
522 size 2/0 Mortar and pestle
522 size 3 do
1.33
2. 95
3. 90
1. 07
1. 22
2. 71
173/i
173/3
173/3
173/3
173/~
173/i
3.00
6.40
12. 00
1.97
1. 58
3. 06
1.70
3.40
7. 22
13. 60
2.22
1. 79
3. 46
1 List price plus 12 percent for handling.
2 List price plus 5 percent for handling plus 8 percent for exchange.
3 List price plus 5 percent for handling plus 8 percent for exchange plus duty.
TABLE 11.-IMPORTS BY CANADA
(In UJ~. dollars)
Chemical porcelain specially compounded to resist acid
Tariff Item No. 288A-Import Statistical No. 7048:
From United States $208, 699
From United Kingdom 20,699
From West Germany 2,006
Total 231,421
Most favored nation rate-17%'%; United Kingdom-free
(Jrucibles and covers
Tariff Item No. 300-Import Statistical No. 7053:
From United States $117, 151
From Republic of South Africa 9,952
From United Kingdom 6,420
From India 2,010
Total 135, 653
Most favored nation rate-15%; United Kingdom-free
Source: U.S. Department of Commerce-American Republics Division
MEXICO
The market in Mexico for chemical porcelain and stoneware is quite limited.
The total dollar value of chemical porcelain and stoneware purchase in Mexico
during 1967 was not substantial, nor were exports of Coors porcelain to Mexico.
The tariff classifications into Mexico do not correspond with Canadian classifi-
PAGENO="0402"
3838
cations either in type of product or in method of assessing duty. Mexican customs
duties are based on three types of rates. For example: In many cases an official
price per gross or legal kilogram is set as a minimum duty per customs item
entered. This is expressed in Mexican pesos. Also a rate of centavos per kilogram
is set and the weight duty calculated according to the weight of items entered.
Whichever is higher (the official minimum or the duty by weight) is assessed,
plus a duty in percent based upon the ad valorem invoice value. To this is added
3% of the duty. The ad valorem rates vary from 8% to 40%.
Nearly all laboratory porcelain is imported under Tariff Item 880 which
includes scientific equipment of all kinds. This item is subdivided into various
paragraphs. The paragraphs of principal interest and the rates are listed below:
880:02:00 Miscellaneous manufactured article of faience or porcelain for
pharmacists, chemists and laboratories. Mortars.
Duty: Official Price 13.00 pesos (minimum or 0.05 pesos per gross kilo-
gram plus 25% ad valorem plus 3% of the duty.
880:02:03 Crucibles and capsules of faience and porcelain.
Duty: Official Price 15.00 pesos (minimum) or 0.02 pesos per gross kilo-
gram plus 8% ad valorem plus 3% of the duty.
880:02:07 Pill tiles of all types (glass, porcelain, etc.)
Duty: Official Price 72.00 pesos (minimum) or 0.05 pesos per kilogram
plus 25% ad valorem plus 3% of the duty.
880:02:13 Apparatus and utensils of faience or porcelain or in which such
materials predominate by weight and solely intended for use in
laboratories other than those failing within 880 :02 :00, :04, :05,
:06, :08, :09, :10, :11
Duty: No official price. 0.50 pesos per gross kilogram plus 35% ad valorem
plus 3% of the duty.
718:08:00 Refractory crucibles and muffles. (Note: This would include fire-
clay, refractory crucibles, possibly graphite and other ceramic
materials. Probably no porcelain entered under this item.)
Duty: Official Price 3.70 pesos minimum or 0.02 pesos per gross kilogram
plus 7% ad valorem plus 3% of the duty.
TABLE Ill-IMPORTS INTO MEXICO
Customs Country of origin Pounds Value in Duty rate Remarks (added by Coors)
item U.S. dollars
718:08:00 United States 154, 169 38, 723. 36 .02 pesos per gross kilogram Mainly clay fireclay, and
Belgium 14, 065 1,632. 48 +7 percent ad valorem refractories; probably no
United Kingdom 546 285. 60 (3.70 pesos minimum + porcelain included.
Republic of Germany_ 24,750 5,156.00 3 percent of duty.)
Total 193,530 45,797.44
880:02:00 United States 458 1, 831. 36 0.05 pesos per gross kilogram Note: Value per pound
Republic of Germany_ 6,409 2,482. 40 +25 percent ad valorem from the U.S. is $3.97
Japan 13 52. 80 +3 percent of the duty. but from Germany is
United Kingdom 2 . 80 (13.00 pesos minimum) $0387.
Total 6, 882 4,367. 36
880:02:03 United States 16, 025 22,456. 64 0.02 pesos per gross kilogram Probably as much as
United Kingdom 2, 259 2, 599. 28 +8 percent ad valorem possible is imported
Republic of Germany 7, 779 9, 389. 60 +3 percent of the duty. under this class because
(15.00 pesos minimum) of the low rate.
Total 26, 063 34, 445. 52
880:02:07 United States 94 338.96 0.05 pesos per gross kilogram Pill tiles of all sorts prob-
+25 percent ad valorem ably mainly glass or
+ 3 percent of the duty. plastic.
(72.00 pesos minimum)
880:02:13 United States 1,289 12, 507.60 0.50 pesos per gross kilogram
Bahamas 22 310. 32 +35 percent ad valorem
United Kingdom +3 percent of the duty.
Republic of Germany 754 3,809. 12
Switzerland 2 56.96
Total 2, 067 16,684. 00
Source: U. S. Department of Commerce-American Republics Division.
PAGENO="0403"
3839
The Mexican customs item descriptions are somewhat complicated and it
appears that the classifications may not be strictly adhered to. For example,
Class 880:02:00 is more inclusive thain 880 :02:03 but more has been imported
under 880 :02:03 in 1962, probably because the ad valorem rate is 8% rather than
25% under 880:02:00.
It is very interesting that the value per pound of product imported under
880:02 :00 from the United States is $3.97 but from Germany is $0.387. Under Item
880 :02:03 the value per pound from the United States is $1.40, United Kingdom
$1.16 and Germany $1.21. It appears that some clerical errors may have been
made and any conclusions should be made only after considerable study and
research. As a matter of interest, the value per pound varies widely. At Coors
net prices (list less dealer discount) 180 Size 1 casseroles are $8.50/pound; 230
Size 0 crucibles are $6.00/pound; while 522 Size 1 mortars and pestles are $0.50/
pound.
There is a relatively small amount of sophisticated industrial activity in
Mexico at this time but more is developing. At present the main customers would
be the universities, some high schools, the mining and smelting industry and the
petroleum industry.
Many of the technicians in Mexico have been trained in Europe. Germany has
been particularly active in selling many products to the Mexican market. Many
technical persons desiring to emigrate into the United States reside in Mexico
until they can enter the United States and thus are accustomed to German
products.
The table of comparative prices (Table IV) shows prices F.O.B. Mexican port
including freight and handling but not duty since it is not known what exact
duty would be applied nor the weight of the shipment. Since Coors and the
German porcelain would presumably be entered on an equal duty basis, the prices
are on a comparable basis.
TABLE IV.-PRICES IN MEXICO WITHOUT DUTY (TYPICAL ITEMS)
Coors list
plus 10 percent
Coors catalog No. Description freight and
handling
Haldenwanger
(German)
plus 20 percent
freight and
handling
l8Osizel Casserole $1.66 $0.49
180 size 2 do 1.73 .58
l8Osize3 do 1.96 .83
l8Osize5 do 6.71 2.22
23OsizeO Crucible .42 .17
23Osizel do .69 .22
23Osize2 do .88 .25
240 size F Crucible cover' .31 .12
24OsizeG do' .32 .13
24Osizel do' .41 .14
27Osize3 Gooch crucible 1.25 .36
430 size OOA Evaporating dish .55 .40
43Osize2 do 1.05 .47
43Osize4A do 1.46 .65
49Osizel Buchnerfunnel 2.92 1.37
49Osize2A do 6.26 2.27
49Osize4 do 11.67 5.18
5lOsize4/0 Hirsch funnel 1.91 .79
522 size 2/0 Motar and pestle 1.54 .86
522 size 3 do 2.98 1.56
`Crucible cover for 230 crucibles.
ExHIBIT A
AUGUST 1, 1967.
ALABAMA
Central Scientific Company, 3232 11th Avenue North, Birmingham 4
W. H. Curtin & Company, 1210 South 20th Street, Birmingham
E. H. Sargent & Company, 3125 Seventh Avenue North, Birmingham 4
- ALASKA
Van Waters & Rogers, 1415 East First Avenue, Anchorage
PAGENO="0404"
3840
ARIZONA
Clico Laboratory Supply Company, P.O. Box 6009, 1841 N. 23rd Avenue, Phoenix
Van Waters & Rogers, 2930 West Osborn Road, Phoenix
Van Waters & Rogers, 2430 East Grant Road, Pucson 85711
CALIFORNIA
A. S. Aloe Company, 1150 South Flower Street, Los Angeles 15
A. S. Aloe Company, 140 Beacon Avenue, South San Francisco
Central Scientific Company, 6446 Telegraph Road, Los Angeles 22
Central Scientific Company of California, 1040 Martin Avenue, Santa Clara
W. H. Curtin, 15215 Marquardt Ave., Santa Fe Springs, California
A. Daigger & Company, 210 South Los Angeles Street, Los Angeles 12
A. Daigger & Company, 10 Tenth Street, Richmond
Adolph Frese Corp., 1430 Grande Vista Avenue, Los Angeles 23
Gentec Hospital Supply Co., 2285 Arden Way, Sacramento, California
La Pine Scientific Company, 920 Parker Street, Berkeley
Los Angeles Chemical Company, 4545 Ardine Street, South Gate, Los Angeles 21
Matheson ScIentific, Inc., 5922 Triumph Street, Los Angeles
Matheson Scientific, Inc., 24800 Industrial Boulevard, Hayward
Nurnberg Scientific Company, 2127 Fourth Street, Berkeley
E. H. Sargent & Company, 1617 E. Ball Road, Anaheim
Scientific Apparatus Corp., 1801 via Burton, Fullerton
Scientific Products, Div. of American Hospital Supply Corp., 150 Jefferson Drive,
Menlo Park
Scientific Products, Div. of American Hospital Supply Corp., 3815 Valhalla Drive,
Burbank
Standard Scientific Supply Corp., 601 Rodier Drive, Glendale
Standard Scientific Supply Corp., 336 Harbor Way, South San Francisco
Van Waters & Rogers, Inc., P.O. Box 1391, San Diego
Van Waters & Rogers, Inc., P.O. Box 3200, Rincon Annex, San Francisco
Van Waters & Rogers, Inc., P.O. Box 2062, Terminal Annex, Los Angeles 54
Van Waters & Rogers, Inc., 850 South River Road, West Sacramento
Westlab Scientific, 557 South Douglas Street, El Segundo
Westlab Scientific, 707 18th Street, Bakersfield
Westlab Scientific, 820 Corey Way, South San Francisco
COLORADO
A. S. Aloe Company, 3800 N. Dahlia Street, Denver 7
E. H. Sargent & Company, 3800 Race Street, Denver 16
Van Waters & Rogers, Inc., P.O. Box 5287,4300 Holly Street, Denver 16
CONNECTICUT
Macalaster-Bicknell Company, Inc., 181 Henry Street, New Haven 11
DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA
Scientific Products, Div. of American Hospital Supply Corp., 3175 V St. NE,
Washington 18
FLORIDA
W. H. Curtin and Company, 388 Minorca Avenue, Coral Gables (Miami)
W. H. Curtin and Company, P.O. Box 606, 2335 Market Street, Jacksonville 1
Fisher Scientific Co., 1393 S. W. 1st Street, Miami
Scientific Products, Delaware Parkway at 20th, Miami 35
Surgical Supply Company, 1050 West Adams Street, Jacksonville
Tech Scientific Supply Company, 36 Northwest 29th Street, Miami
PAGENO="0405"
3841
GEORGIA
A. S. Aloe Company, 5180 Peachtree Road, Chamblee, (Atlanta)
W. H. Curtin Company, P.O. Box 2122, 1782 Marietta Building N.W., Atlanta
Estes Surgical Supply Company, 56 Auburn Avenue NE, Atlanta 3
Fisher Scientific Company, 690 Miami Circle, NE, Atlanta 5
IPCO Hospital Supply Corp., P.O. Box 13797 Station K, Atlanta
Scientific Laboratory Supply Company, 139 Forrest Avenue, NE, Atlanta
Scientific Products, 5056 Peachtree Road, Chamblee (Atlanta)
Will Corporation of Georgia, Box 20155, Station N, 890 Chattahoochee Avenue
NW, Atlanta
HAWAII
Hawaii Chemical Company, P.O. Box 3616, Honolulu
Van Waters & Rogers, Inc., B-K-H Division, 313 Kamakee Street, Honolulu
ILLINOIS
A. E. Aloe Co., 9556 River Street West, Schiller Park
Central Scientific Company, 26005. Kostner Avenue, Chicago 23
A. Daigger & Company, 159 West Kinzie Street, Chicago 10
Fisher Scientific Company, 1458 North Lamon Avenue, Chicago 51
General Biological Supply House, 82005. Hoyne Avenue, Chicago
La Pine Scientific Oompany, 6001 South Knox Avenue, Chicago 29
Matheson Scientific, Inc., 1850 Greenleaf Ave., Elk Grove Village
National Biological Supply Company, Inc., 2325 5. Michigan Avenue, Chicago
Rascher & Betzold, Inc., 730 North Franklin Street, Chicago 10
E. H. Sargent & Company, 4647 West Foster Avenue, Chicago 30
Schaar Scientific Company, 7300 West Montrose Avenue, Chicago 34
Scientific Glass Apparatus Co., P.O. Box 67, 2375 Pratt Boulevard, Elk Grove
Village
Scientific Products, 4700W. Chase Avenue, Chicago
Soiltest, Inc., 2205 Lee Street, Evanston, Illinois
Stansi Scientific Company, 1231-41 North Honore Street, Chicago 22
Welch Scientific Company, 7300 N. Linder Avenue, Skokie
Wilkens-Anderson Company, 4525 West Division Street, Chicago 51
INDIANA
La Pine Scientific Company, 83 Bennet Road, Carmel (Indianapolis)
KANSAS
Fisher Scientific Company, 2200 West 75th Street, Shawnee-Mission, Kansas City
Southwest Scientific Corp., 1301 South Handley, Wichita 13
KENTUCKY
Ace Glass, Inc., P.O. Box 996, 639 South Hancock Street, Louisville
Preiser Scientific, Inc., 1500 Algonquin Parkway, Louisville 3
LOUISIANA
A. S. Aloe Company, 1425 Tulane Avenue, New Orleans 12
W. H. Curtin and Company, P.O. Box 53387, 621 Celeste Street, New Orleans 50
Fi~her Scientific Company, 4543 North Boulevard, Baton Rouge
Mathe'~on Scientific, Inc., 3160 Florida St., Doherty Bldg., Rm. 103, Baton Rouge 6
Scientific Products, 4408 Catherine Avenue, Metairie
Surgical Selling Company, Inc., 732 Atherton Drive, Metairie
PAGENO="0406"
3842
MAEYLAND
A. S. Aloe Company, 12201 New Columbia Pike, Silver Spring
W. H. Curtin & Co., 12340 Parkiawn Drive, Rockville
Fisher Scientific Company, 7722 Fenton Street, Silver Spring
Matheson Scientific, Inc., 10727 Tucker Avenue, Beltsville
Phipps & Bird, Inc., 8055 13th Street, Silver Spring
Preiser Scientific, Inc., Room 1000 Montgomery Bldg., 4720 Montgomery Lane,
Bethesda
E. H. Sargent & Company, 10558 Metropolitan Avenue, Kensington
Will Corporation, 5-31 North Haven Street, P.O. Box 5195, Baltimore 24
MASSACHUSE~JY~S
Ace Glass, Inc., 221 Stafford Street, Springfield
Aloe Div. of Brunswick, 1550 Soldiers Field Road, Boston 35
Combosco Scientific Company, 37 Antwerp Street, Boston 35
Central Scientific Company, 100 Washington Street, Somerville
Fisher Scientific Company, 401 Riverside Avenue, Medford 55
Howe and French, Inc., 99 Broad Street, Boston 10
Macalaster-Bicknell Company, Inc., 243 Broadway, Cambridge 39
Macalaster-Bicknell Corp., 00 Arsenal Street, Watertown
E. F. Mahady Company, 851 Boylston Street, Boston 10
Scientific Products, 101 Third Avenue, Waltham (Boston 54)
MICHIGAN
Will Scientific Inc., 200 East Liberty Street, Ann Arbor
Fisher Scientific Co., 149 Michigan Avenue, Detroit 48220
Matheson Scientific, Inc., 1000 Howard St., Detroit 28
E. H. Sargent & Company, 8500 West Chicago Avenue, Detroit 4
Scientific Products, Div. of American Hospital Supply Corp., 17150 Southfield
Rd., Allen Park
MINNESOTA
A. S. Aloe Company, 3501 Raleigh Avenue, Minneapolis 16
Fisher Scientific Company, 700 Second Avenue South, Minneapolis 3
Physicians & Hospital Supply Company, 1400 Harmon Place, Minneapolis 3
Scientific Products Div. of American Hospital Supply Corp., 3846 Washington
Ave. N, Minneapolis 12
George T. Walker and Company, 2218 University Avenue SE, Minneapolis 14
MISSOURI
Aloe Scientific Div., 5300 East 59th Street, Kansas City 30
Aloe Scientific Div. of Aloe Co., P.O. Box 186, Main Post Office, St. Louis 66
Fisher Scientific Company, 1241 Ambassador Boulevard, St. Louis 63132
Matheson Scientific, Inc., P.O. Box 343, 3160 Terrace Street, Kansas City
Scientific Products Div. ef American Hospital Supply Ooa~p., P2th & Gentry
Street N, Kansas City
Taylor Chemical Company, St. Vincent & Sutherland, St. Louis
NEW HAMPSHIRE
Macalaster Scientific Corp., Route 111 and Everett Turnpike, Nashua
PAGENO="0407"
3843
NEW JERSEY
Ace Glass, Inc., 1938 North West Boulevard, Vineland
Ace Scientific Company, 1420 East Linden Avenue, Linden
Aloe Division of Brunswick, 610 Industrial Avenue, Paramus
J & H Berge, Inc., 4111 So. Clinton Avenue, South Plainfield
Central Scientific Company, 237 Sheffield Street, Mountainside
W. H. Curtin & Co., 438 Pompton Road, Wayne
Fisher Scientific Company, 52 Fadem Road, Springfield
I\Iacalaster-Bicknell Company, North and Depot Streets, Millville
E. H. Sargent Company, 35 Stern Avenue, Springfield
Scientific Glass Apparatus Company, 753 Board Street, Bloomfield
Scientific Products, 100 Raritan Center Parkway, Edison
NEW MEXICO
W. H. Curtin Company, 311A Washington Street, SE, Albuquerque
New Mexico Chemical Surgical Company, P.O. Box 255, 1407 Univ. Boulevard
NE, Aubuquerque
Van Waters & Rogers, Inc., P.O. Box 617GB, 324 Industrial Avenue NE,
Albuquerque
NEW YORK
Biological Supply Co., 1176 Mt. Hope Avenue, Rochester
Fisher Scientific Company, 120 Bldg., 120 Delaware Avenue, Buffalo 2
The Greiner Scientific Corp., 22 North Moore Street, New York 13
Gottlieb Greiner Company, 50 Dey Street, New York 7
LaPine Scientific Company, South Buckout Street, Irvington-on-Hudson
Macalaster-Bicknell Company, P.O. Box 5, Eastwood Station, New Court Avenue
at East Bourne Drive, Syracuse 6
New York Laboratory Supply Company, Inc., 76 Varick Street, New York 13
Science Kit, Inc., 2299 Military Road, TonaWanda
Scientific Products, 40-00 170th Street, Flushing 58
Standard Scientific Supply Corp., 808 Broadway, New York 3
Welch Scientific Company, 331 East 38th Street, New York 16
Will-Buffalo, Inc., 82-90 Chenango Street, P.O. Box 448, Buffalo 5
Will Corporation, P.O. Box 1050, 39 Russell Street, Rochester 3
Will-New York, Box 23, High Bridge Station, New York
NORTH CAROLINA
Cardinal Products, Inc., P.O. Box 1611, Durham
Carolina Biological Supply Company, Burlington
Scientific Products, 3713 North Davidson Street, Charlotte
OHIO
Fisher Scientific Company, 26401 Miles Avenue, Cleveland
Fisher Scientific Company, 3537 Epley Road, Cincinnati 39
Inland Chemical Corp., 1120 Bush Street, Toledo
Will Scientific Company, 230 North Front Street, Columbus 16
Matheson Scientific, Inc., 12101 Centron Place, Cincinnati
Matheson Scientific, Inc., 4540 Willow Parkway, Cuyahoga Heights (Cleveland)
Preiser Scientific, Inc., 9974 Springfield Park, Woodlawn, Cincinnati
E. H. Sargent & Company, 10400 Taconic Terrace, Cincinnati
Scientific Products, 1586 Frebis Lane, Columbus 6
PAGENO="0408"
3844
OKLAHOMA
W. H. Curtin and Company, P.O. Box 747, 514 East 2nd Street, Tulsa
Labco Scientific Division, 20 West Main Street, Oklahoma City 1
The Refinery Supply Company, 6901 East 12th Street, Tulsa 12
OREGON
Nurnberg Scientific Div., 3237 N. Williams Avenue, Portland 12
Scientific Supplies Company, 3950 Northwest Yeon Avenue, Portland 5
PENNSYLVANIA
A. S. Aloe, 250 Seco Drive, Monroeville
Burrell Corp., 2223 Fifth Avenue, Pittsburgh 19
Fisher Scientific Company, 711 Forbes Avenue, Pittsburgh 19
Fisher Scientific Company, Gulph Road (Route 23) King of Prussia
Matheson Scientific, Inc., Jackson and Swanson Streets, Philadelphia 48
Arthur H. Thomas Company, Third and Vine Streets, Philadelphia 5
Williams, Brown & Earle, Inc., 904-906 Chestnut Street, Philadelphia 7
RHODE ISLAND
Eastern Scientific Company, 267 Plain Street, Providence
TENNESSEE
A. S. Aloe Company, Norris Avenue and Armory Drive, Nashville 4
W. H. Curtin Company, 750 Adams Building, Memphis 5
TEXAS
A. S. Aloe Company, 8900 Ambassador Row, Dallas
Central Scientific, 6610 Stillwell Street, Houston
W. H. Curtin and Company, P.O. Box 1546, 4220 Jefferson Avenue, Houston
W. H. Curtin and Company, P.O. Box 5304, 1103-07 Slocum Street, Dallas 22
W. H. Curtin and Company, 519 South Water Street, Corpus Christi
W. H. Curtin and Company, 719 South St. Mary's Street, San Antonio 5
Fisher Scientific Company, 5407 Andrews Highway, Odessa
Fisher Scientific Company, El Patio Building, W., Room 108, 600 Avenue H East,
Arlington
Fisher Scientific Company, 4102 Greenbriar Drive, Houston 6
.Matheson Scientific, Inc., P.O. Box 9387, 6622 Supply Row, Houston
The Refinery Supply Company, 6610 Stillwell Street, Houston 32
E. H. Sargent & Company, 5915 Peeler Street, Dallas
Scientific Products, 9020 Directors Row, Dallas 35
Surgical Selling Company, Inc., 7307 Ardmore Street, Houston 21
Thermal Scientific Company, P.O. Box 884, West 27th Street & Westover, Odessa
Van Waters & Rogers, Inc., P.O. Box 9247, El Paso
UTAH
E. H. Sargent & Company, 375 West 21st South Street, Salt Lake City 10
Van Waters & Rogers, 650 West 8th South, Salt Lake City 6
Wasatch Chemical Company, 2225 South Fifth East, Salt Lake City 6
VIRGINIA
Fisher Scientific Company, 3820 Augusta Ave., Teal Bldg., Richmond
Phipps & Bird, Inc., 303 South Sixth Street, Richmond 5
PAGENO="0409"
3845
WASHINGTON
A. S. Aloe Company, 1818 East Madison Street, Seattle 22
Nurnberg Scientific Div., 3910 5. 12th Street, Tacoma 5
Scientific Products, 14850 N.E. 36th Street, Bellevue
Sherwin Scientific Company, N. 1112 Ruby, Spokane
Van Waters & Rogers, Inc., Scientific Supplies Company, 600 South Spokane
Street, Seattle 4
WEST VIRGINIA
Fisher Scientific Company, 1033 Quarrier Street Bldg., Room 501, Charleston 1
Preiser Scientific, Inc., P.O. Box 551, 900 MacCorkle Avenue, SW, Charleston 22
Surgical Selling Company, Inc., 1705 ~Fefferson Street, Bluefield
Will Scientific, Inc., Box 9277, Springhill Station, South Charleston 3
WISCONSIN
Gentec Hospital Supply Co., Div. of McKesson & Robbins, 250 North Water Street,
Milwaukee
Nasco, Inc., Fort Atkinson
CANADA
ALBERTA
Fisher Scientific Company, 14730 115A Avenue, Edmonton
BRITISH COLUMBIA
Central Scientific Company, 1206 Homer Street, Vancouver
Fisher Scientific Company, 194 W. Third Avenue, Vancouver 10
Canadian Laboratory Supplies, 1449 Hornby Street, Vancouver
ONTARIO
Canadian Laboratory Supplies, 80 Jutland Road, Toronto
Central Scientific Company, 2200 So. Sheridan Way, Clarkson, Ontario
Fisher Scientific Company, 184 Railside Road, Don Mills
Mines Assay Supplies, Ltd., Kirkland Lake
.E. H. Sargent & Company, 9 Milvan Drive, Weston
Welch Scientific, 16 Rivalda Road, Weston
QUEBEC
Canadian Laboratory Supplies, 8766 Delmeade Road, Town of Mount Royal
Central Scientific Company, 104 Gun Street, Point Claire
Fisher Scientific Company, 8505 Devonshire Road, Montreal
MEXICAN DEALERS
Casa Rocas, S. A., Arpartado Postal #233, Monterrey, N. L.Mexico
Hoffman-Pinther & Bosworth, Apartado Postal 101-BIS, Mexico City, Mexico
Curtin de Mexico, S. A. de C. V., Apartado Postal 26265, Antonio Maura #29,
Mexico City 13, D. V., Mexico
PAGENO="0410"
3846
EXHIBIT B
CHEMICAL PORCELAIN SALES
QUANTITY OF ITEMS
Catalog
Number
02101-3 /8
02102-1/2
02103-5 / 8
02104-3/4
02106-1
02401-
04001-2
04002-3
04003-3A
04004-4
04005-5
06001-2
06002-3
06003 -4
07001-2
07002-3
11001-5/0
11002 -4/0
11003-2/0
11004 -1
11005-2
11006-4
11007 -6
11008-6A
11009 -8
11010-13
12001-1
12 002-2
12 003-4
12 004-6
12 005-8
13001-1
Quantity
18
59
705
63
2, 583
168
117
12
44
16
146
372
469
63
56
4, 021
1, 188
1, 044
822
8, 686
4, 404
2, 921
4, 536
4, 121
2, 039
36
222
51
37
44
132
1967
Catalog
Number
13002-2
16001-0
16002-1
16003-2
16004-3
17Q01-2
17002-3
17003-3A
17004-4
18001-2/0
18002-0
18003 -1
18004 -2
18005 -3
18006 -C'3A
18007 -4
18008-04A
18009-5
18010-6
18011-7
18102-1
18103-1
18105 -2
18106 -2
18108-2A
18109-2A
18111-3
18112-3
18114- 3A
18115- 3A
18117-4
18118 -4
Quantity
134
1, 273
3, 167
467
1, 197
1, 796
6, 588
5, 338
1, 643
3, 837
12, 510
6, 384
7, 032
10,923
6, 445
7, 426
2, 528
863
660
176
103
69
48
352
3, 408
3, 336
460
338
568
312
80
156
PAGENO="0411"
3847
Catalog
Number -
- 1812 0-4A
1812 l-4A
18123-5
18124-5
18201-4
19101-3A
19102 -4
22 001-1
22 101-2
22102-3
22 103-4
222 01-1
222 02-2
22 301-1
22 302-2
2 3001-5/0
2 3002-4/0
2 3003-3/0
23004-2/0
2 3005-0
23006- OA
2 3007-1
23008-lA
2 3009-2
2 3010-3
2 3011-4
2 3012-5
2 3013-4/0
23014-3/0
2 3015-2/0
2 3016-0
23017 -OA
2 3018-1
24001 -AA
24002 -A
24003-B
24004-D
24005-F
24006-G
Quantity
25
13
7
7
136
942
274
41
282
132
43
9,288
3, 902
2, 847
954
6,217
4, 584
46, 008
148, 241
265, 736
12, 400
179, 499
42, 887
54, 570
23, 111
5, 079
4, 134
54
252
284
219
96
1, 167
1, 045
1, 829
15, 915
58, 404
131, 367
96, 468
Catalog
Number -
24007-I
24008 -J
24009-K
24010-L
24011-M
25001-6/0
25002 -5/0
2 5003-4/0
2 5004-3/0
25005-2/0
25006-0
2 5007-1
2 5008-2
25009 -3
2 5010-4
25011-5
25013-2/0
25014 -0
2 5015-1
27 001-1
27002-2
27003-2A
27004-3
27005 -3A
27006-3B
27007-4
27008 -4A
27009-5
2 9001-2
29002-3
29101-1
29102-2
29103 -3
30001-0
30002 -1
30003 -3
31101-0
31102-1
32 001-1
Quantity
25, 954
8, 095
2, 602
1,220
590
957
543
1, 639
16, 524
38,290
54, 062
57, 348
24, 336
13, 516
5, 028
2, 087
142
312
176
896
3, 296
3,209
45, 324
2, 164
2, 940
27, 666
3, 300
360
552
3, 152
60
144
233
648
296
2, 990
53
528
504
PAGENO="0412"
3848
catalog
Number
32002-2
320033.
330011
33 002 -2
330033
35001-2
360013
39 001 -1
400010 -
40002 -1
410010
420014
42 002 -2
422 010
422024
422 03-2
422 04-3
42301-2/0
42 302-0
42303-4
42304-2
42305-3
423064
42307-5
42308-6
42309 -6A
42 310-7
42401-1
43001 -4 /0
43002 -3 /0
43003-A
43004-0
43005 -1
43006r~2
43007-3
43008 -4A
43009-5
43010 -6
43011- 6A
Catalog
Quantity Number
1,068 43012-7
2,860 43013-8
216 43014-8A
240 43015-9
379 43016-10
6,266 43017-11
960 43018-12
846 43019-13
1,075 43021-3/0
152 43O22-OOA
2,294 43023-0
48 43024-1
116 43025-2
226 43026-3
72 43101 -1
360 43102-2
612 43103-3
111 4400111
216 44002-12
774 44003-12A
784 44004-13
4,135 44005-14
3,241 45001-3/0
45002 -1
277 45003-2
36 54004-3
222 45005-4
2, 742 45006-5
6,632 45007-6
113,657 45008-7
116,931 47001-15
62,361 49001-4/0
24,161 49002 -0
37,088 49003-4
24, 414 49004-1A
14,731 49005-2
8,668 490062~
6,546 49007-3
3,215 49008-4
.Quantity
2, 847
2, 340
1, 0~9
1, 163
702
106
256
12
144
92
21
108
114
16
864
814
146
137
43
21.
2, 652
2, 989
3, 752
3, 622
1, 659
972
1, 322
659
31
3, 138
20, 556
25, 617
4, 512
15, 614
10, 448
7, 158
4, 690
PAGENO="0413"
3849
Catalog
Number
49009- 4A
49010 -5
49011-6
49012-7
49102-3
49103 -3
49105 -4
49106 -4
49108 -4A
49109-4A
49111-5
49112 -5
49114-6
49115~6
492 01-4A
49202-5
492 03-6
492 04-7
49205-A
492 06-3
492 07-4
49501 -0
49502-1
49503 -2
49504-2A
49505-3
49506 -4
49507 -4A
49508-5
49509 -6
49701-1
49702 -2A
49703 -3
49704 -4
49705 -5
49706 -6
49707-7
49802-3
49804-4
Quantity
2, 879
2, 114
1,107
145
79
207
46
134
59
126
92
92
29
162
736
338
338
266
154
48
55
273
155
244
163
35
81
54
22
24
152
129
186
107
127
136
9
32
Catalog
Number
49806 -4A
49808 -5
49810-6
49812-7
49816 -7
51001-5/0
51002 -4/0
51003-3/0
51004-3 OA
51005-2/0
51006 -0
51007-OC
51008-1
51009 -2
51101 -2
51501-1
52 002-0
52 003-0
52005- OA
52006-OA
52 008-1
52 009-1
52 011-2
52012-2
52014-3
52015-3 /
52017-4
52018-4
5202 0-5
52 02 1-5
5202 3-6
52024-6
52202-3/0
522 03-3 /0
52205-2/0
52206-2/0
52208-1 -
522 09-1
522 11-3
Quantity
32
33
123
150
165
8, 504
12, 796
2, 950
744
1, 453
1, 128
32
161
19
52
21
7, 449
8, 322
3, 179
3, 145
9.683
9, 523
3, 282
3, 369
1, 892
2,270
1, 168
1, 196
346
395
69
102
22, 318
22, 017
20, 720
22, 576
16, 324
16, 201
4, 960
95-159 0 - 68 - pt. 8 - 27
PAGENO="0414"
3850
Catalog
Number
52212-3
522 14-4
52215-4
522 17-6
522 18-6
52220-8
5222 1-8
52302-1
52 303-1
52 305-2
52 306-2
52 308-3
52 309-3
52 311-4
52 312-4
52314-5
52 315-5
52 317-6
52 318-6
52 32 0-7
52 32 1-7
52402-2
52403~2
52405 -4
52 406-4
52408-5
52409 -5
52411-6A
52412 -6A
52 601-7
52 602-7
53102 -4/0
53103-4/0
53105-3/0
53106-3 /0
53108-2/0
53109-2/0
53111-0
53112 -0
Quantity
4, 342
2, 057
2, 273
670
732
469
470
1, 073
1, 119
623
637
341
401
275
303
73
85
216
178
92
87
221
238
98
96
101
93
68
69
2
2~
395
414
88
99
1, 008
942
133
199
Catalog
Number
53114-1
53115 -1
53117 -2
5 3118-2
5312 0-3
5312 1-3
5 312 3-4
5312 4-4
5312 6-5
5312 7-5
5312 9-7
5 3130-7
53132 -9
53133-9
53135-12
53136 -12
53501-1
53502-4
55001-4/0
55002 -3/0
55003-2/0
55004-0
55005 -1
55006 -2
55007-3
55008-4
55101 -4 /0
55102 -3 /0
55103-2/0
55104 -0
55105 -1
56001-1
56002 -1A
56003 -2
56004-4
56005 -6.
57001-0
57002-1
57 003-2
Quantity
1, 112
1, 194
354
358
681
841
74
107
415
378
242
242
45
67
27
96
30
207
3, 327
4, 600
8, 373
1,256
4, 905
466
72
168
423
84
237
200
475
229
50
340
32
24
147
1, 565
1,938
PAGENO="0415"
3851.
Catalog
Number
57004 -3
57005-3A
57006 -4
57007 -5
58001 -4*
58002-5
59001-4
59002-5
60001-3
60002-4
60003 -5
61001-1
61002-2
61003 -3
61004 -5
62401-1
63001-1
63002 -3
63003 -5
63004-6
64001-1
64002 -2
64003 -3
64004-4
65001-1
65002-lA
65003 -2
65004 -3
65005 -4
65006 -4A
65007-5
65801-2/0
65802 -0
65803- OA
65804-lA
65805-iC
68801-1
69001-~0
70001-1
7 0002 -z
70003-2A
Quantity
3, 317
2, 184
1,283
1, 485
347
691
839
1, 644
5, 666
3, 314
6,283
3, 492
1, 988
472
1, 504
1, 275
159
604
293
57
1, 675
2,166
1, 448
848
3, 985
6, 235
2, 953
2, 792
754
329
407
239
249
282
76
215
115
412
6, 883
264
10, 390
Catalog
Number Quantity
70004-4 7,926
700055 1,956
70006-6 48
70007-7 400
70008-8 320
70009-11 36
71001-5 136
71002-8A 102
73001-1 44
75001-0 1,510
75002-1 1,239
75003-2 640
75004-4 1,018
76001-2/0 1,003
76002-1 3,306
76003-lA 375
76004-2 2,169
76201 72
76202-P/3 327
76203-PlO 90
76204-P16 24
76301- * 32
76302-P /3 74
76304-P16 16
76401- 16
76402-P/3 42
76403-PlO 120
76404-P16 16
76501-5/0 6
76502-3 1,130
76503-4 306
76701-5/0 42
76702 -3 2, 517
76703-4 488
76901-5/0 28
76902-3 3,610
76903-4 497
77501-5/0 133
80201-1 288
GRAND TOTAL
2, 556, 513
PAGENO="0416"
3852
PAGENO="0417"
3853
CHEMICAL
PORCELAIN
COORS
U.S.A.
PAGENO="0418"
PERCENT
~---~ N~ ~ f') N~ t~
r'~ .c~ c~ ~ 0 N) A 0) O~ 0 r~' A C) O~ 0
916 ~ ~ 0 0 0 c~ 0 0 0 ~ 0 0:0 :
1918 . . ~ . . . .
.-.-...--, . ..: ~ (o~O ~ _...:~...
. . : ~ : ~ ~: .
920 ~ ~ ~ . ~ . . . . . ,,..
~ ~ ~ ~ : ~ ~ . ~ . ~ . ,: ~* ~ ~
922 . . -1~ . ~ : . i
~. . ~tnrfl ~ ~ . . ~1 ~
. -r-- . *-- rr) r!~ ~ . . .~I
924 . , . .
(4) (4)-~~ - .
926 I, .` ` ,` , * ` :
, .
928 ,. I. ~ , .
-.-i-.... :~. ~-.- , . . ,,, .-,~ ,
C)
-- . I ~ C)0
932 * , , ` . : , . .. . : . .,
1934 . ` `1. . , ` . , :
`1':" `
936 . `. : .., . . . . ` ` .! ` O1~
o
1938
--,.~
1940 , ` : ``~::` ..~. . . ,
* * . :`. -I * `. .
* *. ** *.. *,*. ,.
942 , , :.. :` * . * * ** `I * `. ,
. . , * , . . *
`944
946 ` : *. ` *,* , ` , :: * C)
00.~~.
948' * , *: `, *` ` , * * * .
950, . * ~. , , . :
, .L
J952~~~c* , , * * : ` . -~
- * *., - ,
l954'~G) ` . ,; .~ *
ç~ .~ * . *-~ *_i :---
mo *` .. ~
l956r--~~
I CQ) ` /~-nr- " * *
I °~- . ~-` . , I `
l958--~ *
* ,*
.~CJ) * , `.`I.
l960~-o~, ---j . * * , ,
* _..,..~ 4... , --**,-.~-., -.
I * *. .:
I962r~ *~ `i .j:~ . .` :. *
964
* . I.. ` ~
966 - - - - - ~ ~"`~
I'.) ~ ~ 0 r~ ~ A o~
0 0~0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
PAGENO="0419"
~) C) W
~ ~
-*~ : : a:
0
~ll
~ h
~
~C)
-4
-~ C,)
- -
NN~4?'$~ ~
(~ ~.
-
~
- : - -~ ~ ~
~ ~.
~"C) :
~ r~pp-p~~~ s": PN
~ ~ ~ ~: ~
2 ::::::: ::::::: ::::: :``
~ ~ ::: ::::: .64::::::::::
C_) - C~) 00 N) C) N)
PAGENO="0420"
3856
We would now report that we have made consideilable investigation regarding
the possible marketing of these items in this country, but unfortunately, due
to the fact that a very similar line of speciality item is being manufactured here
by an English finn-Messrs. K.L.G. Ltd.-we feel sure you will appreciate that
this makes the position of marketing your lines, particularly with regard to
Import duties etc., extremely uncompetitive, and most certainly would have a
very limited affect upon the possible sales of your items.
We do trust that under the circumstances you will appreciate the position.
Yours sincerely,
D. F. HAYDON,
General Sales Manager.
EXHIBIT E
P. M. TAMSON N.Y., INSTRUMENTEN,
Den Haag, Holland, July 7, 1Q61.
Mr. CHARLES `S. RYLAND, Esq.,
St. Ermin's Hotel,
London, W.C. 1.
DEAR Sin: We were very much pleased to receive your letter dated June 30,
1961. Mr. James Fisher asked us what porcelain was sold by us and we enclose
a catalogue with pricelist in Dutch guilders. This is WETA-porcelain, a reason-
able good quality, to `be compared with Haldenwanger and Berliner, in our
opinion `better than Rosenthal, and much better than Czec!hoslovakian and such
kinds of porcelain.
We know from experience that your quality is the best of all to be obtained
in the world, since at the end of the war we have sold your porcelain (we refer
to the invoices enclosed of Messrs. Arthur H. Thomas Company, Philadelphia).
At that tline no other makes were available, but later on we have been compelled
to drop your porcelain as soon as the German factories were getting again at
the market, supplying satisfactory qualities `and much cheaper than yours.
Now we `learned from Mr. James Fisher, that at present you are manufacturing
fully-automatic `and perhaps this would enable you to supply us again at com-
petitive prices. As we told you before we are delighted at the very fine quality
of your make and if anyhow possible, we should be glad to take up again the sale
of your porcelain. For your guidance we may state that import duties would
be about 17%.
It will be a pleasure to us to meet you at The Hague at the end of this month
and we shall be glad to make an exact appointment
`Looking forward to your further news, we remain, Dear Sir,
Yours very truly,
J. A. Psw HAVE.
EXHIBIT F
THE CHAIRMAN,
Interdepartm~ental Committee on TradeAgreements,
Department of State,
Washington, D.C.
DEAR Mn. CHAIRMAN: It has come to my attention that there is included in
the list of commodities on which the United States may consider nego'tiating
tariff reductions at the forthcoming meeting of the signatories to the General
Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, chemical and scientific porcelain (Par. 212).
I am utterly astonished that chemical porcelain, which is widely recognized
as absolutely essential to national defense and which is produced by only
one company in the United States, would be placed on this list. The Tariff
Commission itself has stated that "Chemical porcelain is vital in national
defense".
The one company in this country which produces chemical porcelain is the
Coors Porcelain Company of Golden, Colorado. In addition to being the only
United States concern producing chemical porcelain, this company is regarded
in industry circles as being the producer of the finest chemical porcelain in the
world.
Mr. H. W. Ryland, vice president and manager of the Coors Company, testi-
fied on October 31 before the Tariff Commission and the Committee for
Reciprocity Information in opposition to any reduction in the tariff on chemical
porcelain. At tha't time he presented vigorous, documented case against reducing
PAGENO="0421"
3857
this tariff: There is, however, an additional factor to be considered in the case
of the Coors Company. It is that this company is engaged in production of
certain porcelain items of highly secret nature for the Atomic Energy Commis-
sion, the Army, the Navy, and the Air Force, which cannot be secured by these
defense agencies from any other source. The nature of these items of course
could not be satisfactorily discussed by Mr. Ryland at the public hearings at
which he testified. Indeed, some of the items produced by the Coors Company,
especially for the Atomic Energy Commission, cannot be discussed with any
person who has not received the highest security clearance from the Commission.
I cannot conceive that any serious consideration will be given to a reduction
in the tariff on chemical porcelain. However, because of the peculiar essen-
tiality of the Coors Porcelain Company in our national defense picture, I request
that if by any chance serious consideration would be given to a reduction in
the chemical porcelain tariff, you communicate promptly with me in order
that Mr. Ryland can meet with you and arrange a method of demonstration
to you and other appropriate officials, within the limits of existing security
regulations, his company's essentiality to national defense.
Sincerely,
EUGuNE MILLIKIN.
Mr. FULTON. The next witness is Mr. IJecker.
We are pleased to have you appear before the committee.
Will you identify yourself for the record?
STATEMENT OF WILLIAM F. UECKER, Wflfl)OW SHADE MANUFAQ~
TURERS ASSOCIATION
Mr. UECKER. Mr. Chairman and members of the committee, I am
William F. TJecker, general sales manager of Joanna Western Mills
Co., which is one of the member companies of the Window Shade
Manufacturers Association.
Mr. Chairman, we have prepared a printed statement here. Perhaps
in the interests of time we can submit this for the record.
Mr. FULTON. Without objection, so ordered.
Mr. UECKER. Our position is stated in this printed statement, and I
would try to briefly summarize and answer any questions you might
have.
First of all, I would like to describe the article in question, as I am
aware that it is variously described here in this country as window
shades, window blinds, curtains, and so forth.
The article that I am talking about is what is known as window
shades. It is commonly a piece of material made out of treated cotton
cloth or vinyl plastic sheeting. It is cut and hemmed at the bottom,
and it is attached to a wooden roll~r having a spring-powered mecha~
nism that rolls it up and down at the window.
This provides for easy and efficient and economical privacy and light
control.
A recent survey indicated that window shades were used on one or
more windows on more than 80 percent of the homes in the United
States.
Mr. Chairman, the window shade product is an American invention.
The industry itself started here in the United States in the mid-1800's.
Our own company has been in operation since 1897.
Interestingly enough, currently, window shades are largely indige-
nous to the North American Continent, with some use in Western
European countries.
PAGENO="0422"
3858
Now, window shades being a staple item, and particularly the low
end plastic shades in question, are strictly a price article. Currently the
principal exporting country to the United States is Formosa, and this
has caused great difficulties, because we cannot compete pricewise, due
to the very low wages that prevail in Formosa.
Moreover, the threat of an avalanche of further imported low-price
competition has a depressing and detrimental effect on the entire
industry.
We feel that the present rate of duty is wholly inadequate.
I might point out that right at the moment, there is a case on behalf
of the Window Shade Manufacturers Association pending in the
U.S. Customs Court. Here the Customs authority, through administra-
tive practice, changed the classification of imported window shades,
so that the rate of duty was reduced from 17 percent to the present 11
percent.
As a result, we believe that imports are increasing. However, we have
no specific statistics available, inasmuch as there are only two large
importers here in the States, and we are advised that with so few
importers, this is considered confidential information, and is not
available to us.
However, I believe that these statistics would be available to the
committee.
Again, we feel that aid to the companies or to the workers is not the
answer. It just doesn't do any good to drive the industry out of business,
and then start retraining workers or giving them other forms of
relief.
We want to meet competition in the marketplace, and over the years
we have met competition from Canada and Western European coun-
tries; but the low wage rates that prevail in Formosa are another
matter.
We believe that relief should be provided in an escape clause pro-
cedure for industries.
Our last point is that in addition to completed window shades
entering the United States, there is also component parts presently
in the form of vinyl plastic sheeting. The Federal Trade Commission
has ruled in several instances that such articles finished in the United
States from imported parts must indicate the country of origin of
such parts, and we believe that this should apply universally, as in
the case of window shades.
Mr. Chairman and members of the committee, I thank you very much
for your kind attention, and I would be happy to answer any questions
you might have.
(Mr. Uecker's prepared statement follows:)
STATEMENT OF WILLIAM F. UEOKER, WINDOW SHADE MANUFACTURERS ASSOCIATION
My name is William F. Tlecker and I am General Sales Manager of Joanna
Western Mills Company, located at 2141 South Jefferson Street, Chicago, Illinois.
The Window Shade Manufacturers Association is an association made up of
domestic manufacturers of all types and kinds of window shades. However, for
the purposes of this brief the matter will relate only to' the manufacture and sale
of plastic window shades. These shades are manufactured from a sheet of plastic
or vinyl and then attached to a roller having a spring mechanism. The shade is
raised or lowered by increasing or decreasing tension on the spring mechanism
and the plastic is wound or unwound around the roller. The present active mem-
bers are: Breneman, Inc., Cincinnati, Ohio, 45210; Illinois Shade Division of
PAGENO="0423"
3859
Slick Industrial Company, Chicago Heights, Illinois, 60411; Stauffer Chemical
Company, Newburgh, New York, 12550; Joanna Western Mills Company, Chicago,
Illinois; The Western Shade Division of William Volker and Company of Los
Angeles, Los Angeles, California, 90023.
THE PRESIDENT SHOULD NOT BE GIVEN FURTHER AUTHORITY TO BEDUCE DUTIES
Under the proposed Trade Expansion Act of 1968 (H.R. 17551) the President
is seeking further authority to reduce duties. Under the Trade Expansion Act of
1962 the President was given authority to reduce the rates of duty on imported
merchandise to 50 per cent of the rates which existed on July 1, 1962. The
authority/expired on June 30, 1967.
Under the auspices of the so'-cafled Kennedy Round of negotiations most of the
authority granted to the President to reduce rates of duty was used. It is believed
that the reductions in the rate of duty applying to imports into the United
States were predicated not so much on the concessions we received from the
negotiating parties of GATT, but took into account the domestic industry
involved in its relation to the country, its relation to the community, the protec-
tion needed (if any) from competitive imports, capital invested, number of
employees, etc. If it is a fact that those factors were taken into account, then
the reductions in duty under the Kennedy Round were probably the maximum
reductions possible, even if less than the full 50 per cent permitted. Therefore, to
permit the President to have authority to further reduce duties for any reason
would be imposing an undue hardship by the mere threat of further reductions
on those domestic industries subject thereto.
The results of the Kennedy Round have hardly been realized and the mere
authority to further reduce duties could result in a mass exodus of domestic
industries to low wage countries.
For example, the domestic window shade industry is one that is economically
operated with the most modern techniques, up-to-date machinery and the best
quality of plastic sheeting produced. The most competitive single country is
Formosa and despite all the American know-how, etc., it is virtually impossible
to compete due to the low cost of foreign labor. Plastic window shades are strictly
a price item and the American housewife is concerned only with the price when
shopping for the article. Assuming (but certainly not admitting) that Japan or
Formosa produces a comparable window shade, the cost of the imported window
shade is so' much lower, including the present reduced rate of duty, that the
domestic industry may find it necessary to resort to legislative relief to stay in
business. When the full effect of the Kennedy Round reductions is felt by this
industry, it may become very difficult to continue to manufacture plastic window
shades in this country.
No one is disadvantaged if the President is denied at the present time the
authority to further reduce duties. If in a specific instance, for a specific purpose
it is necessary, Congress can authorize such authority. Blanket authority to the
President at this time can only be detrimental to domestic industries.
TO LIBERALIZE ADJUSTMENT ASSISTANCE CRITERIA PROCEDURES FOR FIRMS AND
WORKERS WITHOUT LIBERALIZING THE ESCAPE CLAUSE FOR DOMESTIC INDUSTRIES
WOULD BE LESS THAN A NULLITY
A. History Of The Escape Clause
From the beginning of the Trade Agreements Program there has been concern
that as a result of a decrease in import restrictions there would be such an in-
crease in imports as to seriously injure or to threaten serious injury to domestic
manufacturers. When the President was given authority in 1934 to reduce im-
port restrictions he committed himself to use the authority in such manner as not
to injure sound and important American industries. However, in administering
the Trade Agreements Act it soon became apparent that some domestic indus-
tries would be seriously injured. An "escape clause" was, therefore, included
in trade agreements which permitted the United States to withdraw a conces-
sion under certain conditions.
The Trade Agreements Extension Act of 1951 for the first time had an "escape
caluse" procedure provided for by statute (Sec. 7). This provision in substance
held that the Tariff Commission should investigate all escape clause applica-
tions; imposed a time limit for the investigation; and allowed an actual as well
as a relative increase in imports to satisfy the procedural criteria. The Tariff
Commission pursuant to the investigation then had to determine if as a result
PAGENO="0424"
3860
in whole or in part of concessions granted, imports of the article under investi-
gation were being imported into the United States in such increased quantities,
either actual or relative, as to cause, or threaten, serious injury to the domestic
industry producing like or directly competitive products. Section 7 of the Trade
Extension Act of 1951 was re-enacted in 1955 and 1958. It lasted until 1962.
B. Application Of The Escape Clause
Under Section 7 of the Trade Extension Act of 1951 (and its re-enactment)
113 investigations were completed by the Tariff Commission. Of that number of
investigations the Tariff Commission found that in 33 investigations the criteria
for injury was met by the domestic industry and recommended to the President
that relief be granted; in 8 investigations the Tariff Commissioners were divid-
ed as to their findings and therefore, the cases had to be referred to the Presi-
dent for disposition; and 72 cases were dismissed by the Tariff Commission on
the grounds that the domestic industries did not meet the criteria set up by
Congress for relief.
Of the 41 investigations referred to the President, 15 were granted relief
pursuant to the statute and 26 were denied relief.
C. Changes Made in The Present Act (Trade Ecopansion Act of 1962). From
~$ection 7 Of The Trade Agreement Ecotension Act of 1951
In the Trade Expansion Act of 1962 Congress enacted a sweeping reorganiza-
tion of safeguard procedure which among other things made a form of relief
available to groups not covered by earlier acts, such as individual firms and
employees of injured industries. Under the 1962 Act the President could provide
relief in. cases of injury to an industry, firm or workers by withdrawing, or
modifying the concession or he may grant trade adjustment assistance such as
loans, tax relief and technical assistance. During the debates in Congress on the
1962 legislation it was held out to labor as an inducement for the passage of the
Act that individual groups of workers, not provided for under previous legisla-
tion could obtain trade adjustment assistance.
However, in addition to the attempted beneficial changes made by the 1962
Act, the criteria for "injury" was changed which change made it impossible for
domestic industries, firms or individuals to get any trade adjustment assistance.
Before the Commission can make an affirmative finding under section
301(b) (1) of the Trade Expansion Act of 1962, it must determine (1) that the
imports in question are entering the United States in increased quantities; (2)
that the increased imports are a result in major part of trade agreement con-
cessions; and (3) that such increased imports have been the major factor in
causing or threatening to cause, serious injury to the domestic industry con-
cerned. If the Commission finds in the negative with respect to any one of these
three requisites, it is foreclosed from making an affirmative finding for the
industry.
D. Impossibility of Qualifying For Belief Under Present Criteria
Since the drastic change made by Congress in the Act of 1962 in determining
the criteria for injury to be found by the Tariff Commission before relief can be
secured by an industry, firm or individual, not one petition was found to have met
that criteria. From the enactment of the 1962 Trade Expansion Act to date,
domestic industries have filed 10 petitions with the Tariff Commission for
investigation and trade adjustment assistance; domestic firms have filed 6 peti-
tions and workers have filed 5 petitions. In all, 21 petitions have been filed and
as previously stated the Tariff Commission has not made an affirmative finding
in any.
E. The Proposed Liberalization Of The Tariff Adjustment Provisions Of The
Trade Ecepansion Act of 1962 By The Trade Ecopansion Act of 1968 (Hi?.
17551) For The Benefit Of Firms And Workers Will Help Those Classes Little
If At All Unless There Is A Chance In The Criteria For Injury Applying To
Domestic Industries
As above stated, when Congress changed the criteria for relief to domestic
industries injured as a result of increased imports due to a trade concession
from the escape clause provisions contained in the Section 7 of the Trade Exten-
sion Act of 1951 to the provisions contained in the present act (Trade Expansion
Act of 1962) and included also therein for the first time tariff assistance to
injured firms and workers, not one petition on behalf of domestic industries,
firms or workers qualified. The criteria for securing relief in the present law
PAGENO="0425"
3861
(Trade Expansion. Act of 1962) is the same for domestic industries, individual
firms or workers.
The Administration recognizing that whereas the escape clause provisions of
the Trade Extension Act of 1951 were successfully applied by several domestic
industries which qualified thereunder, the changes made for securing relief by
injured industries, individual firms or workers under the Trade Expansion Act
of 1962, proved to be a complete nullity, is now suggesting amendments to the
latter Act through the proposed "Trade Expansion Act of 1968" (H.R. 17551).
However, the proposed changes in H.R. 17551 apply merely to individual firms
and workers and does not apply to domestic industries. In other words the pro-
posed new Act will make it easier for individual firms and workers to secure
relief from loss of jobs or loss of income due to increased ruinous imports, but
the domestic industry which contains the individual firms and employs the
workers will still be handicapped by the criteria under the Trade Expansion Act
of 1962, which criteria has been impossible to meet up to the present time.
The President in requesting Congress to liberalize the previous impossible
restrictions placed on those industries, firms and individuals seeking justifiable
relief from imports, very studiously limited the proposed changes to apply only
to firms and workers. He stated:
"Some firms, however, have difficulty in meeting foreign competition, and need
time and help to make the adjustment.
"Since international trade strengthens the nation as a whole, it is only fair
that the government assist those businessmen and workers who face serious
problems as a result of increased imports.
"The Congress recognized this need-in the Trade Expansion Act of 1962-by
establishing a program of trade adjustment assistance to businessmen and
workers adversely affected by imports."
It is respectfully pointed out that to offer relief to firms and workers and
not to the domestic industry involved is absolutely worthless. . . . What can it
possibly benefit a firm if it receives tax assistance or a loan or other adjustment,
if the industry is forced out of the business of producing the article because of
low cost foreign competition? What can it possibly benefit a worker in the long
run if he gets extra unemployment benefits or training or relocation, if the indus-
try in which he was employed transfers its manufacturing ability and know-
how to low wage countries because of imports from similar low wage countries?
If the proposed "Trade Expansion Act of 1968" (H.R. 17551) is passed in the
present form as related to escape clause provisions for domestic industries and
tariff adjustment provisions as relates to individual firms and workers, it is possi-
ble that a firm or worker could qualify for relief under the new provisions but
the domestic industry could not qualify even though petitions could be filed by
all three categories at the same time and the same evidence adduced by the Tariff
Commission in its investigation.
The domestic window shade industry would benefit nothing if under the pro-
posed criteria through the Trade Expansion Act of 1968, an individual firm or
window shade worker were granted some of the relief outlined in the act, but
the domestic industry itself gives up production. In order to meet the foreign
competition in the American market place, it would be necessary to put the domes-
tic industry on a competitive basis through the remedies offered under the escape
clause of the Expansion Act of 1962 with the criteria for such relief changed in
the same manner, that the proposed Trade Expansion Act of 1968 intends to
change the criteria for individual firms and workers.
It is strongly urged that the criteria for relief proposed by the new Act
(H.R. 17551) be changed so that it would be identical for domestic industries,
individual firms workers.
AN OMNIBUS QUOTA BILL SHOULD BE PASSED SO THAT ANY DOMESTIC INDUSTRY
THAT IS INJURED ANI) QUALIFIES UNDER AN ANNOUNCED CRITERIA ~~ULD BE
ABLE TO GET RELIEF FROM RUINOUS IMPORTS
Congress is well aware of the many quota bills presently pending and covering
many imported articles. There is no doubt that at least some are meritorious and
are deserving of Congressional action. Obviously, some of them are merely put
into the hopper by Congressmen in order to appease constituents.
In order to reduce the work load of Congress in this connection and to remove
the doubt as to whether or not a domestic industry is entitled to relief from im-
ports by limiting the amount of such imports, an omnibus quota bill should be
PAGENO="0426"
3862
passed. The criteria for qualifying for relief under such a bill could be spelled
out by Congress and would require an overt act on the part of such industry to
seek relief. Therefore, even if a particular industry may be entitled to relief
under such a bill, the relief would not be forthcoming automatically, but it would
be necessary for the industry to petition for the relief necessary.
Again using the domestic plastic window shade industry as an example, we
can see the need for an omnibus quota bill. Imported plastic window shades are
not specifically provided for under the United States Tariff Schedules. At the
present time they are provided for under the provision for "curtains, drapes, etc."
under Item No. 772.35, and assessed with duty (Kennedy Round) at the rate of
11% ad valorem.
The present classification and rate of duty on imported plastic window shades
is the result of a ruling of the Bureau of Customs rendered on January 8, 1966.
This ruling changed the classification of imported plastic window shades and rate
of duty from 17 percent ad valorem to its present rate of duty.
It is the contention of the domestic plastic window shade industry that the
present classification and rate of duty on imported plastic window shades is
wrong. It therefore, instituted an American manufacturer's protest procedure,
under Section 516(b) of the Tariff Act of 1930 protesting against the action of
the Bureau of Customs. This procedure was commenced well over a year ago and
after many delays and set backs, the matter was finally brought before the United
States Customs Court. On February 7, 1968 a trial was had before the Court
(Joanna Western Mills Company vs. United States) where the issues were liti-
gated. A decision has not yet been rendered.
During this period and continuing, it is believed that imports have been in-
creasing drastically. Because imported plastic window shades are provided for
under a catch-all provision of the Tariff Schedules, and since there are 2 large
importers at the present time, no statistics are available to the domestic industry.
Nevertheless, the articles are seen in the market place of this commodity in
increasing amounts and the competition is keener due to the low cost of the
imported article.
Should the pending Court case be lost by the domestic plastic window shade
industry, it may be necessary to seek Congressional relief. However, an onmibus
quota bifi would probably cover a situation presently encountered by this indus-
try and permit it to qualify for relief under a defined criteria. It would not then
be necessary for this industry to seek Congressional relief.
CLOSER COOPERATION SHOULD BE MAINTAINED BETWEEN THE CUSTOMS BUREAU AND
THE FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION IN APPRAISING THE ULTIMATE CONSUMER OF THE
COUNTRY OF ORIGIN OF IMPORTED ARTICLES
Under Section 304 of the Tariff Act of 1930, as amended, generally, all imported
articles capable of being marked, must be marked with the country of origin.
This marking must be legibily, indelibly, and permanently written in the English
language, and in a conspicuous place. There are several exceptions to this general
rule.
One such exception is that where an article is imported to be manufactured
into another article and the country of origin is known to the manufacturer of
the article in this country, then marking on the article itself is not necessary.
Imported plastic sheeting for manufacture into window shades is an article as
above described. The sheeting itself is not marked with the country of origin.
After importation, it is cut to size and mounted on rollers having spring
mechanisms, and a plastic window shade is produced. The finished article has
no marking on it with the country of origin and the article itself is passed off as
100% produced American window shade.
The imported plastic which has no marking with the country of origin is
permitted entry because it complies with the Custom laws. After importation
the Customs authorities lose control over the importation. However, the ultimate
consumer of the window shade should be apprised of the country of origin of
the plastic material.
In order to apprise the ultimate consumer of the country of origin of the plastic
material, it is urged that the Federal Trade Commission order the shade
manufacturer to attach a tag thereto showing that the completed shade is made
from imported plastic sheeting. It is a relatively simple matter for the Custom
authorities to notify the Federal Trade Commission to advise the manufacturer
to affix the tag. If the ultimate consumer still wants to purchase such a shade, the
choice is entirely his.
PAGENO="0427"
3863
BALANCE OF TRADE PAYMENTS
Our balance of trade payments are linked with and tied up with our trade
balances relative to imports and exports. For years it has been the theory that
we are a solvent country as reflected in at least one instance by our favorable
balance of trade. As a result of this fiction we were advised that in order to
keep up our favorable balance of trade, and in fact increase it, we would have
to reduce tariffs so that other nations could sell their exports to us before they
could buy our exports. This concept was stressed even if it meant the extermi-
nation of some domestic industries which were economically operated and turn
over the production of that article to foreign countries.
As of several weeks ago we no longer have a favorable balance of trade. Our
exports, even including government-financed exports, did not exceed our im-
ports. As recently as May 20, 1968 there appeared in the New York Times a state-
ment made by a Vice President of the overseas division of a very large bank,
who said:
"If Government-financed exports are left out of account, the commercial trade
balance this year may show a deficit of $1.5 to $2.5 billion, compared with a small
commercial surplus last year of $250 million."
Since our export statistics when stripped of government financed shipments
will show an unfavorable balance of trade it reduces considerably the argument
of those who claim that duties must be reduced at any cost in order to be able
to export. We now have an unfavorable balance of trade and practically free
trade. Perhaps it is time to take a hard look at the entire picture of world trade
with a view to domestic industries sharing in it.
Mr. BURKE (presiding). Thank you.
Are there any questions?
There being no questions, we thank you for your testimony.
Is Dr. DePodwin here?
Dr. DePodwin?
Without objection, there being no further witnesses, the committee
will adjourn until 10 a.m. tomorrow.
(Whereupon, at 4:30 p.m., the committee adjourned, to reconvene
at 10 a.m., Wednesday, June 26, 1968.)
0
PAGENO="0428"