PAGENO="0001"
tcur~utvii~. A1'IAL I ~
~UEQ4SIO~jI INTEREST RATE POLICY
AND DISCOUNTING ANALYSIS
GOVERNMENT
JULY 30, 31, AND AUGUST 1, 1968
Printed for the use of the Joint Economic Committee
U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE
WASHINGTON : 1968
HEARINGS
BEFORE THE
SUBCOMMITTEE ON ECONOMY IN
OP THE
JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE
CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES
NINETIETH CONGRESS
SECOND SESSION
f. Th_~
98-040
DOC~
LI
Ec~L
ui ~/`y
oc
For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Omce
Washington, D.C. 20402 - Price 70 cents
o~
PAGENO="0002"
SENATE
JOHN SPARKMAN, Alabama
J. W. FULBRIGHT, Arkansas
HERMA~N B. TALMADGE, Georgia
STUART SYMINGTON, Missouri
ABRAHAM RIBICOFF, Connecticut
JACOB K. JAVITS, New York
JACK MILLER, Iowa
LEN B. JORDAN, Idaho
CHARLES H. PERCY, Illinois
HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES'
RICHARD BOLLING, Missouri
HALE BOGGS, Louisiana
HENRY S. REUSS, Wisconsin
MARTHA W. GRIFFITHS, Michigan
WILLIAM S. MOORHEAD, Pennsylvania
THOMAS B. CURTIS, Missouri
WILLIAM B. WIDNALL, New Jersey
DONALD RUMSFELD, Illinois
W. E. BROCK 3D, Tennessee
WILLIAM H. MOoRE
RICHARD F. KAUFMAN
ECONOMISTS
ROBERT H. HAVEMAN
JOHN R. KARLIK
FRAZIER KELLOGG
DOUGLAS C. FRECHTLING (Minority)
`StTBCOMMn'TEE ON ECONOMY IN GOVERNMENT
WILLIAM PROXMIRE, Wisconsin, Chairman
HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES
WRIGHT PATMAN, Texas
MARTHA W. GRIFFITHS, Michigan
WILLIAM S. MOORHEAD, Pennsylvania
THOMAS B. CURTIS, Missouri
DONALD RUMSFELD, Illinois
ROBERT H. HAVEMAN, Economist
JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE
(Created pursuant to sec. 5(a) of Public Law 304, 79th Cong.)
WILLIAM PROXMIRE, Wisconsin, Chairman
WRIGHT PATMAN, Texas, Vice Chairman
JOHN-R. STARK, Executive Director
JAMES W. KNOWLES, Director of Research
SENATE
JOHN SPARKMAN, Alabama
STUART SYMINGTON, Missouri
LEN B. JORDAN, Idaho
CHARLES H. PERCY, Illinois
(II)
PAGENO="0003"
CONTENTS
WITNESSES AND STATEMENTS
JULY 30, 1968
Moorhead, Hon. William S., member of Subcommittee on Economy in Page
Government and temporary chairman, first day: Opening remarks - - - 1
Announcement of hearings and schedule of witnesses 1
Udall, Hon. Stewart L., Secretary of the Interior and Chairman of the
Water Resources Council (presentation of statement made by Hon.
Kenneth Holum, Assistant Secretary, Department of Interior) 3
Caulfield, Henry P., Jr., Executive Director, Water Resources CounciL - - - 8
Extractions from Federal Register, July 22, 1968 re title 18-Con-
servation of Power and Water Resources 15
Hoffman, Hon. Fred, Assistant Director, Bureau of the Budget, accom-
panied by Jack W. Carison, Director, Program Evaluation Staff, Bureau
of the Budget 16
Prepared statement 22
JULY 31, 1968
Eckstein, Otto, professor of economics, Harvard University 50
Chapter IV.-The Social Cost of Federal Financing, from "Multiple
Purpose River Development," Studies in Applied Economic Analysis
by John V. Krutilla and Otto Eckstein 82
Harberger, Arnold C., professor of economics, University of Chicago 57
AUGUST 1, 1968
Enthoven, Hon. Alain, Assistant Secretary of Defense, Office of Systems
Analysis 136
Lynn, Hon. Laurence E., Jr., Deputy Assistant Secretary of Defense,
Economics and Resource Analysis 138
Prepared statement 141
Mackey, Hon. M. Cecil, Assistant Secretary for Policy- Development, De-.
partment of Transportation, accompanied by Dr. James Nelson, Director
Office of Economics 150
Prepared statement 155
Answers to questions submitted by Chairman Proxmire 170
Levine, Hon. Robert A., Assistant Director for Research, Plans, Programs,
and Evaluation, Office of Economic Opportunity, accompanied by Mrs.
Bette Mahoney, staff economist 161
Prepared statement 165
APPENDIX
Statement of Paul A. Amundsen, executive director, American Association
of Port Authorities 183
Letter to Chairman Proxmire from Representative William H. Natcher,
Second Congressional District, Kentucky 185
Letter to Henry P. Caulfield, Jr., executive director, Water Resources
Council from Warrior-Tombigbee Development Association, Birming-
ham, Ala 186
Statement of the Association of American Railroads 187
Statement of the Board of Commissioners of the Port of New Orleans - - 191
Statement of the Port of New York Authority 193
(UI)
PAGENO="0004"
PAGENO="0005"
ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF PUBLIC INVESTMENT DECI-
SIONS: INTEREST RATE POLICY AND DISCOUNTING
ANALYSIS
TUESDAY, JULY 30, 1968
CONGRESS OP THE UNrrED STATES,
SUBCOMMITEEE ON ECONOMY IN GOVERNMENT
OF THE JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITrEE,
Waslvington, D.C.
The Subcommittee on Economy in Govermnent met, pursuant to
notice, at 10:05 a.m., in room 1202, New Senate Office Building, Hon.
William S. Moorhead (member of the subcommittee) presiding in the
temporary absence of Hon. William Proxmire, chairman of the
subcommittee.
Present: Representative Mooi~head and Senators Proxmire and
Jordan.
Also present: John R. Stark, executive director; Robert H. Have-
man, economist; and Douglas C. Frechtling, minority economist.
Representative M00RHEAU (presiding). The Subcommittee on Econ-
omy in Government of the Joint Economic Committee will come to
order. Before we begin I would like, without objection, to make the
announcement of these three hearings, and schedule of witnesses, an
official part of the record.
(The information follows:)
SATURDAY, JULY 27, 1968.
CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES JOINT EcoNoMIc COMMITTEE
STJBCOMMITPEE ON ECONOMY IN GOVERNMENT
Senator Wiffiam Proxmire (D-Wis.), Chairman of the Joint Economic Corn-
nilttee and its Subcommittee on Economy in Government, announced Friday that
the Administration will make public its position on the appropriate interest rate
for evaluating public projects at the subcommittee's hearings next week.
The Wisconsin Senator said that Secretary of the Interior Udafl will discuss
the proposed regulation in his testimony before the Subcommittee on July 30th.
Chairman Proxmire said: "The rate of interest used in evaluating projects is
of tremendous importance in determining whether or not such projects are eco-
nomically feasible. Obviously, an unrealistically low rate can give a distorted
Value to a proposed project.
"The President, in his 1969 Budget Message, noted that the Water Resources
Council was then in the process of developing `a more appropriate interest rate
to be applied in formulating and evaluating water projects. The revised rate...
will be higher than the rate now in use for project evaluation.'
"The Subcommittee is xnost interested in the recommendation of the Council.
We have followed this matter for a long time and are convinced that the interest
rate used in discounting benefits and costs must be significantly higher if the
Nation is to efficiently allocate its resources.
(1)
PAGENO="0006"
2
"The Subcommittee is looking forward to Secretary Udall's statement on this
matter and his description of the reasoning which lies behind this change. The
Secretary will be accompanied by Mr. Henry Caulfield of the Water Resources
Council.
"In addition to Secretary Udall, the Subcommittee will hear prominent aca-
demic economists and analysts in the leading agencies on the development of
Planning-Programming-Budgeting methods. We should learn a great deal about
both the appropriate concepts and techniques for discounting as well as the
problems which the agencies are facing in implementing PPB procedures."
The hearings on "Economic Analysis of Public Investment Decisions: Con-
sistent Interest Rate Policy for Discounting Analysis" are scheduled for July 30
and 31 and August 1. Senator Proxmire noted that the hearing scheduled for
Tuesday, July 30, will be held in room 1202, New Senate Office Building, instead
of in the Capitol as previously announced. The remaining days of the hearings
scheduled for July 31 and August 1 will be held in room S-407, the Capitol.
HEARINGS ON CONSIsTENT DISCOUNTING PROCEDURES FOR PUBLIC
EXPENDITURE ANALYSIS
July 30 and 31 and August 1, 1968
Tuesday, July 30-10:00 a.m.-Room 1202, New Senate Office Building
Interest Rate Policy for Evaluatin~g Water Resource Investments
Stewart L. Udall, Secretary of the Interior and Chairman, Water Resources
Council
Henry P. Caulfield, Jr., Executive Director, Water Resources Council
Fred S. Hoffman, Assistant Director, Bureau of the Budget
Wednesday, July 31-10:00 a.m.-Room AE-1, The Capitol (S-407)
Interest Rate Policy for Public Ewpenditure Analysis-Concept and Measurement
Otto Eckstein, Professor of Economics, Harvard University
Arnold Harberger, Professor of Economics, University of Chicago
Thursday, August 1-10:00 a.m.-Room AE-1, The Capitol (S-407)
Discounting Procedures and interest Rate Policy in
Federal Departments and Agencies
Alain C. Enthoven, Assistant Secretary of Defense (Systems Analysis) and
Laurence E. Lynn, Deputy Assistant Secretary of Defense (Systems (Analysis)
M. Cecil Mackey, Assistant Secretary for Policy Development, Department of
Transportation
Robert A. Levine, Assistant Director for Research, Plans, Programs & Evalua-
tion, Office of Economic Opportunity
Representative MOORHEAD. Today, we begin the first of 3 days of
hearings on the question of consistent interest rate and discounting
procedures in the analysis of public expenditures. These sessions climax
the series of hearings which the committee has held dealing with
questions of interest rate policy and discounting procedures in the
various branches of the Federal Government.
This problem is an important one in the context of the establishment
by the President of the planning-programing-budgeting system in all
agencies of the Federal Government. It is especially pertinent in this
time of rapidly increasing demands on the Federal budget, combined
with congressional budget cutting. It is only through competent
benefit-cost and cost-effective analysis that Congress can rationally
choose among alternatives rather than apply the crude and wasteful
meat ax to the Federal budget.
PAGENO="0007"
3
Today, we have three witnesses who are knowledgeable on the ques-
tion pertaining to interest rate and discounting policies, especially as
they apply to the benefit-cost analysis in the water resources agencies.
We welcome Mr. Kenneth Holum, Assistant Secretary of the Inte-
rior, who will present the statement of Secretary TJdall as Chairman
of the Water Resources Council. We regret that Secretary TJdall was
unable to free his calendar so as to discuss these matters with us this
morning.
Accompanying Assistant Secretary Holum is Henry Caulfield, Jr.,
Executive Director of the Water Resources Council, who will discuss
some of the conceptual issues of interest rate policy and the rationale
of supporting the Council's proposed revision of the interest rate
regulation.
Following their testimony, Mr. Fred Hoffman, Assistant Director of
the Bureau of the Budget, will describe for us the Bureau's position
on the interest rate question and advise us of the efforts of the Bureau
in assisting the agencies to adopt appropriate discounting procedures.
Tomorrow we will hear the testimony of two prominent economists,
and on Thursday, representatives of three Federal agencies will dis-
cuss with us interest rate and discounting procedures.
Before hearing the formal statements of today's witnesses, I would
like to commend the Water Resources Council and the executive offices
of the President for the proposed new interest rate regulations. With-
~out question, this is in the President's words, "a more appropriate
interest rate to be applied in formulating and evaluating water
projects."
As all of you recognize, the Joint Economic Committee has fol-
lowed this matter closely and is convinced that the interest rate used
in discounting benefits and costs must be raised from the three and a
quarter percent rate currently in use if the Nation is to allocate its
resources properly.
I think this morning we will hear the statement of all three wit-
nesses before subjecting any of them to questions.
Senator, do you want to make any statement ~
Senator JORDAN. No.
Representative MOORHEAD. Then we will hear from Assistant Secre-
tary Holum first.
Mr. Secretary~
STATEMENT OP SECRETARY OP THE INTERIOR STEWART L. UDALL,
CHAIRMAN OP THE WATER RESOURCES COUNCIL, AS PRESENTED
BY KENNETH KOLUM, ASSISTANT SECRETARY
Mr. HOLUM. Secretary Udall regrets very much that because of his
busy schedule during this closing week of the Congress, he is not able
to be with you personally. I am happy to have the opportunity to
come before you this morning to present his statement-and it is his
statement, because I am not a member of the Water Resources Council,
although I serve as his representative on the Council of Representa-
tives of the Water Resources Council. It has not been a very big job
because he attends all the meetings of the Water Resources Council
personally, but I do represent him on that Council of Representatives.
PAGENO="0008"
4
Therefore, with your permission, I will read Secretary Udall's state-
ment to you:
APPLICATION OF ECONOMIC CRITERIA AND DISCOUNTING PROCEDURES IN
EVALUATING PUBLIC EXPENDITURES
I welcome the opportunity to testify before this Subcommittee on
Economy in Government of the Joint Economic Committee on the
subject of the application of economic criteria and counting procedures
in evaluating public expenditures. I have followed with interest the
hearings of the subcommittee held in September last year on the
planning-programing-budgeting systems and in January this year on
the interest rate guidelines for Federal decisionmaking, with particu-
lar reference to the survey conducted by the General Accounting Office.
My interest in this subject is keen because of my responsibility as
Secretary of the Interior and the deep involvement of the water
resources programs of my Department with economic evaluation. I
am also interested because of my role as Chairman of the Water Re-
sources Council and the statement in the January 29, 1968, `budget
message of the President that "the `Water Resources Council is devel-
oping a more appropriate interest rate to be applied in formulating
and evaluating water projects."
it is apparent that `as Secretary of the Interior and as Chairman of
the Water Resources Council my responsibility, as well as my concern,
is considerable. However, the responsibility and concern are not newly
acquired or discovered. Indeed, we in the Federal agencies concerned
with the use of water and related land resources can take pride, and
even boast a bit, at our many years of experience with economic
analysis as a positive `tool for shaping the scale and pace of water
resources development related to economic dem'ands and social ob-
jectives. This experience dates at least from the Flood Control Act
of 1936, which provided for the authorization of Federal activities
in regard to navigation `and flood control "if the benefits to whomsoever
they may accrue are in excess of estimated costs * *
Under the impetus of that act the `Corps of Engineers, the Bureau
of Reclamation, and the Soil Conservation Service negotiated the
tripartite agreement in 1939 relating to uniform evaluations. The
Federal Power Commission joined in 1943. These actions began the
long continuing effort in the executive branch to reach common ground
on the concepts and rules of the game and to sharpen the analytical
tools. The Federal Inter-Agency River Basin Committee was formed
in 1946 and developed the first "Green Book," which was published
in 1950 under the title "Proposed Practices for Economic Analysis of
River Basin Projects." This publication was followed by Bureau of
the Budget Circular A-47 in December 1952 as the evaluation stand-
ards by which that agency would review proposed Federal and fed-
erally assisted projects before submission to the Congress. The Green
Book was then revised in 1958 by the Inter-Agency Committee on
Water Resources. Discounting provisions were incorporated in each
of these documents.
In October 1961, President Kennedy requested those Cabinet of-
ficers who would comprise the Water Resources Council to be author-
ized by the then proposed Water Resources Planning Act, to develop
PAGENO="0009"
5
an "up-to-date set of uniform standards for the formulation and evaJ-
uation of water resources projects" and he asked me to be chairman
of this ad hoc council. Henry Caulifleid, who is to testify after me on
this subject, was chairman of the interdepartmental staff committee
that provided necessary staff assistance. That committee drafted the
present policies, standards, and procedures which in their final form,
were approved by the President on May 15, 1962. In this form, to-
gether with a statement by Senator Anderson, who was then chair-
man of the Senate Coramittee on Interior and Insular Affairs, they
were published as Senate Document No. 97 of the 87th Congress,
second session, and still constitute the basic framework for project and
basin analyses. They are regarded as of landmark quality in benefit-
cost analysis by most scholars and practitioners in this field. The Water
Resources Council, the formal statutory successor to the ad hoc coun-
cil formed in October 1961, is actively concerned with problems in
the application of the evaluation standards and with their further
improvement.
This quick recitation of the history of the use of economic analysis
in water and related land resource use and development is only a re-
minder that the water resources agencies have not only been pioneers
in this realm but have championed it as welL Our efforts in this
regard, as well as the magnitude and significance of the water develop-
ment programs and projects, have attracted the attention of many
university scholars and other students of analytical and policy proc-
esses. This attention is welcomed and encouraged, for as recently as
15 years ago few academic economists and other scholars were con-
cerned with water resources. Now, however, an entire field of resource
economics has `developed with a considerable number of well-estab-
lished scholars. These scholars have helped the agencies in the project
evaluation tasks. Indeed we have a most healthy exchange with the
various university water resources study programs. We have invited
scholars to advise us; we have helped finance some of their studies;
and we have sent staff personnel to study under them and to partici-
pate in seminars with them. We have been participants at many of the
meetings of the professional economics, public administration, and
planning societies as panelists on benefit-cost discussions. We know this
exchange has been mutually fruitful.
I believe there is no other Government program that exceeds us in
this endeavor to use economics. In order for a project to be authorized
and to be funded for construction, it is necessary not only to undergo
the usual Bureau of the Budget review and to meet the critical exami-
nation of the congressional substantive and appropriations commit-
tees but also to face interagency comments and to pass benefit-cost
analysis. In addition to these procedural requirements and tests and the
usual scrutiny by the interest groups, we also must pass the searching
appraisal of the jury of our economic and resource peers in the uni-
versities. The numerous articles in the scholarly journals and books
in the academic press on the subject of water and resources planning
and evaluation manifest this close attention.
It is well t.o acknowledge, however, that benefit-cost analysis is not
a foolproof device nor a precision instrument. Its usefulness and essen-
tiality are without doubt, but its imperfections and inadequacies should
not go unmentioned. Many scholars have warned that it can be mis-
PAGENO="0010"
6
leading. Usually their remarks are directed toward the presumption
that all benefits can be known, measured, and quantified equally. It is
true that water and related land resources projects provide many bene-
fits of a commodity or goods and services nature, more or less readily
evaluated in private market terms. But in many instances the projects
provide much more than goods and services. They provide also, in
increasing instances, for the protection and preservation of the quality
of the environment. Note the emphasis on water quality control for
instance with its intangible as well as tangible benefits. Note also the
enhancement of fish and wildlife, the contributions to aesthetics and
the amenities, and the many recreational opportunities created by
water and related land projects and programs. These benefits have
generally been underestimated, partly because of the lack of explicit
private market prices or values to represent them and partly because
the projects have been justified on other grounds, with these latter
benefits given only incidental accounting. The significance of these
kinds of benefits may well outweigh the more traditional benefits in
the future.
Furthermore, water resource projects are being accorded a renewed
positive role in regional economic development. In this regard, because
of the need for population shifts and changing attitudes and values to
manifest themselves, tangible benefits may be long deferred and con-
sideration must be given to interim uses which, hopefully, will yield
to more compelling uses in the future. One can no longer look solely
at projected goods and services based upon past trends as the basis for
planning in areas of unemployed or underemployed human and other
resources. The ecological and environmental effects and contributions
must be evaluated, and the social goals as well as the economic implica-
tions, must be appraised.
Scholars are already referring to the "new economics of resources" to
describe the situation. Dr. Nathaniel Wollman of the University of
New Mexico uses this term as the title of an article in the fall 1967
issue of Daedalus, the Journal of the American Academy of Arts and
Sciences. The entire issue is entitled "America's Changing Environ-
ment" and it presents a series of searching articles. Professor Wollman
says, in regard to the "new economics" that it applies to "bridging the
esthetic gap-by developing new methods of analysis that will show us
how to incorporate into a measured system the direct sensual responses
that up to now have figured solely as intuitively valued side condi-
tions. For what is now measurable, the old economics is good enough."
Furthermore, he says that "if we accept the solutions offered by
existing market forces we shall probably wa;ste and misuse part of
our resources. This conclusion rests upon the probability that there
is a bias in the `old economics' in favor of underestimation rather than
overestimation of needs met by nonmarketed goods and services."
So here we have the disinterested scholar expressing his analytical
insight and concern with the benefit-cost analysis situation when based
only upon tangible values. The view that benefit estimation has been
understated has been expressed also by the congressional committees
concerned with water resources development. This subcommittee, in
fact, at the January hearings on the interest rate survey of the Comp-
troller General, heard such views expressed. Mr. Chairman, I believe
you commented to that effect during the discussions at that time.
PAGENO="0011"
7
The Senate Committee on Interior and Insular Affairs has expressed
similar views in its Report No. 1234 on 5. 3058, a bill to amend the
Water Resources Planning Act to increase the authorization of appro-
priations to the Water Resources Council to administer the act.
Of particular concern-
The committee states-
is the impact of water resource development upon other economic and social
objectives of the Nation. The committee feels that the present interpretation of
Senate Document 97 results in benefit analyses which place little or no emphasis
upon the indirect and secondary effects of projects. As a result, projects are
being formulated and proposed which optimize the value to the direct bene-
ficiaries and neglect the impact, both beneficial and detrimental, upon other
sectors of the economy and society. To facilitate more valid consideration of
investments in water resource development in relation to other Federal pro-
grams, the economic analyses of projects should reflect the broadest scope of
potential benefits and costs which will result from the implementation of pro-
posals. The committee believes that the promulgation of a new discount formula
should appropriately be made a part of a reconsideration and restatement of
principles, standards, and procedures for economic analyses of Federal water
and related land resource projects.
The Senate Public Works Committee, in its Report No. 1342 on
5. 3710, the 1968 authorizations for rivers and harbors flood control
and multiple-purpose projects, has also expressed concern over benefit
estimation. The committee states that project evaluations "should
accurately reflect all primary direct and indirect benefits as well as
the secondary benefits as provided in Senate Document 97." It goes
on to say:
The committee is greatly concerned with this matter and feels that any in-
crease in the discount interest rate should appropriately give attention to recon-
sideration and restatement of principles, standards, and procedures for economic
analyses of Federal water and related land resource projects.
The Public Works and Appropriations Committees of the House of
Representatives state the same case in House Report No. 1549 and
House Report No. 1709, respectively.
These comments and apprehensions suggest that special care should
be taken in the adoption of any new formula for the setting of interest
rates. The action of the Water Resources Council last Friday in pub-
lishing a proposed new formula is to invite comments from all con-
cerned: from the Congress, from the States and local governments,
from industry, conservation groups, the general public as well as from
academic economists and other scholars.
There is little or no substitution for water and its associated re-
sources. Projects and programs in this field provide for national and
regional growth, for employment and for family and social stability,
for us the living as well as those who will come long after we are gone.
Our goal should be to accomplish both full production and the full
life * * * a continuing national prosperity that will include pros-
perity of the human spirit. The material forces and shortrun economic
considerations-that have tried to cast doubt.upon the wisdom of dams
such as Grand Coulee and Hoover with their very long-term benefits,
that have permitted the deterioration of the natural environments, and
that have ignored ecological change and the strong desires of numerous
people for the graces and beauties of the out of doors-should not be
the final determinants of a program's worth.
PAGENO="0012"
8
My remarks are not a plea to abandon or dilute economic analyses.
Our record is clear and very good indeed on the application of eco-
nomics to planning and design, including the use of discounting of
benefits and costs. The Water Resources Council, and all of its members,
intend to continue in this regard and to improve our analyses, taking
into account all the help that is offered to us.
Last Friday, as I have said before, the Council published in the
Federal Register a notice of its proposal for a new interest rate formula
in connection with the formulation and evaluation of Federal and
federally assisted water and related land resources projects. Copies
of that proposal are available for you here today. Mr. Henry P. Caul-
field, Jr., the Executive Director of the Council, will give the back-
ground and details of this proposal. As you may know, he is a profes-
sional economist by training and has a fine reputation as a scholar in
the resources field as well. He also has a rich experience in Federal
water and related land resources programs.
With these remarks I must close. I thank you for the courtesy and
attention you have shown me and for the opportunity to discuss this
most significant question with you.
Thank you.
Representative MOORHEAD (presiding). Mr. Secretary, we thank
you and Secretary Udall.
~Tithout objection, we will now call upon Mr. Henry Caulfield.
STATEMENT OF BENRY P. CAULFIELD, JR., EXECUTIVE DIRECTOR,
WATER RESOURCES COUNCIL
Mr. CAULFIELD. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
I will read my statement. I would like to say, first, that the notice
that appeared in the Federal Register last week, and the proposed
regulation, are attached to my statement.
Representative MOORHEAD. Without objection, they will be made
part of the record. (Seep. 15.)
Mr. OAULFInn. Thank you, sir.
PROPOSED NEW DISCOUNT RATE FOR USE IN THE FORMULATION AND
EVALUATION OF WATER AND RELATED LANE) RESOURCE PLANS
I am very grateful for this opportunity to appear before the Joint
Economic Committee to explain the Water Resources Council's pro-
posed new formula for the determination of the discount rate in the
context of principles, standards, and procedures that now guide the
formulation and evaluation of Federal and federally assisted water
and related land resource plans. Much has been said before the Joint
Economic Committee during the past year about the need to use in-
terest rates or discount rates in the evaluation of Federal programs
generally, and about the discount rate formula now in use for many
years in the evaluation of water resource development projects. In
this connection, many references have been made to "Senate Document
97." Thus I believe it important that the record of these hearings in-
clude testimony by Federal officials concerned with water and related
land resources matters, and specifically about Senate Document 97 and
its provision for the use of discount rates.
PAGENO="0013"
9
Chairman Udall has already noted the provision of the Flood Con-
trol Act of 1936 which initiated explicit benefit-cost analysis of water
resource projects, the many years of painstaking development, testing
and use of evaluation standards that then ensued, and the call by Presi-
dent Kennedy in October 1961 for an "up-to-date set of uniform stand-
ards" that resulted in Senate Document 97, published in May 1962.
SENATE DOCUMENT 97, 87TH CONGRESS
The Council's proposed new formula for the determination of dis-
count rates, published last Friday, July 26, would become, in effect, an
amendment to Senate Document 97. Thus it is important to note, first,
its full title, what the document is, and its major provisions.
Its formal title is "Policies, Standards, and Procedures in the For-
mulation, Evaluation, and Review of Plans for Use and Development
of Water and Related Land Resources." With this long title, quite
understandably, "Senate Document 97" has become its popular title.
It is an executive branch document, in the nature of an interdepart-
ineiital agreement approved by the President, that was published by
the Senate. It was never adopted by the Senate.
As of the day of adoption its provisions have governed, insofar as
they are consistent with law and other applicable regulations, all for-
mulation, evaluation and review of water and related land resource
plans by the Departments of the Army, Agriculture, the Interior and
Health, Education, and Welfare; and, by his letter of approval, Presi-
dent Kennedy made these provisions applicable to the Bureau of the
Budget in its review of projects and programs.
"The basic objective in the formulation of plans," the document
states, "is to provide the best use, or combination of uses, of water and
related land resources to meet all foreseeable short- and long-term
needs." Full consideration is to be given to each of the following sub-
objectives "and reasoned choices made between them when they con-
flict":
DeveZopment of water and related land resources, as part of national
economic development, for:
-Domestic, municipal, industrial, and agricultural water supplies
-Water quality
-Water transportation
-Hydroelectric power
-Flood control
-Land stabilization
-Drainage
-Watershed protection and management
-Recreation and fish and wildlife enhancement; and
-Any other related project development purpose;
Preservation of water and related land resources, as a manifesta-
tion of proper stewardship in the long-term interest of the Nation's
natural bounty, for:
-Protection and rehabilitation of resources to insure availability
for their best use when needed.
-Open space, green space, ~and wild areas of rivers, lakes, beaches,
and mountains.
PAGENO="0014"
10
-Areas of unique natural beauty, historical and scientific interest.
Well-being of people is stated as the overriding determinant in
considering the best use of water and related land resources:
Hardship and basic needs of particular groups within the general public shall
be of concern, but care shall be taken to avoid resource use and development for
the benefit of a few or the disadvantage of many. In particular, policy require-
ments and guides established by the Congress and aimed at assuring that the
use of natural resources, including water resources, safeguards the interests of
all of our people shall be observed.
Planning for the use and development of water and related land
resources, insofar as practicable shall he comprehensive and consider
the needs and possibilities for all significant resource uses and pur-
poses:
All relevant means (including nonstructural as well as structural measures)
singly, or in combination, or in alternative combinations reflecting different
basic choice patterns for providing such uses and purposes-
shall be considered.
Formulation and evaluation of plans, document states, "shall nor-
mally be based on the expectation of an expanding economy." But
plans or alternative plans are to be formulated to permit timely ap-
plication of standards appropriate to conditions of less than "full
employment" nationally, and chronic and persistent unemployment or
underemployment in designated areas:
The prices used for project evaluation should reflect the exchange values ex-
pected to prevail at the time costs are incurred and benefits accrued. Estimates
of initial project costs should be based upon price relationships prevailing at the
time of analysis. Estimates of benefits and deferred costs should be made on the
basis of projected normal price relationships expected with a stabilized general
price level and under relatively full employment conditions for the economy.
All plans shall be formulated with due regard to all pertinent benefits and
costs, both tangible (i.e., capable of expression in monetary terms) and intangi-
ble (i.e., not capable of expression in monetary terms).
* All viewpoints-national, regional, State, and local-shall be fully considered
and taken into account in planning resource use and development.
* Significant departures from a national point of view, requii~ed to
accomplish regional, State, or local objectives, are to be set forth in
planning reports.
When secondary benefits, as distinct from primary benefits (i.e., the
value of goods for services directly resulting from the project, less as-
sociated or induced costs), are included in formulation and evaluation
of a project proposal, then planning reports shall indicate:
(a) The amount of secondary benefits considered attributable to the project
from a national viewpoint. Such benefits, combined with primary benefits, shall be
included in the computation of a benefit-cost ratio.
(b) Secondary benefits attributable to the project from a regional, State, or
local viewpoint. Such benefits shall also be evaluated, when this procedure is con-
sidered pertinent, and an additional benefit-cost ratio computed.
At this point, parenthetically, I would just like to say that this
provision in Senate Document 97 with regard to secondary benefits is
not as widely recognized, both within the Federal Government and
among those concerned outside of the Federal Government, as it should
be. It is a most significant provision; and is, in my professional judg-
ment, a fully justifiable provision.
Now, turning to standards for formulation of plans in terms of bene-
fits and costs, Senate Document 97 directs that comprehensive multiple-
PAGENO="0015"
11
purpose river basin plans "shall be formulated initially to include all
units and purposes which satisfy these criteria in quantitative economic
terms:
(a) Tangible benefits exceed project economic costs.
(b) Each separable unit or purpose provides benefits at least equal to its costs.
(o) The scope of development is such as to provide maximum net benefits; and
(d) There is no more economical means, evaluated on a comparable basis, of
accomplishing the same purpose or purposes which would be precluded from de-
velopment if the plans were undertaken.
These standards for formulation, in the context of appropriate re-
lated criteria (including an appropriate discount rate) constitute what
economists generally refer to as the requirements for economic effi-
ciency. They imply, in this regard, an optimizing model as distinct
from an analytical model for appraising cost effectiveness in meeting
a fixed objective (e.g., a quantity of "firepower" in military analyses).
If an analysis using these standards is based solely upon benefits ap-
propriate to a national viewpoint, then the analysis (within the
limits of the skill of the analyst and the practicability of analysis)
is believed to indicate an optimum contribution to growth in national
income.
I said previously that comprehensive plans were to be formulated
initially to include all units and purposes which satisfy the criteria
of economic efficiency in quantitative economic terms. Senate Docu-
ment 97 states further that this will provide "a baseline from which
the effect of considering intangibles" (e.g., threat to lives, health,
and general security posed by large floods) can be judged. Reports
and plans, the document directs, shall indicate the extent to which
departures from the most efficient economic development are pro-
posed "in order to take into account intangibles or other considera-
tions warranting a modification in scale not reflected in the tangible
benefits and project economic costs."
With the foregoing as a foundation, I would like to turn now,
specifically, to the central focus of this hearing: discount rates.
Discount rates, as has been stated several times in your hearings,
are utilized in planning to convert benefits and costs which are pro-
jected to occur over a period of time to a common time basis. Costs
need to be amortized using a discount rate over the period of years
of analysis (e.g., 50 or 100 years) so that they can be compared prop-
erly with average annual benefits. In arriving at average annual bene-
fits, benefits of the same nominal value beyond the first year are
first discounted each year from time zero by a discount rate to make the
benefits comparable and then their sum is amortized out over the
period of analysis.
Senate Document 97 provides that:
The interest rate to be used in plan formulation and evaluation for dis-
counting future benefits and computing costs . . . shall be based upon the
average rate of interest payable by the Treasury (i.e., the coupon rate) on
interest-bearing marketable securities of the United States outstanding at the
end of the fiscal year preceding such computation which, upon original issue,
had terms to maturity of 15 years or more.
This formula for annual determination of the discount rate is the
same as that which was contained in Budget Bureau Circular A-47,
adopted on December 31, 1952, and withdrawn in May 1962, and that
contained in the Water Supply Act of 1958. The latter provides for
PAGENO="0016"
12
the intere~t rate to be used when obtaining reimbursement over time
from non-Federal interests on Federal investments in municipal and
industrial water supplies.
The subject of interest rates and discount rates has long been the
subject of intense concern. It was prior to promulgation of Senate
Document 97 in 1962 and it is in this hearing.
The concern in 1962 is reflected in t;he following statement contained
in the document:
This procedure shall be subject to adjustment when and if this is found clesir-
able as a result of continuing analysis of all factors pertinent to selection of a
discount rate for these purposes.
In the intervening years, although discussed on many occasions by
those involved in the field of water and related land resources plan-
ning, it was not until April 1967 that the Water Resources Council
`believed it might `be feasible to initiate definite continuing considera-
tion of this subject by its Economics Committee. It then requested the
Committee to do so.
I say "might `be feasible" only because all Committee members have
full-time jobs within their own departments and agencies. The `Water
Resources Council staff, to date, has only been able to assign one-
fourth man-year of concerted professional staff time to `all matters
involved in Senate Document 97. Despite problems of staff time, the
Economics Committee and the `Water Resources Council staff have
been able to contribute very valuably to the Council's consideration
of this important matter.
PROPOSED NEW DISCOUNT FORMULA
The budget message that President J~ohnson sent to the Congress
on January 29, 1968, informed the Congress that-
The Water Resources Council is developing a more appropriate interest rate to
be applied in formulating and evaluating water projects. The revised rate will `be
related to the average estimated current cost to the Treasury of long-term bor-
rowing. It will `be higher than the rate now in use for project evaluation. The
new rate will be applied to future projects in order to assure the `most effective
use of Federal funds in the development of the Nation's water resources.
Later in the budget document, it was stated that-
The interest rate now `being used by Federal agencies in formulating and evaluat-
ing proposed water resource projects is significantly lower than `the cost of bor-
roWing by the Treasury. To improve the evaluation and selection of projects,
administrative action is underway to relate this rate more closely to the average
estimated current cost to the Treasury of long-term borrowing. The new interest
rate, which will be higher than the rate now being used, will be applied in pre-
paring future project evaluation reports.
The reason that the President referred, in this regard, to the Water
Resources Council is that section 103 of the Water Resources Planning
Act provides that-
The Oouncil shall establish, after such consultation with other interested en-
titles, both Federal and non-Federal, as the Council may find appropriate, and
with the approval of the President, principles, standards, and `procedures for
Federal participants in the preparation of comprehensive regional or river basin
plans and for the formulation and evaluation of Federal water and related land
resources projects.
Accordingly, after substantial deliberation in which representatives
of the Bureau of the Budget `and the Department of `the Treasury par-
PAGENO="0017"
13
ticipated, the Water Resources Council has given public notice that it
proposes to establish, under the procedure prescribed in section 103, a
new formula for the determination each year of the discount rate for
use in the formulation and evaluation of Federal plans for use and
development of the Nation's water and related land resources.
Attached to this statement is the Council's notice that appeared in
the Federal Register on July 26, together with the addition to the
Council's rules and regulations which would implement the proposal
if adopted finally by the Council and approved by the President.
Interested persons are invited in the notice to submit written comments,
suggestions, or objections regarding the proposed regulation to me
within 60 days from last Friday.
The basic provision contained in the proposal for determining the
discount rate is as follows:
The interest rate to be used in plan formulation and evaluation for discounting
future benefits and computing costs, or otherwise converting benefits and costs
to a common time basis, shall be based upon the average yield during the preceding
fiscal year on interest-bearing marketable securities of the United States which,
at the time the computation is made, have terms of 15 years or more remaining to
maturity: Provided, however, that in no event shall the rate `be raised or lowered
more than one-quarter percent for any year.
Three points should be highlighted in this proposal.
First, the formula is based upon the current "yield rate" on long-
term Treasury bonds. Thus it is affected by the current market value
of the bonds, whereas the present formula is based upon the "coupon
rate"-that is, the value of the `annual payment by the Treasury on the
bonds regardless of their current value.
Second, the long-term Treasury bonds included in the determination
are only those which, at the time of computation, have terms of 15
years or more `to maturity. The present formula includes bonds which,
"upon original issue," had 15 years or more to maturity.
Finally, the provision should be highlighted "that in no event shall
the rate be raised or lowered more than one-quarter of 1 percent per
year."
Later in the proposal it is stated that "the discount rate to be used
in plan formulation and evaluation during the remainder of fiscal year
1969 shall be 4% percent," except as provided in another section. This
section provides that the present rate of 31/4 percent is to prevail, unless
the Congress otherwise decides, with respect to projects authorized
prior to the close of the second session of the 90th Congress where the
appropriate State or local government agencies have given, prior to
December 31, 1969, satisfactory assurances to pay the required non-
Federal share of project costs.
The current increase in discount rate between the present and the
proposed new formula is 1% percentage points. If the proposed new
formula were based upon the average of bid prices for June of each
year, then for fiscal year 1969 the discount rate would be 51/2 percent.
This would be an increase in the discount rate of 21/4 percentage points.
The President's statement in the budget message calls for a discount
rate "related to the average estimated current cost to the Treasury of
long-term borrowing." The Council's reasons for not proposing a
formula based upon, say, June bid prices-that is, the prices for the
month immediately preceding the beginning of a new "discount
year"-appear to me to be three:
08-940-68-----2
PAGENO="0018"
14
First, the size of the initial change, and the disrupting adjust-
ments to planning programs that it would entail, would be too
great.
It was generally felt that a larger increase would be impractical and
undesirable. The proposed change, itself, would mean that the benefit-
cost ratio of an average long-life capital intensive project of 1.4:1
would be reduced to about 1.0:1.
Second, the degree of yearly fluctuation in the discount rate
needs to be dampened, not accentuated.
Following the yield rate precisely, up and down, could mean a very
substantial change each year in the discount rate. Planning of water
projects from first formulation and evaluation, through congressional
authorization, to appropriation of construction funds, usually takes
5 or more years. It is usually required by the Bureau of the Budget or
the Congress that benefits and costs be recalculated on the basis of the
currently applicable discount rate two or more times during these
years. If the very substantial effect that marked changes in the dis-
count rate can have upon the benefit-cost ratio of a project makes
many projects fluctuate from year to year out of and into the "ball
park" of economic acceptability, then the Federal Government's ad-
ministrative process will be greatly disrupted and made more costly.
Also, congressional and public attitudes will become strongly adverse
to such an unstable process.
To overcome excessive fluctuation in the discount rate from year to
year, the provision was included that the rate would not change, up
or down, by more than one-fourth point each year.
Third, the discount rate to be used in planning water and related
land programs, to be consistent with related provisions in Senate
Document 97, should not be based upon a "bond yield rate" that
is markedly affected by inflationary or deflationary expectations
in the bond market.
No allowance is made for expectations of inflation and deflation in
calculating benefits and costs in Senate Document 97. Thus, no dis-
count rate having such expectations built into it should be used,
unless, of course, all other prices and costs used in the analysis are also
to be adjusted for such expectations.
The actions of the Federal bond market for the past 1 or 2 years
clearly have reflected rising expectations with regard to inflation.
With the passage of the tax bill, recently, yields on long-term Federal
bonds have already declined.
To meet the need for a "deflated" discount rate, the Council's pro-
posal would set the beginning new discount rate at 4% percent. This
rate is based upon the average of bid prices for fiscal year 1966. Also,
the provision of no rise or fall in the discount rate of more than
one-fourth point each year gives some assurance that the discount rate
would not respond inappropriately to expectations of inflation or
deflation in the Federal bond market.
In closing this statement, Mr. Chairman, I would like to state
again that the attachment to this statement includes the Water Re-
sources Council's proposed regulation. No final decision by the Coun-
cil, with the approval of the President, has yet been made. The notice
that appeared in the Federal Register last Friday has provided all
those interested in this matter an opportirnity to provide the Council
PAGENO="0019"
15
with their comments, suggestions and objections within 60 days. Then
the Council will take all communications received into consideration
in making up its mind upon the proposal that will be sent to the
President for his approval.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman, for this opportunity to appear before
the Joint Economic Committee. I hope that this hearing will help
clarify and define the best public interest solution with respect to this
important problem. I trust that it will broaden the range of interest
that is taken within our society in these matters.
Thank you.
Representative MooImEAr. Thank you, Mr. Caulfield. We appre-
ciate your testimony.
(The attachments to Mr. Caulfield's statement follow:)
TITLE 18-CONSERVATION OF POWER AND WATER RESOURCES
Chapter VI-Water Resources Council
DISCOUNT RATE FOR USE IN PLAN FORMULATION AND EVALUATION
NOTICE OF PROPOSED RULE MAKING
Notice is hereby given that the Water Resources Council proposes to establish,
under the procedure prescribed in section 103 of the Water Resources Planning
Act (79 Stat. 244; U.S.C. 1962) a new formula for the determination of the
discount rates for use each year in the formulation and evaluation of plans
for use and development of water and related land resources, by issuing the
regulation set forth below.
The proposed new formula would modify that established by section V. G. 2 of
the interagency agreement dated May 15, 1962, approved by the President on
May 15, 1962, entitled "Policies, Standards, and Procedures in the Formulation,
Evaluation, and Review of Plans for Use and Development of Water and Related
Land Resources", and published on May 29, 1962, as Senate Document No. 97,
87th Congress, 2d Session.
The discount rate for fiscal year 1969, computed as proposed in the regulation
set forth below, would be 4~/8 percent. In following years the rate for any year
would not be changed more than ~4 percentage point from that used during the
previous year. The current discount rate computed on the basis of the present
formula is 314 percent. Interested persons are invited to submit written com-
ments, suggestions or objections regarding the proposed regulation to the Execu-
tive Director, Water Resources Council, 1025 Vermont Avenue, N.W., Washing-
ton, D.C. 20005, within 60 days after the date of publication of this notice in
the Federal Reginter.
HENRY P. CAULFIELD, Jr.,
Ewecutive Director.
Dated July 22, 1968.
TITLE 18-CONSERVATION OF POWER AND WATER RESOURCES
Chapter VT-Water Resources Council
[18 CFR Part 704]
PART 704-PLAN FORMULATION STANDARDS AND PROCEDURES
Subparts A to D [Reserved].
Subpart E-Standards for Plan Formulation and Evaluation.
704.1 to 704.38 [Reserved].
704.39 Discount Rate.
(a) The interest rate to be used in plan formulation and evaluation for dis-
counting future benefits and computing costs, or otherwise converting benefits and
costs to a common time basis, shall be based upon the average yield during the
preceding fiscal year on interest-bearing marketable securities of the United
States which, at the time the computation is made, have terms of 15 years or
more remaining to maturity: Provided, however, that in no event shall the rate
PAGENO="0020"
16
be raised or lowered more than one-quarter of one percent for any year. The
average yield shall be computed as the average during the fiscal year of the
daily bid prices. Where the average rate so computed is not a multiple of one-
eighth of 1 percent, the rate of interest shall be the multiple of one-eighth of 1
percent nearest to such average rate.
(b) The computation shall be made as of July 1 each year, and the rate thus
computed shall be used during the succeeding 12 months. The Executive Director
shall annually request the Secretary of the Treasury to inform the Water Re-
sources Council of the rate thus computed.
(c) Subject to the provisions of subsections (d) and (e) of this section, the
provision of subsections (a) and (b) of this section shall apply to all Federal
and Federally-assisted water and related land resources project evaluation re-
ports submitted to the Congress, or approved administratively, after the close
of the second session of the 90th Congress.
(d) Where construction of a project has been authorized prior to the close
of the second session of the 90th Congress, and the appropriate State or local
governmental agency or agencies have given prior to December 31, 1969, satis-
factory assurances to pay the required non-Federal share of project costs, the
discount rate to be used in the computation of benefits and costs for such project
shall be the rate in effect immediately prior to the effective date of this section,
and that rate shall continue to be used for such project until construction has
been completed, unless the Congress otherwise decides.
(e) Notwithstanding the provisions of subsections (a) and (b) of this section,
the discount rate to be used in plan formulation and evaluation during the
remainder of the fiscal year 1969 shall be 45/s percent except as provided by sub-
section (d) of this section.
(f) Section V. G. 2 of the interagency agreement dated May 15, 1962, approved
by the President on May 15, 1902, entitled "Policies, Standards, and Procedures
in the Formulation, Evaluation, and Review of Plans for Use and Development
of Water and Related Land Resources", and published on May 29, 1962, as Senate
Document No. 97, 87th Congress, 2d Session, is superseded by the provisions of
this section.
(g) This section shall be effective upon publication in the Federal Register.
Representative MOORHEAD. The subcommittee would like now to
hear from Mr. Hoffman, Assistant Director of the Bureau of the
Budget.
Mr. Hoffman, would you also identify for the record your associate?
STATEMENT OP FRED HOFFMAN, ASSISTANT DIRECTOR, BUREAU
OP THE BUDGET, ACCOMPANIED BY JACK W. CARLSON, DIREC-
TOR, PROGRAM EVALUATION STA~T, BUREAU OP THE BUDGET
Mr. HOFFMAN. Mr. Chairman, Senator Jordan, I have with me this
morning Mr. Jack W. Carlson, the Director of the Program Evalu-
ation Staff of the Bureau of the Budget, who will assist me in answer-
ing your questions.
Mr. Chairman and Senator Jordan, I am very happy to appear
before this committee. I believe the subcommittee in its hearings so
far has provided a number of useful papers and has stimulated a
good deal of healthy discussion of subjects that concern me greatly
in my work at the Bureau. I am particularly pleased that the question
of discounting has been raised in the context of the PPB hearings.
I welcome the subcommittee's strong support of the kind of analysis
that is being developed by the planning, programing, and budgeting
system.
This morning, with your permission, I would like to insert into
the record the full statement that I have prepared for the committee
and, `because of its length, merely propose to summarize it at this
point.
PAGENO="0021"
17
Representative MOORHEAD. Without objection, the full statement
will appear in the record and you may now proceed to summarize.
Mr. HOFFMAN. The gist of my remarks will be to emphasize the
complexity of decisions about public investment. My remarks will
be under several headings:
First, I would like to consider complexities in the analysis of public
expenditures generally.
Second, I would like to consider alternative rationales for the ap-
plication of discounting and for the development of discount rates.
Third, I would like to consider the applications of discounting to
public investment decisions as they are made m the course of the
operation of the Executive. Finidly, I would like to present some
thoughts on recent developments and desirable procedures for dis-
counting.
With respect to the analysis of Government expenditures generally,
the primary source of complexity arises from the multiplicity of
Government objectives. There are a number of ways of classifying
the reasons for Government activity. The classification that I would
like to present categorizes these reasons as follows:
First, the provision of public goods; that is, goods whose consump-
tion by one individual does not reduce the amount available for con-
sumption by others. The prime example is, of course, national security;
Second, the redistribution of income;
Third, dealing with spillovers-situations in which one individual's
decisions may affect another and there is no mechanism that forces the
actor to take these effects into account. A prime example of this, is the
emission of pollutants where, as individuals, we do not have to take
account of the amount of pollution we emit.
Fourth, the management of publicly owned resources, such as tim-
berlands or mineral resources. Here, the Government has the obligation
of managing the resources it owns in a way that is efficient from the
point of view of the social welfare.
Fifth, removal of imperfections in the functioning of the private
market system or alleviation of their effects. Examples are the use of
public enterprise to provide competitive standards or the provision of
better information to consumers and producers.
Evaluation of Government activities is made particularly difficult
because each one is likely to have objectives that cut across a number of
the categories I have mentioned. As one example, let me refer to man-
power training programs. They have as one of their effects the transfer
of income to the participants in the program through an increase in
the investment in the human capital of those individuals.. It is also
argued that. they have provided the public good of an improvement in
the quality of the citizenry, particularly in its capacity as au dee-
toraite. I believe it is generally felt that productive, responsible, self-
reliant individuals make a better electorate, and one of the objectives
of our manpower training programs is to increase the number of people
in this category.
The programs also have spillover effects. They reduce the need for
social services and, perhaps, reduce the crime rate in the areas where the
participants live, and increase productivity in the economy as a whole
by overcoming the ignorance of some of the participants about the link
between training and income.
PAGENO="0022"
18
In the case of this group of programs then, it is obvious that we
have a very complex set of effects and objectives.
The problem is compounded because objectives often conflict in the
comparison of programs. As one example, consider on-the-j oh training
and Job Corps programs. Analyses suggest that on-the-job training
programs have higher benefit-cost ratios where the benefits are meas-
ured in terms of the expected increase in income of the participants.
The Job Corps, on the other hand, has a much higher percentage of
disadvantaged people participating in the program. Comparison of
these two programs, therefore, reveals conflicts between the obj ective
of economic efficiency and those of income transfer, public goods obj ec-
tives, and spill-over elimination. The conflict must be resolved when
we determine what priority to give the various components of our
manpower program.
Because of the conflict, an evaluation of manpower training pro-
grams may raise the question of how to measure the value of a dollar
of income transferred to someone in the group of hard core unem-
ployecl as compared with transferring it to someone in the middle
classes. Can we in fact assign some quantitative value greater than
one to a dollar transferred to a poor person? I think we feel, both
individually and collectively, that a dollar so transferred is in fact
worth more than the dollar taken away from the upper income class,
but I suspect we would be hard put to find a specific quantitative
value for such a measure. I might also add that economics offers no
conceptual basis for such a determination.
As a consequence, we find that dollar measures are applicable only
to certain components of the objectives of our public activities. There
are several important consequences of this state of affairs. `Where the
nonmarket components of our objectives are especially important in
program analysis, cost-benefit analysis cannot tell us how far to
extend program activities. When we are dealing with a purely market-
determined kind of program, as we might be in the management of
some of our public resources, one can argue that a cost-benefit ratio
greater than unity is essential to going ahead with a project. Where we
are dealing with programs that have very important components
that cannot be measured by the market, we cannot make such a state-
ment. We cannot guide our manpower training programs, for example,
completely by cost-benefit ratios, cutting them off unless we get a
figure of unity and arranging our priorities purely in terms of the
size of the cost-benefit ratio.
Another consequence is that we have great difficulty in making com-
parisons of program activities across major areas of government
activity. If the market does not provide a measure of the value of
national security, we have no conceptual basis for determining how
much national security we should have as compared with highways,
dams, and education. We cannot fully determine the national priori-
ties in broad program areas by such quantitative analysis.
A third consequence concerns the nature of the analysis we do.
Where market-determined elements are important or dominant, we
do and should do cost-benefit analysis. Where the nOnmarket elements
are quite important, we do a different kind of analysis which I will
refer to as cost-effectiveness analysis. We specify a job that ought to
be done and examine the most efficient way of doing that job.
PAGENO="0023"
19
Now, we can explore the effect of changes in the nature of the job
on the cost of doing it, but basically we are dealing with dollar meas-
ures on the cost side and some nondollar specification of the nature of
the job and its output on the benefit side. I will return to the distinction
between those two types of analyses in the consideration of discounting.
Let me now turn from the problem of public expenditures gen-
erally to the problem of public investment and discounting. The dis-
tinction is based on the explicit consideration of time. Public invest-
ments, like other investments, typically have an early net outlay, fol-
lowed by a later net inflow of resources. In order to determine whether
an investment is worthwhile, it is necessary to compare the early net
outlay with the later return. This means comparing dollar quantities
received at different points in time.
Economics has developed a widely accepted rationale for such com-
parisons. It is based on the balance between the existence of a prefer-
ence by consumers for present consumption over future consumption-
the chicken in the hand is worth more than the one in the bush. It is
also based on the productive possibilities open to us by investment in
physical capital assets that increase the efficiency of production.
Given these two factors-time preference and production possi-
bilities-and given the ability of consumers to alter the time stream
of their consumption by borrowing and lending, a single rate of in-
terest would occur if there were no uncertainty; consumers and en-
trepreneurs would both adjust their activities to that rate of in-
terest. In a world where there are no barriers among markets and no
risk or uncertainty, the Government, too, should use that single rate
of interest as its discount rate in choosing its investment programs.
To depart from the rate would reduce the total productivity of the
economy, including the Government goods and services.
Chairman PROXMIRE (now presiding). Will you repeat that state-
ment ~ Go back one sentence before that, please.
Mr. HOFFMAN. Surely.
The reason for the application of the single discount rate in this
simple model of the economy, is that if the Government departed from
this rate, it would, in effect, be reducing the total value of goods and
services available to the economy, including Government goods and
services.
The reason is that the application of a discount rate higher than the
interest rate would cause the Government to ignore investments that
had a larger return than that available from opportunities in the
private sector, thus diverting resources into lower payoff areas. The
application of a discount rate lower than this interest rate would re-
sult in the opposite effect; there would be overinvestment in Govern-
ment programs because of the diversion of resources from higher
return private investment.
Problems arise, however, as a result of departures from this over-
simplified model. As a result of barriers to entry, the administrative
costs of borrowing and lending, and imperfections in information,
markets are not perfect and funds do not flow among them without
friction. Even more important is the fact that risk and uncertainty are
an inherent aspect of our economic activity. `When we take into account
these departures from the simplest model, we find that a number of dif-
PAGENO="0024"
20
ferent positions may be adopted with respect to the rationale for the
adoption of a discount rate.
The first rationale is one that retains the notion of opportunity cost;
it looks on the discount rate applied to Govermnent programs as re-
flecting the cost of the funds withdrawn from the economy. However,
there are two variants of this approach-one says, simply, we ought to
look at the opporti~mity cost in terms of funds withdrawn from in-
vestment in real physical capital. It assumes that all resources used
would have been invested. A variant of this approach, somewhat more
complex, states the problem more broadily. It notes that funds used by
Government programs are withdrawn not only from investment in
real physical capital, but also from consumption. Its proponents would
argue the appropriate rate is a weighted average of the two, with the
weights determined by the impact on private s!pending of Federal
taxes and borrowing required to fund Federal program activities.
A radical departure from the first two concepts is one which rejects
the judgment of the private market as a basis for determining the dis-
count rate and which holds that the discount rate ought to be a tool of
policy and should specifically reflect governmental objectives. One of
the objectives referred to most often is concern for future generations,
who cannot express their desires in the private market. Another one is
concern for growth, not simply for the income consequences of growth
in the economy, but concern for the broader social consequences of
being in an expanding economy with its greater possibilities for mobil-
ity and relatively painless change.
Still another and quite distinct concept for determining the discount
rate is the cost to the Federal Government of borrowing. This has been
offered as a rationale in the General Accounting Office survey that has
been presented to this siThcommittee. In this version, the rate is de-
terniined by the cost of borrowing plus the income taxes forgone by
the Government. In effect, this concept would reflect the revenue and
spending impact of Govermnent borrowing. It is a budgetary concept
of the discount rate. It would be appropriate, I might add, if one
viewed the Government as having the primary objective of maximiz-
ing its net worth, as economists argue private firms do.
Let me turn now from the alternative rationales for determining the
discount rate to some considerations of the way in which discounting
fits into public investment decisions.
First, given the complex circumstances under which Government
decisions are made, I think there is a strong argument for looking not
only at some overall aggregative measure of the costs and benefits of
Government programs, but also for looking at their year-by-year cost
and benefit implications. We would not need to do this if the Govern-
ment were free to borrow or lend, if it were not subject to specific
budgetary constraints. But given the actual environment in which
public investment decisions are made, there is useful information in
a year-by-year look at the costs and benefits. This does not, however,
get at the question of how we evaluate costs and benefits nearer in
time as opposed to those in the more distant future. To do that we
need to develop a present value concept by applying a discount rate.
I might mention at this point that neither in my paper nor in these
remarks have I covered the notion of the internal rate of return. I
believe that there are problems in the application of that concept, and
I would be glad to discuss it if that were felt to be desirable.
PAGENO="0025"
21
On the question of how to determine the discount rate to apply to
Government investment decisions, my own view is that the broader
of the two opportunity cost methods mentioned is the more appro-
priate. However, there are, at this time, practical difficulties in deter-
mining the value to be assigned under that concept and in getting
general agreement on such a value. Therefore, as a pragmatic solution,
it seems to me that there is merit in adopting a two-part approach,
based partly on the distinction that I made earlier between programs
in which it is appropriate to consider cost-benefit analysis and those in
which we are forced by the inapplicability of market measurement
to rely on cost-effectiveness analysis. In programs where cost-benefit
analysis is appropriate, and particularly in that set of such programs
where the Government goods and services correspond to those of a
particular sector of the private market, we ought to use the rate of
return that currently applies in that sector of the private market. Care
should be taken to define that sector broadly enough so that the effects
of local or specific market imperfections, which themselves may be the
targets of Government action, are largely averaged out.
In other cases I believe that the approach should be to apply a
rate that reflects a riskless opportunity cost averaged over the entire
private sector and then to reflect risk explicitly in the calculations of
costs and benefits. I believe that by doing this we create greater possi-
bilities for reaching common understanding about the basis for deci-
sions than we do when we try to estimate risk on the basis of what a
"similarly risky" activity in the private sector is currently yielding.
If, however, for other reasons it apppears desirable to treat risk in
terms of a discount rate of set of discount rates, they ought to be
identified explicitly as risk premiums added to the riskiess rate that
would apply generally to Government programs.
Now, the question is, what rate to use.
I have identified differences among economists on the conceptual
basis for discounting, but, by and large, I think those differences may
not be as large as the differences that appear when we try to identify
a specific rate, a number, to use. Given this situation, it seems to me
that we can still say that the rate ought not to be any less than the
yield on Government bonds with long terms to maturity. I believe that
most economists would set the rate higher than this, but I could not
at this point pick a number and say that 90 percent of economists
would agree on that number.
One way of handling this uncertainty would be to test the results
of analyses for sensitivity to rates above the yield on Government
bonds to see whether it makes a difference, and then to try to argue the
question outin the context of particular programs.
With that, let me turn to recent developments and sum up what I
think a desirable procedure would involve. You have heard earlier this
morning from Mr. Holum and Mr. Caulfield on the recent develop-
ments with respect to water resource programs in which the Water
Resources Council has taken the lead. The Bureau of the Budget has
worked with the Water Resources Council quite effectively in this, I
believe.
In the course of providing PPB guidelines for several other agen-
cies, we have also adopted a procedure which I think offers the pos-
sibility of generalization after review and further consideration. We
PAGENO="0026"
22
have asked that several agencies, in evaluating their programs, dis-
count cost and benefit streams at a 10-percent rate, and then test for
sensitivity to 7.5 and 12.5 percent rates. In these cases, our thinking
was largely along the lines that we would identify the activity with
corres}~onding sectors of the private economy.
I might also mention a recent study of oil shale development in
which the economic attractiveness of oil shale development to private
developers was tested at rates of 12 percent and 20 percent as a basis
for determining whether this was economically attractive and for
analyzing what government actions might be indicated.
Now, to sum up, I believe a desirable procedure would require, first,
a display over the expected life of the program of costs and benefits
or physical outputs as part of the analysis for decisionmaking. We
now require this in the program memoranda and the program and
financial plans under the PPB system.
Second, for programs that have both costs and benefits expressable
in dollars and which directly displace private investment in a specific
sector, the rate of return in that sector is an appropriate discount rate
for calculating the present value of costs and benefits.
Third, for most public investment, we should use as the appropriate
rate the private returns that must be foregone over the economy as
a whole to release funds for public investment. This rate should elim-
inate allowances for risk, providing that costs and benefits are ex-
plicitly adjusted to allow for the risk of the public project.
Fourth, a riskiess rate of return in the private sector should not be
less than the rate of return on long-term Government bonds, and
neither should the discount rate. Studies should be undertaken to
develop a more reliable basis for estimating the riskiess rate of return
in the private sector.
Fifth, in analyzing programs, we should test for sensitivity to varia-
tions in the discount rate.
Sixth, where subsidies are regarded as socially desirable, we should
express them explicitly in cost-benefit calculations rather than in the
discount rate.
I believe that the above points represent the direction in which
we have been moving and will continue to move and that this move-
ment will produce significant improvement in the analysis of Gov-
~rnrnent investment programs. In the coming months, the Bureau of
the Budget, in cooperation with Federal agencies and departments,
will be continuing its work to improve the use of discounting in the
evaluation of public investment programs.
I might simply add that my discussion of the problem, which has
stressed the complexity of the problem is not, in my mind, an excuse
for abandoning the attempt to apply explicit quantitative analysis
to decisions about Government programs. Rather, it is a challenge to
develop appropriate concepts and the needed data.
Thank you. I appreciate the opportunity to present this to you.
(The prepared statement of Mr. Hoffman follows:)
PREPARED STATEMENT OF HON. FRED S. HOFFMAN, ASSISTANT
DIRECTOR OF THE BUREAU OF THE BUDGET
I am happy to appear before this subcommittee to discuss the question of dis-
counting in the evaluation of Government investment programs. This question
is, of course, a part of the larger question of the evaluation of public expendi-
PAGENO="0027"
23
tures-a principal concern of the Planning, Programing, and Budgeting (PPB)
System. Since the introduction of that system to the nonmilitary side of the
~lovernment, the major Executive Departments and agencies, and the Bureau
of the Budget in particular, have devoted much effort to improving the process
by which Government resources are allocated to accomplish the various objec-
tives of public policy. My remarks will be organized to try to set the problem of
discouting in the context of the broader objectives of improving decisions about
government resource allocation. Recent discussions of PPB before this sub-
committee and before the Senate Subcommittee on National Security and Inter-
national Operations of the Government Operations Committee have emphasized
that decisions about public expenditures should and do have a broader basis
than formal, quantitative analysis. I know of no one concerned with the develop-
ment of PPB who believes that a time will come when formal, quantitative
analysis will or should completely determine decisions about public expenditures.
Nevertheless, the need to develop such analysis is, I believe, among the most
urgent requirements in order to improve the quality of Government.
COMPLEXITIES IN EVALUATING PUBLIC EXPENDITURES
The reasons for dwelling on the limitations of quantitative analysis are to be
found at the starting point of PPB-the broad objectives of Government expendi-
ture. PPB is intended to assure that every dollar taxed or borrowed and spent
by the Government will return at least a dollar's value, but the determination
of that value is often a more complex thing for public than for private expendi-
ture. This arises from the complexity of the objectives of most government pro-
grams. The objectives of public programs affecting resource allocation can be
classified as follows:
-The provision of public goods-that is, goods whose consumption by one
individual does not reduce the amount available for consumption by another.
Decisions about such goods have to be made collectively. Examples are deter-
rence of war and the preservation of scenic beauty.
-The redistribution of income to assist specific groups, such as the poor, the
aged, the disadvantaged. Redistribution may be effected by the transfer of money
income or by the provision of goods and services. An example of the first type is
the public assistance program; food distribution programs are an example of
the second.
-The elimination of spillover effects-situations where John Doe's actions
may benefit or harm Richard Roe in ways that can be ignored by John Doe's
decisions, as when he burns leaves upwind or deposits sewage upriver from his
neighbor in the absence of appropriate charges or regulations.
-The management of publicly-owned resources, such as mineral lands, forests,
waterways and so on, in a way that will insure their efficient use from the
point of view of society.
-The removal of imperfections in the operation of the private market, or
the alleviation of their effects. Examples are the use of public enterprise to
provide a competitive standard where none would otherwise exist, and the
provision of better information to consumers or producers where the market
would otherwise work badly.
Unfortunately for simplicity in the evaluation of government programs, almost
all of them have implications for more than one of the objectives discussed
above. Public expenditures on education may produce transfers of income to the
beneficiaries; it may also provide society a public good in the form of a better
educated electorate, spillover benefits in terms of a reduction in the crime rate
associated with increasing educational levels in the area where the beneficiaries
live, and an improvement in the operation of the labor market as a result of
increasing the information of private individuals about the relation between
education and opportunity. Clearly not all these dimensions of the performance
of our public education programs can be subjected to measurement in terms of
dollars. The dollar yardstick for the measurement of benefits is relevant only
where a private market for the goods or services does or coui `~xist. Since no
private market can evaluate the political value of a better edi~ated electorate,
that element of the output of public education programs must be measured in
non-dollar terms or must be considered qualitatively. This, as I shall discuss
below, has important implications for the evaluation of public expenditures and
for policy on discounting, in particular.
The evaluation of our manpower programs illustrates how multiple criteria
can complicate the task of analysis. It would be easier to evaluate those pro-
PAGENO="0028"
24
grams if the criterion for selection of improvement of programs were solely the
addition to income, no matter whose income is increased. But it does matter
who benefits. For example, an analysis of the Job Corps program estimates
that average net earnings gained by participants in the program are 200 per-
cent of the per-trainee costs. In addition, the program is and should be evaluated
by the characteristics of the recipients of the assistance. Nearly all of the
recipents are poor and under 21 years of age. In comparison, an analysis of
our 1987 experience with the Manpower Development Training Act On the
Job Training Program indicates that this program apparently increases the
average earnings of participants by about five times the cost, but only one-third
of the participants were poor and under 21. In order to choose the desired mix of
programs-or for possible orientation of each program-a weighting for each
criterion is necessary, and we have no objective social basis for assigning a
specific value to a dollar transferred to a poor person relative to a dollar trans-
ferred to someone with higher income.
When we are dealing with a program that has the provision of a public good or
the redistribution of income as an important part of its objectives, evaluation
must take the form of cost-effectiveness analysis rather than cost-benefit analysis.
A cost-effectiveness analysis, as I am using the term, is an analysis that com-
pares the cost of alternative ways of doing a given job with output measured
in physical, social or some other non-market-oriented terms. I contrast it with
the typical cost-benefit analysis that compares costs and benefits directly in
dollar terms.
The distinction is one with important implications for the analysis of pub-
lie resource allocation. Unlike cost-benefit analysis, cost-effectiveness analysis
does not provide information on how far we should carry public expenditure
in a specific program area. To choose an obvious example, the meaninglessness of
a dollar value of changes in the strength of our deterrence of nuclear war
makes it necessary to determine the level of deterrence by the judgment of the
responsible officials; in the water resource area, by contrast, there is general
acceptance of the proposition that only projects whose dollar benefits at least
equal the costs (approximately computed) should be undertaken.
The inability to compare the value of additional spending on national security
and on water resources, or education, or highways means that formal, quantita-
tive analysis cannot determine the broad priorities among areas of government
spending. If the principal role of analysis is, as I believe, in choosing efficient
ways of achieving public objectives witMm each of the broad areas of public
activity, nevertheless, it has an important role in improving the process by which
political, social, and economic considerations are combined to determine broad
priorities. I believe it can exercise thi's role by making more explicit and sum-
marzing more effectively the cost and output consequences of alternative resource
allocations.
Even when benefits and/or costs can be measured in common resources, there
are problems in measurement. Cost estimates are usually based on engineering
drawings which generally exhibit predictable degrees of accuracy. Estimates of
benefits, however, must often rely on more speculative data, such as unforeseen
changes in technology and population shifts which will affect the benefits that
accrue from additional irrigation land, protection of urban lands from potential
flooding, and new recreational facilities. Under these difficult measurement con-
ditions, estimates of benefits are likely to have, at best, substantial margins of
uncertainty.
THE RATIONALE FOR DIscouNTING IN EVALUATING PimLIc INVESTMENTS
Let me turn next from the evaluation of public expenditures in general to the
evaluation of public investments. The distinction rests, of course, on the intro~
duction of time into the considerations of costs and benefits. The typical invest-
ment program is one in which an early net outlay of resources is balanced by a
later net inflow of resources. The evaluation of patterns of net resource flows
requires some method of comparing different streams over time. The economist's
approach to this problem is derived from the possibility open to an individual of
altering the time stream of resources available to him by borrowing or lending,
or some combination of both over time. The terms under which present income
can be traded for future income are, of course, determined by consumers' time
preference for income on the one hanil anti by th~ productivity of capital on
the other.
PAGENO="0029"
25
THE SIMPLEST MODEL FOR DETERMINING TUE DISCOUNT RATE
In the simplest model of our economy there is only one rate of interest facing
lenders and borrowers and governing the rate of investment in productive capi-
tal. The effect of an increase in the rate is not only `to make it undesirable to
engage in `some investment projects or to reduce the total level of investment
but also to change the character of those projects adopted, making them less
capital intensive and more labor intensive. In `this simplest model, and given
the objective of maximizing gross national product, the Government, too, would
apply this rate to evaluating future as opposed to present benefits and costs. It is
widely accepted among economists that this model is inadequate because it over-
simplifies our economy. However, there is less unanimity as to the extent and the
way in which this model should be modified to reflect reality for public policy
purposes.
An important limitation on `the applicability of the model is the existence of
market imperfections 1)0th with respect to `restrictions on entry of capital into
given fields of economic activity and with respect to the information available
to investors and savers. Another equally important limitation is the existence
of risk and uncertainty-the likelihood of realizing the benefits. As a result of
these departures from the simplest model, we find consumers borrowing at much
higher rates th'an `they receive on their savings and substantial variations in
the rate of return on different types of securities and in different industries.
Moreover, the possibility of changes in price levels is also reflected in the market
rates of return on saving and investment.
THE DISCOUNT RATE AS DETERMINED BY PRIVATE RETURNS FOREGONE
In the face of this more complicated view of private investment decisions, it
is possible to distinffuish several alternative conceptual bases for the determina-
tion of a discount rate to be used by the Government for the evaluation of
investments. The simplest position holds that the appropriate rate is the average
ra'te of return in private industry on investments in productive capital assets,
before corporate income taxes. This position is justified on the grounds that
the `opportunity cost of a dollar of public spending is its productivity in private
investment. Unless, therefore, each dollar of pu1)lic investment yields at least
the rate of return in private industry, GNP could be increased, it is argued, by
reducing taxes or borrowing and spending and letting private investment
increase.
A more complex position, but one with the same basic rationale, would reflect
not only the rate of return on productive investment in private industry, but
would make allowance for the ra'tes received and paid by various classes of
consumers. The relative influence of each component on the average is to be
determined by the extent to which additional Federal taxation or borrowing
displaces private investment or consumption. This approach can be quite de-
tailed to take account of the incidence of the increase in taxation on various
classes of consumers an'd investors who face different rates as a result of market
imperfections. This concept, like the preceding one, is basically an opportunity
cost concept.
THE DISCOUNT RATE AS A REFLECTION OF SOCIAL OBJECTIVES
A third concept is a more radical departure. In this approach, the judgment of
the private market is not accepted as the final arbiter of `the appropriate discount
rate for Government programs: instead the discount rate is viewed as a tool for
expressing and carrying out distinctively public objectives. Therefore, it is argued,
the discount rate should be affected by, but need not be identical with the rate
reflecting private opportunities foregone. A form of this position commonly ad-
vanced is the argument that the market rate or complex of rates does not permit
future generations to express their preference in the market place and that the
Government should act as the guardian of their interests, presumably by using a
lower than market rate and thereby producing a shift of income into the future.
It might also be argued that the Government should value growth for its own
sake, apart from the additional income generated, because the viability and vital-
ity of a democratic society are increased by creating more opportunities for up-
ward mobility and change. It is always easier to make desirable changes when
growth permi'ts reallocations in which everyone benefits-even if unequally-
than when reallocation means taking from one person to give to another.
PAGENO="0030"
26
Apart from the fact that specific non-market objectives introduced into the
determination of the rate under this third concept can be questioned (how much
current income should we sacrifice for increasing the real income of future gen-
erations whose average per capita income is likely to be several times Our own?),
it also raises questions of inconsistency between the private and public sectors
and the propriety of expressing the various objectives through the discount rate
for Government investment programs as opposed to other policy variables.
As an alternative to applying a special discount rate, specific social objectives
in particular sectors can be reflected by adjusting benefits apprOpriately, or by
first selecting the size of budgets to be allocated for each public purpose and then
evaluating each project to determine allocation of the limited budget. Social pur-
poses, such as growth and investment for future generations could be incorporated
in criteria that cover both the private and public sectors though they need not be
as broad as policy directed at the overall level of economic activity. For example,
the investment tax credit, by stimulating private investment would promote con-
sistent growth in both public and private sectors.
Adherents of this approach, nonetheless, argue that on pragmatic grounds the
Government should go as far as it can in achieving social objectives through
broad policies, such as monetary and fiscal policy, but if constraints on its free-
dom of action prevent it from imposing a suitable investment policy over the en-
tire economy as a whole, or over large sectors of it, it should accept the second
best solution of adjusting selective or all public investment so far as possible to
achieve proper social objectives.
THE DISCOUNT BATE AS DETERMINED BY REVENUE-EXPENDITURE EFFECTS OF
GOVERNMENT BORROWING
A fourth rationale for the determination of the rate of return which is quite
distinct from each of the others, is the notion of basing the discount rate on the
Government cost of borrowing. One version of this concept, discussed by the help-
ful recent General Accounting Office survey, is the cost of Government borrow-
ing adjusted for taxes foregone. This concept is neither a private opportunity
cost concept nor a social cost concept. Rather it expresses the combined impact
on governmental expenditures (in terms of interest outlays) and revenues (in
terms of taxes foregone) of Government borrowing. This expenditure-revenue
concept implicitly views the Government as though it were an organization at-
tempting to maximize its net worth, as a profit-maximizing private firm does.
THE APPLICATION OF DISCOUNTING TO PUBLIC INVESTMENT DECISIONS
Having reviewed several alternative rationales for the determination of a
discount rate, I should next like to look somewhat more closely at the way
in which discounting fits into the evaluation of investment programs before
discussing the determination of an appropriate rate.
In view of the complexity of the problem, it may be appropriate to start
with a fairly direct approach and suggest that decision makers faced with the
need to choose among alternative streams of net benefits over time, should
begin by looking at the benefits and costs, year-by-year. In a simple world
where the decision-maker was faced with unlimited options to borrow or lend
at a fixed interest rate, this would be unnecessary, but in the world in which
decisions are actually made the ability of the Government to lend or borrow
is limited, the rates are variable over time, and agency budgets cannot be
freely shifted from one year to the next. Under these circumstances the year-
by-year picture of cost and benefit flows may contain highly useful information
to a decision maker. Such a benefit was foreseen from the initiation of the multi-
year Program and Financial Plan in the PPB System. Year-by-year compari-
sons, however, are too complex to be used except where the number of alterna-
tives is relatively few. Where comparisons must be made among a large number
of alternatives, it is necessary to resort to some form of aggregative measure.
Moreover, even where the number of alternatives is small, such comparisons
do not of themselves reflect the fact that dollars now have different and greater
value than dollars in the fr'tnre.
The search for relatively simple measures by which to compare alternative
benefits and costs over time has, unfortunately, produced a wide variety of
such measures, many of which have only simplicity to recommend them. The
recent General Accounting Office survey documents this point. Improvements of
current practices are both possible and desirable, but because of the complexity
PAGENO="0031"
27
of Government objectives and the nature of Government programs, I do not
believe that the proper approach at this time is to attempt to fix a single discount
rate to be applied uniformly over the entire Government. Nonetheless, I believe
it is possible to identify a conceptual basis for selecting public discount rates.
The public investment discount rate should be based on private returns foregone
in consumption and investment and should be adjusted for different methods for
treating risk and inflation between private and public sectors. I believe this
is preferable to the alternative of adopting the rate of return on private invest-
ment foregone alone because Government funds are drawn from both con-
sumption and investment. It is preferable to the social objective approach be-
cause the alternative of directly expressing social objectives in cost and benefit
estimates will produce greater clarity about such objectives and permit con-
sistency between private and public investment policy. It is generally preferable
to the revenue-expenditure concept because the Government's objectives are
usually broader than those of a private firm, since the Government must deal
with public goods, the redistribution of income, and the broad conditions for
efficiency in the economy which are not inherent in corporate decisions. Until
however, the rate implied by the preferred conceptual basis can be measured
accurately and on a continuing basis, we must be pragmatic and use acceptable
substitutes for what the "real" rate must be.
EVALUATING PUBLIC INVESTMENTS COMPARABLE TO PRIVATE ACTIVITIES
It is useful given our uncertainty about the appropriate rate and the measure-
ment of risk to approach the problem by distinguishing two classes of Govern-
ment programs, those that supply goods or services similar to goods and services
being sold in private markets. and those that have objectives that are peculiar to
a government. Obviously, such a distinction must deal with gradations and not
completely discrete categories. Examples of the first type of program might be
those dealing with the administration of Federally-owned mineral or timber
resources, or with the sale of uranium enrichment services from the Federally-
owned Gaseous Diffusion Plants. The primary example of the second type of
program is, of course, to be found in the Defense Department, but our poverty
programs are also heavily weighted in this direction.
Where Government programs can be identified with a particular sector of the
economy and where the programs will probably displace private investment in
that sector, I would argue that the private rate of return on analogous kinds of
investments over the given sector is the appropriate rate for the evaluation of
public investment inclusive of allowance for risk. The sector should be defined
broadly enough to average out the effects on rates of return of specific market
imperfections that would be affected by the proposed Government program and
that may be a principal reason for it. In this way we can take advantage of the
judgment of the private market of a rate inclusive of an appropriate degree
of risk.
EVALUATING PUBLIC INVESTMENTS PECULIAR TO THE PUBLIC SECTOR
The second class of Government programs is quite different however, since
there is no private analogue nor is there likely to be direct displacement of in-
vestment in a single sector of the economy, nor is it generally possi'ble to ex-
press the costs and benefits completely in dollar terms. The significance of the last
point has been discussed above.
For such programs that constitute, I believe, the preponderance of Govern-
ment activities, the appropriate rate at which to discount future costs is a rate
that reflects the opportunity cost of Government spending over the economy as a
whole.
The Treatme~mt of Risk.-However, it is necessary to consider how to handle
risk for such programs. The opportunity cost as inferred from either the rate
of return on productive investment or the weighted average of returns from
deferred consumption and from productive investments foregone, will reflect
some allowance for risk. This occurs because most people when offered a 50-50
chance of getting either zero or $1,000 would be willing to pay less than $500 for
the opportunity. That is to say they try to avoid risk and require compensa-
tion for undertaking it. While I certainly do not wish to argue that Government
programs are riskiess-on the contrary they are often subject to considerable
risk-I believe that better decisions are likely to result from considering the
risks explicitly by adjusting the expected costs and benefits than by attempting
PAGENO="0032"
28
to relate the average risk of peculiarly public programs to "similarly risky"
investments in the private sector.1
Moreover, although there are some reasons for believing that risk increases
as the cost and benefit is farther and farther removed in the future there is
no obvious reason to expect riskiness to compound in the way that the discount
rate does, nor is there any very good basis for expecting similar degrees of risk
or uncertainty on both the cost and benefit side. Also, when only the cost stream
rather than a stream of net benefits is to be discounted, attempting to reflect
differential riskiness among alternative projects may give the wrong signal. If
the discount rate is increased to reflect higher risk, the present value of the
cost stream will be reduced and the riskier project will tend to be preferred.
For these reasons, I believe it is preferable to use a riskless rate to discount
cost streams in cost-effectiveness analyses, and to reflect risk in an increase in
the expected year-by-year costs or a reduction in benefits. If, however, risk is
to be handled in terms of the discount rate, a risk increment `should be explicitly
identified and added to the basic, riskless rate.
Treatment of hiflation.-Finally, the observed rates of return in the private
sector in all probability include some allowance for inflation. Since most analyses
of Government programs are and shoud be, I would argue, carried out in terms
of constant dollar cost estimates, the allowance for inflation in the observed
rates of return should be eliminated. Without such an adjustment to the dis-
count rate, the calculation of anticipated benefits in constant prices would be
penalized more than costs which generally are closer in time, and the result-
ing benefit-cost calculation would be inappropriately low.
THE CHOICE OF AN APPROPRIATE DISCOUNT RATE
At this point, unfortunately, it is very difficult to make the transition from
the rationale for a discount rate to the choice of specific numbers. It would
be expected that those economists who hold that the appropriate rate is
determined by the rate of return on productive investment would choose a
higher rate than those who favor a weighted average of both private productive
investments and consumption foregone in the private sector, and that the
second group, in turn, would choose a higher rate than those who favor a
weighting by social preferences. It would not surprise me greatly, however, to
learn that uncertainty in estimation outweighs the conceptual differences.
On one point, nevertheless, I believe they would all agree and that is that the
estimate of a long-term riskless rate reflecting a private opportunity cost
should not be less than the current yield on Treasury bonds with long-terms
to maturity. Many of them would, I am sure, choose a significantly higher rate.
Because of the conceptual difficulties in identifying and applying a social rate of
time preference and the estimating problems in determining a better estimate
of the average private riskless rate, I believe that as a practical matter it is
appropriate to regard the yield on Treasury bonds as a minimum value for the
discount rate and, where it is relevant, to test the sensitivity of results to higher
rates.
IMPROVEMENTS iw GOVERNMENT DISCOUNTING PRACTICE
Recently, of course, the Government has made significant progress in
improving its evaluation of investment programs. Under the leadership of the
Water Resource Council with the cooperation of the Budget Bureau, we now
have a proposal to increase the discount rate used in water resource projects
and to key it directly to the yield of Government bonds with long-terms to
maturity. In addition, the Budget Bureau has, this year, provided guidelines on
discounting for several agencies in other program areas as part of the PPB
analytic process. These agencies were requested to apply discount rates of
10 percent in their analytic studies. Where it was believed that small variations
in the rate would make a significant difference to the outcome of the analysis,
they were also requested to test for sensitivity of the results to rates of 71/2
and 121/u percent. The Department of Defense has also engaged in attempts to
1 may be argued that risk in private investments is expressed in the discount rate as
opposed to reflecting risk explicitly in components of benefits and cost because the market
in securities has no other way to treat riskiness. An individual investor's evaluation of risk
which may run in terms of detailed predictions about the outcomes of particular invest-
ment projects of a company must ultimately, be reflected in a, price at which he is willing
to buy the company's securities, which in turn implies some rate of return.
PAGENO="0033"
29
systematize the evaluation of investment programs by consistent application
of discounting procedures. And there are other examples where agencies have
applied varying rates for the analysis of projects which impact on particular
private sectors. For example, a recent Department of the Interior study of
shale oil tested the economic attractiveness of oil shale development at alter-
native discount rates of 12 percent and 20 percent.
I believe that there is a good deal more that we can and should do to improve
the evaluation of investment programs. However, I view this as a part of the
overall problem of increasing and improving the analysis of Government expendi-
tures as part of the development of the PPB System. Until analysis has been
strengthened and extended considerably, it will be difficult to assign a great
impact on resource allocation decisions to improvements in the discounting
process alone. Differences in discounting procedures can only have an effect
when costs and benefits of alternatives are systematically compared and when
uncertainties or arguments over the definition and measurement of costs and
benefits do not swamp the difference due to discounting. Because of the con-
ceptual difficulties in comparing outputs of unlike government programs, I
do not believe that improvements in discounting procedures, desirable though
they are, will directly exert a major effect on allocations among different pro-
grams. In the case of the two manpower training programs-sob Corps and
MDTA, OJT-variations in discount rate did not eliminate the need to weigh
the importance of selected target groups.
To sum up, the evaluation of public investments is complex, and raises serious
conceptual and measurement problems not usually confronted when evaluating
private investments. Analysis can and does help to identify better ways to
allocate public resources through cost-benefit analysis and cost-effectiveness
analysis. Discounting is an important element in both types of analyses.
A desirable procedure would:
1. Require display over the expected life of the costs and benefits or physical
outputs of alternative programs as part of the analysis for decision making
(as is now required in Program Memoranda and Program and Financial Plans).
2. For programs which have both costs and benefits expressible in dollars
and which directly displace private investment in a specific sector, the rate of
return in that sector is an appropriate rate for calculating present value of
costs and benefits.
3. For most public investment, use `the private returns foregone over the
economy as a whole to release funds for public investments, as the appropriate
rate. This rate should eliminate allowances for risk providing that costs and
benefits are explicitly adjusted to allow for the risk of the public project.
4. Reflect the fact that a riskless rate of return in the private sector should
not be less than the rate of return on Government bonds. Studies should be
undertaken to develop a more reliable basis for estimating the riskless rate
of return in the private sector.
5. Pest for sensitivity to variations in the discount rate above the yield of
Government bonds where the results of analyses may be affected by small changes
in the discount rate of return.
6. Where subsidies are regarded as socially desirable, express them explicitly
in cost-benefit calculations rather than in the ~discount rate.
I believe that the above points represent the direction in which we have been
moving and will continue to move and that this movement will produce signifi-
cant improvement in the analysis of Government investment programs. In the
coming months the Bureau of the Budget will be continuing its work in coopera-
tion with the Federal agencies and departments to improve the application of
discounting in the evaluation of public investment programs.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Thank you, gentlemen.
Does that complete the statements by you gentlemen?
Mr. HOLUM. Yes, sir.
Chairman PROxMn~E. First, I want to apologize for `being tardy. I
cannot be in three places at once, and I was supposed to be on the
floor, in the Appropriations Committee, and here. The Appropriations
Committee was having a markup of a bill in which I am deeply
involved.
98-940-6&------3
PAGENO="0034"
30
I am going to ask my two colleagues to proceed, because they have
been here through the entire statements and they may have questions
first.
R.epreseiitative MOORHEAD. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Mr. Secretary, first, referring to your statement, as I understand
the thrust of your testimony, it is that at least in the past, a lower rate
of discount was justified, partly because, as you say, "In many in-
stances, the projects provide much more than goods and services," and
things like water quality control, esthetics, amenities, recreation, and
so forth were often underestimated. Am I correctly analyzing your
testimony, sir?
Mr. HoLu~r. I think there has been a very definite inclination on the
part of the agencies involved in water resource development to under-
estimate particularly the regional and social benefits and what we call
the indirect benefits, that result from water resource development. As
part of the effort to improve Senate Document 97-and I guess that is
essentially what we are talking about this morning-we also need to
sharpen up those techniques and provide for the ultimate decision the
best possible analysis of the benefits as well as the costs.
Representative MOORHEAD. Mr. Caulfield, in your testimony, you
quoted from Senate Document 97. At one place, you point out that
Document 97 directs the inclusion of both the tangible and the intan-
gible benefits, and also the secondary benefits. Would there be any other
benefits?
Mr. CAULFIELD. In Senate Document 97, secondary benefits are de-
fined in such a way as to include what some people talk of as indirect
benefits. Secondary benefits here are inclusive of all the types of bene-
fits other than primary benefits, in tangible form, quantitative form,
that people have discussed in this field.
Representative M00RIIEAD. So there can be no improvement over
Senate Document 97 in this respect, is that correct?
Mr. CAULFIELD. Oh, I would not say that. I feel that when we can
spell out more clearly, procedurally exactly how to use these concepts
in context, particularly in areas of underdevelopment and unemploy-
ment, I think we can make a real improvement in the statement of the
document. As far as I am concerned, conceptually, it is all in the docu-
ment, but we can make improvements in the way the document is
stated; yes, sir.
Representative MOORHEAD. Mr. Hoffman, in your prepared state-
ment I think you summed up what I am driving at here. On point. 6,
you said that where subsidies are regarded as socially desirable, they
should be expressed explicitly in cost-benefit calculations rather than
in the discount rate. Would you agree with me, sir, that the present
31/s percent is a subsidy in the form of a lower than realistic discount
of rate?
Mr. HOFFMAN. Yes, sir. I believe that this rate is a subsidy. The sub-
sidy may or may not be warranted, but I think it makes it hard to
understand the nature and reason for the subsidy if it is loaded into
the discount rate. That is my reason for preferring a more explicit
statement o.f subsidy.
Representative MOORHEAD. In your opinion, Mr. Hoffman, is there
any subsidy remaining in the proposed 4%-percent discount rate?
Mr. HOFFMAN. To answer that I would have to evaluate procedures
PAGENO="0035"
31
for considering risk in calculating costs and benefits. Providing the
risk were adequately reflected, I would say that at this time, I have no
basis for arguing for any specific higher number than 4%, or, more
generally, higher than the current yield on Treasury bonds.
Representative MOORIIEAD. Well, Mr. Hoffman, what is the current
yield on Government bonds?
Mr. HOFFMAN. I believe the figure I saw as of July w'as about
5.1 percent. On that, however, it seems to me that Mr. Caulfield's point
has a good deal of merit. I do think that some reasonably stable figure
is required. I do not think that it is possible for the evaluation of water
resources programs to track the weekly ups and downs in the Treasury
bond market.
Representative MOORHEAD. I agree with you, that we have to average
this out, but over what period of time?
Mr. I-IOFFMAN. The solution adopted by the Water Resources Council
is not a bad approximation. Given the long gestation period of pro-
posed water resource projects, I think that you need a relatively
constant figure. I might add, however-and this is a problem that I
would have to think about-where you are dealing with programs
that do not have such a long gestation period for investments you
might want a somewhat more active estimate of the going yield on
Treasury bonds.
One of the reasons why I would accept the water resource solu-
tion is the several-year period between initial proposal and funding.
The relevant rate is the rate at the time when you actually begin fund-
ing, or perhaps at some intermediate time when you become finally
committed to the proje.ct.
Representative MOORIIEAD. But, Mr. Hoffman, Mr. Caulfield's testi-
money on page 14 is th'at they use the `average of bid prices f'or the
fiscal year 1966. That would be the calendar year 1965-66 or 2 years
age. Can you not become a little more current?
Mr. HOFFMAN.YeS, sir. I think in part, this is `a function of when
the proposal was developed, `and I think `that it is a matter of judg-
ment as to what leadtime to use and how active to make it. I would
argue, however that this figure `sets a floor to the figure for use more
generally throughout Government.
I d'o think that we need further study of what a generally applicable
minimum rate would be.
Representative MOORHEAD. Mr. Caulfield, you have excepted from
the new rate those projects that are already authorized. Is this
authorized by the appropriate committee of the Congress-I mean,
is it authorization legislation?
Mr. CAULFIELD. For the most part, sir, that is true. There `are certain
types of projects, such as the smaller Soil Conservation Service proj-
ects, which can be authorized administratively by the Department of
Agriculture. Then the small projects of the Bureau of Reclamation can
be authorized administratively after the Congress has been notified
for 60 days that they propose to go through.
But, by and large, what we are talking about are projects that have to
have the specific authorization of the Congress.
Representative MOORHEAD. `Would this not result in the expenditure
of Federal funds for projects which would be considered uneconomical
based upon the new discount rate?
PAGENO="0036"
32
Mr. CAULFIELD. That may be-there may be such projects, yes. But
in any policy change, there has to be a pro~~ision for transition. The
projects that are involved in the ftpprovals in this Congress have many
commitments made by local people, by States, and so forth. You can-
not just all of a sudden cut them off, in equity.
There has to. be a transition-type of provision.
You will notice that in our transition provision, however, we have
made the proviso that if the Congress should otherwise decide, they
could require a higher interest rate to be used. However, as far as the
Water Council is concerned, we think this is equitable-at this point,
we do-and prior to getting prior comment from all interested per-
sons, I should say. At this point, as a proposal, we think this is an
equitable way of bringing about the transition from one state of
aff airs to another.
Representative M00RHEAD. My time has expired, so I am not ask-
ing this as a question. I might suggest that in addition, you say, "and
funded within x number of years." I concede that a transition period
is necessary.
Mr. CAULFIELD. I see. December 1969, is the stated cutoff date, and
then only for projects authorized by the present Congress, sir. Where
the financial commitments have not been made within 3 years, the
authorization dies. So these cutoff points are in here.
Representative MOORIIEAD. Thank you.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman PRox3rr~u. Senator Jordan?
Senator JORDAN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Mr. Hoffman, I was very much interested in your explanation of
how we evaluate various expenditures that Congress is called upon
to make. You state, and I agree with you fully, that the inability to
compare the value of additional spending on national security and on
water resources, on education, on highways, on manpower training-
these are very difficult judgments to make.
You have outlined several procedures for setting up a discount rate.
You have set up two ways of treating these different types of expendi-
tures. When the marketplace is involved, you use one way; you use a
cost-benefit ratio. When that is not possible, then you go to another
measure of value, in which you use cost effectiveness.
Now, my question to you is, how can the Congress know whether
we should spend money for the national security, for manpower train-
ing, or for a highway or for water resource development projects that
do lend themselves to some connection, some relation to the market?
Mr. HOFFMAN. Senator Jordan, the approach I favor is to pursue the
implications of decisions that have market implications in market
terms as far as we can, and to express their market implications as
far as we can, but also to identify as explicitly as we can all of the other
considerations that ought to bear on the decision. In such cases, indi-
vidual judgments are important elements of the decisions. The political
process comes to bear on these issues, and we `have other ways of evaluat-
ing some of these problems. But the important thing is to identify
clearly and explicitly both kinds of considerations and to present them
as parts of the implications of the decision. This is why I have proposed
the procedure that I have.
Senator JORDAN. What you are saying, in effect, is that either the
PAGENO="0037"
33
application of a cost-benefit ratio in the one instance of a cost-effective-
ness ratio in the other instance, neither is an exact science?
Mr. HOFFMAN. Yes, sir. I would say that they both present useful
information, but they do not exhaust the story. There are other factors
that need to be considered as well.
Senator JORDAN. Explain to me, please, what you mean by opportu-
nity costs.
Mr. HOFFMAN. The opportunity cost of a particular use of a given
resource is the value of that resource in its best alternative use. That is,
in the particular case of public investment funds, the opportunity cost
of those funds is the value of the investments and the consumption that
will not take place in the private sector because those funds have been
withdrawn from the private sector and spent in the public sector.
Senator JORDAN. In effect, then, you take into account the foregone
income tax receipts that might accrue to the Federal Government and
the private development.
Mr. HOFFMAN. On that, sir, it seems to me that one wants to take into
account the total decrease in productivity in the private sector. Part
of that decrease will be foregone income tax; part of it would have
remained in the private sector. But both components together repre-
sent the opportunity cost.
Senator JORDAN. You suggest that if an element of risk is present,
it might be possible to compute that element of risk and translate it
into a cost that would be, a rate that would be, supplemental, added to
your basic rate?
Mr. HOFFMAN. Not quite, sir, as I understand you. Bisk is used in
two senses. Let me talk about a very simple example, the one I used
in the paper. Suppose you have a 50-50 chance of getting nothing, or a
thousand dollars. Now, that in itself is `a ri'sk. If you were thinking of
making 10,000 such bets, then I would argue that the proper procedure
for you would be to evaluate that bet at $500. If somebody said, you
give me $500 and I will toss the die and give you either zero or $1,000,
I would argue you ought to accept `it, or at least you should not care
whether you accepted it or not. If, however, you are going to do it
once, and only once, then I think it is widely accepted that most people
behave `as though that opportunity is worth less than $500, `and `this
represents `a `specific `allowance for risk or risk-aversion in the value
of that opportunity.
Now, I would argue that Government projects have a `similar char-
acter. When you look at the benefits in a given year, you might say
they may `be as large `as $1 million or they may be as large as $5
million in that year, with some spread in between. If the odds were
even, one thing you might do is to say `the average value, the ex-
pected value, `is $3 million; now, `should I value that `bet at $3 million?
On the principle that you `are not going to do this project 10,000
times, `some people would `argue that you ough't to evaluate it at, say,
$2.5 million. Similarly, for costs, where `costs vary, you might want
`to raise the value from the expected value.
`This is a procedure about which it is very difficult to say anything
quantitative. We all Imow that the phenomenon exists, but it is hard
to measure. I would argue that it is better to express explicitly in the
costs and benefits what we mean by that kind of risk allowance than to
PAGENO="0038"
34
try to submerge it in a rate of return by an allowance in a discount
rate.
Senator JORDAN. Do you believe a rate should reflect an incremental
factor for inflation?
Mr. HOFFMAN. If we estimate costs and benefits in constant dollars,
then it would be inappropriate to include an `allowance for inflation.
Senator JORDAN. Thank you, Mr. Hoffman.
Mr. Caulfield, when you outlined a new formula giving an effec-
tive rate of 45/s percent that is a substantial jump from the exist-
ing 31/4 percent. Explain again to me how you would move from the
present 31/4 rate to 4% in t.he transition period.
Are you going to make the 4% applicable, to all new projects?
Mr. CAULFIELD. All projects presented to the Congress for authori-
zation after the 90th Congress, sir.
Senator JORDAN. Beginning with the ne.x.t one?
Mr. CAULFIELD. Yes. sir.
Senator JORDAN. Will you make it retroactive to `any existing
authorizations?
Mr. CAULFIELD. No, sir; that is, the executive branch would not.
Of course, many times tile appropriations committees decide that they
want to reevaluate a project. Of course, it is t.he option of the appro-
priations committees to do so. But as far as the executive branch is
concerned, this is proposed for application for projects authorized
after the 90th Congress.
Senator JORDAN. I see. I think you used an illustration of a project
having a benefit-cost ratio of 1.4 to 1, a.t tile rate of 31/4 percent. This
would be reduced to 1 to 1, the benefit-cost ratio under the new rate
of 4% percent.
Mr. CAULFIELD. Yes; I carefully limited that, though, to an average
long-life capital intensive project. It would be a big fixed structure,
with not much operation and maintenance cost, and the benefit would
be spread over a long period of time.
Senator JORDAN. I am sorry; my thne is up.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman PROXMIEE. Gentlemen, I want to thank you very, very
much for a fine presentation and a most enlightening response here
this morning. I would like to start off with Mr. Hoffman.
Mr. Hoffman, what is the policy of the Bureau of the Budg~t with
regard to applying a discount rate in various departments at the pres-
ent time?
Mr. HOFFMAN. The Bureau has not issued any explicit instruction
on the application of discount.ing throughout Government. I think
we view the problem of the discount rate as a part of the problem of
improving analysis in each of the program areas in each of the agen-
cies, and we have been approaching it by working with each of the
agencies in the context of the PPB system to improve their general
analytical processes, including tile use of discounting.
Chairman PROXMIRE. You have been working on this for a long,
long time, though, and I am just won'dering; we have this tremendous
divergence in the various departments, as you know. We have the
Interior Department, which on water projects has applied, up to now,
the 31/4-percent discount factor.
We have in the Tennessee Valley Authority 4.~ percent; the De-
PAGENO="0039"
35
partment of Agriculture Housing Loans, 4~/8; Office of Econowic
Opportunity family planning program, 5 percent; the Atomic Energy
Commission for Radiation and Pasteurization, for example, Govern-
merit costs, 5 percent; industry benefits, 15 percent.
The Department of Defense, on all shipyard projects, 10 percent; on
14 air stations, 10 percent; 18 other stations, 10 percent. I guess the
Corps of Engineers is 31/4 percent, something of that kind, for the
public works program. The Agency for International Development,
foreign aid, from 8 to 12 percent; the Department of the Interior has a
very interesting variation. They have, as I say, for the water programs,
applied 31/8 or 31/4 percent; for energy and mineral development pro-
grams, for which exploitation to a private function is 12 percent;
utility programs, low-risk 8, high-risk, 12.
The Department of Health, Education, end Welfare goes up to 8
percent on some, 10 percent on others, and so forth.
At any rate, they are all over the place, no consistency at all. It seems
to me both the President and the Congress would be served if there were
either consistency or rationalization, explanation of why you have these
enormous divergences.
Cannot the Bureau of the Budget, as the agency which has the re-
sponsibility to try to bring some order out of chaos, does it not have the
responsibility to proceed in this area?
Mr. HOFFMAN. I would certainly agree, Senator, that there is a good
deal of room for improvement here. I would argue, however, that we
have been working to get that improvement and that the attempt to
impose by some kind of Bureau of the Budget fiat a very specific, very
restrictive procedure and discount rate, would be self-defeating when
there is not yet a common understanding and agreement on all of the
factors involved, either throughout government, or in the economics
profession.
Chairman PRox~nRE. There certainly is agreement in the economic
profession that you ought to he consistent?
Mr. HOFFMAN. Yes, sir.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Here you have a transparent example of a
waste of resources by the Government itself.
Mr. HOFFMAN. The problem is in reaching agreement on how to be
consistent. I think we would all agree that it would be desirable to in-
crease consistency. We have been moving to eliminate some of the worst
examples. Now, how far we go and how fast we can move is a function
of the extent to which we are able to get common agreement and ac-
ceptance of the principles involved. I would agree that the Bureau has
a leading role and a responsibility in this area.
Chairman PROXMIFF. Can you tell us just what the thinking of the
Bureau of the Budget is right now, today, in looking forward to try-
ing to bring some kind of rationalization, some order, some consistency
here?
Mr. HOFFMAN. Well, sir, I am afraid I can give you my thinking
only.
Chairman PROXMIRE. I wish you would.
Mr. HOFFMAN. I believe that we need to clarify the reasons and the
methods involved in discounting in the evaluation of public invest-
ments. I believe we also need to develop a good deal more in the way
of understanding and agreement on a rationale for determination of
PAGENO="0040"
36
the discount rate, and then I think there is a difficult problem of de-
vising an acceptable, widely understood way of estimating the appro-
priate rate. I think we need to do each of these things and, as I have
indicated, we have been moving to get started on this process.
Chairman PROXMmE. Is there not a great deal of unanimity, really,
in the economic profession in having at the very, very least this 4~/8
percent as opposed to the 31/8 ~
Let me read very briefly the. testimony of Professor Baumol, of
Princeton, who did a wonderful job for us in testifying last year:
However, I think if one were to poll, for example, the current and past officers
of the American Economic Association for the past 10 or 20 years, you would
find the unanimity which I described in my statement. I think you would find
that, without a single exception, they would agree that something like the
figure I have mentioned is a minimum for the pertinent discount rate, and would
agree, therefore, that there is nothing shocking about the fact that very few water
resource projects would pass a cost-benefit test if carried out on a rational basis.
Mr. HOFFMAN. Sir, with respect to the agreement on the rate, my
own impressions from talking with a number of economists are in
accord with that opinion. But I would like to point out that there is
one school of thought among economists which could result in their
arguing for a lower rate. I am referring to those who believe that the
discount rate ought specifically to reflect peculiarly governmental ob-
jectives-that it is more than an opportunity cost notion.
Chairman PRox~rIiu~. Perhaps there is this defect in figuring benefits.
Perhaps we are not sufficiently comprehensive or accurate in esti-
mating benefits, but it would seem pretty clear that if you are con-
sistent and accurate in computing benefits, you are just defeating
yourself when you apply a different discount rate in one area than
you do in another, that you are sure to have a waste of resources.
You are going to invest in some areas that you should not invest in,
and fail to invest in some that you should.
Mr. HOFFMAN. My feeling would be somewhat like the one you just
expressed, but I would point out that you would not carry all econo-
mists with that position.
I might add there are perfectly respectable, competent economists
who hold the view that the discount rate ought to reflect more than
simply the private opportunity costs.
Chairman Pnoxmiin. Well, if we wait until we get a unanimity of
agreement among economists, we will never do anything, we know
that. Economists have agreed and disagreed on the tax increase and
on almost every policy or action Congress ever takes. But there is pre-
ponderance of opinion among economists who have studied in this
area and who speak with authority that we should have at least a 4%,
and the evidence we got from the people who testified last year was
that many would go, and I think a predominance, would go to between
10 and 15 percent.
Mr. HOFFMAN. Yes, sir, but that, too, is a specific point of view.
There, I think you would begin to lose a good deal of that preponder-
ance. The profession would truly be divided over whether to go to 10
or 15 percent in the evaluation of public investment programs.
Chairman Pnox~mia. Mr. Holum, Mr. Hoffman in his statement,
says that only projects whose benefits at least equal cost should be
undertaken with regard to water projects. Would you agree to that?
PAGENO="0041"
37
Mr. HOLUM. Are you looking at Secretary Udall's statement or-
Chairman PRoxMIin. No; no, I am looking at Mr. Hoffman's state-
ment. I shall read you the statement; I have it now. It is the second
sentence in the first paragraph:
To choose an obvious example, the meaninglessness of a dollar value of changes
in the strength of our deterence of nuclear war makes it necessary to determine
the level of deterence by the judgment of the responsible officials; in the water
resource area, by contrast, there is general acceptance of the proposition that
only projects whose dollar benefits at least equal the costs (appropriately com-
puted) should be undertaken.
Mr. HOLUM. If my memory is correct, Mr. Chairman, during the
71/2 years I have been here, our legislative committees have reported
favorably on one or two projects that had benefit-cost ratios of less
than unity. As far as I am concerned, if we can adequately improve
our methods of evaluating benefits so that we really do evaluate and
make available to the Congress, and they are the decisionmakers, all
of the facts with the benefits that the project will provide locally,
nationally, now and in the future, on the basis of economic evaluation,
I would expect the Congress not to authorize projects that did not
have a benefit-cost ratio equal to unity.
Chairman PR0xMIRE. In other words, you see nothing magic in
water that makes it different from other investments?
Mr. HOLUM. Well, Mr. Chairman, perhaps not any magic. I do feel
that the matters that we are discussing here this morning, and I think
it is appropriate that they be discussed, very properly, do have some
uniqueness. I would like to point out, as Secretary TJdall did in his
statement, that as far as discounting water projects, the procedures
have been uniform over a long period of time. The water agencies are
acting together through the Water Resources Council and the Water
Resources Planning Act to keep them uniform. But we are dealing
here, when we deal with discount rates as they apply to the develop-
ment and use of our natural resources, with questions that are basic
and fundamental as far as I am concerned, as to whether we are going
to have an exploitative society or a society that cares about its resources
and develops them and utilizes them for the good of people who are
living now and for the good of people who will be living in the future.
So I think there is some fundamental difference between this and
other programs we have been talking about as far as discounting is
concerned and the care that the executive agencies and the Congress
are giving it.
Chairman PR0xMIRE. We might as well be as blunt and comprehen-
sive as we can on this. The problem is, we are not just dealing with
a sheer economic theory. We are dealing with some hard, tough
political facts.
The people who really determine whether we go ahead with many
of these projects are the members of the Senate and the House In-
terior Committees and the Secretary of the Interior. The President
and Members of Congress have many, many other obligations and we
tend to delegate to these gentlemen our decisions to a considerable
extent in this area.
The Secretary of the Interior is a wonderful man, and was a bril-
liant Congressman who comes from Arizona, where water is very, very
PAGENO="0042"
38
important, where, in the House, he sought for many, many years for
water projects in his State, almost as an element of religion.
Look at the Interior Committee of the Senate and you will see that
its members come from the following States: Washington, New Mex-
ico, Nevada, Idaho, Alaska, Utah, North Dakota, Arizona, South
Da.kota, Wisconsin-I am happy to see there is one member from
Wisconsin-Montana, California, Colorado, Idaho again, Arizona
again, Wyoming, Oregon.
Practically all Western States. It is hard to find anyone from east
of the Mississippi who ever serves on the Interior Committee.
Representative MooimEAD. I might say to the chairman, the same
patter1~ holds in the other body.
Chairman PR0xMIRE. Exactly.
So we have, you see, an atmosphere of bias, understandable bias, an
atmosphere of political force here which I think we have to recognize.
Under these circumstances, although I would agree with you that we
have to show grea.t concern for our water resources and perhaps take
a good, hard look at how we figure benefits, nevertheless, I cannot see
for the life of me how you can justify a substantially lower discount
rate for water projects than you can for the defense of this country,
which, as I indicated, is at 10 percent, a 10-percent return instead of
a 31/8-percent return, or for any other investment made by the Federal
Government.
Mr. HoLt~r. Well, Mr. Chairman, first, with respect to our legis-
lative committee members, I hold them in high regard, and I know
you do, too. I think there are members of our legislative committees,
and we have more easterners on the I-louse committee than we do have
in the Senate-
Chairman PRox~IIRE. Mr. Moorhead said there is a similarity and
I believe that is true.
Mr. HOLUM. They come from an area that can understand-it is
not a bias, but we can imderstand-
Chairman PRox~rmE. Well, it is a combination of understanding
and bias.
Mr. HOLUM. They understand water resource development. Although
my Bureau of Reclamation deals only in the West, it is not just a West-
ern problem. The problems we are dealing with are conservation of our
resources, including the programs of the Corps of Engineers. The
programs we deal with in the Water Resources Council are across
the board, across the country. They have to do with wild rivers, the
creation of dams, the creation of national parks.
They are all involved. It is a national problem. I think it is of
national concern to use these resources wisely and properly, not to
exploit them, to keep a healthy economy now, but to provide for a
healthy economy, too, in the future, for our heirs.
Chairman PRox~rrRE. Why stop at that? Why not put it on exactly
the same basis across the board? We all have a strong bias in favor
of problems of our States. If I were a western Senator I would also
be carrying the banner for water.
But looking at this as objectively as we can from the standpoint
of the whole. country, why should we not have the basic figures con-
sistent so that we can make our decisions with our eyes open?
PAGENO="0043"
39
In other words, I am asking you not to defend the 31/s percent; I
am asking you to defend the ~~/8 against a higher percentage which
is applied by so many other agencies.
Mr. H0LTXM. I think in Secretary TJdall's statement-I do not know
if you have had an opportunity to read it.
Chairman PRox1%iI1~. Yes; I read it.
Mr. HoLu~r. I think the record is good. in this area, it has been the
people, not just over the last 6 or 7 years, but over time, the people
involved in water resource development and land conservation who
have worked together to form good methods of accounting and to send
these recommendations to Congress on a uniform basis.
They are moving together now to reconsider the methods of dis-
counting and the rates to be applied. They have made a suggestion,
offered it to the public for comment, and when they get the comments
back, they may be-
Chairman PROXMIRE. I do not mean to be critical of you. I keep
recalling a member of the House who kept putting into the Congres-
sional Record in the appendix something about growing bananas
on Pike's Peak. In other words, if you brought enough water to
the most arid area in the Nation, you would obviously turn it into
a paradise.
The question is, however, whether or not we ought to invest limited
resources and tax the taxpayer on a basis that relies on a discounting
differential which is unfair to most of our States and the overwhelm-
ing proportion of our taxpayers. We ought to go ahead with our
water investments; but we ought to require them to make the kind
of showing that we make for our investments in education and
other areas.
Mr. H0LUM. Senator, if you are talking specifically about the rec-
lamation program, and I would rather not because I am trying to
fill in for Secretary Tldall as chairman of the Water Resources Coun-
cil, but I think the decisionmakers in the Congress do require, and I
think it is part of the total project, that the States of the West, with
the approval of the Congress, put aside the revenues from their public
lands in what we call the reclamation fund. That produces close to
$200 million a year.
That is in turn, under the direction of the Congress, reinvested in
development of the West. These projects do meet the benefit-cost
ratio and are submitted to the Congress on that basis.
Chairman PROXMIRE. I yield to Mr. Moorhead. I shall be right, back.
Representative MOORHEAD. Mr. Chairman, I think you have iden-
tified the problem. We have probably inadequately analyzed and
valued the benefits of the water projects. The Secretary mentioned
this in his statement where lie talked about the esthetic amenities,
and recreaional opportunities. Recreation in the summertime is 80
percent water based. I think that we should take a hard look again
at the benefit side of the equation.
Of course, it is hard to quantify these things, but this is where I
think the thrust should be-greater accuracy on valuing the benefits
plus greater accuracy on the discount rate. If we did properly value
these benefits, we probably would end up with a program of the same
water projects anyway.
PAGENO="0044"
40
But the question to either Secretary Holum or Mr. Caulfield, again-
you testified that the water projects have the same discount rate, but
is it not true-at least I have been so informed-that the evaluation
of the benefits varies, let us say, from the Bureau of Reclamation to
the Corps of Engineers? The Bureau of Reclamation would include
secondary benefits, whereas the Corps of Engineers does not. Am I
correctly informed there, gentlemen?
Mr. CAULFIELD. Yes, sir. Senate Document 97 authorizes the Corps
of Engineers to include secondary benefits in their project analyses
if a secondary benefit cost analysis is indicated. In other words, where
the Bureau of Reclamation puts its projects before the Congress, it
provides a benefit-cost ratio on the basis of cost of primary benefits
and another one with reference to the cost of secondary benefits, so the
Congress can see the separate implications of regional economic
development.
Representative MOORHEAD. But the Corps of Engineers does not?
Mr. CAULFIELD. The Corps of Engineers has not chosen to do so,
by and large.
Representative MOORHEAD. Do you know why?
Mr. CAULFIELD. Well, the Corps, I think they ought to speak for
themselves on this. I think it is fair to say, though, that they have
taken the position in the eastern part of the country that they feel
that the Congress wants them to be conservative, and putting the costs
on a primary benefit basis is the most conservative way of looking at
water resources projects. However, in the Appalachian region of this
country, the Congress has specifically told the Corps of Engineers in
the development of that program to consider the benefits to unem-
ployed resources and underemployed resources. The Corps of Engi-
neers in the projects it now evaluates in that region is taking this type
of indirect benefit which can be attributed as a national benefit, how-
over, into account, as well as the regional impact of benefits that would
be specifically beneficial to that region if the development occurred.
Representative MOORHEAD. So that whether you can go ahead with
a particular water project might very well depend on whether you
include the secondary benefits, and this, as far as the Corps of
Engineers is concerned, would oniy be in the Appalachian region; is
that. right?
Mr. CAULFIELD. Or any area that has been designated as an under-
employment area or unemployment area, like the economic develop-
ment-designated areas throughout the country under the Public Works
and Economic Development Act of 1965. However, it is being specifi-
cally applied by the corps these days in the Appalachian area. That
is why I make specific reference to that area.
I might say the Public Works Committees, as you realize, are the
committees in the House and the Senate, the legislative committees
to which the Corps of Engineers makes its presentation, not the In-
terior Committees. The Public Works Committees of both the House
and the Senate have emphasized to the corps in recent reports, I think
in the Onmibus Rivers and Harbors Act, that the Corps should pursue
secondary benefits in addition to primary benefits in the presentation
of reports.
Representative MooRnm~D. It seems to me that the only reason for a
lower discount rate is if the benefit side of the equation is understated,
PAGENO="0045"
41
as it may be in the Corps of Engineers budget, or may have been in
the past.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Otherwise, you have two minuses trying to
make a plus, trying to compensate for one error by another bigger
error.
Mr. Hoffman, do you think it would be proper for the committee
to undertake a study to measure the appropriate base interest rate to
be published on an ongoing basis for guidance to all Federal agencies ~
Mr. HOFFMAN. Yes, sir, I do. I think it would be a difficult thmg
to do. It might be comparable to the problems that were faced in
developing price indexes or measures of gross national product. It
would involve agreement on a conceptual basis, and then it would
involve the working out of a method for estimating the actual numbers.
Chairman PR0xMIRE. Should that not be done by your agency ~
Mr. HOFFMAN. I would have to think about that, Senator. I think,
based on the analogy with the other two measures that I mentioned
that the answer might be "No." It might be better done with some
other executive department as the operator.
Chairman PR0xMIRE. First, it would have to be done by some exec-
utive department that has some responsibility for all of them. It would
have to be done, secondly, by an executive agency that does not have an
ax to grind. You would not have much in the way of investment in
the Bureau of the Budget, at least not in the usual sense, so you would
be qualified from the standpoint of objectivity.
Mr. HOFFMAN. Yes, sir.
I think if it were done elsewhere within the executive branch, the
Bureau would certainly have to exercise some oversight.
Chairman PROXMIRE. I would appreciate it if, in correcting your
remarks, if you thiiik of it, you could come up with any alternative
that you might consider in this area. This is something we want to
pursue as vigorously as we can.
Mr. HOFFMAN. I shall reflect on it.
Chairman PRoxl\IIRE. Now, Mr. Stockflsch, and also some of the
other gentlemen who have testified before us disagree with you pretty
vigorously-I am not sure I do. You may be right-on this risk aspect.
They argue that the opportunity cost in the private sector has already
taken into account the risk. Mr. Stockflsch puts it this way:
And exactly the same thing happens from the point of view of society, because
society obtains the returns from many thousands of investments and some will
do better than expected, and some will do worse than expected; but on the
whole, the risk incurred by any one individual project is no more pertinent
to the overall returns expected by society than the risks incurred by one par-
ticular policyholder are pertinent to the overall returns of the insurance company.
For that reason, what is relevant, it seems to me, and I think it seems so to
a number of other economists that have some reputation, what is relevant is
the average rate of return obtained by industry from those resources with no
special account taken of the individual risk of the investors in that particular
company. The investors in that particular company may end up losing money on
that investment.
But on balance, society will lose on some and gain on others, and come out on
the average.
Mr. HOFFMAN. That is a position which has been urged by other
economists as well as Mr. Stockflsch. However, I think in order to
maintain that the rate of return has averaged out risk, it would be
necessary to explain differences, for example, in the rate of return on
PAGENO="0046"
42
equity stocks, `and those on corporate bonds for the same corporations.
It would be very difficult to explain different relationships between'
earnings or price or rate of return among the different classes of in-
vestment without some recourse to the notion that they reflect different
evaluations of risk.
Oh'airman PRox~rIn~. I am not sure about that. You take a look at
the price-earnings ratio, not just the relationship between price and
dividends, which is another factor explaining the difference `other than
risk. The price-earnings ratio on the New York Stock Exchange now,
even though we have had a couple of bad days on the stock exchange, I
think you would find that there is not much difference between that and
`the yield on Government bonds right now.
What has happened is that the Stockholder, of course, makes an in-
vestment, will get a return substantially below the return on book
value. In other words, in the actual amount of money invested in the
corporation, which would have a return before taxes of maybe 12 or 13'
percent, and `after taxes, 6 or 6.5 percent. The stockholder is paying
more than that, because by and large, the stocks are valued at above
book value.
Mr. Ho~'r~rAN. Yes, sir. At any one time the relationships are influ-
enced `by a number of factors.
Chairman PROXMIRE. This has been the sit,ua:tion for several years.
Mr. HOFFMAN. It has not always been the situation, though, and it
seems to me that we `have moved into an era where we have certain ex-
pectations about ra'te of growth and inflation and so on that might com-
pensate for current price-earnings ratios that are low relative to the
yields or less risky debt security. Bu't it seems to me that `to explain the
divergences which have occurred in the past one would have to have
recourse to some notion of differential risk.
Chairman PRox~II~. Well, it is hard for me to grasp `why the argu-
ment that Mr. S'tockfisch makes, that the average rate of return, `allow-
ing for the ones who lose everything, comes out to around 12 percent,
why that would not be the appropriate `opportunity cost. I can see this
other argument you make on displacement `of resources. That is some-
thing else.
Mr. HOFFMAN. Mr. Stockfisch's argument, I think, is relevant if you
consider the investment in `an individual corporation from society's
point of view as being `analogous to investment in one among many
items in the portfolio of a mutual fund. The growth `of diversified `com-
panies has `been `a movement, of course, toward precisely this kind of
phenomenon from the point of view of even individual investors.
But it is by no means universally true that risks `are averaged out
among industries or regions even from society's point of view. In fact,
the coal mining industry as a whole has experienced one outcome of a
risky situation. You have different situations in different industries.
You might also have one situation for a firm in one area, `and another
for a firm in `another area.
Chairman PROXMIRE. This is very true, but the coal mining industry
is a good example. The coal mining industry, as you say, has deterio-
rated. Many companies have had to go out of business.
The railroad is another example of an industry where the return is
very low and some have consolidated or gone out of business.
In the other areas, however-you have electronics, for instance,
many areas of research industries that are booming. And television;
PAGENO="0047"
43
I understand, television companies that are on the air have a rate of
return before taxes at around 40 percent-tremendous.
The average, though, works out to be around 12 percent. The point
is that when you take money out of the economy that is returning 12
percent and invest it in a Government activity that is earning 3 percent,
you would seem to have an action that would reduce your rate of
growth and reduce it sharply and result in a malinvestment of funds.
I hasten t.o add right away for those who say, if you argue like that,
you are not going to have any education, the areas of Government that
have the greatest return, as I see it, are the human resource areas-
education, the poverty program have excellent returns.
Mr. HOFFMAN. I would agree that one of the reasons we regard these
programs as among our most urgent programs is precisely because
they do have such high economic and social returns.
But to return to your point, it seems to me that there are two distinct
questions. One is whether it is possible to consider the average rate o-f
return over productive investment as a meaningful figure. I would say
it has meaning. To the extent that funds are drawn out of the private
investment, it does reflect the opportunity cost of those funds. And I
am not arguing for ignoring risk in connection with Govermnent pro-
grams; I am simply saying that the return averaged over investment
projects as a whole does reflect some evaluation of risk; that there are
kinds of risks that are not averaged out, even from an overall social
point of view, and that the risk element either has to be included in
the rate of return used by Government or handled explicitly in the
costs and benefits.
I would argue for the latter course.
Now, there is another point, too. Not all funds withdrawn by Gov-
ernment come from investment in private industrial capital. So there
is the question of the relevant rate of return on funds which, in effect
are drawn out of consumption.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Certainly when you have a situation such as we
have at the present time, where we are trying hard, or at least many
people are trying hard, to put the brakes on the economy, to slow
down inflation, to keep it from becoming too expansive and we pass
a tax increase to do that, certainly at a time like this it would seem
unwise for us to invest money in the Government sector which yields
so much less than it does in the private sector.
At a time when you have idle resources, when, as you say, you are
not displacing your manpower or your other resources, then I can
see a strong argument for going ahead on the basis of recognizing still
what your opportunity costs are and what your discounting is, but
going ahead anyway, because you want to use idle resources.
Mr. HOFFMAN. Yes, sir; I would agree with that entirely. I per-
sonally believe that an opportunity cost approach is the right itpproach
to take. I think the question is how to go about estimating the relevant
opportunity cost-for example, I think one would have to take into
account the fact that funds are drawn from consumption as well as
investment in estimating the rate-and then how to handle risk as a
component of the rate of return.
Chairman PRox~IIRE. I argue with your risk concept, but anyway,
how would the Bureau of the Budget proceed in telling you to make
explicit allowance for risk and uncertainty? For example, take a water
PAGENO="0048"
44
project. Would you make allowance for the notion that we might
make a breakthrough in the saline area so we might be able to get
some sea water that might possibly make water projects unnecessary
or obsolete?
Mr. HOFFMAN. Yes, sir; I think that would be an entirely relevant
observation. When you move to that kind of consideration, you are
moving from risk to what economists would call uncertainty. The
difference is that in a situation of risk you are able to estimate the
odds, in a situation of uncertainty, you are not. We do feel-at least,
I feel, and I think it would be generally accepted-that investment
in a water resource project would be risky by virtue of the possibility
of technological obsolence; that is to say, the benefits that you calcu-
lated as flowing from that project might not accrue; because there
might turn out to be a cheaper way to do it.
I would think that, at the very least, that where such possibilities
can be identified their effects on benefits ought to be calculated. If
it is possible to estimate the probability that technological obsolescence
will occur, you can estimate an average value. `Where you cannot make
such an estimate you can simply look at the two streams of benefits
and say: This is how it will turn out if we do not get the break-
through; this is how it will turn out if we do. You must then call
upon the judgment of the decisionmaker to evaluate those two streams
of benefits, discounted to present values.
Chairman PROXMIRE. How would you arrive at the discount rate,
again, for the riskless and those that have a risk? Would you have
more than one level of risk?
Mr. HOFFMAN. `Well, the notion of a two-part approach is really,
as I tried to indicate, a pragmatic notion. It is a way of getting
started. In some areas, we can identify G~overnment activities with
particular parts of the private sector. In those areas, I would say
we ought to rely on the judgment of the private sector as to risk.
The private sector does give us measure of risk in those cases. It is
in the areas where public activities have no direct analog that I
would argue that we want to handle risk explicitly outside the dis-
count rate, and then we should start from an estimate of a riskless
rate of return.
Chairman PRox~rIRE. If you do that, then you would have to correct
the discount rate now being used by the Defense Department for ship-
yards and many other things of this kind, and you would have a
situation where you would either have to spend more money or not
fund projects which show a positive benefit-cost ratio.
Mr. HOFFMAN. Now, in those cases, Senator, it seems to me that
the relevant question is not whether to go ahead with a project or
not, but how best to do it; that is to say, the calculation in the case
of Defense would be, what is the best way to provide the right kinds
and mixture of ships? Should you do it by buying new ships, should
you modify old ships, and so on.
Chairman PRox~rIRE. Maybe in part, but is it not possible at all
to consider it a kind of cost-agency comparison? In other words, if
you find a good rate of return on shipbuilding, go ahead with it,
where you do not on a water project that would show a comparable
rate of return?
Mr. HOFF3IAN. No, sir; I would have a great-
PAGENO="0049"
45
Chairman PROXMIRIi. Or are we comparing apples and oranges?
Mr. HOFFMAN. I am afraid you are in the case of Defense and
Water Resources.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Well, those are bad examples. I think there
are some instances, though, where you have limited funds and you
have to decide that you have to go ahead with a good poverty program,
for example, or a somewhat less good public works program.
Mr. HOFFMAN. Yes, I think in some areas-
Chairman PROXMIRE. And your rate of return would help you make
that judgment. It is not just a matter of intuition or political prefer-
ence, it is a matter of being guided to some extent, at least, by what
the facts show you on the kind of return you will get.
Mr. HOFFMAN. I agree completely, Senator Proxmire. I think that
an analysis should be pushed as far as it can legitimately carry
us, and we ought to benefit from analysis as far as we possibly can,
and I would try to make as many cross-program comparisons as I
legitimately could, using cost-benefit analysis. I would argue, how-
ever, that very early we run into difficulties that have to be expressed
as footnotes to the calculations, at least, and possibly as more.
Chairman PROXMIRE. I have just one other question for you, then
I have a couple of questions for Mr. Caulfield.
Mr. Hoffman, you state the need to measure on a continuing basis
accurately the rate implied by the correct conceptual basis. What
agency should, in your judgment, undertake the study? Would it be
a helpful guide if the base rate could be computed on an ongoing
basis for the guidance of our agencies?
Mr. HOFFMAN. If I might, I would like to reflect further on that
question before I provide an answer.
Chairman PR0xMIRE. Very good.
(The following was subsequently received from Mr. Hoffman:)
As I have indicated in response to an earlier question, efforts to improve the
application of discounting to public investment decisions must first achieve a
common understanding and agreement on the conceptual basis for discounting,
and second, reach agreement on a method or methods for calculating the
discount rates to be used. Finally, after completing the first two stages, the
assignment of responsibility for preparing current estimates of the rates will
have to be considered.
The Bureau of the Budget proposes to continue and intensify its review of
alternative conceptual bases and methodologies for determining discount rates.
I believe the Joint Economic Committee can also continue to play a useful role
in this activity. The Bureau of the Budget will be happy to work with the com-
mittee on this. The committee's hearing record has clearly demonstrated that there
exists a variety of informed views on the conceptual basis for discounting and the
methods of calculating appropriate rates. The Bureau of the Budget in its review
of alternatives will seek the views of experts from the Federal Government,
private industry, labor, and the academic community.
Our objective, of course, is to improve and better coordinate discounting
techniques used for evaluating the benefits and costs of public investment in the
Federal Government. The task is made more difficult by the fact that any general
guidelines will have to take into account the legislative history and special
characteristics of the various Federal programs. Until agreement has been
reached on concepts and methods, permitting judgment of the nature and
magnitude of the task of providing current estimates of the discount rate or
rates, I believe it would be premature to attempt to assign responsibility for
this task.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Now, Mr. Caulfield, while you state the new
basis for calculating the rate of interest, you do not state the economic
98-940-8S-----4
PAGENO="0050"
46
concept upon which this rate is premised. Is it the concept of opportu-
nity cost in the private sector? Do you agree with Mr. Hoffman's
conclusions on the rate concept?
Mr. CAULFIELD. The Water Resources Council, in developing this
proposal, did not adopt any particular theory of the rate of return.
Instead, it was reflecting what it believed to be the intent of the Presi-
dent, the intent of the President's words in the budget message, which
did not in itself reflect a particular theory, either social time prefer-
ence or opportunity cost concept, of the proper discount rate.
Chairman PRoxMnm. If you follow the current cost theory, obviously
it would have to be higher than 4%, would it not?
Mr. CAULFIELD. No, not necessarily, in terms of the testimony that
you had from Professor Baumol and in connection with the testimony
you had from Mr. Hoffman, the point was made that it would be at
least the yield rate.
Chairman PROXMIRE. ProfessOr Baumol indicated that it was not his
preference, but you could not find any lower rate than that.
Mr. CAULFIELD. You are right, pardon me. He said he thought no
economists would be in favor of using less than the yield rate. This
is the yield rate, in my judgment, corrected for inflation.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Corrected for inflation?
Mr. CAULFIELD. Yes. Since 1966, there has been a substantial ex-
pectation of inflation.
Chairman PEJOXMIRE. Would there be inflation in one area and not
in others?
Mr. CAULFIELD. We have used benefit-cost analysis in terms of con-
stant prices. Therefore, we need a discount rate that does not exces-
sively reflect expectations of inflation, such as the interest rates that
have been occurring in the last year or so. As evidence, for example,
sir, is the fact that 4 weeks ago, the yield rate was about 51/2 percent
and now it is just possibly a shade over 5 percent, since the tax bill
became law.
Chairman PR0XMIRE. Well, on the assumption that your costs do
take into account inflation, I can certainly speak on that. Congress
estimated it would cost $65 million to build the new House Office Build-
ing and it cost them $160 million. They estimated $20 million for this
building and it cost $26 million. They are always underestimating the
costs by an enormous margin.
It seems very unusual to assume that they have corrected for infla-
tion in their estimate of costs.
Mr. CAULFIELD. The point is, they have not corrected for inflation.
They have used the prices at the time of the estimate. Those esti-
mates proved wrong because there was inflation between the time when
they made the estimates and subsequently. There may also have been
mistakes in the estimate.
Chairman PROXMIRE. I understood you to say that the reason for
this 4% instead of perhaps a higher rate is because inflationary fac-
*tors were eliminated in its application to water projects. Am I wrong?
Mr. CAULFIELD. Pardon me. I shall go back now. One could have
taken the view, for example, in June, as my testimony indicated, one
could have said that the discount rate for 1969 should be based on the
average of June prices. That would have turned out at 5.5 percent. We
found this not to be uppropriate, because, in our judgment, 5.5 percent
PAGENO="0051"
47
included a substantial expectation on the part of the public of inflation,
and that expectation was reflected in the yields on bonds.
In consequence, we took a figure of 4% percent, which was the aver-
age, based on the average of daily bid prices in 1966. This happens to
be the period just before the substantial rise in the Federal bond
market.
Now, we have not taken any fixed figure of 4%, sir. What we have
taken is a figure starting with 45/s which can change up or down not
more than one-fourth point per year. Thus, it will reflect, we `trust-
this is the proposal and comments can be made upon it-it will reflect
the trend, the deflated trend, hopefully the deflated discount rate or
the yield rate on Government bonds, staying within that limitation.
Chairman PR0xMIRE. For the record, why do you put the yield rate
instead of the coupon rate?
Mr. CAULFIELD. For the very reason that has been expressed many
times before this committee: the coupon rate is the rate that in terms
of the present bond issues of the Treasury reflects the 2 percent yields
in 1940, and the control on interest rates during the war, and thus,
it has not moved up very rapidly.
Ten years ago or so, there was only a 1-percent spread between the
coupon rate and the yield rate. Today there is an over 2 percent spread
between the coupon rate and the yield rate. The yield rate more accu-
rately reflects-
Chairman PROXMIRE. The current rate of interest is reflected more.
accurately in the coupon rate at the present time?
Is that right or wrong?
Mr. CAULFIELD. It is wrong. The current cost of money is reflected
in `the-
Chairman PROXMIRE. You are talking about the yield on current
issues rather than the overall yield of the whole Government-
Mr. OAULFIELD. I am talking about the yield on bonds that were
issued maybe 15 years ago as indicating the yield that is published
in the papers every morning on Government bonds relating to their
price.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Then you are talking about the yield for an
investor that goes right out and buys a bond. He would expect-
Mr. CAULFIELD. Yes, it reflects the current market value of those
bonds.
Chairman PR0XMIRE. Then I have to go back to these other questions.
The discount rate to be given in any year to be based on the average
yield for the preceding fiscal year. Why is the 4% rate based on 1966
instead of 1967?
Mr. CAULFIELD. Because this is part of our effort to start with a
figure that did not reflect, we trust, inflationary expectations on the
part of the people in the bond market. Since for the last year or so,
there have `been, as you know, expectations of inflation in this country,
the tax bill is aimed at curbing those expectations of inflation. Right
after the tax bill was passed, the yield has gone down almost half a
point.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Gentlemen, once again, thank you very much.
This has been most entertaining, as well as enlightening for me.
I very much appreciate it. You have done a fine job. I think we
are `making progress in this area.
PAGENO="0052"
48
I did not mean to be too critical of you gentlemen from the Interior
Department. I think that your decision to increase the rate to 4%
percent is statesmanlike and sensible, and certainly can be justified
on any kind of an economic basis.
I question whether it is enough, but it is an excellent beginning.
I am delighted to see the Bureau of the Budget is so concerned about
this and is working as you have demonstrated, Mr. Hoffman, in the
direction of a more consistent rate for all the agencies. I think that
once we get this, we can begin to establish some priority. Then, when
we increase or decrease spending, we can do it on the basis of much
more reason than we have in the past.
You are so right, Mr. Hoffman, in the argument that this cannot be
the basis for a definitive decision; all it is is a guideline. But it can be
an enormously helpful guideline, believe me, in congressional debate
and in finally getting a result that enables us to grow as much as our
resources will permit.
Thank you, gentlemen, very much. The subcommittee will recon-
vene at 10 a.m. tomorrow morning in the public hearing room of the
Atomic Energy Committee, room S-407.
(Whereupon, at 12:40 p.m., the Subcommittee on Economy in Gov-
ernment recessed, to reconvene at 10 a.m., Wednesday, July 31, 1968.)
PAGENO="0053"
ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF PUBLIC INVESTMENT DECI-
SIONS: INTEREST RATE POLICY AND DISCOUNTING
ANALYSIS
WEDNESDAY, FULY 31, 1968
CONGRESS OP THE UNITED STATES,
SUBCOMi'IITrEE ON ECONOMY IN GOVERNMENT
OF THE JOINT ECONOMIC COMMrTrEE,
Washington, D.C.
The subcommittee met, pursuant to notice, at 10 a.m., in room S-407,
the Capitol, Hon. William Proxmire (chairman of the subcommittee)
presiding.
Present: Chairman Proxmire.
Also present: John R. Stark, executive director, Robert H. Have-
man, economist; and Douglas C. Frechtling, minority economist.
Chairman PROXMIRE. The subcommittee will come to order. Gentle-
men, other members might possibly be here later, but as you imow,
this is convention time in Miami for the minority and it is also a time
when we in the Congress are trying to get as much done as possible
before we recess. Consequently, other members of the committee are
very much involved in other necessary activities this morning which
may conflict and make it difficult for them to attend.
Today is the second in the current series of hearings on the question
of consistent interest rate and discounting procedures in the analysis
of public expenditures. As we were again made aware yesterday, this
problem is an important one in the context of the new planning-
programing-budgeting system which has been instituted in all Federal
agencies. Indeed, in this time of congressional budget-cutting, it is
only with the guidance of competent economic analysis that Congress
can rationally choose among alternatives rather than apply the waste-
ful meat-ax approach to the budget.
In our session yesterday, the statements by Secretary of the Interior
Udall, Chairman of the Water Resources Council, and Henry Caul-
field, the Executive Director of the Council, explained the new pro-
posed regulation for improved interest rate policy in the water re-
sources area. In addition, Mr. Fred Hoffman, Assistant Director of the
Bureau of the Budget, presented us with a thoughtful analysis of the
conceptual basis for consistent interest rate policy. In addition, he
proposed a procedure for consistent expenditure evaluation among
the various agencies.
Today, we will hear the testimony of two prominent academic
economists on the interest rate question. They are Dr. Otto Eckstein of
Harvard University, a former member of the Joint Economic Com-
mittee staff and the Council of Economic Advisers, and Dr. Arnold
(49)
PAGENO="0054"
50
ilarberger, of the University of Chicago. Both of these gentlemen are
prominent in the area of public expenditure economics and should
contribute substantially to our understanding of this matter.
Tomorrow, we will hear the testimony of representatives of three
Federal agencies on the status of interest rate and discounting pro-
ceclures in their agencies.
Dr. Eckstein, we will be happy to have you go ahead.
STATEMENT OF OTTO ECKSTEIN, PROFESSOR OP ECONOMICS,
HARVARD UNIVERSITY
Mr. ECK5TEIN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. It is always a pleasure to
me to work with the Joint Economic Committee and to continue my
long association.
INTEREST RATE POLICY FOR THE EVALUATION OF FEDERAL PROGRAMS
These hearings of the Subcommittee on Economy in Government of
the Joint Economic Committee are a milestone in Federal expenditure
policy. Government investment in physical and human capital has
increased enormously in the last 30 years, and the crisis in our cities
makes a dramatic further growth of public investment very likely. If
these investments are `to be productive in accomplishing our national
purposes they must be well planned, employing sensible economic prin-
ciples and meaningful tests of performance.
Although it appears to be an abstract and highly technical matter,
the choice of interest rate in planning is fundamental and important.
The history of many economies, including our own, is replete with
capital projects based on faulty interest rates, with disastrous results
and enormous waste. Perhaps the most extreme example was the
attempt by the Soviet Union to plan an industrialization process with-
out the use of any interest rate-an absurd undertaking saved only by
the ingenuity of technicians in introducing interest-like criteria under
other names. Under Joseph Stalin the use of zero interest rates helped
produce the worst of gigantism. Projects of enormous scale and capital
intensity were started in the various regions of the Soviet Union.
Because of their size and capital intensity, years went by with little
payoff from these slowly progressing monuments. Even after their
completion their returns were often modest. After Stalin's death, as the
aspirations of the Russian people have begun to make themselves felt,
his successors have sought a higher degree of rationality in economic
calculations, and among other things have encouraged more systematic
testing of capital investments in terms of their rate of return. Even for
large investments a rate as high as 10 percent is prescribed today, and
for less capital intensive projects the rates are higher.
Another interesting example can be found in the United Kingdom.
Its premature investment in atomic energy for electric power report-
eclly can partly be blamed on the Government's use of a low interest
rate in planmng at a time in the early 1950's when capital was scarce.
In the United States the larger part of physical investment has been
in private haiids. While the actual capital market bears no more than
a family resemblance to the perfect allocating mechanism of economic
theory, it still provides a vital discipline to investment decisions to
avoid the very grossest errors.
PAGENO="0055"
51
But in the public sector, interest rate policy perhaps has been just as
remote from economic rationality as in the Soviet TJrnon. In many
fields of investment there is no use of interest tates at all. In the water
resource areas the interest rates have been about 3 percent, leading to
the usual results: excessive scale of development, excessive capital
intensity, in other words, waste of the Nation's capital.
So lonp~ as Federal investment was no more than a few billion dol-
lars a year, the waste that resulted from a 3-percent interest policy was
a luxury that we could afford. But the magnitudes of the tasks before
us have increased, and we expect more from economic policy than we
used to do. As we attempt to bring economic rationality into the pub-
lic sector generally, interest rate policy must be thoroughly reexamined.
My testimony today will attempt to contribute to the discussion which
will lead to the foundation of a sound and comprehensive interest rate
policy for Federal investment programs.
I. THE ROLE OF THE INTEREST RATE IN A MARKET ECONOMY
Interest rates serve four essential functions in the market economy:
(1) The price for liquidity.-The interest rates in the short-term
money market are paid for the use of money for a brief period, usually
less than a year. The variations of short-term interest rates are mainly
determined by the interplay of swings in the financial needs of business
and the Federal Government and the policy of the Federal Reserve
System. These interest rates are not pertinent to the planning of long-
lived public investments.
(2) The price and cost of long-term capital.-Long-term interest
rates are the price for borrowing long-term capital. As such, they
serve to allocate that share of the Nation's savings which becomes
available for long-term investment. They funnel savings into those
uses in which they promise to yield a return greater than the interest
rate. They also serve to keep capital out of uses which do not hold the
promise of yielding the market rate of interest.
(3) Interest rate as a means of valuation of income and consump-
tion at different points in time.-}iouseholds can choose to consume
their lifetime income in various time profiles by saving or borrowing.
Typically, households borrow in their early years while acquiring
a home and raising children, pass through a savings phase prepara-
tory to retirement, and draw down their savings thereafter. The prices
confronting households in these choices are the interest rate at which
they can borrow, such as the interest rate on home mortgages, on in-
stallment credit or personal loans, and the rates at which they can lend1
such as the interest rates on savings accounts, Government bonds and
the return on common stocks.
(4) Interest rates as a way of compevsating for the return for
taking ris/cs.-Interest rates differ according to the riskiness of the
loan or investment. The highly diverse structure of actual interest rates
found in the economy is partly due to differences in risk as viewed
by investors.
II. IMPERFECTIONS IN CAPITAL MARKETS
In a perfectly competitive, and perfectly functioning market econ-
omy, there would be only one interest rate for all risk-free loans of
any given maturity. This interest rate would be faced by both the
PAGENO="0056"
52
borrowers and the lenders. In this way, there would be assurance that
the return on marginal investments of businesses exactly equals the
rewards for marginal savings made by households. The optimal total
amount of saving and investment would be determined through free
choice in this process, and, leaving errors aside, the optimal combina-
tion of investment projects in the economy would be undertaken.
Economists differ in their assessment of the degree of correspond-
ence between this ideal picture and the actual market economy as we
know it. My judgment is rather far out on the spectrum of imperfec-
tions: as I have stated earlier, I assume "The capital market to be
imperfect, to be rife with rationing, ignorance, differential tax treat-
ments, reluctance to finance investment from external funds, slow
adjustment processes, et cetera, which destroy the normative signifi-
cance of actual rates found in the market." These imperfections, once
acknowledged, give rise to two further concepts for interest rates
which have received much attention in `the academic discussions of
interest rates for evaluating public investments.
(5) The social rate of tim~e preference.-With no single market rate
`embodying marginal returns and marginal household preferences
perfectly, and with the total savings of the economy not necessarily
optimal, a new basis must be found for deriving a socially optimal
interest rate. This problem is of particular significance in countries
where investment is heavily government-determined, but it is of perti-
nence even in the United States.
Theorists have devoted considerable effort to the derivation of an
optimal rate of social time preference, some would say an excessive
rate. The rates have been derived from theoretical models of economic
growth and postulated functions for the marginal utility of con-
sumption over time. It is usually inferred from this literature that
the rate of social time preference is low; that is, that the planner's
interest rate should be low, giving full weight to the welfare of future
generations and overriding the myopic desires of present individuals.
(6) A second concept which arises from the imperfections of the
capital market is the opportunity cost of public capital: In the absence
of a perfect capital market no one single actual interest rate can be
used as a test to assure that the return of a public project will exceed
the return of whatever other investment-or consun~ption-is for-
gone in its stead. It therefore becomes necessary to identify, on the
most realistic analysis possible, what actual other investments-or
consumption-are forgone, and what their return would have been.
In examining these forgone opportunities, and then identifying
the opportunity costs, one must ask these questions:
(a) Where would the resources have been used in the absence of the
particular public investment-in the public sector or in the private
sector?
(b) If the resources are drawn from the public sector, that is, if the
particular public investment is at the expense of other public expendi-
tures within a fixed budget, what return would have been earned?
(c) If the resources are drawn from the private sector, are they
obtained through taxation or through additional Government bor-
rowing? If general fiscal policy considerations require that the addi-
tional resources be obtained through taxation, one must postulate a
specific set of tax changes in order to identify what private expendi-
PAGENO="0057"
53
tures are forgone, and one must then measure the returns in those
alternative uses. If general fiscal policy permits the public investment
to be financed by public borrowing, one must trace what private in-
vestments are forgone because of this particular Government claim
in the capital market.
(d) Does the public investment preempt a private opportunity at the
physical site, or in the same product market, or in utilizing a scarce
natural resource? If there is preemption of private investment, an
additional test must be performed to assure that the public investment
is superior to the preempted private opportunity.
Let me add that I would not include the possibility of preemption
of private opportunities in deriving the interest rate itself. It is really
a side test that must be performed on a `project-by-project basis.
Let me examine quickly what I think is a theoretically correct solu-
tion in an imperfect economy and then evaluate if practically it is a
solution.
III. A THEORETICALLY CORRECT SOLUTION IN AN IMPERFECT MARKET
ECONOMY
A theoretically correct solution to the problem of the choice of inter-
est rate for public investment planning in an imperfect market econ-
omy is as follows:
(1) Identify the actual opportunities that are forgone and measure
the flow of returns that would have been earned in the alternative
use;
(2) Apply the social rate of ti'me preference to derive the present
value of the returns forgone in the alternative use;
(3) Undertake only those public investments which yield more pres-
ent value per dollar of expenditure than the forgone alternatives.'
`This formulation, w'hich I sketched in my book, "Water Resource
Development," translates into U.S. Government practice as follows:
(1) Apply the social time preference rate of interest in the valua-
tion of projects; but
(2) Compute the `benefit-cost ratio of the forgone `opportunities in
the private or public sector. If the interest rate is very low, if we as-
sume the social time preference to be very low, the benefit-cost ratio
of the forgone opportunities will be very high.
(3) Undertake those public projects which `have a benefit-cost ratio
greater than the benefit-cost ratio of the forgone opportunities. With
an interest rate of 3 percent, they would nowadays come to a benefit-
cost ratio on the order of 2.
While thi's formulation is correct within the particular theoretical
model, and I `had `high hopes for it 10 years ago, there are serious
difficulties in applying the method. It is my present judgment that
a more workable approach must be developed. The faults are these:
(1) There is no generally agreed upon empirical basis for deriving
the rate of social time preference. `One can make plausible arguments
in favor of high or low rates. When individuals have a chance to ex-
press their preferences about present versus future consumption th'ey
1 This formulation does not deal with the optimal time schedule of public investments,
the physical or economic Interdependence of projects, adjustments for risk, or the
intricate question of the symmetrical treatment of taxation.
PAGENO="0058"
54
value the present highly. The willingness of households to borrow at
interest rates in excess of 10 percent is a strong kind of evidence. I
doubt that a rate of social time preference is defensible in a democratic
society which is dramatically different from the interest rates revealed
to be preferred by consumer saving and borrowing actions.
The theoretical argument has been advanced that the people may
choose to redistribute income to future generations collectively-re-
flecting low social time preference-while expressing high time pref-
erence in their private actions. In other words that what they choose
to do together, knowing that all will do it together through the tax
system, they may choose to be more farsighted than they will in their
individual family planning. While not refutable by logic, it is a fragile
position. There is no evidence that it is true that people have such
collective preferences; governments in underdeveloped countries have
been known to misjudge the wishes of their people in taking this point
of view, plairning on a very capital intensive basis with low interest
and then finding great local objection to the fact that the projects do
not pay off.
(2) Even if one accepts the argument of collective desire to redis-
tribute income to the future-that is, even if one grants the theoretical
argument in total, it is still very dubious that public investments are
the most desirable method of accomplishing this goal. A higher rate
of taxation reducing the Government deficit, lowering interest rates
and permitting a higher rate of capital accumulation, whether private
or public, is a far more direct and efficient method of making pro-
vision for the future than to provide a privileged access to cheap capi-
tal for a few kinds of economic activities which have no extraordinary
growth potential.
flT SOME PRAGMATIC CONSIDERATIONS
Before deriving a sound criterion for Federal public investments,
that is, before we finally come to the hard issue of what is the right
rate, if there is such a thing, let me set down a few postulates that
will underlie my conclusions.
1. The rate of return on capital in the United States is high. We
are able to keep the economy prosperous through fiscal and monetary
management of aggregate demand; fluctuations around our natural
growth trend are becoming smaller. If you compare the 1950's with
the 1960's, the variations are smaller; if you compare prewar with
postwar, the fluctuations are smaller. The rate of advance of tech-
nology remains very great; the computer-probably the greatest in-
novation since the introduction of the automobile 50 years ago-
assures further rapid technological progress.
The recorded rates of return on capital are high in most major
sectors of the economy. The only exception I can think of are rail-
roads. The market rates of interest, which reflect long run forces of
supply and demand for capitaL are high and will probably remain so.
As the Vietnam war draws to a close and is, at last, financed through
higher taxes, the interest rates will diminish somewhat. But it is very
unlikely that interest rates will fall to the plateau that prevailed in
t.he early 1960's, when unemployment was 51/2 percent for 5 years and
prices were stable, when the rate of investment was low and the Gov-
ernment deficits small.
PAGENO="0059"
55
2. That the demands on public budgets will remain great so that
the competition for budget money will remain st~ff. This means that
the opportunity cost in the public sector will be high. Whatever en-
tenon is used, it must reflect the overall Federal budget position, in-
cluding the needs for large public investment in human resources, the
considerable outlays for military purposes, and the needs for social
overhead investments in a rapidly advancing economy.
3. Third, as a fundamental postulate, the high productivity of capi-
tal must be reflected in the interest rate used for planning and evaluat-
ing public investments. The two-step procedure discussed above, that
of using high social time preference rates and revaluing opportunity
costs at a social time preference rate, does not appear to be workable
for our government. The logic that a low interest rate must be coupled
with cutoff benefit-cost ratios on the order of 2 is too obscure for Gov-
ernment and general public discussion. The first part of the method,
that low interest rates can be justified on social grounds, is attractive.
But the pressures on agencies and their desire to promote their pro-
grams are such that they will never accept the second part of the meth-
od, that investment programs only be accepted if benefits exceed costs
by a factor of 2.
If the two-stage procedure is not workable, the interest rate itself
must reflect the high opportunity costs of capital in the private and in
the public sector.
The operational question then becomes: What should that interest
rate be?
V. WHAT INTEREST RATE FOR PUBLIC INVESTMENTS?
Given these postulates, the social time preference approach is
ruled out. With it is also ruled out any logic which would produce in-
terest rates as low as 3 percent which are still applied in some Federal
programs. There are no observable interest rates anywhere in the
economy as low as this: Capital yields substantially more in all sectors,
and households~ make their saving-borrowing choices also at much
higher rates. This is not to argue that the social time preference consid-
eration be eliminated completely in the derivation of the final rate, but
the weight given to it must be very limited if resources are not to be
grossly wasted.
The Governme'nt borrowing rate.~ This concept has some things to
recommend it if it is used properly, but it cannot survive full theoretical
scrutiny. On the one hand, it is the interest rate at which the Govern-
ment, as an enterprise, is able to obtain capital by borrowing. It also is
a measure of the pure, risk-free, long-term interest rate in the market.
On the other hand, the rate is not appropriate because, in actual prac-
tice, public investment projects are not financed by borrowing but by
taxation. The opportunity costs in the private or public sectors are like-
ly to exceed the long-term Government borrowing rate.
Nonetheless, if the Government borrowing rate were applied cor-
rectly, it would yield a better answer than current practice. The trou-
ble has been that the actual Federal interpretation, as spelled out for
example in Senate Document 97, has been very different from a "busi-
nesslike" enterprise borrowing cost.
PAGENO="0060"
56
Senate Document 97 bases the rate on the average rate payable on
outstanding TJ.S. securities having maturities of 15 years or more. Be-
cause of the 41/4 percent interest ceiling, the Treasury has been unable
to issue any securities of longer maturity since April 18, 1963, and has
issued no 10-year bonds, `which is less than the 15 years postulated, since
May 15, 1964. It has issued notes of medium term in recent years, most
recently a 7-year issue on May 15, 1968, paying 6 percent. This issue is
currently yielding 5.54 percent. In response to the improvement in the
bond market after the tax rise, long-term Treasuries are yielding 5.1
percent, a yield made possible only by the complete lack of new issues,
and the capital gains component in their yield. If the Treasury were to
issue new 15-year debt today, assuming that the interest ceiling is
eliminated, it would have to pay at least 51/2 percent.
T'he Government bond rate is a measure of pure interest, before
allowance for risk. If it is to be the basis for policy, a risk premium
must be added, either in the interest rate or elsewhere in the criterion.
Tn~ OPPORTUNITY COST OF Pu~LIo INVESTMENT
Let me turn now to what I think is the correct method. To estimate
opportunity cost of public capital obtained by taxation is an intricate,
but feasible piece of analysis. In an earlier book, "Multiple Purpose
River Development," with J. V. Krutilla, I presented such a study and
obtained estimates of 51/2 to 53/4 percent under the conditions prevail-
ing in 1955. I have not attempted to redo that exercise. The interest rate
structure has moved up 21/2 percent since then-that is, most long rates
have moved up by that amount, suggesting that the opportunity cost
today is approximately 8 percent. I append the earlier study for the
record, if the committee wishes, to indicate the method in detail.
VI. CONCLUSION AND RECOMMENDATION
The borrowing cost for long-term capital for the Federal Govern-
ment is 51/2 percent-if the Govermnent could borrow long term. The
opportunity cost for tax-raised capital is about 8 percent. What, then,
should be the interest rate for Federal investment planning?
In my judgment, both rates are of some pertinence, but the heavier
weight Should be placed on the opportunity cost estimate based on
tax financing. The Government borrowing rate can `be interpreted as
the lower limit of the opportunity cost of borrowed capital, which is a
part-albeit a small part-of Federal financing. Under contemporary
circumstance, and subject to more detailed reestimation of opportunity
cost, under today's interest rate conditions, an interest rate of about
7 to 71/2 percent is a proper rate for Federal planning to assure eco-
nomic use of the Nation's capital.
My testimony has not dealt with the estimation of benefits or the
selection of goals. I do not believe that all investments should pass a
narrow test of economic efficiency. Programs of human investment and
of urban reconstruction have important social and redistributive goals
which justify some sacrifice of economic efficiency.
But nothing is gained by confusing sensible economic planning
through an unrealistic interest rate policy. Let us quantify our social
goals and allocate our scarce resources so they will yield a maximum
social return.
PAGENO="0061"
57
I thank you, Mr. Chairman.
(See p. 82 for oh. IV of the book by Dr. Eckstein and John V.
Krutilla, referred to in preceding statement.)
Chairman PROXMIRE. Thank you, Professor Eckstein.
Professor Harberger, you may proceed.
STATEMENT OP ARNOLD C. HARBERGER, PROFESSOR OP ECONOMICS,
UNIVERSITY OP CHICAGO
Mr. HARBERGER. Mr. Chairman, I am honored by the opportunity to
participate in these important hearings and I share the concern of this
subcommittee with the problem of improving the productivity with
which public capital investment decisions are made.
I am also pleased to share this table with Professor Eckstein and I
applaud his excellent statement. While we have some divergences of
opinion which will undoubtedly come out in the course of the morning,
we share the final conclusion that the relevant discount rate for proj -
ect evaluation should be much higher than it is in order to avoid seri-
ous waste of public funds in investments of low yield.
ON THE OPPORTUNITY COST OF PUBLIC BORROWING
I begin these general comments with a discussion of the approach
to the discount rate to be used to evaluate public investments suggested
by the Comptroller General of the United States in his report to this
committee, dated January 29, 1968, and of the methodology outlined in
appendix III of that report. The key feature in which that concept and
methodology differ from those of Senate Document 97 is that the
Comptroller General's report advocates that the cost of Government
borrowing should include, in addition to the interest actually paid by
the Government, an adjustment factor to take into account the taxes
that the Government loses on the income that would have taken place
had the Government decided to borrow less-for example, as a con-
sequence of not undertaking a particular investment project.
There can be no doubt that an adjustment of the type suggested by
the Comptroller General is required if the total social costs imposed
as a result of additional Government borrowing are to be accounted
for. Whenever the economy is operating at levels close to capacity, the
resources raised by the Government have to be diverted from alterna-
tive uses; and the benefits which those resources would produce in those
alternative uses are foregone as a consequence. These `benefits clearly
include the taxes that would be paid on the income from private invest-
ments that are displaced by Government borrowing.
However, the Comptroller General's report errs in concentrating
on the "cost to the Treasury" of incremental borrowings rather than
focusing more broadly on the "costs to the economy" of such borrow-
ing. This leads to the neglect of the State and local taxes that would
have been paid on private investments displaced by Federal borrow-
ing-a point which I shall treat at some length below.
The report also is inconsistent in its application of the incorrect
principle which it espouses. If one were to attempt to measure the
"cost to the Treasury" of incremental Government borrowing, surely
account should be taken of the effect of such borrowing in the yields
PAGENO="0062"
58
of Federal indirect as well as direct taxation, but in point of fact in-
direct-tax effects are totally neglected in the report.
Moreover, a correct measurement of the "cost to the Treasury" of
added Government borrowing would include the effect on tax yields of
such increases in interest rates and profit rates as might ensue as a
cousequence of such borrowing. The Comptroller General's report does
not take these into account and hence deviates from its seated objective
of measuring the "cost to the Treasury." The error in this case was in
a sense a happy one, however, for while the effect on tax yields of in-
duced increases in interest and profit rates operates to reduce the "cost
to the Treasury" of Government borrowing, it has no such effect on
the "cost to the economy." As will be shown below, the tax gains to
the Government arising from changes in interest and profit rates in-
duced by incremental borrowing reflect corresponding losses to the
private sector. Thus the Comptroller General's report was right in
neglecting such gains, from an overall "cost to the economy" point of
view, but the report fails to recognize that in so doing it deviates from
its stated objective of measuring "cost to the Treasury."
Apart from the above-mentioned errors, which can be corrected with
relative ease, the Comptroller General's incorporates two significant
insights.
The first is that the Government, in its normal borrowing operations,
does not control the distribution by type of the investment that is dis-
placed. What happens as a result of additional Government borrow-
ing is that the capital market is made a little tighter, as a consequence
of which corporations, unincorporated enterprises, and households
engaged in borrowing all have to scramble a bit harder for funds.
Lending terms are likely to be tightened by financial institutions to all
classes of borrowers, and are unlikely to fall exclusively on any one
class. In particular, it is highly unlikely that the funds obtained by
the Government will, in our present financial structure, all be diverted
from corporate investment. Government borrowing will instead dis-
place some corporate investment, some noncorporate investment, some
residential construction, and perhaps some purchases of consumer dur-
ables. This nieans that we cannot take the rate of return to capital in
any single sector of the economy as the opportunity cost of public bor-
rowing, and it therefore rules out the use of, say, the corporate rate
of return, which has been suggested by some investigators as a measure
of this opportunity cost. If one is to use private-sector rates of return
to obtain the opportunity cost of public funds, what is clearly called
for, at least under present institutional arrangements in the capital
market, is a weighted average of the rates of return applying in all
relevant sectors of the private economy, the weights reflecting the de-
grees to which investment in each sector is estimated to be displaced
by public-sector borrowing.
The second important insight reflected in the Comptroller General's
report is that when Government borrowing displaces private invest-
ment, the cost of such borrowing to the economy is better measured by
the rate of interest on Government bonds plus the tax loss on the income
foregone because of displaced private investment, rather than by the
overall yield or productivity of the displaced investment. The reason is
the complexity of our economy and of our capital market in particular.
At any one time one may find in the market some bonds yielding 6
PAGENO="0063"
59
percent, others yielding 7 percent and still others yielding 8 or 9
percent. Why do not all investors forego the 6-percent opportunities in
favor of those yielding 9 percent? The answer is obviously that some
investors do precisely that, but others regard the 9-percent bonds as
too risky for their taste. And those who invest in both classes of bonds
will at the margin be indifferent between the two investments.
This leads me to introduce the concept of the supply price of capital
funds. When businesses seek additional capital, they do not willingly
raise it from high-cost sources when lower cost sources are available;
they instead try to obtain their funds in the cheapest way possible. Yet
some businesses have to pay very handsome interest rates on borrowed
funds, and to hold out prospects for high rates of return on any
equity capital they raise, while others can issue debt at lower rates and
equity at lower expected yields.
In order to pay the supply price of capital, business has to earn more
than that, because the yield that investors receive is net of business
taxes.
The supply price of debt capital to a firm might be 7 percent, and that
of equity capital 8 percent, yet in order to pay these rates, the firm
might have to earn 15 percent on its investment. To see this, suppose an
investment of $1 million, financed 70 percent by equity and 30 percent
by debt. The possible outcome of such an investment in a typical year
might be:
Gross-of-tax income accruing to additional capital $150, 000
Less additional property taxes paid on the new assets 17, 000
Less corporation taxes paid on additional equity incomes 56, 000
Equals income from new investment, net of business taxes 77, 000
\~Thich breaks down into:
Interest on additional debt (0.07x300,000) 21, 000
Plus net income from additional equity (0.08X 700,000) 56, 000
In order to pay an average supply price of capital equal to 7.7 per-
cent, this firm must earn a 15-percent return.
Suppose for the moment that this was-highly unrealistically, but
useful as an imphfying assumption-the only investment displaced by
the Government's borrowing an additional $1 million at a rate of 5
percent. The rate of return on the displaced investment is 15 percent,
but the true opportunity cost of the additional funds is not 15 percent
but, in this example, 13.2 percent. This result is obtained as follows:
Actual interest cost paid by Government on new debt $50, 000
Taxes forgone on income from displaced investment:
Property taxes 17, 000
Corporation taxes 56,000
Personal income taxes 9,000
Total opportunity cost 132, 000
Only the personal income tax component of this opportunity cost
calculation remains to be explained. This is due to the fact that the
income, net of business taxes but gross of personal taxes on the dis-
placed investment was $77,000, and this is replaced by interest income
on Government bonds of $50,000. Assuming a marginal personal tax
rate of 331/3 percent, there is involved in the displacement a loss of
personal income tax revenue equal to $9,000-equals one-third of
$27,000.
PAGENO="0064"
60
In this example the difference between the 15 percent rate of return
to the displaced investment and the 13.2 percent opportunity cost of
capital is equal to the difference of 2.7 percentage points-equals 7.7
minus 5-in the supply price of capital facing the displaced invest-
ment and that facing the Government, reduced by one-third to ac-
count for lower personal income tax revenues.
The methodology underlying the above calculation is, apart from
the treatment of property taxes, essentially identical to that presented
by the Comptroller General on pages 25-26 of his report. This brings
me to an elaboration of my first point of difference with that report.
From the point of view of economic logic, when attempting to measure
the cost to the society as a whole of Govermnent borrowing, there is no
ground to distinguish whether the taxes foregone on the income from
displaced investments would have accrued to the Federal Government
or to State and local governments. By focusing on Federal taxes
alone, the report unduly narrows its focus. Property tax considerations
must enter into any comprehensive measure of the overall opportunity
cost of Government borrowing, particularly when property taxes pta.y
as important a role in the overall fiscal system as they do in the United
States.
The report likewise leaves excise and sales taxes out of considera-
tion, an omission which is harder to understand than that of property
taxes since, even apart from highway taxes which might be consid-
ered as user charges, the excises by themselves produce some $10
billion per year in revenue to the Federal Government. Of course,
State and local sales and excise taxes should also be brought into ac-
count; these, which yield considerably more than the Federal excises,
further emphasize the importance of incorporating sales and excise
taxes into the overall calculation of the opportunity cost of Govern-
ment borrowing.
To see how the adjustment for sales and excise taxes should be made,
assume that the product produced by the displaced investment in
the preceding example is subject to sales and excise taxes of 10 per-
cent, and that total costs of sales are distributed as follows:
Percent
Earnings of capital, gross of property, and profit taxes 20
Earnings of labor, gross of fringe benefits, and social security taxes 20
Depreciation of capital 10
Material inputs 50
Sales and excise taxes apply to the total of all these costs, but we need
to know what part of such taxes to attribute to the displaced capital
inveStment. On the working hypothesis that materials inputs bear a
fixed relationship to total output in the indusry in question, the fol-
lowing formulation holds. Add "Depreciation to earnings of capital,"
giving a gross of depreciation capital share of 30 percent, in this case.
Then allocate the material input share to labor and capital in propor-
tion to their adjusted shares. In this case we thus allocate to capital 20
percent from "Earnings of capital gross of property and profits taxes"
plus 10 percent from "Depreciation of capital," plus 30 percent from
"Materials." The total is 60 percent, on which sales and excise taxes
will have to be paid, say, at a rate of 10 percent. Our figure for the
"Earnings of capital gross of property `and profits taxes" was $150,000
in the earlier example. This corresponds to 20 percent of total costs.
The excise taxes attributable to this additional capital `are 10 percent
PAGENO="0065"
61
time,s 60 percent of total costs or 0.10 times $450,000, which equals
$45,000.
The revised calculation of opportunity costs then would read:
Actual interest cost paid by Government on new debt $50, 000
Taxes forgone on income from displaced investment:
Property taxes 17, 000
Oorporation taxes 56,000
Personal income taxes 9,000
Sales and excise taxes foregone as a result of displacement 45,000
Total opportunity cost 177, 000
In this case, the presence of a mere 10 percent excise or sales tax has
changed the social opportunity cost of the funds in question from 13.2
to 17.7 percent.
My next comment concerns the report's division of displaced invest-
ment into just two categories-corporate and noiicorporate. In prin-
ciple this breakdown could be extended `to many different sectors. And
even though a finer breakdown may appear to be an unnecessary
refinement at this early stage of the process of developing a better
measure of the opportunity cost of public funds, at least one addi-
tional investment sector-owner-occupied residential housing-defi-
nitely deserves to be included. The reason is that this type of invest-
mentis subject to very different t'ax treatment from other noncorporate
investment. Instead of paying personal income taxes on the income
accruing to their housing, owner-occupiers receive tax relief on account
of such income. Thus, if $1 million of housing investment were dis-
placed by Government investment, the calculation might look like this:
Actual interest cost paid by Government on new debt $50, 000
Taxes forgone on income from displaced investment:
Property taxes 15,000
Personal income taxes -16, 661
Total opportunity cost 48,333
If the Government bonds carried an interest rate of 5 percent and
the relev'ant marginal personal tax rate was 331/3 percent, the tax
adjustment here would actually lower the opportunity cost of funds
obtained through the displacement of residential construction to 4.83
percent, rather than raising it to 13.2 or 17.7 percent as occurred in
our previous examples where business investment was displaced. The
importance of owner-occupied housing construction in total invest-
ment in the United States, and the known sensitivity of such con-
struction `to changes in capital market conditions make it quite essen-
tial to take explicit account of the peculiar tax status of this kind of
investment when estimating the opportunity cost of public borrow-
ings.
I turn now to a comment on the report which is of comparatively
minor significance, and is introduced here only for the sake of com-
pleteness. The report assumes that all of in increase in Government
borrowing is reflected in displaced private investment, and none in
increased private savings. Since increased borrowing from any source
tends to increase interest rates, a rise in savings will presumably
result if they display a positive responsiveness to changes in interest
rates. Since the `available evidence suggests that :the responsiveness of
savings to changes in yields is at best small and possibly zero, the as-
sumption made in the report is certainly a defensible one. Nonetheless
98-940 O-68----5
PAGENO="0066"
62
I shall here sketch how one would measure the social opportunity cost
of $1 million of funds raised through increased saving:
Actual interest cost paid by the Government $50, 000
Less additional taxes on interest from increased savings 16,667
Totai opportunity cost 33,333
In this example, the social opportunity cost of funds coming out of
newly generated saving is only 3.3 percent.
I now turn to an illustrative calculation of the overall social oppor-
tunity cost of capital, after the fashion of that presented on pages
25 and 26 Of the Comptroller General's report. For this purpose I shall
assume that funds obtained at the expense of corporate investment
have an opportunity cost of 15 percent-lying between the 13.2 ~per-
cent and the 17.7 percent of our two examples-that those obtained at
the expense of investment by noncorporate firms have an opportunity
cost of 8.5 percent,1 that those coming at the expense of housing in-
vestment-owner-occupied-have an opportunity cost of 4.8 percent,
and that those generated by increased savings have an opportunity
cost of 3.3 percent. I shall further assume the following pattern of
"sources" for the funds obtained.
Percent of
Relevant
Source of funds incremental
borrowings
opportunity
cost (percent)
(1) X (2)
(1)
(2)
(3)
Displaced corporate investment. 50 15.0 7.50
Displaced noncorporate investment 25 8. 5 2. 13
Displaced owner.occupied housing construction 15 4.8 0.72
Newly stimulated savings 10 3.3 0.33
Overall opportunity cost
10.68
Note that in spite of my having introduced two additional sources,
withvery low opportunity costs, my resulting figure is substantially
higher than that emerging from the report. This is in. part due to
my having used 5 percent rather than 4 percent as the basic mterest
rate on Government bonds, and in very small part due to a somewhat
higher before-tax yield assumed on corporate and noncorporate in-
vestment. But in the main the difference is attributable to my taking
property, sales, and excise taxes into account in the calculation. These
taxes are lumped together in the national income accounts under
the classification "Indirect business tax and nontax liability" and
they~ account for the overwhelming bulk of that category. For 1967,
the national income accounts show that category as amounting to
almost $70 billion, or well over 11 percent of the approximately $600
1Thls can be obtained as foflows:
On $1 million of Investment displaced from the noneorporate sector we have:
Actual interest cost paid by Government on new debt $50 000
Taxes forgone in income from displaced Investment:
Property taxes_.~~~
Personal Income ~
Sales and excise taxes forgone as a result of displacement__
15, 000
- 10, 000
10, 000
Total o~portunity cosL~~~~___,_ ~-. 85, 000
I assume here a rate of return of 8 percent net of property taxes, which results In
$80,000 of taxable Income displaced, compared with $50,000 of taxable Income generated
by Interest on the Government bonds. Sales and excise taxes are assumed to be at an
average rate of 5 percent with annual sales of $200,000 forgone as a consequence of the
diversion of Investment.
PAGENO="0067"
63
billion of final-goods spending by the private sector. Property taxes
alone, at around $40 billion, outstrip the yield of the corporation
income tax, and sales and excise taxes, at around $30 billion, amount
to about 5 percent of private-sector acquisitions of final goods and
services. These are far-too-important components of our tax structure
to be left out of account in the exercise of estimating the opportunity
cost of public funds.
Let me emphasize that the exercise just completed is illustrative, and
not the result of the long and careful research it would take to come
up with a thoroughly defensible estimate of the opportunity cost
it seeks to evaluate. However, I am convinced that the order of magni-
tude is probably correct, and that it is doubtful that further research
along the same lines would modify the 10.7-percent figure by more
than, say, 2 percentage points-that is, the result of such research
would probably be an estimate somewhere in the range between 8.7
and 12.7 percent.
At this point let me express a general caveat concerning the distinc-
tion between the "overall cost to the economy" of Government borrow-
ing, and the "cost to the Treasury" concept, elaborating upon my
introductory comments in this regard. It is all too easy to identify
what I have called "Taxes forgone in income from displaced invest-
ment" plus "Sales and excise taxes forgone as a result of displace-
ment" with the "net change in tax revenues resulting from added
Government borrowing." This would be a convenient identification if
it were only true, but unfortunately it is not, which complicates the
analysis a bit. The designation "Taxes forgone on income from dis-
placed investment," and its counterpart for sales and excise taxes are
the correct ones, but the net change in tax revenues resulting from
added Government borrowing is likely to be a different figure. The
difference stems from the fact that the displacement of some private-
sector investments is likely to raise the yield of capital that is already
in place, and of those current investments that are not displaced
by the added Government borrowing. As a consequence, tax revenues
stemming from these sources are likely to be higher than they would
be in the absence of the added borrowing.
If, as a consequence of added borrowing, the yield rises on capital
which would in any event be present, the result is in effect a transfer
from the consuming public in general to the owners of capital. Given
our tax structure, a part of this transfer will be retransferred to the
Government. But it would be totally incorrect to count extra revenues
of this type as part of the benefit of added Government borrowing,
without taking into account the loss to consumers that they reflect.
When the changes in the positions of consumers, owners of capital,
and the Government are evaluated together for transfers of the type
under discussion, the end result nets to zero. What consumers lose
through such transfers is gained by owners of capital or by Govern-
ment; the transfers therefore produce no increment in overall
welfare.1
Finally, I turn to an issue posed by the work of Professor Eckstein
in "The Social Cost of Federal Financing." 2 Professor Eckstein there
11 follow a longstanding conveation of cost-benefit analysis in placing the same social
valuation on an extra dollar received or given up by any group.
2 Ch. 4 in John V. Krutilla and Otto Eckstein, "Multiple Purpose River Development"
(Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press, 1958). (See p. 82, this volume.)
PAGENO="0068"
64
developed a methodology similar to those used in this paper and in
the Comptroller General's report, but applied it to the raising of funds
by taxation rather than by borrowing. This raises questions like (a)
Are there reasons why the opportunity cost of public funds obtained
via borrowing should be regarded as superior to the opportunity cost
of funds raised by taxation as the relevant discount rate for public
project evaluation? (b) Since funds come from both sources, should
not the relevant rate be an appropriately weighted average of the two
opportunity costs? (c) Should not different rates of discount be used
depending on how the funds in question are raised?
I cannot here go into all the ramifications of these questions, but
will instead briefly sketch the main issues and propose the outlines
of some answers. With respect to question (c), the first problem is
that we do not know, except for the case of earmarked taxes, what is
the source of the funds used in any particular project. Second, there
should be-apart from a risk adjustment which would undoubtedly
vary from project to project-a single rate of discount used for all
Federal projects, since to do otherwise would mean that projects are
undertaken in some areas which are inferior to projects rejected in
other areas.
With respect to question (b), one faces first the issue of what weights
to `apply to the opportunity costs of funds raised by each of the in-
numerable possible ways of increasing tax revenues. There simply is
no standard pattern in administration recommendation or congres-
sional decisions about changes in tax rates, tax bases, and the like. On
the other hand, there is presumably a definable pattern in which
Government borrowing displaces private investment, which is deter-
mined by the relative sensitivity of different types of investment-and
possibly of saving-to changes in the degree of tightness of the capital
market. On this ground alone we have a basis for preferring the op-
portunity cost of borrowed funds to an unknown and unstable mix of
opportunity costs of tax funds-or to a weighted average containing
such a mix-as the relevant discount rate.
This brings us to question (a), since if the opportunity cost of bor-
rowed funds can be defended as being superior to that of tax funds we
should, given our answer to (b), be willing to opt for the former as
the discount rate. I perceive two related grounds on which the superior-
ity of the opportunity cost of borrowed funds can be claimed. The
first is that, in any given situation, more taxation means less `borrowing
associated with given Government expenditures. This means that when
an extra dollar is raised via taxation, it can release to the private sec-
tor capital funds that will have a social yield equal to the social oppor-
tunity cost of Government `borrowing.
To calculate the social yield of taxation, therefore, we simply go
through the above Government borrowing exercise in reverse, and ob-
tain the saving in interest costs on account of having less debt plus
the incremental tax revenues derived from the extra private investment
that a lower level of Government borrowing generates.
The second ground for preferring the opportunity cost of borrowing
is that it can uppropriately serve as a guide to tax decisionmaking.
We are accustomed to seeing and discussing `benefit-cost analyses of
public expenditures; perhaps the idea of benefit-cost analyses of public
revenue raised in particular ways is less familiar, but it is equally sound.
PAGENO="0069"
65
There is oniy one rate of discount which can bring rational calcula-
tions to both sides of the tax-expenditure picture in this way, and that
is what I have called the social opportunity cost of public `borrowing.
The market price of a product should affect a farmer's production
and consumption decisions in the sense that any excess of production
over consumption can be sold in the market, and any excess of pro-
duction over consumption must be bought in the market. Even
though for some products the amount bought or sold might be small
relative to the farm's production of the product and the family's
consumption of it, it is perfectly valid for the farmer to base his
production decisions on the market price and for his wife to base the
family's consumption plans on the market price.
In just the same way the social opportunity cost of government
borrowing can operate to guide taxation and expenditure decisions. It
matters not that total borrowing is small relative to taxes and expendi-
tures; what is important is that any extra taxes tend to reduce borrow-
ing and any extra expenditures tend to increase it. The one price that
can serve as a guide to both sets of decisions is therefore the oppor-
tunity cost of government borrowing.
Let it be noted, too, that the use of the social opportunity cost of
government borrowing as a guide to tax and expenditure decisions does
not mean that the discount rate is beyond the influence of public
policy. Actually, there are two ways in which public policy can in-
fluence this rate. First, changes in the rates of tax applicable to the
different sectors can change the social opportunity cost of capital
obtained at their expense. Thus, a reduction in corporation tax rates
would at one and the same time serve to channel more funds into the
corporate sector of the economy and also to reduce the opportunity
cost of any government funds subsequently obtained at the expense
of that sector.
Secondly, to the extent that the social cost of additional tax revenue
is judged to be lower/higher than its social yield, increases/de-
creases in the level of taxation over time can make more/less
capital available to the private sector, thus leading to decreases/in-
creases in the market level of interest rates and of private-sector
capital yields generally. Thus, though at any point in time the oppor-
tunity cost of public borrowing is basically determined by the nature
of the then-existing tax and capital-market structures, public policy
can be used to influence the way in which this discount rate moves
through time, via public decisions concerning both the nature of the
tax structure and the overall volume of revenue to be raised through
taxation.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Mr. Harberger, do you arrive at any general
conclusion on the discount rate level? What ought it to be?
Mr. HABBERGER. WeJl, the caJculation that I made, which admittedly
is quite rough-
Chairman PROXMIRE. 10.8 percent?
Mr. HARBERGER. 10.7 percent. I would say that something between
8.5 or 11.5 or 12 would probably represent the plausible range for
such an estimate.
Chairman PR0xMmE. As I recall, the Comptroller General, in his
analysis, in his concept as you indicated, is somewhat close to yours;
PAGENO="0070"
66
that is, it is the cost of long-term borrowing plus forgone taxes or
either 7 or 8 percent.
Mr. HARBERGER. That is right.
Chairman Pi~ox~rnti~. I take it, Mr. Eckstein, you arrive in that
general area, too.
Mr. EOKSTEIN. Yes, Mr. Chairman.
Mr. H imor~. My calculation differs from that of the Comptroller
General in the particular sense that it takes into account the effects
of Government borrowing on sales and excise taxes, and on property
taxes. It seems to me that we should not take a narrowly, purely
Federal focus in calculating these tax changes. The tax changes really
represent what we call in economics external effects of Govermnent
borrowing, and if, at the same time as tax revenues are changing for
the Federal Government, they are also changing for State and local
governments, they should be counted.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Will you spell out what is your rationale for
including the tax-forgone item in your calculations?
Mr. HARBERGER. Let me start at another end of the spectrum. If
we get government funds, let us say, at the expense of corporate in-
vestment with a yield of 15 percent, we might simply take 15 percent
as the opportunity cost of those funds, even though the Government
is only paying 5 percent on its borrowings. The reason why taxes come
into the picture is because the full differences between the 15 percent
earned on corporate investment and the 5 percent paid on Govern-
ment bonds does not represent a true cost to investors. A part of the
difference is simply a compensation for the extra risk borne by in-
vestors in corporate securities. If the 15-percent yield of corporate
investment can be broken down into 5 percentage points of interest-
equivalent to that on Government bonds-plus 2 percentage points
of risk premium; plus 8 percentage points of taxes, the opportunity
cost of Government borrowing at the expense of such investment would
be 13-equals 5 plus 8-not 15 percent.
Chairman Pi~oxrnER. Is this a risk element?
Mr. HARBERGER. It is a risk or taste element on the part of the general
public, but it is a genuine cost that is important, I think, or it is
relevant to take into account.
Chairman Puox~iius. That element is wholly gone, absent, from
the Government investment?
Mr. HARBERGER. Yes. At least, the risk element is measured by com-
paring the yields on private securities with those on Government
bonds. One need not ask the question, Does the public have some sense
of risk concerning Government bonds? The differential we observed
in the market is the additional sense of risk that the public has when
it compares corporate securities with Government bonds.
Chairman PRox3nns~. You arrive at how big a difference, now?
Mr. HARBERGER. How big a difference in-
Chairman PRox~rnn~. Between the Government and corporate bonds.
Mr. HARBERGER. It varies all over the map, Senator.
Chairman PRox~mrn. I know, but overall, in arriving at your calcu-
lation of 13 and-
Mr. HARBERGER. What happens is if you were to say in the example
I gave that 15 percent is the productivity that capital would have in
the corporation, of which 8 is taxes and 7 is the cost of capital to cor-
porations, that compares with, let us say, a 5-percent yield on Govern-
PAGENO="0071"
67
mont bonds. Let us divide up the 15 into 8 which are taxes, 2 which
are risk premium, if you like, and 5 which represents the cost of
Government bonds.
Chairman PROXMIRE. When you say 8 are taxes, you are talking
about the fact that you have a corporation income tax of 50 percent,
roughly, and then, in addition to that, you have property taxes and
other taxes?
Mr. }IIARBERGER. Right.
What I am saying is that in measuring the social opportunity cost
of capital, if we start with the 15 and divide it up into those three
segments-8 of taxes, 2 of risk premium, and 5 of the cost of Govern-
ment bonds-the 2 of risk premium should not be counted as part of
the opportunity cost of Government funds any more than the excess
wages that are paid in an outlying mining district should be con-
sidered as a part of the true profit of that enterprise. The risk premium
is a part of the after-tax supply price of capital, at which investors
would voluntarily make their funds available for corporate investment.
Chairman PROXMIRE. I would like to ask. you, Dr. Eckstein, to coin-
ment on this, the notion of the need for inclusion of foregone taxes.
Mr. ECKSTEIN. There are two ways of getting to the same point. If
you start out with basic interest costs and then you want to get to the
total return on capital, you have to build in all the individual com-
ponents, risk, taxes, and so forth, that account for the difference.
So you do have to track down all the miscellaneous taxes.
Another approach is to start out with a gross return on capital itself
rather than the borrowing costs, which get you to the same place in
one step. If you take the tax approach, which is the approach that I
have used in the past, you do not go through all these questions about
which taxes are forgone and where; this is a somewhat treacherous
game, because it can also be played on the benefit side. You get to the
return on capital in one step. But if you take the borrowing approach,
you certainly have to include taxes.
Chairman PRoxMniE. Now, it seems there is this merit in taking the
conceptual approach that Dr. Harberger takes here, from the political
standpoint. That is that we now base the discount rate on the cost of
borrowing. That is the justification used in Senate Document 97 and
all the other documents that have been argued. It would seem perhaps
easier to persuade Members of the Congress to recognize the forgone
taxes than to move into a new area, which I find a little more con-
genial, frankly, but nevertheless, I am not sure other Members of the
Congress would-but this new area of return on capital: How do you
feel about that?
What is the difference?
You say you arrived-I can see that you seem to arrive at a fairly
similar position. But why is your approach conceptually superior,
other than, as you say, you do not have to worry about this variety of
taxes?
Mr. ECKSTEIN. Let me deal with several of these questions sys-
tematically.
I think the tax approach is conceptually superior because, in fact,
the bulk of Federal financing is tax financing, not borrowing. Even
our $25.4 billion deficit is only $25.4 billion out of $180 billion. That
ispointl.
PAGENO="0072"
68
Professor Harberger is right, that the tax approach requires you to
postulate a specific set of tax changes. I suppose if the Government
did an official calculation, it would not be able to reassess each year
what the next tax change would be, it would have to take some aver-
age of the tax system, where the revenues actually come from on the
average and assume some change based on average revenues.
Chairman PR0xMIRE. Is it not true that you have the same kind of
problem on rate of return? Does that not vary all over the place?
Mr. EOKSTEIN. Yes; but if you take the average of a tax system as
the cost, if you assume that the money is raised in proportion with the
tax system, you have identified the sources of the money; you then
have to estimate only once what the return on capital is in those
sources. So it is a computation that is not easy, but I did such a study
in 2 months in the summer of 1956 when I was asked the question,
What is the opportunity cost of Federal capital? The Government
could do that study very well, and I think with reasonable precision
Let me stress one other point. The results are fairly insensitive to
small changes in assumption. At the time I did it, I postulated two
kinds of tax models, one which would have emphasized consumption
and the other which would have emphasized investment.. I thought
at the time, one is a Republican tax change and the other is a
Democratic.
Chairman PROxHIRE. Which one is the Democratic, the consump-
tion?
Mr. EoKs~rEIN. it emphasized consumption. That was back in the
mid-1950's. We `have all come a long way since then.
Chairman PR0xMIRE. We have not reversed our roles, though, have
we?
Mr. Ecxs1~IN. Not totally.
The results were within a quarter of a point of each other. All of.
these models are weighted averages of the actual rsturns. The differ-
ence between Harberger's estimate and mine is not really due to his
use of a borrowing rather than a tax model, it is the assumption about
the fraction of resources that comes out of the corporate sector.
The average rate of return in the corporate sector is on the order
of 15 percent; in manufa~turing, it is even higher.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Is it that `high before taxes?
Mr. EcKsmIN. Yes.
Chairman PRox3m~E. Then it `includes utilities and railroads, `the
whole thing?
And this would be over a period of' substantial time?
Mr. ECKSTEIN. The average, even including railroads, must be close
to 15 percent. In manufacturing we average more than 20 percent.
Ohairman PROxMIRE. You say this is `true of the period b~t.ween
1948 and 1968?
Mr. EOKsTEIN. Yes; it `has its ups and downs because of recessions,
but it is on that magnitude. My model extracts a smaller share of re-
sources from manufacturing than Harberger's model. It is a scientific
judgment. I would like to see it settled by doing as good a study as
you can of it. I believe that somehow, the corporate sector gets its
capital and exploits its good investment opportunities, and if you take
resources from them one way, they get their capital through borrow-
ing or by cutting down dividends disbursements. If you trim the 50-
PAGENO="0073"
69
percent source of the Harberger calculation to a 10- or 25-percent
source, you bring the Harberger estimate down to the other studies.
I do not think, apart from that, it matters for the outcome whether
you use a straight borrowing approach corrected with taxes or
whether you take a tax approach going directly to rates of return.
All of these things are weighted averages of the actual rates prevail-
ing, and they all get up to 7 or 8 percent. I have no particular brief
for my method of 10 years ago. It can be done reasonably by a bor-
rowing approach, corrected by taxes.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Can you gentlemen agree that there is any
consensus on these approaches in the economic profession among those
who specialize in this area, the Government investment area?
Or is it one that is fairly evenly divided, or is it partly so?
Mr. HARBERGER. I am afraid, Senator, that the profession has been
rather lax in working its way into this theory. You have sitting before
you two out of a handful of people, or maybe a couple of handfuls of
people, who have paid serious attention to this problem. I do not
think that we can talk about professional consensus at this stage of the
game. The particular formulation that I was working on in preparing
my comments is going to come out probably later this year or early
next year in a paper, and to my knowledge, it has never before been
explicitly thoroughly developed in the economic literature.
Mr. EcKs~rEIN. We should report that there is a group of scholars
mainly concerned with the problems of less developed countries that
still develop theoretically the social time preference approach. Now, to
my knowledge, except for one attempt of mine, they have never
attempted to convert this into numbers. It is a very intricate and amus-
ing theoretical game to devise these social time preference rates from
models. If you ask them, would you recommend that the Congress
build a project which promises to yield 3 percent, they would say, no,
on the grounds that there are better uses for the money.
Chairman PRoxMini~. Yesterday, we had testimony on the views of
the economic profession. You usually get more of that when you do
not have the economic profession in front of you, although the men
were all competent, fine men. But is there, in your view, a feeling, an
overall feeling in the economic profession, would you say, that the
present system, A, is inadequate; B, is much too low; C, whether you
take the Eckstein or Harberger approach or some other approach, that
it would be in the area of 7 or 8 to 12 or 15 percent-at any rate, sub-
stantially higher? Is that a fair conclusion?
Mr. ECKSTEIN. The present approach is indefensible, even on its
own logic.
Chairman PROXMIRE. That is not only your conclusion but the con-
clusion of other people in this area?
Mr. ECKSTEIN. I cannot imagine any economic scholar who would
endorse the present approach.
Chairman PROXMIRE. By that you mean the 4%?
Mr. EoKsr1~nN. No; I was thinking of the 3.1.
Chairman PROXMIRE. How about that 4% percent?
Mr. HARBERGER. I believe the overwhelming bulk of the economics
profession would say that the rate on Goveimmenit bonds is itself far
too low to be used as a discount rate for public investment decisions.
Chairman PROxMIRE. Would you agree, Dr. Eckstein?
PAGENO="0074"
70
Mr. EcKs~IN. I think so. I would share that judgment. You would,
of course, find people generally emphasizing that you ought `to con-
sider social goals, you ought to consider benefit measurements. There
are many other dimensions of the problem. Economists do not believe
all Government actions are strictly to promote GOvernment efficiency,
or that the Govermnent is in the business of maximizing profits on
these projects. What they would say, I believe, is that it is on the bene-
fit measurement side, on setting social goals in a quantitative way and
pursuing them rationally; that is the area where you ought to think
of the broader perspective, not in the choice of interest rate.
Chairman PROXMIRE. The interesting thing said by Mr. Fred Hoff-
man of the Bureau of the Budget was that the 4~/8 percent, which was
championed by the other two, Mr. Caulfield and Mr. Holum, who was
speaking for Secretary Tidall-he said this rate was not inconsistent
with an estimate of the risk-free social opportunity cost capital over
the whole economy, but it is an absolute minimum estimate to this rate.
Mr. ECKsI'nIN. There is no way of raising 4~/8 capital in this econ-
omy. If you go to the capital market and offer 4% percent, they will
not let you in the door.
Chairman PRoxMinE. That brings me to another question I was go-
ing to ask a little later. Let me ask it now. This relates to `the notion
that you have an inflationary element involved here. The Water Re-
sources Council defended reliance on the current yield of Government
securities observed 2 years ago, with a 4% determination. This is de-
fended on the grounds that more recent observed rates are too high
because of inflation expectations. Does this approach seem theoretically
correct or reasonable to you?
Mr. HAi~imrn. Let me speak to that point, Mr. Chairman, because
I have spent a fair part of the last 10 years in Latin America, where
rates of inflation of 20 percent and up have not been uncommon. It is
indeed true that in a market economy, inflationary anticipations can be
incorporated into the interest rate and you find in places like Chile
and Argentina interest rates of 20 and 25 percent, which are that high
simply as a reflection of inflationary anticipations. TJnder those cir-
cumstances, it would be necessary to come to an estimate of (the so-called
real interest rates; that is to say, an interest rate adjusted downward
for inflationary anticipations.
However, I believe that the extent of inflationary anticipations in
our present structure is very minor in comparison with the dif-
ferences between the Government bond rate and the yield of capital
in the private economy, and, to put it another way, very minor in
comparison with the weight of the tax adjustments that the Comp-
troller General's report and my own statement consider to be the
major component of the difference.
Chairman Paoxi~rnu~. Very minor, but is it sufficient, conceivably,
to justify 4% percent as an absolute minimum estimate of the rate for
so-called risk-free social opportunity costs?
Mr. HARBERGER. I would say that 4% percent is lower than what I
would call the wbsolute minimum; therefore, even more of an absolute
minimum.
Mr. EOE5TEIN. Whatever the reasons may be, Senator, the interest
rate structure is higher. The interest rate is a price by which the
economy operates. So private investment decisions are made on the
PAGENO="0075"
71
basis of higher interest rates. As a result, the returns required for
the productive investments in the private sector must substantially
exceed the actual interest rate, not a price-corrected interest rate.
It may well be, for example, if you evaluate a human investment
project, that you would have to include a realistic wage projection
into those future earnings `and not just a productivity projection.
Chairman PRoxMIiu~. r1~his is a matter of accurately computing your
benefits, really?
Mr. EOKSTEIN. So there is a question of symmetry. You cannot as-
sume one thing on the cost side and another thing on the benefit side.
You only really confuse the planning process by creating a syn-
thetic situation on the cost side. The fact of the matter is that the
interest rates in this country are an important element in resource allo-
cation, and the interest rates, whatever their reason, are far more
than 4%.
Chairman PRoxMinE. But the argument by Mr. Caulfield is that we
are in a period which, `as you defined in your paper, is much more in-
flationary now than it was in the period 1960-65. The idea was to avoid
rapid ups ~and downs and, therefore, we `should look to a more stable
period which presumably we could return to, rather than this tem-
porary period now that we are in, when you are making investments
over a period of many, many years.
Mr. EOKSTEIN. That is a long-term judgmental question about the
outlook on interest rates. I have looked into that question some and
this is my judgment on it: The interest rate structure moved up about
2.1 percent from the plateau of the early sixties to the peak of a few
months ago. The question is: How far will these interest rates recede
toward that plateau when Vietnam is over, now that the Federal Gov-
ernment financing is straightened out? It is my judgment, which may
be quite wrong, but it is my judgment that the interest rates will re-
cede by perhaps as much as 75 basis points, or three-quarters of a
percent. The Government bonds have already receded 50 basis points
because of the dramatic change in the Federal financing needs.
So I would think it would be a mistake to give a very heavy weight
to the average of the early 1960's, when unemployment was 5.5 per-
cent. After all, we are not going to settle for that over the next 10
years as an average. It also did assume that industrial prices were
absolutely stable, which does not seem to be in the cards right away,
either.
So I do not recommend that we base the interest rate computation
on the very peak wartime rates of December 1967 and briefly in
May of 1968. That would not be reasonable.
But I do not think one can justify a large further decline in the
assumption about the interest rate from the present levels. You could
argue for a fall of another quarter of a percent or half a percent as
wartime circumstances and the current inflation. But that seems to me
what the most prudent man would project.
Chairman PRoxMnu~. Now, on the assumption, then, that we arrive
at a different kind, or at least a different figure for the so-called risk-
free social opportunity cost of capital, not 4%, but some other figure,
assuming you build on that, it would still seem to me to be necessary
to use some kind of explicit adjustment of benefit and cost streams
to allow for the risk and uncertainty that is in these projects, because,
PAGENO="0076"
72
of course, we know that none of the Government investments are
absolutely risk free, and many of them are quite risky.
Could you gentlemen describe the procedures by which Govern-
ment analysts could make these explicit allowances for risk and un-
certainty in benefit-cost streams?
I take it you have to do that-at least Mr. Harberger does-
because Mr. Harberger made the assertion, as I recall, that we should
have a single discount rate for all projects. If you do that, obviously,
you are assuming that they all have the same risk or that you are
building that into your benefit and cost systems in arriving at the
figure.
Mr. HARBERGER. Yes.
Chairman PROXMIRE. How do you do it?
Mr. HARBERGER. I think it is possible, and probably the most feasi-
ble way to deal with the problem is to try to identify the considera-
tions governing the risk premia that prevail in the private sector of
the economy. We have some excellent studies which show that the risk
premia on corporate bonds in the private sector can be fairly. closely
predicted on the basis of such items as the debt-equity ratio of the
corporation and the varia~bility of the earnings of the corporation and
the general financial stability of the corporation. What we need t.o do
is try to get counterparts of these, to say for a particular Government
investment, whether it is like a public utility investment in terms of its
underlying riskiness, or whether it is like a uranium prospecting in-
vestment. Then we can make an appropriate risk adjustment for each
particular pro~ject.
An alternative would be to make a sort of standard risk premium
for all Government investments on the ground that the Government
has a widely diversified portfolio, and to sort of incorporate, let us
say, the average risk premium on all private investments on top of
Government risk-free rate in order to arrive at the rate of discount
to be used to evaluate Government projects.
Chairman PROXMIRE. You see, so much of this Government activity
is different than our experience in the private sector. For example,
how do you determine the risk element in providing Federal scholar-
ships for higher education, for instance? Here is something where
we think a rate of return is higli, but we can provide so many that
maybe we get to a point where we decide that it is not wise to invest
more in that field but in seine other field on the one hand.
Headstart is another example where it seems to me it would be very
hard to compute the risk factor. Eveii the water resources programs,
where you have tremendous technological developments in saline
research on the one hand and atomic research on the other.
What do you do about this kind of thing? Can you really arrive
at a figure, or do you have to take some kind of overall judgment and
just apply it?
Mr. HARBERGER. I suspect that at the moment the latter would be
the course of prudence. Practically speakmg, I would say if the Gov-
ernment were to move from present practice to simply incorporating
a risk-free rate in all its decisions and not making any allowance for
risk, there would be a tremendous improvement in the picture. It would
be still better to use an appropriately calculated risk-free opportunity
cost plus a general blanket across-the-board allowance for nsk in the
PAGENO="0077"
73
discount rate itself, without making a separate risk allowance for each
project or program. A third and still better, approach would be to try
to identify especially risky Government investments, investments of
medium risk, and investments of demonstrably low risk and to make
separate risk adjustments for each of these three categories. If we
could simply identify investments in those three classes and have a
higher than average discount rate for those that bear the earmarks of
being highly speculative and a lower than average discount rate for
those of types with assured histories of proven payoffs, we would be
doing a decent job, although obviously not the best conceivable job.
Chairman PRoxMnu~. Dr. Eckstein, how would you handle this?
Mr. EOKSTEIN. I do not think you can put it all into the interest
rate. If you think of investments in technologies, which after all, are
a good deal of Government expenditure these days, there you ought
to be very conservative, so you ought to assume a short economic life
or be conservative in other aspects of the computation. I do not think
you can put all of that-you ought to insist on a high interest rate as
any reasonable enterprise would.
If you look at human investments, evaluating Headstart if you
could do it by this method, that kind of program, which have, on the
other hand, a lifetime payoff, again I do not see how you can weigh
risk properly by putting in the interest rate.
We know these are high risk investments. We know there are great
social rewards, savings in social cost later on. I do not see how you
can-I do not think it makes any sense even in these areas to put in
an arbitrarily low interest rate which is just; an arbitrary way of
muddling the computation. You ought to use a rate of the sort we
have been talking about even in those areas, but I would not-
Chairman PROXMIRE. If you do not do it with the interest rate, how
do you arrive at risk? Usually we do adjust the risk through interest
rate. This is-
Mr. EOKSTEIN. Let us take Job Corps, which is not the most difficult
of these to evaluate. The benefit of Job Corps is the expected increase
in lifetime income of the trainees compared to the income they would
have gotten if they had not gone to Job Corps.
There is a probabilistic matter and the analysis as conducted is
probabilistic. Some percentage of these youngsters will get better jobs.
Some percentage will not. Some percentage will drop out in the first
few months with no visible benefit.
I would put the risk adjustment conservatively into a realistic as-
sessment of these probabilities and a realistic assessment of the in-
creases of income-things of that sort.
In the water area, and the general hardware area, roads, things of
that sort, I think you can use a risk premium approach. If you start
out with a pure interest rate, something like the Government bond
rate, then you ought to add a percent or two because that is what you
would be earning in the private sector for that kind of investment.
That is the risk premium that prevails in the telephone company, the
electric power companies. That is the kind of investment it is.
Chairman PROXMTRE. You say in your statement, Dr. Eckstein, the
Soviet Republic, U.S.S.R., now uses a 10-percent discount by and large.
Mr. EOKSTEIN. Yes.
PAGENO="0078"
74
Chairman PROXMIRE. And, you deplore the fact they used a zero
rate when Stalin was in charge and there was a terrific misallocation
of resources and waste. You apparently feel this is much better.
Do you feel that that 10 percent can teach us a lesson that we ought to
be around 10 percent, too? Is this 10 percent arrived at through pretty
careful and thoughtful and effective calculation or is it wrong?
Mr. ECKSTEIN. Well, I have no way of assessing the Russian situa-
tion in detail. We can see in the Russian case what happens if an econ-
omy embraces this principle broadly of having no interest rate at all.
The 10 percent rate is used now. Of course, they do not call it interest
rate even now, but the computation really amounts to that. That is what
they are doing and it is a drastic change of policy.
Chairman PROXMIRE. That is an excellent case study that had not oc-
curred to me. I have heard nobody else use it and it is a good example
of how wasteful it is if you have either a zero or excessively low dis-
count factor. As you say, we can do some things like grow bananas on
Pikes Peak. You can justify any kind of water investment if you ram
your discount rate low enough.
Mr. ECKSTEIN. Because you simply are not charging yourself for
the cost of capital. Nowadays the Soviet Union has come so far as th
use "cost of capital." Interest is forbidden by Karl Marx but they do
now use something they call the cost of capital. Now, whether-I
should also add that for lighter investment they use figures as high as
20 and 30 percent.
Chairman PRox3rnu~. I take it, from your earlier remarks that all of
your testimony this morning, particularly with regard to the arriving
at something like a 7- to 10-percent discount factor, is on the assumption
that we have, if not full employment, high-level employment and un-
employment around 4 percent. In other words, if we had a recession,
depression, if we had much idle resources, you would have a much lower
discount factor because you would have some adjustment, you would
not be taking resources from the private sector by and large. You
would be putting to work resources that would otherwise be idle; is
that correct?
Mr. ECKSTEIN. Yes, although even under those conditions you might
have a backlog of good projects with high returns that you might not
have to dip that low into low return projects even in a recession. Still
on strict economic calculation, the opportunity cost of capital falls
sharply as recession deepens into depression.
Chairman Pnox~rnu~. You would apply, however, this figure that
you have suggested, and so would Dr. Harberger, I take it, as long as the
unemployment rates are, say, between 3 and 5 percent.
Mr. HARBERGER. I think, Mr. Chairman, that when we get into a
situation of unemployment, there are really two things that happen.
Chairman Pnoxa~riim. Well, unemployment is a very broad index of
the whole economy.
Mr. HARBERGER. Right.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Obviously, if we have that we have plants op-
erat.ing at 80 percent of capacity, if we have, say, 5 percent of unem-
ployment, but assuming there is a correspondence and you have iden-
tical capacity.
Mr. HARBERGER. When we start out with a situation in which these
are unemployed resources of various types, we can incorporate into
PAGENO="0079"
75
the benefits of particular projects the benefit that they have in absorb-
ing unemployment and still use a high discount rate. The inclusion of
the extra benefit arising from the employment of unemployed resources
would improve the prospects of a project being approved.
Now, the second thing that happens is, as Professor Eckstein pointed
out, in times of recession and depression, the general level of market
rates goes down. But, that fall in market rates is not a fall which
carries over the entire life of a project, 20-, 30-, 50-year project, and the
appropriate way of taking into account that fall is to lower the dis-
count rate for the immediate years but not to lower it for all of the
later years.
Quite a complex analysis is involved in this sort of thing, but in
general when you are dealing with a short-range phenomenon of un-
employment, you allow it to create extra benefits if your project is
employing unemployed resources. Similarly, if your short-range
phenomenon is a drop in general market level of interest rates, you
allow that to infiuence~ your use of capital in the immediate future.
But if the capital that you put into a project is going to be tied up
for 20 or 50 years, you do not want to allow the short-term phenomenon
of a low-interest rate to influence your discounting over the entire life
of the project. Just the discounting corresponding to the years during
which this low-interest rate is expected to prevail.
Chairman PRoxMIinl. Do you want to comment?
Mr. ECKSTEIN. Well, I should add one footnote to that, though.
Even if it is a long-lived project, if it is built during the recession,
it is being built when the capital has little opportunity cost. The answer
to your question, is, "Yes"; we are thinking in the:3- to 5-percent range.
Chairman PR0xMIRE. Most of these projects, these water projects
and others, take a number of years to build. They are not built in a
year or 6 months. You cannot say that we have either a situation of,
say, shortage of labor resources available or shortage of capital re-
sources available on the one hand, or say that we have excessive unem-
ployment because under the Employment Act, under~ our experiences
that we have had under it, the progress we have made, I would agree~
with you that we are not going to have five and a half percent unem-
ployment, that no party could stand it, and we recognize we cannot
stand it.
One of the members of this committee has written to me protesting
very strongly about changing the discount approach to water projects.
One of the arguments that this man makes is that in the present cal-
culations of benefits, we overlook the increased profits of the business-
men who are operating in the area and that this is an oversight and
this is one of the reasons why he says you can justify a lower discount
rate.
No. 1, is this a fact, that we do overlook profits consistently?
No. 2, should we include them? Is this justification for a lower
discount rate?
Mr. EOKSTEIN. Well, historically we did count stemming benefits
which are the profits of processors and we counted induced benefits
which are the profits of the people selling to the farm. I had not been
aware that the progress on reforming benefit-cost standards had
reached the point where we no longer counted these kinds of benefits
but I could-
PAGENO="0080"
76
Chairman PROXMIRE. Do you count this as progress?
Mr. EOKSTEIN. In a sense-this is another set of issues. You cannot
answer that, all the capital that goes into processing industries would
have been idle. It would have earned some other return.
Chairman PRox~1IRE. Are you also saying perhaps the business that
would go to the people in a particular State, say in Wisconsin, because
we have a. new water project, might come from business in another
State, so that increased profits for the people in Wisconsin might be
decreased profits for the people in Minnesota or Illinois or something
like that?
Mr. EOKSTEIN. Yes. It is very difficult to show that locating this
activity near this project is all additional activity, or additional em-
ployment, or additional profits.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Suppose you can show that it is. Suppose you
can show it is something new. To the extent that it is would you then
say the profit should be recognized as part of the benefits?
Mr. EOKSTEIN. Yes. Then, you could compute the benefits of that
original-
Chairman PRox~rnt~. It is your understanding they are.
Mr. EOKSTEIN. I have not attempted to follow it in the last year or
two, but it was my understanding that there was still some counting
of it.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Mr. Tilarberger?
Mr. HARBERGER. Mr. Chairman, I think there is a sort of a standard
approach to this in the theoretical literature which runs essentially as
follows: Suppose that a power dam is built, and that as a consequence
of that dam there arises in the neighborhood an industrial complex,
which means a lot of investment, a lot of employment, and a lot of
income generated. Let us suppose that investment in general in the
economy has a yield of 10 percent. If investment in a particular plant
near this power dam has a yield of 15 rather than 10, the extra 5 can
be attributed to the powerplant but not the whole 15. And by the same
token, if labor resources locate themselves near the dam, and in those
industries they earn $4 an hour, where in alternative opportunities in
the economy they would earn $3, you can attribute the benefits of the
extra dollar an hour to the project, but you cannot attribute the
whole $4 an hour.
Chairman PROXMIRE. I would like to ask you gentleman now about
something that has troubled me very, very much and see if there is
any rationale at all in the economic profession or on economic theory
grounds for the discrepancy we now have in our Federal agencies in
applying discount factors.
The Comptroller Generai's report, with which I am sure you are
familiar, showed the variation which grows from 3 percent, in fact,
zero in some cases, a few, not many, but 3 is not uncommon and three
and an eighth as we know is common, three and a quarter, three and
an. eighth, for the big public works investment, all the way up to-
well, it is 10 percent for much of the Defense Department which repre-
sents a very large part of our total investment, and it goes up to 15
percent in some cases. In the Interior Department itself it varies from
3.1 to 12 percent.
Is there any justification for this variety? Would it be proper for
the Congress to insist on a uniform discount rate for all agencies with-
PAGENO="0081"
77
out exception but with the instructions, of course, to provide for appro-
priate cost and benefits to adjust to the fact that you have this?
Mr. EOKSTEIN. It would be proper for the Congress to instruct the
executive branch in that way. Perhaps it should be a minimum, because
in the technology areas you probably should use higher rates You
should make some
Chairman PROXMIRE Oh, I see Then, you say there should be a
floor.
Mr. EOKSTEIN. Yes.
Chairman PRoxMnm. And that floor would be 7 to 8 percent, in your
view-
Mr. ECKSTEIN. Yes. Then the technology areas-
Chairman PRoxMnu~ (continuing). Ten percent in Mr. Harberger's
view, and then you have some of these programs which represent a
high degree of technology Let us see One of the programs here is
radiation pasteurization, for example, Atomic Energy Commission.
Industry benefits, 15 percent. I do not kno.w whether-that is what
they apply now which is above what you recommend. I take it, you
would not say they should come down.
Mr Harberger~
Mr. HARBERGER. I think, Senator, the idea of a uniform discount
rate for all Federal agencies has a great appeal and it is an idea that
can be sold I think that talking about, let us say, the whole problem
of adjusting for risk is an extremely difficult one, and that the only
basis on which one could argue for differential interest rates would be
on grounds of risk When you get to the question of risk, it is obviously
not an agency-to-agency phenomenon so much as a project-to-project
phenomenon, so even taking risk into consideration does not give you
much of a basis for saying one agency should have a different discount
rate than another agency.
My own preference would be to set upon a single risk-free discount
rate, and then to say that agencies and the Bureau of the Budget
should make appropriate allowance for risk in all of their projects and
activities. The allowance that they make for risk may consist of raising
the discount rate in certain cases above the risk-free one, but it may
also consist in shading the benefits or possibility making spccial upwai d
adjustment of costs.
Chairman PROXMIRE. That is our difficulty. There is so much political
incentive involved here and political power involved that the more
exceptions you make, in some cases you say you can raise the discount
rates and in other eases you can shade the benefits, unless you have
pretty firm and explicit guidelines, unless you are going to arrive at
a fairly consistent discount rate it is going to be very hard to break
this bad habit. You know how hard it is to change a situation in Gov-
ernment as it is when you have vested power involved as you have in
this case. Men of great influence in the Senate are going to fight to the
death on this. There could be a filibuster if we ever succeed in bringing
a bill to the floor. It is going to be very, very hard to achieve this kind
of reform in any event.
Mr. HARBERGER. I think if you. operate with a risk-free discount
rate of 8 percent, the options there are only one way. You either penal-
ize a risky project by using a 9- or 10-percent rate, or you penalize
98-940 O-68-6
PAGENO="0082"
78
it by being extra conservative in the estimation of benefits and some-
what inflating your costs as a contingency factor.
All of these operate against the project. The oniy options anybody
has is to be more conservative or more demanding, if you like, than
an 8-percent risk-free rate would dictate.
Chairman PROXMIRE. I would like to ask you, Mr. Eckstein-as a for-
mer insider in the Government-I would like to ask your opinion on
how you would proceed in achieving consistent interest rate policies in
Federal agencies.
For example, should some Federal office undertake a study to develop
a methodology for estimating the social opportunity cost of capital?
Should some agency calculate this rate on an ongoing basis to be used
by all agencies as a basic risk-free rate? If so, who should do it?
Mr. ECKSTEIN. I think it could be done, and should be done, by an
agency which has an economic, scientific-economic research capability.
It should be an agency which has no immediate stake in the outcome,
which suggests a number of candidates. One possibility, of course, is
the Council of Economic Advisers, although they are rather heavily
occupied as it is. It could be the Office of Business Economics in the
Department of Commerce. It could conceivably be the Federal Re-
serve System, although that might get into a question of the proper
role of the Federal Reserve within the Government. It could be the
Bureau of Labor Statistics. They have capable economists who could
do it.
Chairman PROXMIRE. How about the Bureau of the Budget?
Mr. EcKs~IN. The Bureau of the Budget could do it and I suppose
it could be part of the standards that they set down.
Chairman PROXMIRE. They have the power.
Mr. ECKSTEIN. They could also make it stick. I would think that
any effort of this type would have to be under Bureau of the Budget
sponsorship. It is then really a personality question as much as any-
thing else, whether the rate will command a greater respect in the
Government if it is done inside the Bureau or by somebody, some
economists' shop somewhat removed from the Bureau.
There is also a question whether such a study should have some
panel of outsiders to get it as far removed from bureaucratic struggles
as possible.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Well, I think if we are going to make progress
in this area, and I hope and pray we are, I `think the testimony we
have had from you gentlemen and from the Comptroller General
and others has been most helpful, but if we are going to do it we are
going to have to have a far greater concern by the economic profession,
that they recognize the wisdom of this kind of thing and maybe one
way of getting at it should be ~ realization of what we do when we
act as we have acted to cut expenditures this time. Many economists
opposed that action. I happened to vote for it and supported it as did,
of course, the majority of the Members of the House and Senate. We
did it in a blind, overall way. The President may exert greater wis-
dom in exercising his discrimination, but we do not have a basis for
determining priorities and it seems to me, here we begin to get them
through this and development of PPB. We at least have some kind
of a framework on which, when we have to reduce expenditures, and
we hope in the future we are going to be in a position with an expand-
PAGENO="0083"
79
ing economy where we have this happier problem than the reverse,
that we can make the decision rationally.
Do you not feel that this is going to take much greater concern by
the economic profession and then hopefully, by the public? There is
a tremendous political force, of course, for keeping Government ex-
penditures under control. We know it has happened in the last couple
of years, how enormously they have increased. We know that Dr.
Schultze, when I asked him, said the end of the Vietnam war is not
going to mean much of a cutback in defense expenditures. Nitze, when
he testified before the Senate Appropriations Committee, said he
thought we would have a budget of $75 million for defense after the
Vietnam war is over. We have $82 million now, so not much of a saving
is anticipated.
Under these circumstances and with the terrific problem of the
cities and all the other demands that we are going to have that are now
built in, we must continue and must expand. Unless we get something
of this kind, it seems to me, that we are going to have the same pres-
sure for keeping spending down but it is going to be much less
rational. We are going to get a serious dissipation of the investment
we should bring to bear in the areas where we should bring it to bear.
Mr. Harberger?
Mr. HARBERGER. Mr. Chairman, let me try to explain the apparent
apathy of my colleagues. I think that Professor Eckstein and I are
sort of quixotic in the interests and energies that we have put into
the improvement of criteria for evaluation of public sector actions.
When you actually think about how one could raise money in this
country and improve economic efficiency, we first have the agriculture
program under which, for the last several years, we have spent about
$4 or $5 billion a year to take land out of cultivation, while with the
other hand the Government is spending money on irrigation dams to
bring land into cultivation. It does not take an economist to see that
these two operations are working at cross purposes and one could save
money on both sides and have the same amount of effectively cultivated
acreage as we have now.
You look at the supr program which is not only highly costly in
terms of money, but is also highly costly in terms of total consumer
welfare in the United States. The cost of this program to the economy
as a whole has been estimated as high as $500 million a year.
You look at the oil depletion problem and the possibility of saving
Federal money or raising further Federal money by a more rational
approach to that.
These are things that are counted in the billions of dollars. Some
of my colleagues look at the sort of thing I do and accuse me of nit-
picking on the corners, trying to solve the last details of appropriate
interest-rate policy or to expTlore the last nuances of the criteria by
which we should measure benefits and costs. What about the big
issues. If we cannot get people to recognize the wastes that are
involved in so many obvious cases in our Federal spending pattern,
how can we ever expect to get people down to the point where they
are going to recognize the comparatively smaller differences about
which this sort of analysis is concerned?
Chairman PROXMIRE. Now, we are talking about the biggest kind
of investment. Dr. Eckstein and you, too, Dr. Harberger, have referred
PAGENO="0084"
80
to how this can apply not just to water projects, not just to the
big public woi'ks projects, but it can apply across the board to a great
deal, not all, obviously, but a great deal, of public expenditures, and
that it can give us a much more objective criteria, at least, on the
basis of which we exercise our value judgments. We `are not going
to be bound by this, not going to say we will never violate it but
at least we will know what we are doing. We would not deceive our-
selves by providing a discount rate that provides a benefit-cost ratio
that is completely false. Because there is so much money involved and
the people do not like to pay taxes and because taxes in the view of
many people are already high, it would seem to me that we can sum-
mon a great deal of political support for a more rational approach
once we can get the idea so that the economic profession espouses it
and then the public picks it up.
Wherever I have had a chance to talk with people in my State, I
found great support for this. But I am `just wondering if the economics
profession cannot do more with it.
Mr. EOKSTEIN. Mr. Chairman, the academic community can feel
guilty on many scores and many issues where they were late rather
than leading, but in this area I do not think we need to plead guilty.
I think the basically correct answers have been developed over the
last 15 years and have been available for at least 10 and it has just
taken this long for the needs to become understood in the Govern-
ment, `and here in the Congress.
To me it is a source of great pleasure `that a congressional committee
would devote itself to this apparently obscure technical subject which
in fact, is a very fundamental subject and guides our public-the
interest rate does guide the pattern of public investment. So, I wish
you well. [Laughter.] And I think if we can make progress on this
at last, I think that is the way I have to put it, if at last we can make
progress on this, we will have helped set the stage in a small way
toward a more effective public effort in all our social programs.
Chairman PROXMIRE. You see, one of the difficulties is there is a
tendency in some administrations, some a little more than others, not
to reveal all the facts, not to give all the inform'ation and not to keep
Congress `as well informed as possible. After all, knowledge is power.
When you know the score you are in a much better position, much more
powerful posi'tion, to act than when you do not and I think that if
administrations in the future will do their best to take the initiative in
informing Congress on what PPB leads to, what it spells out, what
these things can do in `arriving at more rational decisions, then I think
we can begin to make progress.
* Let me just ask one more quick question. That was a rollcall, so I
cannot detain you very long.
What assumption, if any, do you make, Mr. Harberger, with regard
to monetary policy in your calculations about displacement of the
private investment by Government investment and borrowing? Do you
just assume monetary policy is fixed and established and will not vary?
Obviously you could adjust monetary policy, could you not, to permit a
greater rate of investment and then not displace, at least in the borrow-
ing area, not displace private capital.
Mr. HAlunutolut. I assume that within the context of the tax-fiscal
system which is preva.i ii ng at a given moment in time, that monetary
PAGENO="0085"
81
policy operates to keep us from getting into a serious recession. In
the background of my analysis is an active monetary policy aimed at
preventing recession and inflation.
Chairman PROXMIRE. I guess that was the only other question I had,
and I want to thank both you gentlemen for a superlative job. This is
most helpful, much more so than I tl1ink you know. I know how you
feel about these 15 years, Dr. Eckstein and Mr. Harberger, in which
this has been known. We have moved like molasses in the winter, but
I think we are beginning to understand this now and to make more
progress on it. Certainly I am going to fight hard to get this committee
to make as vigorous a recommendation as possible.
I would appreciate it if you gentleman would expand your remarks
in any way you would like, if you wish to do so, when you review your
transcripts for the record. We will send a few questions, perhaps, to
supplement this at the time that you get your transcript for correction.
The subcommittee will stand in recess until tomorrow morning at 10
o'clock. We will meet in this room.
(Whereupon, at 11 :50 a.m., the hearing was recessed, to reconvene
at 10 a.m., Thursday, August 1, 1968.)
(The following material accompanied Dr. Eckstein's statement:)
Chapter IV. The Social Cost of Federal Financing from "Multiple
Purpose River Development," Studies in Applied Economic Analysis,
by John V. Krutilla and Otto Eckstein; published for Resources for
the Future, Inc., by The Johns Hopkins Press, Baltimore, Md., 1958.
PAGENO="0086"
82
iv The Social Cost
of Federal Financing
We have seen how the interest rate in the competitive model serves
as a price in the capital market bringing the savings preferences
of consumers into consistency with the investment plans of business
enterprises Let us now extend the examination to investment
undertaken by government
Most of the activities of government are devoted to satisfying
collective wants, wants which cannot be met through goods and
services sold in the market place. Whenever the ballot box and
the political process replace market choice, investment decisions
will not be made by comparing the rate of return of investments
with the market rate of interest.1 Many of the collective goods
produced by public investments are valued qualitatively, preclud-
ing computations of the rates of return which underlie private
investment decisions. The costs are more specific, however;
resources employed in a public undertaking have alternative uses
* in the production of marketable commodities and will; therefore,
have a price which measures their opportunity cost.
* This cost cannot be measured directly from the borrowing cost,
since the funds are raised by taxation, but within the competitive
Some goods, such as electric power, supplied by government are marketable;
others, such as flood control, though nonmarketable, can be valued at prices
established in related markets. Yet the fact that the investment decision is made
in a political context results in the introduction of other considerations and
makes it unlikely that the decision will be made in accordance with the eco*
nomic principle alone.
PAGENO="0087"
83
model the social cost can easily be imputed. An* analysis based
upon the competitive model would go like this: The cost of capital
is measured by the interest rate. Insofar as the necessary taxes
reduce marginal investments of firms, they prevent the creation of
a stream of returns whose relationship to the foregone investment
would have been just equal to the interest rate. Similarly, taxes
which fall on consumption reduce the present levels of consumption
for which people are willing to pass up the opportunity of collect-
ing the market rate of interest. In other words, the consumer
places the same value on the expenditure of the marginal consump-
tion dollar as on a perpetual income stream equal to the interest
rate. Thus, if government desires to place an economic value on
the cost of raising capital through taxation, it can simply apply
the market rate of interest.2
* Unfortunately, the American economy does not fit .the competi-
tive model closely enough to permit use of so simple a procedure.
The substantial risk premiums in the terms on which business can
borrow, and the rationing of credit to some businesses and to most
consumers, preclude the existence of a unique rate of interest and
prevent consideration of any single actual rate as a measure of
the social cost of capital. Yet, in considering alternative methods
of financing water resource development and in evaluating the
economic worth of projects, reasonable estimates of the social cost
* of federal funds are essential. Since the market cannot be consulted
* for the price of capital, as competitive theory would suggest, it is
necessary to derive an estimate by more complicated empirical
* procedures which take account of some of the complexities of the
process by which savings are actually channeled into investment.
That is the task undertaken in this chapter. First, as background
* *`for our inquiry, we shall examine the salient facts about saving and
..borrowing in the United States in a recent year. Then, through
the use of models, we shall attempt to derive a figure that can serve
as a measure of the social cost of public funds used in development
of water resources. *
* This assumes: that the taxes are raised without causing any distortion in
decision-making. If there are tax-induced distortions in the economy's alloca-
tion of resources, the true social cost of raising capital by taxation will be
greater than the market rate of interest.
PAGENO="0088"
84
Saving and Investment in the United States
Before turning to our methods of estimation, let us take a quick
look at some rather rough, but revealing, figures about the capital
formation of the United States in the year 1955, which will serve
as a background for the analysis. Table 3 indicates the total gross
investment of the major sectors 9f the economy, defined somewhat
more broadly than in the standard national income accounts-
though even the set of categories used here misses large amounts of
investment by government. The startlingly large figure for house-
holds, $52 .billion, is offset to a significant degree by the deprecia-
tion of "durables" which last only a relatively few years, and
TABLE 3. Gross Capital Formation in the United States, 1955
Sector ($ billion)
Households:
Residential construction 17
Automobiles 17
Other durables 18 52
Corporate business:
Plant and equipment expenditures 25
Inventory investment 4
Other 1 30
Unincorporated business:
Plant and equipment expenditures 4 4
Farms:
Construction and equipment 4 4
Government:
Federal construction 3
State and lOcal construction 9 12
Total 102
similarly for some of the other items. Yet it is clear that much
investment occurs outside the business sectors; in fact each sector
plays a significant part in the process of capital formation.
In the financing of these investments, there are significant depar-
PAGENO="0089"
85
tures from Chapter Il's idealized picture, in which we assumed the
savings of individuals to be the source of capital, with investors
paying the market rate of interest on the requisite loans.3 House-
holds financed their purchases of automobiles in large part through
installment credit, with the total outstanding increasing $4 billion.
over the year, an amount which is about half the net investment
in cars after depreciation. About $15 billion of $17 billion of
residential construction was offset by an increase in mortgages,4
but the $18 billion of other durables was financed out of income
for the sector as a whole. The Department of Commerce reports
total personal saving to be $17 billion, but this figure does not
reflect the borrowing done by households in the form of mortgages.
If we subtract money borrowed in this way, we find that net per-
sonal saving is at most $2 billion or $3 billion. That is, the house-
hold sector-which in our theoretical model was to provide the
savings for the business sector-actually saved little more than it
invested in its own durables.
Of the $30 billion of real investment carried on by corporations,
$15 billion came from depreciation and amortization allowances
and another $9 billion from retained earnings. Only the remaining
$6 billion was financed by new securities-$2 billion in common
stocks and $4 billion in bonds and notes. And of this total, public
utilities issued all but $400 million of the stock and $2 billion of
the bonds and notes. There was also an increase of bank loans of
$4.5 billion, and an increase o~ other liabilities of $1.5 billion, but
this was more than offset by the increase in customer receivables.
Thus the business sector as a whole, other than public utilities,
borrowed no more than 8 or 10 per cent of the funds for its real
investment.
Unincorporated business, which is typically small, and for which
our figures are much more sketchy, invested about $4 billion in
plant and equipment. Much of the investment of this sector, which
consists primarily of retail and other service establishments, con-
sisted of the construction and improvement of stores, which were
financed largely by mortgages and bank loans. But the sector as a
whole withdrew relatively little from the capital market; repay.
`See W. A. Salant, "Saving, Investment, and Stability," American Economic
Review, May 1956, pp. 42-54.
4This figure includes mortgages issued on old houses.
PAGENO="0090"
86
ments of old loans and mortgages roughly offset new ones.
The picture in agriculture is quite~ similar; $4 billion of con-
struction and agricultural implements was financed principally
through bank loans and mortgages, but the repayments of other
farmers were at least equal to the borrowing.
Finally, $12 billion of construction was carried on by govern.
ment. The $9 billion share of state and local government led to
the issuance of $5 billion of new securities, but surpluses run by
* : other state and local bodies reduced the net deficit of the sector to
* $1.5 billion. The federal government invested at least $3 billion
in construction, a figure which omits much military work, but this
* . was entirely financed out of taxes, and there was a net cash surplus
of $2.7 billion for the year. Foreign investment for the year was
negative, with repayments exceeding new investments by $300
million.
It can be seen from these figures that the net borrowing of. the
various sectors is less than 10 per cent of the total capital formation
for~ the economy as a whole. This is significant. On both the lend-
ing and borrowing side of the capital market we need to take a
second look at the factors that~ determine the level of investment
and of saving for each group of decision-makers.
The significance of the small amount of net borrowing or lending
of the sectors depends, in part, on the degree to which the lenders
provide funds for the borrowers within the same sector. To some
extent, there is a common capital market for all sectors, in which
some personal, business, and government savings are commingled
through the activities of financial intermediary institutions. But,
at least in the case of the household sector, we find the capital
flows primarily within the sector. Of the $15 billion of mortgages,
savings and loan associations acquired $5.4 billion; life insurance
companies, $3 billion; mutual savings banks, $2.4 billion; indi-
viduals, $2.4 billion; and commercial banks, $1.7 billion. All but
the last of these sources administer the savings of individuals and,
even in the latter category, much of the money available for mort-
gages springs out of individuals' time deposits. As for the $5
billion of installment and other credit, the household credit cor-
porations which handle the largest part of this paper raise their
own funds by sale of their notes to insurance companies and other
financial intermediaries who draw the bulk of their funds from
individual savings.
PAGENO="0091"
87
For the other sectors, the case is not so clear. Corporate securities
draw on a wide variety of sources. Unincorporated business is
financed in part by bank loans-which, to a considerable extent
represent money created by the banking system-and in part by
loans from individuals who are willing either to invest in the
business or to lend the owner money because of ties of friendship
or family. The securities of state and local governments, because
of their tax.exempt feature, are particularly attractive to individuals
with very large incomes, and thus can be assumed to draw on indi-
vidual savings. Capital for agriculture is supplied in the form of
mortgages by banks and insurance companies and in the form of
* loans by. commercial banks.
Interest Rates in the American Economy
There is no one interest rate-capital is offered on a very wide
range of terms. Bonds, notes, and other debt instruments of
~:~governments and corporations find a ready market at rates ranging
from 2 to 5 per cent, depending on the terms of the loan and the
credit standing of. the issuer. Mortgages of good quality are
financed at rates between ~`/2 and 6 per cent, though this rate is kept
lo~ by~ government guarantees of a large part of the total. Other
consumer credit is expensive ranging from 5 to over 25 per cent,
I. with the typical automobile, installment loan held by a large
credit company costing 9 to 12 per cent. Yet the sales finance
companies are able to raise their funds at rates below 4 per cent.
The difference between their lending and borrowing rates is
explained by the high cost of administration and collection, the
pooling of many small, risky loans to reduce risk, and substantial
profits. Bank loans to corporations and unincorporated business
may cost from 3 to 6 per cent, depending on size, the region of
the country, and the credit standing of the borrower, but their
availability is strictly rationed to each firm. Loans to agriculture,
while only slightly more expensive, are even more severely rationed
* to each farmer. Most personal saving, in the form of savings
accounts, insurance, and pensions, receives a return of 3 per cent or
so, with investments in , stocks the only substantial excep-
tion. `And stock ownership is still restricted to a relatively small
PAGENO="0092"
88
proportion of savers, who receive an income yield of only 4 per
cent, but who have been receiving large capital gains.
Measuring the Social Cost of Public Capital:
The Method of this Study
The task of discovering the true social cost of the capital devoted
to water resource development under actual conditions is much
more difficult than if our theoretical model applied in a straight-
forward way. The model determines one interest rate for each
period, a rate which indicates both the opportunity cost of capital
in other fields, and the rate at which consumers are willing to give
up present income for a future income stream. In reality, there are
many interest rates for both borrowers and lenders, and we are not
free to fasten upon any one of them for our purpose. Yet the
sound formulation of public policy requires some clear idea about
this social cost. Use of a rate which is much too low may result in
the waste of the nation's capital in a project yielding less satisfac-
tion to consumers than if left in its alternative use. Use of an
excessively high rate will leave water resources underdeveloped as
compared to other resources in the nation's economy. For the
typical problem of financing public investment by taxation, we,
therefore, need to derive an appropriate estimate for the social
cost of capital.
Our method will take account of the actual structure of capital
flows in the United States. First, we shall try to determine where
the tax money that provides the capital used for federal resource
development actually comes from-that is, the incidence of the
marginal tax dollars. This requires quantitative study of the
revenues produced by different taxes, the persons and organizations
who pay these taxes, and the extent to which taxpayers are able to
shift their tax liabilities to others. It also requires that we assume
in what proportion the various taxes would be increased were the
program to be expanded, or which ones would be cut in the
event of contraction. Once we know the sources of the money,
we can proceed to the second stage and estimate what value attaches
to these funds in their alternative uses.
When government imposes taxes in order to finance public
investments, it levies a compulsory loan or forced saving on the
PAGENO="0093"
89
community, which releases the resources for the undertaking. The
taxes lead to a reduction of consumption by households, to a
decline in investment, or both. The social cost of the capital raised
from foregone investment is clear: the investments would have
yielded a certain rate of return to the community which would
have increased the future flow of real national income. The social
cost, therefore, is equal to the foregone rate of return on private
investments.
To estimate the cost of funds which would have been spent for
consumption, we must turn to the saving and borrowing behavior
of households. Each individual has certain preferences about the
allocation of his expenditures over time, more particularly, the
allocation between present and future consumption. If he' post-
pones consumption, he earns interest on the resultant saving; if he
pays outstanding debts he reduces his interest payments accordingly.
A rational consumer will allocate his expenditures over time in
such manner that the rate at which he is willing to give up present
consumption for the income stream made possible by the resultant
increase of his saving will be equal to the interest rate which he
faces in making this choice. Thus, a saver will push his consump.
tion to the point where the satisfaction of a future income stream
equal to the interest rate is exactly equal to the satisfaction he
derives from the marginal dollar of consumption. Similarly, a
borrower will derive satisfaction from his marginal dollar of con-
sumption equal to the stream of interest payments he must make
on this marginal expenditure dollar which he has borrowed.~
Figure 13 illustrates this optimum condition of consumer
behavior. It shows the consumer's indifference map between
present consumption expenditures and increases of his future
~annual consumption streams.
If the consumer's income in the present period is represented by
point a (Figure 13-a), then he can reach any of the points on the
two line segments, ad and ae, which start at that point. Moving to
`This formulation does not detail the intertemporal optimum conditions
between all present and future periods and, hence, cannot describe the entire
future time profile of an individual's consumption. It is sufficiently detailed
for our limited purposes, however, and we seek to keep our assumptions as
simple as possible. The same reasoning can be applied to the rate of substitu-
tion of consumption expenditures between any two periods, provided the entire
structure of future interest rates is also known for the individual.
PAGENO="0094"
FIGURE 13. Effects of
Differences in Time
Preference on Choice
Between Present and
Future Consumption
90
V
V
V
13-a
C
E
C
0
U
V
C
C
C
4)
V
C
18-c
PAGENO="0095"
91
the right along the steeper line, means that he is borrowing to
increase his present consumption at the expense of future dimin-
ished consumption; the slope of this. line r~flécts the relatively
*~high borrowing rate. Moving to the left on the less steep line
represents saving out of present income at the relatively low interest
rates that can be earned on savings accounts and other assets It
can be seen from the diagram that point a', the point of tangency
between the saving line and an indifference curve, is the preferred
point that this individual can reach: it is on the highest attainable
indifference curve. Point b (Figure 13-b) illustrates the case
where the individual will borrow and thereby reach the preferred
point b', while point c (Figure 13-c) represents a situation where
the individual does not find it worthwhile to lend at low rates or
to borrow at high rates, and so simply spends his current income.
There are several fundamental factors which determine the
general shape of a particular consumer's indifference map in any
one period. First, there is the phase of the consumer's life cycle
of earnings and of expenditure needs. A young married person-
with an expectation of a rising income, with dependent children,
and with large needs to fully equip his household with standard
durables-has a high preference for current consumption expendi-
tures. An older person, expecting a falling income and retirement,
saves to increase his consumption later on, and so on. Second, an
individual's attitude toward satisfaction enjoyed at different points
of time will be reflected ip this preference map. People with a
very short horizon will have strong preferences for present con-
sumption, while misers will favor the reverse. Third, a person's
need and desire for providing for financial contingencies will help
to determine these preferences. Many other factors could be cited,
but this brief list at least indicates their general nature.
Much of consumer borrowing is* for the sake of purchasing
durables before sufficient cash can be set aside to pay for them;
all mortgages and most installment paper fall in this category.
Such borrowing, in a sense, is for investment rather than consump-
tion, for in each instance the asset yields a return to the owner.
The return may be monetary; a house, for example, reduces rent
payments. It may be a saving of labor, as in the case of washing
machines. The rest of the return may be in the form of satisfac-
tion enjoyed directly, sometimes as extra convenience, often as the
enjoyment of consumption through use of the durable. But what-
ever the form of the. return, a rational consumer will borrow at a
PAGENO="0096"
92
given interest rate only if his enjoyment of the return is at a rate
at least as great as his interest payments. Thus, we can assume
that a person who is willing to pay 12 per cent interest on the
purchase of a car on credit, or a homeowner paying 5 per cent on
the mortgage on his house, presumably is enjoying satisfaction
from these assets at rates at least equal to these figures.
In order to determine the social cost of funds raised through
taxation of an individual with given preferences about his saving-
borrowing behavior (or with given opportunities for investing in
durables), we must ascertain the interest rates which he faces. A
dollar of taxation is a reduction of his current income. If we can
assume that the marginal dollar an individual spends for present
consumption, or the dollar he saves, would be worth a future
annual income stream equal to his interest rate; then the same
interest rate would apply to the dollar required to pay an increase
in taxes. Conversely, a tax reduction of a dollar can be converted
into a future income stream equal to his interest rate. Interpreting
taxation for public investment as a compulsory loan for the sake
of future benefits, the social cost of this investment is equal to the
interest rate which the government would have to offer to the taxed
individuals to induce them to grant the loan voluntarily. Our
analysis does not assume that all of the taxed, money would have
been saved voluntarily; presumably part of it would have been
consumed. We assume only that the decision about the fraction
to be saved is made rationally and in the light of the opportunities
for chang~s in future income which the interest rate measures.
These assumptions are sufficient to derive the value of marginal
income in terms of a future stream which can be expressed as an
interest rate. We can then apply this reasoning to marginal changes
of income which are caused by taxation.
A further requirement for the estimate of the social cost of mar-
ginal tax dollars is to discover how these dollars are apportioned
among the major categories of decision-making ~mits that face
different interest rates. This means allocation of the taxes between
businesses and households, between borrowers and lenders, between
borrowers at high rates and borrowers at moderate rates, and so on.
For households, we use three categories-lenders, borrowers at
mortgage rates, and borrowers at short-term credit rates-combined
with a breakdown by income class. In the case of business, we
estimate the effect on inve~tment and its potential return, in
accordance with the size of assets of the taxpaying firms.
PAGENO="0097"
93
Our analysis necessarily is confined to small changes in expendi
tures and taxation relative to the over-all levels of the federal
budget Large tax changes, such as a 30 per cent reduction in
income taxes, would lead to such substantial shifts in consumers'
decisions and in the rate of return schedules of business that
assumptions of the present relationships between incomes, prices,
interest rates and rates of return would no longer be valid There
might be effects on consumers' incomes which would convert bor-
rowers into savers effects on the total amount of saving and of
investment which might alter and shift the interest rate structure,
and changes in the relative prices of consumer goods and capital
goods which would result in a shift from investment to consump-
tion in the private sector Since all of water resource development
absorbs little more than 1 per cent of the federal budget, any tax
changes made possible by changes in this program would be so
small as to be truly marginal; no limitation to the applicability of
our analysis to this field is imposed by these considerations
As with other criteria of economic efficiency our measure
abstracts from changes in the distribution of income. We view the
public investment as a loan by society to itself in order to build
certain physical investments That is, we assume that it does not
matter to whom benefits and costs accrue In fact much of the
cost is usually borne by individuals who do not benefit from the
investment so that the distribution of income is changed If we
attached a different value to a dollar of cost or benefit for different
groups, our efficiency measure would need to be modified. In the
~present context the value of the addition of a dollar to the future
income stream is assumed to be the same for all taxpayers and
1beneficiaries And if we go beyond the measurement of cost and
compare it with benefit, we make the additional assumption that
who receives the benefits and costs is a matter of indifference
These are ethical judgments which each person is free to accept
or reject Insofar as our interest is focused on the increase in total
national income and on the efficiency of particular programs in
promoting this objective this assumption serves as a means of
isolating this facet of the problem from redistributive
`For further discussions of this question see the last sections of Chapters Ix
and xii In the water resource field this value judgment has been made explicit
by the Congress in the Flood Control Act of 1936 where it is specified that
benefits must exceed costs for a project "to whomsoever they may accrue," in
order for a project to have economic feasibility and to be eligible for authoriza.
tion.
98-940 O-68------7
PAGENO="0098"
94
Our quantitative analysis could be presented, with no substantive
difference, either as an expansion of investment and a tax increase
or as a contraction of investment and a tax cut. It is the change
in taxes which is sigmficant it does not matter whether the public
investments would increase existing taxes. or prevent a possible
reduction Since the actual tax policy issues have appeared in
terms of tax reductions in recent years, we consider the problem
from this point of view
In order to measure the cost. of capital for a wide. range of taxes,
we. present two models using different sets of assumptions about the~
potential tax cuts which are forestalled by the public investments
In Model A, we assume that the personal income tax is reduced in
a manner most advantageous to low income families and that sales
taxes are lowered. These tax cuts.would primarily boost .consump#:
don. Model B consists.. of.a, reduction of the personal income tax
with emphasis on upper income brackets combined with a reduc
don of the corporation:income tax. This model would increase
investment~ ~. .
Throughout the analysis it is.assumed that the government runs a.
successful stabilization.;policy.. This is not to say that full employ-
ment: and.: stable :prke. levels prevail constantly, . but only: that
neither major unemployment nor severe inflation is allowed to
develop This assumption accords both with the avowed objectives
of the: government and with the general setting assumed for federal
resource development programs and it corresponds with the record
of recent years. . Most of. the data. for our quantitative analysis are.
based onthe year.. 1955, a year in which employment. washigh and
prices stable, and the money supply was~ moderately tight.
In this context, a reduction in a specific government expenditure
must be cOnsidered an autonomous change that must be offset by
some weapon in. the arsenal of the. stabilizers.: it is this reasoning
which forces: us to derive our estimates of social cost on the basis
of specific counteracting fiscal or monetary policies
TThus our procedure measures what Musgrave calls the ::"differential mci-
dence of expenditures (See R A Musgrave General Equilibrium Aspects of
Incidence Theory," American Economic. Reijiew,. May. .1953,:. pp. 504.17).. A'
reduction of expenditures by $1.00 may require an offsetting tax cut of `less than
$1.00,. because :the multiplier effects of the former: may exceed, the: effects of
tax reduction~. (see. H. C. Wallich, . "Income-Generating. Effects of a Balanced
Budget," Quarterly Journal of Economics, `1944, pp. 78.91).. In our quantitative
PAGENO="0099"
95
This may seem to. be a cumbersome procedure for deriving one
number-.the opportunity cost applicable to resource development
funds. But there is no short cut. With capital coming from many
sources, which . face widely differing borrowing and lending ratei
of interest and whose. saving and investment, decisiOns are~ çOndi~
*tioned by altogether different factors, the actual impact of federally
financed projects on the economic activities of~ the otherS sectors Of
the economy varies widely. It has been argued, for. example, that
the true opportunity cost óf~ capital- is .the rate' of return earned on
the marginal, investments of the most .sucéessful' private firms, such
as DuPont or General Motors, rates~ which before- taxes are in
excess of 20 per cent. But this is not the true opportunity cost;
reduction of the federal program .by $100 million would not result
in expansion of investment by such firms of an equal amount It
has also been argued'.that the interest rate on'long-term gOvernment
bonds measures the social cost of public capital.8 This rate is also
inappropriate, because it presupposes that the entire cost of projects
is financed out of voluntary bond purchases and that~ the risks
attached to projects are borne :by .the buyers-two conditions that
do not: hold. ..A number of other easily derived rates can be `sup.~'
ported by plausible arguments but in the end the arguments break
down.. `:A sector-by-sector. approach, assuming a specific: incidence
of marginal taxation, is..far mOre trustworthy because it corresponds
to the actual conditions under which public capital is raised
Before embarking on our detailed quantitative `study, a~ few pre-
cautionary co~nments should be made about our basic assumptions
We take it as axiomatic that a measure of the social cost of capital
which is consistent with an economic efficiency approach must
accept the sovereignty of consumers choice, even in matters of
study we assume that the fiscal authorities reduce taxes by the appropriate
amount, i.e., an . amount sufficient to result in the utilization .of a bundle of'
resources equal to the quantity released by the reduction of expenditures.
Thus, we assume constancy of effective demand. We also assume that our result
is not affected by any redistributions of income attributable to the multiplier
effects of the two offsetting changes in the budget.'~~ ` . . ~:
~ practice of most agencies and the recommendations of Budget Bureau'
Circular A 47 and of the Sub Committee on Benefits and Costs of the Federal
Interagency. River Basin Committee imply this `position. See".Otto Eckstëin,"
Water -Resource Development: The Economics `of Project EvaluatiOn' "(Cam.
bridge Harvard University Press in press) Chapter iv for a survey of actual
practice. ` , ` :. ,. . ` `. . .", ` , , -. T.. -
PAGENO="0100"
96
allocation of expenditures over time, and particularly with regard
to their decisions on how much to consume and how much to
invest. It has been widely contended that consumers' sovereignty
should be rejected for intertemporal choices because of the myopia
of individua1s,~ which leads to inadequate amounts of saving and
investment for society as a whole from a long-run .point of view.
It has also been contended that it is not the function of govern-
ment slavishly to follow individual desires, but to act for unborn
generations, to take the lead in providing for the future.
We do not reject these considerations and shall return to them
later in this chapter. In some instances, they will be reflected in
the higher social criteria which may supersede the efficiency criteria
as we have defined them. But, throughout this study, we take the
view that economic efficiency is one of the significant criteria and
that it requires measurement of gains and costs in terms of the sub-
jective valuations of the individuals who constitute our society. In
the case of the cost of capital, we also look to individual prefer-
ences, and it is on this basis that we prOceed.
Model A: A Tax Cwt Stimulating Consumption
`Our first tax model estimating the social cost of capital consists
of reductions which are particularly favorable to low-income
families. . In Model A, 80 per cent of the tax cut is in the form
of an increase in the personal exemption of the federal income tax.
The other 20 per cent is assumed to go into a reduction of those
federal excises which would, in fact, be most likely to take place.
When our computations for each of these tax cuts are completed
and the results combined we arrive at the following applicable
interest rates:
9M. Dobb, On Economic Theoiy and Socialism (New York: International
Publishers, 1955), PP. 38-41, 73-77, 244-45, and 258-60; A. C. Pigóu, The Eco-
nomics of Welfare (4th ed.; London: Macmillan Company, 1932), pp. 22-30;
W. J. Baumol, Welfare Economics and the Theory of the State (Cambridge:
Harvard University Press, 1952), pp. 91-92; and R. H. Strotz, "Myopia and
Inconsistency in Dynamic Utility Maximization," Review of Economic Studies,
1955-6, pp. 165-180.
PAGENO="0101"
97
Per cen~t
Increased personal exemption 5 87
Reduced excises 549
Weighted average for Model A 5 79
INCREASING THE EXEMPTION OF
THE PERSONAL INCOME TAX
A tax cut in the form of a higher exemption frequently has been
proposed in Congress. Assuming that the income tax liabilities
are not shifted it is easy to compute the incidence of the tax cut
by income classes Let us suppose the exemption is raised by $1 00
The tax saving on the typical return in each income class depends
upon the marginal tax rate paid the saving for the income class
also depends upon the number of exemptions claimed. It can be
seen from Table 4 that most of the tax saving accrues to those with
low and middle incomes-those with incomes of $5,000 or less.
TABLE 4. Incidence by Income Classes of an Increase
in the Personal Exemption
Number
Income class exemptio
($ thousand) (000)
of
ns'
Tax saving
per dollar b
. (cents)
T
($
otal tax
saving
thousand)
P
dis
of - t
er cent
tribution
ax saving
0 to 3 24472
21
5 139
195
3 to 5 44,557
24
10,694
40.6
.
5 to 7.5 23,066
27
6,228
23.6
7.5 to 10 4,906
33
1,619
6.1
*
10 to 15 2,705
41
.
1,109
4.2
15 to 20 984
50
492
1 9
20 to 30 839
59
495
1.9
30 to 50 507
67
340
1.8
50 to 100 223
79
176
.7
Over 100 63
90
57
*
.2
~U.S. Treasury Department, Internal Revenue Service, Statistics Of Income
for 1951, 1955, based on returns with taxable income.
b Marginal tax rates at average income tax liability reported in each class
Discovery of the rates at which each income class saves or bor
rows requires examination of its asset and credit position. The
PAGENO="0102"
98
Survey of Consumer- Finances provides relevant data on this
question; they are summarized in Table 5. It shows, for each
income class, what percentage of spending units have a significant
amount of short-term consumer debt and mortgages.
TABLE 5. Asset-Debt Position of Consumer
- -
$0 to $3,000
- (per cent)
Income class
$3,000 to $5,000
(per cent)
Over $5,000
(per cent)
Owed more -than $100 of con- -
sumer debt 33 - 52
Owed mortgages only 5 8
Owed neither kind of debt.... 62 40
52
11
37
Source: 1956 Survey of Consumer Finances, "Consumer Indebtedness," Federal
- Reserve Bulletin, July 1956, p. 702.
To derive the interest rates on which consumers make their
marginal borrowing-saving decisions, we must estimate the rate of
return earned on their assets and the rates paid on their debts. Let
us assume that the interest paid, on the assets held by debt-free
households is 3 per cent, a rate typical of the savings accounts and
U. S. government bonds into which most households in the lower-
income brackets put their savings. To take account of the higher
returns earned on common stock by 15 per cent of the class with
incomes above $5,000,10 we increase this rate to 3.75 per cent for
the class with no debts. -
A rate of 5 per cent `is applied to mortgage loans. This rate is
somewhat above that - charged on loans guaranteed by the Federal
Hàusing Administration or the Veterans Administration, but corre-
sponds to rates on conventional first mortgages and allows for the
considerably higher rates which prevail on second mortgages.11
As for interest on short-term consumer credit, rates vary widely,
`from less than 6 per cent on some personal bank loans (and 0 per
101955 Survey of Consumer Finances, "The Financial Position of Consumers,"
Federal Reserve Bulletin, June 1955, p. 621.
~ This rate corresponds to the findings of Morton for 1947. See J. E. Morton,
Urban Mortgage Lending Experience, National Bureau of Economic Research
(Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1956), pp. 80-81.
PAGENO="0103"
99
cent on loans within families) to over ;30~ per cent. On some small
loans of finance companies This range can be narrowed by study
ing the composition of personal debt Of the $36 billion out
standing at the end of 1955, $14 billion was automobile paper 12
The rates of most automobile paper were between 8 and 12 per
cent, with that held by banks near the lower figure and by finance
companies near the higher one. Another $6 billion was for other
consumer goods paper, which has comparable rates Personal loans
constituted $8 billion. Of these the small loans which bore very
high rates were offset to some degree by low rates on bank loans
available to the best of the credit risks Of the remaining about
half were charge accounts and~ the rest were service cre4it~ and
repair and modernization loans The rates on these categories
tended to be relatively low, ranging from 6 per cent on regular
charge accounts to 9 per cent on modernization loans. The average
rate for personal debt suggested by these figures is about 10 per
cent A breakdown by type of holder is consistent with this
estimate, since banks hold 33 per cent, credit unions 5 per cent,
stores 25 per cent, sales finance companies 28 per cent and others
9 per cent It would be incorrect, however to assume that all
income classes pay the same rates Generally, poorer people obtain
small loans at very high rates and borrow from sales finance com
panies for their durable goods purchases those with higher incomes
are able to obtain bank loans and have charge accounts To allow
for this factor we assume a rate of 12 per cent for consumer credit
for those with the lowest income and a rate of 9 per cent for the
rest
Interest payments are deductible from federal income taxation
This implies that the actual rate which governs the choice of con
sumers is not the rate paid but the rate adjusted for the saving
in taxes But the applicability of this reasoning is limited by the
~wide use of the standard deduction in income tax returns Itemized
deductions were made on only 8 per cent of the returns for $3 000
or,less 24 per cent for $3,000 to $5,000 and 40 per cent for $5,000
and over Because the tax saving from this source is usually more
significant in the case of mortgages, we use the borrowing rate
after taxes only in the case of households with mortgages
~ U S Department of Commerce Survey of Current Business March 1956
p S 16
PAGENO="0104"
100
Interest receipts on the other hand, are taxable income which
again argues for the use of interest rates after taxes But the
amounts of interest received are relatively small for most house
holds and frequently are not reported to the tax collectors Only
7 per cent of returns with incomes below $5 000, and 20 per cent
with higher incomes, reported interest receipts 13 Therefore, we
use the before tax interest rates except for half of the interest
recipients with top incomes.
Our set of categories for assigning interest rates to households
does not properly describe one group in the debt.free households.
The fact that the largest percentage of debt-free households is
found among the lowest incomes does not mean that low-income
families have less need for credit. Rather, many of these families
are not sufficiently good credit risks to get any loans except small
loans at very unattractive terms. It would be incorrect to assume
that these families make their borrowing-saving decisions on a rate
of S per cent. For a sizeable group of low-income families, the lack
of the use of credit can be explained on other grounds. Unskilled
workers are heavily represented; because their income reaches a
peak relatively early in life, they have relatively little inducement
to borrow. Still other low-income families consist of older people
who are living on their capital; they also have no incentive to
borrow. To take account of the group who wants credit but is too
poor to obtain it, we assume that 20 per cent of the nonborrowers
have a high time-preference and, if they were free to do so, would
make use of short-term consumer credit at the usual rate of 12
per cent.
Table 6 gives the rates derived in the manner we have indicated,
with adjustments for taxes incorporated in the figures. Table 7
gives the distribution of households by income class, asset-debt
position, and by their marginal borrowing or lending rates. Those
whO owe both consumer debt and mortgages are considered to be
paying the higher borrowing rate (that for consumer debt), which
is the rate that must be considered marginal. Low-income families
unable to borrow at reasonable rates are listed separately.
~U S. Treasury Department, Internal Revenue Service, Statistics of Income
for 1952, Preliminary Report. These figures include returns reporting miscel-
laneous income on the federal income tax form 1040a. We apply after-tax inter-
est rates to one-half the interest recipients in the top class because that is the
degree of complia~ice suggested by our asset-debt data.
PAGENO="0105"
101
TABLE 6. Interest Rates Faced by Households in Their
Saving-Spending Decisions
Interest rates for income class
$0 to $3,000 $3,000 to $5,000 Over $5,000
(per cent) (per cent) (per cent)
Owed more than $100 of con-
sumer debt 12.0 8.3 7.3
Owed mortgages only 4.0 3.9 33
Owed neither kind of debtS
and held savings 3.0 3.0 3.2
Unable to borrow at reason-
able rates 12.0 .. . -
Source: See text.
The table also gives the average rate for each income class and the
distribution of tax savings caused by an increase of the personal
exemption. The final figure, computed by weighting the average
rates applicable to the three income classes by their shares of tax
savings, is equal to 5.87 per cent.'4 This is the rate which our
quantitative analysis suggests as the proper measure of value to
consumers of the tax savings made possible by an increase in the
exemption of the personal income tax.'5
~` The use of income classes as defined by the Internal Revenue Service in
combination with the definitions o~ the Survey of Consumer Finances introduces
a slight upward bias into the estimate. The Survey's "spending unit" indudes
all related persons living together who pool their incomes, while the Internal
Revenue Service gives its figures in terms of tax returns. Since some spending
units will file several tax returns, relatively fewer spending units will fall into
our lowest-income class. This bias is accentuated by the fact that our tax data
pertain to 1951, when incomes were lower than in 1955. Data for the distribu-
tion of income from the two sources suggest that as many as one-half of the
returns filed in the lowest-income class in 1951 should be assigned to "spending
units" in the next income class in 1955. Similarly, the data suggest that one-third
of all returns filed in the middle-income class in 1951 belonged to "spending
units" in the highest class in 1955. On these assumptions, our estimate for the
interest rate would fall to 5.70 per cent. This probably overstates the bias since
the Survey's sample appears to underrepresent low-income "spending units."
Our analysis has not endeavored to impute a rate of return to the invest-
ments made possible by the increased savings of consumers. Presumably, a
return greater than the borrowing cost is earned on these investments, which
serves as an inducement for the investor. An estimate of this extra return
requires identification of the marginal borrowers to whom these investible funds
PAGENO="0106"
TABLE 7. The Average Interest Rate Applicable to the Distribution of Tax Savings From Increasing
Personal Exemption Based on Distribution of Spending Units by Income Class,
Asset-Debt Position, and Marginal Borrowing or Lending Rates of Interest
$0 to $3,000
(2)
(1) Interest
Item Per cent rate b
of units (per cent)
Income class
.
$3,000
to $5,000
Over $5,000
(3)
Per cent
of units'
(4)
Interest
rate b
(per cent)
(5)
Per cent
of units'
(6)
Interest
rate b
(per cent)
Owed more than $100 of consumer debt .. 33
Owed mortgages only 5
bwed neither kind of debt 50
Unable to borrow at reasonable rates b **** 12
12.0
4.0
3.0
12.0
52
8
40
-
8.3
3.9
3.0
-
52
11
37
7.3
3.5
3.2
.
Average rate for each income class
7.0
5.8
5.4
Percentage distribution of tax saving ....
19.5
40.6
39.9
Average applicable interest rate
5.87
`1956 Survey of Consumer Finances, op. cit.
b See text.
C Statistics of Income for 1951, op. cit.
PAGENO="0107"
103
REDUCING SELECTED EXCISE TAXES
In addition to the increase in personal exemption, amounting to
80 per cent of the tax cut, our Model A calls for a cut in excise
taxes sufficient to make up 20 per cent of the decline in government
revenue. We assume a reduction for only those commodities which
seem likely to be affected by an actual move to cut excises. Thus,
all road user taxes are excluded because they have been set aside
to finance the expanding federal highway program. Taxes on
alcoholic beverages and tobacco are ruled out because they are
imposed, in part, for noneconomic reasons and have a long accepted
place in the federal revenue structure We treat the remaining
excises as if they were cut proportionately, and assume that the
price elasticity of consumer demand is such that the relative
increase in sales will be the same for all commodities in question
These two assumptions imply that the proportionate cut in tax
rates leads to a proportionate fall in the revenues from the various
excises
The incidence of excise taxes is usually assumed to fall on the
consumer16 The incidence by income classes, then, depends on the
distribution of the tax cut among commodities and on their
income elasticity Table 8 sheds some light on this question It
lists the major federal excises, shows the revenues derived from
them and their percentage distribution, and gives estimates of the
income elasticities of the commodities which have been made by
the U S Department of Commerce Using the distribution of taxes
as weights, an average income elasticity is computed for the entire
excise tax cut Both the prewar and postwar figures produce an
would be made available a task we shall not assay Were we to assume that
the return above borrowing cost is 3 per cent-a liberal figure in view of the
low and middle income sources of these savings and the channels into which
their savings usually flow-and were we to apply marginal propensities to save
by income classes (see footnotes to Table 14) to estimate the share of the tax
cut that would be saved we would increase our estimate by 12 percentage
points resulting in a figure of 599 per cent.
"Musgrave and Tucker followed this assumption in their studies of tax
incidence (See R A Musgrave J 3 Carroll L D Cook and L Franc Dis
tribution of Tax Payments by Income Groups A Case Study for 1948 National
Tax Journal March 1951 and R S Tucker Distribution of Tax Burdens in
1948 ibid September 1951) This assumption is only a first approximation
and overlooks the effects of product substitution.
PAGENO="0108"
104
TABLE 8. Excise Taxes and Income Elasticities for Selected
Goods and Services
* Musical instruments and radios . 248
Records . ~. ........ 8
Appliances 107
Cameras 15
Jewelry 142
Furs 27
Toiletries 72
Luggage 51
Admissions 189
Telephone 520
Transportation 632
Average elasticity
Income elasticity b
1929-40 1947-54
2.5 1.1
2.5 . 1.1
1.3 0.3
1.5 0.6
1.8 0.3
1.5 1.5
0.8 0.5
1.1 1.8
0.8 -0.4
0.5 1.7
1.1 1.1
1.15 1.00
a U. S. Treasury Department, Treasury Bulletin, March 1956. Figures are for
fiscal 1955.
b U. S. Department of Commerce, "Consumer Expenditure Patterns," Survey
of Current Business, September 1955, pp. 23-32. These estimates are based on
time series analysis and are of questionable statistical validity in view of the
small number of observations and the strong trends in some of the series. But
the similarity of the results for the average of the two periods offers considerable
evidence that the actual value is not far removed from 1.0. It may appear puz-
zling that these luxuries do not have a higher elasticity; but the result can be
explained by the wide range of goods and prices offered in each category.
estimate very close to 1.0, which implies an incidence of the taxes
among income classes similar to the distribution of income.1T
Table 9 shows the distribution of family income and the interest
rates applicable to the tax saving in each class. Averaging the
rates by using the income distribution as weights, gives us the
1TRolph has put forth the view that factors of production bear the cost of
excise taxes through backward shifting. Our computation is consistent with this
assumption if the changes in factor payment are proportional, for this will
distribute the tax saving among income classes in accordance with the distribu-
tion of income. See E. R. Roiph, "A Proposed Revision of Excise Tax Theory,"
Journal of Political Economy, April 1952, pp. 102-17.
Tax revenue ~ Per cent of
- Commodity .* . ($ million) tax revenue
12.3
.4
5.3
.7
7.1
1.3
3.6
2.5
9.4
25.9
31.4
PAGENO="0109"
105
*
interest rate applicable to this form of tax cut.18 This rate turns
out to be 5.49 per cent.
* Averaging the 5.87 per cent rate for the increased personal
exemption and the 5.49 per cent for excise cuts, weighted by their
relative importance, we get an over-all estimate of the applicable
rate under the tax assumptions of Model A, which is equal to 5.79
per cent.
TABLE 9. Reduction of Selected Excise Taxes: Distribution of
Income and Applicable Interest Rates, 1955
*
Applicable
Family income Family personal Per cent Per cent interest
class income distribution distribution rate C
($ thousand) (S billion) before tax after tax ~` (per cent)
Oto3 25.0 9 10 7.0
3 to 5 59.1 21 22 5.8
5to7.5 81.6 28 28 5.8
7.5 to 10 47.1 16 16 5.4
10 to 15 29.3 10 10 5.0
Over 15 46.0 16 14 4.6
Average applicable
interest rate 5.49
S. F. Goldsmith, "Income Distribution in the United States, 1952~55," Survey
of Current Business, op. cit., June 1956, pp. 9.16. Our income classes have to be
defined as income before tax because the Survey data on which our interest rates
are based are given that way.
b Since the income elasticities were derived from regressions on disposable or
after-tax, income, it is the distribution of income after taxes which supplies the
proper weights for our average interest rate. The distribution after taxes was
computed by applying the average tax rate for each income class (given in the
Goldsmith article cited above) to the before-tax income.
c The rates for the lower brackets are carried over from the preceding section.
The breakdown in the upper brackets is derived in detail in the discussion of
Model B~
~ A reduction of excise taxes is less likely than a reduction of income taxes
to result in accrual of additional returns to marginal investors to whom addi.
tional private savings are made available. This is because the tax cut leads to
price reductions of consumer goods and hence induces some substitution of
consumption for saving. While we cannot be sure that the substitution effect
will exactly cancel the income effect on consumption, it is unlikely that the net
result will be significant. The distribution of the tax cut among income classes,
and particularly to high-consumption families, strengthens this conclusion.
PAGENO="0110"
106
Model B: A Tax Cut Stimulating Investment
In Model B, we make quite different assumptions about the tax
cuts made possible by a reduction in expenditures, though we again
try to cast our assumptions~ in a plausible form from a political
point of view. We assume that 50 per cent of the reduction will be
taken by reducing the rate structure of the personal income tax.
Rather than assume a new rate schedule, we assume that it is the
objective of the rate changes to reduce the tax bill of each taxpayer
in the same proportion. Income tax payments represent a larger
percentage of the income in higher brackets; therefore, such a tax
cut would produce a more than proportionate increase in after-tax
incomes in the higher.income classes and would, therefore, reduce
the degree of progression of the personal tax structure. The
remaining 50 per cent of the reduction is assumed to take the
form of a cut in corporate income taxes, distributed among corpor
ations in proportion to their tax liability. Combining the interest
rates applicable to each of these tax cuts, we derive our over-all
estimate for Model B as follows
Per cent
Proportionate reduction of personal
* income taxes 5.29
Proportionate cut in corporation taxes . ... 5.59
Weighted Average for Model B 5.44
REDUCING PERSONAL INCOME TAX
LIABILITIES PROPORTIONATELY
Much of the method applied in Model A can be used for the
personal income tax cut favoring upper.income families. Let us first
look at the distributio~i of tax savings among income classes, given
in Table 10. Comparing the incidence of this tax cut with the inci-
dence of an increase in the exemption, we find that much * more
of it accrues to high-income classes, 59 per cent of it to incomes
over $7,500. Where Model A; emphasized the asset-debt pOsition
of families with low and middle incomes, for whom the Survey of
PAGENO="0111"
107
Consumer Finances provides good coverage, Model B must give
much more detailed estimates for the upper-income classes. Insofar
as the tax cut does accrue to families with incomes below $5,000,
TABLE 10. Incidence by Income Classes of a Proportionate
Reduction of Income Tax Payments 1954
Family personal income Per cent distribution of
($ thousand) income tax liability
OtoS 36
Sto5 13.2
5to75 240
75 to 10 144
10 to 15 103
15to20 50
20to30 6.5
3Qto5O 78
50 to 100
Over 100 75
Goldsmith op ctt p 15 The breakdown of the 345 per cent paid on
incomes above $15,000 is in proportion to the tax liabilities of these classes in
1952, as given in the Statistics of Income for 1952, Preliminary Report, U. S.
Treasury Department, Internal Revenue Service.
we can simply use the interest rates derived earlier. But a some-
what different approach is required for the upper-income groups.
In the lower brackets, the diversity of interest rates is explained
primarily by the presence or absence of debt and by the kind of
debt owed. In the upper brackets, the form of the assets from
which income is derived and the rates at which such income is
taxed are the most important variables.
First, we determine what proportion of families in .each class
has debts in such amounts that borrowing rates would dominate
choices between spending and saving, and then estimate the re1e~
vant borrowing rates For the remaining families which include
a rapidly increasing share as we go up the income scale, we ti y to
determine the kind of earning assets from which they derive their
nonwage income and at what rates of return this income is received
Again combining the distribution of incidence of the tax cut with
the interest rates applicable to different income classes, we derive
an average rate which measures the value of the money released
by the postulated tax cut.
PAGENO="0112"
108
Table 11 presents the asset-debt position ,of househOlds with
incomes greater than $5,000. It shows a wide prevalence of debt,.
which results from lumping all incomes above $10,000 into one
bracket. Since debt for consumption purposes falls rapidly in the
higher brackets, in our subsequent analysis the figures for the
bracket over $10,000 are applied only in the range $10,000 to
$15,000 Also in the higher brackets, the relevance of the borrow
ing rate ceases, because the rate of return on assets increases while
the borrowing cost falls, until at some point on the income scale,
the borrowing rate is no longer marginal-the return on assets
playing the role instead. When that point is reached, consumer
credit is likely to be in the form of charge accounts owed as a
matter of convenience, and mortgages owed-in part-in order to
raise funds for investment purposes.
Table 11 also shows the interest rates applicable to debtors in
these income classes. As in Model A, rates of 9 per cent on short-
term debt and 5 per cent on mortgages are used in deriving these
rates but in the case of the upper income classes it is assumed
that interest, payments are deducted from the tax liability and the
rates are adjusted accordingly.
To derive the rates of return which upper-income families earn
on their assets, we estimate asset holdings by income class and the
rates applicable to each asset category. Table 12 shows in what
form upper-income classes receive property income as reported in
income tax returns.
TABLE 11. Debt Position of Families with Incomes Over ,~5,OOO
Per cent owed
Income class more than $100
($ thousand) of short.term
debts
Per cent owed
mortgages
Per cent owed
neither kind
of debt
Interest rate
applicable
to debtors
(per cent)
5to7.5
56
11
~3
6.2
7.5 to 10
ver 10
. 52
41
22
26
~7
56
4:9
~1956 Survey of Consumer Finances, op. cit., pp. 701~43.
In. the case of business and professional income, part is actually
managerial wages or income earned for supplying professional
services. While we have no direct data on this breakdown, the
Department of Commerce has estimated that, in 1949, 11.3 per cent
PAGENO="0113"
109
of all incomes of ~5,000 and overwas professional income; 37.8 per
cent, from farms; and the remaining 50.9 per cent from unincor-
porated business.'9 We consider all of the professional income to
be a form of wages.2° As for the income from farms and unincor-
porated business, we allow 50 per cent of the income as managerial
TABLE 12. Percentage Breakdown of Nonwage Income in
Upper-Income Classes
Business
Income class and pro.
($ thousand) fessional
Dividends
plus retained
earning
Rent
*
Interest
Income
from
trusts
5 to 7.5 .
69.9
14.2
8.9
5.0
2.1
7.5 to 10
67.0
17.0
6.9
6.2
2.7
10 to 15
67.0
18.4
6.7
4.5
3.4
15 to 20
66.3
19.6
6.1
4.2
4.0
20 to 30
62.7
21.8
5.9
4.2
5.3
30 to 50
58.6
26.1
5.5
4.0
5.8
50 to 100
46.3
36.4
5.5
3.9
8.2
Over 100
22.2
56.8
*
4.3
2.9
13.9
Statistics of Income for 1952, Preliminary Report, op. cit. Direct data on the
holdings of assets of investors, not derived from tax information, are generally
consistent with the figures given here. See J. K. Butters, L. E. Thompson, and
L. L. Bollinger, Effects of Taxation on Investment by Individuals (Boston:
Graduate School of Business Administration, Harvard University, 1953), p: 468.
TABLE 13. Percentage Breakdown of Income from Assets in
Upper-Income Classes
Income class
($ thousand)
Business
Dividends
plus retained
earnings
Rent
Interest
Income
from
trusts
5 to 7.5
56.4
20.6
12.9
7.2
3.0
7.5 to 10
47.5
27.2
11.1
9.9
4.3
10 to 15
47.4
29.4
10.7
7.2
5.4
15 to 20
46.5
31.0
9.6
6.6
6.3
20 to 30.
42.7
33.5
9.1
6.5
8.2
30 to 50
38.2
39.0
8.2
6.0
8.6
50 to 100
27.5
49.0
7.4
5.2
10.9
Over 100
10.9
64.2
5.1
3.3
15.8
U. S. Department of Commerce, National Income, 1954 Edition, A Supple-
ment to the Survey of Current Business, p. 76.
While many professions require considerable investment in equipment, a
reduction in income would not be likely to affect this kind of investment.
98-940 O-68----8
PAGENO="0114"
110
wages and the remainder as income earned on assets. Table 13
gives the distribution of income from assets which is implied by
these assumptions. -
Turning to the rates of return, Figure 14 throws considerable
light on prevailing rates in unincorporated business._Each dot on
the frequency distribution indicates the median rate of return of a
sample of firms in an industry. Most of the firms have assets in
excess of $50,000-the proper size to yield incomes which fall into
the brackets with which we are concerned. Both the means and
the medians of the industry medians fall very close to 6 per cent2'
3
2
0
Manufactt~ring
P.~EDIAN 6.0%
MEAN - - 6.6%
I
I
`Wholesale
.
*~.
L.!~
MEDIAN -6.0%
MEAN - - 6.0%
.
Retail
MEDIAN - 5.6w
MEAN--6.1%
I
I I
I
III
I
II
2 6 1, 10 12 14
Median rate of return on equity by industry
FIGURE 14~ Rates of Return in Small and Medium.Sized Firms
Source: Dun's Review, October, November, and December 1955. Data compiled
by Roy A. Foulke.
for all three categories of data; we use this figure as our estimate.
In the case of farming, the average rate of return on investment,
after allowing for the value of operator and family labor, has been
estimated at 4.9 per cent for the year 1949, although the return in
38 per cent of the regions of the United States is in excess of 6 per
cent 22 The subsequent deterioration of farm prices has lowered
the average return. But we are concerned with farms yielding an
income in excess of $7,500, earned only on the farms which are the
"se of the median assures that the presence of a few large firms or of a
few extreme values will not bias the estimates.
E~ G. Strand, E. 0. Heady, and J. A. $eagraves, Productivity of Resources
Used on Commercial Farms, U. S. Department of Agriculture, Technical Bulletin
No. 1128, November 1955, p. 50.
PAGENO="0115"
111
largest and most successful, and located in the better regions, and
so we assume a rate of return of 6 per cent to apply.
Treatment of the returns on stock poses severe problems. The
ex post rate of return has been extremely high in recent years
because of the doubling of common stock prices. If we considered
all capital gains to be income, the annual rate of return of recent
years would exceed 15 per cent. But in making decisions, indi-
viduals did not fully anticipate these capital gains, nor would it
be realistic to suppose that this rate will continue indefinitely.
Yet, it also would be unrealistic to exclude all capital gains, since
the high rate of income retention of corporations makes likely the
continued growth of the value of stocks. To take account of this
factor, we assume that the yield on stocks is equal to dividends
plus retained earnings. In 1955, the average dividend yield on all
common stock was 3.93 per cent; since only 50 per cent of earnings
~as paid out, we assume a total rate of return of 8 per cent.
`Income from rent, interest, and trusts represents relatively small
shares of total property income. For the rate of return on real
estate, we use two sources. The first is profits of corporations whose
main business is the holding of real estate. This has been at the
rate of 12 per cent before taxes,23 a figure which primarily repre-
sents commercial property and apartment houses. Second, for
residential property as a whole, some unpublished investigations of
R. Muth suggest an average rate of 5.5 per cent.24 Since commercial
property and residential property of above average profitability
are likely to be held by individuals in the upper-income brackets,
we assume that rental income is earned at a rate of return of 8 per
cent. For interest, a rate of 3 per cent is assumed. This is slightly
higher than the rates of 2.8 to 2.9 per cent which prevailed on
government bonds in 1955, but lower than the average yield of
3.25 per cent on corporate bonds.25 Finally, we assign an interest
rate to income from trusts. Since the trusts represent various
combinations of other assets, we simply assume that their rate of
U. S. Treasury Department, Internal Revenue Service, Statistics of Income for
1951 (Washington, D. C.: Government Printing Office, 1955), and Statistics of
Income for 1952, op. cit.
24 an abstract, see R. F. Muth, "The Demand for Non-Farm Housing,"
Econometrica, April 1957, p. 365.
~` Board of Governors, Federal Reserve System, Federal Reserve Bulletin, May
1956, p. 477.
PAGENO="0116"
112
return is equal to the average rate of return earned by the income
class.
These rates have been stated before taxes. In the case of funds
actually used for investment, this rate measures the social oppor-
tunity cost since the assets which the money makes possible yield
this return. But in determining a rate of interest which measures
the value of the funds used for consumption, we must use the rates
of return that could be earned after taxes, since these are the
rates which households actually face in making decisions. Table
TABLE 14. Rates of Return Earned by Households, Adjusted for Taxes by
Upper-Income Clas.ces and Form of Property
Rate
s of return for form of property income
(per cent)
Income class Business
($ thousand) income
Dividends
plus retained
earnings Rent Interest
Average rate
of return a
(per cent)
Rate of return be-
.
fore tax b 6.0
8.0 8.0 3.0
Rate of return after
taxes by house-
holds c for:
5 to 7.5 4.5
63 6.0 2.2
5.0
7.5 to 10 4.2
6.2 5.7 2.1
4.7
10 to 15 3.8
5.8 5.1 1.9
4.4
15 to 20 3.2
5.1 4.2 1.6
3.8
20 to 30 2.5
4.6 3.2 1.2
3.2
30 to 50 2.1
4.4 2.8 1.0
3.1
50 to 100 1.4
4.0 1.9 1.2
2.9
Over 100 0.7
3.4 0.9 0.9
2.8
Applicable rate of
retUrn" for:
.
5 to 73 43
63 6.0 2.2
5.0
7.5 to 10 4.4
6.4 6.0 2.2
4.9
10 to 15 4.4
6.4 5.9 2.2
5.0
15 to 20 3.9
5.9 5.2 2.0
4.6
20 to 30 3.9
6.0 5.1 1.9
4.6
30 to 50 3.7
5.8 4.9 1.8
4.6
50 to 100 3.2
5.6 4.3 2.3
4.6
Over 100 2.8
5.2 3.7 1.9
4.6
by the distribution of property inco
me within the
a The average is weighted
income class.
PAGENO="0117"
113
See text.
The following marginal tax rates are applied to the respective income
dasses:' .25, .29, .36, .47, .59, .65, .76, and .89. These rates represent the mar-
ginal rate in each income class as indicated by the average tax liability reported
for the class. In applying the rates, half of the income from stock is considered
long-term capital gain. Also 25 per cent of the interest income in the top two
brackets is considered to be from tax-exempt bonds yielding an average of 2.6
per cent; this assumption is based on the findings of Butters, Thompson, and
Bollinger, op. cit., p. 468.
d These rates are derived as follows: We assume the following marginal pro.
pensities to save: 0, 12, 26, and 26 per cent respectively on the first four
brackets, and 40 per cent on all brackets over $20,000. (Source: Survey of the
Bureau of Labor Statistics to revise the Consumer Price Index, 1950, as reported
in Business Week, June 16, ]956, p. 104; the figure for the top bracket is based
on the 1936 survey of the National Resources Committee, reported in M. Bron-
fenbrenner, et al., "A Study in Redistribution and Consumption," Review of
Economics and Statistics, May 1955, p. 153, adjusted downward in accordance
with the shift of the known portions of the consumption function.) We apply
the rates after tax to the portion of the tax cut that would be consumed and
the rates before tax to the share that would be invested, and then compute a
weighted average.
These rates can be given an alternative interpretation to that of the text.
Where the government is considered a "partner" in the ownership of the assets,
the return in excess of the after-tax rate can be considered to be the return
earned by the government on the assets. The rate at which taxes are paid on
the part of the tax cut which is invested measures the government's share of
the returns.
14 first gives the rates of return after taxes, and then shows the
adjusted rates of return allowing for the higher rates that must be
applied to the portion of the tax cut which is actually invested.
Taking these adjusted rates in combination with the distribution
of various kinds of property income of Table 13, we derive the
average rates of return applicable to the property holders in each
income class (final column of Table 14). Combining the resulting
rates with the rates given for debtors in Table 11, we derive the
average interest rate for the entire income class (column 3, Table
15). Finally, bringing in the rates for low-income classes from
Model A, and the distribution of the tax cut from Table 10, we
compute the over-all interest rate for this form of tax cut. These
computations, summarized in Table 15, show an over-all rate of
5.29 per cent.26
* ~ If we assume that an additional return of 3 per cent above borrowing cost
accrues to the investors to whom the additional savings are made available, our
PAGENO="0118"
114
TABLE 15. Summary of Derivation of Interest Rate Applicable to
Reduction of Personal Income Tax Payments
Proportionate
(1) (2)
Interest rate Interest rate
applicable to applicable to
Income class debtors investors
(3)
Average rate
for class
(4)
Per cent
distribution
($ thousand) (per cent) (per cent)
(per cent)
of tax cut
OtoS . -
7.0
3.6
3to5 - -
58
13.2
5 to 7.5 6.2 5.00
5.8
24.0
73 to 10 5.6 4.93
5.4
14.4
10 to 15 4.9 5.03
5.0
10.3
15 to 20 - 4.56
20 to 50~ - 4.64
4.6
5.0
4.6
6.5
30 to 50 - 438
4.6
7.8
50 to 100 - 4.56
4.6
7.7
Over 100 - 4.63
4.6
73
Average applicable interest rate
5.29
Source: See text.
REDUCING THE CORPORATION INCOME
TAX PROPORTIONATELY
In order to discover the interest rate applicable to a cut in the
corporation income tax, we must first analyze its incidence. To
what extent is it passed on to consumers through lower prices and
to workers through higher wagçs? There is little evidence on these
questions. Coim argues 27 that the benefit of the reductions after
World War II accrued primarily to profits and, to some extent, to
wages, but that under less inflationary conditions more of the tax
cut would be passed on to consumers. Musgrave,ss in his study of
the incidence of taxation, assumes that 33 per cent of the tax is
passed on to consumers and 12 per cent to wage and salary earners,
leaving 55 per cent as the increase in corporate earnings. We adopt
his assumption for our tax cut.
estimate is increased by .61 percentage points to 5.9 per cent. This probably
overstates the effect, since the return to the investor is identical with the
return to the saver on a large part of the property incomes
Gerhard Colm, "The Corporation and the Corporation Income Tax in the
American Economy," American Economic Review, May 1954, p. 493.
~ Musgrave, Carroll, Cook, and Franc, op. cit., p. 16.
PAGENO="0119"
115
The interest rate applicable to the share of the tax cut benefiting
wage and salary earners can be derived from the distribution of this
form of income by income classes and our earlier estimates of
interest rates. Similarly, the part of the tax cut passed on to con~
sumers can be allocated to income classes in accordance with the
distribution of consumption, and then be combined with our
*interest rates. The rates derived from these computations, suim
marized in Table 16, are 5.81 per cent for wage and salary earners
and 5.68 per cent for consumers.
TABLE 16. Derivation of Interest Rates Applicable to the Shares for Wages and
Salaries and Consumption of a Reduction in the Corporation In*
come Tax
Per cent
Income dass distribution of
($ thousand) wages and salaries
Per cent
distribution of
consumption b
Applicable in.
terest °
(per cent)
Oto3 15
12
7.0
3to5 33
24
5.8
5 to 7.5 29
29
5.8
7.StolO 11
15
5.4
lOtolS 5
9
5.0
Over 15 7
11
4.6
Average applicable interest
rate (per cent) 5.81 5.68
Statistics of Income for 1952, op. cit., adjusted for 1955 conditions by apply.
ing the pattern of change of the distribution of personal income as reported in
Goldsmith, op. cit.
b Assumes average propensities to consume in the respective income brackets
as follows: 1.1 ,.96,.90,.82,.75, and .60. These propensities are taken from
M. Bronfenbrenner, et al., op. cit.; values for the four lower income classes are
based on Federal Reserve Board data for 1950; values of the two upper income
classes are from National Resources Committee data for 1935.6, adjusted upward
in accordance with the drift of the known portions of the consumption function.
C See Tables 7 and 15.
Part of the unshifted portion of the tax cut is passed on to divi~
dend recipients. We use the relationships between div~dends and
earnings established by Lintner to discover the share going to
dividends. He found that an increase in earnings will lead to a
gradual increase in dividends until the traditional payout ratio of
PAGENO="0120"
116
the firm has been restored.29 In the first year, dividends will rise
13.5 per cent of the increase in earnings; in subsequent years, the
same percentage of the gap between the dividend paid in the
:previous period and the.diyidend called for by the firm's traditional
payout ratio will be closed. For the country as a whole, the
average payout ratio was about .5030 in 1955, so a reduction of
the tax by $1.00 will increase dividends 13.50 in the first year,
23.40 in the second year, and so on until the increase would equal
500. An average of these payments over a period of 100 years-a
period corresponding to the economic life of water resource projects
-would be 470. So, of the 54 per cent of the tax cut which accrues
to increased profits, 47 per cent is passed on to dividend recipients.
The distribution of dividends by income classes is given in Table
17. Applying the interest rates derived earlier, we find that a rate
of 4.96 per cent is applicable to this portion of the tax cut.
These allocations leave 29 2 per cent of the tax cut as the increase
of retained earnings. How much will the investment of the taxed
firms increase as a result? To answer this question, we consider
* firms with assets greater than $10 million separately from smaller
firms. This division into "large" and "small" corporations is~
necessary because the influence of the availability of additional
* funds on investment varies sharply with the size of the enterprise.
We assume that 75 per cent of the tax is paid by large finns, 25
per cent by the rest 31
In regard to large corporations, Lmtner cites a number of reasons
J: Lintner, "Determinants of Corporate Savings," Chapter 14 in Savings in
the Modern Economy, W. Heiler, ed. (Minneapolis: University of Minnesota
Press, 1953); and Lintner, "Distribution of Incomes of Corporations among
Dividends, Retained Earnings and Taxes," American Economic Review, May
1956, pp. 97-113.
~ Statistics of Income for 1952, op. cit. The payout ratio of small corporations
is lower, and we assume a ratio of .35. This figure is an average of the payout
ratios by asset size, weighted by the distribution of tax payments, and allowing
for a gradual approach to the average ratio.
In 1951, corporations with assets over $10 million paid 70.4 per cent of the
tax (Statistics of Income for 1951, op. cit.). Figures for all corporations for
1951 are not yet available, but we can make a good estimate from the data on
manufacturing. In this sector, which pays two.thirds of the entire tax, the per.
centage. paid by large corporations rose from 76 to 82 per cent from 1951 to 1955.
Our estimate assumes a somewhat smaller increase of taxes paid by large corpora.
dons outside manufacturing.
PAGENO="0121"
117
TABLE 17. Derivation of interest Rate Applicable to the Share of Corporation
Income Tax Cut Benefiting Dividend Recipients
Income class Per cent
($ thousand) of di
distribution
vidends&
Interest rate b
(per cent)
OtoS
4
7.0
8to5
6
5.8
5to73
8
5.8
7.5tolO
7
5.4
lOtol5
11
5.0
15to20
2OtoSO
7
11
4.6.
4.6
.
30 to 50
5OtolOO
Over 100
Average applicable interest rate ..
13
14
19
4.6
4.6
4.6
.
4.96
a Statistics of Income for 1952, op. cit.
b See Table 15..
for believing that the effect on real investment will be small.82
Most corporations are forced to maintain a certain level of invest-
ment. Failure to expand capacity or to maintain a steady rate of
reduction of costs, by jeopardizing the firm's competitive position
in the industry, would pose a serious threat to its long-run future.
Investment for diversification, which is usually motivated by a
d~sire to reduce the variability of production levels and earnings,
would also be relatively immune to changes in tax rates. If inter-
nally generated funds are inadequate for these purposes, the firm
borrows. The effect on investment incentives caused by a tax rate
which takes away part of a firm's profits on successful ventures, is,.
to a large extent, offset by the government's bearing part of the
losses through reduced tax liability in the event of failure. Finally,
~J. Lintner, "Effects of Corporate Taxation on Real investment," American
Economic Review, May 1954, pp. 520~34. For an analysis of the effect of tax-
ation on the conditions of supply of capital see J. K. Butters, "Federal Income
Taxation and External vs. Internal Financing," Journal of Finance, September
1949, pp. 197.205. In . times of very tight money, the effect on internal invest-
ment will be larger, of course. For a somewhat stronger emphasis on liquidity
as an investment.determining variable, particularly in recessions, see J. Meyer
and E. Kuh, "Acceleration and Related Theories of Investment: An Empirical
Inquiry," Review of Economics and StatLstics, August 1955, pp. 217.80.
PAGENO="0122"
118
in many instances, the limit to a firm's rate of expansion is not set
* by the diminishing attractiveness of profit opportunities in relation
* to borrowing. costs, but rather by its supply of managerial per~
sonnel The firm undertakes as much investment as its staff can
handle successfully Lintner believes this analysis to be particularly
* applicable in periods of high employment. In depressions, firms
hesitate to borrow for fear of inability to repay, and the relationship
between the levels of taxation and of investment becomes much
* stronger. Since our analysis supposes that a successful stabilization.
policy precludes depression, we assume that an increase of retained
earnings of ~1.OO would lead to only 100 of added investment in
the firm. A rate of return of 21 per cent, the average rate of return
of large corporations in 1955 before taxes,33 is assumed for the
share~ of the tax cut that would be invested by the firm.
The liquidity of the large firm would be increased by the remain
ing 900 of increased retained earnings Firms with a sigmficant
* amount of debt would be able to lower it; firms which raise funds
by financing their accounts receivable could reduce this practice;
those which are creditors would be able to increase their financial
assets-consisting in~ the case of large corporations primarily of
government securities.34 Thus, the major share of the increase of
retained earnings would add primarily to that large pool of low-
interest, low-risk, relatively liquid capital into which excess corpora-
tion funds are channeled, and from which the loans of large
corporations, governments, and financial institutions are drawn.
An increase .in~ the supply of loanable funds in this market would
have several effects. To some extent, interest rates on low-risk
securities would fall and the severity of rationing would diminish,
leading to some increase of mortgages and perhaps even a small
This figure is derived as follows: 78 per cent of the tax cut goes to manu-
facturing, 17 per cent to utilities, and 5 per cent to trade. The average rate of
return of large corporations in manufacturing was 28.8 per cent (reported in
Quarterly Financial Report for Manufacturing Corporations, Fourth Quarter
1955, Federal Trade Commission and Securities and Exchange Commission,
Washington, April 1956). The rate for utilities was estimated directly from
prevalent standards of rate regulation to be equal to 10 per cent. The rate for
trade, which is equal to 20 per cent, assumes that it stood in the same ratio to
the rate in manufacturing as in 1952. (Figures for 1952 from SEC data.) A
weighted average yields our estimate. The concept of rate of return used by
the SEC may overstate the actual rate by 1 to 2 per cent.
`4C. E. Silberman, "The Big Corporate Lenders," Fortune, August 1956, p. 112~
PAGENO="0123"
119
increase of business borrowing. The effect of the drop in low-risk
interest rates would be gradually diffused through the credit struc-
ture, as banks and other financial institutions adapted their port-
folios to th~ changed pattern of interest yields. Because the primary
impact of an increased supply of funds is on the low-interest, low-
risk sector of the capital market, and only the spill-over occasioned
by secondary repercussions makes funds available to risky invest-
ments producing higher yields, we assume an average rate of 5 per
cent to apply to this part of our tax cut.
The investment behavior of small corporations is considerably
more sensitive than that of large corporations to changes in tax
rates.85 Companies with high growth potential are affected most
adversely by corporate taxes, which prevent internal accumulation
of the capital they need. External sources of long-term capital are
available to small companies only at high cost in terms of both
money and loss of control.36 The corporation income tax also
diminishes the attraction of risky investments, since a small firm is
*less likely to be able to take advantage of the loss-offset provisions
to reduce the tax liability on profitable operations. But the signi-
* ficance of these arguments should not be overstated. Not all small
business would grow rapidly in the absence of taxes; the need for
new capital of many companies is small and can be satisfied. A
recent survey of the Department of Commerce ~ found that of all
the firms in their sample, 56 per cent had no desire for outside
financing, 24 per cent obtained all the funds they desired, 13 per
cent obtained some, and only 7 per cent failed to obtain any. New
firms were somewhat less successful in raising capital and, most
significantly, it was the demand for long-term and, particularly, for
equity funds which failed to be met. On the basis of this evidence,
we assume that 50 per cent of the increase in retained earnings is
invested within the small firm; to this we assign a rate of 18 per
~ Lintner, "Effects of Corporate Taxation on Real Investment," o~ cit.,
p. 533.
For an analysis of the case of the growing firm, see J. K. Butters and J.
Lintner, Effect of Federal Taxes on Growing Enterprises (Boston: Graduate
School of Business Administration, Harvard University, 1945).
3'~ughlin F. McHugh and Jack N. Ciacco, "External Financing of Small and
Medium-Size Business," Survey of Current Business, op. cit., October 1955,
pp. 15-22 *
PAGENO="0124"
120
cent.ss The remaining 50 per cent, we assume, is used to reduce
bank loans or to purchase liquid assets, at a* rate of 5 per cent.
The computation for this form of tax cut is summarized in Table
18. The interest rate applicable to a reduction of the corporation
income tax is 5.59 per cent.89
TABLE 18. Summary of Derivation of Interest Rates Applicable to Proportion.
ate Reduction of Corporation Income Tax Payments
P
Incidence
er cent
of
tax cut
Applicable
interest rate
(per cent)
Shares of tax cut:
Shifted to consumers
Shifted to wage and salary earners .
Left as increased corporate earnings
33.3
12.5
54.2
5.68
5.81
~
Large corporations-Distribution of 75 per cent of
total increased corporate earnings:
47 per cent passed on in dividends
53 per cent retained as earnings of which
10 per cent invested in firm
90 per cent reduces debt or loaned in market....
.
19.1
2.2
19.4
4.96
21.00
5.00
Small corporations-Distribution of 25 per cent of
total increased corporate earnings:
35 per cent passed on in dividends
65 per cent retained as earnings, of which
50 per cent is invested in firm
50 per cent reduces debt or loaned in market....
Average ap~plicablé interest rate
4.7
.
4.4
4.4
4.96
~
18.00
5.00
.
~
5.59
Source: See text.
,
~` This rate is obtained as follows: In manufacturing, to which 54 per cent of
the tax cut accrues, the average rate of return of small corporations was 18
per cent in 1955 (Quarterly Financial Report, op. cit.,); for utilities, which pay
9 per cent of the tax, the rate is about 10 per cent; and in trade, which pays
18 per cent of the tax, the rate is 20 per cent (footnQte 33). The remaining 19
per cent of the tax cut goes to finance, services, and construction; we assume
that the average rate for small corporations applies here. A weighted average
of these rates yields our estimate.
Again making an allowancç of 3 per cent for the return accruing to the
investors of the additional personal savings, our estimate is raised by .24 per-
centage points to 5.83 per cent. Were we to assume an extra return of 3 per
cent on the funds made available to the capital market by corporations as well,
PAGENO="0125"
121
Combining this estimate with the interest rate of 5.29 per cent
for the proportionate reduction of personal income taxes, we derive
an over-all estimate for Model B of 5.44 per cent.
interpretation of Our Results
The estimates of opportunity costs derived from our two models
were quite similar, although the assumed changes in taxation were
very different. This suggests that a value of the order of magnitude
of our derived results could serve as a measure of the social cost of
capital for federal investment. But before accepting this conclu-
sion, it is necessary to examine possible errors in the assumptions
and in the data of our quantitative analysis.
ACCURACY AND LIMITATIONS
A possible source of error is our analysis of the incidence and
effects of taxation. Insofar as possible, we have tried to follow the
views generally held by experts in this field. Changes in most of
our assumptions would have only a moderate effect on the results.
Experiments with somewhat different assumptions of incidence
produced estimates similar to those obtained. Two exceptions,
however, would upset our results. First, if it is assumed that a
reduction in* the corporation income tax will lead to an upsurge of
investment by large corporations, then more of the tax cut would
earn the high rates of profit which are prevalent. We have tried
to show, however, that this effect is unlikely under the assumed
economic condition of high employment. Second, it can be argued
that the high levels of federal taxation lead to a large waste of
economic resources caused both by the managerial efforts devoted
to the tax problem and the distortions in economic decisions of
firms and households resulting from a desire to avoid taxes. These
considerations are not likely to have much relevance to the problem
under study here because the magnitudes of the possible tax reduc-
tion are so small compared to the taxes which are needed to finance
the total estimate would rise to 639 per cent. In times of moderate monetary
policy, the condition postulated for our analysis, these effects would not be of
the magnitude indicated here.
PAGENO="0126"
122
defense and other programs. Our result is meant to apply .only~ to
small tax cuts.4°
The rates of return which we assumed are another possible
source of error. Through parts of the analysis, average rates were
used to approximate marginal rates of return. Households were
assumed to add to their assets in such proportion that the average
rate of return of their property incomes would remain constant.
For any one firm or household that is not likely to be a good
approximation; but for large aggregates the error will be smaller.
The typical household will not hold assets in the proportions of
the group average; some households will make investments in
their own business, others in common stocks, others in real estate-
depending upon the experience of the head of the household and
the; opportunities to which he has access. Additional funds are
likely to be put into the household's major form of asset. With the
tax cut spread over all households in the income class, the money
is likely to be invested proportionately to total holdings.
Similarly, business was assumed to make its additional invest-
ments at a rate equal to its average rate of return. In the case of
industry, the tax cut is diffused over successful and marginal firms
in many fields. This does not rule out a systematic bias between
marginal and average rates, but the direction of bias is not clear.
On the onehand, extra funds must go into investment opportunities
~ We have made no allowance for effects originating in rounds of re.spending
subsequent to the economic units on whom the initial impact falls. The
increase in disposable income due to a tax reduction will have multiplier
effects on the incomes of others, of course, but we have assumed that a cor-
rectly managed fiscal and monetary policy offsets these multiplier effects.
Nevertl~eless, the multiplier effects and their policy offsets will lead to some
redistribution of income, and it is logically possible that there are systematic
differences between the time preferences of the gainers and the losers of this
redistribution. This would affect our estimate. But since both the initial reper-
cussions and their offsets are diffused more or less randomly through the
economy, it is most unlikely that there will be systematic. differences between
the two groups in this regard. Further, the similarity of our estimates for
* different taxes argues that if there are systematic differences in the two groups
with regard to important economic characteristics, the effect on the social cost
of capital will still be small. For a full discussion of these effects, see A. H.
Conrad The Multiplier Effects of Redistributive Public Budgets Review of
Economzcs and Statzsttcs, May 1955 pp 160 73 also see M Bronfenbrenner
Taro Yamane, and C. H. Lee, "A Study in Redistribution and Consumption."
ibid pp 149 59
PAGENO="0127"
123
which are considered marginal in comparison to the opportunities
that are undertaken without the tax cut. On the other, new invest-
ment opportunities may yield generally higher returns than the
reported average, for old and new capital. Also, business will not
undertake .any investment unless the expected rate of return meets
minimum standards that are sufficiently high actually to yield an
adequate return for the particular kind of investment. Finally it
should be stressed that most of Model A and a' large part of Model
B do not use this approximation. .
Our results are not meant to apply in periods of serious inflation.
or. depression. In an inflationary period, monetary'policy is likely
to be pursued ~with such vigor that the supply of~ investible funds
to firms will be severely restricted, while the attractiveness of high
returns on investments will exercise strong pressure to invest any
funds that become available; Under these conditions, the increase
in retained earnings made possible by a reduction in the corporation
income tax would, in large part, lead to investment, within the
firm. Since large corporations tend to earn high~rates of return on
internal investments, the interest rate applicable .~ such a tax .cut
would be considerably higher than our estimates. Even the, reduc-
tions in personal taxes are quite likely to have significant invest-
ment effects. For in periods of money shortage, when there is
sharp competition among borrowers for funds, more personal
savings are likely to find their way. into business uses in which high
rates of return prevail
In years of depression when government expenditures are
designed to raise the total level of effective demand in order to
employ idle resources, the social cost of capital is extremely low
Tax policy, in such periods, would endeavor' to tax idle hoards of
funds rather than money which would be spent for' consumption
or investment, and much of public expenditures would be financed
by government loans designed to avoid competition with private
demands for investible funds In real terms, many of the resources
absorbed by public investment would have been idle and, hence,
.would have an opportunity cost close to zero. Expressed `as an
interest rate it is not at all inconceivable that the social cost of
public capital would be negative in such circumstances
The year 1955, for which our estimate was derived, can be con
sidered. typical of long-term conditions, however... Employment was
high, though not to a point where inflation had set in Fiscal and
PAGENO="0128"
124
monetary policies were moderate, endeavoring to keep the economy
within a narrow range of balance, without drastic inflationary or
deflationary measures. Consumer indebtedness reached an all-time
high, but the strong upward trend in the use of credit suggests that
the debt position of 1955 will be typical for future years.
How wide then is the range of error of our estimates? We believe
that the actual level lies within a range of 1 per cent of our esti-
mates for the general economic conditions postulated for our
analysis. This statement is based both on judgment and upon
experiments in which those assumptions most open to question
were varied. Combining all reasonable assumptions that would raise
the rate yields an estimate of 7 per cent; conversely, all plausible
assumptions that would produce a low rate yield an estimate of 5
per cent. It is our conclusion that the probable value for the
economic conditions postulated lies between 5 and 6 per cent~
AN ALTERNATIVE A TIGHTER MONETARY POLICY
So far, our analysis has assumed that the expenditures for water'
resource projects would be offset by taxation sufficient to preserve
balance in the economy. Let us also consider briefly the case where
monetary rather than tax policy is used to restore equilibrium.
An expansion of the federal program would then have to be offset
by a tightening of monetary policy of sufficient degree to release
the quantity of resources needed for the program. To estimate the
`social cost Of capital under this assumption, it is necessary to
discover which. economic activities would be curtailed by the
diminished supply of credit.
It is unlikely that a change in monetary policy would be a per-
mánent method of compensating for, a change in expenditures,
because this would reduce the remaining potential of this stabiliz-
ing weapon. But the initial offset might well be in this form,
subsequently to be converted into a change of tax rates.
We shall not undertake a full-scale quantitative effort to measure
the incidence of monetary policy. The kinds of assumptions
required would be considerably more arbitrary than those of our
tax study, and the rates of return that would be earned by the
marginal borrowers to whom credit would be denied could not be
estimated with sufficient accuracy. However, we can get some idea
PAGENO="0129"
125
of the order of magnitude by listing the sectors affected by mone-
tary policy and the rates of return prevailing in them.
Bank loans are the traditional, perhaps most important, form of
credit that can be reduced through monetary policy. Loans to
business, which totaled $31 billion in 1955, were made at nominal
average rates of 4.2 per cent.41 While we cannot estimate what
rates of return would have been earned on curtailed loans, we
know that the rate expected by the borrower must be at least 4.2
per cent. And it is probably more, in view of the somewhat higher
interest rates charged to marginal borrowers and the return above
borrowing cost which must be expected as an incentive to take the
risk of the investment. Loans to individuals totaled $17 billion
and were made at a wide range of rates-from as low as 4.5 per
cent to over 10 per cent, depending upon the purpose, the col-
lateral, and the credit worthiness of the individual. The marginal
loans that would be refused because of a tighter monetary policy
would have borne rates well above the minimum of the range.
The market for mortgages would also be tightened by monetary
policy,, both thtough a toughening of the terms and diminished
availability of funds. Total outstanding mortgages were in excess
of $130 billion, but the impact of the policy is concentrated on
only a portion of the market. The rates on this category of credit
largely fall between ~½ and 6 per cent and would apply to the
mortgages that are precluded by the change in the monetary policy
necessitated by a public investment. Debt issues of state and local
governments would be curtailed, bearing very low interest rates,
but often used to finance investments yielding higher returns, e.g.,
schools, hospitals, etc. Oth~r forms of credit-such as brokers' loans
on securities, corporate borrowing from sources other than banks,
etc.-would also bear part of the impact, but the effect would be
less important quantitatively.
These figures suggest that the social cost of federal capital raised
in this manner is roughly of the same order of magnitude as the
cost of releasing the necessary resources through taxation. Depend-
ing upon the exact combination of weapons employed by the
~ "Business Loans of Member Banks," Federal Reserve Bulletin, o~. cit.,
April 1956, pp. 328-40. This rate makes no allowance for the common practice
of requiring minimum account balances, which raises the effective rate of the
loan by as much as 1 per cent.
98-940 O-68-----9
PAGENO="0130"
126
monetary authorities and the circumstances at the time, the rate
* might be somewhat higher or lower; but the difference in cost
under: the two types of policies is moderate. The extent to which
* the resources will be drawn out of investment rather than con-
*sumption will differ more broadly, however.
AN ALTERNATIVE: SEPARATING RISI(-BEARING -
FROM PURE INTEREST
So far, we have treated risk as a source of market imperfection,
and have considered differences in interest rates caused by varying
risk premiums to lead to a misallocation of resources. In the model
we employ, a correct allocation of resources would require that the
rate of return on marginal investments of all kinds be the same. If
* it were not, the total return could be increased by switching invest-
ments from fields with low marginal returns to fields with higher
returns. In - the real world, where there are differences in risk, a
higher return is expected to prevail on the riskier investments, with
--part of this higher return a risk premium. This is a -reward -for
taking risks, and may be needed to attract capital into risky uses
Yet our model would consider such differences inefficient we
-assume that the riskiness of - the returns on an investment do not
detract from their contribution to real national income. That is,
:: the satisfaction derived from- the national output is -independent -
of the total amount of risk taken on the nation s investments
In the context of public investments, there is considerable justifi
cation for this assumption From the point of view of the economy
as a whole, the risks on investment are far smaller than the sum of
risks of individual investments Where one undertaking in one
locality may fall far short of its expected outcome, other under
- takings will succeçd beyond expectations, and to some extent the
- - failure of some assures the success of others. There is much can-
cellation of risks since the insurance principle of -pooling reduces
greatly the relative dispersion of outcomes for the nation's invest-
ment program as a whole. And, from the point of view of the
long-run growth of the country, the increase of national income
produced by risky investments on which a high return is to be
earned, whatever the reason, will be greater than the increase of
income to be expected from low-risk, low-return investments. - -
PAGENO="0131"
127
There are other reasons for adhering to our model's assumption.
First, the empirical evidence on the relationship between risk-
taking and individual welfare is scanty and unconvincing While
people purchase insurance to reduce risk, they also gamble.42
Second, and more important, there are two very strong institutional
factors in our economy which erode the relationship between high
* risk an4 high return~ One is the giant corporation which under-
takes so many investments that there is much pooling of risks
within its own program The suppliers of the corporation s capital
bear only a fraction of the sum of risks of the individual invest-
ment projects, and the same is true of the company itself. The
other institutional factor is our tax system, which makes risky
investments particularly attractive to wealthy individuals since
* they. usually lead to capital gains rather than ordinary income.
With much the largest part of the investable funds made availablç
by personal sources43 coming from taxpayers in the upper brackets,
the differential between tax rates on capital gains and on ordinary
income promotes the willingness to take risks to such an extent that
the difference between the rates of return of risky and secure
investments must be much diminished
Let us briefly consider the cost of capital if risk premiums are
treated as prices paid for the factor service of risk bearing Lenders
are assumed to be rational in this respect, and the risk premium of
a loan must be sufficient to compensate for the risk which is taken
On this assumption, a federal loan which displaces a risky private
`loan and invests the proceeds in a risk free project would entail
a lower social cost than the alternative since there is a reduction
in risk bearing If we make the bold assumption that all differ
ences in interest rates for the same period are risk premiums, then
it might be argued that the true social cost of a risk-free federal
investment is the pure interest rate alone-a rate which is prob-
ably best approximated by the yield on federal securities with a
tei~m equal to the life of. the investment.
~ Cf M Friedman and L J Savage The Utility Analysis of Choices Involv
ing Risk Journal of Political Economy, August 1948 pp 279 304 and F
Mosteller and P Nogee An Experimental Measurement of Utility ibid,
October 1951, pp. 371-405. *
~ For a full discussion of this point, see J. K. Butters, L. E. .Thom~son, and
L. L. Boilinger, Effects of Taxation, investment by individuals, (Boston:.. Gradu.
PAGENO="0132"
128
Actual resource projects are not free of risks, however. Where
outputs are marketable, there is no assurance that the expected
revenues will be collected; even in the case of nonmarketable out-
puts, such as recreation and flood control, there is no guarantee
that the expected benefits will actually accrue. In the case of water
resource projects, there are always the risks caused by meteorologic
and hydrologic uncertainties. Yields on government securities do
not reflect these risks, since the federal taxing power stands behind
the bonds and any losses on projects will be paid out of taxes.
To discover a risk premium which reflects individual willingness
to bear risks, we would need to estimate the cost of raising money
for water resource projects that would be incurred by a public
corporation unable to employ, the taxing power to guarantee its
securities. The cost of financing some of the purposes, such as
navigation, electric power, and municipal water supply, would be
similar to the cost incurred by private utilities, since the service
and the risk is almost the same. These companies typically could
raise capital at an average cost of 4.5 per cent in l955,~~ which
serves as a first approximation for these purposes. The financing of
irrigation would, in part, depend upon the securitr of the repay-
ment contracts and, in part, on the likelihood that the settlers
would realize the projected benefits. Nonreimbursable purposes,
such as flood control, for which there are no comparable private
industries, are subject to the risk that benefits will not be fully
realized. To impute risk premiums for these purposes, we would
need to take account of the fact that in some instances, particularly
in the case of flood control, the projects also serve to reduce risks-
a factor which should lower the interest rate. We shall not venture
an estimate. Suffice it to say that, taking the water resource pro-
gram as a whole, the interest rate derived from these assumptions
would be well above the pure rate of interest as measured by the
long-term government bond rate, but would be far below the
highest rates prevailing in the private economy.
ate School of Business Administration, Harvard University, 1958) especially
Chapters 2,4.7, 9, 10, and 17.
~ This assumes 50 per cent of the funds to come from bonds paying 3.22 per
cent, 15 per cent from preferred stock paying 4.25 per cent, and 35 per cent
from common stock with an earnings price ratio of 6.5 per cent. All figures
are net of taxes. For a more detailed discussion of these figures see Chapter'
vu, Table 88.
PAGENO="0133"
129
A FINAL COMMENT
Our statistical analysis has provided an estimate which is designed
to reflect the social cost of capital raised by federal taxation We
defined our concept of social cost in terms of the opportunities
foregone in the private sector of the economy, either because of
curtailed investment or of curtailed consumption According to
our results, if an efficient allocation of resources is the criterion,
only those public investments that can produce a rate of return
equal to the opportunity cost-or a rate of 5 to 6 per cent-should
be undertaken In operational terms, this would require that an
interest rate of that order be used in the evaluation of projects.
Acceptance of this conclusion, however requires that the exact
meaning of the notion of efficiency in this context be made clear.
As we pointed out in Chapter II, efficiency is a relative concept
dependent on a specific distribution of income. An arrangement
which is efficient with one distribution of income may be inefficient.
with another The set of demands resulting from one income
distribution will not be identical with the demands generated by a
different income distribution, and so the prices which lead to
efficiency in one case will not be appropriate to the other.
In considering the efficiency of an interest rate this inter
dependence takes on particular significance The interest rate
indicates the relative value of output realized at different points in
time including the relative values for different generations When
we accept an interest rate determined by the preferences of the
present generation-as we do in our quantitative models-we
implicitly accept the time preference of the present generation of
decision makers Children and unborn generations have no vote
in the market place. `With the power of the ballot distributed
differently from the power of the purse, the community-when
acting collectively through the political process-may decide on a
distribution of consumption among generations different from the
distribution it indicates through its saving behavior There is no
logical reason to give priority to one judgment over the other, our
economic analysis must presuppose that the distribution of income
and consumption implicit in the efficient allocation of resources
is acceptable to society Should an ethical choice be made through
the political process to distribute more of the total consumption to
future generations, our opportunity cost measure of the interest
PAGENO="0134"
130
rate would cease to be a proper indicator of social value. A lower
interest rate might lead to a larger number of projects, would
favor projects which are particularly long-lived, and would
lead to the fuller development of the potential of many project
opportunities.
The decision not to abide by the market judgment need not be
based entirely on ethical considerations. As we have seen earlier,
the capital market is imperfect because of the riskiness of invest-
ment and for various institutional reasons. Also, because of
imperfect perception of future circumstances and the uncertainties
surrounding individual lives, it is less likely that consumers make
their saving-borrowing decisions as rationally as their choices
among commodities. Consequently, the actual intertemporal
choices in our economy, including the determination of the over-all
level of saving and investment, are made in a rather haphazard
manner.45
These arguments provide a point of contact between economic
analysis and conservationist philosophy. Most of the policies advo-
cated in the name of conservation are designed to make stronger
provision for the future than the market mechanism would call for.
Resource development is a particularly potent area for the kind of
investment designed to benefit future generations. There are
opportunities for development of extremely enduring, in some
cases perpetual, additions to the nation's capital stock, which will
increase in value as population and the economy grow. It may well
be that the desire to redistribute income toward future generations
can provide some rationale for continued use of a low interest rate.
But this line of argument has limitations. Insofar as a low
interest rate leads to the justification of some projects at the
expense of others which can produce a better return, the rate will
result in a social loss even within water resource fields. Also, if the
fundamental objective is the redistribution of income toward the
future, the critical variable is not so much the. interest rate as the
over-all level of investment.46 The best policy to meet this objec-
~` It is not clear whether the actual level of saving is higher or lower than
the ideal (defined in terms of the judgment of the present generation). On the
one hand the large gap between borrowing and lending rates indicates that
the level is too low on the other the saving carried on by corporations may
far exceed the level desired by their stockholders. .
~ For a fuller discussion of this point, see Otto Eckstein, "Investment Criteria
PAGENO="0135"
131
tive is to increase the amount invested every year and to put the
funds into those lines of activity in which the rate of return is
greatest. In this way, the contribution to future output is maxi-
mized and, should the time profile of output made possible by the
investment place too much of the output in early years, an appro-
priate share of it can be reinvested. A series of reinvestment cycles,
each at a high rate of return will make a greater contribution to
the welfare of future generations than investment in one very
durable project which yields a low rate of return. It may be
possible that the federal government is limited in the~ fields in
which it can employ the desired extra investment that resource
projects yielding low rates of return must be undertaken because
of a lack of better opportunities But this argument holds only
if the additional ethical judgment is made that the extra investment
must be carried on under federal aegis
There are other reasons for using a low interest rate. It may be
a means of subsidizing new regions in a manner designed to pro-
mote their growth to maturity. In some instances, the low interest
rate helps to justify projects needed as stand-by capacity for defense
purposes. Or it may be a means of increasing the economy's rate
of growth for the sake of preserving a lead over the Russian
economy. But in these situations, the low interest rate serves to
obscure the true issues. The public~ will be better informed and
will be able to come to a more soundly based judgment if the
costs of meeting these purposes are made explicit
We present a brief formal derivation of the model employed to
measure the social cost of capital drawn from consumption
Let C1 = consumption expenditure of individual 1 in the present
period,
S1 = net saving of 1 in the present period,
= disposable income of 1 in the present period,
= interest rate faced by 1 for his marginal saving-borrowing
decisions,
for Economic Development and the Theory of Intertemporal Welfare Eco-
nomics," Quarterly Journal of Economics, February 1957.
Note to Chapter IV
PAGENO="0136"
132
and A1 = perpetual future consumption stream that 1 can enjoy.
Two identities are implicit in these definitions
(1) Y~ = C1 + S1, and
(2) i1~S1.= M1.
The identity (2) defines the rate at which saving produces a future
consumption stream. We assume a utility function
(3) U1 = U1 (C1,A ~),
which reflects l's present valuation of current consumption and con-
sumption in the future. He maximizes his utility function subject
to his income and interest constraints. This is equivalent to maxi-
mizing the Lagrangean expression
(4) ~ = U1 (C1,A1) - A (71-C1--S1) ~ (i1i.~S1-M1),
which has the first-order maximum conditions
au1
(5) -+A=O, A-~i1=O, and -+~=O.
Therefore,
au1 au1
(6) = ~ and = -~, and so
au1
ac1
(7) -~-~y-- = Zj, or ~- =
aA1
A change in taxation is a change in disposable income, part of
which will change consumption, part saving. Thus,
(8) i~Y1 = ~C1 + ~
and the change in l's utility is
(9) ~U1 = ~-~- ~, +
neglecting higher order terms on the grounds that they will be of
the second order of smalls. (9) is equivalent to
PAGENO="0137"
133
au1
(10) t~U~ j~ ~ + i~ ~ or
au1
(11) ~ =
We define a Social Welfare Function for all the individuals 1 in the
economy
(12) W=Z~ U;
Then
(13) t~W~ = i~ ~ where c refers to costs.
We assume that is the same for all individuals and equal to
the arbitrary constant a Then
(14) ~ = a ~; z1t~Y1
i~W~ measures the costs in the analysis. The benefits are a flow of
future annual income accruing to various individuals, or
(15) B = X1i~B1
Assuming the value of marginal future income the same for bene~
ficiaries as for taxpayers, we have
(16) i~Wb=~;t~Bj.
In order for a project to represent a favorable economic change,
the value of benefits must exceed the value of costs, or £~Wb > ~
This requires
(17) aZ;L~B; >aZ;i;~Y;. S
This inequality is unaffected by the value for a. For convenience,
let a = 1. Then the criterion becomes
(18) ~ i~B1 > ~ z~ ~Y1 or
(19) 1
Use of the interest rate that our analysis seeks to estimate for
benefit cost analysis is equivalent to criterion (19) We have esti
PAGENO="0138"
134
mated ~ ; the benefitcost criterion then becomes
(20) >1,
Zi iij~~~~y' ~i
which is identical to (19).
PAGENO="0139"
ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF PUBLIC INVESTMENT DECI-
SIONS: INTEREST RATE POLICY AND DISCOUNTING
ANALYSIS
THURSDAY, AUGUST 1, 1968
CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES,
S1JBCOMMITTEE ON ECONOMY IN GOVERNMENT
OF THE JOINT ECONOMIC C0MMITrEE,
Washington, D.C.
The subcommittee met, pursuant to notice, at 10 a.m., in room 5-407,
the Capitol, Hon. William Proxmire (chairman of the subcommittee)
presiding.
Present: Chairman Proxmire.
Also present: John B. Stark, executive director; Robert H. Have-
man, economist; and Douglas C. Frechtling, minority economist.
Chairman PROXMIRE. The committee will come to order.
As I said yesterday, this is an unfortunate time of year for hearings
because Members of the House and Senate are busy winding things up
and others are in Miami, Fla., winding other things up. At any rate,
I am delighted with the quality of the hearings so far. We delayed the
beginning of the hearings this morning a little bit, waiting for the
statements. I had not seen your statement, Mr. Lynn, but I have it
here now.
This is the final session in the current series of hearings on the
interest rate and discounting procedures in Federal agencies. These
have been most helpful hearings for a number of reasons. We have
heard the announcement and rationale for a proposed new interest
rate procedure for water resource agencies.
We have heard proposals for implementing consistent, across-the-
board interest rate and discounting procedure in all Federal agencies.
it has been recommended that a base risk-free interest rate be pub-
lished on an on-going basis as a guide to all analysts of public invest-
ments.
All of these are important steps in the implementation of a sound
planning-programing-budgeting system in the Federal Government.
Indeed, it is becoming increasingly clear as the demands on the
Federal budget grow that Congress requires the guidance of compe-
tent economic analysis of proposed expenditures. It is only with such
guidance that we in the legislative branch can rationally choose among
alternatives rather than apply the wasteful meat ax to the budget.
This morning we will hear the statements of representatives of three
Federal agencies. We welcome Assistant Secretary Mackey of the De-
partment of Transportation, Assistant Secretary Enthoven of De-
fense, and Dr. Laurence Lynn, who is his deputy, and Dr. Robert Le-
vine, Assistant Director of the Office of Economic Opportunity.
(135)
PAGENO="0140"
136
They will discuss with us the use of discounting in their agencies
and their suggestions for the improvement of discounting and interest
rate policy throughout the Federal Government?
Mr. Enthoven, you may proceed.
STATEMENT OP ALAIN ENTHOVEN, ASSISTANT SECRETARY OP
DEFENSE, OYFICE OF SYSTEMS ANALYSIS
Mr. ENTHOVEN. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman. I very much
appreciate the opportunity to take part in these hearings, which I
think are performing a very valuable public service.
DISCOUNTING PROCEDURES AND INTEREST RATE PoLicY IN FEDERAL
DEPARTMENTS AND AGENCIES
In the Department of Defense we now use analyses of military
effectiveness in relation to cost ("cost-effectiveness analysis") regu-
larly as one of the factors considered in reaching program decisions.
however, we emphasize analysis as an aid to judgment and not as a
substitute for it. Thus, discounting calculations, when they are used,
are but one of the factors to be judged in the total context of decision.
In our cost-effectiveness analysis we use discounting-or accumu-
lated interest charges as I now prefer to look at it-selectively as an
analytical tool. In some cases, the time profiles of expenditures of the
alternatives under consideration are not significantly different from
each other. In such cases we don't include interest charges; rather, we
focus. attention on the significant differences that do exist among the
alternatives. In other cases, however, the time profiles of expenditures
do differ significantly. In such cases, we do introduce cumulative in-
terest charges in comparing costs and in designing "equal cost" alter-
natives.
I have found that the easiest way to explain the commonsense of
discounting is to pomt out that it is equivilent to adding a cumulative
interest charge to the cost of Government programs. When comparing
two systems, each of which will provide a desired level of military
effectiveness, we believe that the system which involves extra invest-.
ment today should produce enough savings later on to pay .off both
principal and interest. Discounting future costs back .to present values
is frequently misunderstood and is sometimes erroneously used in
such a way as to make the cost of particular programs look smaller. By
showing how interest charges add up over time, the basic issue is much
more easily grasped.
As for the question of what interest rate to use, available evidence.
suggests that the opportunity cost of resources used by the Govern-
ment in our economy is in the 5-10 percent range, though I realize that
the conceptual and empirical difficulties. involved in coming up with
such estimates are very great.
In my judgment, 10 percent is a sensible choice for us in the Depart-
ment of Defense, first because it is close to t.he best available estimates
of the opportunity cost.of capital and, second, because our investments
in new weapons are both very large and subject to great technical and
strategic risks. . .
The fact that the before tax yields on many private investments are
PAGENO="0141"
137
sithstantially higher than 10 percent reflects a substantial compensa-
tion for their riskiness. I believe it is reasonable for us to make at
least a modest allowance for risk in our interest rate calculations.
However, I think that in our analysis we should treat the uncer-
tainties explicitly and not merely fold them into a higher target
rate of return. This makes it possible for the uncertainties to be judged
explicitly by the official responsible for making the decisions.
I would like to give my full support to the establishment of a
consistent discount rate policy for evaluating Federal investment,
though I recognize the basic discount rate used throughout the Federal
Government may not need to be as high as 10 percent.
The issues involved in choosing an appropriate discount rate con-
cept and a correct discount rate are extremely complex, a fact which
is borne out both in the economic literature on the subject and in the
recent testimony before this committee. The basic point, however, is
quite straightforward: The resources used by the Government in its
investment projects can also be used productively by private con-
sumers and investors. Whether the Government raises its funds by
taxation or by borrowing, some consumers must forgo consumption
opportunities which, since they already pass up risk-free investments
offering 5 percent interest, must be worth at least 5 percent to them,
and some investors must forgo in investment opportunities which
return 10-20 percent before taxes.
Government agencies should take these opportunity costs into ac-
count when calculating the costs of their projects and determining
their value to society.
I believe that the rate that is used should not be biased either for or
against Government investments.
Adopting a sensible interest rate policy should have two desirable
results: First, it should lead to a more rational allocation of resources
between the private economy and the public sector; second, it should
encourage the proponents of investment projects to design them specifi-
cally to achieve high rates of return.
Discounting should be much more than a mechanical procedure for
weighing future costs and benefits. Project designers should recog-
nize that features that do not pay their way in significantly increased
benefits or reduced costs should be left out. If they do, the Govern-
ment will have a menu of much more productive investment alterna-
tives to choose from.
Proper discounting is only one aspect of good analysis, however.
If the analyses underlying investment proposals are poorly conceived,
or if benefit and cost estimates are faulty, discounting is unlikely
to lead to better decisions. As a practical matter, the use of discount-
ing will probably place an even greater premium on competent analy-
sis. If programs must be justified against tougher cost-benefit criteria,
great care must be taken to insure that benefit and cost concepts
and estimates are sound.
I think this committee is performing a valuable service by surfacing
the discounting problem and promoting rational debate on the com-
plex issues involved: I appreciate the opportunity to support the com-
mittee's objectives.
Thank you, sir.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Thank you, Mr. Enthoven.
PAGENO="0142"
138
Our next witness is Mr. Lynn.
Mr. Lynn, you have a substantial statement, I see. We would be
delighted to have you summarize it or present it in any way you see fit
STATLELMENT OP LAURENCE E. LYNN, JR, DEPUTY ASSISTANT SEC
RETARY OP DEPENSE (ECONOMICS AND RESOURCE ANALYSIS)
Mr LYNN Mr Chairman, I would like to read comments from my
statement to support Dr. Enthoven's testimony.
The commonsense of using an interest rate concept in government
investment decisions is this: The Government should obtain a rate
of return on its investments at least as large as the value of the con-
sumption and investment, opportunities private citizens must give up.
Therefore, the Government should assess itself an interest charge
on the, funds it needs that is equal to the opportunity cost of these
funds to private consumers and investors
Returns to Government investments should be large enough to cover
both principal and interest. If the Government ignores these oppor-
tunity costs and undertakes project with relatively low rates of return,
then society as a whole-public and private-is not receiving the
maximum attainable value from it.s resources; the general welfare
will be lower than it could be. In fact, Government agencies should
deliberately design their investment projects with their `rate of return
in mind
Establishing and enforcing appropriate discounting procedures
should not only lead to wiser investment decisions but encourage the
design and development of better investment projects as well.
An important analytical question is, how should the Government
be assumed to finance its new projects, and how do consumers and
investors share in providing the resources; that is, how does one
define and measure opportunity costs ~
I believe that the Government can be assumed to finance its activ-
ities out of tax revenues and that in the long run, the alternative to
more: Government spending is lower taxes, not less borrowing. The
amount the Government plans to borrow each year should be assumed
to be;determined mainly by how much the Government wants to stim-
ulate or restrain aggregate demand by varying the size of its deficit
or surplus, not necessarily by the level and composition of Government
investments.
It is sometimes argued that the discount rate should be reduced in
those periods in which resources are unemployed and their opportunity
cost is, therefore, zero As a pr'tctical matter, discount rate procedures
~hou1d not be manipulated to reflect highly changeable circumstances
such as the extent and nat.ure of unemployment. When the Government
desires to stimulate private economic activity, it will want to expand
investments earning the highest rates of return, not seek low return
projects. If there aren't enough of these high payoff projects, an explicit
judgment can always be made to finance projects with relatively low
returns as calculated by the usual methods.
In 1958, Prof. Otto Eckstein, who appeared before you yesterday,
estimated the reduction in private consumption, private investment,
housing, and, other types of investment when the Government obtains
PAGENO="0143"
139
resources through taxation. At that time, his estimate of the opportu-
nity cost of public capital obtained through taxation was about 6 per-
cent. However, in private correspondence, and I believe here yesterday,
he indicated that usrng current data with his model would yield a cost
estimate of about 8 percent.
Other investigators have calculated the cost of capital to the Govern-
ment by assuming that the Government borrows the necessary funds
They have estimated that the cost of borrowed capital is signifi-
cantly higher than the interest yield on Government bonds: Because
Government borrowing displaces private investment to a significant
extent, the Government forgoes the taxes it would collect on the re-
turns to these investments. Tlis cost to the Government must, be added
to the Government bond yield, less the taxes the Go%ernment collects
on this yield, to come up with the right opportunity cost.
Working along these lines, the GAO estimated that Government
borrowing costs may be as high as 7 to 8 percent, and other investiga-
tors have estimated it at closer to 10 percent. There are some problems
with interpreting these calculations as opportunity costs, but I think
the important thing to recognize is that both the tax models and the
borrowing models economists have used have produced similar esti-
mates of the opportunity cost of public capital, answers which are
in the 7 to 10 percent range. I believe that further research along these
lines will support this result, since both taxing and borrowing affect
both consumption and investment to a significant degree.
Up to this point, the discussion has been in terms of undifferentiated
Government investments whose costs and benefits can in principle be
measured. In fact, there are many different types of Government in-
vestments, and for many of them it is difficult or impossible to meas-
ure or compare the value of `the benefits, even in principle. For
example, it is impossible to put a monetary value on' the benefits of
investment in a new defense weapon system.. It is not possible, even
in principle, to develop a market test of the volume of assured destruc-
tion capability against the Soviet Union or our ability to defeat
Warsaw Pact tactical air forces in conventional combat in Europe,
still less to put a monetary value on improvements in those capabilities.
In situations where there is no market test of benefits, two types of
analyses must be done. First, should we buy the capability, however
we measure the benefits? Secondly, which of the alternative ways of
providing this capability should we choose ~
Since this is the characteristic type of problem encountered in the
Defense Department, it is worth discussing how we do it in more
detail..
Typically we measure the benefits or effectiveness of our invest-
ments against some criterion of military need. For airlift and sealift
investments, for example, the need is expressed in terms of the desired
schedules for moving forces to where they may be needed. For tactical
air investments, one way the need can be ex~pressed is in terms of
delivering ordnance to a target system, against expected opposition, in
sufficient quantity to destroy a certain percentage of the targets. We
set up tests of effectiveness like this in each mission area, using perhaps
several different measures of effectiveness. Deciding whether Or not
additional investments should be undertaken involves complex judg-
ments about the value of the extra effectiveness relative to its cost
PAGENO="0144"
140
But in choosing among alternative ways of achieving a given level
of effectiveness, however, formal analysis has an important role to
play, and the proper use of discounting is an important part of the
analysis. We are concerned to know which alternative will provide
the desired effectiveness for the lowest total cost, over the relative
lifetime of the projects.
Alternatively, we may be interested in knowing which of several
equal cost alternatives gives us the most for our money.
The question arises here as in cost-benefit analyses as to whether
costs in different years should be equally weighted and the answer
is no. We should not be indifferent between programs which involve
high outlays today and programs the costs of which are spread more
evenly in time. Because the differences in cost among the alternatives
have an opportunity cost to the private economy, an appropriate inter-
est rate should be charged in estimating total program costs in order
for the system which provides a given level of effectiveness for the
smallest opportunity cost to the economy to be chosen.
At the end of my statement I have given a number of examples
of how we have used discounting in the Defense I)epartment. I might
add that these examples were not specially prepared for this testimony.
They have been taken directly from our working papers and have
actually been used in our considerations of various proposals. I would
like to review one of them to show how we do analysis using dis-
counted costs.
A common problem is to decide whether a new weapons system will
have payoffs in increased capability or in reduced costs for achieving
given effectiveness which justify a large initial investment in research,
development, and procurement. For example, the Defense Depart-
ment is considering new types of transport aircraft for use in the com-
bat theater beginning in the mid-1970's.
These aircraft will be expensive to develop, but they promise im-
proved performance and lower operating costs. In our analyses, we
have sought to constructseveral alternative tactical airlift force struc-
tures, each of which will provide the same capability to move troops,
equipment, and supplies from selected types of origins to selected types
of destinations over the entire period of the next 15 years.
The ~bjective is to see whether a new aircraft will reduce the costs of
providing the designated capability enough to repay the investment in
development and procurement at a reasonaible rate of return.
I have included a table which summarizes the costs of different forces
designed to meet one particular set of lift requirements over the next
15 years. For purposes of this comparison, year-by-year procurement
and operating costs were computed, and an interest charge of 10 percent
compounded annually was added. Separately shown are estimated re-
search, development, test and evaluation costs, also calculated on a
year-by-year basis with allowance for interest at 10 percent. The pur-
pose of showing these costs separately is to show how the time profiles
of costs for the different forces vary. During the development phase of
new aircraft, existing aircraft must be kept in the force. They are re-
placed only when the new models become available.
The table in the statement shows that all three new aircraft will
enable us to reduce the total cost of buying and operating the forces
required for the job. Only with aircraft B, however, can we completely
PAGENO="0145"
141
write off the development bill at 10 percent over a 15-year period. Nat-
urally, then, we are quite interested in aircraft B. However, there are
great uncertainties about the cost estimates as well as about the tech-
nical risks, and we have to take these uncertainties into account. What
this analysis is supposed to do is to encourage the proponents of new
aircraft types to design them so that they are as profitable as possible
an investment for the Defense Department without sacrificing the
capability to meet basic mission requirements.
The best time to encourage this type of work is in the very early
stages of an analysis when the alternatives are still being designed.
Mr. Chairman, this concludes the remarks I would like to make.
Chairman PROXMIRE. I wish you would go on for just a few moments
and give us your analysis on the supersonic transport.
Mr. LYNN. I am pleased you noticed.
Chairman PROXMIRE. I did. I could not resist it.
Mr. LYNN. We have, of course, had some experience in the past with
doing economic analyses of the SST program, because Mr. McNamara
was quite deeply involved in the Government committee dealing with
that subject. We do not attempt to review or judge the merits of the
investment. We attempt merely to do economic analysis of the payoffs
of this investment in cash terms, given the very great uncertainties
and risks associated with the program. The analyses we show here are,
I think, a very good illustration of how difficult it is to take into
account all of the uncertainties in arriving at a sensible decision. But
I think what we have tried to do is to display the revelant information
in a meaningful way so a decisionmaker can focus on it.
For example, there are a variety of estimates of how large the SST
market will actually be. There is also the question of what discount
rates to use. So we show, for different estimates of the size of the
SST market, the present value of the SST investment at discount
rates of 5,10, and 15 percent.
In this way one can look at the question of how the uncertainties
about the size of the market affect judgments about the SST program
and at how opinions about the right discount rate affect these judg-
ments. As to what the judgments finally are, of course, that involves
a great many more considerations than we can encompass in this par-
ticular kind of analysis.
Chariman PROXMIRE. You are a diplomat as well as an economist.
I shall come back to this in the questioning.
(The prepared statement of Mr. Lynn follows:)
PREPARED STATEMENT OF LAURENCE E. LYNN, JR.
The need for appropriate discounting and interest rate policies in govern-
ment agencies is now widely recognized, thanks in large part to the Joint
Economic Committee. The correct and consistent use of discounting, however,
is only one aspect of good analysis. Using the "right" discount rate will not
necessarily lead to wiser decisions on government investments if the support-
ing analyses are poorly conceived and carried out. On the other hand, good
program analyses will reflect the appropriate use of discounting procedures
in both the design and the evaluatIon of alternatives.
This paper first discusses an appropriate interest rate policy for use in
Federal agencies. Second, the Defense Department's current discounting poli-
cies and procedures are described, along with several examples of how discount-
ing has been used in practice in DoD.
98-9400----68-1O
PAGENO="0146"
142
I. AN INTEREST RATE POLICY FOR USE ~N FEDERAL AGENCIES
A. THE COMMON SENSE OF DISCOUNTING
In evaluating investment opportunites open to the government, we attempt to
project both their costs and their benefits several years into the future and to
determine which investments to undertake. We may, for example, determine
those projects for which the value of the benefits exceeds the cost over some
appropriate period of time. Or, if we are comparing alternative ways of achiev-
ing some specified objective, we may seek the alternative which satisfies the
objective for the lowest total cost. In either case, the question is, should~ we
assign the same weight to a dollar of cost or benefit no matter when it occurs?
Economists unanimously answer no far a relatively straightforward reason.
For the government to invest, it must obtain the necessary resources from
the private economy, either from those who would otherwise consume them
or from those who would otherwise invest them on their own behalf. Private
consumers and investors are far from indifferent about when they must give
up resources to the government. It resources he would otherwise use are trans-
ferred to the government, the private investor foregoes the opportunity of
earning a rate of return which, in today's economy, ranges from 10 to 20 per-
cent before taxes. *The consumer must give up consumption opportunities.
Though we can't measure the value of these opportunities directly, we can
observe that consumers who pass up opportunities to invest in interest-earn-
ing assets, the lowest and safest of which now yield about 5 percent, must value
today's consumption at least as highly as the future interest returns they are
passing up.
For both investors and consumers, therefore, giving up a dollar today means
giving up both the dollar and the interest return (implicit or explicit) it will
bring. If the day of reckoning with the government can be postponed, interest
can be earned or consumption enjoyed for at least a while so that when the
government's claim for a dollar comes in, something of value-the interest that
* has accrued-will remain in private hands. To the private sector, therefore,
today's dollar is more painful to give up and today's benefits are more valuable
than tomorrow's costs and benefits. They should be assigned a greater weight
in the government's analyses to reflect the value of the consumption and invest-
ment opportunities that the private sector must give up.
Thus, the common sense of using an interest rate concept in government invest-
ment decisions is this: the government should obtain a rate of return on its
investments at least as large as the value of the consumption and investment
opportunities private citizens must give up. Therefore, the government should
assess itself an interest charge on the funds it needs that is equal to the oppor-
tunity cost of these funds to private consumers and investors. Returns to govern-
ment investments should be large enough to cover both principal and interest;
If the government ignores these opportunity costs and undertakes projects with
relatively low rates of return, then society as a whole-public and* private-
is not receiving the maximum attainable value from its resources; the general
welfare will be lower than it could be.
In fact, government agencies should deliberately design their investment proj-
ects with their rate of return in mind. Establishing and enforcing appropriate
discounting procedures should not only lead to wiser investment decisions but
encourage the design and development of better investment projects as well.
For example, new defense weapon systems typically involve very heavy outlays
in early years but reduced operating costs later on. By pointing out early in
the process of reviewing and analyzing a proposed system that tomorrow's sav-
ings have less weight than today's cost, we hope to encourage system designers
to insure that today's outlays produce the largest possible potential savings and
to forgo expensive design frills with little or no payoff.
This line of reasoning should form the basis for the government's discount
rate policy. But to say this is far from settling the matter. A large number
of issues must be resolved in defining and measuring opportunity cost and
in coming up with practical guidelines for policy. These issues have produced
most of the debate that has taken place among economists on the question of
the "right" discount rate.1 I would like to review briefly some of these issues
1fiome economists have argued that an appropriate discount rate is the social rate of
time preference. According to this argument. private time preference, that is the strength
of the individual consumer's preference for consumption today versus cOnsumption
tomorrow, is shortsighted. The government, representing society, should adjust its rate
PAGENO="0147"
143
and try to put them in perspective. This review suggests that practical guide-
lines for government discount rate policy must recognize the existence of
several different analytical situations and perhaps more than one rate.
B. PROBLEMS OF DEFINING AND MEASURING OPPORTUNITY COST
When the government undertakes an additional investment project, it must
raise the necessary funds by taxing or borrowing. Depending on how the financing
is done, the resources are obtained from both consumers and investors. It can
be argued that taxation affects mainly consumption whereas borrowing displaces
mainly investment. The question is, how should the government be assumed
to finance its new projects, and how do consumers and investors share in pro-
viding the resources?
I believe that the government can be assumed to finance its activities out of tax
revenues and that in the long run, the alternative to more government spending
is lower taxes, not less borrowing. The amount the government plans to bor-
row each year should be assumed to be determined mainly by how much the
government wants to stimulate or restrain aggregate demand by varying the
size of its deficit or surplus, not by the level and composition of government
investments.2
In 1958, Professor Otto Eckstein estimated the reductions in private consump-
tion, private investment, housing and other types of investment when the gov-
ernment obtains resources through taxation.3 At that time, his estimate of the
opportunity cost of public capital obtained through taxation was about 6 percent.
However, in private correspondence, he has indicated that using current data with
his model would yield a cost estimate of about 8 percent.
Other investigators have calculated the cost of capital to the government by
assuming that the government borrows the necessary funds.4
They have estimated that the cost of borrowed capital is `significantly higher
than the interest yield on government bonds. Because government borrowing
displaces private investment to `a significant extent,5 the government foregoes
the taxes it would collect on the returns to these investments. This cost to the
government must be added to the government bond yield less the taxes the govern-
ment ccollects on this yield. Working along these lines, the GAO estimated that
downward as an expression of society's willingness to see resources transferred to future
generations. Providing for future generations is a "public good ;" that Is, collectively
society is willing to forego consumption today to Increase the welfare of posterity but no
individual will volunteer to foot the bill himself. The government must give expression to
this willingness through its investment projects.
There are three counter arguments to this view:
1. In the case of natural resources which cannot be replaced once they are `used up' or
destroyed, judgment to conserve them should be made on the merits of the case. Manipu-
lating the discount rate for this purpose is not appropriate. In fact, it is probably
impossible to determine what an appropriate rate would be in such cases.
~. The best way to insure the welfare of posterity is to adopt a policy to stimulate both
public and private Investment to achieve higher growth rates today. Moreover, such a
policy would seek public projects with the highest returns, not the lowest.
3. The use of a social rate of time preference across the board, rather than in special
cases, would mean that a great many relatively unproductive public projects would dis-
p1ac~ many productive private projects.
2 It is sometimes argued that the discount rate should be reduced in those periods in
which resources are unemployed and their opportunity cost is therefore zero. As a
practical matter, discount rate procedures should not be manipulated to reflect highly
changeable circumstances such as the extent and nature of unemployment When' the
government desires to stimulate private economic activity, it will want to expand invest-
ments earning the highest rates of return, not seek low return projects. If there aren't
enough of these high payoff projects, an explicit judgment can always be made to finance
projects with relatively low returns as calculated by the usual methods.
Otto Eckstein and John V. Krutilla. Multiple Purpose River Development, Baltimore:
Johns Hopkins University Press, 1958, Chapter 4.
See, for example, Summary of Use by Federal Agencies of the Discounting Technrque
in Evaleating Future Programs, by the Comptroller General of the United States, January
29, 1968, pp. 25-28.
6 However, the impact of a larger governemnt deficit on consumers and investors will
depend on how much the money supply is allowed to increase. To the extent that the
money supply increases, the price level will rise and the government's resources will be
withdrawn from those consumers whose real incomes are reduced by the Inflation. Con-
sumers hurt by inflation are probably those, such as those on fixed incomes, who value
present consumption most highly and whose opportunity costs are higher than the return
on risk-free bonds.
To the extent that the government as a borrower displaces other borrowers In competing
for an available supply of credit, on the other hand, private investment will be reduced.
The displaced Investment Is likely to be interest sensitive investments such as state and
local government projects and housing, as well as projects with relatively low returns or
high risk. The attractive and highly profitable investments of the private sector will not be
much affected by small increases In the costs of credit.
PAGENO="0148"
144
- government borowing costs may be as high as 7 to 8 percent, and other investi-
gators have estimated it at closer to 10 percent.°
Notice that these calculations look only at the cost to' the government, and not
the opportunity cost to the economy, associated with the government's borrowing.
However, the latter cost is the relevant cost against which to judge government
projects. Of course, it would be possible to calculate the' opportunity cost to
society, assuming that the government borrows, by looking at the rate of return
which the displaced private investments earn. Eckstein's 1958 findings on the re-
turns on investments displaced by taxation probably give a good idea of these
costs also, and they suggest an opportunity cost of borrowing' of about 7-8
percent.
Hence, `both a "tax" model and a "borrowing" model come up with answers to
the 7-10 percent range.7 I believe further research will support this result, since
both taxing and borrowing affect both consumption and investment to a significant
degree.
However rates of return on private investments include compensation for
their riskiness. Estimates of, the opportunity cost of resOurces drawn from the
private sector just cited include some risk compensation. Individual government
investment projects are certainly not free of risk, either, especially large invest-
men'ts in new weapon systems with a great deal of technical uncertainty. If we
assume that the private sector must he compensated for `bearing risk, should the
return required on risky government investments also include a risk premium,8
as we assume when we use discount rates that are based on opportunity cost
estimates that reflect some compensation for risk?
Economists differ on this question One view is that the discount rate used in
evaluating a project should include as much compensation for risk as the yields
on similar investments in the private sector. An opposing view is that no ri'sk
premium should be included in the government s discount rate just as writing
a new policy does not add to the total risk borne `by an insurance company, an
additional government investment does not add to the overall risk on society 5
total investment Hence according to this argument a risk compensation is un
necessary, and the discount rate should be riskless.
If the latter view is accepted, `the discount rate should be the best estimate of
,a risk-free rate of return available in the private sector, presumably the current
yield on long-term government bonds, or about 5-fi% percent.
`In the absence of fully satisfactory answers to questions about the appropriate
way to handle risk in government investments, the best way to proceed is to adopt
5 percent as the basic discount rate to be used throughout the government and
to insure that each project valuation includes an analysis of the uncertainties
associated wi'th both costs and benefits. The cost and benefit estimates used in the
evaluation should be those that can reasonably be expected in light of these
uncertainties.
Several types of `risky situations could justify adjustments in the discount rate
used for particular projects, however. For example, success or failure on a
government flood control project will pay off if it prevents devastation of an
area, but it will "fail" if the threat never materializes. However, the government's
project, though risky, reduces the riskiness of investments in the threatened area.
Hence, the' undertaking of a risky government project may reduce the risk on
society's total investments. On the other hand, government investment in, for
example, a supersonic transport may mean that investment in other forms of
passenger transportation becomes more risky. The understanding of a risky
government project may increase the risk on society's investments. The former
example could be used to defend a lower discount rate on the project in question
than the opportunity cost of capital; the latter example could be cited in behalf
of a higher rate on the project in question.9
6 of~ the estimates cited assume that government borrowing displaces private in-
vestment dollar for dollar. Because effects on consumption are Ignored,' the estimates
probably overstate the actual cash cost.
7 is assumed that the government bond rate reflects consumers' and investors' expecta-
tions about future inflation. A downward adjustment in the discount rate is necessary
when evaluating projects for which estimates of costs and benefits are in constant dollars.
~ fact that government bonds are regarded as risk-free does not mean that bond
holders regard rovernment projects as riskiess. or that they are In fact riskless. Rather,
it reflects the fact that there Is no default risk on loans to the government because the
taxing and money printing power of the state supports the government's credit rating.
When comparing alternative ways of ax~hieving a given level of benefits or effectiveness,
however. `adding a risk premium th the discount rate applied to costs has the perverse
effect of making the rl~kier system look better.
Suppose two systems, A and B, which are expected to perform a renuired mission epually
wel1~ and their ten-year systems costs are as below. Based on use of a 10 percent discount
PAGENO="0149"
145
Weapon system
Procurement
cost, year 1
Operating cost,
years 2 to 10
Total cost
undiscounted
Total cost
discounted at
10 percent
A
B
$100
37
$10
20
$190
217
$138
138
The best procedure may be to make clear exactly what the risks are, without neces-
sarily trying to quantify them, so that he can decide how best to proceed.
Still another problem is an investment in a project which, though its success
or failure may not affect the riskiness of private investments, is so very large
that it probably increases aggregate risk because it is a risky project in itself.
This is frequently the case in the Defense Department. In such cases compensa-
tion for the added risk may well be justified.
C. THE REDISTRIBUTION PROBLEM
Those who bear the cost of government investments may not be the same as
those who receive the benefits. Government investment redistribute income
within the economy, and many are specifically designed to do just that.
For example, the benefits of a flood control project may accrue mainly to the
resident of the particular river basin, though the costs are paid by consumers
and investors at large. Similarly, an investment in a program for the disad-
vantaged such as Head Start will benefit mainly the children who receive the
aid but the costs will be widely shared. Many will argue that the discounting
procedure, which implies that economic efficiency is the dominant criterion for
choosing a project, should be modified when beneficial redistributions take place,
perhaps through lowering the discount rate on projects which redistribute bene-
fits in the "right" direction, or else scrapped altogether.
My own view is that this is a problem of analysis. If redistribution benefits
are claimed for a program, these benefits should also be subjected to analysis.
That is, a redistribution objective should be specified and the costs of alternative
ways to achieve it compared. It may be the case that a project which cannot meet
other tests of efficiency is also an inefficient way of redistributing economic wel-
fare. Explicit analysis is, I believe, preferable to manipulating the discount rate
and will lead to a much clearer understanding of the issues and alternatives.
D. PROBLEMS OF MEASURING BENEFITS
So far we have been talking about undifferentiated government investments
whose costs and benefits can in principle be measured. In fact, there are many
different types of government investments, and for many of them it is difficult
or impossible to measure or compare the value of the benefits, even in principle.
For example, it is impossible to put a monetary value on the benefits of invest-
ment in a new defense weapons system. It is not possible, even in principle, to
determine how valuable in monetary terms is our assured destruction capability
against the Soviet Union or our ability to defeat Warsaw Pact tactical air forces
in conventional combat in Europe, still less to put a value on improvements in
those capabilities. For a different reason it is impossible to decide the market
value of the protection a dike provides to a community, because the individual
citizen cannot buy such protection for himself in the market; either everybody
enjoys it or nobody enjoys it. Investments in post office facilities can, in principle,
be valued because the private citizen could buy as much or as little postal service
as he liked.
In situations where there is no market test of benefits, two types of analyses
must be done. First, should we buy the service or capability, however we measure
the benefits? Secondly, which of the alternative ways of providing this service
or capability should we choose? Since this is the characteristic type of problem
encountered in the Defense Department, it is worth discussing how we do it in
more detail.
rate, DOD would be indifferent between them, since the present value of each cost stream
at 10 percent is $138. But suppose System B (while normally expected to perform as well
as A) has a greater chance than A of not performing the mission. If, say, two percentage
points are added to the discount rate for B, and Its costs are discounted at 12 percent,
while A Is still discounted at 10 percent, System B will be procured, since the present
value of Its cost Is $128. Thus, the riskier system would be procured, even though System
A is probably the better choice.
PAGENO="0150"
146
Typically, we measure the benefits or effectiveness of our inystments against
some criterion of military need. For airlift and sealift investments, for example,
the need is expressed in terms of the desired schedules for moving forces to
where they may be needed. For tacitcal air investments, one way the need can
be expressed is in terms of delivering ordnance to a target system, against
expected opposition, in sufficient quantity to destroy a certain percentage of
the targets. We set up tests of effectiveness in each mission area, using perhaps
several different measures.
Deciding whether or not additional investments should be undertaken in a
given mission area involves complex judgments about the value of the extra
effectiveness relative to its cost. Such judgments involve questions both of how
much is enough and of how soon do we want or need the capability.
In choosing among alternative ways of achieving a given level of effectiveness,
however, formal analysis has an. impotant role to play, and the proper use of
discounting is an important part of the analysis. We are concerned to know
which alternative will provide the desired effectiveness for the lowest total
cost. Alternatively, we may be interested in knowing which of several equal cost
alternatives gives us the most for our money. Again, the question arises as to
whether costs in different years should be equally weighted and again the
answer is no. We should not be indifferent between programs which involve high
outlays today and programs the costs of which are spread more evenly in time.
Because the differences in cost among the alternatives have an opportunity cost
to the private economy, an appropriate interest rate should be charged in esti-
mating total program costs in order for the system with the smallest opportunity
cost to be chosen.
Many non-defense problems can be analyzed using cost-effectiveness methods.
Though the judgments about whether the benefits or effectiveness are worth it
are not easy to make jüdgmSnts focused on the right questions and explicitly
drawn issues are likely to lead to better decisions than faulty benefits calcub~
tions.
II. CURRENT DoD PoLICIEs ON THE USE OF DIscouNT RATES
A. CURRENT PROCEDURES
Department of Defense Instruction 7041.3, dated December 19, 1966, and signed
by the Assistant Secretary of Defense (Comptroller) provides specific procedures
for evaluating proposed defense investment projects where the sole or primary
justification for such projects is economic. Examples of the kinds of proposals to
which this Instruction is applicable include, but need not be limited to, the fol-
lowing:
1. Repair vs. replace. (New procurement)
2. Refurbishment to reduce operating and/or maintenance costs.
3. Fuel conversion to reduce fuel costs.
4. Consolidation projects for warehouses, depots, and repair activities, to im-
prove efficiency or reduce costs.
5. . Modernization projects to mechanize, improve work flow and layout, and in-
crease capacity which lead to a reduction in costs.
6. Material and supply handling projects to increase efficiency and capacity.
7. Acquisition of Automatic Data Processing Equpipment (ADPE) to increase
efficiency or reducecosts.
Note that each of these situations possesses the essential characteristics for an
economic analysis: a commitment of resources with the expectation of receiving
benefits (i.e., cost savings) over some future period of time. Further, these re-
sources and their attendant benefits canbe measured in dollar terms.
The concept of the discount rate used in the Instruction is as follows: A dis-
count rate is management's evaluation of two factors associated with investment
analysis.
1. The interest cost of the money.
2. The risk and/or the uncertainty associated with the proposed project and
the estimates contained therein.
The benefits, or cost savings, expected to result from the investment are to be
discounted at 10 percent. The costs are to be discounted at 5, 7 or 10 percent de-
pending on how the project is financed. However, this Instruction is now in* the
process of revision and the multiple rate procedure will probably be discarded in
favor of a uniform rate applied to both costs and benefits
The Instruction puts the role of the cost-benefit analysis in perspective as.
follows: "Although an economic analysis is part of the information that . a
decision-maker should consider, it rarely provides the complete basis for decision.
PAGENO="0151"
147
At one extreme there are alternative choice decisions which can be made on the
basis of an economic analysis. "Lease vs. Buy" and "Replacement Decisions"
(replacement of an existing asset with a newer model) fall into this category.
Another category of alternative choice decisions involves projects for which the
economic implications must be weighed against other, non-monetary, considera-
tions. "Make vs. Buy" decisions involve an economic analysis but also require, for
example a judgment as to whether the proposal is in conflict with the Govern
ment's policy of not competing with private industry. Finally, at the other end
of the spectrum, there are those projects for which it is difficult or impossbile to
quantify the associated ëosts and/or benefits. Examples of these might include
projects to improve personnel health or safety factors. These different categories
of alternative choice decisions should be recognized and the weight given to
economic analysis should be governed accordingly
This Instruction also points out that this procedure is not applicable to pro
posed investment projects justified solely or primarily on the basis of military
necessity or combat effectiveness. Where an economic analysis would add to or
support the justification for projects of this kind, it is recommended that such an
analysis be submitted with the investment proposal.
Our weapon system investments are analyzed in detail. We use discounting
procedures in cases where clearly they are called for, such as when the time
streams of costs for the systems being compared are different. We have not
thought it w~ise to formalize the use of these procedures as yet because a great
deal of judgment must be exercised in each problem to determine which aria-
lytical tools are appropriate.
B EXAMPLES OF THE USE OF DISCOUNTING IN THE DEPARTMENT OF DEFENSE
1. A new armed heZieopter for the Army
The Army proposed large-scale procurement of a new armed helicopter to pro-
vide fire support for its combat forces. Analyses of this problem showed that the
new system performed many of the same types of missions that were performed
by the artillery, tanks, mortars and other armed helicopters already in the
Army's program. The Army believed that the new helicopter was a needed addi-
tion to its fire support capability, though it was expensive.
The Secretary of Defense decided to buy the new helicopters provided that
the Army was willing to replace a portion of its previously approved fire support
force structure with them. The replaced force structure was to be equal in cost
to the new helicopter system over the ensuing ten years. The cost concept to be
used was a present value cost: the actual year-by-year cost outlays for both
forces discounted at 10 percent. The assumption was that the Army would be
willing to accept these terms if the new helicopters were, in the Army's judg-
inent, more capable than the equal cost force they replaced.
The resulting table showing the two forces and their costs had the following
format.
COST SUMMARY
[Expenditures in millions of dollars]
*
Fiscal year
1969
Fis
cal year
1970
Fiscal year
1971
Fi
scat year
1978
10-year
cost, total
10-year
cost,
discounted
Cost of new helicopter force:
Initial investment:
Equipment
Initial pilot training
Annual operating cost
Combat consumption
Retirement pay
Total
.
Terminal value of equipment
and ordnance
Net cost of n
ew force
Cost of forces tra
ded off:
Initial invest
ment
Annual operating costs
Combat consumption
Retirement pay
Total
Terminal val
Net cost of f
ue of equipment
orces traded off__
Difference in net
costs
PAGENO="0152"
148
The main contribution of the use of discounting procedures was to insure that
a dollar approved for expenditure in FY75 was not weighted equally with a
dollar of expenditure of FY69 in comparing the costs of the two forces. As a
result, though the new force required extra expenditures initially, the cash
savings achieved in later years were large enough to constitute a 10 percent
return on the initial investment.
The main issue for both judgment and analysis was whether the new force
was more effective over the period than the replaced force. The Army judged
this to be the case.1°
2. A new pipe shop cleaning plant for the Charleston, S.C., naval shipyard
The Navy proposed to construct a new building for the chemical cleaning of
pipe components to meet the exacting standards of nuclear submarines and sur
face ships. At the time of the proposal, the task was being done in a temporary
open shed 25 years old. In accordance with DOD Instruction. 70413, the follow-
ing calculations were made to justify the project
(a) Investment required (building cranes chemical tanks expected
to last 20 years) - $275, 000
(b) Annual savings (lower utilities cost, maintenance and chemical
waste) 43, 026
(c) Present value of new building's terminal value 36,000
(d) Present value of annual savings and terminal value discounted
at.10 percent 402,253
(e) Benefit/cost ratio (line (d)Jline (a)) 1.46
Investment in the new building makes possible a stream of annual savings
compared to continued use of the old facility which represents a return signifi-
cantly greater than 10 percent
3. Tactical airlift capability for the Air Force
The Air Force indicated that the high attrition of C-130E aircraft in South
Vietnam would mean that the Defense Department would lose the capability
of about one C-130E squadron within two or three years. The problem was how
to replace this lost capability. Analysis indicated that we had basically three
alternatives:
a. Buy another squadron of C-130Es.
b. Operate an existing squadron of C-l3OBs (an older model C-130) at a
higher utilization rate than we had planned, and modify them as necessary to
prolong their useful lives.
c. Keep two O-130B squadrons that we had planned to give to the reserves
in the active force structure, but plan to use them at low utilization rates, and
modify them as necessary for prolonged life.
The choice was between investment in new aircraft, which would mean lower-
ing operating costs later on, and continued operation of older aircraft with their
higher operating costs. The ten year cost summary was as follows:
10-YEAR COST SUMMARY
[In millionsj
Undiscounted Discounted at
10 percent
Option A-Buy C-130E's $161.4 $114. 0
Option B-Increase use of 1 C-130B Squadron 215.6 132.6
Option C-Keep 2 C-130B squadrons at low use - 293.0 180.2
Buying the new aircraft yields returns of better than 10 percent in reduced
operating costs. Hence, the decision was made to go ahead with C-130E procure-
ment.
4. A new tactical airlift~ aircraft for the Air Force
A common problem is to decide `whether a new weapon system will have payoffs
in increased capability or in reduced costs for achieving given effectiveness which
10 conclusion means that the return on the Investment was greater than 10%, with
the returns in excess of 10% beIng taken In increased effectiveness.
PAGENO="0153"
149
justify a large initial investment in research, development and procurement. As
an example, the Defense Department is considering new types of transport air-
craft for use in the combat theater beginning in the mid-1970s. These aircraft
will be expensive to develop, but they promise improved performance and lower
operating costs. In our analyses, we have sought to construct several alternative
tactical airlift force structures, each of which will provide the same capability
to move troops, equipment and supplies from selected types of origins to selected
types of destinations over the next 15 years. The objective is to see whether a
new aircraft will reduce the costs of providing the designated capability enough
to repay the investment in development and procurement at a reasonable rate
of return.
The following table summarizes the costs of different forces designed to meet
one particular set of lift requirements over the next 15 years. For purposes of
this comparison, year by year procurement and operating costs were computed,
and an interest charge of 10% compounded annually was added. Separately
shown are estimated research, development, test and evaluation costs, also
calculated on a year by year basis with allowance for interest at 10%. During
the development phase of the new aircraft, existing aircraft must be kept in the
force. They are replaced only when the new models become available.
15.YEAR COSTS WITH INTEREST AT 10 PERCENT
[In billions]
No new With new With new With new
aircraft aircraftA aircraft B aircraftC
Procurement and operating
Research, development, test, and evaluation
$13.3
$11. 8
1. 8
$12. 4
0. 9
$12. 2
1.9
Total
13.3
13.6
13.3
14.2
This table shows that all three new aircraft will enable us to reduce the total
cost of buying and operating the forces required for the job. Only with aircraft
B can we completely write off the development bill at 10% over a 15 year period.
However, there are very great uncertainties about the cost estimates as well as
about the technical risks. What this analysis is designed to do is to encourage
the proponents of new aircraft types to design them so that they are profitable as
possible an investment for the Defense Department without sacrificing the
ability to meet basic mission requirements. The best time to encourage this type
of work is in the very early stages of an analysis when the alternatives are being
designed. Had no interest charges been assessed, the new aircraft would, of
course, have been much more attractive, and much less effort would be put
into economical design.
5. The supersonic transport program
The Department of Defense has in the past participated in economic analyses
of the Supersonic Transport Program and has a continuing responsibility to
review the program for potential military uses. The following tables shows the
potential profitability of the SST program purely as a financial investment: the
present value of total program costs to the government is subtracted from the
present value of the return flow of funds from the manufacturer. No attempt
is made to pass on the merits of the non-financial aspects of the program. All SST
costs prior to FY 69 are considered "sunk", and the calculations assume a fresh
decision can be made on whether to continue the program.
PRESENT VALUE OF SET INVESTMENT
[In millions]
Discount rate
5 percent 10 percent 15 percent
SST market as calculated by Institute for Defense Analyses (IDA) -$344 -$528 -$579
SST market as calculated by Federal Aviation Administration (FAA) 218 -239 -421
PAGENO="0154"
150
.
nt
erest charges at-
5 percent
10 percent
15 percent
IDA estimates of market size
FAA estimates of market size
-1,057
670
-4,370
-2, 143
-14,401
-10,477
Thus, if the opportunity cost of funds is estimated at 5%, the program will lose
a billion dollars by 1900 using1DA estimates of market size but will earn a return
for the government of $670 million using FAA market estimates. At 10%, the
program will cost the government $4.4 billion by IDA market estimates, $2~1 bil-
lion by FAA market estimates.1'
The choice of a discount rate will significantly influence estimates of the pro-
gram's profitability as a financial investment. Moreover, this example also shows
the explicit analysis of uncertain future benefits. Two different estimates of poten-
tial market size are used in caculating profitability. Hence, judgment can be
focused on how the uncertainties about the market should affect the investment
decision.
Chairman PROXHIRE Mr Mackey ~
STATEMENT OP N CECIL MACKEY, ASSISTANT SECRETARY FOR
POLICY ])EVELOPMENT, DEPARTMENT OP TRANSPORTATION,
ACCOMPANIED BY DR. JAMES NELSON, DIRECTOR, OITICE OP
ECONOMICS
Mr. MACKEY. I might begin by saying that somehow, the SST portion
of our statement was omitted in the gathering process.
Chairman PROXMIRE. I can understand. [Laughter.]
Mr MACKEY Mr Chairman, with me this morning is Dr James H
Nelson, who is Director of our Office of Economics in the Department
of Transportation. He has been on loan to us for approximately 11
months now, from Amherst College, and has been directly involved
in much of the economic analysis which the Department has been trying
to undertake m its formative stages Unfortunately, this will be his
last opportunity. He is going back to the academic world at the end
of this month.
I am glad to have a chance to be here this morning and to join in
the discussion of discounting and the use of quantitative analyses
in Government programs. In light of the testimony which you have
heard in the past 2 days, I would touch only very briefly on the
standard framework of analysis which is normally employed to estab-
lish a case for discounting future costs and benefits and to determine
11ff pre-1968 costs are included in these calculations, the government's cost is $6.5-$9.O
billion.
Based on FAA estimates of the potential size of the SST market, the program
breaks even as far as the government is concerned at a discount rate of 6.85
percent. If the opportunity cost of the program's funds is estimated at greater
than 6.85 percent, the program will not break even. Using IDA estimates of mar-
ket size (which assume that sonic boom restrictions will limit sales), the break-
even rate is 1.33 percent. If a higher discount rate is used the program will not
break even.
The following table shows results from the same calculations but allowing
interest charges to accumulate through 1990, rather than discounting program
costs back to the present.
SST PROGRAM COSTS TO 1990 INCLUDING INTEREST CHARGES
[In millions of dollarsj
PAGENO="0155"
151
a rational rate of discount. Instead, my testimony will emphasize the
many unusual features of discounting transportation costs and benefits
which complicate the forecasting chores of the Department of
Transportation.
The Department of Transportation obviously does not have respon-
sibility for the total investment budget of the U.S. Government,
although the Federal highway program is one of the larger single
elements in this budget. We are not directly concerned with overall
investment criteria in the sense that the Treasury, the Bureau of
the Budget, or the Council of Economic Advisers would be. The
Department does have important areas for potential investment which
involve tradeoffs between investment and operating expenses.
But the more important aspect of the use of investment criteria
by the Department of Transportation, within its present statutory
framework, is its inability to lay down uniform rules for methods of
calculating future costs, future benefits, or appropriate rates of clis-
count to convert these future costs and benefits into present values.
The outstanding example of this inability is contained in the DOT
statute itself. Section 7(a) instructs the Secretary to "develop and
* * * revise standards and criteria consistent with national transpor-
tation policies, for the formulation and economic evaluation of all
proposals for the investment of Federal funds in transportation facili-
ties or equipment * * ~ but this instruction is subject to two major
qualifications. Section 7(a) itself contains a list of six conceptions,
including very important ones `with respect to grant-in-aid and water
resource projects. This water resource exception is at least partly bal-
anced by provision for membership of the Department of Transpor-
tation in the Water IResources Council, but it nevertheless leaves dis-
counting and other investment criteria with respect to water trans-
portation in a different environment than comparable criteria for
Government investment in other modes of transport.
Mr. Chairman, as you will note, part of section 7(a) of our act
is particularly limiting in that it specifies in detail the method for
calculating waterway benefits in terms of a comparison of waterway
transportation rates in the future and existing rail rates or existing
truck rates so that there results an inherently unnatural and unrealistic
comparison. But it is built into law and the judgments on water
resource projects are based on that statutory standard.
In addition, as I will later point out in more detail, the application
of uniform rules is rendered difficult by the division of investment
responsibility for transport facilities such as highways and certain
airports between Federal and State or between Federal and local
government agencies, and by divisions both between modes and, within
many of the modes, between private ownership and investment-as
with railroads, or airlines, or trucking concerns-and public ownership
and investment_as with highways and major airports.
The conceptually ideal situation, of course, would be to begin with
a unified approach to definitions of benefits, costs, and appropriate
rates of discount to be applied to future values. This ideal situation
would have special advantages in the field of transportation, due to the
degree of substitutability of demand for important transportation
modes-such as the demand for freight movement by rail, by barge,
or by motortruck-as well as the possibility of trade-offs between
PAGENO="0156"
152
public investment in infrastructure and safety facilities and private
investment in operating equipment. A standard discount criterion
could even be useful in determining the most economical surfacing to
be used on a particular highway. This conceptually ideal situation
must, of course, be visualized in terms of relating the appropriate dis-
count rate to the development of the entire economy. The very exist-
ence of net new investment is incompatible with static assumptions
abOut the economy ; and, in particular, the existence of such net new
investment in new forms of economic activity is likely to be accom-
panied by steadily increasing productivity.
In the rest of my statement, I will give some examples of this
relationship of discount criteria to other dynamic investment criteria
as well as of some of the problems created by the mixture of competi-
tion and complementarity prevalent among modes of transportation
with different types of ownership and control.
I would like to give a summary of the present discounting practices
of the operating administrations within the Department of Trans-
portation.
First, the Bureau of Public Roads might be expected to have the
most important decisions with respect to appropriate discount rates,
because its annual investment budget greatly exceeds that of all the
other model agencies in our Department combined.
But the Bureau's investment funds are derived from the highway
trust fund, so that the inflow into the highway investment pool is
immediately determined by the receipts of specified taxes and not by
a showing with respect to discounted costs and benefits.
Moreover, the great majority of the Bureau's investment expendi-
tures are distributed to individual States to be used according to set
formulas along with State highway money. Neither the State-by-State
distribution nor the percentage Federal share in each type of highway
directly reflects costs, benefits, or discounts of future values to arrive
at present values. State highway departments use discount rates rang-
ing.from 0 to 8 percent.
The Federal Highway Administration has also agreed to use stand-
ard rates for sensitivity analysis as provided by the Bureau of the
Budget.
These standard rates are generally 7.5 percent, 10 percent, and 12.5
percent, as Mr. Hoffman indicated earlier.
The Federal Aviation Administration has based its discounting on
Bureau of the Budget Circulars A-54 and A-76. Where it has em-
ployed discounting procedures, and this has not been in all of its
projects, it has used interest rates which essentially reflect the cost
of Government borrowing as reported by the Treasury Department.
Over the past few years these rates have risen from 4.2 to 5.5 percent.
Some recent sensitivity studies have used the same rates already men-
tioned for the Bureau of Public Roads; that is, 7.5, 10, and 12.5
percent.
Although the Urban Mass Transportation Administration has been
active in providing capital grants for local transportation purposes,
it has not engaged m direct investment activities. It has not established
a discountingpolicy. Nor has discounting been utilized by either the
Federal Railroad Administration Or the St. Lawrence Seaway De-
velopment Corporation. The Coast Guard is just beginning to con-
PAGENO="0157"
153
sider interest rates in its economic studies, and in a pending polar
study it is using the rates recently suggested by the Bureau of the
Budget.
That completes the review of our current practices. I would like
to mention briefly the problem which confronts the Department in
connection with economics of safety. Virtuafly all of the Department
of Transportation programs are heavily safety oriented, and they
involve determinations of some value to be placed on human life. It
is always difficult and it is not very popular, we find, to try to assign
values. It is very difficult conceptually and analytically. Nevertheless,
it is a necessary part of any rational analysis of the kind of programs
which the Department of Transportation has. I think perhaps the
most significant point to mention is that as we view the value ot indi-
vidual life in terms of economics and in terms of the changing social
environment, it appears to us that we would need constantly to
increase the outlays for any given assurance for saving human life.
The value, both from the production and the consumption standpoint,
I suppose you would say, of human life is increasing. We are at work
trying to find ways to take this into account in our analysis.
I would like to skip some now. The next part of my statement
refers to problems which result from the private and public nature
of the investment decisions. Mr. Hoffman went into this in some de-
tail. It is particularly significant to us in Transportation because of
mixed ownership. The multiple decisionmaking process in public in-
vestment is important to us.
Due to the highway trust fund, the United States has now come
within sight of a nationwide express highway system built to minimum
standards in accordance with an articulated plan. Federal funds
were available for highways for a generation before the highway trust
fund was created.
But State `and local governments still receive the lion's share of
the funds derived from taxes on automobile and trust use; and State
and local governments dominate in providing both the funds and. the
criteria for new highway investment. This dominance in determining
criteria is especially marked if we believe `that the Interstate Highway
System, with 90 percent Federal financing, confers general benefits
which are hard to quantify, while projects of more local significance
may be more susceptible to detailed economic analysis.
This multiple decisionmaking has produced sharp contrasts in dis-
counting policies. As I mentioned, a number of States use zero discount
rates in the process of evaluating the costs and benefits to be expected
from new highway mvestment. Other States use discount rates over
the entire range from 0 to 8 percent. These extreme differences in
policy do not necessarily imply that the zero interest-rate calculations
produce larger highway programs, because the total size of such pro-
grams may be determined by receipts from use taxes or other budget
constraints. But, if a given investment fund proves to be inadecjuate
at a zero discount rate, then it must be parceled out among individual
pmjects on the baths of benefit-cost ratios a good deal higher than
unity. A combination of a zero discount rate and high benefit-cost
ratios is sure to distort both the geographical distribution and the
physical characteristics of highway investment. The very word "in-
PAGENO="0158"
154
vestment" implies the importance of time. Yet a zero discount rate
assumes that time has no importance.
The same general phenomenon occurs in different forms in financing
aviation investment. The Federal Aviation Administration, a com-
ponent of the Department of Transportation, systematically employs
discounting to determine the present values of future costs and bene-
fits. Yet most rnvestment in airports is made locally, on the basis of
investment criteria which are typically unaanounoed even if they are
known. Local airport finance may enforce some discounting rules in
practice: An airport financed by revenue bonds must automatically
convert some future benefits into cash flows and effectively discount
these future cash flows by applying applicable rates of interest
against them. But many airports are not financed by revenue bonds.
Also, the very choice between revenue bonds and obligations pledging
full faith and credit produces a further option in interest rates which
may be used for discounting in addition to the option created by the
fact that local obligations, free of Federal taxes, typically involve
interest rates lower than those available to the U.S. Treasury.
Again, Mr. Chairman, the problems involved in the consideration
of taxes in the discounting process have been considered rather
thoroughly. I shall not go into those in any detail, except to say that
in Transportation, there may be some basis for distinctions between
the way we consider property taxes and the way we consider income
* taxes. This is because of the use which transportation facilities gen-
erally make of high-quality land which would be available for other
uses if transportation facilities are not built, and also because of the
relation of the benefits produced by certain transportation facilities
to the locality in which the facility has to exist. This is a complication
that we have to deal with. I do not have any particular solution to
offer on how to cope with it.
Turning to the special case of railroad investment, the Department
of Transportation operates the Alaska Railroad. The city of Cincin-
nati owns, but does not operate, the Cincinnati Southern, Otherwise,
the railroad map of the United States is dominated by private
ownership.
The next part of my statement gives us a little history of this. There
are still massive problems for rail investment created by the com-
petitive environment in which railroads operate. Many railroads
are in a position to avoid payment of Federal incomes taxes on part or
all of their income, due to tax loss carry forwards. This helps to im~
prove their competitive position vis-a-vis public investment by reduc-
ing or eliminating the spread between their gross and their net return.
But these tax loss carry forwards are also a factor in the growing
phenomenon of footloose railroad cash. The roadbed may be immo-
bilized, but the cash flow derived from depreciation, net income, and
sale of miscellaneous assets is not. Therefore, the problem of railroad
investment in the face of competition may be further subdivided into
two different problems: negatively, competitive forces have cut into
railroad earnings, and continue to hold them down; positively, the
opportunity cost of converting railroad cash into railroad investment
seems to be rising as alternative uses of the cash become relatively
more attractive.
To sum up: The problem of discounting costs and benefits of new
PAGENO="0159"
155
railroad investment goes much deeper than indicated by a simple
contrast between "public" and "private" considerations. If railroads
were experiencing the exuberant growth which characterizes highway
or airport construction, many of the most glaring contrasts between
railroad and other transport investment criteria would be greatly re-
duced. The problems of private ownership, of divided ownership, of
obsolete physical capital, and often of obsolete balance sheets, combine
to make the development of acceptable criteria for railroad investment
a matter of deep concern to the Department of. Transportation as well
as to the railroads themselves.
In conclusion, I would like to say that we in the Department are
in general agreement with those who support the discounting tech-
niques as a part of our analytical process. We feel that the discount
rates which we have used are probably too low and should be re-
examined. But I would like to add that many of the problems which
are encountered in analyzing transportation investment illustrate that
you cannot solve the basic issues simply by changing the discount rate.
The opportunity to nullify the effects of raising the discount rate by
changing the consideration, the identification, or the evaluation of
costs and benefits is very great. This has been illustrated particularly
iii the water resources area. So while we. are in favor of moving in
the direction of better discounting procedures, we do not want to lose
sight of the problem of improving the overall quality of. our analysis,
the better identification of benefits, the bette.r description of them, and
the better quantification of them.
(The complete statement of Mr. Mackey follows:)
PREPARED STATEMENT BY CECIL MACKEY
My testimony today will touch only briefly on the standard framework of
analysis which is normally employed to establish the case for discounting future
costs and benefits and to determine a rational rate of discount. Instead it will
emphasize the many unusual features of discounting transportation costs and
benefits which complicate the forecasting chores 0f the Department of Trans-
portation.
Standard analysis of discounting is concerned with one aspect or another of
the general question: how much to invest? It is always concerned with invest-
inent, or disinvestment, because the whole point to the use of interest or discount
rates is to obtain comparable present values for streams of costs and benefits
which are expected to have different time-shapes. Specifically, for problems in-
volving positive investment, at least some costs are expected to precede benefits.
For individual projects, a standard question takes this form: given a flow of
anticipated future benefits, should we incur costs now, or wait? If we decide not
to wait, should we incur heavy costs now in order to gain lower costs in the
future, or should we minimize present costs in return for heavier future outlays?
More generally, this kind of analysis can be spread over many projects, to
determine the optimum size for total investment budgets or the optimum mix
for total investment programs.
The Department of Transportation obviously does not have responsibility for
the total investment budget of the U.S. Government, although the Federal high-
way program is one of the larger single elements in this budget. We are not
directly concerned with overall investment criteria in the sense that the Treas-
ury, the Bureau of the Budget, or the Council of Economic Advisers would be.
It does have important areas for potential investment which involve trade-offs
between investment and operating expenses.
But the more important aspect of the use of invesement criteria by the De-
partment of Transportation, within its present statutory framework, is its
inability to lay down uniform rules for methods of calculating future costs,
future benefits, or appropriate rates of discount to convert these future costs and
benefits into present values.
PAGENO="0160"
156
The outstanding example of this inability is contained in the DOT statute
itself. Section 7(a) instructs the Secretary to "develop and * * * revise stand-
ards and criteria consistent with national transportation policies, for the
formulation and economic evaluation of all proposals for the investment of
Federal funds in transportation facilities or equipment * * s", but this instruc-
tion is subject to two major qualifications. Section 7(a) itself contains a list
of six exceptions, including very important ones with respect to grant-in-aid
and water resource projects. This water resource exception is at least partly
balanced by provision for membership of the Department of Transportation in
the Water Resources Council, but it nevertheless leaves discounting and other
investment criteria with respect to water transportation in a different environ-
ment than comparable criteria for government investment in other modes of
transport.
In addition, as I will later point out in more detail, the application of uni-
form rules is rendered difficult by the division of investment responsibility for
transport facilities such as highways and certain airports between Federal and
state, or between Federal and local government agencies, and by divisions both
between modes and within many of the modes between private ownership and
investment (as with railroads, or airlines, or trucking concerns) and public
ownership and investment (as with highways and major airports).
The conceptually ideal situation, of course, would be to begin with a unified
approach to definitions of benefits, costs, and appropriate rates of discount to
be applied to future values. This ideal situation would have special advantages
in the field of transportation, due to the degree of substitutability of demand
for important transportation modes-such as the demand for freight move-
ment by rail, by barge, or by motor truck-as well as the possibility of trade-
offs between public investment in infrastructure and safety facilities and private
investment in operating equipment. A standard discount criterion could even
be useful in determining the most economical surfacing to be used on a par-
*ticular highway. This conceptually ideal situation must, of course, be visualized
in terms of relating the appropriate discount rate to the development of the
entire economy. The very existence of net new investment is incompatible with
static assumptions about the economy; and, in particular, the existence of such
net new investment in new forms of economic activity is likely to be accom-
panied by steadily increasing productivity.
In the rest of my statement, I will give some examples of this relationship
of discount criteria to other dynamic investment criteria as well as of some of
the problems created by the mixtures of competition and complementarity
prevalent among modes of transportation with different types of ownership
and control.
The Bureau of Public Roads might be expected to have the most important
decisions with respect to appropriate discount rates, because its annual invest-
merit budget greatly exceeds that of all the other model agencies in our denart-
ment combined. But the Bureau's investment funds are derived from the High-
way Trust Fund, so that the inflow into the highway investment pool is im-
mediately determined by the receipts of specified taxes and not by a showing
with respect to discounted costs and benefits. Moreover, the great majority of
the Bureau's investment expenditures are distributed to individual states to
be used according to set formulas along with state highway money. Neither the
state-by-state distribution nor the percentage Federal share in each type of
highway directly reflects costs, benefits, or discounts of future values to arrive
at present values. State highway departments use discount rates ranging from
zero percent to eight percent. The Federal Highway Administration has also
agreed to use standard rates for sensitivity analysis as provided by the Bureau of
of the Budget. These standard rates are generally 7.5 percent, 10 percent, and
12.5 percent, as Mr. Hoffman indicated caviler.
The Federal Aviation Administration has based its discounting on Bureau of
the Budget Circulars A-54 and A-76, and accordingly has used interest rates
which essentially reflect the cost of Government borrowing as reported by the
Treasury Department. Over the past few years these rates have risen from 4.2
percent to 5.5 percent. Some recent sensitivity studies have used the same rates
already mentioned for the Bureau of Public Roads: i.e., 7.5, 10, and 12.5
percent.
Although the Urban Mass Transportation Administration has been active
in providing capital grants for local traneportation purposes, it has not engaged
in direct investment activities. It has not established a discounting policy. Nor
has discounting been utilized by either the Federal Railroad Administration or
PAGENO="0161"
157
the Saiiit Lawrence Seaway Development Corporation. The Coast Guard is just
beginning to consider interest rates in its economic studies, and in. a pending
polar study it is using the rates recently suggested by the Bureau of the
Budget.
Now to return to more general considerations affecting the position of the
Department with respect to discounting, and to the net values derived there-
from:
1. The economics of safety
Probably the most widespread and pervasive set of responsibilities of .the De-
partment of Transportation are those related to transportation safety. These
responsibilities extend all the way from air traffic control by the FAA to the
Coast Guard's role in boating safety. And the most extreme form of the prob-
lem of safety involves an attempt to guarantee that there will be a future-
not simply to apply a proper rate of discount `to it.
Thus the investment of most general interest to the Department of Trans-
portation is the individual's investment in his own life. And here it should be
noted that standard discounting procedures for reducing larger future estimates
to smaller present values may require at least some offset. For, in a dynamic
economy, the average individual of a given age is worth steadily more through
time. So the stream of future benefits `to be discounted is not constant, but ris-
ing, even for just one hypothetical individual of constant age. Translated into
investment policy, this means that we should constantly increase our outlays
for a given assurance of saving human life.
Another corollary of the economics of safety has to do with the reduction of
uncertainty. Most discussions of discounting assume a given degree of risk in
comparing different investments. But the precise function of investments in
safety is to reduce the risk of death or accident accompanying an individual's
travel.
Therefore the most general aspect of the Department of Transportation's
interest in discounting criteria is in connection with preserving our national
investment in people.
2. The unit of investment decision
It is customary to assume that investment is either "private" or "public".
Private investment is usually supposed to take place in an environment char-
acterized by a considerable degree of competition, although it is often recognized
that a business firm contemplating a new investment may bear in mind the
dangers of spoiling the market by depressing prices with the additional units
of output it expects to produce. But public investment is usually expected to be
monopolized, in the sense that it is performed by something called "the govern-
ment" which is responsible for the investment decision and all its consequences.
Finally, there is no body of economic discussion relating to the special problems
of competing public and private investments-railroad way and structure versus
highways, or, in a much more limited sense, some railroad way and structure
versus airports-nor is there any received economic doctrine with respect to the
complementary relationships between private investments such as planes or
motor vehicles and public investments such as airports or highways. This section
of my comments will sketch in only a few of the anomalies which result from
these divisions of investment responsibility.
a. Multiple decision-making in public investment
Due to the Highway Trust Fund, the United States has now come within
sight of a nationwide express highway system built to minimum standards in
accordance with an articulated plan. Federal funds were available for highways
for a generation before the Highway Trust Fund was created. But state and
local governments still receive the lion's share of the funds derived from taxes
on automobile and truck use; and state and local governments dominate in
providing both the funds and the criteria for new highway investment. This
dominance in determining criteria is especially marked if we believe that the
Interstate Highway System, with 90 percent Federal financing, ~confers general
benefits which are hard to quantify, while projects of more local significance may
be more susceptible to detailed economic analysis.
This multiple decision-making has produced sharp contrasts in discounting
policies. As I mentoned, a number of states use zero discount rates in the process
of determining the costs and benefits to be expected from new highway invest-
ment. Other states use discount rates over the. entire range from zero to eight
98-9'40-68----1l
PAGENO="0162"
158
percent. These extreme differences in policy do not necessarily imply that the
zero interest-rate calculations produce larger highway programs, because the
total size of such programs may be determined by receipts from use taxes or
other budget constraints. But, if a given investment fund proves to be inadequate
at a zero discount rate, then it must be parcelled out among individual projects
on the basis of benefit-cost ratios a good deal higher than unity. A combination
of a zero discount rate and high benefit-cost ratios is sure to distort both the
geographical distribution and the physical characteristics of highway investment
The very word "investment" implies the importance of time. Yet a zero discount
rate assumes that time has no importance.
The same general phenomenon occurs in different forms in financing aviation
investment. The Federal Aviation Administration, a component of the Depart-
ment of Transportation, systematically employs discounting to determine the
present values of future costs and benefits. Yet most investment in airports is
made locally, on the basis of investment criteria which are typically unannounced
even if they are known. Local airport finance may enforce some discounting rules
in practice: an airport financed by revenue bonds must automatically convert
some future benefits into cash flows and effectively discount these future cash
flows by applying applicable rates of interest against them. But many airports
are not financed by revenue bonds. Also, the very choice between revenue bonds
and obligations pledging full faith and credit produces a further option in in-
terest rates which may be used for discounting in addition to the option created
by the fact that local obligations, free of Federal taxes, typically involve interest
rates lower than those available to the U.S. Treasury.
b. The ragged edge between public and private investment
The tax differential mentioned in the preceding paragraph is, of course, even
more oTwious if public and private investments are compared. A locally-financed
transportation investment may disregard both direct and indirect income tax
payments. Income of the project itself is not taxable; and interest paid to bond-
holders is free of Federal income tax. A Federally-financed project involves in-
direct Federal income tax payments by holders of Federal securities which are
the counterparts of the investment expenditure, but the project pays no income
taxes directly. Private investment financed by bonds has the same Federal income
tax position as Federal investment; but private investment financed by sale of
new equity capital involves both direct and indirect income taxation by all
relevant levels of government. To complicate matters still further, equity capital
created by ploughing back earnings may greatly reduce the indirect tax liabilities
of stockholders who take the capital-gains route to keep themselves in funds or
who have no need to sell stock.
This description could, of. course, be applied to the differences in income tax
liabilities of private and of different kinds of public investors anywhere in the
economy. Its particular significance for transportation arises from the inter-
relationships of public and private investment in transport investment. Where
the two are complementary, as they are in aviation, the practical results may be
just the reverse of the over-extension of airports relative to airplane investment
which pure discount theory would lead one to expect. Hard-pressed local govern-
ments may refuse to incur further debt even if it is incurred to finance an invest-
ment which seems almost sure to be profitable. And revenue bonds may not be
saleable in one big lump for a huge new airport. But the most difficult cases are
not those of investment complementarity between the private and public sectors.
These most difficult cases involve investment competition, in the sense of invest-
ment in facilities to provide competitive services. The outstanding example of
this competition is that of highways and railroads. But the rail investment prob-
lem has so many other aspects that it requires special treatment of its own.
3. The special case of railroad investment
The Department of Transportation operates the Alaska Railroad. The City of
Cincinnati owiis, but does not operate, the Cincinnati Southern. Otherwise the
railroad map of the United States is dominated by private ownership. Therefore
it may seem paradoxical to single out railroad investment policy in a statement
devoted to Federal Government standards for discounting future costs and bene-
fits. Moreover, most important present-day problems of railroad investment can-
not be attributed simply to public investment in highway facilities for the specific
purpose of facilitating freight movement. The contrasting attitudes of the Ameri-
can Trucking Association and the American Automobile Association on truck size
and weight limits are enough to indicate that truck and passenger car uses of
PAGENO="0163"
159
highways are not automatically complementary. But the passenger automobile
now dominates short- and medium-distance intercity passenger transportation
as, in numbers, it dominates in the use of most highways. Therefore any system
for the allocation of highway investment would have to assess an important share
of the total against passenger transportation. Both the provision of highway fa-
cilities for trucks and the competition with rail freight which this provision
makes possible are to some extent by-products of the provision of facilities which
would be demanded in any case by drivers of passenger automobiles.
Moreover, although many segments of the national rail net are subject to
competition from waterways operators who pay no user charges, this competi-
tion is specialized with respect to both area and commodity.
There are still massive problems for rail investment created by the competi-
tive environment in which railroads operate. Many railroads are in a position
to avoid payment of Federal income taxes on part or all of their income, due
to tax loss carry-forwards, which helps to improve their competitive position vis-
a-vis public investment by reducing or eliminating the spread between their
gross and their net return. But these tax-loss carry-forwards are also a factor
in the growing phenomenon of footloose railroad cash. The roadbed may be im-
mobilized, but the cash flow derived from depreciation, net income and sale of
miscellaneous assets is not. Therefore the problem of railroad investment in
the face of competition may be further subdivided into two different problems:
negatively, competitive forces have cut into railroad earnings, and continue to
hold them down; positively, the opportunity cost of converting railroad cash into
railroad investment seems to be rising as alternative uses of the cash become
relatively more attractive.
As if these problems were not complicated enough, there exists a further
railroad investment problem which is a product of both history and technology.
Historically, most railroads financed themselves to the maximum possible ex-
tent by the issuance of mortgages on their fixed assets. These often contain
"after acquired" clauses which subject any further fixed assets to the original
lien. Even without such provisions, loans against rolling stock provide the lender
with more mobility and hence more security than loans against investments in
way and structure. Historically, also, most railroads supplied themselves with
whole systems of branch lines, and elaborate patterns and stations and yards,
all built on the assumption of minimum hauls for local drays and wagons. The
motor truck has revolutionized terminal services, and eliminated the need for
much railroad fixed plant. Technical improvements in railroading must strug-
gle against a financial, investment, and operating structure which combine to
throw a deep shadow of the past into the present
Finally, each individual railroad enterprise may be both too big and too
small to achieve maximum credit in security markets for investment in tech-
nological advance. Individual railroads involve massive capital investments re-
flected in high balance sheet valuations of assets. Specific improvements due to
new investment may lose most of their effect on earnings ratios due to the mas-
sive size of this asset denominator. Conversely, most individual railroads are
too small to realize for themselves all of the beneficial systems effects of new
investments.
To sum up: the problem of discounting costs and benefits of new railroad
investment goes much deeper than is indicated by a simple contrast between
"public" and "private" considerations. If railroads were experiencing the exu-
berant growth which characterizes highway or airport construction, many of the
most glaring contrasts between railroad and other transport investment criteria
would be greatly reduced. The problems of private ownership, of divided owner-
ship, of obsolete physical capital, and often of obsolete balance sheets combine to
make the development of acceptable criteria for railroad investment a matter of
deep concern to the Department of Transportation as well as to the railroads
themselves.
4. Trust fo~nds, and pay-as-you-go
Federal highway programs have always been on a pay-as-you-go basis in the
sense that no new bonds were ever issued as a specific offset to Federal high-
way contributions. But the major present Federal commitment to highways,
via the Highway Trust Fund, is pay-as-you-go in a much more direct and mean-
ingful sense. Receipts are earmarked for highway investment, and are thereby
enclosed in what amounts to a budget within the budget.
The basic idea of a trust fund involves segregation* of particular receipts
from the general budget. But a trust fund need not involve the further principle
PAGENO="0164"
160
of pay-as-you-go. Investment could be financed by borrowing, with future trust
fund receipts hypothecated against payment of bond interest and principal.
Many state highway budgets once operated on this basis. So the following re-
marks will not be directed toward trust funds in general, because trust funds
in general have no particular relationship to the problem of discounting future
costs and benefits. Instead, attention will be focussed on the special features of
Federal funding of its contribution to the Interstate Highway System, via a
combination of a trust fund and pay-as-you-go.
If the provision of highways had to respond to a growth in demand as rapid
as that now facing airports, a pay-as-you-go type of trust fund would involve
unusually high discount rates if it were the only source of investment. Conversely,
a pay-as-you-go trust fund for a relatively mature industry would involve suc-
cessive investments which could be justified only at lower and lower discount
rates for future benefits. The essential problem with any trust fund, therefore, is
that it simply extrapolates the past into the future.
This analysis cannot be applied directly to the Federal Highway Trust Fund,
because the proceeds from this fund are used as a supplement to the larger funds
already available to states and localities for the specific purpose of financing
construction of the Interstate Highway System. Upon completion of this system,
however, the incompatibility of a pay-as-you-go trust fund with thQ whole idea
of appropriate rates of discount for future benefits will have to be faced.
5. Money prices and shadow prices; `user charges and tolls
A benefit is a benefit, whether it is charged for or not. But the "benefit" numera-
tor in benefit-cost calculations may assume very different values depending on
the presence or absence of a specific charge for the service enjoyed. A "user
charge" may also take the form of a specific charge for a specific service, in
which case it might properly also be called a "toll"; or it may represent a gen-
eral charge for the use of the service in general.
Neither the distinction between money prices and shadow prices nor the dis-
tinction between user charges and tolls is peculiar to charging for transportation.
Moreover, neither distinction seems to have any direct relevance to the problem
of a proper rate of discount for use in converting future into present values. But
*there are substantial indirect connections between these concepts and both trans-
portation and discounting. The world of transportation not only involves a mix-
ure of public and private enterprise. It also involves a jumble of real prices and
shadow prices, of general user charges and specific tolls. To revert to the rail-
road illustration: if all railroads were publicly-owned, the case for charging
rates only sufficient to cover operating costs would be better than for other
forms of transport; for, as long as the rail system contains excess capacity, extra
use does not entail the costs of additional investment. Elimination of all spreads
between rates and operating costs would enlarge total benefits derived from the
use of railroads as well as the problems of covering railroad financial charges.
Conversely, the land and air space used by the most convenient large airport
in a metropolitan area may be vastly preferable to those available anywhere
else in the area; and expansion of the airport may be possible only with sharply-
rising costs. In crowded metropolitan areas, even a public body might expect to
earn large economic rent on its most favorably-situated facilities. In terms of
the relationship of pricing, benefits, and investment policy, the combination of
private ownership of excess capacity and public ownership of very scarce re-
sources may produce results which are far from perfect.
Even if the type of ownership is matched against the presence or absence of
excess capacity at zero prices, there remains the fact that what matters is not
the appropriate or proper discount rate, as such, but the appropriate or proper
net relationship of discounted benefits and costs expressed as present values.
The benefits to be derived from use of a facility at a zero price will normally
exceed those to be anticipated from future use at a positive price unless special
problems on congestion are created as total use increases. Once congestion ap-
pears, the whole level and distribution of benefits will be affected by the use of
specific tolls, to control use of facilities, on the one hand, or by the use of general
user charges, on the other band.
Chairman Pnox~imnn. Thank you, Mr. Mackey.
Mr. Levine?
PAGENO="0165"
161
STATEMENT OP ROBERT A. LEVINE, ASSISTANT DIRECTOR FOR
RESEARCH, PLANS, PROGRAMS, AND EVALUATION, OFFICE OP
ECONOMIC OPPORTUNITY, ACCOMPANIED. BY MRS. BETTE
MAHONEY, STAFF ECONOMIST
Mr. LEVINE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
I would like to commence by introducing Mrs. Bette Mahoney, who
is our staff economist in this field.
Mr. Chairman, I would like to submit my statement and make an
oral statement.
Chairman PROXMIRE. In that case, your prepared statement will be
printed in full in the record.
Mr. LEVINE. Since my remarks deal mainly with qualifications on
our use of this kind of analysis, I will start by emphasizing that we
need this kind of analysis in the poverty program. In the current state
of our knowledge we treat this analysis as an art rather than as a
science; that is, even though we have a single measurable objective,
the erosion and end of poverty in the United States, we do not have
any single system on the benefit side where we can compare different
sorts of contributions to this single objective. Frankly, sir, we are not
near it.
For this reason and for reasons of various of the specific qualifica-
tions I shall mention and that are mentioned in the written statement,
the discount rate is not yet of crucial importance to either our analysis
or, I think, the analysis of other human resource programs. There is
too much else to be done before sensitivities to different discount rates
become crucial.
One of the chief qualifications I want to mention is very simply the
difficulty of conceptualizing some of our benefits. In three cxf our major
categories of programs under our program budgeting system, for ex-
ample, training programs, manpower programs, benefits are easy to
conceptualize, at least. We know we should be measuring increased
earnings due to a training program. When we move to another cate-
gory, education, it is slightly less easy to conceptualize. `We do not really
know the contribution of education to increased earnings and there-
fore to the erosion of poverty.
In some other fields-community action, for example-when we talk
about institutional change, we know from so-called soft sociological
analyses that community action is essential to the end of poverty; we
do not know how to measure the immediate results which will give us
the contribution to this ending of poverty. I should add in this con-
nection that we are doing work with esoteric techniques such as con-
tent analysis, pattern analysis, and so forth, in an attempt to measure
the soft ends of our program and put them on a basis where we can
at least measure increments of one program against another. But we
have not yet reached this happy state.
Even in programs where we can conceptualize, there are difficul-
ties of measurements as such. I think there are very few human re-
source programs that have very good data systems at this time. Perhaps
the best one I know is OEO's Job Corps program, where the expe-
rience of the young people in these Job Corps centers is fairly carefully
PAGENO="0166"
162
recorded and tabulated and where, on a sample basis, followup is
carried on by polling organizations on a scientific sampling basis. The
Job Corps can do this because: First, the program itself costs enough
so that the additional cost of a good data system seems to justify itself;
second, Job Corps is more centrally controlled than most human re-
source programs, and the data system can be imposed by central
direction.
For other good reasons, the trend in human resource programs is
toward decentralization and local control. I think we must realize that
when we decentralize and control locally, we are sacrificing somewhat
on the availability of data or the possibility of our demanding data
for these programs.
Given, though, that we can do and have done some conceptualiza-
tion and that we can do and have done some measurement, what is the
implication of these measurements and analyses for our programs as
compared to other programs? I think it would be very difficult and
wrong to make direct comparisons between our benefit-cost analyses
and those for the physical resource programs of the Federal Govern-
ment.
As suggested in the paper, we have set up some definitions of con-
sumption and investment benefits from the human resource programs.
By investment benefits we mean those benefits which bring economic
returns in the increased product sense, and this is only one of the ob-
jectives of any one of our programs, increasing the contribution to the
national economy of our clientele. It is an objective, but it is only one.
It is a measurable objective, which is measurable against the other
programs.
Inaddition to these, we have the whole set of other benefits which
we call, for convenience, consumption; benefits having to do with the
distribution of the resources, goods, and income in our economy and
benefits which are not of the type which typically can be analyzed by
benefit-cost analysis. I believe these benefits have not really been ade-
quately handled by any form of economic analysis at this stage. For
this reason, the whole set of other social goals put into our program
and other human resource programs by the political process, which
is the proper way to put them into these programs, must be handled
analytically, different from the benefits which are the benefits of many
of Mr. Mackey's Transportation programs.
All of this leads to several qualificatioi~s. I have frequently tried to
make qualifications about our use of benefit-cost ratios. The first is
that in our kind of program, a benefit-cost ratio less than one, less
than unity, does not mean that a program is unsuccessful. There are
usually many intangibles which we define into this consumption cate-
gory which camiot be computed into benefits; whereas the costs are all
too tangible.
Further, even though a ratio of less than one might indicate that
transfer payments are cheaper than a specific resource program such
as the training program or programs which lead to increased earnings
on the part of a recipient and contribute to the commonweal, there is
a clear social and political preference favoring other programs as com-
pared to transfer payments, and allowances must be made for this.
Let me give you an example of one of our studies cli5dn~ed in thi$
submission. We did a benefit-cost study of the Job Corps, done by
PAGENO="0167"
163
Prof. Glen Cain of the University of Wisconsin. We did not have the
problem of trying to justify a benefit-cost ratio of less than one. The
range of investment portion of the benefit-cost ratio was in the order
of 1.1 to 1.5, and we used the number that about 1.2 was the best esti-
mate of the-
Chairman PROXMIRE. What was the discount used?
Mr. LEVINE. They were discounting the estimated future earnings
attributable to the Job Corps program.
Chairman PRoxMI~. What percent, what interest?
Mr. LEVINE. The numbers we used for discount rate were 5 percent
and 7 percent. As I said in the paper, the effective discount rate was 3
percent compared to 5, and 5 percent compared to 7, because we believe
it is in this particular sort; of training program that it is necessary to
take account of the overall increase of general labor productivity at
roughly 2 percent a year, which has historically been occurring in our
economy. We take this into account by reducing the discount rate for
purposes of computation, although the conceptual and theoretical dis-
count rate used here is 5 and 7 percent.
In any case, we did arrive at these benefit-cost ratios on the order
of 1.2, but we did not allow for benefits which are some of the chief
benefits claimed by the Job Corps, benefits which we could not meas-
ure, what they call the socialization process, the ability of these kids
to get along with other kids and therefore to get along with fellow
workers. We did not allow for their learning about the world of work.
We did not allow, in the case of the Women's Job Corps, for future
family stability, which is very crucial to the problem of poverty, which
would stem from the training they get in the Women's Job Corps.
All of these components are immeasurable. They are on the uncertain
side of my dichotomy of social benefits. For these reasons we have
made a guess, that perhaps a true benefit-cost ratio, if you discounted
the consumption benefits the same way, would be something on the
order of 2 rather than 1.2. That is a pure guess. You cannot do it
mathematically.
The second qualification, the state of the art, and state of data iii
our field, are both primitive enough that it is almost always unwise
to compare programs unless the ratios are computed in a single spe-
cific study for the purposes of such a comparison. We have done one
such study, a sensitivity study, comparing the Upward Bound pro-
gram for senior high school students to go to college and the Head-
start program, which presumably is to get similar kids at a much
younger age. What we wanted to know is what would be the effect
of a discount rate using estimated future earnings increase as a benefit
measure between two programs, one of which paid off in earnings
immediately after the program was finished-that is the Upward
Bound program-as compared to one which could not conceivably
pay off in the earnings until 10, 11, 12 years later. This study was
done and the kind of estimate we came up with was that, given the
partially known benefits of Upward Bound, which gave us a çpretty
good `benefit-cost ratio for Upward Bound, the Headstart effectiveness
would have to be on the order of 1 to 2 increased years of education
attributable to the Headstart program to equalize them.
Frankly, this surprised me. I think if Headstart works at all, it is
going to be an easy thing to achieve, and I would have guessed the
PAGENO="0168"
164
discount rate would have killed Headstart. Again we are using the
same range of discount rates, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman PRox~nnE. Let me just interrupt to say that your assump-
tion that it would have killed Headstart is on the further assump-
tion that you just cannot crank in all the benefits of Headstart. The
benefits that you have alluded to in these other respects, with regard
to stability in socialization and therefore reducing the crime rate and
that kind of thing.
Mr. LEVINE. Not completely, really.
Chairman PROXMIRE. As part of it, though; because I understood
you to say your benefits were primarily related to specific increases in
earnings.
Mr. LEVINE. Yes, sir.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Which certainly is only part, and perhaps a
small part, of the benefits.
Mr~ LEVINE. That is true. This applies, I think, perhaps to both
programs, the intangible benefits. My prestudy guess, which proved
wrong, that the discount rate would kill Headstart, however, was
based purely upon the idea that any comparable set of benefits would
be killed by 10 years of discounting, 10 or 11 years of discounting.
Chairman PROXMIRE. You found out that was not true?
Mr. LEVINE. We found out this was not true. Let me then make a
point on that basis. It is going to be true for some programs. This
leads us specifically to a final point I would like to make, which is on
the discount rate as such.
I am not sure what discount rate should be used even on the invest-
ment portion of programs like ours. Because there is a conventional
analysis, we use a discount rate we believe to be in the opportunity
cost range, this 5 to 7 percent, for our kind of program. I have not
thought this all the way through, but it may be that because the Amer-
ican people, with our kind of program, have exhibited a clearly dif-
ferent kind of time preference, a time preference which can be ex-
pressed in the phrase, "Let us do this once and for all, and do it in a
fundamental way, which will cure something for the long run," in the
long run implying a weight on the distant future which ordinary
discount rates will not give you-it may be that for some programs
of this nature, there is a political preference expressed for a low dis-
count rate. In a sense, the American people are saying that comparing
benefits of similar programs, getting away from the comparability of
these programs to others, comparing benefits of similar programs to
one another, it may be that the political preference which must be
honored here is to do things in a way which values the distant future
much more heavily than any economic use of discount rates on eco-
nomic benefit programs will ordinarily give you.
Ohairman PROXMIRE. I wonder if that is the case or if you simply
should extend your benefits over a longer period? After all, in some
of our physical programs, we extend benefits for 100 years. You
could-it is true that the benefits would diminish rapidly if you have
a higher discount rate. I am not sure that there is necessarily a
preference for great-grandchildren. After all, in many ways, life in
tins country has been getting easier and education greater and leisure
more abundant, and so forth. This trend seems likely to continue. The
children and those of us who are living now are probably the ones
who will have a tougher time than future generations.
PAGENO="0169"
165
`Mr. LEVINE. I am not sure, either, Mr. Ohairman, but the extension
of a benefit foT 100 years at 6 percent, the hundredth year is still
not terribly important. I think `we can design the mechanical system,
the mathematical system, to take account of what we believe to `be
the true preference structure. All I am suggesting here is that for our
kind of program, complex as it is, partly economic, partly noneco-
nomic as it is, perhaps the discount rate should be looked at in a
different way. It might come out numerically similar or numerically
different, depending on what the true preference structure is. But I
am not sure that the opportunity cost discount rate is the proper one.
That is the note I would like to end on.
(The prepared statement of Mr. Levine follows:)
PREPARED STATEMENT OF ROBERT A. `LEVINE
OEO, and particularly my office which has the cost/benefit analysis function,
has been concerned with such analysis and associated discounting questions for
several years. In the recent past, members of my staff have conducted four
studie's, three of which may be categorized as Benefit-Cost studies and the fourth,
similar in purpose, as a Cost-Effectiveness study. These studies Were of the Job
Corps, Upward Bound, a Family Planning Program, and a comparison of Upward
Bound, Follow Through and Head Start. I will use material from two of these
studies as examples' in my discussion.1
However, I should emphasize that to date the question of the discount rate
per se has not been a critical one at OEO. The simple truth is that the study
of human resources and the quantification of benefits derived from programs
involving such investment is in its infancy. The really big problem we are con-
cerned with now is that of pure measurement of benefits and cost in human
investment programs; and until we have good benefit and cost figures', the dis-
count rate is not so important. Great sophistication on discount rates is really
not needed in human resource problems until one has developed sophistication on
the cost and benefit side.
Let me give an example. In many ways, training programs are the easiest
of human investment programs to measure. Yet, even here the practical prob-
lems are staggering. It "is simple to specify exactly what we want to measure
in a manpower program. Essentially the individual can anticipate some level
of income before training. We expend money in his training (the cost) and
thus expect an increase in his income. The difference between his income before
training and after training represent the benefits. But how do we measure
them? Does his last pretraining wage serve as a good proxy for his future in-
come stream were he not trained? Does his first post-training wage become his
future earnings after' training? Frankly, there is much disagreement here. How
can we measure these `benefits?
And, if the questions are hard in the training field, one can imagine the prob-
lems in programs working with very small children, with a Community Action
Program or with criminal rehabilitation. However, until we can measure these
kinds of benefits and the relevant costs with greater sensitivity, extreme sophisti-
cation in assigning discount rates is not a terribly important problem.
In fact, we have substantial hesitance about the extent to which human
resource programs can be compared to physical resource programs on the `basis
of benefit-cost analysis. This hesitance is in part due to the difference in sophisti-
cation and `accuracy `associated with measuring the benefits of these programs.
It is also due to the large "consumption" element associated with human resource
programs.
The benefits which accrue from a program are twofold: (1) those which yield
an economic return; and (2) those which Aatisfy tastes and preferences. For
convenience, we call these different types of benefits, investment and consumption
~ two studies are: Benefit/Cost Estimates for the Job Corps by Glen G. Cain and
Comparison of Head ~tairt, Follow Through and Upward Bound by Bette Mahoney and
Lewis Rosern Mr. Cain performed the study of the Job Corps while on a year's leave from
the University of Wisconsin to the Research and Plans Division In my Office. He is pres-
ently, as he was before he joined my staff, a member of the staff of the Department of
Economics and Institute for Research on Poverty at the University of Wisconsin. Mrs.
Mahoney and Mr. Rosen are presently Economists on my staff.
98-940-68----i2
PAGENO="0170"
166
benefits. The investment benefits can theoretically be measured in the market
place directly by contrasting the value of increased productivity with the re-
source cost of creating these benefits-the standard basis for benefit-cost analysis.
Consumption benefits cannot be easily measured directly, but may be an im-
portant element of program impact for human resource programs. Thus, it is
possible that considerations like justice and equity, consumption benefits in our
terminology, would lead to expenditures on programs which are not justified
by the economic or investment benefits alone. Indeed, such consumption benefits
ordinarily form a major portion of the justification for human resource pro-
grams. But not for the more purely economic physical resource programs and
herein lies a crucial difference which makes comparison between the two difficult
or meaningless.
The costs of programs are theoretically easier to measure. The costs to the
individual beneficiary himself are the opportunity costs of his participation. Thus,
for example, if the results of a program were that all students remained in
school an additional year, the foregone earnings associated with that additional
year of school must be incorporated. The cost to society is the foregone output
which could have been produced by the resources used in the program. In our
example, both the foregone production of the students undertaking an additional
year of school and the equipment, teacher output and the like are resource costs
to society. The costs to the government are straightforward. They are the
budgetary costs expended on the program.
We believe that the Federal Government must look beyond its own budgetary
process in determining whether an investment should or should not be made.
Once having determined that an investment is a good one for socinty, it is useful
to see what transfer payments between individuals are necessary so that we may
assess the political desirability of such transfers. The assessment of the political
desirability is traditionally the function of the President and the Congress. The
benefit-cost analyst has little to add in making these decisions except to make
the extent and nature of the transfers explicit in reports of the studies.
lit is at this stage that discounting plays an important role in the analysis of
costs and benefits of programs. The traditional use of discounting in benefit-cost
analyses of human resource programs is to determine the present value of future
benefits. However, discounting may also be used to make different costs com-
parable. For example, as shown in Mahoney and Rosen's comparative study of
Head Start and Upward Bound, an essential difference between these two pro-
grams is the length of time which intervenes between the incurring of cost in
each program and the onset of returns. Upward Bound costs are incurred just a
few years before participants enter the labor force, while Head Start costs are
incurred eleven years earlier in a youth's life than this.
For purposes of such comparisons, it can be assumed that the target popula-
tion is the same for the programs and that the programs are substitutes for one
another. The assumption is that a child is to be treated once-either as a pre-
elementary school child in Head Start or as a high school student in Upward
BouniI The comparison is to determine at what point we would be indifferent
between providing the child with either program.
Discounting eliminates the distortion which would accompany a dollar com-
parison of costs incurred at different points in time. Were it assumed that Head
Start and Upward Bound will have the same upward impact on lifetime earnings,
then the choice between programs (as investments) would rest on a comparison
of their costs. If returns are identical, the two programs will be equivalent if
the costs (properly discounted) are the same. If we simplify by assuming that
the primary economic benefit derived from Head Start and Upward Bound is
that associated with educational gains, then a measure of educational level
may be used as a proxy for the economic benefits (although this strict measure
of quantitative incremental educational attainment ignores a quality impact
which is one of the bases of the Head Start program).
At present, there exist some estimates of the educational attainment of Up-
ward Bound students. These estimates are incomplete primarily because the pro-
gram is new enough that no graduate has had time to complete college. In any
case, these quantitative educational gains estimates, in conjunction with per-
student costs to the Federal Government for Upward Bound and Head Start
permit some "cost effectiveness" estimates to be calculated. Such a calculation
indicates the importance of discount rates.
The question is posed as follows: aiven the estimated educational g~ii1 of
Upward Bound participants, how much educational gain must Head Start pro-
PAGENO="0171"
167
duce so that the two programs will yield identical gains per dollar? The estimated
net gain produced by Upward Bound is one and one-fourth years. The cost per
student to the Government of a full-year Head Start program in 1967 was $1,050;
the cost per student of Upward Bound in fiscal year 1967 was $1,254. Using
interest rates of 4, 5, and 6 percent, the Head Start costs can be brought forward
11 years and made compara~ble with Upward Bound costs: the adjusted costs are
$1,616, $1,793, and $1,993 for 4 to 6 percent respectively. Thus, for Head Start
and Upward Bound to be equally "cost effective," Head Start would have to pro-
duce educational gains of 1.61, 1.79, or 1.99 years over a full school career,
depending on the discount rate. The measure of cost-effective gains in this type
of analysis is very sensitive to the discount rate used. The lower the discount
rate the smaller the required gains from Head Start.
This leads us to the issue of the appropriate rate of discount. In general, it is
our view that the opportunity cost of investing in the public sector is the foregone
return in the private sector and not the cost to the Treasury of borrowing money.
The rates of 4 to 7 percent used in the evaluation of our programs were chosen as
representative of a safe private investment, although cogent arguments have been
made by some for real rates of interest as high as 9 to 10 percent. In any case,
the higher rates of many of today's safe investments include an inflation rate.
That is, part of the actual interest rate reflects the real return on investments
but the expectation of inflation raises the interest rate by an amount that reflects
higher prices expected in the future. Since the benefits of programs are measured
in real terms, the appropriate discount rate is that which measures the real
returns on investments and not the nominal rate which includes a price-change
factor. To the extent that similar programs can be compared to one another a
uniform discount rate is appropriate.
Although differences in the discount rate can make a difference in program
evaluation, differences in the measurement of benefits may still be much more
critical. For example, in Professor Cain's study of the Job Corps, two methods of
estimating benefits in the form of improvements in labor market earnings were
used. One method consisted of comparing the post-program earnings of ex-Corps-
men with those of a group of young men who had been accepted into the Corps
but did not participate. The second method estimated the gains in reading and
mathematics skills by Corpsmen and translated these educational gains into
expected future lifetime earnings using a careful study of the relation between
earnings and education by Giora Hanoch. Using an effective discount rate of
5 percent, the benefits measured by the first method were 42 percent higher than
an estimate using the second method but with the same discount rate. A com-
parison of the benefits calculated by the first method using two different effective
discount rates showed the benefits using the 5 percent rate to )e only 39 percent
higher than the benefits using the 7 percent discount rate.
Note that I have been using the term "effective discount rate" when referring
to the rates used in the Job Corps study. There has been some confusion about the
rates used in the evaluation of our programs. The rates of 5 and 7 percent were
used in the evaluation of our programs. The rates of 3 and 5 percent ta~bulated in
the Comptroller General's report as the rates used for evaluating our programs,
were used for calculation purposes only. They are not the effective discount rates.
Since the Job Corps was evaluated in terms of the improvement In labor
productivity of the Corpsmen, we have argued that the rate used to discount
future earnings from labor should allow for the secular growth in wage rates.
This does not mean that a growth factor should be attached to every set of
prices measuring the benefits of investment projects. Aside from the influences
of inflation or deflation, product prices may rise or decline over time and it
is difficult to judge the expected long-run trend. But, when estimating future
wages on the basis of current wages, a growth factor generally should be applied
to the current wage levels. A secular rise in real wages in the near future is a
realistic expectation. This secular rise will be due to that technological progress
and capital deepening which will be reflected in a large part in a more rapid
growth in the demand for labor than in the supply of labor.
We estimate that the secular growth stemming only from the rise In the price
of quality constant labor is approximately 2 percent a year. The increase in
the marginal value of labor is representative of the real increase in the produc-
tivity of the labor. Thus, it Is expected that the difference between what a
Corpsman is expected to earn over his lifetime, as measured in present benefits
and what he would have been expected to earn without Job Corps, will increase
at a rate equal to the secular growth in real wages. Our estimates of the bene-
PAGENO="0172"
168
fits measured in present increments should have been inflated by two percent a
year before they were discounted. To simplify the calculations, the improvement
in labor productivity was discounted by three and five percent instead of in-
creasing these benefits by a two percent growth rate and then discounting by
five and seven percent. Mathematically, the two procedures are identical. Thus,
the effective discount rates used were 5 and 7 percent and not the 3 and 5 percent
used in the calculation.
The inclusion or exclusion of the growth rate of real wages does not alter the
comparison of the use of different interest rates and different measures of bene-
fits but it does highlight the difficulties in measuring the benefits from human
resource programs. To further highlight these difficulties, let us assume that the
appropriate measure of benefits is that differential in income which would be
received over the lifetime of the individual. Direct analysis of the impact on
lifetime earnings is impossible if evaluation is to be undertaken within a rea-
sonable amount of time.
One possible way of calculating the benefits is to use the well-documented
correlation between lifetime earnings and educational level. Thus, it is possible
to use the difference in educational attainment between participants in the pro-
grams and nonparticipants of equal qualifications (age, sex, race, socioeconomic
background, natural ability, etc.) and then use the correlation between educa-
tional level and lifetime earnings to provide a dollar measure of program returns.
The use of educational level as a direct measure of lifetime earnings implies
that the programs have no economic impact unless they lead to higher educational
attainment.
A second possible way of calculating the benefits, also used in the Job Corps
study, measures some initial differences in income between program partici-
pants and a control group and makes some assumptions about the pattern of
future differentials. Potential assumptions are numerous and past patterns of
such differentials not very well documented.
Thus, differences occur by using alternative procedures of estimating the
same benefit-differential lifetime earnings. Further, this is not the only benefit
of a program. Given the present state of the art of measurement, there are many
intangibles which cannot be translated into dollar benefits. For example, there
are many benefits in addition to the increased earnings of the participants of
Job Corps. Some of the gains are measurable in principal but have yet to be
measured. Possible reductions in crime and welfare rates are examples. Others
may never be measurable, but are still important, such as the benefits to earnings
capabilities gained from what Job Corps calls the "socialization process"-the
ability to get along with other people in a work situation. Other gains are even
less tangible but are perhaps the most important of all. An example here would
be effectiveness of Women's Job Corps in maintaining the stability of the future
families of girls currently passing through the program.
In conclusion 1 would like to say that the discount rate and discounting play
an important role in the process of evaluating human resource programs. How-
ever, the art of identifying and measuring benefits, in the near future, is likely
to have much more of an effect on our evaluations. This does not mean that the
questions surrounding discounting should not be answered but only that, in the
human resource area, the attention of our analysts must be directed primarily
at those most basic questions of benefit calculations.
Chairman PRox~IIRE. Gentlemen, these have been very, very interest-
ing as well as diversified presentations.
Mr. Enthoven, or Mr. Lynn-I do not know which would like to
respond to this, perhaps both of you-I infer from your statement that
any discrete undertaking which has either cost or benefit effects accru-
ing in the future requires disco~mting for an appropriate appraisal
of its current worth. Do you agree with that?
Mr. ENTHOVEN. Yes, sir; we do agree with that.
Mr. LYNN. Very much.
Chairman Pnox~mm. So that any agency which has a capital budget
to allocate must undertake this kind of analysis if it is to efficiently
allocate this budget among alternatives.
Mr. ENTIJOVEN. I believe that is correct, sir.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Mr. Mackey, would you agree to that?
PAGENO="0173"
169
Mr. MAcliaY. Yes, sir.
Chairman PR0xMIRE. I have here a letter from Mr. Turner in re-
sponse to an inquiry of him, in which he says:
Replying to your letter of February 9, the Bureau of Public Roads does not
use discounting techniques in administering the Federal aid and direct Federal
highway construction programs. In addition, we do not plan to use discounting
techniques in the future.
how can you defend the U.S. Government policy of allocating this
multibillion-dollar highway capital budget without recourse to such
analysis?
Mr. MACKEY. I would not purport to defend it, Senator.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Well, what can we do about it? Would it not
make sense for Congress to require its States and municipalities to
initiate, at least to institute PPBS before they can qualify for Federal
funds?
Mr. MACKEY. I think that would be one approach. It might be quite
a reasonable one. I think there is certainly an alternative approach
which I hope that we will be able to accomplish even in the absence
of that kind of congressional action. We have just recently initiated a
review of all of the discounting procedures within the Department.
They vary widely, and I would hope that in a relatively short time
we would have a far more consistent policy, and maybe some of the
plans of some of our various components would change.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Well, I hope you can do this as soon as possible.
Of course, the difficulty with our highway program is that it tends to
be somewhat insulated from the discipline, even the relatively feeble
discipline the Government can exercise, let alone the discipline that pri-
vate corporations have to exercise in order to survive in that you have
regular source of trust fund income, primarily from the gasoline tax.
That does not, it seems to me, justify its exemption from the use of
resources which, after all, are secured by taking money from the tax-
payer which otherwise could be invested, would be invested to a consid-
erable extent, either in consumption or an investment in `the economy.
Mr. MACKEY. This is one of the main problems I was trying to get
at in my discussion of the highway trust fund. I think you know, too,
there have been a number of instances in the transportation field where
the Congress itself has been considerably more reluctant than the execu-
tive branch to try to apply similar types of rational analysis. We are
prepared to move as far as we can as rapidly as we can to apply this
across the board.
Chairman PR0xMIRE. You note in your statement that there are a
number of other legal restraints which keep the Department of Trans-
portation from instituting sound economic analysis. You mention sec-
tion 7 of the Department of Transportation Act. Would you outline
what some of these constraints are?
Mr. MACKEY. You mean under section 7?
Chairman PRox~ITRE. Yes.
Mr. MACKEY. There are six items which are included in section 7
where we are not allowed to develop investment criteria. The two most
important of those `tre the ~tater resources area and grant in `ud pio
grams. Since the highway program and the Federal aid airport pro-
gram are grant-in-aid programs it would seem that this applies. We
do not have a definitive legal opinion as to the scope of' sectiOn 7 in its
PAGENO="0174"
170
applicability. But the legislative history indicates that the Congress
was clearly trying to carve out some areas where they do not want us to
go, do not want us doing this kind of analysis.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Is this the controversy about using current
rates rather than costs in evaluating waterway projects?
Mr. MACKEY. That is the second paragraph of section 7(a). The first
paro graph of section 7(a) lists the exemptions, and the second para-
graph says specifically what rates shall be used in the evaluation of
waterway programs and projects. It is the argument of current rail
versus future waterway rates.
Chairman PROXMIRE. The requirement is that you use current rail
rates, which would seem to me to be a transparently unfair
comparison.
Mr. MACKEY. Obviously.
Chairman PRox~rInE. In fact, I voted against the Transportation
Act creating your Department because I thought it was so unconscion-
able. I spoke very vigorously about this on the floor. Congress, as
you indicated, had another view and they passed an act putting this
kind of unfairness right in the law.
Mr. MACKEY. That was not part of the original administration pro-
posal for the Department Act.
Chairman PRox~IIn~. Will you submit for the record an answer
to the following question: What are the primary constraints which
now hinder the implementation of a sound economic analysis in your
Department which could be relaxed by congressional action?
Mr. MACKEY. Yes, sir.
Chairman PRoxi~rinE. What kinds of legislation would you find most
helpful in removing these impediments to sound economic analysis
of the Department of Transportation expenditures?
Mr. MACKEY. I shall be glad to.
AcswERs TO QuEsTIoNs ASKED BY SENATOR PROxMIRE OF MR. MACKEY
The questions were:
1. What are the primary constraints which now hinder the implementation
of sound economic analysis in the DOT which could be relaxed by Congressional
action?
2. What kinds of legislation would you find most helpful in removing these
impediments to a sound economic analysis of DOT expenditures?
There are three primary features of DOT legislation which may operate as
constraints to the implementation of sound economic analysis in the Depart~
ment. These are:
1. Sections 7(a) and 4(b) (2) (B) of the Department of Transportation
Act.
2. Laws relating to the Federal Aid Highway Program.
3. The Federal Airport Act.
Part I contains explanations of how each constraint might affect the imple-
mentation of sound economic analysis in DOT and how certain legislation could
improve conditions. Part II contains a discussion of administrative and non.
economic considerations which might alter the nature of the legislation.
PART I: CONSTRAINTS ON IMPLEMENTATION OF ECONOMIC ANALYSIS
Provisions in the DOT Act
The language of Section 7(a) of the Department of Transportation Act limits
the Secretary's role in developing investment criteria for the formulation and
economic evaluation of proposals for the investment of Federal funds when those
proposals are concerned with certain types of projects.
Section 4(b) (2) of the same Act is also pertinent. It states that "Nothing in
PAGENO="0175"
171
this Act shall be construed to authorize, without appropriate action by Con-
gress, the adoption, revision, or implementation of-
(A) any transportation policy, or
(B) any investment standards or criteria."
During the last several years, the Executive Branch, through the Bureau of
the Budget has evolved a system (PPBS) for planning Federal expenditures in
an economically efficient manner through the setting of what amount to invest-
ment criteria. These criteria are applied in most government Departments and
agencies as an administrative requirement. There would not appear to be special
reasons for imposing particular restrictions such as those in Sections 7(a) and
4(b) (2) on DOT's authority to manage its programs.
Laws Relating to the Federal Aid Highway Program
The Federal Aid Highway Program as it is currently structured under Title
23 would appear to contain the following three principal constraints on the im-
plementation of sound economic analysis.
1. The law provides that Federal Highway expenditures be determined by the
amounts collected from motor vehicle user taxes as they are placed in the High-
way Trust Fund. Such pay-as-you-go trust fund financing schemes can be restric-
tive in the following two ways:
i. The trust fund equation of expenditures to amounts received from user
taxes may not guarantee an economically efficient total amount of expendi-
ture to the extent that might be possible if the receipts were from a competi-
tive market and the taxes were annually adjusted.
ii. The pay-as-you-go arrangement may build a further inflexibility into
the system. In any program in which future receipts accrue as a result of
capital expenditures the agency should be allowed to borrow against future
earnings at some rate of interest. Under a more flexible system, a program
with a rate of growth (and rate of increase of capital stock) higher than
the interest rate would spend in a given year more than it collects, while a
low growth program would collect more than it spends.
2. Another type of inflexibility, essentially independent of the trust fund con-
cept, may arise from the fact that amounts allocated to specific States and spe-
cific programs within States are distributed according to formulas in proportion
to areas, populations, and miles of postal route without explicit regard to the
relative benefit/cost relationships of projects among or within those States.
Furthermore, the funds which States receive for constructing Interstate High-
ways are apportioned in proportion to the estimated cost of completing the sys-
tem in each State, which would hardly be expected to provide an incentive for
economic allocation with the State since the State itself contributes only ten
percent.
3. Finally, the fact that the funds for highway construction are allocated with-
in each State by the State Highway Department or equivalent agency tends to
make it more difficult for DOT to implement economic analysis since these agen-
cies are not under its administrative control.
Broad legislative changes needed to relax the above apparent constraints
might be along the following lines:
Money collected from road user taxes might be placed in the Treasury
and not in a special fund.
Road user taxes might be revised on a continuing basis according to the
long run marginal cost due to the movement of different types of motor ve-
hicles. Special congestion taxes might also be levied where appropriate and
feasible.
Grants might be allocated to States based on benefit/cost considerations
of capital investments towards which the grants would apply.
The DOT, in cooperation with the States might help develop benefit/cost
criteria for the evaluation of highway investment.
The total amount of grants might be determined by the results of bene-
fit/cost studies of capital investments.
The Federal Airport Act
Although the Federal Airport Act contains a method of allocation of funds
similar to the highway laws in that most of the fundings is allocated by a fixed
formula based on area and population of States, it does not, however, contain
the trust fund features of the highway laws and it provides more Federal. ad-
ministrative control over individual projects by means of the National Airport
/
PAGENO="0176"
172
Plan formulation. It also allows the Federal Aviation Administrator to allocate
25 percent of the annual appropriations at his discretion.
In order to provide more flexibility for implementation of economic analysis
it might be necessary to allow the Administrator to allocate the full amount of
appropriations at his discretion, i.e. according to uniform investment criteria
set by DOT.
PART II: ADMINISTRATIVE AND NON-ECONOMIC CON5ID~ATIONS
Section 7(a)
As explained in Part I, the amendment of Section 7(a) of the Deparhnent of
Transportation Act would facilitate implementation of effective economic analysis.
There does not appear to be any important administrative or non-economic rea-
son why the Act should remain as it is.
Laws Relating to the Federal Aid Highway Program
The concept of a trust fund related to user charges contains the desirable fea-
ture of allowing for long-range programing of highway expenditures. This feature
could be retained without much distortion provided that the level and structure
of user charges feeding the fund are reviewed at relatively frequent intervals
with an eye to revision in the light of changes in National transportation demand.
The pay-as-you-go nature of the fund could possibly be revised, however, so that
bonds might be issued against future user charges revenues, and the total amount
of annual construction might be determined by economic studies of transportation
demand. The pay-as-you-go formula is currently mitigated to some extent by the
provision that Federal funds can be used to repay State bonds for highway
construction.
Perhaps the best feature of the distribution formulas is that they provide a
generally predictable source of funds for each State for its planning purposes. But
a portion of these funds might still be allocated at the discretion of the Secretary
using guidelines which give priority to States with projects having high benefit!
cost ratios. Also the distribution of expenditure as among Interstate, primary,
secondary, and urban extension roads within a State could be somewhat more
flexible than provided by the current law (which provides a separate set of funds
for Interstate Highways, and which allocates 45 percent of another set of funds
to primary, 30 percent to secondary, and 25 percent to urban extensions and does
not allow either of these three apportionments to increase or decrease by more
than one-fourth within a State through transfers).
As to the restrictions caused by lack of direct administrative control of State
Highway Departments, there appears to be logic in retaining this feature of
decentralized planning since a large portion of projects, particularly in urban
areas, are of essentially local concern.
The Federal Aid to Airports Act
The distribution formula serves the same general purposes here as in the high-
way case. However, the current 25 percent allocated at the discretion of the Fed-
eral Aviation Administrator might likewise be increased to allow further flexi-
bility without eliminating the automatic allocation completely.
Grant Programs in General
Eventually, grant programs regarding urban transportation and ultimately
intercity transportation should be put on a common basis. A decision-making body
at the local level which is choosing between alternatives, one of which involves
90 percent Federal financing (an Interstate highway), and the other of which
involves competition with other areas for a small amount of grant money (mass
transit), is likely to be biased in its choice. Legislation of a scope broad enough
to change the current situation should be designed to improve the incentive
structure for grant recipients to induce them to implement economically efficient
systems. This kind of incentive structure would reinforce the effect of investment
criteria established by DOT.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Mr. Levine, in your testimony, you claim that
the interest rate is of comparatively minor importance in evaluating
public investment in human resources and that benefit estimation is
the main bottleneck. This being the case, what do you consider to be
the crucial next move to either improve the conceptual basis for bene-
PAGENO="0177"
173
fit estimation or the empirical measurement of the concepts which we
already have?
Mr. LEVINE. The next crucial move has to be data systems. I men-
tion in my remarks some obstacles to this in terms of decentralization.
Nonetheless, I think we have work to and we are working on design-
ing methods of getting data in. I think we ought to use more sampling,
perhaps, rather than trying to get uniform data which ends up in
warehouses when we get it at all, rather than try to get universal data.
I think the design of data systems which will provide the necessary
data in sufficient quantity, sufficient range, is basic to everything else
in the human resources programs.
Chairman PROXMIRE. What plans does your `agency have for im-
proving the reliability of benefits in human resources?
Mr. LEVINE. Well, again, this goes to the data. We are going into
sampling. We are going into some evaluation of programs on a sample
basis because the operating systems are not providing data that will
enabie us to do this kind of analysis. One immediate effort is to go' out
for `a contract that will compare five manpower training programs.
This is not just our Department, this is the Department of Labor and
ourselves in cooperation. We compare the MDTA training program,
Job Corps, the Neighborhood Youth Corps, the new JOBS, J-O-B-S,
the National Alliance of Businessmen program, and the new careers
program on a basis which will get followup data and current experi-
ence data on the participants in these programs, compare their charac-
teristics, and then their subsequent experience, to make estimates of
future earnings and therefore to do comparative benefit-cost analyses
on these crucial training programs.
That is our most immediate program, and I think most exciting, that
we have along these lines.
I mentioned our efforts to harden soft data in the community ac-
tion area. We are engaged now in a full-sca~Ie fieldwork which will
provide data for analysis of the Headstart program, the full year
and the summer Headstart programs, both as to their immediate effec-
tiveness with children and to their effectiveness going into the first
years of the child's education. These are .a few examples of the kinds
of plans we have to do this analysis.
In each case we are using sample data. That may be, so far as our
kind of program goes, the only way to do it.
Chairman PROXMIRE. I cannot think of anything you could do that
would be more important. I really cannot. I think this goes to the
very heart of it. We know we are going to have limited funds for
these things. We have been through this. A lot of people feel we are
gOing to fall into a great windfall of Federal money that will be
available when the Vietnam war is over. Unfortunately, this is just
not true. The competent people in the Defense Department-Secre-
tary Nitze told us in the Appropriations Committee that he would
estimate that we would be fortunate if the Defense budget is kept at a
$75 billion level. It is now $82 billion, so $7 billion is not much of a
saving.
We know the enormous cost of housing which is going to burgeon.
We know in so many other areas where the demands for Federal funds
are going to increase at a very, very rapid rate. We also. know how the
/
A
PAGENO="0178"
174
people who pay taxes are reacting and the great power they have in
the Oongress, properly so.
So that there is just going to be a great pressure on finding out
what programs have a good payoff, what do not, and determining
on the basis of the fairest, most objective kind of comparison rather
than any political pressure which are the best programs, and then
move ahead onthem.
So I just hope you can put a lot of time and effort into this.
I think the Defense Department has been the real pioneer in this.
I suppose anybody just thinking about it 10 years ago or 15 or 20 years
ago, you simply cannot apply it to Defense. It is something where
there is no fair comparison. You cannot really use the kinds of analyses
that are appropriate for private enterprise in our Defense expendi-
tures. Yet it has been applied, as you know, I think, with brilliant
success; with great economic effect, and with an ability to increase our
firepower, for example, with a relatively modest increase in cost. It
can be done so effectively there; it seems to me it can be done even in
your area, which I a.dn~it is puzzling, difficult, and which has, as you
say, a great problem in estimating benefits. But I think you should
do it in two ways: No. 1, you should extend it just as broadly as your
imagination can, challenge these assumptions all along the line.
Then, No. 2, you should make your findings available to the Con-
gress when these programs come up so that we have an opportunity
to consider the alternatives, so that we do not just cut deeply in the
Department without knowing precisely what the effect will be and
without knowing what the alternatives are. This is the only way I
think we can get effective efficiency and economy in our governmental
operations.
Mr. LEVINE. I certainly agree, Mr. Chairman. Let me emphasize I
was not saying we cannot do it; we are doing it. The specific rigorous
methods are slow in coming. The cost-benefit method of thinking has,
I think, been pervasive in a lot of our work, both internal and in our
presentation to Congress. We have tried to present programs as alter-
natives, using qualitative statements where quantitative were not
available.
We have also done, as I indicated, quantitative work and, in fact,
this has been supplied for 2 years now to our legislative committees.
I would not like to leave the impression that we are in the state the
Department of Defense was in 20 years ago, but we are certainly not in
the state the Department of Defense is in now.
Chairman Piox~mu~. HEW has done some good work in this area,
too, as you know. They also ~have a problem not unlike that of the
Department of Transportation in some of these other areas, where
you are dealing with physical production which can be measured more
objectively and precisely and compared in terms of benefits. They do
not have as much of that, yet they have made some real progress.
Mr. Ohartener has been a real force there in the past. I guess he is
over in Commerce now, but he was in the Health, Education, and Wel-
fare Department.
Mr. LEVINE. Yes, sir.
Chairman PROXMIRE. I would like to come back to Defense, and I
very much appreciate, Mr. Enthoven, your emphasis on the fact that
cost effectiveness is an aid to judgment and not a substitute for it.
PAGENO="0179"
175
There is no question about that, and with your experience in the De-
partment of Defense, you have found that to be true. You have many
instances, I am sure, where you found that one system seems to work
out better on a cost-effectiveness basis, but there are other reasons that
could cause you to choose the one that has proven itself less. But at
least you have these guidelines in front of you; is that not the case?
Mr. ENTHOVEN. Yes, sir.
chairman PR0xMIRE. And you have found that discipline, I take it,
essential?
Mr. ENTHOVEN. Essential for the definition and defense of the pub-
lic interest.
chairman PRoxMnm. You seem to go a little lower in your discount-
ing range. You said a 5- to 10-percent range for opportunity cost for
Government investment. Yesterday, Dr. Eckstein-and you all know
what an authority he is-said 7 to 8 percent, Harberger said 12 percent;
Mr. Lynn said 7 percent and up, as I understood him.
Why did you go as low asS percent?
Let me just say that when we discussed this yesterday, it was brought
out that 5.5 percent in Eckstein's view is just about the minimum we
can expect for the riskiess interest rate in terms of what the Federal
Government borrows on a long-term basis. He just does not think it
will go much lower than that, unless we get unemployment, which we
do not expect.
Then you have to add to that, as Mr. Lynn pointed out, your taxes
forgone. When you do that, you come up to a minimum, it would
seem, of 7.5 percent.
How can you go as low as 5?
Mr. ENTHOVEN. When I said 5 to 10 percent, Mr. Chairman, I was
merely describing my impression of the range of expert opinion today.
For one thing, one could make a case for a rate as low as 5 percent, if
one were to adjust current interest rates for the fact that they reflect
expected inflation. For another thing, some economists argue that the
Government should use a riskless rate in evaluating its investment.
chairman PROXMIRE. That was disputed with great vigor yester-
day by the economists who were here. They contended that-I think
Eckstein's argument was that it would not go much more than 75
basis points, which would be three-quarters of a percent, below this
present level in the future.
Mr. ENTHOVEN. I would not want to argue for anything like the
5-percent rate myself, Mr. Chairman. I personally be1ieve that a much
more accurate estimate of the opportunity cost of capital is some-
where in the range of 8 to 10 percent.
Chairman PRox~rI~. You cannot think-or can you think of any
justification for the operation of the corps of Engineers, which is in
your Department, with regard to their present operation, which is
about 314 percent, for public works projects, and which, for water re-
sources projects, will be 4% percent? Is there any possible economic
justification for that, in your view? I do not mean to be putting you
on t.he spot.
Mr. ENTHOVEN. I must admit I have not studied that particular
question recently, Mr. Chairman. But that does seem to me to be a very
low rate. If we expect other projects in the Government to be designed
around a higher rate, then that is too low.
PAGENO="0180"
176
Chairman PROXMIRE. It is just too low, obviously. It may be that
we are forgetting some of the benefits here or overstating the costs.
But if you have a calculation which includes the costs-
Mr. ENTHOVEN. Yes, sir.
Chairman PROXMIRE (continuing). And includes the benefits, all
the benefits, then it seems to me very hard to justify going much lower
than, as you say 8 to 10 percent; 7 percent anyway. It does not mear~
you do not go ahead even though you have a benefit-cost ratio of less
than unity, but at least you go ahead with your eyes open. You know
what you are doing.
Mr. ENTHOVEN. I agree., Mr. Chairman. I do not think that a de-
partment should he allowed to use an unrealistically low rate on the
basis of alleged nonquantifiable benefits. It would be better to use a
realistic rate and then to define, describe, and defend the nonquanti-
fiable benefits, and present them for the judgment of responsible
officials in the executive and legislative branches.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Mr. Lynn, how would you-or would you de-
scribe for the committee the procedures by which the Government
analysts can make explicit allowances for risk and uncertainty in the
benefit-cost streams?
Mr. LYNN. I think it is important to distinguish between the con-
cept.s of risk and uncertainty.
Chairman PROXMIRE. All right.
Mr. LYNN. Various programs may be subject to foreseeable kinds
of risks; such as, tha.t the costs will be somewhat higher or somewhat
lower than we estimate, or that the particular performance character-
istics will vary somewhat about t.he expected values that we have set
for them.
Chairman PR0xMIRE. That is the uncertainty aspect.
Mr. LYNN. That would be what I would consider the risk aspect;
that is, we can define probabilities for various of these different states
occurring and perhaps develop formal distributions of both the cost
estimates and the performance estimates.
On the other hand, there are other kinds of uncertainties, for ex-
ample, that the requirements may be very different than we estimate
or that the system may not work at all, or that the whole environment
within which we are looking at our problem may change in some
major way. I do not think there is any way to fold such uncertainties
into a discount rate adjustment. I think the best thing to do with those
kinds of situations is to analyze cost and effectiveness under different
circumstances, and then make judgments on the basis of alternative
possible outcomes, rather than trying to subsume every consideration
in the discount rate.
Chairman PROXMIRE. So that you would stick with the discount rate
we have been discussing rather than vary the discount rate depending
on the risk and uncertainty involved, and you would try to provide for
the risk and uncertainty in the benefits?
Mr. LYNN. Well, both the analytical and the practical problems of
handling risk are very subtle.
Chairman PROXMIRE. I think from the political standpoint, that a
consistent rate would be much more desirable. If you can get a rate
and apply it for everybody, you are in much better shape, it would
seem to me, than if you get a rate that varies all over the place.
PAGENO="0181"
177
We have this horrible example now, where it goes all the way from
zero in a few cases, 3 percent and 31/4 percent in an enormous amount
of investment, up to 10 percent for you, where we have most of our
investment, to 12 and 15 percent in other areas. This is so confusing
that it just seems to me you cannot get the kind of discipline necessary
so that Congress knows what it is doing.
Mr. LYNN. Yes; I believe there are very great virtues in consistency.
To the extent that an agency or a proponent of a particular system
argues that special considerations apply, I believe these considera-
tions are best treated by making them explicit by showing alterna-
tive costs and benefit estimates rather than by trying to fold these
questions into the discount rate. I agree with you on that point.
Chairman PRoxMIlre. Let me ask you gentlemen: On Tuesday, the
committee heard testimony which distinguished between public in-
vestments which displaced private investments and those which did
not. For those investments which did displace private investment, it
was recommended that the rate of return in the pertinent private
sector be used for discounting rather than the social opportunity cost
of capital over the whole economy. For those investments that dis-
placed resources in general, the use of the social opportunity cost of
capital over the whole economy was recommended.
Does this distinction strike you as being pertinent? Start with Mr.
Enthoven, or Mr. Lynn, or both of you answer.
Mr. ENTHOVEN. I think that the correct position for the Govern-
merit in general, Mr. Chairman, is to use a single rate-our best esti-
mate of the opportunity cost of the capital used by the Government-
as the norm. However, using that rate as a point of departure, it
might be appropriate to use a different rate in some cases in which
there are special circumstances that justify it. But the deviation
from the norm should be identified and defended explicitly. Now the
example you mention-in which public investment displaces private-
might be such a case. I am not sure. The governing criterion should
be the maximum social product. Moreover, I do not think the issue
of public versus private enterprise should be hidden behind an interest
rate argument. I think it should be made explicit and debated on its
own merits. Perhaps Dr. Lynn has thought about it.
Mr. ~ I think there is a real problem with trying to identify
the opportunity cost of a particular kind of Government investment
with a return on a similar type of private investment. One of the
virtues of the opportunity cost concept is that it forces one to be con-
cerned with what the foregone opportunities actually are, never mind
what the characteristics of the specific project under review may be.
Now, in some instances it may very well be the case that if the Gov-
ernment undertakes a project, the private sector will not.
On the other hand, if the Government undertakes the project, the
foregone opportunities are more likely to be spread very broadly
rather than to be focused on particular industries. I think that adher-
ing to the discipline of the opportunity cost concept and of a sound
measurement of opportunity cost is a much better procedure than
trying to make pair-wise comparisons between public and private
projects of all kinds.
Chairman PRoxMine. Mr. Mackey?
PAGENO="0182"
178
Mr. Ithoiu~. I think in our area there are some attractive aspects
of trying to identify the more or less business-oriented aspects of
Government. But I am not sure that you gain much in the long run.
Some of the investment we undertake is clearly very similar to what
business undertakes. We go at it in a very businesslike way; others,
we do not.
You get into a great many questions. One, for example, is what if
the public investment you are undertaking is really due to the fact
that you have a private monopoly, either in that field or some other
field, and you have to get into it. Questions of this sort tend, in my
mind, at least, to detract from the usefulness of this kind of distinc-
tion. So I guess where I come out is I am probably more inclined to
say that the social opportunity costs applied across-the-board may
make more sense.
Chairman PnoxMnu~. Mr. Levine?
Mr. LEVINE. I am less certain than the rest of my colleagues about
the importance of a single discount rate covering all programs and
all purposes. I feel this way because I think our problem is a very
real problem. I think the answer that applies to your question is it
depends upon what policy question you are asking. If the policy
question is one of anature comparing two programs with similar use
of resources-in our field, for example, a public housing program
versus a private housing program-I think that the appropriate dis-
count rate might be the cost of private capital in the mortgage market.
For the same public housing program, however, if you could compare
it to another sort of antipoverty program, a different discount rate
riiight be appropriate. I am not scared of having two different discount
rates for two different purposes. So I think for some purposes this
would be justified, for some policy decisions. For other policy deci-
sions, the proper discount rate might be the overall opportunity cost
of capital to the Government.
Chairman PRoxMnu~. How about the utilization of resources aspect
of this question in light of a different assumption? Would you change
your views on this if we did not make the assumption I assume all
you gentlemen are making and that the economists yesterday made,
that we are operating, if not at full employment, fairly close to it or
at least at the level of unemployment at which any lower level would
result in unacceptable inflation? Supposing we had a situation of
unemployment that was very high and of utilization of plant ca-
pacity which was quite low, so we had available resources, we would
not be displacing resources when we engage in Government activity.
How would this affect the discount rate, if it would?
Mr. ENTHOVEN. Well, if we have significant unemployment, it makes
sense for the Government to spend more or tax less to correct it. If
you used a lower discount rate, that would stimulate public invest-
ment. If that were done, however, it ought to be justified explicitly
as for that purpose, and there should be a uniform policy.
Chairman PROXMIRE. How would you do that? This is quite a serious
problem. Yesterday Dr. Eckstein made the assumption that we just
cannot get below ~.5 percent unemployment. He felt that if you were
below that, we would not stand for it, Congress would not stand for it.
He may be right or he may not be right, iii the 1950's we had periods
where it was 7 percent. We have had periods where our plant capacity
has been utilized at 75, 70 percent.
PAGENO="0183"
179
Obviously, these idle resources could be used on some quite marginal
Government projects and make a contribution to economic growth.
Mr. LYNN. I think one important purpose of a discount rate is to
discriminate between profitable projects and unprofitable projects.
That is a somewhat different problem than deciding on the overall
level of investment the Government may want to undertake to stimulate
private demand.
Chairman PROXMIRE. So that what you might do under some cir-
cumstances is only invest where you have a benefit-cost ratio of maybe
1.5 or 2 to 1, and other circumstances, you may go below unity?
Mr. LYNN. In my view, that would be a more practical procedure
than trying to manipulate the discount rate to track a very changeable
set of circumstances. It is much easier to change your ideas about
what is an acceptable cutoff ratio; if you have significant unemploy-
ment problems, lower the ratio.
Chairman PROXMIRE. It has been :suggested to the committee that
the next step in achieving a consistent interest rate policy would be
for some Federal agency to undertake a study to implement the
methodology for estimating the social cost of capital over the whole
economy. Would you gentlemen agree with this recommendation?
If this is not the first step, what would you think-what would be
the next step?
Mr. LYNN. In my own personal judgment, there are still a lot of
unresolved questions in coming up with a fully acceptable concept
for measuring the social opportunity cost.
Chairman PROXMIRE. That, of course, is what the agency would have
to do.
Mr. LYNN. I simply have not thought about who should do it, but
I do think there are advantages to trying to reconcile the different
ideas and opinions that people have about the right concept and how
to go about measuring it. I do not know who might do it, but I think
such a study would be useful.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Mr. Mackey?
Mr. MA0KEY. I guess I share the opinion. I think it would be useful
to have. I do not know who would do it, whether it would be the Bureau
of the Budget or whether they should try to find a single agency and
encourage this agency to do it.
Chairman PRox~IIRE. One certain criterion such an agency should
have, it should not have an ax to grind. Obviously you should not
pick an agency with an ax to grind. Certainly you should be repre-
sented. But something like the Council of Economic Advisers, the
Bureau of the Budget, some agency which has a degree of objectivity
as well as a professional competence in this area should be in charge.
Mr. Levine?
Mr. LEVINE. I certainly would like to see such a study covering the
human resource field. As I have indicated, I have some doubt about the
need for consistency between these and others, but there is certainly a
need for consistency of discount rate and, for that matter, methodology
of cost-benefit work in the fields covered by HEW, the Department of
Labor, and ourselves.
I have seen one set of studies which somebody tried to compare,
where there was a simple difference, that savings to the Government
PAGENO="0184"
180
in one study were subtracted from costs and in the other study were
added to benefits. You get different ratios that way. When subtracted
from costs, you might get a negative ratio. There are all sorts of
methodological inconsistencies.
Chairman PROXMIRE. What you are saying is you want a competent
agency to make the study?
Mr. LEvI~. Yes, sir.
Chairman PROXMIRE. However, as Dr. Otto Eckstein said yesterday,
he thought it was also important that you have an agency to put this
into effect like the Bureau of the Budget, that would have authority
and power, could make its position effective.
Mr. LEVINE. I would not presume to choose the agency. In the
manpower training study I mentioned before, we are achieving that
by having joint sponsorship of the two agencies.
Chairman PROXMIRE. I am talking about something different from
that. What we are interested in from a congressional standpoint is
having this done in a comprehensive way. I understand perfectly your
feeling that human resources are a special and different kind of case
than physical resources. That is a strong case.
It may well be that we would have to work on some kind of dif-
ferentiation. Nevertheless, I would persist that you ought to have one
agency or one group that would make this study. Then, whether or
not we would decide or the Budget Bureau, the President or the Con-
gress would decide to cover human resources in this way is another
decision.
Mr. LEVINE. I was not arguing against that at all, Mr. Chairman.
I was just backing it up by saying in my narrower field, I see a need
for at least a study covering that field.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Let me ask, presuming that the study was able
to measure effectively the opportunity cost of capital, would you
gentlemen think that the publication on an on-going basis of this
basic risk-free rate as a guide to all Federal agencies would be a helpful
move for sound decisionmaking?
Mr. ENTHOVEN. I think it would be helpful, Mr. Chairman. I have
introduced the discount rate as a factor to be considered in particular
decisions and gotten the reaction that I was pulling a rabbit out of a
hat as an argument in a particular case. Then I have had to explain
and defend the whole theory of interest rates. An authoritative
Government-wide position on interest rates would make it possible
for practitioners m particular areas to refer to it. Then they would
not have to argue the whole issue of discount rates and their relevance
in each particular case. I do think, of course, that it will always be
necessary to consider the specifics in each case, including the risks and
the other special factors involved.
Mr. MAc~nr. Mr. Chairman, I would like to say that the degree of
acceptance of concepts like discounting appear to me to vary widely
within any large organization. As you pointed out, within our own
organization, the Department will have some differences of opinion.
Apparently the Department of Defense has some. I would think in
considering a study like this, one of the alternatives might be finding
some way to have it done in effect for the Congress more directly than
within the executive branch itself, because ultimately, even a more
serious problem than broad-scale acceptance within the executive
PAGENO="0185"
181
branch may be acceptance within the Congress and the willingness
to make decisions on it there. Perhaps some combination of the Joint
Economic Conimittee and the Appropriations Committees getting
together to agree that this is necessary-actually, you make the final
decisions beyond what we have made.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Well, in view of your experience with the
kind of restraints that have been put on your department that we
talked about earlier, I can understand that view. Frankly, as one who
has been up here in the Senate for more than 10 years-nearly 11 years
now-I am convinced that if this is going to be effective with Congress,
when you get the great diversity of views and interests the Congress
represents focused in this area, it has to come from the President of
the United States. He just has to do it.
We discussed yesterday the fact that the Interior Committee, which
has such a tremendously important role to play in water resource
projects, consists of people who come overwhelmingly from Idaho and
Nevada and Arizona and in the House, Colorado, the Western States
that have a crucial stake in water projects. They would like to see
the lowest possible discount rate applied. These are the people to whom
Congress has delegated policy with regard to water.
Even on the Appropriations Committee, the Interior Subcommit-
tee-I happen to be a member of that, but most of the Members
gravitate toward that subcommittee because they want to represent
their State's resources needs as effectively as possible. It is perfectly
understandable.
Under these circumstances, I just do not think you are going to get
effective action in the Congress unless the President of the United
States takes a clear and decisive position, as only he can, on a policy
which will do justice to all people in the society, in the Nation, by
recommending something that is consistent.
That is why it would seem to me that the executive branch has to be
heart and focus of this operation. Although we up here on the Hill
can help, we would like to go into battle with the administration
behind us.
Mr. M~&cici~. I am sure your observation and my views are influ-
enced by the experience we have had, which is correct. But when the
administration attempted to take this kind of leadership in the whole
field of transportation, which is a very significant one in terms of
social and economic impact and dollar level of expenditures, that
kind of leadership was not welcomed with open arms. I just think
you have a great problem of acceptance no matter what kind of lead-
ership the executive branch is able to take unless there is a little
more concern on the part of Congress.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Of course, you cannot expect that leadership
to be welcomed with open arms, recognizing the makeup of Congress.
You have to keep fighting and coming back and getting up off the
floor again and again. It is pretty rugged, but this is the way you do it,
I would think, if it is going to be done at all.
Let me get into something a little more explicit and direct. This is
the last area.
Mr. Lynn, I would like to have you give me a little more specific
detail on your analysis of the supersonic transport. Your table entitled
"Present Value of SST Investment" (see p. 149) -you have minus 344,
98-94O-~8-----i5
PAGENO="0186"
182
minus 528, minus 579; does that mean that the SST market, as cal-
culated by the Institute for Defense Analysis, would not `have been
economically viable even with a 5-percent discount rate for the SST?
Mr. LYNN. That means `that under `the recoupment formulas that the
Government has decided upon to regain the cash value of its invest-
ment, it would end up in `a negative position `at the end of the period
under consideration.
Chairman PROXMIIRE. What was `that period?
Mr. LYNN. To 1990. If the IDA market estimates are `accepted, the
Government would end up in a negative position and the size of it
would depend on which discount rate you chose to use.
Chairman PRox~nm~. Even `if you take `the FAA `analysis, which is
about as biased as you can get, if you `apply the 10-percent discount
rate, which would seem under these circumstances-and if I `have ever
seen a risky investment, believe me this is it, from the technological
standpoint and all other kinds of standpoints-you would end up
in `a negative position even by 1990; is that correct?
Mr. LYNN. That is correct.
Chairman PROXMIRE. Negative what, minus $239 million?
Mr. LYNN. That is the negative present value at 10 percent?
Chairman `PRox~mu~. Yes. If you adopt the 15 percent, which would
be much more appropriate, it would be $421 `million ou't of `t'he taxpay-
ers' pocket.
Mr. LYNN. That is correct.
Chairman PRox~1nu~. The break-even point `is 6.85 percent?
Mr. LYNN. Yes, sir.
Chairman PROXMIRE. I take it it would be pretty h'ard to justify a
break-even point of 6.85 percent for something like `the SST.
Mr. LYNN. I might add that the estimates here assume that all of
the costs of the program prior `to fiscal 1969 are counted `as sunk costs.
Our calculations here look only at those outlays we would `have to un-
dertake beginning with `the next fiscal year.
Chairman PnoxMnm. In other words, you are not even including
those costs?
Mr. LYNN. No, sir.
Chairman PROXMLRE. Brother, they are sunk.
Well, thank you, gentlemen, very, very much. This has been, I think,
a fitting climax to our hearings. Perhaps I should not have brought the
last item up. But you have done a fine job. We appreciate it. You `have
given us some examples which I think we are very much `indebted to
you for.
I would like to state at this point that `additional materials `and state-
ments will be `included in the appendix, as is our usual custom.
The committee will stand adjourned.
(Thereupon, at 11 :55 a.m. the hearings in the above matter were
concluded.)
PAGENO="0187"
APPENDIX
STATEMENT OF PAUL A. AMUNDSEN, EXECUTIVE DIRECTOR,
AMERICAN ASSOCIATION OF PORT AUTHORITIES
The public port industry of the United States, as represented by this Associa-
tion, consists of some 70 deepwater port systems, on all coastlines under develop-
ment by agencies of state or local governments. Within the 70 are numerous
multi-port complexes involving State-wide port authorities.
This Association recognizes the problem before the Subcommittee on Economy
in Government of the Joint Economic Committee in weighing a realistic and
perhaps more uniform approach to the rate of return on the Federal dollar in-
vested. We sense that the concern of the Committee lies in the general range
of water resource projects identified with conservation, flood control, irrigation,
and other humanitarian concepts wherein there is much latitude and few guide-
posts, so that realistic investment norms are sought as an aid to the policy-maker.
It is Our general feeling as public agencies that the importance of water
resources is such that the Federal government should not expect a rate of return
on investment in them any higher than the actual average interest cost to the
Treasury of funds it borrows on a long-term basis.
But specifically, we feel that the Committee should be aware of the rather spec-
tacular economics of ship channels, which are also "waterway projects" and
should exercise great caution in the use of arbitraries which might affect the more
substantial local investment, and, indeed, the national economy to the extent it
is dependent upon world trade, together with a major job market.
We would hope that through these hearings, the Committee, and, indeed, the
Congress and various departments of the administration can be made more
aware of a most attractive national investment.
The port authorities are responsible for the development of piers, wharves
and docks over which flows the foreign trade of the United States. Port facilities
of the country are provided, in the main, through local public funds under gen-
eral obligation bond issues, or revenue bond issues, or operating revenues, or ap-
propriations by State and local governments.
During the two decades following World War II approximately $2,127,464,000
has been invested by the local agencies in direct port facilities.
Correspondingly, the Federal government investment in the deepwater ports
of the United States, mainly in the form of ship channels, has totalled about $1.2
billion during the same period of time.
Thus it may be seen that on a national average taken over two decades local
government is putting into port facilities for foreign commerce very close to
$2.00 for every $1.00 invested by the Federal government.
To complete this general picture, almost $55 billion in two-way foreign trade
(1966 figures) flows through this port system annually.
More than $2.5 billion was collected by the Federal government in Customs
for the fiscal year ending July 30, 1968 on imported goods flowing over these
facilities.
According to a port by port survey, recently undertaken by The American
Association of Port Authorities, approximately 600,000 jobs are directly in-
volved in the ports in handling this export and import trade. These include such
people as stevedores and longshore labor, towing, pilotage, freight forwarding
and customs brokers, warehousing and packaging, banks and marine insurance,
and the like.
In a broader sense, a study by the Marine Administration of the Department
of Commerce several years ago reported that 2,500,000 workers were employed
in export related industries in states having port facilities, with almost a million
additional workers supported by activities connected with U.S. imports.
(183)
PAGENO="0188"
184
Turning to the relationship of these facts to the matter before the Committee,
it would seem that the provision of navigable channels for world shipping is
not an optional matter, from the viewpoint of the Federal interest. The channels
~ina~st be provided to carry an annual flow of $55 billion worth of merchandise
with all its beneficial impact on the national and local economies and level of
employment. Examined from this standpoint, the investment guideposts become
academic. Norms should be the most nominal that can be established consistent
with general policy. Channels may, indeed, be viewed more as a part of a trading
nation's operating eci~pen~se than from the standpoint of direct investment.
But the Federal investment in channels for ocean shipping remains, despite
the above philosophy, a very profitable one. By any standard an investor who
can, for his dollar, attract two additional dollars of partnership venture capital
and obtain a rate of return of more than 400% per year on his annual investment
is in a good business. This is precisely what has happened to the Federal dollar
invested in channels for world shipping over the twenty year cycle referred to
above . . . in terms of Federal investment in channels, local port authority in-
vestment in piers, wharves and related facilities, and Customs receipts to the
Federal government.
Viewed from the investment standpoint, again the norms should remain nomi-
nal. Harbor improvements are authorized under cost-benefit ratios and are just
as sensitive to the interest rate as are any other waterway projects. But they
have, in addition, a competitive factor which should not be overlooked by the
Committee.
The United States port system, the finest in the world, has been built by free
competition among the port communities of all seacoasts. While this competition
is for cargo traffic, it exists as well in the area of Federal appropriations for
channels. There are just so many Federal dollars appropriated for this work,
and the question of which ports obtain the work goes back to the cost-benefit
ratio.
Therefore, any radical change in the rate of interest applied to cost on the
one hand and benefit on the other will penalize a series of port communities
by altering their competitive position from the standpoint of channel appropria-
tions. Should the result be a diminished flow of cargo, economic impact on these
communities could be severe and should not be underestimated.
The cargo though even a small port community can generate, in that com-
munity, as much as $50 million a year in direct income. For a larger port, the
figure can range between $250 million and $300 million in community income.
We would hope that the Committee, as it weighs the broader problem, would
take no action which would curtail Federal sponsorship of necessary and justifi-
able harbor improvements.
PAGENO="0189"
CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES,
HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES,
Washington, D.C., Augast 17, 1968.
Hon. WILLIAM PROXMIRE,
Chairm~an, Joint Economic Committee, Congress of the United Btates, Washing-
ton, D.C.
DEAR MR. CHAIRMAN: In my opinion, the development of our land and water
resources is vital to the continued economic growth of this country. If the projec-
tions of population growth are anywhere near correct, we are not allocating an
adequate proportion of our annual expenditures for this purpose.
The concept of using the so-called opportunity cost of money, which I am told
would be in the neighborhood of 10 to 15 percent in the economic analysis, would
effectively stop the development of all land and water resource projects.
I would like to cite the following example of a project in my state which is re-
cent enough to reflect current procedures of the Corps and at the same time has
been in operation long enough to demonstrate the trend of the commerce being
developed.
For fiscal year 1955 initial construction funds were provided for moderniza-
tion of locks and dams I and 2 on the Green River in Kentucky. At that time the
cost of the work was estimated at $14,399.00. The report of the Corps was predi-
cated on the movement of 2,250,000 tons of coal annually; on this basis, the
Corps reported the benefit-to-cost ratio as being 1.5 to 1. The hearing record for
fiscal year 1955 before the Appropriations Committee shows that there was a
demand for Green River coal by both the TVA and AEC. At that time it was
pointed out that AEC could save 40~ a ton on coal for their Portsmouth plant
alone. Similarly, the savings to TVA to certain of their steam plants of 300 a ton
was indicated. In the case of AEC, firm contracts for 15 years had been signed
with the Ohio Valley Electric Corporation for the delivery of 1,780,000 tons an-
nually. Under the terms of the contract, if the coal could be furnished from the
Green River fields the price to AEC would be 400 a ton less than the alternative
source. The savings to the ABC under that contract alone would be $8,500,000 in
15 years. In both of these cases, the savings in `transportation costs would accrue
directly to the Federal Government, because TVA and ABC are Federal agencies.
Bearing in mind that the estimated tonnage used in the economic justification
for this project was 2,250,000 tons. Actual tonnage on this waterway was:
1957 2,693,350 1962 8, 494, 301
1958 4, 794,960 1963 7,764,284
1959 5,170, 118 1964 10,363, 520
1960 5,446,365 1965 11,309, 727
1961 7, 590, 542 1966* 11, 677, 155
*The latest year for which tonnage is available.
Actual deliveries of coal to ABC and TVA were far greater than the estimates,
and consequently, the direct savings to the Federal Government are substantially
greater than the estimates. While time does not permit a determination of actual
shipments to these Government facilities for incorporation in this letter, I shall
attempt to secure this information and forward it to you at an early date. The
principal point I wish to make is that this project not only was economically
justified by a wide margin, but the savings to the Federal Government in trans-
portation costs alone will more than pay the entire cost of modernizing these
structures. Clearly, it is a wise and prudent investment of Federal funds.
Taking the Corps' estimate of costs and benefits and using the lower figure
of the so-called opportunity cost of money-10%, the benefit-to-cost ratio would
have been 0.56 to 1.0, clearly an uneconomical project.
I sincerely hope that the sub-committee will find it possible to fully consider
this and other similar cases that may be presented before taking final action.
Sincerely,
WILLIAM H. NATOHER.
(185)
PAGENO="0190"
186
WARRIOR-TOMBIGBEE DEVELOPMENT ASSOCIATION,
Birmingham, Ala., August ~O, 1968.
Mr. HENRY P. CAULFIELD, Jr.,
Eccecutive Director, Water Resources Council,
Washington, D.C.
DEAn Mn. CAULFIELD: This is in response to your notice in the Federal Register
under date of July 26, 1968:
We have followed with considerable interest the proposals made before the
Joint Economic Committee that interest/discount rates used in the evaluation of
costs of water resources projects be substantially increased. Giving the proposals
only superficial consideration or looking at them from only a single view point,
makes them seem plausible.
There must be available to the Committee economic studies on which the vast
Appalachia program is based which would demonstrate that much of that pro-
gram is not economically feasible even when the present low interest/discount
rate is used. The Appalachia program, as well as others having to do with general
sociological improvement of the areas which they cover, I believe were enacted
(unless I am badly mistaken) to provide long-range social and economic benefits
rather than immediately traceable economic benefits.
Should application of drastically increased discount rates for water-related
public improvements be made obligatory, many will go by the board. Among
them could be those with which this Association is most concerned-the remain-
ing projects on the Warrior River and tributaries-all of which lie within the
area encompassed by the Appalachia Bill and which have had the support of
the entire Alabama delegations in the House and the Senate. Thus, on one hand,
Congress will have enacted programs to raise the economic and social level of an
area and, on the other hand, if the drastically higher discount rates are estab-
lished, will have instituted rules to negate these benefits.
I believe that the members of the Joint Economic Committee want to be fair
and, therefore, would want to hear equally the opinions of economists with
opposing points of view regarding the social and economic advantages and dis-
advantages of both the low and high discount rate.
We would very much appreciate your making this letter a part of the record
of the Committee.
Sincerely yours,
0. M. KILIAN,
Eccecutive Vice President.
PAGENO="0191"
STATEMENT OF ASSOCIATION OF AMERICAN RAILROADS
CONSISTENT DISCOUNT PROCEDURE FOR PUBLIC EXPENDITURE ANALYSIS
My name is Burton N. Behling. I am Vice President, Economics and Finance
Department, Association of American Railroads (AAR), Washington, D.C.
The AAR is a voluntary association and represents railroads accounting for
98 percent of the operating revenues of all linehaul railroads in the United States.
I appreciate the opportunity of submitting this statement on behalf of the AAR
concerning "Consistent Discount Procedure for Public Expenditure Analysis."
This Committee is to be commended for conducting these pioneering hearings.
I am confident the hearings will foster improvements in evaluating public in-
vestments by focusing attention on the critical role of interest rates used in
such analyses.
INTRODUCTION
Historically, there has been no uniform method for computing interest rates
for use in evaluating public investments. This deplorable condition has resulted
in the misallocation of resources between the public and private sectors of the
economy as well as among various public investment undertakings. Moreover,
the lack of a uniform interest rate formula makes it almost impossible for the
Congress to evaluate the relative economic efficiency of alternative public invest-
ments recommended by the various Government Departments.
My statement briefly discusses the following interest rate concepts that have
been used or proposed foruse in evaluating public investments:
1. Coupon rate on long-term Treasury securities.
2. Yield on long-term Treasury securities.
3. The social rate of time preference.
4. The opportunity cost of capital.
5. Cost of long-term Treasury securities adjusted for taxes forgone.
For the purpose of this statement, the relevancy of the five concepts of interest
rates listed above are evaluated on the basis that the appropriate interest rate
for use in evaluating public investments should provide the most efficient allo-
cation of the Nation's limited resources between the public and private sectors
of the economy as well as between the present and future generations.
I have assumed that the public investment of resources should meet the test
of economic efficiency, although recognizing some government programs involving
social goals or objectives need not meet this test. However, this does not preclude
the use of the discounting procedure for evaluating public expenditures for
strictly social goals.
After determining the most relevant interest rate concept for use in evaluating
public investments, I have suggested a rate of interest for use by all Government
Departments.
COUPON RATE ON LONG-TERM TREASURY SECURITIES
Senate Document No. 97, 87th Congress, 2nd Session, provides that the discount
rate for use in evaluating water and related land resource projects be based on
the average rate of interest payable by the Treasury on interest-bearing market-
able securities of the United States outstanding at the end of the fiscal year
preceding such computation which, upon original issue, had terms to maturity
of 15 years or more. The application of this formula currently results in an
interest rate of 314 percent for evaluating the costs and benefits of water and
related land resource projects.
There is no question that this formula results in understating the real cost
of borrowing by the U.S. Treasury. It is equally clear that returns in the private
sector are substantially greater than 314 percent. Consequently, the use of this
formula has resulted in the misallocation of the Nation's resources. There is
general agreement among economists that an interest rate based on the coupon
rate of long-termTreasury securities is not relevant for the purpose of evalaating
public investments.
(187)
PAGENO="0192"
188
YIELD OF LONG-TERM TREASURY SECURITIES
On July 26, 1068, the Water Resources Council proposed a new formula for
computing the interest rate to be used in the formulation and evaluation of water
and related land resource projects. The Water Resources Council proposed that
the discount rate be determined as follows:
"The interest rate to be used in plan fOrmulation and evaluation for discount-
ing future benefits and computing costs, or otherwise converting benefits and costs
to a common basis, shall be based upon the average yield during the preceding
fiscal year on interest-bearing marketable securities of the United States which,
at the time the computation is made, have terms of 15 years or more remaining
to maturity: provided, however, that in no event shall the rate be raised or low-
ered more than 1/4 percent in any year." (Underscoring added.)
The Water Resources Council computes the proposed discount rate to be 45/s
percent and recommends it be used in plan formulation and evaluation of water
and related land resource projects during the remainder of fiscal year 1969. It
should be noted that the proposed discount rate of 4~/8 percent is based upon the
average of bid prices for fiscal year 1966. This contradicts the formula quoted
above which provides that the interest rate to be used in fiscal 1969 be based
on 1068 yields. The Council adopted the bid prices for fiscal 1966 to meet the needs
for a deflated discount rate, since the Federal bond markets for the past two
years have reflected rising expectations with regard to inflation.
Although this formula is a substantial improvement over the procedure pro-
vided by Senate Document No. 97 and is a step in the right direction, it, too, does
not accurately reflect the real cost of long~term borrowing by the United States
Treasury. The use of this formula will continue to result in the misallocation of
the Nation's resources since the returns in the private sector of the economy are
substantially greater than 4% percent.
The Water Resources Council proposes that the current coupon rate of 314 per-
cent be used to evaluate projects which have been authorized by or will be au-
thorized by Congress prior to the close of the second session of the 90th Congress,
and where the appropriate state or local governmental agency or agencies have
given satisfactory assurances by December 31, 1969, to pay the required non-
Federal share of project costs, unless Congress decides otherwise.
The proposal to continue to use the coupon rate of interest (3i4%) in evaluat-
ing authorized projects, even though no construction has commenced, has no
economic merit and will result in the misallocation of the Nation's limited re-
sources. I am confident there are a number of authorized projects with marginal
benefit-cost ratios based on an interest rate of 314 percent which could not meet
the test of economic efficiency if evaluated on the basis of an interest rate of 4%
percent. Moreover, this proposal places the Congress in the position of having to
appropriate funds for water and related land resource projects on the basis of a
dual standard.
THE SOCIAL RATE OF TIME PREFERENOE
According to this concept, public investments provide benefits to future gener-
ations and it is unlikely that the current cost of capital provides the correct
interest rate for evaluating public investments. Thus, it is contended that current
interest rates do not permit future generations to express their preference and
the Government should adjust the current rate downward because of the willing-
ness of present consumers to shift or redistribute income to future generations.
There is little evidence to support a finding that people collectively approve the
redistribution of income to future generations. Moreover, there are no readily
available data for use in computing the social rate of time preference.
If this concept were followed without considering the opportunities foregone
in the private sector of the economy, it would result in the misallocation of re-
sources since public investments made on this criteria would displace private
investments, for which the returns are much greater. If we are collectively
concerned about the well-being of future generations, efforts should be made to
stimulate those investments that will result in economic growth, which will obvi-
ously increase the well-being of future generations.
OPPORTUNITY COST OF CAPITAL
The opportunity cost of capital is based on the returns foregone in the private
sector of the economy since the Government must obtain its capital through taxes
or borrowing. In the private sector, the opportunity cost for investors is currently
PAGENO="0193"
189
estimated to range from 10 to 20 percent before taxes. The opportunity cost of
consumers is at least equal to the rate that they can receive on riskiess Govern-
ment bonds, currently estimated to be about 51/2 percent. Judged by interest rates
consumers are willing to pay, rather than forego current consumption, the oppor-
tunity cost of capital to consumers is considerably higher, ranging upwards from
7 percent.
An interest rate reflecting the opportunity cost of capital will result in the
most efficient allocation of resources in the public and private sectors of the
Nation's economy. An interest rate which is below this level will divert resources
from the private to the public sector and result in the misallocation and wasteful
use of resources. Conversely, the use of an interest rate in excess of the oppor-
tunity cost of capital in the private sector will discourage public investments
and encourage private investments and consumption, resulting in the misalloca-
tion of resources.
The use of the opportunity cost concept will stimulate both public and private
investments and economic growth, which will increase the incomes of future
generations. Consequently, the opportunity cost of capital in the private sector
is the most relevant interest rate for use in evaluating public investments.
GOVERNMENT ACCOUNTING OFFICE (GAO) COST OF TREASURY BORROWING
The GAO in a hearing before this Committee on January 29, 1068, calculated the
cost of Government bonds to be approximately 7~/2 percent. The GAO essentially
computed the cost of Government borrowing by modifying the average coupon
rate and yield rate on long-term Treasury bonds by making an allowance for
taxes foregone, corporate and personal, as a result of Government borrowing.
Although the GAO is to be commended for its efforts to calculate a meaningful
interest rate, it has certain inherent weaknesses. For example, as noted herein,
the coupon rate on long-term Government bonds has no relevancy and I question
its use by the GAO in calculating an average rate of interest. Moreover, if an
adjustment is made for corporate and personal taxes foregone, similar adjust-
ments must be made for property and sales taxes.
The calculation made by GAO does not accept the concept of opportunity cost
or the yield on long-term Government bonds. Surprisingly, it results in an interest
rate for Government borrowing which closely approximates the average oppor-
tunity cost of capital in the private sector. The GAO formula for calculating the
cost of Government borrowing requires numerous technical adjustments and is
inferior in principle to the concept of the opportunity cost of capital.
RECOMMENDED RATE OF INTEREST FOR USE IN EVALUATING PUBLIC INVESTMENTS
As previously noted, I consider the opportunity cost of capital in the private
sector results in the most efficient allocation of resources between the public
and private sectors of the economy as well as between the present and future
generations. I have not had the opportunity to calculate the opportunity cost of
capital in all relevant sectors of the private economy. However, in the interest of
being conservative, the minimum meaningful opportunity cost in the private
sector should not be less than 5.5 percent, based on returns consumers (taxpayers)
can obtain from riskless Government securities. It is also clear that the return
to private investors will conservatively average about 12 percent. It is suggested
that the relevant interest rate for use in evaluating public investments is in the
range of 8 to 10 percent.
Recognizing that historically public investments, particularly water and land
resource projects, have employed interest rates that were much too low, the
interim use of an interest rate of 5.5 percent, with a subsequent upward adjust-
ment, is recommended. This will allow a period of time for the various Govern-
ment agenices to adjust and make the transition to a more relevant, but higher,
discount rate. Undue delay in adopting a relevant interest rate would only result
in the wasteful use of the Nation's limited resources.
NEED FOR FURTHER STUDY
The fact that various Governmental agencies use different interest rates for
evaluating public investments clearly indicates the need not only for further study
but the need of the Executive Department to provide the necessary leadership
in this area. Although the proposal of the Water Resources Council is a step in
the right direction, as noted herein, it obviously will not result in the most efficient
PAGENO="0194"
190
allocation of the Nation's limited resources. I recommend a continuing study of the
appropriate interest rate or rates to be used in evaluating public investments be
made the responsibility of the Bureau of the Budget or the Council of Economic
Advisers. Not only do they have the professional competency to make the study,
but they are not directly involved in construction or investment programs.
CONCLUSION
Although the interest rate used to evaluate public investments is of critical
importance, we should not overlook the fact that there is no substitute for the
proper analysis of benefits and costs resulting from public investments. For ex-
ample, at the current time there is a legal constraint in evaluating the benefits
resulting from inland navigation projects. This constraint is contained in Section
7 of the Department of Transportation Act of 1966, which requires that naviga-
tion benefits be computed by comparing current rates of overland carriers with
estimated barge rates on projects being studied. There is general concurrence
among knowledgeable transportation economists that this procedure cannot re-
sult in the proper evaluation of benefits resulting from navigation projects. This
can only be done by comparing the long-run marginal costs of all carriers.
PAGENO="0195"
STATEMENT OF BOARD OF COMMISSIONERS OF THE PORT OF NEW
ORLEANS
DISCOUNT RATES FOR USE IN THE FORMULATION AND EVALUATION OF WATER
RESOURCE PROJECTS
The following statement is submitted in behalf of the Board of Commissioners
of the Port of New Orleans (an Agency of the State of Louisiana) on the subject
of the application of economic criteria and discounting procedures in formulating
and evaluating Federal water and related land resource projects. The interest
of the Board, based upon its direct responsibilities, obviously is concerned pri-
marily with channel and harbor development projects for the benefit of deep-
water navigation. However, the development of the inland waterway system of
the Mississippi River and Tributaries which provides a major transportation
network connecting the mid-continent area of the Nation to the Port of New
Orleans and the Gulf Intracoastal Waterway, as well as other shallow draft
channels also are within the Board's area of interest. Furthermore, the safety
of the Port and City of New Orleans, as well as the entire State of Louisiana,
is dependent upon the Federal works for river flood and hurricane protection.
This Board is gravely concerned with the proposals to increase drastically the
discount rate for use in water resources development projects, the effect of which
would be to reduce the benefit-ratio ratios on future potential improvements. In
the economic analysis of water resource projects, an increase in the interest
rate has a double-barrelled effect on the benefit-cost ratio. First, as the interest
rate goes up the interest charge on the borrowed money increases and therefore
the annual cost increases. Second, the present value or worth of future benefits
are drastically reduced as the discount rate increases.
The order of magnitude of the effect of increased discount rates may be shown
by the following example. A project having an assumed economic life of 50 years
may show a benefit-cost ratio of 1.5 to 1 at 3% interest. If this project has a
substantial portion of its benefits accruing in the later years of its life, a higher
discount rate will drastically reduce the future benefits. Therefore, an interest
rate of 4% will reduce the benefit-cost ratio from 1.5 to 1.2. When the interest
rate is increased to 5%, the benefit-cost ratio drops to 1.0; and increasing the
interest rate to 6% results in an unfavorable benefit-cost ratio (below unity).
In recent years, relatively few projects reported by the Corps of Engineers
for authorization have a benefit-cost ratio in excess of 1.5. The impact of a
proposed higher interest rate in evaluating waterway projects therefore becomes
readily apparent.
It is noted that the discount rate for use in plan formulation and evaluation
of projects for waterway development has been 31/4%; however, the Water
Resources Council has announced a proposed new formula for computing rates
under which the rate for fiscal 1969 would be 45/~%, an increase of 1% per-
centage points. Furthermore, it is indicated by the announced policy of the
Water Resources Council that the interest rate shall be subject to recomputation
each year, with the provision that the rate shall not be raised or lowered more
than one-quarter of one percent per year.
The impact of the proposed increase from 3~% to 4%% cannot be fully evalu-
ated on the basis of information currently available. However, no doubt this
drastic adjustment will affect adversely a number of important projects which
are now in the final reporting phase by `the Corps of Engineers. Certain of these
projeets will fall in the category of those having an unfavorable benefit-cost
ratio unless corresponding adjustments are made in the evaluation of benefits.
The gradual adjustment of the interest rate for use in cost analyses may be
fully justified. However, a sudden increase in the interest rate which is to be
applied only to the projects for waterway improvement is discriminatory and
prejudicial to the orderly expansion and development of the Nation's water
resources.
It is understood that consideration is being given to a radical increase in the
interest rate to 71,~% and that upwards of 10% to 15% has been advocated.
(191)
PAGENO="0196"
192
Such a higher rate is excessively and unreasonably high and certainly its appli-
cation to water resource projects would be damaging to the National interest.
The Corps of Engineers has been notoriously conservative in evaluating the
benefits of channel and harbor improvements. Furthermore, the economic
analysis of waterway resources projects has not evaluated secondary or social
and expansion benefits. The benefits attributable to a project from a regional,
State or local viewpoint are not fully evaluated under current procedures. Unless
and until the procedures are revised to allow the full evaluation of benefits to
include the direct and indirect benefits, the tangible and intangible benefits and
also the regional, State and local benefits, the increase in interest rates will be
unbearable. Furthermore, the procedures for the evaluation of public works
projects generally ignore national objectives which are particularly prominent
in the development of channels and harbors required for the operation of the
ports of the United States.
It is recognized that for many years the various Government agencies engaged
in water resources development have used their own judgment as to the interest
rate to be used for Federal and local investments in the evaluation of proposed
projects. This practice has led to inconsistencies among agencies in the appli-
cation of benefit-cost analysis. The elimination of these inconsistencies and the
application of uniform economic criteria and techniques to measure the economic
worth of Government expenditures is to be desired. However, the direction of
movement now indicated would burden the waterway projects with an unreason-
able rate of interest without offsetting changes in evaluation of benefits.
The Board of Commissioners of the Port of New Orleans is gravely concerned
with abrupt and imprudent action in the adjustment of interest rates to be used
in the cost analysis of channel development which will cause a severe cutback in
Federal sponsorship of necessary and justifiable harbor improvements. The
results will be extremely detrimental to the growth and expansion of the mari-
time and port industries of the United States.
PAGENO="0197"
193
STATEMENT OF THE PORT OF NEW YORK AUTHORITY
(By Austin J. Tobin, executive director)
I am pleased to have this opportunity, at your invitation to express the views
of The Port of New York Authority regarding the current deliberations by the
Joint Economic Committee on the possibility of increasing the interest rates
used in public investments by the Federal Government. The questions posed in
your letter of July 24 would seem to be directed toward the whole spectrum of
Federal projects. Since there are considerations here that go well beyond the
purview or expertise of the Port Authority, I should like to address my comments
particularly to the matter of waterway improvements by the Army Corps of
Engineers in which we have a particular and direct interest.
Our concern is not so much with an increase in the interest rates on waterway
projects above the present 31/8 per cent level as it is with the amount to which
this rate would be raised and the possibility that a higher rate might be recom-
mended for waterway improvements than for other federal works projects.
Certainly, a 10 to 15 per cent level, referred to in the past as a possibility, would,
in my opinion, be both unreasonable and completely irrelevant to an economic
analysis of national waterway improvements.
There certainly is no correlation between the rate of return earned on high
risk enterprises in the private sector and the interest or discount rate which
should be used in evaluating the efficacy of public projects dedicated to serve the
public interest. Yet, the suggestion that a 10 to 15 per cent interest rate be used
is based on just such a theory. An increase of this magnitude could only result
in the elimination of urgently-needed improvements and thus be of incalculable
harm to the national interest. Indeed, waterway development has and continues
to be a matter of vital national transportation policy which can at best be
only imperfectly evaluated by the limitations of benefit-cost analysis techniques.
Historically, waterway improvements have produced direct and indirect benefits
substantially greater than those initially predicted by the Corps. Many such
projects would never see the light of day if subjected to an excessively high in-
terest rate, since the present worth of benefits would be reduced and costs cor-
respondingly increased, thereby possibly creating benefit-cost ratios of less than
1.0 for many vital projects.
I do not believe that it is appropriate for us to suggest a specific interest rate
to be used in justifying waterway improvements. If the rate level is to be raised,
the Port Authority strongly urges that it be to a reasonable level appropriate
for public investments. In our view, such a rate should be no higher than the ac-
tual average interest cost to the Treasury of its long-term borrowing, with such
cost to be determined on the basis of yield rates to investors in long-term Federal
securities. But in no event should the rate for waterway projects be higher than
the levels used by other agencies of the Federal Government in the economic
analyses of similar public enterprises. In this connection, and in response to
your question #4, we believe that calculations of interest rates on a continuing
basis, and adopted by all Federal agencies for application to projects of the same
general nature would be most appropriate and desirable. In other words, a uniform
interest rate should apply equally to all comparable public projects, whether
they be for flood control, reclamation, harbor channels, waterway improvements,
or others.
0
PAGENO="0198"