PAGENO="0001"
90th Congress } JOINT COMMITTEE PRINT
IMPACT OF THE PROPERTY TAX: ITS
ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS FOR
URBAN PROBLEMS
SUPPLIED BY THE
NATIONAL COMMISSION ON URBAN PROBLEMS
TO THE
JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE
CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES
~ ~
~ 0 ~ ~
COLLFCE ~ ~ ~ IrrsJ~
~ L!Bp~ ~ /
~ ~`4~' ~1. 08102
V
~JUNi ~
MAY 1968 8
~OV. DOC.
Printed for the use of the Joint Economic Committee
U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE
94-0540 WASHINGTON : 1968
sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office
Cf Lj~ ~ Washington, D.C. 20402 - Price 20 cents
PAGENO="0002"
SENATE
JOHN SPARKMAN, Alabama
I. W. FULBRIGHT, Arkansas
HERMAN E. TALMADGE, Georgia
STUART SYMINGTON, Missouri
ABRAHAM RIBICOFF, Connecticut
JACOB K. JAVITS, New York
JACK MILLER, Iowa
LEN B. JORDAN, Idaho
CHARLES H. PERCY, Illinois
WILLIAM H. MOORE
HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES
RICHARD BOLLING, Missouri
HALE BOGGS, Louisiana
HENRY S. REUSS, Wisconsin
MARTHA W. GRIFFITHS, Michigan
WILLIAM S. MOORHEAD, Pennsylvania
THOMAS B. CURTIS, Missouri
WILLIAM B. WIDNALL, New Jersey
DONALD RUMSFELD, flhinois
W. E. BROCK 3o, Tennessee
JOHN B. HENDERSON
DONALD A. WEBSTER (Minority)
(H)
GEORGE R. bEN
JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE
(Created pursuant to sec. 5(a) of Public Law 304, 79th Cong.)
WILLIAM PROXMIRE, Wisconsin, Chairman
WRIGHT PATMAN, Texas, Vice Chairman
JOHN R. STARE, Executive Director
JAMES W. KNOWLES, Director of Research
EcoNo~IIsTs
PAGENO="0003"
LETTER OF TRANSMITTAL
MAY 20, 1968.
To the Members of the Joint Economic Committee:
Transmitted herewith for the use of the members of the Joint
Economic Committee and other Members of Congress is a research
report on the "Impact of the Property Tax" prepared by Prof. Dick
Netzer, of New York University, for the National Commission on
Urban Problems, chaired by former Senator Paul H. Douglas. This
study has been reproduced as a joint committee print because of its
special relevance to the committee's hearings on selected aspects of
the Report of the National Advisory Commission on Civil Disorders.
This paper is the first in a series of studies initiated by the Douglas
commission as a complement to its own staff studies and extensive
public hearings held throughout the country. In this connection, I
would like to commend Chairman Paul H. Douglas for the outstanding
work his commission has undertaken. His leadership continues to set
the same high standards of excellence which he maintained as a U.S.
Senator and provided to the Joint Economic Committee during his
years as chairman. While the committee is pleased to have this study
available for our own inquiry, it is not at this time expressing either
approval or disapproval.
WILLIAM PR0xMIRE,
Chairman, JOint Economic (lommittee.
(III)
PAGENO="0004"
PAGENO="0005"
CONTENTS
Page
Letters of transmittal III
Impact of the Property Tax: study prepared for the National Commission
on Urban Problems VII
(V)
PAGENO="0006"
PAGENO="0007"
IMPACT OF THE PROPERTY TAX
EFFECT ON HOUSING, URBAN LAND USE, LOCAL
GOVERNMENT FINANCE
By DICK NETZER
Professor of Economics, New York University
Prepared for the consideration of
THE NATIONAL COMMISSION ON URBAN PROBLEMS
(VII)
PAGENO="0008"
COMMISSION MEMBERS
PAUL H. DOUGLAS, Chairman
Washington, D.C.
DAVID L. BAKER
Garden Grove, Calif.
HUGO BLACK, Jr.
Miami, Fla.
LEWIS DAVIS
New York, N.Y.
JOHN DEGROVE
Boca Raton, Fla.
ANTHONY DOWNS
Chicago, Ill.
EZRA EHRENKRANTZ
San Francisco, Calif.
ALEX FEINBERG
Camden, N.J.
JEH V. JOHNSON
Poughkeepsie, N .Y.
JOHN LYONS
St. Louis, Mo.
RICHARD W. O'NEILL
New York, N.Y.
BICH~RD RAVITCH
New York, N.Y.
CARL E. SANDERS
Atlanta, Ga.
Mrs. CHLOETHIEL WOODARD
SMITH
Washington, D.C.
To~i J. VANDERGRIFF
Arlington, Tex.
COLEMAN WOODBURY
Madison, Wis.
(VIII)
PAGENO="0009"
NATIONAL COMMISSION ON URBAN PROBLEMS,
Washington, D.C.
Hon. PAUL H. DOUGLAS,
Chairman, National Commission on Urban Problems,
T'Vashington, D.C.
DEAR MR. CHAIRMAN: We are forwarding to you and the CoIn-
mission this first in a series of background study reports on a number
of key issues and problems which the President and the Congress have
asked this Commission to examine. The views expressed in this and
other study reports are those of the authors and do not necessarily
represent those of the Commission or of its individual members.
This report entitled "Impact of the Property Tax" was prepared
by Dr. Dick Netzer, who is professor of economics and the head of
the All-University Department of Economics at New York University.
No one is more qualified to examine this problem than Dr. Netzer
whose work in this field is widely known. He was assisted in his research
by Mr. Stanley Natkins, of the Graduate School of Public Adminis-
tration at New York University~ The study was prepared under the
guidelines devised by Mr. Allen Manvel, associate director of the
staff of the Commission.
Sincerely,
HOWARD E. SHUMAN,
Executive Director.
(IX)
94-054 O-68----2
PAGENO="0010"
PAGENO="0011"
FOREWORD
This study is one of many undertaken by the staff and consultants
to the National Commission on Urban Problems. It is part of the
research effort being undertaken by the Commission prior to its
own recommendations to the President, to Congress, and to the
Secretary of Housing and Urban Development.
The findings and conclusions reached in this property tax study are
those of Dr. Dick Netzer, and do not necessarily reflect the views of
the Commission àr the staff. The report is being released in advance
of the Commission's findings and recommendations because it deals
with one of America's vital urban issues. If the report stirs public
discussion and wider understanding of this issue, its publication \~ill
serve a useful purpose.
This report focuses on one of the specific charges to the Commis-
sion-the study of "local tax policies with respect to their effect on
land and property cost and on incentives to build housing and make
improvements in existing structures" (sec. 301, Housing and Urban
Development Act of 1965). The author, Dr. Netzer, is an authority
on these questions. He finds that the property tax as now constituted
is a deterrent to new housing and to the maintenance of existing
housing, and that it places a particular burden on low-income renters.
A tax ha'ving these characteristics-at a time when some estimates
indicate that about one out of every 10 American dwelling iunits is
substandard-requires urgent attention. The property tax is the
biggest single source of local government financing, and increased
revenues are needed to maintain and upgrade essential local services.
In this context, suggestions for improving and strengthening the tax,
as well as for finding alternatives, are high-priority matters.
In addition to problems of property taxation, the Commission is
charged with studying a number of other matters; namely, building
codes, zoning and land use, housing codes, Federal taxation as it
affects housing, development standards, and how to provide an ade-
quate supply of housing for low-income families.
It is hoped that this and forthcoming background reports, along
with testimony in the Commission's extensive public hearings, will
give insights to the public which are pertinent to the solution of
current city problems.
PAUL H. DOUGLAS, Chairman.
(XI)
PAGENO="0012"
PAGENO="0013"
CONTENTS
Page
URBAN FISCAL PROBLEMS AND PROSPECTS 1
THE URBAN PROPERTY TAX 4
Nature of "the" property tax 4
State use of the tax 5
Legal coverage 5
Assessment organization 6
Role of the tax in urban public finance 6
Wide variations 8
Sources of property tax revenue 12
Property tax considered as a sales tax 13
EFFECTS OF THE PROPERTY TAX IN URBAN AREAS 16
Housing and the tax burden 16
Share paid through rents 17
Special burden on the poor 18
Property tax deters improvements 21
Urban development and land use 22
Central city economics 22
Intrasuburban variations 26
AN APPRAISAL OF THE PROPERTY TAX 29
Effects on housing and urban development 29
Effects on other resource allocation 30
Effects on income distribution 30
Quality of administration 32
Inherent and remediable defects 35
POSSIBLE REMEDIES 36
Increase State-Federal responsibilities 36
Other local revenue sources 39
User charges for public services 39
Local income taxes 40
Land value taxation 41
Taxation of land value increments 43
Improvement of the existing institution 43
Tax base consolidation 44
Fiscalfederation 44
Better administration 45
Hardship adjustments 45
Housing tax incentives 46
Deemphasis
SCOPE OF COMMISSION RESEARCH 47
(XIII)
PAGENO="0014"
PAGENO="0015"
URBAN FISCAL PROBLEMS AND PROSPECTS
In recent years, as throughout the 20 years following World War II,
local and State government public expenditures have been increasing
more rapidly than has the Nation's total output and income. (See
table 1.) Public expenditures in urban areas have always been signifi-
cantly higher, in relative terms, than those in nonurban areas, and re-
cently have been increasing slightly faster, in dollar terms, within the
urban areas. This is to be expected, since nearly all the Nation's popu-
lation growth has been occurring in urban areas. But urban population
growth does iiot explain the rate of increase in public spending. Indeed,
the increase in per capita local government expenditures in metro-
politan areas was more rapid than the increase in aggregate gross
national product between 1957 and 1962.
Perhaps most striking, public expenditures in the larger central
cities have been climbing steeply, despite their losses or slow growth in
population. In the most recent 4-year period for which data are avail-
able, expenditures of municipal governments in the larger cities rose by
27 percent, as shown in table 1-about three-fourths as rapidly as
exl)enditureS of all other local governments combined.
To be sure, substantially more external aid to central cities in the
provision of public services has been forthcoming in recent years. State
and Federal aid to central city governments has risen considerably
more rapidly than have central city expenditures. Also, the direct role
of State governments in the provision of public services in and for the
central cities has expanded considerably. Since the passage of the In-
terstate Highway Act in 1956, the States have been far more active in
the construction of central city highways than previously. In a growing
number of States, the State government is directly involved in urban
mass transportation, in park and open space activities, and in housing
programs. In some States in the Northeast, expansion of State higher
education programs has had an important effect on central city popu-
lations. Desipte all this, the taxes imposed by central city governments,
collected from static populatioiis and slowly growing central city
economies, continue to rise sharply.
The explanation for rising public expenditures in urban areas is not
hard to find. In the central cities, local-tax-financed outlays for services
directly linked to poverty (in the health and welfare fields) have not
been static; the central cities of the 12 largest metropolitan areas ac-
count for one-eighth of the country's population, but nearly two-fifths
of health and welfare outlays financed from local taxes. For central
city governments, the problems associated with poverty and race are
by far the most urgent of public problems.
(1~
PAGENO="0016"
2
TABLE 1.-Percentage increases in non-Federal public expenditures, 1957-62 and
1962-65/66
Perce
ntage increase
1957-62
1062-65/66
Gross national product 1
Total expenditures:
All State and local governments
27
48
33
35
All local governments
46
35
Local governments in metropolitan areas-
all SMSA's 2
47
(3)
38 largest areas
Central city governments in large cities ~. - -
Per capita expenditures:
All State and local governments
(3)
31
36
.
34
27
28
All local governments
34
28
Local governments in metropolitan areas-
all SMSA's
30
(3)
38 largest areas
(3)
24
1 For calendar years 1957-62 and 1962-66.
2 For identical collections of metropolitan areas in 1957 and 1962.
Not available.
4 rncludes only the municipal government (excludes separate overlapping county, school district, and
special district governments); for the 42 cities with a 1960 population of more than 300,000 excluding
Honolulu.
5 Based on estimated 1957, 1962, and 1966 populations.
Source: Adapted from various publications of the U.S. Census Bureau, Governments Division.
Neither poverty nor racial disabilities can be eliminated solely by
governmental action, and still less by action by local or State and
local governments combined (that is, governments other than the
Federal Government). But local governments do have a major respon-
sibility to grapple with these problems and can make a major contri-
bution toward their alleviation. In the American system of govern-
ment, it is local governments which are responsible for providing edu-
cational services that over time will have a major bearing on the
chances the poor and racially disadvantaged have to overcome their
disadvantages. Local governments are also responsible for a. wide
range of health and welfare services, which are almost entirely oriented
toward the poor in American cities. They have had, since the. late
forties, major responsibilities in connection with the housing of the
poor. And, as far as the poor are concerned, local government recrea-
tional facilities are about the only recreational facilities available.
A second major set of problems confronting the older central cities
lies in the fact that they have a huge legacy of obsolescence. Their
stock of housing and other social capital-that. is, public and quasi-
public facilities of all kinds-is old, often physically deteriorated,
and generally far from competitive with the new parts of the same
urban areas. It may be, as some have argued, that the best national
policy would be to allow this obsolescence to continue, and allow fur-
ther deterioration of the older parts of the older cities. In this case,
population would decline in these sections and, Presumably at some
stage, values would be so low that private renew-al of such areas would
become possible. Or, if desirable, public renewal could be undertaken,
but on the basis of exceedingly low values.
Developments in recent years suggest that this is hardly a likely
course of action. For one thing, there is the plight of those who, be-
PAGENO="0017"
3
cause they are poor, or Negro, or both, have little chance to escape
the deteriorating areas. Amelioration for these hundreds of thousands
of people is both politically and morally necessary. Quite apart from
moral isues, most cities and the Federal Government appear to have
decided that it is necessary to replace obsolete social capital and to
compete for residents and businesses in an atmosphere of rising ex-
pectations. That is, the cities feel they must offer an environment of
pTlbhc facilities and services which, together with other attractions
that the central locations may have, offset the blandishments of the
newer and presumably more modern sections of the metropolitan areas
where standards of public services and amenity are high indeed.
In the newer sections of metropolitan areas-the new portions of
central cities as well as the urbanizing fringes of the metropolitan
area-the main governmental problem is the provision of the new
social capital needed by a rising population, and a population which
has peculiarly heavy demands for public services and facilities, notably
schools.
In the aggregate, these urban problems have caused a diversion of
resources from private to public use, via tax increases. This relative
expansion of the public sector is costly in another way.
If local governments are to command resources, they must pay prices
for these resources which are competitive with those prevailing in the
economy, notably salaries of public employees. If they are to expand
more Tapicily than the private sector, they must bid away resources
by paying even more. This they are doing, as is shown by the rapid
increase in urban government salary levels, especially for occupational
groups whose talents are in heavy demand in the private sector.
As table 1 suggests, the rate of increase in the expenditure of urban
governments is not tapering off; if anything, it is increasing. This is
consistent with our observations of the urban fiscal scene (with almost
continual fiscal crises), and our observations of the urban social scene,
with the huge unmet needs for new and improved public services. But
these trends do conflict with some of the recent projections of the
outlook for State and local finances in the decade ahead. These projec-
tions are generally optimistic, in that they foresee no great fiscal
strains, largely because of an expected tapering off of the rate ~f the
increase in expenditure.
The projections may be right, but there is room for skepticism. For
example, the projections have not allowed for the recent surge in
expenditure for public assistance programs. Between 1962 and 1965-66,
local government public welfare expenditures rose by nearly 50 per-
cent, a rate of increase nearly double that found in the more compre-
hensive sets of projections; in New York State, public welfare
expenditures will be more than double those implied by the projections
sponsored by the Council of State Governments.'
`For a recent evaluation of the projections, see Revenue Sharing and Its Alter-
natives, hearings before the Subcommittee on Fiscal Policy of the Joint Economic
Committee, U.S. Congress, July 31-Aug. 3, 1967, especially pp. 65-106.
94-054 O-68--3
PAGENO="0018"
THE URBAN PROPERTY TAX
All of this is, of course, relevant to an appraisal of the property
tax, since the property tax is by far the largest single source of funds
to finance public services in urban areas. If, as seems likely, urban
public expenditure continues to rise sharply, and if there are ~io major
changes in fiscal institutions, the property tax will bear a large share
of the burden; the various deficiencies of the tax will be aggravated by
its use at continually increasing rates.
NATnRE OF "THE" PROPERTY TAX
A century ago, the property tax in nearly all States was one which,
in law, applied at a uniform rate to all forms of ~rivately owned
wealth (with exemptions for charitable and similar organizations)
within a taxing jurisdiction-to all types of real property, to tangible
personal property, and to wealth in intangible forms, notably bank
deposits and securities. Even then, the property tax differed greatly
among the thousands of local units employing the tax. The level and
composition of legally taxable wealth varied widely; the effectiveness
with which local assessors discovered and valued this wealth also
varied widely; and the ratios of public expenditures financing by the
tax to assessed values had a wide range, producing major variation
in tax rates, whether measured as a fraction of assessed values or of
the underlying market value of the taxable forms of property.
All these sources of variation continue to exist., to a pronounced
extent, among the 70,000 or so local govermnent units which are au-
thorized to levy property taxes. But., in addition, the generality of the
property tax has been substantially reduced by successive State stat-
utory and constitutional enactments exempting various classes of
personal property from the ordinary general property tax. A further
complication is that some of these exemptions have been accompanied
by new forms of property taxation on the exempted classes of prop-
erty, most commonly on intangibles, motor vehicles and public utility
property; these "special property taxes" have rates which are not those
applied in general property taxation, but usually a uniform statewide
rate. Still another complication is that the State governments, all of
which relied heavily on the property tax in the 19th century, have
withdrawn from property taxation, though in varying degrees.
The result has been to create distinctive statewide property tax
systems in each of the 50 States (and the District of Columbia), im-
posing 51 different legal patterns on top of the wide intrastate varia-
tion in taxable wealth, administrative performance, and fiscal require-
ments. *Thus, there are really 70,000 or so different property taxes in
the United States, grouped into 51 systems with common legal settings.
As of 1962, nearly 96 percent of all property tax revenue came from
local government general property taxation; for the purposes of this
report, this major component of the tax will be treated as if it. were
(4)
PAGENO="0019"
5
the entire property tax. Another 1 percent of property tax revenue
came from local special property taxes, and about 3 percent of the
revenue accrued to State governments, mostly in the form of special
property taxes.2
STATE USE OF THE TAX
Although the State share of the tax is small in the aggregate, it is
not uniformly so. Consider the 47 States (including the District of
Columbia) containing standard metropolitan statistical areas
(SMSA's). In 21 of them, State property tax revenue amounted to 1
percent or less of total State-local property tax revenue in 1965-66.
In another 14, the percentage ranged between two and five. At the other
extreme, there were four States in which the State government per-
centage was more than 15.~
However, in nearly all the large urban concentrations, the State
share of property tax revenue is very low. In all except five of the
States containing very large SMSA's-the 38 largest with populations
over 700,000-the State share was 5 percent or less.4
LEGAL COVERAGE5
The process of exemption has gone furthest with respect to intangi-
ble personal property, for two rather obvious reasons. First, some
forms of intangibles (like securities) are easily concealed and all
forms are highly mobile; this makes assessment of intangibles extra-
ordinarily difficult and comes close to converting the tax into one on
honesty. Second, even if the assets could be discovered readily, a gen-
eral property tax at the rates common in this country-5 percent and
more-is a confiscatory tax when applied to the conventional low-yield
liquid assets; consider, for example, a 5-percent tax on demand de-
posits in commercial banks, which bear no interest at all.
In any event, there are no local property taxes on intangibles in 20
of the 47 SMSA States and in 11 of the 23 States with the largest
SMSA's-over 700,000 population. In 14 of the SMSA States (and,
eight of the large SMSA States), there are local special property
taxes, usually applied at very low rates, on some forms of intangibles.
In 13 of the SMSA States, some or all types of intangibles are subject
to local general property taxation, but even in these cases, intangibles
generally amount to only trivial proportions of total assessed values.
In Illinois, for example, intangibles valuations amount to only about 1
percent of total assessed values, and barely equal 3 percent of total
privately owned bank deposits, not to mention the vast array of other
types of intangibles which are also legally subject to tax.
Some forms of tangible personal property are subject to local gen-
eral property taxation in all except foui of the SMSA States. The
From U.S. Census Bureau, Property Taxation in 1962 (State and Local Gov-
ernment Special Studies No. 47, November 1964).
From TJ.S. Census Bureau, Governmental Finances in 1965-66 (1967).
This grouping of SMSA's is related to data availability and will be used fre-
quently in subsequent paragraphs. The Census Bureau now publishes annual
data on the finances of local governments in these areas.
The information in this section is for 1961, from U.S. Census Bureau, 1962
Census of Governments, vol. II, Taxable Property T7alues (1963, revised August
1964), pp. 5-6.
PAGENO="0020"
6
great bulk of taxable personal property consists of business machinery
and equipment and inventories. Household goods are generally taxed
and fully taxable in only nine of the SMSA States. Motor vehicles
comprise a significant part of the tax base in some, but by no means
all, metropolitan areas, as the following tabulation shows:
Number of S
tates containing
SMSA's
Large SMSA's
Taxed under local general property tax
21
7
Taxed under local special property tax
5
2
No local property taxes
21
14
ASSESSMENT ORGANIZATION
Another dimension of interstate property tax system differentials
is the geographic organization for assessment. This is of significance
from the standpoint of concern about fiscal disparities within metro-
politan areas, or at least from the standpoint of obtaining information
about these disparities. The smaller the geographic unit at which the
assessment is done, the more difficult it is to utilize available informa-
tion on taxable capacity and tax rates for local government units
within a single metropolitan area~, since individual assessing districts
may assess taxable wealth at very different proportions of its market
\Taliie
In 12 of the 47 SMSA States (and 7 of the 23 large SMSA States),
assessment is done by city, village, and town officers, rather than by
countywide assessment organizations. In several other States, the pat-
tern is a mixed one, with some countywide assessment. In two-thirds
of the SMSA States (and 13 of the 23 large SMSA States), county-
wide assessment is the general rule, for metropolitan areas.
ROLE OF THE TAX IN URBAN PUBLIC FINANCE
Prior to the 1930's, the property tax provided three-fourths or more
of the general revenue of American local governments aiid more than
four-fifths of their locally raised general revenue (that is, excluding
payments from other levels of government), as table 2 shows. Largely
because of the greatly increased grants-rn-aid for welfare and school
purposes from State and Federal governments, the property tax de-
clined sharply as a proportion of total general revenue in the 1930's
and 1940's. From the early 1950's to the early 1960's, the property tax
stabilized at just under half of total general revenue. However, in
the past few years, a slow decline in its relative role apparently has
resumed (see Figure 1), again largely due to increased grants-in-aid.
In a sense, table 2 understates the long-term decline in the relative
role of the property tax in the financing of urban public services.
State governments are important direct providers of public services,
through State government agencies, in addition to their indirect role
in financing local government~. The more important direct State gov-
ernment services include highways, public assistance (in a majority of
the States), higher education, mental hospitals and correction. The
relative importance of direct State government expenditure has risen
PAGENO="0021"
7
H,gi CONTRIBUTION OF PROPERTY TAXES TO LOCAL GOVERNMENT
REVENUE (selected years, 1927 to 1966)
Percent
~
40 __ 7 __
.111
1927 1946 1956 1965-66
source: table 2
considerably since the 1920's. But in the 1920's, the States still relied
to an important extent on the property tax, which is no longer true.
Taking this into account, the property tax probably finances less than
one-third of the costs of State-local urban services today, compared to
over two-thirds in the 1920's.
TABLE 2.-Trends in the role of the property tax in local government finances, 1927
to 1965-66'
[In percent]
1961-66
1962
1956 1946 1927
Property tax revenue as percent of total
local government general revenue:
All local governments
Local governments in 38 largest
SMSA's2
45
47
48
50
49 58 74
Other areas
43
46
Property tax revenue as percent of locally
raised general revenue:
Alllocalgovcrnments
Local governments in 38 largest
SMSA's 2
67
66
69
68
69 78 82
Other areas
69
70
on u.s. census Bureau, 1962 Census ef Gevernments, vol. vi, No. 4, Historical Statistics en Gerern-
snental Finances and Employment (1964) and Leral Gerernment Finances in Selected A1etrapelitan Areas in
1965-66 (1967).
2 Those with pcpulations over 700,000.
3 Total general revenue less revenue from other governments.
PAGENO="0022"
8
If intergovernmental payments are ignored and attention is focused
on general revenue raised from local sources, the decline in the rela-
tive importance of the property tax was concentrated in the late 1940's
and early 1950's, to consequence of increased utilization of local non-
property tax sources. On a nationwide basis, however, the property
tax continues to provide about two-thirds of locally raised general
revenue, both within and outside the major urban concentrations.
Moreover, the relative decline merely reflects a n~ore rapid increase in
other revenue-in absolute terms, property tax revenue continues to
rise sharply. In the period of less than 4 years, from 1962 to 1965-66,
property tax revenue rose by nearly 30 percent-$5.4 billion on a
nationwide basis and $2.7 billion in the 38 largest SMSA's.
Because State aid looms relatively larger in the finances of local
governments in the less urbanized parts of the country, the property
tax accounts for a larger proportion of local government general
revenue in the largest SMSA's than elsewhere, but a smaller propor-
tion of locally raised general revenue, because nonproperty taxes are
largely an urban phenomenon (table 3). Also, as is to be expected,
property tax revenue is substantially higher on a per capita basis in
the larger urban areas.
WIDE VARIATIONS
There is considerable variation among the major urban areas in the
extent of their dependence on the property tax. In part, this is a con-
sequence of State aid arrangements, but this is by no means the whole
story. By far the most important differential in State aid provisions
relates to assignment of the responsibility for administration of public
assistance. Where the State government handles public assistance,
State grants to local government for welfare purposes are, quite
naturally, very small; where the local governments have the adminis-
trative responsibility, it is accompanied by sizable grants from the
States. Thus, in the 21 large SMSA's where public assistance is pri-
marily a local responsibility, intergovernmental revenue per capita
in 1965-66 was $120; in the other 17 large SMSA's, with primary State
government responsibility for public assistance, the corresponding
figure was only $66.
However, as table 3 shows, relative dependence on the property tax
differed little in the two types of areas. This suggests that the prop-
erty tax (much higher on a per capita basis in the local welfare respon-
sibility SMSA's) finances a not inconsiderable share of the locally
raised expenditure for public assistance. It also suggests that differ-
ences among areas in reliance on the property tax cannot be explained
mainly by State aid difference. In fact, the major source of the differ-
ence appears to be the extent to which local nonproperty taxes are
employed.
These differences are large ones. In SMSA's located in States where
local nonproperty taxes are virtually nonexistent-in New England,
New Jersey, and Indiana, for example-the property tax accounts for
80 to 90 percent of locally raised general revenue. By contrast, in
SMSA's where income taxes are widely used by local governments,
such as Cincinnati and Pittsburgh, the property tax percentage is only
about 60. In Illinois and California SMSA's, where sales taxes are
used widely by local governments, the property tax percentage is in the
65 to 70 range.
PAGENO="0023"
9
TABLE 3.-The role of the pro pery tax in local government finances, 1965-66 1
38 largest SMSA's2
Areas where welfare
All local
governments
Outside 38
largest
SMSA's
Total 38
SMSA's
primary responsi-
bility of-
State Local
govern- govern-
ment ment
Property tax revenue as
percent of-
Total general revenue -
Locally raised general
45
43
47
48 46
revenue4
Property tax revnue:
In millions
Percapita5
67
69
66
64 67
$23, 836
123
$11, 573
101
$12, 263
154
$3, 954 $8, 309
121 177
1 Based on U.S. Bureau of the Census, Local Government Finances in Selected Metropolilan Areas in 1965-66
(1967 and Governmental Finances in 1965-66 (1967).
2 Those with populations over 700,000.
3 The classification is based on statewide ratios of State government direct expenditure for public welfare
and of local government direct expenditure for public welfare to total public welfare expenditure. 15 of the
areas are in States in which State direct expenditure in 1965-66 was 75 percent or more of the total and another
2 in States with State/State-local ratios of 50-75 percent. 17 are in States with local/State-local ratios of 75
percent or more and another 4 in States with local/State-local ratios of 50-75 percent.
4 Total general revenue less revenue from other governments.
5 1965-66 revenue divided by estimated July 1, 1965, population.
Even lower percentages can be found in some areas dominated by
large central cities which rely very heavily on nonproperty taxes. (The
instances cited in the preceding paragraph concern SMSA's in which
both central city and suburban governments employ such taxes.) As
table 4 shows, the property tax looms much larger in local government
finances in the large SMSA's for county governments, school districts,
and small municipalities and townships than it does for the central
city governments, which on the average obtain barely over half-51
percent-of their locally raised general revenue from the property tax.
TABLE 4.-Dependence on the property tax by local governments in the 38 largest
SMSA's, 1965-66, by type of Government 1
Type of government
Property tax reve
nue as percent of-
Total local
government
general revenue
Locally raised
general revenue 2
All local governments in 38 largest SMSA's
Counties
Municipalities
(34 central cities with 1960 populations of
300,000 or more)
(Other municipalities)
Townships
School districts-
Special districts
47
46
39
(37)
(47)
65
55
27
66
75
53
(51)
(58)
80
88
32
1 Based on U.S. Bureau of the Census, Local Government Finances in Selected Metropolitan Areas in 1965-66
(1967) and City Government Finances in 1965-66 (1967).
2 Total general revenue less revenue from other governments.
PAGENO="0024"
10
In general, the property tax finances a significantly smaller share
of the costs of public services in central cities than in outlying parts of
the larger metropolitan areas, because of use of nonproperty taxes by
the municipal governments in most of the large central cities. This is
illustrated by the first two columns in table 5, for 11 large SMSA's.°
In nine of the 11 areas, the relatively smaller role of the property tax
in the central cities is evident. In the Baltimore area the differences are
small, and in New Orleans the property tax is relatively insignificant
in both central city and suburbs. But despite the smaller relative im-
pOrtance of central city property taxes, on a per capital basis property
tax collections in the central cities are equal to or greater than such
tax collections in the suburbs, except in the Washington, New York,
and Philadelphia areas, as shown in the last two columns of table 5 and
in figure 2. And in these three cases, the disparity in the relative role of
the property tax is greater than the disparity in the per capita prop-
erty tax revenue; that is, the very heavy use of nonproperty taxes more
than offsets the lower per capita property tax payments. This is just
another way of making the common observation that tax burdens are,
in most cases, greater in central cities than in suburbs; usually this is
reflected in the property tax data, but elsewhere the explanation lies
in nonproperty taxes.
~ SMSA's selected for table 5 are, with two exceptions, those in which the
central city is an independent city not in any county, or has a combined city-
county government structure, thus simplifying the comparison. The exceptions
are Chicago and Detroit.
TABLE 5.-The property tax in local government finances: Central cities versus out-
lying parts of selected large SMSA's, 1965-66 1
Area 2
Property tax revenue
as percent of locally
raised general revenue
Central city Outlying
Property tax revenue per
capita
Central city
Outlying
Baltimore
73 71
$136
$108
Boston3
82 87
258
177
Chicago4
71 79
156
157
Denver
65 80
164
143
Detroit5
69 74
156
130
New Orleans
39 34
48
37
New York
Philadelphia
St. Louis
48 88
46 70
44 76
175
88
111
234
121
114
San Francisco6
68 72
253
238
Washington, D.C
29 70
110
131
1 Based on U.S. Bureau of the Census, Local Government Finances in Selected Metropolitan Areas, 1965-66
(1967).
2 Except where otherwise indicated, the central city is the city named in the stub and the outlying parts
of the area comprise the remainder of the SMSA.
The "central city" is Suffolk County; the SMSA is Massachusetts State economic area C.
The "central city" is the whole of Cook County.
2 The "central city" is the whole of Wayne County.
The outlying parts exclude Alameda County, because Oakland has central city characteristics.
PAGENO="0025"
$300
11
Fig.2 PROPERTY TAXES IN SELECTED LARGE METROPOLITAN AREAS,
1965-6 6
(Per capita amounts)
SMSA $100 $200
BALTIMORE
BOSTON
CHICAGO 1/
DENVER
DETROIT 2/
NEW ORLEANS
NEW YORK
PHILADELPHIA
ST. LOUIS
SAN FRANCISCO
WASHINGTON, D.C.
OUTLYING AREA E~
CENTRAL CITY ~~;;
source: table 5
94-054 O-68----4
1/ `Central city' is whole of Cook County.
2/ `Central city' is whole of Wayne County.
3/ `Outlying area' excludes Alameda County.
PAGENO="0026"
12
SOURCES OF PROPERTY TAX REVENUE
Cutting across the geographic variations, there is an important eco-
nomic distinction in property taxation. The tax can be viewed as
comprising two distinct forms of taxation, with quite different eco-
nomic characteristics.
The first is the tax on residential property and on consumer-owned
personal property, where the latter is subject to tax, largely consisting
of motor vehicles. This tax is one of selected types of consumer ex-
penditure, with economic effects similar to those of other types of
consumption taxes.
The second is the tax on real and personal property used in business
and agriculture. Its economic effects are in some ways similar to those
of other forms of business taxation, but are dissimilar in other ways.
The dissimilarities take three major forms. First, this is a tax on
business inputs-land and capital-rather than on profits or gross
receipts, the base of the predominant nonproperty types of business
taxation. Second, the impact of the tax therefore varies among indus-
tries on the basis of the structure of inputs, falling most heavily on
those which employ large amounts of land, buildings, equipment and
inventories relative to output. Third, few other forms of business
taxation vary so much among small geographic areas-they are usually
statewide or nationwide in scope.
Table 6 indicates the estimated distribution of assessed values sub-
ject to general property taxation in SMSA's in 1961. Based upon the
not unreasonable assumption that the sources of SMSA local govern-
ment property tax revenue closely reflect this distribution of assessed
values, a crude estimate of 1962 property tax revenue by type of
1)roperty is presented in table 7. Roughly half of the revenue was
derived from taxes on housing and another 42 percent from taxes on
nonfarm business property. The remaining 8 percent includes taxes on
farm property (as expected, this is minor in urban areas), taxes on
consumer-owned tangible personal property, and taxes on property
which cannot reasonably be allocated between businesses and house-
holds, like vacant lots and intangibles.
TABLE 6.-Estimated distribution of assessed values subject to
taxation in SMSA's, by type of property, 1961 1
general property
Type of property
In billions
Percent distribution
Total
Single-family houses
Other housing
Acreage and farms
$244.6
100.0
97. 1
25. 1
6.8
39. 7
10.2
2.8
\Tacant lots
5.3
2.2
Railroad and public utility property 2
Commercial realty
16. 6
36.2
6. 8
14.8
Industrial realty 2 3
Other real property ~
19. 9
1. 0
8. 2
. 4
Personal property 2
36. 7
15. 0
1 Adapted from U.S. Census Bureau, 1962 Census of Governments, vol. II, Taxable Property Values (1963;
revised August 1964). Involves the following estimates by the author: distribution by property type of partial
exemptions; distribution by property type of State-assessed property; public utility property included in
reported data on induitrial realty (locally assoncd).
2 Includes both State-assessed and locally assessed property.
3 Excluding railroad and public utility property.
About $400,000,000 is separately assessed mineral rights.
Note: Because of rounding, detail may not add to totals.
PAGENO="0027"
13
TABLE 7.-Crude estimate of sources of local government property tax revenue in
SMSA's, by type of property, 1962 1
Type of property
Percent distribution
Housing2
Railroad and public utility property
Other real and personal property used in nonfarm business `.~_
Other
50
7
35
8
Total
100
1 Based on distribution of assessed values in table 6, adjusted for estimated revenue from local government
special property taxes and its distribution by property type.
2 Includes estimated housing property listed as acreage and farms.
3 Includes separately assessed mineral rights; 80 percent of all personal property; and commercial and
industrial realty.
4 Includes agricultural property; vacant lots; consumer-owned motor vehicles; household goods; intangi-
bles subject to general property taxes; and other and unallocable real property.
PROPERTY TAX CONSIDERED AS A SALES TAX
The half of the property tax revenue which comes from taxes on
housing can be compared, if they are considered to be consumption
taxes, to consumer expenditure for housing. In 1962, cash outlays for
housing by SMSA homeowners and rental payments by SMSA renters
amounted to an estimated $34.9 billion.7 Housing property taxes
amounted to 19 percent of this total; they amounted to 24 percent of
housing expenditure excluding th~ tax paymei~ts, which is the conven-
tional American way of looking at other forms of consumption taxa-
tion.8 Business property taxes, on the other hand, can best be com-
pared to the value of business output-in this case, estimated national
income originating in nonf arm private business enterprises in
SMSA's. Business property taxes amounted to about 2.4 percent of
this total in 1962, in SMSA's.°
There are significant geographic differences in the relative roles of
housing and business property as sources of property tax revenue.
Quantification of these differences for entire metropolitan areas is
complicated by the existence of so many submetropolitan assessment
organizations, with differing levels of assessment. In table 8, data are
presented for 19 areas, mostly single counties in multicounty SMSA's,
for which the assessment-level problem can be overcome and for which
there are available central city data. Housing comprises only 20 per-
cent of the property tax base in the Atlanta area,1° but nearly 70 per-
cent of the tax base in the San Antonio area. However, most of the
areas cluster around the 50-percent level.
This is an updating to 1962 of 1960 housing census data, based on changes in
the housing stock and in the housing components of the Consumer Price Index
between 1960 and 1962.
This analysis is amplified below-.
Corporate profits tax liability in 1962 amounted to 9.4 percent of national
income originating in corporate business, on a nationwide basis. This includes
State as well as Federal corporate profits taxes.
10 This is because homestead exceptions amount to roughly 20 percent of the
gross assessed value of taxable property in Georgia; these exemptions, by defini-
tion, apply almost entirely to housing in urban areas.
PAGENO="0028"
14
TABLE 8.-Housing as a percent of assessed values subject to general property taxation
ire selected metropolitan county areas, 1961 1
Area
Entire
designated
Central
city
Outlying
portions
area
Bexar County, Tex. (San Antonio)
68. 6
61. 9
93. 4
Washington, D.C., plus Montgomery and Prince
Georges Counties, Md
Shelby County, Tenn. (Memphis)
Maricopa County, Ariz. (Phoenix) 1
San Diego County, Calif. (San Diego) 1
Tarrant County, Tex. (Fort Worth)
Franklin County, Ohio (Columbus)
Los Angeles County, Calif. (Los Angeles) 1
59. 4
55. 7
53. 9
53. 6
52. 7
51. 7
51. 0
52. 3
55. 0
52. 4
53. 5
51. 3
48. 1
51. 1
68. 0
58. 1
49. 4
53. 8
55. 9
58. 6
50. 9
Cook County, Ill. (Chicago)
Hamilton County, Ohio (Cincinnati)
Multnomah County, Oreg. (Portland) 1
King County, Wash. (Seattle)
Alameda County, Calif. (Oakland) 1
Jefferson County, Ky. (Louisville)
Lucas County, Ohio (Toledo)
Cuyahoga County, Ohio (Cleveland)
Jackson County, Mo. (Kansas City)
Jefferson County, Ala. (Birmingham)
Fulton County, Ga. (Atlanta) 1
50. 4
48. 1
46. 4
46. 3
45. 5
44. 7
42. 5
39. 8
39. 6
37. 7
20. 6
44.4
43. 1
44. 0
43. 8
39. 6
41. 3
42. 9
25. 7
35. 7
37. 3
21. 5
61. 4
53. 8
54. 1
50. 3
49. 9
47. 8
41. 9
54. 8
57. 6
38. 2
14. 8
1 Adapted from U.S. Census Bureau, 1962 Census of Government, vol. II, Taxable Property Values (1963;
revised, August 1964). The areas selected met 2 criteria: (1) assessed vlue data for the central city were
shown in the census volume; and (2) countywide assessment prevails, so that the census county-area data are
not distorted by differing assessment levels. The 1 exception is Washington, D.C.; the 2 Maryland counties
appear to have assessment ratios similar to those in the central city. In the referenced (1) cases, partia ex-
emptions were allocated between housing and other property types by the author; except in the case of
Atlanta, these were of minor consequence and the estimates do not affect the results significantly.
Despite the increasing decentralization of economic activity in met-
ropolitan areas, most central cities continue to have substantially
heavier concentrations of business activity within their boundaries
than do the outlying parts of their metropolitan areas. At the same
time, the central cities have relatively more low-quality housing than
do the suburbs, and substantially more multifamily housing (which is
generally less valuable, per unit, than single-family housing, even if
of equivalent quality). Therefore, housing usually comprises a lower
proportion of the tax base in central cities than in suburban areas.
This is true for 13 of the 19 areas in table 8, especially for Chicago,
Cleveland, Kansas City, Washington, D.C., and Oakland. The housing
share is roughly similar in central city and suburbs in five cases; it is
significantly higher only for Atlanta, where the outlying sections are
small in population relative to the central city."
There do not appear to be systematic regiona~ differences in the
housing share of the metropolitan area tax base; the areawide differ-
ences appear to be related more to the legal coverage of the tax (a
function of State laws), and to specific economic characteristics of
individual metropolitan areas. However, table 8, as well as data for
other areas not shown in the table, suggest that the central city-sub-
urban disparities in the housing share are sharpest in the Northeast
111t should be observed that table 8 deals primarily with individual major
counties rather than with entire metropolitan areas. However, of the 19 areas
listed, seven consist of entire single-county SMSA's as defined in 1961. The seven
are Bexar, Shelby, Maricopa, San Diego, Franklin, Lucas, and Jefferson.
PAGENO="0029"
15
and Midwest. This seems to be related to two factors. First, the large
older central cities in these regions developed in an era in which nearly
all economic activity was concentrated in the central cities, and they
still retain much of this activity, particularly commercial activity. In
contrast, the newer parts of the country have developed with a more
dispersed pattern of activity from the start. Second, the large old
cities do have very large blocks to old low-quality and low-value
housing and some of them have very large proportions of multifamily
housing. This suggests two rather distinct groups of metropolitan
areas, insofar as the effects of the property tax are concerned.
One additional partial explanation for the disparities in the housing
share of the tax base lies in the frequent favorable treatment of
housing by central city assessors, which is discussed at greater length
in a subsequent section. For example, were housing and business prop-
erty assessed at similar fractions of market value in cities like Chicago,
a substantial fraction of the apparent central city-suburban disparity
in tax base composition would disappear, but by no means all of the
disparity.
PAGENO="0030"
EFFECTS OF THE PROPERTY TAX IN URBAN AREAS
HOUSING AND THE TAX BURDEN
As suggested previously, the property tax on housing is analogous
to taxes commonly known as consumption taxes; that is, general sales
and selective excise taxes. Like the ordinary consumption taxes, the
great bulk of the burden of the housing property tax appears to rest
upon housing consumers, whether they are owner-occupants or ten-
ants. There are some exceptions; the chief one is that owners of rental
property canot shift the burden of that portion of the tax which falls
on the land underlying their buildings. But, for the country as a whole,
probably well over 90 percent of all property taxes on housing are
borne by housing occupants.
Since this is so, it is useful to view property taxes in relation to con-
sumer expenditures for housing. This expresses the relationship in a
form similar to that with which we are familiar in connection with
other consumption taxes-a sales tax of 4 percent of taxable purchases,
for example. There are two sets of data available to illustrate this re-
lationship. The first expresses property taxes as percentages of the esti-
mated rental value of housing (as found in the national income ac-
counts).
As table 9 shows, property taxes average about 19 percent of the
rental value of nonfarm housing in the United States currently, equiv-
alent to an excise tax of nearly 24 percent on rental value, excluding
property taxes (parallel to the way in which sales tax rates are stated,
as percentages of sales before sales tax is added).
The second set of relationships, also shown in table 9, is perhaps a
more realistic one, from the standpoint of housing consumers them-
selves. This is the relationship noted in the previous section, and esti-
mated for all SMSA's as of 1962. (The table 9 data are for 1960.) It
expresses taxes as percentages of actual cash outlays for housing-
expenses of owner-occupants or rental payments of tenants. The per-
centages are very high expressed in this way, too, especially outside
the South. Converted to a before-tax form, they range-excluding the
South-from sales-tax-equivalent rates of 18 percent for large apart-
ment houses outside New York City to 30 percent or more for single-
family houses in the Northeast, and multifamily properties in New
York City. In general, the upper end of this range applies to most of
the Nation's large cities outside the South.
(10)
PAGENO="0031"
17
TABLE 9.-Property taxes on housing as percent of housing expenditure
1960 1065
I. In relation to rental value of nonfarm housing
(national income data): 1
Owner-occupied housing 18. 1 18. 9
Rental housing 19. 3 19.4
All nonfarm housing 18. 5 19. 1
II. In relation to actual housing expenditure or rents
(census data) : 2
Owner-occupied single-family houses-
All United States 17
In standard metropolitan statistical
areas 19
Northeast region 24
North central~~~~_ 20
South 10
West 18
Rental properties-
1-4 unit properties 17
5-49 unit properties 17
New York City 23
Elsewhere 16
50-or-more unit properties 20
New York City 23
Elsewhere 15
1 Includes the imputed rental value of owner-occupied houses. Based on data in U.S. Department of
Commerce. The National Income and Product Accounts of the United States, 1929-65, A Supplement to the
Survey of Current Business (1966). Taxes on rental property estimated by the author.
2 Based on 1960 Census of Housing data, including special tabulations for New York City. The data,
except for the New York figures, appear in Netzer, Economics of the Property Tax (Brookings Institution,
1966), tables 2-8 and 5-6. For owner-occupied houses, taxes are expressed as percentages of annual cash
housing outlays by owners; for rental properties, taxes are expressed as percentages of rental receipts for
mortgaged properties.
SHARE PAID THROUGH RENTS
What this means is that very large numbers of urban families pay,
via their rents, or directly if owner-occupants, taxes which amount to
very sizable increments to their housing costs. This is shown more
directly in table 10, which contains a distribution of housing units in
multifamily rental housing subject to property taxes amounting to a
sales tax equivalent of 20 percent or more. New York City is broken
out, because it accounts for so large a fraction of the multifamily
housing stock (about one-fourth), because its property tax rates are
high (though no higher than in most other cities in tile Northeast and
a few elsewhere), and because its sales-tax-equivalent tax rates are
so high (in part because rent control keeps rents, the denominator of
the fraction, down). For the country as a whole, as of 1960, 3.6 million
households-more than half the total in this type of housing-were
subject to rates of 20 percent or more, and 1.2 million were subject to
rates in excess of 33.3 percent.
PAGENO="0032"
18
TABLE 10.-Estimated number of households living in rental housing subject to high
property tax rates, 1960 1
[In thousands]
Real estate tax relative to rental receipts, stated as
a sales tax equivalent 2
New York
City
Elsewhere in
United States
U.S. total
33.3 percent or more
541
676
1,217
25 to 33.3 percent
20 to 25 percent
Total, 20 percent or more
568
293
513
1, 021
1,081
1, 314
1, 402
2, 210
3, 612
1 Adapted from U.S. Census Bureau, 1960 Census of Housing, vol. V, Residential Finance, pt. 2, Rental
and Vacant Properties and from special tabulations for New York City. The census data for this purpose
cover only mortgaged properties acquired before 1919; the estimates shown here have been adjusted to cover
all rental properties. These data cover only properties with 5 units or more.
2 Real estate tax as a percent of rental receipts less real estate tax.
These very high tax rates are greatly in excess of the rates applicable
to other forms of consumer expenditure, with the exception of taxes
on liquor, tobacco, arid gasoline. The highest retail sales tax rate
currently is 5 percent, and this rate applies only in places which
exempt food from the tax; the typical sales tax rate is closer to 4
percent. If we exclude liquor, tobacco, and gasoline, all the indirect
taxes which fall upon consumers-including shifted business taxes
as well as ordinary sales and excise taxes-probably amount to less
than 10 percent of nonhousing consumer expenditure-less than half
the level of housing taxation. It is simply inconceivable that, if we
were starting to develop a tax system from scratch, we would single
out housing for extraordinarily high levels of consumption taxation.
More likely, we would exempt housing entirely from taxation, just as
many States exempt food from the sales tax.
SPECIAL BURDEN ON THE POOR
The situation is even worse than the preceding discussion implies
with respect to the low-income population. We have not discussed
income heretofore. But the housing property tax is heavily regressive,
absorbing a much higher fraction of the incomes of the poor than of
the rich. This is largely because housing expenditure looms so large
in the budgets of poorer families; in addition, the poor tend to be
concentrated in the high property tax rate central cities.
Table 11 indicates how heavily the property tax does burden poorer
renters in the country as a whole, and for New York City, the only
individual city for which good evidence exists.12 The burden on the
poor in the latter case is even heavier than in the country as a whole.
However, because rent control in New York City moderately reduces
ratios of rent to income for poorer families in the city, the housing
property tax is probably more severe for poor families in other large
northern cities than it is in New York, on balance.
`~ The New York City figures apply to homeowners as well as renters, but are
dominated by the latter, who occupy 79 percent of the city's housing units.
PAGENO="0033"
19
TABLE 11.-Estimates of housing property taxes as a percent of income, by income
class
Income class
All renters, United
States, 1959-60'
New York City
1960-61 2
Less than $2,000
$2,000 to $3,000
$3,000 to $4,000
$4,000 to $5,000
$5,000 to $7,000
$7,000 to $10,000
$10,000 to $15,000
Over $15,000
8. 5
~* 9
3. 0
2. 5
2. 1
1. 8
1. 6
1. 4
8. 6
5. 6
4. 1
3. 4
2. 8
2.4
2. 2
2. 7
1 From Netzer, op. cit., table 3-8.
2 Adapted from Alan D. Donheiser, "The Incidence of the New York City Tax System," in Graduate
School of Public Administration, New York University, Financing Government in New York City (1966),
p. 177.
This regressivity, illustrat~d in figure 3, is of concern, and not just
from the standpoint of equity pure and simple. High taxes on housing,
relative to taxes on other uses of the consumer's dollar, are likely to
discourage expenditure for housing. But they are likely to be an espe-
cially severe deterrent to the poor, since they have so little leeway in
family budgeting-there is little else that they can forego in order to
rent better housing. This amounts to saying that the poor probably
are more sensitive to price (rent) differentials than are the rich, out of
necessity rather than choice.
The general effect of these very high property taxes on the supply
of housing to the low-income population has two components. First,
taxes raise the cost of housing to the occupants and simply put a sig-
nificant part of the existing housing stock beyond the reach of many
in the low-income population. For example, take a large urban family
with an income of $4,000. The maximum tolerable rent for such a f am-
ily (if the rent is not paid by public assistance) might be said to be 30
percent of income, or $100 a month. Assume that the prevailing level of
property taxes is 25 percent of rents in that city. Were property taxes
on housing eliminated, this family could afford to rent an apartment
now renting for $133 a month, without exceeding the 30 percent rent/
income ratio, an apartment which is now out of reach.
Second, high property taxes discourage consumption of and invest-
ment in housing in general, by the entire population.'3 There is ample
evidence that consumers will buy more and better housing if its price is
lower, just as they do with regard to most other objects of consump-
tion. It can be and has been argued persuasively that one of the most
effective ways of helping the low-income population (with respect to
housing) is to rapidly increase the total supply of housing in a par-
ticular city and metropolitan area; a decrease in prices (rents), while
having no immediate effect on total housing supply, does create a
larger effective housing market for those who now suddenly can afford
13 It should be noted here that any tax tends to reduce income available for
expenditure by consumers, and that a reduction in disposable income will re-
duce demand for housing as well as demand for other consumption goods and
services. But in general, this reduced-income effect will depress demand for
housing much less than will the increased price effect of a tax which, like the
property tax, specifically applies to housing as such.
PAGENO="0034"
20
Fig.3 HOUSING TAXES PAID ON RENTED NONFARM HOUSING AS A
PERCENT OF FAMILY INCOME OF RENTERS BY INCOME CLASS,
1959-60
Percent
~,
4~7
-~---~_~
~/~` vç~
7'~/~'
7~7
.
I
under 2.000 3,000 4,000 5,000 7,000 10,000 15,000
$2,000 to 3,000 to 4,000 to 5,000 to 7,000 to 10,000 to 15,000 and over
source: table II
Income class of renters
more of the existing housing. The evidence from the 1950's strongly
suggests that the housing conditions of the poor improved most radi-
cally in those areas in which the total suppiy of housing rose i~'iost
rapidly. The process by which this occurs is related to the rate of turn-
over of housing; this argument has been carefully developed in a re-
cent article, using New York City evidence.14
There is yet another aspect to all this. Most low-income families do
spend large proportions of their incomes for housing, but not all of
them do so. In the 1960 census, there were 3.8 million renter households
with incomes below $3,000 for whom rent/income ratios were coin-
puted. Roughly 600,000 of these spent less than 25 percent of their
incomes for housing. Now it is a worthy objective to attempt to per-
suade some of these families to moderately increase the proportions of
income spent for housing, by offering them greatly improved housing
14 See Frank S. Kristof, "Housing Policy Goals and the Turnover of Hous-
ing," Journal of the American Institute of Planners, August 1965, pp. 232-245.
PAGENO="0035"
21
conditions at small increases in rent. A reduction in the property tax
burden could do just that, by reducing the prices of housing across-
the-board. To return to the $4,000 urban family, assume a present rent/
income ratio of 20 percent, which means a monthly rent of $67. A 50
percent reduction in property taxes, combined with an increase in the
rent/income ratio to 25 percent, would permit this family to rent an
apartment which now rents for $97 a month, a 45 percent improvement
in housing conditions (presumably) with a one-fourth increase in
actual rental payments.
PROPERTY TAX DETERS IMPROVEMENTS
This line of argument applies not only to the central city poor.
It can be generalized to apply to the broader problem of improving
the future prospects of the large, old central cities as attractive resi-
dential locations for families of all income levels. An essential in-
gredient of such an improvement program must include offering a
stock of housing which affords a reasonable alternative to the housing
available in suburban locations. This means modernizing of that por-
tion of the central city housing stock which is amenable to moderniza-
tion,'5 replacing other parts of the old housing stock with new hous-
ing, and building housing on the limited amount of available central
city land.
High property taxes effectively shrink the market for all these types
of improvement in the central city housing suppiy. This is perhaps
most obvious for owner-occupants of unmodernized older housing
considering rehabilitation; the rehabilitation is not only costly and
difficult to finance, but in most cities, it also will result in some in-
creases in assessment. In some cases, the assessor will heavily discount
the improvements, but in other places where the old housing is assessed
at levels which are low for that city, the rehabilitation may trigger a
very large increase in the assessment and in tax liability. In any event,
one of the few case studies of this subject suggests that fear of poten-
tial property tax increases can be a potent deterrent to improvements
of central city residential properties.'°
The effects of high property taxes in shrinking the market for new
central city housing seem to be obvious to policymakers, for they are
increasingly attracted to tax exemption or abatement schemes for
specified types of new housing, of types similar to the New York
arrangements under which 70,000 middle income housing units have
been built. It should be noted that the issue here is not the height of
central city tax rates compared to those in the suburbs, for middle
income families. Indeed, frequently the central city tax bills, for the
housing which could be an alternative to suburban housing, will be
lower than the taxes in the suburbs.
In suburban communities, particularly bedroom suburbs, the public
services that a family receives or has access to are very closely tied
to the local taxes that the same family pays. Therefore, in a sense, the
property tax in maily suburbs is analogous to a general charge for
`~ Experience in a number of cities suggests that there is very little old hous-
ing which is not amenable to modernization, although some of it is very costly.
`~ George Sternlieb, The Tenement Landlord (Urban Studies Center, Rutgers-
The State University, 1966), Chap. 11.
PAGENO="0036"
22
the use of public services, or perhaps even to a local income tax. It is
unlikely to be a deterrent to consumption of housing; that is, to the
expenditure of consumer income for housing.
For the central cities, this is not the case. Central cities provide a
wide variety of services and tax a wide variety of property types.
Individuals cannot reasonably assume that the prices of housing con-
fronting them include an identifiable tax component which is in effect
a charge for a preferred package of public services. WThat they do
observe is that housing is expensive in the central city. It may not be
any more expensive in the central city than in the suburbs. But an
effective city-rebuilding strategy requires that the central cities en-
courage more private expenditure for housing, and this may in turn
require that housing be much cheaper in the central city than in the
suburbs.
Moreover, the suburban nexus between taxes and public services is
likely not to be present in the central city for yet another reason-
inevitable more of the new central city housing will be rental housing,
rather than owner occupied. Therefore, the taxes per se will not be
apparent to the central city housing consumer-only the rentals, which
reflect a tax component. And, making the comparison still worse, prop-
erty taxes paid through rents are not deductible in computing Federal
income tax liability, as are taxes on owner-occupied properties.
URBAN DEVELOPMENT AND LAND USE
The argument thus far is that the property tax does have one impor-
tant class of effects on urban development and land use: by reducing
consumer demand for housing in central cities, it tends to retard cen-
tral city rebuilding and may very well make suburban areas appear
relatively more attractive for households in a position to choose sub-
urban residential locations as an alternative to central city locations.
There are two other classes of effects: (1) central cities versus
suburbs in respect to nonresidential land use; and (2) the pattern
of land use in outlying parts of metropolitan areas.
CENTRAL CITY ECONOMICS
There has been much discussion of the effects of taxes on the loca-
tion of economic activity in recent years. Most analysts have come up
with negative findings, to the effect that State-local tax differentials
have little impact on location, largely because tax differentials are so
small, relative to the differentials in other costs of doing business,
especially labor and transport costs.
However, most such studies have been done on a statewide or inter-
regional basis, using States or regions as the units of observation.
Nontax costs do differ greatly among widely separated locations, so
the usual findings are not surprising. But within a single metropolitan
area, nontax cost factors are likely to differ only slightly; indeed, in
some cases, local taxes may be the only costs of doing business which
differ among alternative locations. An analysis of tax differentials for
manufacturing in the New York area in the late 1950's indicated very
PAGENO="0037"
23
large differentials in State-local tax burdens, with the older central
cities having markedly unfavorable positions.'7 A more recent study of
New York City's finances provides fairly clear evidence that these
major business tax differentials actually have stimulated decen-
tralization of economic activity away from the central city.'~
Moreover, if the tax differentials are unfavorable to central city
locations, this reinforces rather than works against the powerful eco-
nomic forces making for decentralization of economic activity from
central cities to suburbs. The central cities have been losing out rela-
tively (and in some cases absolutely) with respect to manufacturing
and wholesale distribution of goods and with respect to population-
serving activities (which follow population out to the suburbs). Tax
differentials may trigger decisions to move away from the central city
which might have occurred in any case, but at a later date. But this
acceleration of locational shifts is a loss to the central cities.
Of course, not all economic activities are equally susceptible to tax
differentials. For one thing, some kinds of activities have heavy re-
quirements for special types of public services, which higher central
city taxes may buy. Then, too, there will be no effect on location if the
tax disadvantages do not exceed the special advantages of central city
locations-for example, for corporate headquarters in large-city cen-
tral business districts-or if there is no choice at all, typically the case
for banks, public utilities and newspapers.
Are actual property taxes on business property enough higher in
central cities so that they do in fact stimulate or contribute to migra-
tion of economic activity from central cities to the outlying parts of
metropolitan areas? It is difficult to assemble conclusive evidence on
this, but there is some fragmentary evidence which supports a positive
answer to the question.
Consider the data in table 12. The last column of the table presents
estimates of the differentials in effective tax rates for all types of tax-
able property for 24 large central cities and their immediately adjacent
suburban hinterlands. There are only four cases in which suburban
effective tax rates are clearly above those in ceiitral cities (5 percent or
more higher) and another three cases in which effective rate levels
are roughly the same in central cities and suburban territory. In the
remaining 17 cases, central city tax rates are substantially higher;
they are nearly twice as high as in suburban areas in such older central
cities as Newark, Cincinnati, and Baltimore.
`~ Alan K. Campbell, "Taxes and Industrial Location in the New York Metro-
politan Region," National Tax Journal, vol. II (September 1958), pp. 195-218.
18 See the papers by Leslie E. Carbert, James A. Papke, William Hainovitch,
and Henry M. Levin, in New York University Graduate School of Public Admin-
istration, Financing Government in New Yor1~ City (1966). In this case, non-
property taxes appear to be the real culprits.
PAGENO="0038"
TABLE 12.-Property tax differentials, central cities versus suburbs-selected large metropolitan areas, selected years between 1957 and 1961 1
[Values show outlying portions of area as percentage of central city]
Region
Central city
Suburban area
Percent ratio of suburb
an area to central city
Approximate effective
tax rate relationship 2
Per capita property
taxable values
,
Per capita property
tax revenue
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
4 (6)
Rest of:
Northeast
New York City
Philadelphia
Buffalo
SMSA
SMSA
Erie County
131
146
112
134
94
96
102(100)
64
86(92)
North-central
Newark
Rochester
Chicago
Detroit
Cleveland
St. Louis
Milwaukee
Essex County
Monroe County~.
Cook County
Wayne County_~.
Cuyahoga County.
SMSA
Milwaukee
158
100
123
102
106
96
138
91
58
93
87
88
105
91
58(51)
58(75)
76
85
83(97)
109
66(81)
West
S
Cincinnati
Kansas City
Columbus
Los Angeles
San Francisco
San Diego
Seattle
Denver
Portland
County.
Hamilton County -
Jackson County~.
Franklin County~
Los Angeles
County.
SMSA
San Diego County.
King County
SMSA
Multnomah
122
52
117
102
85
100
91
90
77
66
62
137
68
89
90
66
58
47
54
119
117
67
105
90
73
64
61
South
Oakland
Baltimore
Washington, D.C
Atlanta
Louisville
County.
Alameda County~.
SMSA
SMSA
Fulton County_. - -
Jefferson County -
90
110
95
82
145
78
58
96
71
98
87
53(55)
101
87
68
I From Dica Netzer, op. cit., table 5-7, p. 118, and app. 0. The presentation hero omits Central city equals 100.
data for SMSA's which are not among the 38 largest. Col. S divided by col. 4.
2 Figures in parentheses are based on direct computations of effective rate differentials
from various local sources. The other figures are derived by dividing the data in col. ~ NOTE: SMSA-Standard metropolitan statistical area.
by those in col. 4.
PAGENO="0039"
25
These figures do not apply solely to business property. However,
some inferences can be drawn about business property on the basis of
the limited evidence on differential assessment practices, by type of
property, in some of the large central cities, from the 1962 Census of
Governments.19 This evidence suggests that effecti ye tax rates 20 on
business property areprobably significantly lower in Kansas City and
St. Louis than in their suburbs; but in San Francisco, New York, and
Cleveland, central city taxes on business property are probably higher.
In the latter cases, the rough parity in overall rates appears to be a
consequence of favorable central city treatment of housing in assess-
ment practices.
In Atlanta, San Diego, and Los Angeles, central city business prop-
erty tax burdens are probably less unfavorable, relative to their
suburbs, than table 12 indicates. But in Chicago and Seattle, the busi-
ness tax differentials are even more unfavorable than the table would
suggest. In the other cases, the table 12 figures are probably reasonably
accurate reflections of the differentials for business property. All this
suggests that there are a fair number of large central cities in which
business tax differentials could be a real factor in accentuating the
dispersal of economic activity away from the central cities.
This conclusion is based on data which are several years old. How-
ever, there is no real indication that the situation has changed signifi-
cantly in the past 5 to 10 years.21 Indeed, the continued rapid rise in
expenditure by the local governments serving central cities, combined
with the much slower rate of increase in their taxable property values,
may indicate that the situation has deteriorated.
Table 13, for 10 selected central city areas, shows that nominal
property tax rates have increased very steeply in recent years in a
number of cases. If the ratios of assessed to market value have not
declined substantially (which does not seem to be the general case),
then there have been some substantial increases in central city effec-
tive tax rates, including the rates on business property.
For presentation and discussion of evidence, see Netzer, Economics of the
Property Tax (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1966).
20 Effective tax rates express the relationship of the tax charged to the market
value of the property-an appropriate basis for comparing levels of property
taxation in different localities. The nominal tax rate is that set by local tax
authorities and applied to the officially assessed values of properties. Compari-
sons of nominal rates are likely to be meaningless or misleading unless one also
has information about valuations-i.e., the relation between assessments and
full market value-in the particular localities involved.
21 In the case of the most extreme differential in table 12-Newark-the situ-
ation may have worsened. For 1967, the effective property tax rate in the central
city was 6.6 percent, compared to a 3.25 percent average for the remainder of the
SMSA. See I~Iorris Beck, "Fiscal Disparities in Metropolitan Areas," paper pre-
sented at the National Tax Association Conference, Atlanta, Ga., Oct. 23, 1967.
PAGENO="0040"
26
TABLE 13.-Changes in assessed values versus changes in tax revenues, selected
csntral city areas, 1957-65 1
Percent increase in
per capita
Central city areas in listed SMSA's
Assessed Tax revenue
Implied
percent
increase in
nominal
values
property
tax rates 2
Baltimore, Md 18 49 27
Boston, Mass 2 37 35
Cleveland, Ohio 17 46 25
Indianapolis, Ind 7 24 16
Milwaukee, Wis 31 57 20
Minneapolis-St. Paul, Minn.. 21 30 8
Newark, N.J 57
Paterson-Clifton-Passaic, N.J 6 54 46
Portland, Oreg 29 42 11
Providence, R.I 28 90 48
1 The first 2 columns are based upon computations made for the Advisory Commission on Intergovern-
mental Relations in connection with its report, Fiscal Balance in the American Federal System. The ACIR
data are for average annual increases, and have been converted back to 8-year increase figures. The ACIR
tax revenue data are for total tax revenue, not just property tax revenue; the areas selected are those in
which non-property-tax rove sue is relatively insignificant and in which major annexations or reassessments
did not occur in the 8-year period.
2 Computed from data underlying the first 2 columns on the assumption that changes in the relatively
minor non-property-tax revenue did not appreciably affect the growth rate of total tax revenue.
INTRA-SUBTIRBAN VARIATIONS
There are very large numbers of local government units in metro-
politan areas with property taxing power-over 7,000 such units in
the 38 largest SMSA's at present. The average large SMSA thus
has about 200 taxing units. This implies, of course, that the size of
most of the units is small-an average population of less than 15,000
per unit outside the central cities. Small size alone assures that there
are wide disparities within a single SMSA in regard to the level and
adequacy of the tax base and the height of tax rates. If the units are
sufficiently small, the location of individual plants can have major
fiscal effects on the individual taxing jurisdiction.
The evidence indicates clearly that differentials in property tax
base per capita (or per pupil, for school districts) within metropolitan
areas are very large ones, even if the extreme cases, like industrial
enclaves and resort communities, are ignored. Ranges of 10 :1 are not
uncommon.°2 Such wide variations in taxable capacity have two kinds
ofeffects, from the standpoint of urban development. First, they per-
mit individual communities within an urban area to offer public serv-
ices which differ greatly in scope and quality. To some extent, this need
not exercise anyone; rich communities, like rich families, will enjoy
a higher standard of living than poorer places in any society which
places a high value on choice and diversity. However, it is not so easy
to be complacent about wide variations in the quality of those public
services which are basic to the future well-being of metropolitan areas
(and to that of the Nation), like education, nor about wide variations
in the quality of services which have effects on neighboring communi-
ties, like disposal of wastes and control of air and water pollution.
See Netzer, op. cii., pp. 124-125.
PAGENO="0041"
27
Second, although rich communities generally spend more than
poorer ones, in most cases they do not spend as much more as their
superior tax bases would permit. The result generally is that the
rich communities have lower tax rates than do their poorer neighbors.23
This is often observed in aggravated form in connection with small
communities with extensive concentrations of business property. The
public service requirements of the business property are low, but it
call yield very large amounts of tax revenue. The consequence is an
extremely low tax rate.
This, in turn, has two effects. It encourages economic activity to
locate in low-tax jurisdictions, which may or may not be the optimal
locations for particular forms of economic activity. Equally important,
it encourages communities to plan land use for fiscal advantage, rather
than on the basis of broader considerations:
The* examples of the industrial tax colonies and the high
income/low tax rate enclaves have encouraged large numbers of
communities to zone to attract tax base and repel consumers of
public services. From a fiscal standpoint, the best of all possible
worlds appears, to many suburban decisionmakers, to be develop-
ment of the community's vacant land by campus-type offices and
laboratories and by housing expensive enough to assure that there
will be few schoolchildren (because of the anticipated age levels
of the owners).
The popularity of this "fiscal merchantilism"-efforts to export
service costs and import tax base-has generated a good deal of
argument about the extent to which the various forms of land
development "pay for themselves." There are, of course, endless
possibilities for local variations in cost-revenue situations for
particular classes of property. The presence of factories and shop-
ping centers can increase some costs disproportionately, under
certain circumstances, and have adverse rather than favorable
effects on property tax rates. In some places, more expensive
residential property is associated more with larger numbers of
schoolchildren per family than with less expensive residential
development. But by and large, the intuitive judgments of local
policymakers are likely to be right since, in suburban areas, the
school levy is usually more than half the total property tax levy;
business property, that is, produces a school tax "profit," and much
residential property produces a school tax "deficit." And if the
latter is tile case, the best way to minimize the "problem" is to
have as few "deficit-producing" houses as possible, for example,
by requiring very large minimum lot sizes for single-family
houses. Thus, in the New York area as of 1960, nearly half the
vacant land in the 22-county region was zoned to require single-
family houses on lots of 1 acre or more.
This is not the place to comment in depth on the adverse conse-
quences of land use decisions made on the basis of property tax
considerations. It should suffice to say that efficient patterns of
land use in metropolitan areas, in the broadest sense, are not
necessarily those that maximize the current fiscal position of
23Ibid pp. 125-430.
PAGENO="0042"
28
governments in the area. There is more to urban society than the
contemporary public sector and governments are seldom in busi-
ness to maximize their own welfare. Even if maximization of the
public fisc were the overriding criterion for land use planning, the
property tax is far from the whole story; moreover, a multiplicity
of taxing jurisdictions, each striving to maximize its own cost-
revenue combination, is highely unlikely to maximize for the
area as a whole.24
It may be that this problem will be of lesser importance in future
years. One reason for asserting this is that, as the larger SMSA's
grow and spread, more and more of the urbanization will occur in
previously rural areas which are served by relatively large (in a geo-
graphic sense) taxing units; much recent urbanization has occurred
in closer-in territory already carved up into rather small units. The
larger the geographic size of the jurisdiction, the less the temptation
toward "fiscal zoning," since each individual land use decision will
have a lesser impact on the overall fiscal results. However, this favor-
able tendency will be realized only to the extent that large numbers
of new taxing units are not created as urbanization arrives; this is a
function of State laws governing the creation of new units of govern-
ment, which differ greatly.25
In addition, it has been claimed by a number of observers that dif-
ferentials in tax rates, expenditure levels, and tax bases have been de-
clining within metropolitan areas, at least among the jurisdictions out-
side the central cities.26 This observation appears to be almost entirely
a consequence of the urbanization of previously rural jurisdictions
which then become like the already urbanized ones. There does not
seem to be any pronounced tendency toward uniformity when the corn-
parison is confined to communities already nrbanized at the beginning
of the comparison period; this part of the problem does not appear
to be withering away.
In short, the conclusion here is that the incentive to plan land use
for fiscal ends is now, and has been, a real one, and will continue to
distort urban development pattei~ns as long as these four conditions
obtain in metropolitan areas:
(1) The existence of a large number of separate and relatively
small local government units.
(2) Responsibility on the part of these governments for the
provision and a major part of the financing of costly public
services.
(3) Reliance by these governments mainly on the property tax,
the base of which is closely related to land uses within each
jurisdiction.
(4) Placement of extensive powers over land use patterns in
the hands of these governmental units.
24Ibid., pp. 131-132.
23 There is some reason to believe that the generation of new units is slowing
down. Between 1962 and 1967, the number of municipalities was virtually un-
changed, while there was an increase of 800 (about 5 percent) between 1957 and
1962. Also, the rate of increase in the number of special districts (not all of
them with property taxing power) slowed down somewhat in the latest 5-year
period and the number of school districts continued to decline as rapidly as in the
previous 5-year period. See U.S. Census Bureau, 1967 Census of Governments,
"Governmental Units in 1967," preliminary report (October 19G7).
26Netzer, op. cit., pp. 132-135.
PAGENO="0043"
AN APPRAISAL OF THE PROPERTY TAX
This appraisal consists, in the main, of a catalog of defects, some of
them a summary of previously elaborated points. The property tax
does have virtues, so the public interest is in doing what can be done
to minimize the defects, rather than merely describing the defects of
the institution. The principal virtues are pragmatic rather than philo-
sophical ones. The tax exists; it produces very large revenues; and our
society and economy have adjusted to and worked through many of
the baleful effects of the tax, at least of present levels of property
taxation. These are significant advantages, but they are not enough
to compel us to reject reform out of hand, or to ignore methods of
reducing reliance on the tax over time.
EFFECTS ON HoUsING AND URBAN DEVELOPMENT
To briefly recapitulate the appraisal developed in the previous sec-
tion, the property tax, on balance, has the following kinds of sig-
nificant effects on urban housing and development:
1. The tax amounts to a very high consumption tax on housing
expenditure and thus tends to reduce consumer demand for hous-
ing. This in turn tends to limit growth in the stock of urban hous-
ing and to limit improvement in the quality of the existing
housing stock.
2. These effects are not likely to be very evident in suburban
communities, especially the better-off ones, for two reasons. First,
the connection between property tax payments and local public
services provided homeowners is a clear one in most suburbs. Sec-
ond, the Federal income tax advantages of homeownership, for
relatively well-off taxpayers, offset the property tax in large
measure.
3. However, the deterrent effects of high taxes on consumption
of, and investment in, housing in large central cities are serious.
This is likely to be more true for tenants than for homeowners,
and more so for lower income groups. For upper income groups,
the outcome may be a marginal encouragement to the observed
trends toward suburban residential locations; for the poor, the
outcome will be less and poorer housing.
4. In many places, the property tax helps to make central city
locations relatively unattractive for some types of business activ-
ity, although the evidence on this is by no means unequivocal.
5. Outside the central cities, in metropolitan areas which oper-
ate with large numbers of local taxing units (most SMSA's out-
side the Southern States), there are very large differentials in
property tax bases. One consequence is an unacceptably wide vari-
ation in the scope and quality of the public services essential for
urban living and for the achievement of a good urban environ-
ment.
(29)
PAGENO="0044"
30
6. Another consequence is wide variation in effective property
tax rates. This can promote a less-than-optimal pattern of the
location of business establishments. Equally important, it often
leads to emphasis on fiscal criteria in land use planning-efforts to
maximize the fiscal position of each of the large number of taxing
units-rather than concern with the broader social, economic, and
esthetic considerations which should be the basis for planning
decisions in urban areas.
EFFECTS ON OTHER RESOURCE ALLOCATION
The effects of the property tax on central city housing and on the
location of economic activity in urban areas are by far the most im-
portant of its resource allocation effects, for urban areas. There are,
however, some other types of effects related to the fact that property
taxes are usually much heavier burdens on some types of industries
than on others, notably on particular types of public utility enter-
prises. Some of these effects are of relatively minor importance for
urban areas in general, although important for specific firms. For
example, the characteristically high property taxes on gas utilities
increase gas rates to consumers relative to the prices paid for fuel oil,
thus marginally discouraging use of gas for heating.27
A more important effect is among competing forms of transporta-
tion. Because railroads own their own rights-of-way, and because of
frequent discriminatory assessment of railroad property, property
taxes on railroads are very high relative to those on others types of
transportation. It is estimated that, in 1957, property ta.xes amounted
to 4.9 percent of national income originating in railroad transporta-
tion but only 0.04 percent of national income originating in air trans-
portation; 28 the corresponding figure for motor freight transportation
was probably about 2 percent. Since these are regulated industries,
the tax differentials do show up in rates to users, and encourage use
of the nonrailroad modes. On balance, this facilitates decentraliza-
tion of industrial activity away from central cities, since one of their
major advantages in the past has been their superior rail freight
facilities.
High and rising taxes on agricultural property 29 reduce net income
of farmers and thus, on balance, help speed the conversion of farmland
on the rural-urban fringe to urban uses. The more general effect on
agriculture probably is to encourage marginal farmers to leave the
industry and concentrate farmland in fewer but more heavily capi-
talized units of production.
EFFECTS ON INCOME DISTRIBUTION
One of the more frequent charges against the property tax is that
it is more regressive 30 with respect to personal incomes than alterna-
tive forms of taxation. Before examining the evidence on the distribu-
~` In New York City, natural gas rates to domestic consumers might be 10 per-
cent lower, were property taxes no higher than those reflected in retail fuel oil
prices. Since the prices of the two heating fuels are roughly equivalent now, the
property tax appears to be a real deterrent to gas use.
Netzer, op. cit., p. 26.
~ In 1957, these amounted to nearly 8 percent of national income originating
in agriculture, versus 2 percent for nonfarm business. Ibid., pp. 24, 28.
30 Regressive taxes exact a higher percent of income as income decreases;
progressive taxes exact a higher percent of income as income rises.
PAGENO="0045"
31
tion of property tax payments by income class, it is worth noting the
probable income distribution effects of other forms of State-local
taxation:
1. General sales taxes.-In those jurisdictions where food is
exempt, these taxes are regressive for the very lowest income
groups, roughly proportional in the middle-income ranges, and
regressive again for upper-income groups. Where food is
included in sales taxes, they are much more regressive, and
throughout all income categories.
2. Selective sales taxes are usually quite regressive.
3. Personal income taxes covering all forms of personal income
are very progressive in those States with graduated rates, and
mildly progressive where there are flat rates but personal exemp-
tions or credits. The typical flat-rate local income tax without
exemptions and applying only to earned incomes is proportional
for lower and middle-income households, but regressive for the
rich, who have substantial property income.
4. Business taxes.-Taxes on gross receipts, value added and
profits (if it is assumed in the latter case that the bulk of the
tax is shifted forward to consumers) have an incidence pattern
something like the general sales tax with food exempt, that is,
moderately regressive. If it is assumed that a substantial part of
taxes on corporate profits is borne by stockholders, then these
taxes become progressive among upper-income groups.
In the aggregate-fOr the country as a whole-the incidence of the
property tax is roughly proportional to income, except among the
lowest income groups, where the tax amounts to very high fractions
of incorne.~' The property tax therefore appears at least as good on
income distribution grounds as most other State-local tax forms,
except for personal income taxes. However, the aggregate conceals
important variations. The important distinctions are, first, between
nonresidential and housing property taxes; and second, within the
housing sector, among geographic areas.
The nonresidential property tax is rather like a general consump-
tion tax, because much of the tax, notably that on utilities and most
trade and service activities, is shifted forward to consumers. The tax
is therefore regressive up to incomes of about $10,000. However,
because some of the tax is not shifted-including that part on the land
underlying nonresidential structures-the tax tends to be progressive
above that income level. As for property taxes on housing:
Rather good evidence on incidence by income class of property
taxes on owner-occupied houses strongly indicates that this com-
ponent of the tax is even more regressive than the nonresidential
component. Somewhat less direct evidence indicates that the tax
on rented housing is still more regressive. However, because
renters tend to be both poorer and decidedly smaller consumers
of housing (and hence pay less property tax, via rents), when
the two series are combined, the picture is less clear. Residential
property taxpayments decline sharply as a percentage of aggre-
gate income as income rises in each class in the lower half of the
income distribution but the percentage climbs again in the middle-
31 For amplification, see Netzer, op. cit., chap. III.
PAGENO="0046"
32
income range up to the $10,000-$15,000 level. For the income class
over $15,000, the percentage again drops.32
The combination of homeowners and renters has an important geo-
graphic characteristic-it combines central city residents and subur-
banities. Within each of these geographic groupings, housing property
taxes are probably markedly regressive. This is surely the case with
respect to large central cities, as a number of studies of individual
areas indicate; see, for example, the evidence for New York City in
table 11 above. For such cities, the property tax is decidedly inferior to
other forms of local taxation on income distribution grounds.
There is one important consequence of the regressivity of the prop-
erty tax in central cities. As indicated earlier, the property tax in
central cities finances substantial expenditure which, in effect, redis-
tributes income in kind-health and welfare services, education for
children in low-income families, et cetera. Thus, to a considerable ex-
tent, central cities find themselves in the position of taxing the poor to
provide services to the poor, which is surely nonsense.
Equity in taxation refers not only to the burden of taxation on
households in different income groups; it also includes the extent to
which tax burdens differ among the households within a particular
income group. Since consumption of housing is a major determinant
of property tax burdens, and since this differs widely within income
groups, property tax burdens do in fact differ considerably within in-
come groups. There is some degree of this "horizontal inequity" even
under an income tax, since exemptions, deductions, and the statutory
definitions of income subject to tax result in differences in tax liability
among taxpayers with a given total income. Under the Federal income
tax law, in most income classes, the typical taxpayers will have tax
liability which is roughly 20 to 25 percent more or less than the mean
tax liability in their income classes.
But taxes based on consumption expenditure or property values give
rise to much larger degrees of horizontal inequity, since tax liability
depends upon consumption decisions as well as inconie status. For New
York City, for example, it is estimated that the residential real estate
tax has a coefficient of variation of roughly 65 percent in all income
classes. That is, the typical family's housing tax burden is almost two-
thirds greater or less than the mean burden for its income class.33
In summary, the regressivity among income classes of the housing
component of the property, and its horizontal inequity within income
classes, are serious defects in the property tax, relative to other con-
ceivable forms of local taxation.
QUALITY OF ADMINISTRATION
Ordinarily, the principal factors in an appraisal of any tax are its
resources allocation effects (including effects on the location of eco-
nomic activity, for taxes imposed on less than a nationwide basis) and
its income distribution effects. We usually assume that at least the
larger units of government can administer any major form of taxa-
tion tolerably well. This assumption is not valid for the property tax,
`~Ibid., p. 40.
33Melvin and Anne White, "A Per~ona1 Income Tax for New York City: Equity
and Economic Effects," in Graduate School of Public Administration, New ~!ork
University, "Financing Government in New York City" (1966), pp. 460-465,
482-488.
PAGENO="0047"
33
however, even if we confine the analysis to relatively large units of
government. It is generally agreed that, according to the principal
measure of the quality of administrative performance in the property
tax-uniformly in the ratios of assessed to market value for individual
properties-the existing quality of administration is very bad indeed.
Moreover, some observers argue that the potential for high-quality
performance at reasonable administrative costs is very limited, espe-
cially within large urban areas.34
There are two principal elements in the indictment of assessment ad-
ministration. First, the evidence is clear that, within most assessing
jurisdictions, even the most common, least heterogeneous properties-
single-family nonfarm houses-are assessed at widely varying frac-
tions of market value. Second, owners of different types of property in
a single area are treated differently by assessors, sometimes systemat-
ically but often erratically.
The best evidence on the lack of uniformity within property types
is that of the Census of Governments-comparisons of the selling
prices of houses actually sold with their assessed values, and expressed
as a "coefficient of dispersion," that is, the average deviation from the
median assessment/sales ratio as a percent of the median ratio. As
table 14 shows, in 1961; 21 percent of the areas located within SMSA's
had coefficients of 15 percent or less and another 24 percent were in the
15 to 20-percent range. But a sizable number of areas, including six of
the country's very large cities, had coefficients of 30 percent or more.
The 20-percent level is often taken to indicate good assessment qual-
ity. But it appears to be a very modest standard of administration
when compared to sales or income tax administration. A 20-percent
coefficient means that the typical homeowner can expect to be faced
with a tax bill which is 20 percent more or less than it should be, given
a legal requirement for uniformity. It is hardly conceivable that sales
or income tax administrators would be satisfied with an average error
in tax payments of 20 percent-S percent would be a more likely stand-
ard, and one which is realized in Federal income tax administration.
Not one place in SMSA's satisfied this more rigorous standard in 1961.
TABLE 14.-Dispersion of assessment ratios for nonfarm houses in selected local
areas in SMSA'S, 1961 1
Number of areas Percentage of total
number
Total number of selected areas with co-
efficients in intraarea dispersion (in
percent)2 of
483
100
Less than 15
102
21
15 to 19.9
115
24
20 to 24.9
102
21
25 to 29.9
71
15
30 to 39.9
62
13
40 or more
31
6
1 From TJ.S. Bureau of the census, 19C~ Census of Governments, Vol. II, Taxable Property Values, Table 16.
2 Average deviation of ratio of assessment to sales price (for houses sold in a 6-month period) from median
ratio in the area, as a percent of the median ratio.
34Netzer, op. cit., pp. 173-183.
PAGENO="0048"
34
There is some evidence that it is by no means inexpensive to realize
a higher degree of uniformity. Typically the low-dispersion places
spend more for administration, relative to revenue, than do the high-
dispersion places. But although more costly administration may im-
prove things somewhat for the relatively easy-to-assess single-family
houses, it is by no means clear that a greater administrative effort can
produce reasonable standards of uniformity for other types of prop-
erty, which are often complex and, in many cases, infrequently sold.
Thus both assessors and independent appraisers must rely on
some proxy for market value (which is the conventional legal
basis for taxation), and any proxy variable is likely to have a
coefficient of correlation which significantly differs from ± 1.0 in
a world with all sorts of market imperfections. The most coin-
monly used proxy for buildings is depreciated reproduction costs,
with both depreciation and reproduction costs determined for
individual properties by applying detailed formulas and tables,
rules which cannot help departing from the market's evaluation
in individual cases. Another common proxy used for income-
producing properties is capitalized earnings. The earnings data
are likely to be objectively determinable, but the capitalization
rate may not coincide with that of prospective purchasers.
In their search for "true value," assessors combine the varieties
of evidence: sales of similar (but not identical) properties, re-
production costs, an evaluation of the observed condition of the
subject property and of its environment, and income. However
objective the basic evidence, its weighting is entirely subjective
and varies from case to case.
* * * It would appear that the tax on business property in
general can be regarded as a collection of taxes nominally meas-
ured by market value but actually measured by a varied and
changing set of evidence more or less related to market value. Nor
is the situation much better in a large jurisdiction with regard
to residential realty which is varied in age, type, style, and loca-
tion; only where the stock of housing is homogeneous in all major
respects (as in a suburban subdivision built within a brief span of
time) is there any assurance that market value and its proxies
will be closely correlated.35
All this refers to uniformity within classes of property. The second
count in the indictment refers to differences among types of property.
In a fair number of large cities, the assessment ratio for single-family
houses differs significantly from that for other types of property;
more often than not, the ratios for single-family houses are lower
than for the other types.3° A frequent pattern is that found in New
York City-very high assessment ratios for office buildings, large re-
tail stores and hotels; only slightly lower ratios for multifamily hous-
ing and for industrial structures; considerably lower ratios for one-
and `two-family houses; and extremely low ratios for vacant lots.
To some extent, such differences among property types represent an
accommodation to economic realities, albeit an extralegal and erratic
accommodation. For example, relatively high tax burdens for central
~ Ibid., pp. 180-182.
20Ibid., table 4-1, p. 76.
PAGENO="0049"
35
bu~iness office structures probably reflect an awareness of the central
city's strong competitive position in this field, as contrasted with its
weak competitive position with regard to industrial activity.
But one cannot be sanguine about all the differentiation. The fre-
quently high assessment ratios for multifamily housing may very well
conflict with central city housing policy goals; few large old central
cities can expect substantial expansion in their supplies of housing to
result from a policy of favoring low-density single-family housing.
Similarly, underassessment of vacant land is hardly consistent with
any rational urban development program. And, more generally, lack
of uniformity in assessments, if widely appreciated by taxpayers, has
a real, if intangible, effect on a city's ability to obtain more revenue
from the property tax. Voters are far more likely to resist tax increases
if they believe the tax to be unfairly administered than if they be-
lieve it to be reasonably equitable. Bad administration is, in this sense,
an Achilles' heel, and is so considered even by those whose appraisal
of the tax on other grounds is far more favorable than the appraisal
presented in this paper.
INHERENT AND REMEDIABLE DEFECTS
It should be noted that this catalog of defects in the property tax
can be subdivided in another fashion. Some of the defects appear to
be fundamental to the nature of the property tax; others, notably
poor assessment of single-family houses, are much more remediable;
and still others largely relate to the fact that the tax is levied by so
many jurisdictions operating within a single urban area.
The major defects which seem to be inherent in the property tax
are these:
1. Its adverse effects on the central city housing stock;
2. The difficulty in uniformly assessing business property;
3. The horizontal inequity of housing taxes within income
classes;
4. The regressivity of housing taxes among tenants and among
homeowners; and
5. The lack of neutrality among types of economic activity,
particularly in connection with taxes on transportation and public
utility property.
The defects which relate to local government fragmentation, cor-
rectable at least in part were the tax to be levied over broader
geographic areas, are these:
1. The adverse effects of high central city business property
taxes;
2. The effects on urban development patterns outside the central
cities; and
3. Some part of the regressivity of the tax, in particular that
part which results in taxing the central city poor to provide public
services designed to alleviate or overcome poverty.
This classification, then, suggests some possible policies to overcome
the major failings in the property tax.
PAGENO="0050"
POSSIBLE REMEDIES
To the extent that the defects of the property tax are inherent ones,
the principal remedies must take the form of some reduction in the
reliance on the property tax* for the financing of urban public
services.37 The alternative financing is by higher levels of government
which do not use the property tax, or by other local government
revenue sources. Reduced reliance on the property tax will also
diminish the importance of the other types of defects, mainly related
to the fragmented local government patterns. But these latter defects
can also be remedied in part by reforms within the institution of the
property tax itself.
INCREASE STATE-FEDERAL RESPONSIBILITIES
The increase of State and Federal Government responsibilities is an
obvious route toward reduced reliance on the property tax, and one
which is in keeping with developments in fiscal federalism since the
1920's.
These developments include both the transfer of direct responsibility
for the actual performance of some functions from the local to State
and Federal levels of government, and increased State and Federal
financing of functions still performed at the local level.
Consider four of the major functional classes of civilian public
expenditure: education; highways; public welfare; health; and hos-
pitals. In each case, the local government share of total direct public
expenditure by all three levels of government declined appreciably
from 1927 to 1965-66; for example, from 71 to 32 percent for highways
and from 69 to 52 percent for welfare. But there were even larger
declines in the proportions of local government expenditure financed
from local, rather than State and Federal, revenue sources. As a result
of this (and of another much less important factor, the expansion
of local nonproperty revenue sources), the property tax now finances
half or less of local expenditure for these functions, compared to 75
percent or more in 1927.
The combined effect of functional transfers, increased grants-in-aid,
and increased use of local nonproperty revenue sources is indicated
by the following estimates of the percentages of total public expendi-
ture of all levels of government financed by the property tax: 38
~ This does not necessarily mean a rollback in property tax levies or rates.
In practice it will mean a reduction in the relative role of the property tax; that
is, financing increased expenditures in future years from revenue sources other
than the property tax.
are very rough estimates based on Census Bureau data; they some-
what overstate the decline for education.
(36)
PAGENO="0051"
37
[In percenti
1965-66
1927
Education
37
Highways
Public welfare
13
8
56
61
Health and hospitals
15
32
Suppose the 1927 percentages prevailed today, and expenditure levels
were no different than they are. To finance these four functions, local
governments would have needed, in 1965-66, an additional $23 billion
in property tax revenue, above and beyond the $23.8 billion they
actually received ($12.5 billion more for education; $5.5 billion more
for highways; $5.1 billion more for health and welfare services). Thus,
we can say that during this period, there has been an upward shift
of nearly half the potential property tax burden.
But a strong argument can be made for further upward shifts,
in two functional areas. One is education; very small portions of
the eventual benefits from education are recaptured within the con-
fines of individual school districts, since our population is so mobile-
perhaps no more than 20 percent on the average. This argues for a
much increased role for external financing, especially at the Federal
level. Since education now absorbs slightly over half of current prop-
erty tax revenues, such shifts could greatly reduce reliance on the
property tax.
A second area is that of poverty-linked services, notably welfare
and health services, which now absorb roughly 10 percent of total
property tax revenues, but substantially more for the large central
cities. A good case can be made for relieving the property tax of the
job of financing all public services linked to the existence of poverty.
Since this burden if concentrated in central cities, it would alleviate
the central city-suburban disparities and the property tax problems
these create; it would also alleviate the regressivity problem in the
sense of taxing the poor for services to the poor.
This is very much in keeping with the historic trends. During the
last 30 years, each of the important institutional changes which re-
duced pressures on the property tax has been associated with redis-
tributive services. These include the Federal and State assumption of
most public welfare costs in the thirties, via grants-in-aid, transfers
of functional responsibilities, or direct Federal social insurance pro-
grams; the steady expansion of the State government role in financing
education in the past 20 years; the gradual increase in Federal fi-
nancing of health services (either directly or through grants-in-aid),
culminating in medicare and the 1965 social security amendments; the
Federal role in the provision of housing for low-income people; and
most recently, the new Federal participation in antipoverty programs
and in the costs of education where there are extensive pockets of
poverty. All of these Federal-State aids combined have not been suf-
ficient to keep effective property tax rates from rising at a fairly rapid
rate. But without external aid to urban-area local governments, the
rise might have been far more rapid.
PAGENO="0052"
38
Some evidence on the extent to which complete external financing
of poverty-linked services would have alleviated central-city-suburban
tax effort (tax revenue divided by personal income) disparities, had
this been in effect in 1962 in 22 of the largest SMSA's, is presented in
table 15. The estimates are those of Prof. `Woo Sik Kee of West Vir-
ginia University. On the average, the tax effort disparities would have
been cut in half: central city tax burdens would have been nearly 25
percent lower, while suburban tax burdens would have been 15 per-
cent lower. Converted to effective property tax rate terms, this would
have reduced central city tax rates to levels equal to or less than those
in suburban areas in a number of cases.
TABLE 15.-Measures of tax effort in central cities and suburbs in 22 largest S1~1SA's,
1962 1
(Per capita tax revenue, 1962, divided by per capita income, 1960)
SMSA
Actual ta
x revenue
Adjusted ta
x revenue
2
113
Cities
Suburbs
Cities
Suburbs
Cities
Suburbs
New York
9. 5
7. 5
7. 8
7. 0
7. 3
6. 8
Chicago
Los Angeles
Philadelphia
Detroit
7.4
8. 4
7. 4
7. 5
6. 1
7. 0
4. 9
5. 7
6. 6
7. 3
6. 6
6. 2
5. 8
6. 0
4. 6
4. 9
6. 2
6. 8
6. 1
5. 5
5. 6
5. 6
4. 4
4. 6
Baltimore
6. 9
4. 4
6. 0
4. 3
5. 3
3. 9
Houston
5. 9
5. 6
5. 4
5. 4
4. 7
4. 9
Cleveland
7. 4
5. 2
6. 1
4. 4
5. 5
4. 2
St. Louis
7. 6
5. 1
5. 9
4. 8
5. 2
4. 4
Milwaukee
8. 4
6. 5
6. 8
5. 4
6. 3
5. 2
San Francisco
7. 4
7. 2
6. 1
6. 0
5. 6
5. 6
Boston
11. 2
7. 4
8. 9
6. 8
8. 3
6.4
Dallas
5. 7
3. 7
5. 2
3. 1
4. 8
2. 7
Pittsburgh
San Diego
Seattle
7. 2
6. 3
5. 0
4. 9
6. 7
3. 6
6. 8
5. 3
4. 5
4. 7
5. 6
3. 2
6. 3
4. 7
4. 2
4. 5
4. 9
2. 9
Buffalo
7. 5
7. 0
6. 2
6. 2
5. 7
5. 9
Cincinnati
8. 2
4. 5
6. 5
4. 2
5. 7
3. 8
Atlanta
6. 3
3. 7
5. 1
2. 8
4. 5
2. 4
Minneapolis
Kansas City
Newark
Mean
7. 0
6. 0
12. 3
6. 5
5. 4
7. 0
5. 3
5. 1
9. 5
5. 6
5. 0
6. 5
4. S
4. 5
8. 9
5. 3
4. 6
6. 2
7. 6
5. 7
6. 3
5. 1
5. 8
4. 8
1 Data computed by and presented in Woo Sik Kee, "City-Suburban Differentials in Local Government
Fiscal Effort" (mimeo., Regional Research Institute, West Virginia University, October 1967).
2 Total tax revenue minus the estimated locally financed portion of expenditure for public welfare, health,
and hospitals.
3 Total tax revenue minus the estimated locally financed portion of expenditure for public welfare, health,
hospitals, and for education of children in families with incomes less than $3,000.
To some extent, Professor Kee's estimates understate the reduction
in the disparity. He is looking at tax effort as if all local taxes were
charges against personal incomes received by residents of the communi-
ties levying the taxes. But some part of the burden of taxes paid by
businesses is "exported" to other communities, via higher product
prices or reductions mt he profits accruing to nonresident owners of
PAGENO="0053"
39
businesses.~9 And generally speaking, the export percentage is higher
for central cities than for suburban areas, if for no other reason than
the lesser role of housing in the central city tax base.
Estimates made for New York City suggest that 25 percent of its
tax burden was exported in the early 1960's.4° Similar estimates for
suburban counties in the New York SMSA suggest that only about
15 percent of their tax burden was exported. Applying this correction
to Kee's estimates, actual tax burdens on residents can be said to have
been 7.1 percent of central city residents' personal incomes in 1962
and 6.3 percent for suburbanites. Had the poverty-linked services
been entirely financed from external sources, the percentages would
have been 5.5 for the city and 5.7 for the suburbs. Since effective prop-
erty tax rates in central city and suburbs in this SMSA are roughly
equivalent, the upward shift would have resulted in effective suburban
rates nearly one-fifth above those in the central city, if the entire effect
of the transfer fell on the property tax.
OTHER LOCAL REVENUE SOURCES
Changes in intergovernmental fiscal arrangements of the types pro-
posed here could have a potent impact. Kee and other observers have
asserted that much of the remaining disparity in tax burdens-where
any does remain, after correction for tax exports-can be associated
with the extent to which the central city accommodates the surrounding
suburban population with places of employment, shopping and cul-
tural facilities and, presumably, the public services supportive of these
activities.
To the extent that this is in fact the case, it strengthens the argument
for greater reliance on other local government revenue sources, notably
direct charges for the use of public services and facilities (paid by
actual users wherever they may live) and local income taxes paid by
residents and commuters alike.
USER-CHARGES FOR PUBLIC SERVICES
Local governments do currently employ user-charges; they obtain
roughly 18 percent of their locally raised general revenue from charges
for services (other than utility services) and from special assessments.
About half of this amount comes from school lunch and similar
charges, hospital charges and public housing rental payments, but
charges apply to a wide range of other services. Despite this, there is
considerable potential for greater exploitation of user-charges, in con-
nection with activities which do not have significant income-redistri-
bution objectives. The case for this has been put as follows:
~ * * many of the public services provided by local govern-
ments are in many ways like those provided by public utility
companies. That is, they are not provided uniformly to the entire
population, but rather in distinguishable quantities and qualities
to individual families in the population, who consume them in
For comprehensive estimates of this, see Charles E. McLure, Jr., "Tax Ex-
porting in the United States: Estimates for 1962," National Taa~ Journal, vol.
20 (March 1967), pp. 49-77.
4° See Alan D. Donheiser, "The Incidence of the New York City Tax System,"
op. cit. Table II, p. 162.
PAGENO="0054"
40
accord with their personal preferences. For example, not all f am-
ilies use the same amount of water, not all use the same amount
of highway transportation, and so on. There is a strong case for
financing such services in the same way public utility services are
financed-that is, via user charges which are like prices, rather
than through general taxes.
If the purpose of providing the public service is to offer differ-
ent consumers the services they want, and place some value on,
then they ought to pay for such services in proportion to the costs.
Otherwise, governments will be called upon to provide a great deal
more of the service than people would be willing to consume if
they did have to pay for it, which is a wasteful use of resources;
or the service will be in such short supply that a form of nonprice
rationing will be employed to allocate the service among con-
sumers. The outstanding example of this is street congestion in
cities: users pay for highways in the aggregate but not for specific
individual uses of the streets, and therefore, not surprisingly,
treat highways as a free good. The only deterrent to use of the
streets at the most crowdec[ times and in the most crowded places
is the value one places on time; the rationing in effect then results
in those who place a low value on time pre-empting the street
space from those who place a high value on time. Ordinarily, in
our society, rationing is on the basis of price. Somebody who val-
ues a service highly bids it away from someone who places a lower
value on that service and would rather use his income for alterna-
tive kinds of consumption.4'
The most striking opportunities for greater utilization of user-
charges, as this would suggest, are in connection with financing of
urban highway and parking facilities and services, waste collection
and disposal, and recreational activities; the potential revenue in these
areas alone equals roughly one-tenth of property tax revenue on a
nationwide basis. The potential is relatively larger in urban areas,
especially the larger ones, which provide more of these services and
are generally less effective exploiters of user-charges.
LOCAL INCOME TAXES
The case for local income taxation does not rest on the argument that
it is a good device for central city taxation of commuters. To be sure,
the potential here is a large one. The municipal governments of the 43
largest cities collected $3.3 billion in property tax revenue in 1965-66.
Excluding Washington, D.C., their local income tax revenue was $242
million, largely made up of the collections in Detroit, Louisville, and
the larger cities in Pennsylvania, Ohio, and Missouri. But if all 43
cities had a flat 1-percent tax on income earned within the central
cities, revenue would have amounted to perhaps $1.3 billion, probably
$300 million of this from commuters. This is a substantial fraction of
property tax revenue for these units of government.
The more general case for income taxation is that it does not have
an especially adverse effect on housing, as does the property tax. It
~` Netzer, "Financing Urban Government," in James Q. Wilson, editor, The
Metropolitan Enigma (Chamber of Commerce of the United States, 1967), p.
PAGENO="0055"
41
escapes the regressivity charge. Moreover, for central cities, it is su-
perior to local sales taxes and other loca' business taxes, since unlike
the latter, it is highly unlikely to encourage migration of economic
activity away from the central cities.
Local income taxation heretofore has been largely a large city affair,
except in Pennsylvania. However, in time, it may become more like the
widespread use of local sales taxes, which in States like California and
Illinois, are virtually universally used supplements to the State sales
tax, collected by the State. As such, local nonproperty taxes have the
general character of the State tax, since, if universally applied, they
have no impact on the intrastate location of economic activity. They
may be thought of as a susbtitute for outright grants-in-aid from
State tax revenue, with the distribution of the funds based on the
origin of the tax collections rather than on the traditional kinds of
State-aid formulas. The latter can permit much more adequate reflec-
tion of differences in needs among communities (although State-aid
formulas frequently do not realize this potential). On the other hand,
the local tax supplements permit much more local government discre-
tion in the use of the funds.
LAND VALTTE TAXATION
An entirely different type of alternative revenue source would be
a heavy tax on land values in urban areas as a partial substitute for
currently collected property tax revenues.
As the name implies, land value taxation is a tax on the value of
land alone, irrespective of the value of buildings or the lack of build-
ings on a site. A step in this direction is the graded or differential
tax-the application of a higher tax rate to the land portion than to
the improvement portion of property valuations.
The argument for exclusive taxation of site values, or for substan-
tially heavier taxation of land than of buildings, is an old one, and
differential site value taxation is widely practiced-in western Canada,
Australia, New Zealand, and South Africa, for example. The merits
of the case have been submerged for many years by the extravagant
claims of the proponents of site value taxation. Moreover, skepticism
has been bolstered by the apparent absence of discernible effects in
the places where site valuation is utilized.
However, the case for~ site value taxation is a good one. The argu-
ment, on equity grounds, is that most of the value of land is a conse-
quence, not of actions by individual owners, but of collective invest-
ment, community development, and population growth. Individual
landowners therefore can realize large "unearned increments" over
time. It is entirely appropriate for the community to recapture these
unearned increments by taxation, and use them for community pur-
poses. There are complications in this equity argument, related to the
fact that most landowners have already paid, in their purchase prices,
for at least some of the unearned increment, but by and large the equity
argument makes sense.
The economic argument is even more compelling. A tax on site value
which is independent of the improvements on the site will not affect
entrepreneurial decisions as to the use of the site; the best (most profit-
able) use before tax remains the best use after the tax is imposed. In
PAGENO="0056"
42
other words, the tax is neutral with regard to land use decisions. Since
the present property tax, on both land and improvements, is not neu-
tral but tends to discourage investment in buildings, a switch from the
present tax to exclusive site value taxation (or to a tax heavily
weighted on the land portion) would tend to have strong land use
effects.
Provided that demand permits, it would encourage owners to de-
velop their sites more intensively, in an effort to minimize tax liability
as a percentage of current receipts, since additional investment in
buildings would not increase tax liability. Within individual urban
jurisdictions, taxes on vacant land would tend to rise, thereby increas-
ing the holding costs of vacant land and making the speculative with-
holding of land from development a less attractive proposition. Thus,
a switch to site value taxation is likely to have its maximum impact in
two parts of a metropolitan area-in the central areas, where it would
encourage more investment in buildings, and in the outlying sections,
where it. would tend to discourage land speculation and the resulting
patchy patterns of land development (less "leapfrogging" over sites
withheld from the market).
In theory, there are few if any legitimate economic arguments
against site value taxation. On an operational level, there are grounds
for hesitation.
First of all, one may doubt the actual strength of the positive tend-
encies associated with a switch to site value taxation. It is, after all,
a major institutional change, and major institutional changes should
not be pressed unless their positive effects are also expected to be major
in extent. However, it should be noted that effective property tax rates
in most American metropolitan areas are high and rising. The nega-
tive land use effects of the present tax are likely to become increas-
ingly apparent in time, and the likely benefits from a change in the
basis of taxation will correspondingly increase.
Second, there is some question about the revenue adequacy of site
value taxation. Some calculations suggest that the present yield of
property taxes on nonf arm realty substantially exceeds the total rental
value of privately owned nonfarm land. Thus, even a 100 percent site
value tax might not yield enough to fully replace the existing property
tax (on real property, exclusive of personalty). This suggests that
only a partial, rather than a complete, shift is possible, diluting the
possible advantageous land use effects.
Third, there are administrative problems if both land and build-
ings are taxed, but at differential rates-the "graded tax" concept
applying in Pittsburgh, Hawaii, and western Canada, for example.
This makes it very important to accurately value land and buildings
separately. Under a pure system of site value taxation, the building
value is irrelevant. Under the conventional property tax, the distinc-
tion between land and building for any individual site is also irrele-
vant, although the statutes may require the assessor to make some
statement about the notional separation. It seems likely that joint ad-
ministration of the two different types of taxes will produce bad ad-
ministration of the site value tax, in that assessors will tend to relate
land and building valuations as they often do at present. Therefore,
the proposal here is for a separate system of land value taxation,
levied and administered, if possible, over a wide geographic area-
a whole State or SMSA.
PAGENO="0057"
43
TAXATION OF LAND VALtTE INCREMENTS
The equity argument for taxation of increases in land values is at
least as strong as that for annual taxes on total land values. This kind
of tax is aimed at recapturing for the government a higher propor-
tion of what economists call the unearned increment-the rise of land
value that occurs, not through efforts of an owner but through gov-
ernmental action (new highways, subway lines, zoning changes, etc.)
and through growth of the population and industry of the community.
Land value increment taxes strike directly at the unearned incre-
ments realized by specific individual owners, and do not penalize
present owners who have not realized substantial land value incre-
ments. The claim in this case is not that community improvements
tend to enrich landowners in general; tax liability occurs only when
enrichment is demonstrated by the realization of capital gains on
land.
Variants of this approach to taxation are used in a number of coun-
tries. In some Hispanic countries, specific public improvements are
financed from taxes on the estimated (although not necessarily
realized by sale) increase in the value of adjacent properties; this is
done on a very large scale in some of the major cities in Colombia. In
our own country, special assessments to finance street and sewer proj-
ects have a similar rationale. In a number of European countries,
this approach shows up in the income tax treatment of capital gains
on land, which is much less favorable than that of other types of
capital gains.
Thus, land value increments could be taxes in a number of ways
and at different levels of government. Perhaps the easiest method
might be through State income taxation, by a special supplemental
rate on capital gains on land or by including a larger portion of the
gain as ordinary income (rather than the 50 percent now included
in most States, following the Federal practice). This seems easiest,
because the gains are already reported and legal definitions do exist
and are applied.
Like annual land value taxation, this form of taxation would be
largely neutral with respect to the use of land and would not dis-
courage new construction. However, its economic impact and revenue
potential would be somewhat less. Presumably, the land value incre-
ment tax would apply only to gains actually realized (including con-
structive realization at the death of the owner). Very high tax rates
would tend to postpone realization of gains, although closing the
transfer-by-death loophole would reduce this. Nevertheless, the eco-
nomic impact would be in the right direction and the equity effects
appropriate. Therefore, this seems good policy, especially if straight-
forward annual land value taxation does not prove acceptable.
IMPROVEMENT OF THE EXISTING INSTITUTION
Since some of the major defects in the existing institution relate to
the fragmented structure of local government in urban areas, an ob-
vious direction for reform is application of the property tax over
wider geographic areas, thereby reducing tax rate disparities by
evening out the differences in tax base per capita or per pupil. There
are two approaches to this.
PAGENO="0058"
44
TAX BASE CONSOLIDATION
One would be to regionalize a segment of the tax base-eliminate
local taxes on some types of property and levy property taxes on these
types over a broader area, with either use of the proceeds for region-
wide (or statewide) functions or distribution of the proceeds to local
government units on the basis of some measure of need. A frequent
suggestion along these lines is for regional or statewide taxation of
business property, to eliminate local competition for economic ac-
tivity and attendant pressures on land use planning.42
FISCAL FEDERATION
A second approach is to regionalize the financing (and perhaps
administration) of part or all of selected local government functions,
but still utilize the property tax to the extent it is 110w used. The most
dramatic proposal along these lines is to employ a statewide property
tax for the great bulk of (non-Federal) school funds.4' There also have
been proposals for metropolitan areawide school financing in, perhaps,
some kind of fiscal federation. Under this scheme, State school aid
would continue as at present, but paid to an areawide authority. The
area authority would then levy a uniform areawide property tax and
distribute this revenue and the State aid on a per pupil basis. For most
school districts, this would provide adequate program levels. However,
they would be free to supplement the levels with local levies, but pre-
sumably only few districts would do so. Since property taxes for
schools amount to roughly half of total property taxes, there would be
an appreciable reduction in property tax disparities.
Smaller, but real, reductions in disparties would result from metro-
politan areawide financing of functions with a fundamentally regional
character, like transportation and waste disposal. Within single-county
SMSA's, this could be done on a county basis. In fact, even in multi-
county SMSA's, significant reductions in disparities could be achieved
by increased countywide financing. An indication of the potential can
be found in aggregate data for SMSA's from the 1962 Census of
Governments.
Consider a few functions with a regional character, or for which
countywide administration is -common in some parts of the country.
Expenditure for these functions can be derived into that handled by
county-scope units of governments (counties, combined city-county
governments like New York, Philadelphia, and Baltimore, and large
special districts) and that handled by subcounty units. The following
is the approximate proportion of SMSA local government expenditure
in 1962 handled by subcounty units:
Percent
Highways 55
Waste disposal 60
Parks and recreation 60
Health and hospitals 30
Public welfare 15
~` It should be noted that the planning difficulties could be accommodated in
another way-by regionalizing land iesc controls rather than taxation. There is
much to be said for this course of action; indeed, there is hardly anything to be
said in defense of land use planning by a huge number of small jurisdictions.
But this is an entirely seperate subject.
~ has been proposed by Lynn A. Stiles, of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago.
PAGENO="0059"
45
Now, had these functions been financed entirely on a countywide
basis, roughly $1.7 billion of property taxes collected on a subcounty
basis in 1962 would have been collected county-wide. This is roughly
half the total property tax revenue of the subcounty units (excluding
school districts) in that year.
BETTER ADMINISTRATION
The position in this report is that improved assessment of most
types of complex business property is a utopian goal, but that it is
possible to do a much better job with respect to housing, vacant lots
and the simpler, more common types of business property, like small
store buildings. The basis for this argument is that there are fairly
frequent sales of such property to provide a basis for assessment. The
requirements for realization of such improvements as are achievable
are professionalization and adoption of truly systematic procedures-
indeed, full computerization of the primary assessment process.44
These in turn imply large-scale assessment organizations.
Except in the very largest States, this may very well imply state-
wide assessment; it surely is not consistent with assessment districts
having populations of very much less than 500,000. The general rule
seems to be, if full use is to be made of the possibilities for computeri-
zation, the bigger, the better. This, then, is no less radical a proposal
than the others advanced in this report, since this country has been
firmly wedded over many decades to the notion that small local assess-
ment districts are an essential component of local self-government.
HARDSHIP ADJUSTMENTS
One way in which the burdensomeness of the property tax, including
its regressivity, has been attacked has been through the device of
special exemptions and abatements for various kinds of "hardship"
cases. The homestead exemptions which became popular in the 1930's
were one manifestation of this. More recently, there have been adop-
tions of devices to relieve property tax burdens for older people.
Almost without exception, exemptions and abatements have proven
to be clumsy and inefficient methods of relieving hardship. If a partial
tax exemption is offered to a whole class of property owners-such as
the aged-it is likely to relieve the real hardship cases only if it is
very generous, and hence very costly in foregone tax revenue. Mean-
while, many property owners who are not hardship cases, benefit. If
the generosity of the provision is tempered by revenue-loss considera-
tions, it may be of trivial value for those really hard hit, and ad-
ministratively complex as well. Moreover, tax relief for homeowners,
whether aged or not, tends to ignore the frequently worse-off cases
among renters.
One way out of this is to offer carefully tailored credits for very
burdensome property tax payments under State income tax laws.
Such credits can be restricted to those whose income status makes it
clear that the burdens are real ones. An example of this is the provision
in Wisconsin, adopted in 1963, for income tax credits for the aged,
both homeowners and tenants, who have both low incomes and pay
~ has been done on an experimental basis with extraordinarily good results
in California.
PAGENO="0060"
46
high proportions of their incomes in property taxes, directly or
through rents.45 This kind of provision parallels the spreading use of
income tax credits to offset the regressivity of State sales taxes, and
could be usefully employed on a widespread basis.
HOUSING TAX INCENTIVES
The obvious deterrent effects of high property taxes on housing
has led to the use of tax exemptions and abatements for specific kinds
of new housing construction and rehabilitation, most notably in New
York State. The New York programs have had some success in stirnu-
lating construction of middle-income housing, with real though in-
direct effects on the housing status of poorer families.
Even from the standpoint of an exclusive emphasis on increasing
the supply of housing, the tax abatement programs now being used
have a serious drawback-they are administratively very cumbersome,
and therefore slow-moving. When governments single out particular
groups in the population for extraordinarily favorable treatment, they
are likely to try very hard to insure that the benefits do in fact accrue
to the worthy target population, rather than to unintended freeloaders
with no special claim on the public purse. The attendant restrictions
can greatly complicate matters.
New York's most generous tax abatement scheme is a good example
of this. Under this plan, designed to encourage rehabilitation of older
housing occupied by lower income people, an owner can recover 75
percent of the cost of the improvements through tax reductions over
9 years. However, the improved property is subject to rent control,
and the owner typically must forego rent increases he might otherwise
be entitled to. As a result of this and other complications, the program
is little used.
The administrative difficulties could be overcome by a general tax
abatement or exemption for all new housing investment, not just that
which satisfies complex administrative requirements. The selective tax
abatement programs are moderate in size,~~ and therefore the reduc-
tion in taxes has a negligible effect in increasing property taxes on
other types of housing. But an effective across-the-board exemption
program for all new investment would be a different matter. It could
result in a significant shift in the tax burden to older properties, in-
cluding older properties occupied by relatively low-income households.
Therefore, such a program is a questionable one unless it is linked
to steps to reduce the reliance on the property tax in general, such as
those suggested in the preceding section of this study. And if there
is a substantial reduction in reliance on the property tax in general,
the need for special housing exemptions will be greatly reduced.
~ Billy Dee Cook, Kenneth E. Quindry, and Harold M. Groves, "Old Aged
Homestead Relief-The Wisconsin Experience," National Tax Journal, Vol. 19
(September 1966), pp. 319-324.
~ The various New York City programs as of the end of 1965 covered 75,000
units, 2.5 percent of the city's housing inventory. City of New York, Committee on
Housing Statistics, Housing $tatistics Handbook (August 1966), table 1-3.
PAGENO="0061"
47
DE-EMPHASIS
In summary, the highest priority would seem to attach to dc-empha-
sis of the property tax per se. It is a generally inferior tax instrument,
although not the worst of all possible taxes. But an inferior tax be-
comes a monstrous one if applied at high enough rates.
There are alternatives to ever-increasing property tax rates in urban
areas, alternatives which require a willingness to acept real change
in that most conservative of all institutions, local government.
SCOPE OF COMMISSION RESEARCH'
Zoning and land use:
Problems of land assembly.
Regionalism in land use controls.
Land value trends.
New techniques in land use and development controls.
Zoning in the suburbs.
Zoning in the central city.
Zoning case studies.
Building codes, housing costs, and technology:
Impact of local building codes, regulations and practices on
housing costs.
Structure of building codes.
Building code administration.
Analysis of the building industry.
Urban technology.
Development standards and urban design.
Development standards and the development process.
Labor practices and housing.
Housing costs.
Housing programs:
Housing needs.
Programs for expanding low- and moderate-income housing.
Evaluation of social objectives of low-income housing programs.
Evaluation of types of home ownership.
Financing.
Community development and renewal.
Processing time and procedures for housing programs.
Housing construction goals: implications.
Housing codes:
Goals and administration.
Legal remedies for housing code violations.
State of housing code enforcement.
Code enforcement: Costs and effects.
Housing code standards.
Taxation and government finance:
Demographic developments and prospects.
Impact of the property tax.
Federal taxes and housing.
School districts: Lessons on governmental unit consolidations.
Land taxation.
`Listing does not imply all research performed will lend itself to publication.
PAGENO="0062"
48
Housing and social problems:
Housing and the large poor family.
Creative neighborhoods.
Racial and economic integration: Factors and problems.
Statistical surveys:
Canvas of 3,100 local governments on substance and administra-
tion of zoning, planning, and building regulations (codes and
standards).
State study of land values, improvements, and assessments.
Land use patterns in 130 major cities.
Correlation of housing conditions and poverty areas.
0