PAGENO="0001"
THE 1968 ECONOMIC REPORT
OF THE PRESIDENT
HEARINGS
BEFORE THE
JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE
CONG~RESS OF THE UNITED STATES
NINETIETH CONGRESS
SECOND SESSION
INVITED COMMENTS
PART 3
Printed for the use of the Joint Economic Committee
~
PROPEIflY OF F~iC~, 1~E SlATE U~VERSITY
COLLEGE OF SOU1H JERSEY LIBRARY
CAMDEN, N. J. 08102
~
/ U.S. OVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE
7 p!r~~L ~`°~I?~/~ ,,ZASrnNGTON 1968
For sale by the S intendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office
Washington, D.C. 20402 - Price 55 cents
`N
PAGENO="0002"
SENATE
JOHN SPARKMAN, Alabama
J. W. FULBRIGHT, Arkansas
HERMAN H. TALMADGE, Georgia
STUART SYMINGTON, Missouri
ABRAHAM RIBICOFF, Connecticut
JACOB K. JAVITS, New York
JACK MILLER, Iowa
LEN B. JORDAN, Idaho
CHARLES H. PERCY, Illinois
WILLIAM H. Mooas
HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES
RICHARD BOLLING, Missouri
HALE BOGGS, Louisiana
HENRY S. REUSS, Wisconsin
MARTHA W. GRIFFITHS, Michigan
WILLIAM S. MOORHEAD, Pennsylvania
THOMAS B. CURTIS, Missouri
WILLIAM B. WIDNALL, New Jersey
DONALD RUMSFELD, Illinois
W. E. BROCK, 3D, Tennessee
JOHN B. HENDERSON
DONALD A. WEBSTER (Minority)
(II)
GEORGE R. IDES
JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE
(Created pursuant to sec. 5(a) of Public Law 304, 79th Cong.)
WILLIAM PROXMIRE, Wisconsin, Olzairrna;v
WRIGHT PATMAN, Texas, Vice Chairman
Joux R. STARE, Executive Director
JAMES W. KNowLEs, Director of Research
EcoNoMIsTs
PAGENO="0003"
PAGENO="0004"
PAGENO="0005"
THE 1968 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT
The letter appearing below was sent to the following organizations:
American Bankers Association, American Federation of Labor and
Congress of Industrial Organizations, American Iron and Steel Insti-
tute, American Life Convention, Chamber of Commerce of the United
States, Conunittee for Economic Development, Communications Work-
ers of America, Conference on Economic Progress, Consumers Union
of the United States, Inc., Cooperative League of the U.S.A., CUNA
International, Inc., Federal Statistics Users' Conference, Independent
Bankers Association, Life Insurance Association of America,
Machinery and Allied Products Institute, National Association of
Mutual Savings Banks, National Consumers' League, National Fed-
eration of Independent Business, National Federation of Independent
Unions, National Planning Association, Railway Labor Executives
Association, National League of Insured Savings Associations,
United Automobile, Aerospace and Agricultural Implement Workers
of America (UAW), United Mine Workers, United States Savings
and Loan League. These organizations were invited to submit their
views or comments on the text and recommendations contained in the
1968 Economic Report of the President. Fifteen organizations and one
individual submitted statements and their views were considered by the
Joint Economic Committee in the preparation of its report on the
President's Economic Report.
FEBRUARY 8, 1968.
DEAR MR. -~ : Since our schedule of hearings on the 1908 Economic
Report of the President is very full and time is short, the Joint Economic Com-
mittee once again is calling upon a number of leaders of banking, business, labor,
agriculture and consumer organizations for written statements containing eco-
nomic facts and counsel for consideration in the preparation of its report.
The 1968 Economic Report of the President, including the annual report of
the Council of Economic Advisers, is enclosed. We would appreciate having
your comments on the materials and recommendations in this report.
In order that we may have ample time for consideration of these comments,
written statements should be received by March 1, 1968. We will need 30 copies
sent to G-133, New Senate Office Building, Washington, D.C. 20510, for distribu-
tion to committee members and the staff.
Such comments as you care to give us will be made available to the public
in a printed volume of invited statements.
Sincerely yours,
WILLIAM PBOXMIRE, Chairman.
(719)
PAGENO="0006"
PAGENO="0007"
AMERICAN FEDERATION OF LABOR AND CONGRESS OF
INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATIONS
By NATHANIEL GOLDFINGER, DIRECTOR, DEPARTMENT OF RESEARCH
The national economy's advance, which got underway in 1961, con-
tinues to add to employment, incomes, and output. The economic per-
formance of the past 7 years has been a most welcome improvement
after the trend of rising unemployment and recurring recessions dur-
ing most of the 1950's.
Despite this record of achievement, the American economy remains
some distance from full employment. Unemployment persists at
much too high a level and in 1967 there was no improvement in this
important indicator of the American people's economic well-being-
3.8 percent of the labor force remained unemployed.
The economic advance, thus far, has failed to provide enough job
opportunities for a rapidly growing labor force in a period of radical
technological change-particularly for the most disadvantaged job
seekers among teenagers, Negroes, and unskilled workers.
Moreover, the benefits of the national economy's much-improved
performance in the 1960's have not been shared equitably among the
various groups in the population. A disproportionately great share
has gone to business and upper income families, even after account-
ing for last year's small decline in profits.
Unfortunately, the Council of Economic Advisers' Economic Re-
port of January 1968 indicates a willingness to accept a reported un-
employment rate of approximately 4 percent as a goal of national
economic policy, rather than to continue to press for further reduc-
tions of the unemployment level.
As for the lopsided distribution of the benefits of the economy's
much-improved performance of the 1960's, the economic report says
nothing at all. Indeed, this important issue of economic and social
policy continues to be ignored by the Council of Economic Advisers.
THE REMAINING PROBLEM OF UNEMPLOYMENT
The economic expansion of the 1960's boosted employment and in-
comes and, in 1960-66, it reduced the level of unemployment. As sales
and production picked up after the beginning of 1961, weekly work-
ing hours were increased following the part-time work schedules that
had spread in the 1950's. The continued pickup resulted in the recall
of workers, who had been laid off, and, gradually, in the hiring of
additional workers.
The rise of employment during the 1960's-and, after 1963, the con-
centrated increase of factory and construction jobs-finally reduced
unemployment after a rising trend during the previous decade. Be-
(721)
PAGENO="0008"
722
tween 1963 and 1966, reported unemployment dropped from 5.7 per-
cent of the labor force to 3.8 percent. But in 1967, the level of reported
unemployment remained at 3.8 percent.
The economic advance had not gone deeply enough by 1967 to pro-
vide job opportunities, at decent wages, for all persons who are able
to work and desire employment.
With officially reported unemployment of 3 million or 3.8 percent of
the labor force, the actual level of joblessness in 1967 may have been
as much as 3.5 million to 4 million or more, after accounting for those
jobless workers, particularly among shim dwellers, whom the Labor
Department fails to count as unemployed in its monthly surveys.
The unemployed in 1967 included workers who were temporarily be-
tween jobs, workers in seasonal industries who were on temporary
layoff and new entrants into the labor force-probably about 1.5-2
million. In addition, some of the unemployed were out of work, during
1967, as a result of economic conditions in their industries, such as
inadequate sales.
The large numbers of remainmg unemployed-and the underem-
ployed part-time workers, as well-were essentially disadvantaged and
unskilled workers, with little if any education or regular work experi-
ence. The general economic advance had not yet reached the most dis-
advantaged workers among the unskilled, teenagers, and Negroes, par-
ticularly those in urban slum areas and depressed rural communities.
Yet there are those who claim that the economic advance has gone too
far and c1 amor for unemployment-breeding restrictive policies.
In 1966, the Federal Reserve pursued a very restrictive monetary
policy, which pushed interest rates to their highest levels in 40 years,
threw residential constructioin into a deep recession along with related
industries and contributed to the economic slowdown of the first half
of 1967. There is danger that similar policies may be pursued in 1968,
despite the fact that unemployment persists and industry is operating
only about 85 percent of its productive capacity.
There are also those who clamor for a slashing of Federal expendi-
tures for such essential measures as Federal aid for education, housing,
urban affairs, health care, air and water pollution measures, anti-
poverty and welfare-those who claim that America's $800 billion
economy cannot afford improved public facilities and services in the
midst of the Vietnam war.
To adopt unemployment-breeding restrictive measures and to slash
expenditures for programs to achieve domestic social progress would be
unwise economic policy and dangerous social policy. America needs
continued progress toward full employment and it needs improved and
expanded public facilities and services to meet the needs of a rapidly
growing, urban population.
Recent estimates by the staff of the Joint Economic Committee and
the National Planning Association indicate that the real volume of total
national production must increase about 4_41/2 percent per year merely
to prevent unemployment from rising. These estimates are based on the
rapid growth of the labor force and increased pace of rising
productivity.
A continued reduction of remaining unemployment and underern-
ployment in the period ahead, therefore, will require a continuing rise
PAGENO="0009"
723
in the real volume of total national production that is somewhat greater
than 4_41/2 percent per year. It will also require adoption of a Federal
program to create 1 million public service jobs for the hard-core unem-
ployed and seriously underemployed.
On these issues, the AFL-CIO Executive Council declared on Feb-
ruary 23, 1968:
We reiterate our conviction that the American economy has the resources to
extend and expand social advances at home, while meeting military requirements
in Viet Narn. The cost of the war should not be absorbed by cutting back or
freezing essential federal programs for domestic progress. The great productive
ability of the American economy can provide the foundation for both continued
social progress at home and an honorable settlement of the war in 1/iet Nam.
The expected sharp rise in the government's administrative budget deficit in
fiscal years 1908 and 1909, due to military expenditures, can be reduced, without
mounting pressures on interest rates and the availability of money and credit. A
temporary war surtax is needed to reduce the amount of money the government
will have to borrow in the money market and to eliminate the threat to home-
building and related industries from tight money and higher interest rates.
The needed `temporary surtax should `be based on abillt~ to pay, including taxa-
tion of personal and corporate income that escapes taxation through major loop-
holes in the tax structure. The surcharge on corporations should `be at least twice
as great as on personal income. The surcharge on personal income should be
clearly set on the basis of ability to pay. Corporate and personal income, excluded
from taxation by tax loopholes, should `be subjected to at least the same tax rate
as the surcharge.
We insist that the top-priority objective of national economic policy should be
to achieve .and sustain full employment-jobs at decent wages, for all people who
are ajile `to work and desire employment. The demand for goods and services from
consumers, government and business must expand sufficiently to provide enough
new job `opportunities for the unemployed, for the great numbers of entrants into
the labor force and for those displaced by spreading automation. The federal
government's tax, expend'iture and monetary policies, in combination, should
encourage the `necessary expansion of demand to achieve and maintain full
employment.
Adoption of a program to create one million pubjic service jobs for the un-
employed and seriously under-employed is essential-along the lines of the bill
introduced by Congressman O'llara of Michigan. Such decisive measure to create
jobs in socially useful work-to perform much needed services that would not
otherwise be done in parks, playgrounds, hospitals and other public facilities-
is urgently needed.
Manpower training programs-including basic literacy education, personal
guidance and health rehabilitation-are essential to aid the unemployed and
under-employed to compete more effectively for available employment. Although
such programs do not create jobs, they can be of great benefit to the national
economy, as well as the workers themselves, by upgrading the skills of the un-
employed and unskilled. The recent emphasis on government-financied business
programs to train workers should not include wage subsidies or other payments
to the employer, beyond the extra cost of providing special training and sup-
portive services for the hard-core unemployed, that are in addition to his normal
training costs. Even the best-planned training programs, however, can be of
little avail, if `they are not accompanied by government programs to create
jobs and achieve full employment.
UNBALANCED DISTRIBnTION OF BENEFITS OF THE ECONOMIC
ADVANCE
Most Americans have benefited from the economic advance of the
1960's-from increased employmen't and gains in income. But these
benefits have not been s'hared equitably.
Business and upper income families have received a major share
of these gains. Improvements in the wages and salaries of nonsuper-
visory workers have lagged.
PAGENO="0010"
724
Although some business and Government spokesmen attempt to
blame rising unit labor costs for much of the increase in the price level
in the 1960's, the record clearly shows that the price level has been
rising, regardless of what happened to labor costs per unit of produc-
tion. Between 1960 and 1965, for example, when unit labor costs of
manufactured goods fell 11/2 percent or more (the decline may have
been about 3 percent, according to the Bureau of Labor Statistics),
wholesale prices of manufactured products rose 1.7 percent, boosting
profit margins and increasing the business share of the fruits of the
economy's progress. And when workers sought to catch up with the
gains of the economic advance and the more rapid rise of living costs
in the past 2 years, business raised prices at a faster pace, in an attempt
to maintain enlarged profit margins.
After a brief and slight decline in 1967, from the great heights, cor-
porate profits are now booming again. As the Wall Street Journal of
February 13, 1968, reports:
Business appears to be back on the comfortable track it wandered off for
a year beginning in late 1006-the track that leads straight from one quarterly
profit record to another.
Between 1960 and 1967:
-Corporate profits, after payments of taxes, skyrocketed 77 per-
cent.
-Dividend payments to stockholders soared 70 percent.
-Total wa.ge and salary payments to all employees in the entire
economy increased merely 56½ percent-reflecting increased employ-
ment of 8.6 million people, as well as tile wage and salary advances
of individual employees.
-Weekly aftertax take-home pay of nonsupervisory employees ill
private industry, with three dependents, increased only 25 percent-
and in terms of buying power, less than 11 percent.
Moreover, in tIle 2 years between December 1965 aild December
1967, the buying power of tilese workers' weekly take-home pay ac-
tually fell 1.1/2 percent.
* -Real compensation per hour of nonsupervisory employees in
private, nonfarm industries increased only about 21/2 percent a year
ill `tile 7 years, 1960-67. But the real volume of production per man-
hour in tile entire private economy rose at a. yearly rate of 3.3 percent.
These disparate trends, which result from business policies and
Government tax measures, are utterly ignored in tile Economic Re-
port, as if they never occurred. Tile failure of tile Council of Economic
Advisers to examine these lopsided trends represents poor economic
analysis, a. blindness to social issues and, perhaps, simple prenmclice
against nonsupervisory workers. tile major economic group ill tile
Nation.
Tile vast majority of wa.ge. and salary earners have not. received
a fair share of the fruits of the national economy's advance.
A disproportionately large share has gone to business, to executive
a.nd managerial perSonllel~ to the self-employed sucll as doctors and
similar groups, to capital gains from the sale of property, to those
who receive a. sigmficant part of their income from interest payments.
This llnfair digtribution of the benefit~ of the economy's progress
is clearly unjust to wage and salary earners, who are the vast majority
PAGENO="0011"
725
of the population and the backbone of American society. It undermines
the strength of consumer markets, the base of our economic system.
This lopsided distribution of the gains of the economic advance helps
to explain the slower-than-expected expansion of consumer sales in
the past year, which seems to mystify so many business and Govern-
ment commenators on economic trends. In addition, it widens the eco-
noirnc and social distance between various groups in the Nation-a
trend that is socially dangerous.
In the Economic Report, the Council of Economic Advisers rarely,
if ever, deals with workers' wages and salaries as income. The text of
the Economic Report deals with them almost invariably as costs. This
failure to recognize wages and salaries as income to workers, as well
as costs to business, reflects a bias that runs through the report. This
bias results in inadequate economic analysis-a failure to recognize
that nonsupervisory wage and salary earners are the major demand
factor in the economy and that the lopsided distribution of the benefits
of the economic advance has economic consequences, such as the un-
balanced relationship in 1965-67 between business investment and the
expansion of productive capacity, on the one hand, and the effective
demand for goods and services, on the other hand.
While the Economic Report stresses the cost impact of wages and
salaries, it utterly fails to indicate, even in as little as one sentence, that
the purchasing power of aftertax weekly earnings of nonsupervisory
employees in 1967 was less than in both 1966 and 1965.
Nowhere in the Economic Report is there an analysis of the serious,
continuing lag of increases in nonsupervisory employees' wages and
salaries behind the incomes of business and wealthy families-behind
profits, dividends, the nearly 100 percent rise of personal interest pay-
ments in 1960-67, the incomes of managerial personnel and self-
employed professionals, capital gains from the sale of property.
In its statement on national economic issues, adopted on February 23,
1968, the AFL-CIO executive council states:
The lag of real wages and salaries must be ended. A substantial rise in the
buying power of wages, salaries and fringe benefits is needed to provide wage
and salary earners with a fair share of economic progress and to strengthen con-
sumer markets that are the foundation of the American economy. Only through
an improved balance in the economy-between wages, profits, dividends and other
forms of income-can there be assurance of sustained, economic growth to reach
full employment and maintain it.
Rising business profits should be based on an expanding sales volume-rather
than on swollen profit margins at the expense of workers and consumers.
We will continue to press for wage and salary increases to offset rising living
costs and to advance buying power. We firmly believe that wage and salary
earners deserve to share equitably in the gains of the economy's progress. The
nation's rapidly rising productivity and great profitability of business makes pos-
sible such improvements in wages, salaries and fringe benefits, within the context
of a relatively stable price level. S
We repeat again, as we have in the past two years: If the President determines
that there is a national emergency that warrants extraordinary stabilization
measures-with even-handed restraints on all costs, prices, profits, dividends,
rents, corporate executive compensation (salaries, bonuses and stock options), as
well as employes' wage and salaries-he will have the support of the AFL-CIO.
But rigid application of a single "magic number" based on one economic factor
alone, cannot be a workable or fair means of wage determination in a country of
continental size, with thousands of different markets, industries and occupations.
We are prepared to sacrifice--as much as anyone else, for as long as anyone else-
so long as there is equality of sacrifice.
PAGENO="0012"
726
A much-improved balance in the private economy is essential if
America is to be able to reach and sustain full employment. The lop-
sided distribution of the gains of the economic advance makes it diffi-
cult to achieve full employment and, within the context of social and
political realities, impossible to sustain it.
Failure to recognize the consequences of this lopsided distribution
is one of the major failings of the "new economics," which naively be-
lieves that the Federal Government can quickly and simply offset
any and all weaknesses in the private economy by pushbutton con-
trols. Not only is America a vast and complex continental economy,
with scores of different industries and markets, but, in a.ddition, the
Council of Economic Advisers is neither the Congress nor the Fed-
eral Reserve System nor the entire executive branch.
The forward advance of the American economy requires a sound
foundation in a much-improved balance in the private economy.
ADJUSTMENTS TO RADICAL SOCIAL CHANGES
Radical changes in technology and race relations, accompanied by
rapid urban growth, continue to strain the fabric of American society.
America's urban crisis is rooted in these rapid and radical social
changes, as well as in the long, tragic history of Negro slavery,
segregation, and discrimination.
These problems festered during most of the 1960's-with a rising
trend of unemployment, government subsidies for technolgical
change and no adjustment programs, a sharp decline of low-rent
public housing construction and general neglect of urban, public
services.
Much of the long-delayed legislation of the 1960's to achieve piece-
meal adjustments to the radical changes in American life were first
steps, without previous experience, precedents, and trained personnel.
Moreover, Federal appropriations for these purposes were kept down
by public apathy. Yet these measures were greatly oversold and their
adoption aroused expectations of overnight solutions that were im-
possible to achieve.
The growth of the American population has increased sharply-
from several hundred thousand a year in the 1930's to an average
yearly rise of 2.7 million since World War II. Moreover, the num-
ber of people in rural areas has been declining while metropolitan
area growth has been booming. Each year, the population of Ameri-
ca's metropolitan areas grows by over 3 milion, the size of a very
lar~e city.
The pace of technological change, too, has speeded up considerably
in the years since World War II. One measure of that speed is the
time elapsing between a new discovery and the point at which it is in-
troduced commercially. A study prepared for the National Automa-
tion Commission found that the time required to cover that distance
has been cut by almost two-thirds-from an average of 37 years for
innovations developed around the turn of the century to 14 years
for innovations developed in the post World War II period.
Another measure of the speed of technological change is the rate
of productivity growth. Between 1909 and 1947, output per man-
PAGENO="0013"
727
hour in the total private economy rose at an annual rate of 2 per-
cent; between 1947 and 1967 it rose 3.2 percent per year. This jump
in the rate of productivity growth by more than 50 percent means
that, on the average, production during each hour of work can double
in 22 years instead of in 36 years.
This stepped-up pace of technological change has resulted in the
displacement of large numbers of unskilled and semiskilled jobs,
difficult problems in labor-management relations concerning in-plant
changes of job requirements and classifications, shifts in industry
location, the economic distress of many old mining and railroad cen-
ter communities, the decline of several labor intensive industries and
the growth of new industries that employ relatively few unskilled
workers who have little education.
In 1967, for example, manufacturing production was more than 70
percent greater than in 1953. But the number of factory production
and maintenance workers was only 1.4 percent greater.
Between 1953 and 1967, the number of people employed on class I
railroads declined 600,000, a drop of 50 percent. Employment in min-
ing fell 253,000, a decline of 29 percent.
The largest employment decline was in agriculture-a drop of 2.5
million or 40 percent. Hundreds of thousands of farmers, farmwork-
ers and their families have been leaving the rural areas in search of
jobs and homes in the cities. But the types of unskilled and semi-
skilled jobs, in the urban areas, that helped to adjust previous gen-
erations of foreign immigrants and rural American migrants into
America's cities have not been expanding.
These trends of rapid technological change and migration out of
rural agricultural and mining areas are continuing.
Many of those who seek their future in the cities are Negroes. Be-
tween 1940 and 1967, probably about 4 million Negroes moved from
the South-primarily rural areas-to the cities of the North and West.
In 1960, according to the Department of Labor, about 40 percent to
nearly 50 percent of the Negro population of 10 major northern and
western cities was born in the South.
The Department of Labor estimates that almost 1.5 million Negroes
left the South in 1950-60, following a similar migration of 1.6 million
Negroes in the wartime decade, 1940-50. This historic migration is
continuing at about that rate in the 1960's.
For the country as a whole, the proportion of Negroes in city popu-
lations rose from less than 10 percent in 1940 to over 20 percent in 1965.
In most of the large northern and western cities the rise was greater.
All of the new migrants to America's cities of the past quarter of
a century-white and Negroes, Puerto Ricans and Mexican-Ameri-
cans-have faced the difficulties of adjusting to a new and strange
environment. But these difficulties have been especially harsh for
Negroes.
The Negro migrants to the cities of the past quarter of a century
have brought with them a history of slavery, segregation, lack of edu-
cation and frequently poor health, as well as suspicion of government
authorities. On coming to the cities of the North and West, the new
migrants have faced the discriminatory practices of those areas, lack
of adequate housing and the impact of automation on job opportuni-
ties for uneducated, unskilled workers.
PAGENO="0014"
728
In ghetto areas in the cities, about 10 to 15 percent of the adult men
and about 40 to 50 percent of out-of-school teenagers (including an
estimate of those usually not counted by the Labor Department) are
unemployed. In addition, a Labor Department survey of slum areas
1fl November 1966 found that nearly 7 percent of those with jobs were
employed only part time although they wanted full-time work, and
20 percent of those working full time earned less than $60 a week.
This same Labor Department. survey found that nearly 40 percent of
the families and unrelated individuals in big city slum areas earn
less than $3,000 a year.
However, it costs about $9,200 at present prices, to maintain a modest
standard of living, including some amenities and a few luxuries, for
a family of four in America's metropolitan areas-more for a: larger
family and less for a smaller family. Elimination of the amenities
and luxuries would result in a cost of about $5,000 to maintain a mini-
mum decent standard of living for a family of four in our urban
areas-scaled up and down for different family sizes.
Yet Government reports indicate that probably 20 percent of the
families within city limits earn less than the amount necessary for a
minimum decent standard of living. Within ghetto areas, perhaps
60 to 70 percent or more of the families are in that category. The re-
sult is badly overcrowded housing, inadequate diet, poor medical care,
few books and magazines for about 20 percent of city families and
about 60 to 70 percent of those who live in ghetto slums.
The hard-core slum areas continue to deteriorate. People with jobs,
some skills and some regular incomes have been moving out. They a.re
replaced with new migrants from the rural South-adding to the re-
maining lowest income families, the jobless, the aged and fatherless
families.
A large proportion of these slum residents depend on welfare pay-
ments, often to mothers with dependent children and no father pres-
ent. The Labor Department survey of November 1966 found that 30
percent of the population in East Harlem, 30 percent of the Watts
population, 40 percent of the Bedford-Stuyvesant. chilren and 25 per-
eent of the adults receive welfare payments. Moreover, the lack of ade-
quate child-care facilities in slum areas is a barrier to employment for
women with children.
Trapped by a history of degradation and the recent impact of auto-
mation, these new migrants to the city are also trapped by the imavail-
ability of low- and moderate-cost housing, as well `as by discrimination
aga.inst colored people.
The peak home construction year, before World War II, was 1925.
From 1926 to 1945, a period of 20 years, homebuilding was in a slump.
It wasn't until 1946 that the 1925 level of housing starts was reached.
Since 1945, the ups and downs of residential construction have fol-
lowed conditions in the money market-interest rates and availability
of money. Normal business operations and Government programs have
provided housing for families in the middle-income range and above
(at present, about $8,000 amiual income and more).
The residential construction of the postwar period, however, has
essentially ignored housing for the entire bottom half of our income
distribution-for t.h~ lower middle-income group as well as the poor.
PAGENO="0015"
729
For lower middle-income families, with current incomes of about
$5,000 to $8,000, the postwar years have seen only little new housing
construction, with present rentals or carrying charges and taxes of
about $85 to $135 per month. This is particularly true for large fami-
lies, with three or more children, in this income range.
For the urban poor-families with current incomes of about $5,000
a year and less-there has been hardly any new housing construction
during `the 22 years since World War II and there was very little of
such construction in the preceding 20 years from 1926 through 1945.
Almost a half century of rapid change in our cities-including the
great Negro migration-has passed, with hardly any housing con-
struction for low-income families.
Realistic rentals for poor families would have to be concentrated
around $40 to $70 a month. Since the private market cannot provide
such housing, public housing and public rehabilitation are essential.
But, in recent years, the total number of new public housing dwelling
units has been only about 30,000 to 40,000 per year.
Moreover, the urban renewal program, which has bulldozed city
slum area~s has concentrated on the construction of commercial build-
ings and luxury high-rise apartments. Relocation of families, dis-
placed from the slums, ha.s been neglected or ignored and there has
l)een hardly any replacement of low-rental housing.
In `addition, during the 1950's and early 1960's, the traditional con-
servative opposition to low-cost publicly subsidized housing for the
poor was joined by many so-called liberals-the same coalition that
debunked the impact of automation on unskilled and semiskilled
factory workers and on industrial location as a trade union myth. As a
result, the New Deal's beginnings to provide low-cost public housing
nearly perished between 1952 and 1966.
At the same time, middle- and upper-income families have been
moving to the suburbs. This movement has opened up older housing
in the cities. But, combined with the movement of industry to the
suburbs and countryside, it has reduced the tax base of the cities,
when the demands on their financial resources for housing, welfare,
education, and public facilities are mounting. Moreover, the change of
industrial location has compounded the problems of inadequate mass
transportation facilities for low-income city dwellers to get to the new
areas of employment growth. And most suburban communities have
rather rigid color-bar restrictions, as well as~ an absence of low-cost
housing.
America now faces a complex of social problems that `are related
to rapid and radical changes in technology, urban growth, and race
relations, as well as the history of the American Negro in the past 350
years. No city or State or private group can solve these problems in
isolation or by themselves. Workable solutions require nationwide
social measures, with adequate Federal funds and standards.
Instant adjustments and overnight solutions to this complex of
problems are impossible. Gimmicks and slogans can achieve headlines,
but hardly any positive results. Yet rapid forward strides are essential
to the preservation of a free and' democratic society.
Immediate measures are needed to provide jobs, decent housing, and
adequate community facilities. Planned programs over the next decade
or two are required to revitalize the fabric of American society.
PAGENO="0016"
730
One million public service jobs for persons now unemployed or
seriously underemployed are needed-such as in parks, playgrounds,
day care centers, hospitals, schools, and libraries. To provide this nec-
essary means of helping people lift themselves out of poverty and depri-
vation, Congress should inmledia.tely adopt a $4 billion program to
fund Federal, State, and local government agencies and nonprofit or-
ganizations for the creation of such public service jobs at wages not
less than the Federal minimum wage.
The Federal Government must become the employer of last resort..
Two and a half million new housing units each year including:
Public housing through new and rehabilitated low-rent homes for
the 20 percent of city families whose incomes are below requirements
for a minimum decent standard of living. New low-rent public hous-
ing construction, at a 30,000 to 40,000 annual level in 1960-66, should
be immediately increased to 200,000 to 300,000 for each of the next 2
years and 500,000 a year thereafter. Such construction should be sup-
plemented by a large-scale public rehabilitation program. Adequate
appropriations for the rent supplement program are also a necessity.
The Federal Government must become the landlord of last resort,
as well as the employer of last resort.
Housing for lower middle-income families, not eligible for public
housing and unable to afford decent dwellings in the standard, pri-
vately financed housing market. Federally subsidized interest rate
loans and a Federal subsidy for the partial abatement of local taxes
on such properties are needed to increase construction of such housing
by cooperatives, nonprofit and limited dividend corporations. In addi-
tion, Federal legislation should make it possible for such groups to
acquire existing properties, with Government insurance of long-term
and low-interest loans.
Moderate-income housing, already operating with Government-in-
sured mortgages, stepped up through measures to encourage greater
involvement of pension funds, college endowment funds, and private
trusts.
Open housing, in suburbs and new towns as well as in cities, as an
essential part of a meaningful effort to rebuild our metropolitan areas.
Urban renewal, no longer confined to commercial and expensive
high-rise construction. The focus instead must be on homes in balanced
neighborhoods, with families displaced by slum clearance given assist-
ance in finding decent dwellings at rents they can afford.
Model cities program, with adequate appropriations.
Mass transit, improved and expanded, is an urgent need in all metro-
politan areas.
Accelerated construction of public facilities, such as water supplies,
sewage systems, mass transit, schools, hospitals, day-care centers, play-
grounds, libraries, museums, clean air and water are essential to re-
build America's metropolitan areas. Congress should adopt at least a
$2 billion a year grant-in-aid program to State and local governments,
in addition to categorical grants-in-aid.
A substantially expanded Neighborhood Youth Corps program, to
help youngsters remain in school and to provide work and training for
those who have dropped out of school.
The opportunity for quality education for all, by closing the educa-
tional gap between the privileged and underprivileged schoolchildren
PAGENO="0017"
731
of our Nation through special incentives to teachers in the areas, Fed-
eral aid for more effective school types programs, full use of school
buildings for job training, adult education, and community activities.
In addition, expanded vocational training must be realistically geared
to the modern job market.
Manpower training, linked with job placement and adequate train-
ing allowances, should aim at lifting the skills of the labor force, par-
ticularly the disadvantaged.
Public welfare assistance, restructured, with the program based on
need alone, a Federal minimum standard of payments and adequate
Federal funds should be provided; State work-incentive programs
should enable welfare recipients to retain a substantial amount of the
dollars they earn without penalty, to encourage people to find jobs and
eventually get off the welfare rolls, and demeaning investigations of
applicants should be eliminated.
Relief of rural poverty, concentrated in the Southern and South-
western States primarily, by Federal legislation to provide farmwork-
ers with unemployment compensation and according to them the same
right other workers have under the National Labor Relations Act to
organize unions and bargain collectively; by adequate Federal funds
to assist low- and moderate-income rural families to buy or rehabilitate
housing; continuation and strengthening of the Vocational Education
Act of 1963 and the Education Act of 1965 in rural areas; Federal aid
in establishment of adequate public facilities, such as highways, hos-
pitals, schools, vocational and technical training institutions, in rural
areas; application of the regional approach, used in the Government's
Appalachia program, to other economically depressed regions of the
country; extension of the Agriculture Department recreational and
tourist activities in rural areas, and provisions of full and fair employ-
ment opportunities for Negroes, Mexican Americans, and other mi-
norities to work in the industries of rural areas and in State and local
governments.
Continued labor-management efforts, through collective bargaining,
to provide improved job security to workers and to cushion the effects
of technological change on the work force.
A Federal Government maintained national inventory of needs for
housing, public facilities, and services, by specific categories, based on
present unmet backlogs and estimates of future population growth.
Each State and metropolitan area, with the technical assistaiice of
the Federal Government, should develop and maintain a similar inven-
tory of needs within its geographical jurisdiction.
The Joint Economic Committee has demonstrated the feasibility of
developing such inventory by category. The Council of Economic Ad-
visers, however, has failed to coordinate such national inventory, by
category, program, and degree of annual progress in meeting the needs.
Such inventories of present and projected requirements should serve
as the foundation for nationwide programs in each category. They
should also be used as yardsticks for the measurement of progress to-
ward meeting the objectives of adequate housing, public facilities, and
services.
A planned national effort, under Federal leadership is needed to
apply as much of the Nation's resources-manpower, materials, and
90-191-68-pt. ~J-2
PAGENO="0018"
732
finances-as possible, to meet the requirements of a rapidly growing,
urban population, while providing a sound foundation for the co~ -
tinned advance of the private economy.
Achievement of these objectives will require Federal funds, plan-
ning, and leadership. But it will depend, too, on the initiative and local
implementation by the States and metropolitan area governments, as
well as the cooperation of private groups in society.
Successful adjustments to rapid and radical social changes will not
be achieved automatically. Positive and bold policies are needed-by
local communities and State governments, as well as by the Federal
Government. Resources for such adjustments are available in the in-
genuity of the American people and in the vast productive power of the
national economy. But the will to achieve such adjustments-and the
necessary foundation of a rapidly growing full-employment economy-
must be strongly asserted by the American people and implemented by
their elected representatives and officials.
PAGENO="0019"
AMERICAN IRON AND STEEL INSTITUTE
The testimony on the domestic steel industry before the Joint Eco-
nomic Committee on February 16, 1968, of Mr. Harry L. Graham,
legislative representative of the National Grange, appears to have
been based upon observations he made several months ago durmg a
2-week visit to Germany. He is critical of the industry on essentially
four grounds: Archaic production methods, lower tecimological effi-
ciency than foreign steel companies, interest in expanded profits, and
lack of interest in plant modernization.
I. P~o~uc'rio~ METhoDs
A. The charge that the American steel industry "by and large `is
Still engaged in producing by the Bessemer process of the last century"
is incorrect. During the last year for which Bessemer production was
separately reported by steel producers to `the American Iron & Steel
Institute (1966), such production accounted for only two-tenths of
1 percent of the total production. Bessemer steel was 2.8 percent of
total U.S. production during 1956 `and 5 percent in 1946-thus of only
minor significance in the United States even two decades ago.
B. Mr. Graham used the WTest German steel industry `as an example
of efficient production methods which the United States `should adopt.
West Germany, `however, produced 27.7 percent of i'ts steel in 1966 by
"the Bessemer process of the last century" and 42.8 percent in 1956.
Comparable figures for the total European Coal and Steel `Community
(ECSC) were 35.5 percent by the Bessemer process in 1966 and 52
percent in 1956.
C. Not only is `there `a sha:rp `contrast between tIm United States and
the ECSC (including West Germany) in the degree to which the
oldest stee'lniaking method (the Besse'mer process) `has been utilized
during recent years but there is also an equally sharp contrast in the
rapidity at which production by the neweSt steelmaking method-the
basic oxygen process (BOP)-has been substituted for open hearth
production ( still the major method of steelmaking in both areas).
Specifically, `during the decade from 1956 to 1966 (the latest year for
which data are available for the ECSC and West Germany), BOP
production went from less than a million tons in both the ECSC and
the United States to 22 million tons in the community countries-but
to 34 million tons in the United States. On the other hand, during this
same period open hearth production was expanded in both the ECSC
and in West Germany (by 3 million and 2 million `tons, respectively),
while producti'on by this method was reduced by 18 million tons in the
United States. (During 1967, `open `hearth producti'on in the United
States declined an `additional 14 million tons.)
In passing, it should also be noted that Mr. Graham's claim that
National Steel Corp., was the first to install a BOP furnace in this
(733)
PAGENO="0020"
734
country is also incorrect. McLouth Steel Corp., installed its first BOP
furnace in 1954-8 years before National Steel; in fact, there were
19 other commercial-scale basic oxygen furnaces in operation in this
country at the time National Steel's first furnace began operation in
1962.
D. Any realistic evaluation of rates of modernization which com-
pares the speed at which new methods of production are adopted in
various countries and which seeks to arrive at value judgments about
differences in such rates must necessarily recognize and allow for dif-
ferences between countries with respect to a wide variety of factors,
such as the following: Economic conditions, alternative uses of avail-
able funds, purpose of investment (for example, expansion versus
replacement), efficiency of existing equipment contemplated to be
replaced, operating costs of new facilities as compared with the costs
of continuing to operate existing facilities, efficiency of existing inter-
related facilities, economical scales of production, costs and benefits
associated with possible improvements to existing facilities, versa-
tility of new facilities, likelihood of further significant technological
improvements in the near future, and attractiveness of other alterna-
tive new processes.
Likewise, a decision by one company to utilize its funds for a par-
ticular type of investment gives little, if any, indication of whether
a similar investment would be appropriate for another company faced
with completely different circumstances.
II. TECHNOLOGICAL EFFIC~NCY
A. Mr. Graham asserts that German and Japanese steel companies
"have been bringing into production new steel mills with the most
advanced production techniques in the world" and that as a result
they have been able to sell their steel cheaper in this country than
American steel. He also asserts that quotas "would snnply lock in our
inefficiencies in the competitive steel business."
B. There is, of course, no completely accurate method of comparing
steelmaking efficiencies among countries because of wide differences
in methods of measurement, product mix, factor prices, and methods
of industry organization. One measurement which has been used, how-
ever, is the number of man-hours required per ton of production;
man-hour data, of course, reflect the combined effect of all the factors
of production. In 1966, the latest year for which comparable data are
available, American steel producers required an average of 12.8 man-
hours per ton of shipments, versus 17.3 man-hours for Japan. WTith
respect to the European Economic Community, a recent publication
of the United Nations concluded that-
While it is not possible to derive precise conclusions from the comparison, it
can be stated that: (a) One country-the United States-had lower (in most
cases substantially lower) labor requirements per unit than any of the other
countries covered by the comparison and also showed one of the fastest reduc-
tions in unit labor requirements between 1960 and 1964; (b) All but one of the
large and medium-sized European steel industries included in the comparison
had unit labor requirements one and one-half to two and one-quarter times those
of the United States with a bunching of countries (on a man-hour basis) near
the upper end of this range
PAGENO="0021"
735
C. Technological knowledge about steelmaking and related subjects
is quickly transmitted throughout the steelmaking world so that any
company-if it can obtain the necessary capital-can have the latest
technology in a relatively short period of time. Although steel is
made in the United States with fewer man-hours per ton than abroad,
our advantage in efficiency is insufficient to offset our much higher
hourly employment costs-as is reflected in unit costs being about $25
per ton higher than in Europe and about $40 per ton higher than in
Japan. This is one of the major reasons why foreign steel is sold in
this country for less than domestically produced steel-not our lower
productive efficiency, as Mr. Graham contends.
D. American steel producers not only shared their technical knowl-
edge with foreign steelmakers after the war to help them get back onto
their feet, but the American Government and international agencies
such as the Export-Import Bank of Washington advanced over $2
billion to build, modernize, or expand foreign steel plants from 1947
through 1966. Much of the postwar gain in technology abroad has been
the result of borrowing American technology. Japan, for example,
started very late in steel research; in fact, most of the major steel
laboratories in Japan have only been established during the last decade.
The role which American steel producers have played in the de-
velopment of the Japanese steel industry was acknowledged by Mr.
Yoshihiro Inayama, president of Yawata Iron & Steel Co., at the recent
meeting of the International Iron & Steel Institute:
In counting our achievements since the end of the World War II, the Japanese
steel industry cannot but recall the whole-hearted assistance that the American
and European steelmaking nations extended to us in respect to techniques, equip-
ment, raw materials and funds. This assistance was vital to achieving today's
prosperity in our industry. It is my firm conviction that, however hard we may
have tried, such phenomenal development as Japan's steel industry enjoys today
could never have been achieved without the invaluable assistance and coopera-
tion extended to us.. . . In this sense we may say without exaggeration that you
are the real magicians who accomplished our "economic miracle."
E. During much of the postwar period American corporations and
individuals were being taxed for aid to steel industries and other in-
dust.ries abroad, while at the same time both the ability and the in-
centive of American steel companies to invest in new plant and equip-
ment were being severely restricted by tax law provisions for deprecia-
tion which were far less adequate than those applicable abroad. In
addition, American steel producers have expanded and improved their
steel mill facilities without direct financial help of any kind from
Government.
F. On the question of "inefficiencies" an American steel production,
it is true that if the industry could start from scratch, the total
production function would obviously be somewhat more efficient. The
reason why all existing facilities are not immediately scrapped and re-
placed with others incorporating the latest technology is because an
orderly, case-by-case evaluation of facility needs is financially much
more prudent. But this approach to facility replacement is no different
from that utilized by any other industry. (In agriculture, for example,
a farmer might wish to scrap his existing tractor or milking machine,
regardless of their efficiency, and buy an improved model every time
one becomes available. However, he knows that such an approach
would quickly lead to bankruptcy.)
PAGENO="0022"
736
III. P~oms
A. Mr. Graham asserts that American steel companies "have been
more interested in expanded profits than in modernization of their
plants." Domestic steel companies are obviously interested in in-
creasing their profits. That is one of the objectives of the very high
levels of capital expenditures. Actually, however, just opposite of
Mr. Graham's assertions has been occurring recently. Profits earned
by 14 of the largest 15 domestic steel companies during 1967 were
lower than those earned in 1966 and also lower than those earned in
1965.
B. Rather than being conflicting objectives, plant modernization
and profits are closely related objectives. For example, facility im-
provements are made with the hope and expectation of earning a
profit.. Prospects of profits are necessary to attract either new debt
capital or new equity capital. Other factors being equal, the greater
the profits available for reinvestment in the business, the faster im-
provements can be made in productive efficiency.
C. During recent years, the domestic steel industry has ranked near
the bottom of all industries in terms of rates of return on investment.
This restricts domestic steel companies' ability to invest in more
efficient facilities at a. faster rate not only from internally generated
funds but also from externally generated funds from investors ob-
tained in competition with companies in all other industries.
IV. PLANT MODERNIZATION
A. Mr. Graham cites the modernization undertaken during receiit
years by the German steel industry as an example which the domestic
industry should follow. From this, one would conclude that the
German industry has been investing money in new facilities at a
rapidly increasing rate and that just the opposite is the case in the
United States. Actually, exactly the reverse of this has been happen-
mg during recent years. As shown below, capital expenditures by U.S.
steel companies increased by 120 percent during the 1963-67 period,
whereas they have declined by 45 percent in West Germany and by
43 percent in to the total ECSC.
CAPITAL EXPENDITURES BYIRON AND STEEL INDUSTRIES
[Dollars in millionsj
Year
United States
West Germany
E.C.S.C.
1963
1964
1965
~1,O40.0
1,600.0
1,822.5
453.1
379.3
. 311.6
1,479.5
1,315.3
932.3
1966
1967
Percent change (1963-67)
1,953.0
2,292.0
±120
292.0
247. 1
-45
837.5
837.6
-43
B. In light of the above, it is apparent that the American steel
industry has been doing exactly what Mr. Graham and other critics
of the industry advocate. However, as the recent Senate Finance
Committee's staff study on "Steel Imports" pomtecl out, "Unless the
new investment in fixed assets produces cost savings in excess of
PAGENO="0023"
737
higher costs per ton, and unless tonnage increases to absorb the in-
creases in fixed costs, profit margins will actually fall." This, of course,
would make further financing more difficult.
0. Despite the current level of capital expenditures by the American
steel industry, such expenditures cannot be expected to lead to sig-
nificant reductions in unit costs because existing technology, includ-
ing that presently approaching adoption, does not point the way to
massive reductions in unit material and labor requirements. certainly,
it will not reduce substantially the difference between the low unit
labor costs of Japanese producers and the much higher unit labor
costs of American producers. In fact, to equalize those costs without
reducing hourly employment costs in this country, it would be neces-
sary to du:t immediately the man-hours required to produce 1 ton of
steel from the present level of `about 13 to `a presently unattainable
4-a decrease of about 70 percent. Even if new technologies were
developed which could quickly and profitably effect this substantial
reduction, there would of course be no technical barrier `to prevent
their concurrent installation `by foreign steelmakers.
PAGENO="0024"
AMERICAN LIFE CONVENTION
and the
LIFE INSURANCE ASSOCIATION OF AMERICA
This statement is submitted on behalf of the American Life Con-
vention and the Life Insurance Association of America, two trade
associations with a combined membership of 351 life insurance coin-
panies. These companies account for 92 percent of the legal reserve
life insurance in force in the United States. The life insurance business
today holds over $177 billion of assets, which represent the savings
that millions of policyholders have entrusted to us. We have a deep
concern in the proper functioning of the economy to protect these
savings. Accordingly, we appreciate the opportunity to comment on
the materials and recommendations contained in the Economic Report
of the President together with the annual report of the Council of
Economic Advisers and we hope that these comments will prove
helpful to the Joint Economic Committee for the Congress.
PROSPECTS AND PROBLEMS FOR THE EcoNoMY
The question of appropriate economic policies for 1968 must be
analyzed against the background of the prospects for economic ac-
tivity, and whether these prospects raise problems for the economic
health of the Nation. The Council of Economic Advisers has offered
the forecast that gross national product in 1968 will total $846 billion,
representing a gain over 1967 of $61 billion. This forecast is based
on the Council's estimate that our productive capacity will permit
an increase in real output of somewhat over 4 percent, or about $32
or $33 billion in 1968. The remaining increase in estimated GNP
would represent merely increased prices of goods and services which
are expected to lift the dollar GNP by another $28 or $29 billion.
The Economic Report forecast makes the assumption that overall
price increases in 1968 will be "somewhat in excess of 3 percent."
In our view, unless remedial action is taken, there is a grave danger
that price levels will advance significantly more than 3 percent in
1968, in the light of the recent price trends in the economy and the
clear signs of excessive demands that are developing. The forces of
inflation are gaining dangerous momentum which threatens price
inflation at a rate above 4 percent with serious consequences for
domestic economic stability and also for our critical balance-of-
payments position.
Price increases have shown a rapid acceleration during recent
months. As may be seen on page 105 of the Coimcil's annual report,
the GNP price deflator covering all goods and services rose at a 4-
percent annual rate in the second half of 1967, following a 2.6 rate
of advance in the preceding 9 months. Consumer price increases in
(738)
PAGENO="0025"
739
the second half of 1967 stepped up to a 3.8-percent annual rate after
an earlier gain of only 2.2 percent. `Wholesale industrial prices had
been rising only 1 percent, but quickened their advance to a 2.7-
percent rate in the latter half of 1967. These rates of price increases
are rapid, and most alarming.
There is considerable evidence~ that these price trends are not
merely temporary but will continue and strengthen if left unchecked.
For example, the unemployment rate has been running well below
4 percent during the past 12 months and declined to 3.5 percent in
January, revealing the pressures on our available labor force. Utiliza-
tion of industrial capacity has risen in recent months close to the
preferred operating rate for many industries. Recent wage negotia-
tions have led to wage increases of 6 percent or more, well above
productivity gains, setting an inflationary pattern for key labor con-
tracts scheduled for bargaining in 1968. Minimum wage levels have
advanced another notch, raising costs of production in many lines
of business. In short, the stage is set for a wage-cost-price spiral during
1968 which could gain dangerous momentum if excessive demands
are permitted to develop.
At the beginning of this year, the standard forecast developed by the
majority of private economic analysts was that activity in the first half
of the year would be quite strong, but that lesser gains in GNP were to
be expected after midyear. The smaller gains foreseen for the second
half were attributed primarily to the anticipation of a steel strike in
August, a tapering off in the rise in defense spending, and assumptions
that a continued high rate of personal saving would mean less-than-
buoyant consumer spending. On these assumptions, many private fore-
casters predicted a GNP of about $845 billion in 1968, fairly close to the
forecast of the Council of Economic Advisers.
It is our judgment that predictions of a second-half slowdown in
GNP will prove to be in serious error and that the outlook clearly
points to a continued strong advance and possibly an acceleration of
GNP in the latter half of 1968. The temporary influence of a steel strike
can easily be offset by other factors, as witnessed in similar periods in
the past, with little effect on the rise in GNP. For example, the $1'/2
billion Government pay increase scheduled for the third quarter will
provide a sizable boost in spending power. The accumulation of con-
sumer savings during the past year provides a very large reservoir of
potential spending, especially if consumers decide to speed up their
buying in anticipation of substantial price increases on consumer prod-
ucts. Signs of serious inflation would stimulate further spending and
add further to the pressures of demand.
Of perhaps greatest importance in the current outlook is the clear
evidence that military spending will be much larger in the coming
months than had been expected a few weeks ago. Recent developments
in Vietnam and in North Korea are now expected to lift defense out-
lays by $4 to $5 billion more than had been estimated in the January
budget figures. The second-half slowdown in C-NP that had earlier
been projected has been outmoded by these later developments.
It must be recognized that we are in a wartime economy, and our
economic policies must be shaped to take account of the drain on our
resources that the war requires. In contrast to goods produced for
civilian use, military goods are not available to satisfy civilian de-
PAGENO="0026"
740
mands, with the result that military spending places greater pressure
on domestic price levels. `With national defense expenditures likely to
reach $85 billion in fiscal 1969, instead of the $80 billion budgeted in
January, our economy faces a heavy strain on resources.
The total impact of the Federal Government sector upon the econ-
omy and price pressures is shown most directly by the size of the
Federal budgetary deficit. According to the January budget estimates,
the deficit for fiscal year 1968 will reach $19.8 billion and will total
$22.5 billion in tl~e absence of increased taxation. For fiscal year 1969,
the budget deficit would reach a range of $25 billion to $30 billion in
view of the additional defense spending now in prospect. Coming on
top of a resurgence of demand in the private sector and growing de-
mands from our State and local governments, a Federal deficit of this
dimension clearly is bound to create excessive demands and rapidly
rising price levels.
Inflationary trends of recent months have been widely ascribed to
`~cost-push factors" in the economy, but the outlook for 1968 poses the
additional danger of a. "demand-pull" inflation based on excess de-
mand for goods and services. If both types of inflation are allowed
to exist simultaneously, reinforcing each other with successive price
increases, a wage-price spiral of serious proportions is in prospect not
only for 1968 but. continuing into 1969 and beyond.
The threat. of spiraling prices is a. matter of great concern to every-
one and especially to the life insurance business and its millions of
policyholders, beneficiaries and pensioners whose benefit expectations,
savings and living standards would be seriously eroded by price in-
flation. Because of its uneven impact upon different economic groups,
and especially on those living on pensions or fixed incomes, inflation
has been rightly described as the cruelest tax of all. Inflation poses a
threat to the health of our entire economy and to our ability to sus-
tain stable economic growth.
EFFECTS OF INFLATION ox OFE BALANCE OF PAYMENTS
The effects of inflation on our balance of payments are of great im-
portance to our Nation. Our balance-of-payments position has sharply
worsened within the past several months. dramatized by a drain on the
U.S. gold stock of almost $1 billion during the fourth quarter of 1967
`While the causes of these payments difficulties are many sided, a basic
element is the degree of confidence in the value of the dollar in the eyes
of our trading partners abroad. Foreign financial interests are watch-
ing carefully the ability of the United States to control inflation. Con-
sequently, the stakes in the fight against inflation are enormous, in-
volving our ability to control forces which could jeopardize the po-
sition of the dollar in international finnace.
If excessive demands are allowed to develop in 1968, one conse-
quence would be to increase the volume of imports required by an
economy under strain. Second, the inflation of domestic price levels
that would result from an overheated economy would have a direct
and cont.iuing effect upon our ability to compete in world markets
during 1968 and for many years to come. Not only would there be
greater price incentive to buy imported goods because of lower rela-
tive prices abroad, but the rise in domestic prices would compound
the difficulties of selling American products in foreign markets.
PAGENO="0027"
741
A third element, of direct and immediate importance, relates to the
willingness of foreign countries to hold dollars as an international
reserve currency. This is perhaps the most vulnerable point in our
balance-of-payments position in the immediate future. If it is be-
lieveci that the United States will tolerate sharply rising price levels,
foreign money centers will lack the confidence in the future stability of
the dollar which is so vital to their willingness to hold dollars instead
of gold in their international reserves. The result could be a flight from
the dollar and disruptive shifts of short-term capital which would
further damage our international payments position.
TI-IE NEED FOR RESTRAINTS
The critical problems described above urgently demand immediate
policy correctives. We are faced with total demands from the public
and private sector which far exceed our productive capacity. In order
to prevent a dangerous wage-cost-price spiral which would jeopardize
our domestic stability and possibly cause irreparable damage to our
international payments system, we must embark immediately on a pro-
gram of fiscal and monetary restraint at home, combined with actions
to control our precarious balance-of-payments position.
`We believe that the problems we face offer a serious threat to the
American economy. They are due in a large measure to the war in
Vietnam and the need to improve living conditions in our cities. These
extraordinary demands require that comprehensive measures be
adopted to restrain inflation, 1'Ve, therefore, urge the use of every avail-
able means to bring the situation under control.
1. REDUCTIONS IN FEDERAL SPENDING
We would urge the Congress to carefully review those areas of
Federal spending which might be cut during the coming months. Ex-
penditure reductions should center not just on the postponement of
spending programs but also on the careful trimming of less-essential
programs which are of lower priority under our present circumstances
of rising defense needs and added strains upon our productive capacity.
The problem of controlling Federal spending is not merely one of
immediate budgeted outlays. Over the years, a number of programs
have been adopted which served useful and appropriate purposes at
the time but which have been continued in spite of changing circum-
stances and have added to budgetary totals year after year. The result
has been an unrelenting upward trend in governmental outlays and a
mass of programs which prove to be relatively uncontrollable on short
notice, even when other forms of spending become more essential.
For the long term, therefore, we urge favorable consideration of
S. 2032 and H.R. 10520, identical bills which would establish a Gov-
ernment Program Evaluation Commission on a bipartisan basis to
study existing Federal programs to determine the effectiveness of these
programs and the priorities which should be assigned to them in the
light of the fundamental needs of the Nation. We believe that this
approach holds great promise for achieving the long-run objective of
bringing budgetary outlays under closer control. By eliminating or
PAGENO="0028"
742
reducing programs with lower priority, greater flexibility would be
provided, especially when military requirements arise to place more
urgent demands upon budget resources.
We recognize that Federal programs must be responsive to urgent
domestic problems that confront our Nation. For example, the Eco-
noinic Report states: "We must deal more effectively with our urban
problems. More and more of our people live in cities. Yet cities threaten
to become less and less livable-unless we take decisive steps * *
The life insurance business shares this concern and sense of urgency
over the problems that beset our urban areas. Last September, we an-
nounced a program to invest $1 billion of life insurance investment
funds to finance improved housing, increased job opportunities and
needed services for low and moderate income families living in the
blighted core areas of our cities. We believe that action to improve
the quality of life in our cities should not be delayed and will require
the efforts of private business as well as the government sector.
2. INCREASED TAXATION
Last August, the President proposed a program of increased Fed-
eral taxa.tion to reduce the budgetary deficit. At that time, the life
insurance business testified before the House Ways a.nd Means Com-
mittee in support of the need for substantial spending cuts and a
temporary uniform tax surcharge on both personal and cooperate
income. We believe that enactment of a temporary tax surcharge is
even more essential now and should be achieved at the earliest possible
date.
Prompt passage of a tax increase could have an immediate impact on
inflationary pressures by removing spending power from the private
sector, with substantial effects on total demands on our economy.
A tax increase would demonstrate t.o the world that we are willing to
pay the rising costs of our defense outlays through taxation, rather
than through inflationary borrowing. The urgency of our international
payments problem also requires a prompt decision to increase taxes
before the situation reaches a new crisis stage.
A tax increase can never be a. popular measure. However, we believe
that the public has not fully considered the alternative it faces--
inflation arising from inordinate demands on our economy. We would
urge passage of a temporary tax surcharge as an economic measure
of the highest urgency, which is essential in the long-run interest of
every citizen.
Without fiscal action to curb spending or increase taxes, the fiscal
1969 deficit could easily reach $25 or $30 billion, as described earlier.
The tax measures proposed by the administration would reduce that
figure by approximately $13 billion, leaving a deficit of $12 to $17
billion. If additional reductions in controllable budget programs can
also be adopted, the deficit could be further reduced to a. figure which
would represent a. more appropriate budget.ary position in a period
of rising private demands in a. fully employed war economy. More-
over, a smaller deficit would lower Treasury borrowing requirements
that would otherwise be extremely heavy, especially during the latter
half of calendar year 1968.
PAGENO="0029"
743
3. MONETARY RESTRAINT
The question of Treasury borrowing needs are closely related to
the credit posture of the Federal Reserve System. The view is some-
times expressed that fiscal restraint would lessen the needs for the
Federal Reserve to embark upon a policy of credit restraint. Stated
another way, failure to reduce the budget deficit would require the
Federal Reserve to adopt a more restrictive monetary policy. How-
ever, this approach overlooks the market reality that the enormous
financing requirements of the U.S. Treasury limit the freedom of the
monetary authorities to restrain credit growth, since doing so could
jeopardize the success of Treasury refundings or new cash borrowing
operations.
During 1967, Federal Reserve policy remained in an easy position
which permitted a growth in bank credit by an unprecedented dollar
total of $35 billion. As pointed out in the Council's annual report, total
bank credit expanded during the first 11 months of 1967 at an annual
rate of 12 percent. `This expansion `in credit and in :the money supply
is related, we believe, to the accelerated rise in domestic price levels
during the past several months. `Continuation of credit expansion at
the pace of 1967 would reinforce strong inflationary pressures through
excessive additions to availitble spending power. However, the need
to provide for the financing of Treasury securities through the com-
mercial banks has left the Federal Reserves in the awkward position
of maintaining relative ease in the face of an oversized Federal deficit.
In brief, an unwillingness to adopt fiscal restraint to achieve a lower
budget deficit would add to the difficulties of reducing the growth in
bank credit. `Stated another `way, fiscal restraint and a lower deficit
would permit the monetary `authorities to follow appropriate policies
to curb credit-financed demands in the private sector.
In our view, monetary policy should move in gradual steps toward
less expansionary policies, to avoid making credit available in such
large amounts that demand outruns our capacity to produce, with a
resulting rise in price levels. It is well recognized that there is usually
a considerable time lag `before monetary policy begins to act upon
basic economic forces. For this reason, if the Federal Reserve is to
be effective in `curbing excessive demand's later this year, then steps
should be taken `as soon as possible toward a less expansionary credit
policy.
Any discussion of a less easy credit policy usually `brings fears of
higher interest rates, credit shortages, and a shutting off of residential
mortgage finance. But these consequences need not occur if a reduc-
tion of the Federal budget deficit lowers the `borrowing requiremen'ts
of the Treasury thus making room for the financing of residential
construction, business capital `outlays, and other private sector
activities.
4. BALANCE-OF-PAYMENTS POLICIES
On January 1, the administration `announced a broad program of
correctives to improve our balance-of-payments position, including
mandatory controls on direct investment abroad, a more stringent pro-
gram of voluntary controls on financial flows to foreign countries, and
proposed curbs on tourist travel outside the Western Hemisphere.
PAGENO="0030"
744
It is important that proposals to impose these direct controls should
not divert attention from the urgent need to adopt reinforcing policies
of fiscal and monetary restraint. In retrospect, adoption of such re-
straint some time a.go might have helped greatly to avoid our present
situation. For the future, policies of domestic restraint may prove
even more important than direct controls in. providing a fundamental
solution to our international-payments problem.
CoxcLusIoN
We believe that the problerns of excessive demand, spiraling infla-
tion and foreign payments difficulties represent a greater threat in
1968 than in many years. Effective solutions to these problems demand
immediate attention by the Congress, by the administration, and by the
monetary authorities. It is not a question of choosing among available
approaches but ra.ther of using spending reduction, increased taxation,
credit restraint, and balance-of-payments measures in a combined effort
t.o restrain the excessive demands and resulting inflation that our
economy now faces.
While these solutions are not easily accepted by many, they are pre-
ferable to the altarnatives of spiraling inflation and a balance-of-pay-
ments crisis. Unless early action can be taken, the Government could
later be forced to consider controls over wages, prices and credit in a
desperate attempt to correct intolerable inflation.
PAGENO="0031"
CHAMBER OF COMMERCE OF THE UNITED STATES
By Dr. CARL H. MADDEN, CHIEF EcoNoMIsT
The Chamber of Commerce of the United States welcomes the oppor-
tunity to submit written comments on the Economic Report of the
President and the annual report of the Council of Economic Advisers.
Like their predecessors, these reports are highly useful and of excellent
quality. Both the text and the appendix tables contain valuable eco-
nomic information.
Traditionally, these documents provide a rationale connecting social
and economic policy covering a wide range of issues. The chapter titles
of the Council's report indicate the range and importance of these
questions: sustaining prosperity, the strategy of stabilization policy,
the problem of rising prices, economic development and individual
opportunity, and the international economy.
But a careful reading of the reports brings all of these aspects of
the economy into sharp focus on one overarching problem of national
economic policy: because of past errors in national economic decisions,
the chief policy aim, both at home and abroad, must be defense of
the dollar.
It is no longer possible-if it ever was-to view domestic economic
developments as though they occur in a "closed economy" insulated
from the rest of the world. The pressures of our international com-
mitments and recent balance-of-payments moves and raids on our stock
of gold have awakened the country to the fact that domestic inflation,
fed by a persistently large Federal budget deficit, "spills over" into
internatioal trade and finance, threatening not only to worsen an
already serious balance-of-payments problem, but even to upset the
international monetary system.
THE EXTENT OF 11.5. INFLATION
Although moderately prosperous by most standards, 1968 is ex-
pected to suffer from consumer price increases of 3 to 31/2 percent.
This further inflation follows rises to 2.8 percent last year and 2.9 per-
cent in 1966. Nor are upward movements restricted to consumer prices:
the average price of final goods and services produced (the "GNP
deflator") rose even more-by 3 percent in both years. And the more
sensitive wholesale price index, after remaining virtually unchanged
from 1958 through 1964, rose 2 percent in 1965 and 3.3 percent in 1966
before leveling off during the minicession of last year. But in January
of 1968 the wholesale index stood almost a full percentage point higher
than in January of 1967; and in February rose further, so that its
upward course has been resumed.
(745)
PAGENO="0032"
746
Not only is inflation continuing on a broad front this year, but its
pace is accelerating. Moreover, inflation has changed in form. Unlike
its 1965-66 demand-pull character, inflation last year turned into cost-
push as a wage-price spiral was set in motion by leading labor con-
tract settlements that established wage gains twice as great as pro-
ductivity improvements.
Despite the tendency for inflation to be self-perpetuating, the argu-
ment is sometimes heard that our historical record justifies confidence
in a reasonably stable price level. Those who argue this way point to
the fact that 82 percentage points of the 130-percent rise in prices in
the pnst three decades reflected wartime conditions during `World
War Two and the Korean war. But adherents to this viewpoint ac-
knowledge that since `World `War Two the price level has neither
leveled off nor declined. This is the "creeping inflation" phenomenon,
some of which Arthur Ross, the U.S. Commissioner of Labor Statis-
tics, has attributed to an upward bias in consumer price statistics as
currently compiled. But this bias accounts for oI~ly about 1.3 per-
centage points of the average annual Consumer Price Index increases
of 1.9 percent since 1961 and the current annual rate of 3 to 3½ per-
cent. The difference remains to be explained.
WHICH PRICES ARE RISING?
A price index is an average; and averages can conceal as well as
reveal what they are intended to measure. The Consumer Price Index,
for example, is made up of several subindexes, including the cost of
medical care, food, horneownership, apparel, and upkeep. Some of
these costs have risen much more than others. For example, the fastest
rising cost has been medical care, a labor-intensive item, which in
December 1967 was ahnost 26 percent higher than in 1964-up almost
9 percent a year. On the same comparison, food prices rose 5 percent
a year; homeownership 4 percent; and the item, "apparel and upkeep,"
rose 3½ percent. As previously indicated, all items combined rose
about 3 percent per year. Individual items in the wholesale price index
behaved in a similar fashion, with the prices of hides and machinery
and equipment rising fastest.
Changes in prices of individual items reflect underlying shifts in
demand and supply. Demand-supply analysis of the sharp rise in
medical costs shows that the faster increase in demand for these serv-
ices, partly due to medicare and medicaid, has exceeded the increase
in the supply of skilled personnel and medical facilities. On the other
hand, the fast rise in the price of hides has been attributed more to
international supply than to demand conditions. But a general rise
in prices, as measured by a broad index or average, reflects economy-
wide changes and not simply forces affecting a few industries.
THE PROCESS OF INFLATION
There are two popular explanations of how inflation starts a.nd is
propagated. The first explanation, called demand-pull, stresses a faster
increase in money spending than can be quickly translated into in-
creased output. Such a rapid rise in overall money spending is brought
PAGENO="0033"
747
about by an excessively large increase in the money supply-7.2 per-
cent in 1967, compared to the normal 4-percent growth figure. The
second explanation, termed "cost~push," attributes rising prices to
"administered" cOsts and pri~es set by powerful gEoups in the econ-
omy-the Government (through minimum wage laws, farm price
suppor~ts, and the like), labor unions (negotiated wage increases
greater than productivity gains), and some business firms ("admin-
istered pricing").
The stepped-up, rate of price increase in late 1965 undoubtedly
resulted from acceleration of Government spending for Vietnam in
a fully employed economy without the slack to accommodate a com-
parable step-up in production. The result was that the Government
bid away manpower and capital from the private sector and, in the
process, boosted prices. This was the pull of demand at work. So rapid
was the escalation of demand in the capital market-much of it specu-
lative and anticipatory-that a "credit crunch" developed in mid-1966,
especially in that part of the market devoted to mortgage financing.
This demand-pull inflation set the stage for a wage-price spiral
that developed in 1966 as representatives of organized labor sought
and obtained wage increases that built in the earlier price rise. These
higher than productivity wage gains caused employer companies to
raise product prices in an attempt to preserve the profit margins
necessary to generate internal funds for investment in plants, machin-
ery, and equipment. This investment is necessary not only to replace
wornout and obsolete capacity, but also to expand that capacity. Profits
are also necessary to provide investors with a return on their invest-
ment.
Once inflation gets underway it tends to be self-perpetuating. This
is especially true of "cost-push" inflation typified by `the current wage-
price spiral, as is emphasized by the Council of Economic Advisers
in chapter 3 of its report. Just so long as the greater than productivity
annual increase in wage rates is "validated" by further injections of
Federal deficit spending, the upward spiral of costs `and prices will
continue.
THE DANGERS OF INFLATION
But isn't a little inflation good for the economy-or at least not
harmful? Why is a wage-price spiral so bad?
The answer to the first question is a flat "No." Inflation hurts the
economy. It retards the real growth of output partly through a reduc-
tion in efficiency; it redistributes incomes away from the great major-
ity who work for relatively fixed incomes in favor of the few who
engage in speculative activities; it harms our international competi-
tiveness; and if not checked it can bring on a recession if costs rise
faster than prices. In fact, the whole international monetary system
suffers because of inflation in this country, due to the dollar's role
as the key international currency.
The cost-push pressures of the wage-price spiral accelerate and mag-
nify inflatioliary pressures generated elsewhere. `When we had `high
unemployment and a gradually rising level of total spending in the
economy bert7wOën 1961 and 1964 average union contract settlements
were no highei~ ththi the productivity gain of 3 to 3~/2 percent. But
90-191---68-pt. 3-3
PAGENO="0034"
748
the banking system can be an engine of inflation when it is speeded
up through large and growing deficit borrowing by the Government
in a fully employed economy. It is at this point that continuous deficit
spending "engages the clutch" of the wage-price spiral.
CURBING INFLATION
It is far easier to permit inflation to develop than to curb it-not
because the anti-inflationary weapons are lacking, but because of their
political unpopularity. Excessively easy monetary and credit policies
and Federal deficit spending in a high-employment economy are the
direct causes of demand-pull inflation and the indirect causes of the
cost-push variety. The cures are the reverse: tightening credit and
shrinking the deficit. The 1951 tax increase helped stem the Korean
war inflation. The Federal Reserve's tight credit policy in 1966 slowed
the economy's price rise appreciably, despite a growing Federal deficit.
But the inflation resumed after monetary policy once again turned
expansionary in 1967 and the Federal deficit deepened. Even when
the upward wage-price spiral is set in motion monetary and fiscal
restraints can be effective.
Even when demand-pull pressures predominate, if fiscal policy does
not support monetary policy, the Federal Reserve cannot do the neces-
sary job alone. If the Treasury is running a deficit, the "Fed" is
hampered by its commitment to "maintain an even keel" (not to
tighten credit) during Treasury borrowing operations. Furthermore,
if the "Fed" is forced to act alone to stem inflation by applying the
monetary control brakes-as in 1966-it causes the economy to swerve,
like a speeding automobile whose brakes work unevenly. In that in-
stance the unduly severe impact of tight money on the construction
industry brought a precipitate decline in homebuilding activity.
It is not sufficiently recognized that traditional monetary-fiscal
policies can be effective in curbing cost-push inflation by dissipating
the underlying demand-pull pressures. The Council of Economic AcT-
visers' report (pp. 119-128) tacitly admits this fact in its discussion
of price and wage policy: but there is no explicit treatment of this
question which is of more than theoretical importance. The Council's
apparent underestimation of this point affects the price-stabilization
policy prescriptions in its report.
WAGE-PRICE CONTROLS
The seriousness of this oversight is apparent in the reiteration of
the Council's wage-price guideposts which were abandoned in 1966
precisely because a wage-price spiral had set in. Wage-price controls
either of a direc.t or indirect kind are undesirable-both because they
are ineffective and, more importantly, because t.hey distract attention
from the need to follow the proper anti-inflationary policy-adequate
monetary and fiscal restraints applied in unison. Pressure for such
controls builds up because of the failure to use a proper monetary-
fiscal policy "mix".
The nub of the question of price stability is the often cited "trade-
off" between price increases and unemployment. Studies of this ques-
PAGENO="0035"
749
tion to date strongly suggest that once the overall unemployment rate
drops below about 4 percent, price increases accelerate. If this is so,
then any national economic policy is misguided that solely through
excessive injections in spending depresses the unemployment rate
below about 4 percent. Reductions in unemploymep± significantly
below the 4-percent level should be accomplished by other than ag-
gregative spending measures such as upgrading of worker skills, en-
hanced labor mobility, and improvements in job placement procedures.
The run on gold and the dollar since the British devaluation last
November 18 and subsequent economic developments clearly indicate
that if the TJnited States does not by itself immediately take steps to
control inflation and reduce its international payments deficit through
proper monetary-fiscal policies, international pressures will force this
action.
PAGENO="0036"
COMMITTEE FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT
By EMu~Io G. CoLL~u)o, CHAIRMAN, RESEARCH AND POLICY
COMMITTEE
We appreciate the opportunity to present to the Joint Economic
Committee the views of the Committee for Economic Development on
the Economic Report of the President and the annual report of the
Council of Economic Advisers. These reports provide a valuable de-
scription and analysis of many of the opportunities and problems fac-
ing the United States today and in the years ahead.
Our comments today are centered around four issues.
The first concerns fiscal policy, where we believe that fiscal restraint
is necessary now. We support the President's tax proposals, which
would represent the major element of restraint, but in addition believe
that further expenditure reductions would be desirable. We shall at-
tempt to state the case for a stabilizing budget policy as forcibly as
we can.
The next issue concerns the evident failure to give adequate atten-
tion to a longer run program for Federal expenditures and taxes de-
signed to meet both our existing and emerging needs. Each new fiscal
problem brings forth a hastily introduced program designed to meet
the problem of the day without any apparent relationship to a long-
run program or strategy. We now have several forms of voluntary and
direct controls over various forms of economic activity. We shall
draw attention to these controls and suggest how an appropriate long-
run fiscal strategy could avert their becoming permanent fixtures
of Government policy.
The third question concerns the current inflationary pressures
which, we believe, present a serious threat to economic stability and
efficiency both at home a.nd abroad. We agree with the Council's view
that, while both cost-push and demand-pull elements are present in
the current situation, prompt fiscal action would brake the rising spiral
of wages `and prices. We fear, however, that the administration still
places far too much reliance on voluntary wage and price restraint
as a means of dampening inflationary pressures.
Finally, there is the President's emergency program for dealing
with the deterioration in the balance-of-payments position of the
United States. The President's measures and proposals represent a
continuation of the piecemeal approach to solving the balance-of -pay-
ments problem, an approach which has led the Government to rely
principally on measures designed to reduce the flow of U.S. private
capital abroad. These short-term expedients are clearly not in our
long-run interests, nor is it clear that we are more prepared today than
we `have been for the past 5 years to embark on more basic, long-term
solutions.
In what follows, our positions on these four issues will be more fully
developed.
(750)
PAGENO="0037"
751
FLEXIBILITY AND POLIOIY MAKING IN 1968
The Council's report states that "the limitations of the economists'
ability to predict the future argue for prudence in policy decisions,
flexibility in the use of instruments, and continuing efforts to improve
the reliability of forecasting techniques" (italic added). The efforts
to improve the quality and quantity of economic information will no
doubt bear fruit. But any benefits to be derived therefrom will appear
with a long lag. For the present the courses of action open to us are
only those of prudence and flexibility in stabilization policy.
As CED has said many times, a stabilizing budget policy is achieved
when the Government sets its expenditure programs and tax rates so
they would yield a surplus under conidtions of high employment and
price stability. Since the Federal budg~t is now in deficit, the present
budget policy of the Government falls short of the stabilizing budget
rule. It is our view that a policy designed to provide a budget surplus
best deals with the dangers of continued inflation without foreclosing
our ability to handle a lapse from high employment. If the deficit at
high employment is allowed to continue and if total public and private
demand rises more than anticipated, we face the danger in the present
overheated state of the economy of a still higher rate of inflation. If
total demand should rise less than is now widely anticipated, the
depressing effects of the surplus can be offset `by prompt actions to
reduce taxes, to move toward greater monetary ease, and to restore
currently deferred but desirable public expenditures.
Several major uncertainties complicate economic policymaking in
1968 and argue for prudence and flexibility; these are the Vietnam
situation and the strength of consumer demand. Almost all forecasts,
including that of the Council, `anticipate a continued acceleration of
economic activity throughout the first and second quarters of 1968.
There are a few signs, however, which lead some forecasters to antici-
pate that, even without a tax increase, private demand will moderate
in the second half of 1968. Others see little reason to believe that with
or without a tax increase economic activity will moderate at all in the
last half `of `the year. This uncertainty about the `future course of
economic activity clearly is finding its reflection in the failure of Con-
gress to come to grips with current fiscal an'd monetary requirements.
With the `economy currently operating at or very near its potential,
with wages and prices rapidly rising, with interest rates at historic
highs, and with demand expanding more rapidly than our capacity
to produce, the evidence strongly indicates the need for a program
of fiscal restraint imposed in part by the proposed tax surcharge. If
the surcharge is not enacted the country `will suffer serious setbacks.
-Prices `andwages will continue to rise at unacceptable rates. To
paraphrase' the Council, another ominous turn will have `been given
to `the wage-price spiral, postponing still ~further into the future
a return to price stability.
Our international competitive `position will be weakened and
the deterioration in our balance of trade will beaccentuated. The
effects of continued price inflation in the United States along with
rapidly accelerating incomes will increase our demand for im-
ports and reduce our ability to export.
PAGENO="0038"
752
-Monetary policy will once again be the only restraining influ-
ence with the result that interest rates will he under strong upward
pressure. It is quite clear that if fiscal restraint is not exercised
in the face of excessive demand and inflation, an expanded demand
for loans in both public and private sectors will, unless deliberately
accommodated by expanding reserves, produce a tighter monetary
policy and rising interest, rates.
-Our domestic capital markets, advanced as they may be, are not
perfect and, as we were reminded in 1966, the pressures caused
by restrictive monetary policy can cause confusion, disturb con-
fidence generally, and lead to severe distortions in the pattern of
economic activity. Small businesses, farmers, and prospective
homeowners lose out to the Federal Government and other strong
borrowers in the struggle for funds. Housing construction and
local government projects can be substantially affected. In an
economy with excessive total demand, some spending must be cut
if price level increases are to be kept within bounds. To restrain
housing substantia.lly again in 1968 is to postpone a considerable
amount of const.ruct.ion spending into some later period when fi-
nance is available. At that later time, rapid increases in construc-
tion will most likely lead to large price and wa.ge increases in this
sector of industry. Thus we will provide inadequate housing in
1968 a.nd sectoral inflation in the housing industry whenever the
level of demand in the economy moves back closer to its potential.
On the ot.her hand, if we enact the tax surcharge and find that t.he
strength of demand is not exc.essive several courses of action are open:
-Monetary policy could remain expansive or only moderately
restrictive, thus assuring an acceleration of savings flows to savings
institutions. This flow, given the high levels of income a.nd low
vacancy rates, could accommodate a substantial increase in the
demand for housh~g. Moreover, under such a monetary policy~
interest rates would moderate from their highs and credit would
be made more available to those sectors unable to compete under
current conditions.
-Certain of t.he more desirable Federal as well as State and local
government expenditures which have been postponed could be
undertaken or reprogramed.
-In the most unlikely event that private demands showed them-
selves to be so weak that a relaxation of monetary policy and an
increase in government expenditures would not assure high em-
ployment at stable prices, the ta.x surcharge could always be re-
vised or repealed.
Thus the course of prudence in policy decisions and flexibility in
the use of stabilization instruments available to the Government. argues
sti~ongly in favor of the proposed surcharge. The risks of excessive
growth in demand and accelerated inflation are great, given the pos-
sibility of. an acceleration of defense expenditures, significantly higher
consumer spending, or an acceleration of inventory accumulation or
plant and equipment expenditures. In the summer and fall of 1966
when monetary policy was the only instrument used to restrain the
ecOnomy in the face of very st.rong demand, we experienced a very
rapid rise in interest rates, severe distortions in credit markets, and
PAGENO="0039"
753
a pronounced depression in housing. Enactment of the tax surcharge
substantially reduces the risks of a recurrence of these distortions
and introduces considerable fiscal and monetary flexibility to deal with
the uncertainties in the year ahead.
In our opinion the tax surcharge by itself will not achieve all of
the fiscal restraint needed in the current situation. It is especially
important that the Federal Government examine its own spending
plans with great care. As the Nation's priorities change toward more
concern about problems of cities, poverty, and education, new areas
of spending become important. Therefore extra effort must be taken
to assure both the necessary restraint in the total of expenditures and
the needed reallocation of spending within the Federal budget. Among
the areas where we would assign lower priorities, and hence seek ex-
penditure reductions, would be, for example, in space exploration.
Substantial cuts should be made in agricultural subsidies especially in
light of the Council's statement that the bulk of farming now originates
on large farm businesses rather than from poor farm families and
thus the bulk of these subsidies do not meet their stated objectives.
Reflecting the current shortage of resources for investment and the
very high productivity of private investment, public investments in
reclamation, harbors, rivers, and highways must be reduced, deferred,
or stretched out and also be made to pass more rigid and competitive
requirements.
Given the strength of private and public demands, the low level of
unemployment and the evident strain in labor markets, and the rate
of increase in prices, Congress must act now to provide a substantial
amount of fiscal restraint. Prompt enactment of the tax increase
and sufficient expenditures cuts to bring the high employment Federal
Government budget on national income and product account into a
modest surplus must be the objective of Government policy.
A BUDGET POLICY BEYOND 1968
Except for commenting on studies directed to the problems and op-
portunities presented by a deescalation of the war in Vietnam, the
report contains few references to a fiscal program for the future.
While much might be said about the effects of the changes in na-
tional priorities on the composition of future Federal expenditures,
our comments here are concentrated on the problems of taxation. One
major objective in this area relates to improving the flexibility of fiscal
policy within the current tax structure. Another concerns changes in
the tax structure designed to accelerate economic growth and improve
the flexibility of the tax system as a stabilization tool.
The quickest and most effective method of affecting private spend-
ing, when change is needed, and with a minimum of carryover into a
later period when change is not needed, is through a temporary change
in tax rates. It is especially important that a generally accepted method
of tax rate change, both up and down, be available for prompt use
when recession or inflation threaten. Too often in the past we have
been confronted with the alternatives of raising or lowering expendi-
tures or relying solely on monetary policy.
To strengthen our ability to use temporary changes in tax rates as
a way of stopping a recession and promoting recovery or holding back
PAGENO="0040"
754
excess demand and averting inflation requires that means be devised
for putting the tax change quickly into effect and for assuring its ter-
mination at some point.
The essential condition for use of a temporary tax cut as an anti-
recession instrument or a. temporary tax increase as an anti-inflation
instrument is that the Executive, the Congress, and the public at large
should understand the functions that such a change would be intended
to serve, the circumstances in which it would be appropriate, and the
distinction between such a temporary change and basic, permanent
revision of the tax structure.
However, basic revisions in the tax structure can also be timed to
help solve current fiscal problems. For example, in April 1966 the CED
advanced the concept of a value-added tax to add desirable fiscal re-
straint to the economy, to aid our balance-of-payments problems, and
for the longer term to spur growth in the domestic economy by per-
mitting a reduction in corporate income tax rates.
For almost 10 years, the United States has experienced a deficit in its
balance of payments. Over that period of time it has become clear that
the United States could improve its fiscal policy tools to assist in the
solution of this problem. This lack of mechanisms with which to deal
with the problem is in part responsi:ble for the temporary interest
equalization tax both at its original level and at its higher rates, for the
voluntary capital constraints which have now become direct capital
controls, the controls over foreign lending by financial institutions,
the proposed taxes on travel, as well as the suggestion that we move to
impose taxes on imports and rebates on U.S. exports.
In 1966 the CED suggested tha.t discussions take place to establish
the usefulness of a broadly based, low-rate tax on value a.dded which is
acceptable under G-ATT rules in stimulating both exports and domestic
growth. If such an examination had taken place and such a tax were
immediately available today it would contribute to our current ob-
jectives better than many of the alternatives now so hastily chosen.
It could be used to restrain domestic demand and pric.e inflation, and
it would stimulate exports relative to imports and thereby lessen the
need for the onerous direct controls on investment abroad as well as
the proposed taxes on travel.
We do not propose the value-added tax now as a substitute for the
income tax surcharge and expenditure restraint proposed above. These
proposals should be adopted immediately, we do, however, once again
call for a detailed examination of the role a value-added tax could
play in the U.S. tax system.
INFLATION AND VOLUNTARY CONTROLS ON WAGES AND PmoEs
We agree with the President and the Council in their belief that
"inflation impairs economic efficiency, redistributes income capri-
ciously, and weakens the Nation's competitiveness in world market.."
We also share their pronounced distrust for direct controls as a means
of achieving price stability. However, we do not share their faith in
the efficiency and effectiveness of vohmtary controls over wages and
prices. Wage and price guidelines are an attempt to make possible
PAGENO="0041"
755
a low rate of unemployment without inflation. We believe this is a
desirable goal of public policy. But we do have severe reservations
that the suggested procedures will achieve this end.
If one examines the history of the guideposts in the U.S. economy
there are good reasons to believe that the stability of labor costs in the
period 1961-65 in the United States was due more to slack in the
economy than to exhortation about statesmanship in wage and price
policy. The guidelines may have `been innocuous, and in 1965 and 1966
when the economy reached high employment levels, insofar as the
guidelines diverted attention from the basic need for fiscal restraint
they may have been counterproductive. Now, with the economy pro-
ducing at or above its potential for the third year in a row, with about
3.5 percent unemployment, and `with very strong upward price and
wage pressure, the need is for immediate and su'bsi antial `fiscal restraint.
The report contains a proposal to establish a `Cabinet Committee
on Price Stability. One function of this Committee would be to confer
with representatives `of business, labor, and the public at large in an
attempt to reach some consensus on appropriate general standards to
guide private price and wage decisions. In most other contexts, such
efforts to form a consensus on prices or wages would be considered
inimical to a competitive market determination of prices and wages
and therefore as undesirable and against the public interest. We seri-
ously `doubt that the findings of such a Committee, however correct,
would result in the promotion of competition, efficiency, an'd price
stability in the United States.
In addi'tion to questioning the effectiveness of an incomes policy
in achieving its stated objectives, there are other most important diffi-
culties `with these suggestions. As the CED said in its testimony on `the
President's Econoniic Report in 1964,
At issue is the role of free, competitive `markets as compared with the role of
Government in `the guidance of our economy. One aspect of the issue is whether
there is a way of exercising Government influence over prices and w'ages through
moral suasion `and leadership that will be effective `without in fact constituting
Government control of a kind generally considered alien to American tra'dition
and values. Other questions, on the assumption that such influence without con-
trol is possible, include `how, by what legal proceSses, the Govèrnmèn't will deter-
mine the standards of price and wage behavior to which the economy should
conform. How can it be assured that the standards will bear equitably and with-
out discrimination upon all the individuals, businesses `and unions `to whom
they are expected to apply? If the guidepost ~o'licy is a response to a belief that
competition in labor and product markets is inadequate, is it better to move in
the direction of more Government influence rather than in the direction of
strengthening competition?
In summary, the evidence seems to indicate that an incomes policy
without fiscal and monetary restraint will not work and that with ade-
quate fiscal and monetary policies an incomes policy is a poor substi-
tute for improvements in labor mobility, a lessening of restrictive la-
bor practices, and improvements in the competitiveness of product
markets. We have already seen what were professed to be temporary
and voluntary controls over foreign capital flows persist and actually
become direct controls, because we were unwilling to adopt fiscal and
monetary policies adequate to deal with our balance-of-payments dif-
ficulties. It would be most. unfortunate indeed if we were to see the
PAGENO="0042"
756
same course of events unfold with respect to the wage and price con-
trols which are advanced in the report because we continue to be un-
willing to adopt the necessary fiscal restraint.
TOWARD INTERNATIONAL EQUILIBRIUM
For some years now the Government has invoked a variety of meas-
ures to reduce the LT.S. balance-of-payments deficit and end the gold
drain. Although the deficits recorded in 1965 and 1966 were smaller
than in previous years, we were fa.r from a satisfactory long-term solu-
tion to the balance-of-payments problem. Then. in 1967, the deficit in-
creased sharply. It is clear that the balance-of-payments deficit can
be eliminated either by increasing the surplus on private interna-
tional transactions or by reducing the deficit of the Government's in-
ternational transactions, or both. In recent years Government policies
have been directed at. both fronts.
To increase the surplus on private transactions the Government has
tended to look for individual items which could he affected by specific
actions rather than to seek more general adjustment through appro-
priate broad monetary and fiscal policies. The piecemeal approaches
have often proved ineffective and this had led to their proliferation.
The substantial increases in the payments deficit and severe gold loss
last year have led to direct controls over a vital part of our economy.
The emergency measures announced by the President on January 1,
1968, were designed to restore the waning confidence abroad in the
Government's willingness and ability to deal with balance-of-pay-
ments problem.
The justification for introducing the various piecemeal balance-of-
payments measures has been that they provide us with a "breathing
spell" during which we could achieve basic improvements in our pay-
ments position. Yet, we do not find in the Council's report an ade-
quate statement of how we are to move from the present emergency
controls to a long-run solution which would make them unnecessary.
The United States continues to earn a surplus of exports over im-
ports. However, continued inflationary pressures and repeated eco-
nomic overheating over the last 3 years have damaged the U.S.
competitive position and resulted in a declining export surplus. More-
over, continued inflation in the United States casts doubts on the
stability of the dollar and thus undermines a. principal reason why
foreigners have found it attractive to hold dollars.
The most promising way to achieve a lasting improvement in the
U.S. payments position is by restoring balance to our internal economy.
More than a year ago, the Committee for Economic Development
emphasized this in a policy statement entitled, "The Dollar and the
World Monetary System." To use the words of this statement:
Fortunately for the United States there is currently little conflict between the
demands of an appropriate domestic fiscal and monetary policy and those of the
external United States payments position. Under present conditions of inflation-
ary full employment there is need for a program of further domestic restraint.
Such a program could reduce the present balance-of-payments deficit sub-
stantially.
The consequences of continued inaction in the fiscal area are clearly
evident in our deteriorating trade surplus. Moreover, the countries of
PAGENO="0043"
757
Europe view our continued fiscal inaction as highly irresponsible on
our part and are likely, in the absence of early action, to circumscribe
quite strictly the amount of cooperation we may expect from them in
reducing the U.S. payments deficit further.
The CED is also concerned about the direction our policies have
taken as a result of the most recent measures. We should not deceive
ourselves into think that there is anything "better" about restricting
international capital movements rather than restricting international
trade or travel. Restrictions on either cause the world to forgo eco-
nomic benefits which would result from voluntary decisions made in
response to free market forces. Moreover, current and proposed re-
strictions on capital movements, trade, and travel will undo much of
the progress that we have made in the last quarter century toward
greater freedom for international trade and investment.
StTMMARY
In summary, the CED believes that a prudent course of action at
the moment is (1) a program of substantial fiscal restraint on the part
of the Federal Government-the immediate enactment of the proposed
surcharge and a reduction of expenditures to yield a modest surplus
in the high-employment budget on national income and product ac-
count, (2) prompt consideration by the administration and Congress
of the potential usefulness of the value-added tax along the lines sug-
gested by the CED in 1966, and (3) prep~trations for a move in the
direction of eliminating direct controls, specialized taxes, and direct
Government influence in the functioning of business which have been
imposed to offset the influences of inflation in the domestic economy
and on the balance of payments.
PAGENO="0044"
COMMUNICATIONS WORKERS OF AMERICA
Last year the unemployment rate in the LTnited States was 3.8
percent of the civilian labor force-the same rate as registered in
1966. In the early 1960's, when unemployment was at intolerably
high levels of 5 percent or more, the Council of Economic Advisers
set 4 percent as the "interim goal" on our road to the achievement
of full employment. It is apparent from this year's annual report that
the Council has now determined that the country will "settle" for an
unemployment rate in the neighborhood of 4 percent in order to avoid
facing the pressures of excess demand.
~Te find this evaluation of the potential of the. U.S. economy rather
conservative. In the first place, as the Council itself acknowledges,
the (now) revised method of measuring unemployment undoubtedly
understates the number of jobless, in comparison to what the figure
would have been had the former criteria been used in assessing persons
still actively in the labor force.
Secondly, we do not consider that an economy with 3 million jobless
and with considerable idle plant capacity can be said by any means
to be at full employment. A full-employment unemployment rate
should be that rate at which most of the jobless, at any point in time,
are classified as frictional unemployed (in transition between jobs).
Yet the Council points out that the burden of unemployment last
year fell most heavily on those disadvantaged groups who are being
left behind in this period of general prosperity.
The utilization rate of manufacturing plant capacity was oniy 85
percent in 1967. This, coupled with substantial hard core unemploy-
ment, indicates to us that economic policy must be geared on a priority
basis to increasing employment through measures designed (a.) to
match workers to jobs and (b) to create the new jobs necessary to
move the unemployment rate to below 3 percent.
The Council of Economic Advisers does not believe that real gross
national product can grow more than a. little over 4 percent this year
without severe excess demand. This rate of growth would leave the
unemployment rate substantially unchanged from last year. We be-
lieve that there is enough slack in the economy to allow a higher
growth rate without creating inflationary pressures beyond those
already anticipated. Indeed, the most reliable "moderating" force,
in terms of the threat of runaway inflation, lies in the degree to which
we commit ourselves to an expanding (rather than a flat or "normal")
rate of growth.
In addition to unemployment, there are a number of other domestic
issues demanding immediate attention. Last summer's riots were a
manifestation of despair among a substantial segment of our popula-
tion, stemming from inadequate job opportunities, substandard hous-
ing, poor quality education, an antiquated welfare system, and a host
of other conditions that are the antithesis of the Great Society. Yet
(758)
PAGENO="0045"
759
the Council, after acknowledging these problems and praising already
existing programs, proposes few bold or imaginative solutions.
It is clear to us in CWA that what we are doing now is not enough.
Massive programs and a commitment of genuine concern are urgently
needed. The continuing unrest in our urban srums indicates that ~he
disadvantaged are not willing to wait for the termination of the Viet-
nam war to enter the mainstream of American society.
We do not deny that the building of the Great Society is going to
cost money. We recognize thepressures on the Federal budget resulting
from our multibillion-dollar involvement in the Far East. We, there-
fore, call upon the 90th Congress-and specifically on the House Ways
and Means Committee-to institute, on a priority basis, legislation to
tap those sources in our economy which today carry no share of the tax
load whatsoever, or ride at such reduced rates as to be virtually free-
loaders.
In a recent article in the American Scholar, former Senator Paul
Douglas-long a lone voice in the Congress on behalf of tax reform-
noted that only about half the total pers~ônal income in the United
States is subject to taxation-while the other half completely escapes a
tax levy. The basic exemption in personal income tax of $600 per per-
son accounts for only a fraction of this latter amount.
In a statement issued by CWA's executive board last August, we
called on the Congress (a) to bring the half of long-term capital gains,
which now totally escapes Federal taxation, under a progressive tax
schedule geared to the level of such gains; (b) to tap the income from
State and municipal bonds on a progressive basis, also geared to the
level of income accruing to the individual taxpayer from such sources;
and (c) to revise the depletion allowance schedule (beginning with
the 271/2 percent writeoff for oil and gas) to bring it in line with the
level of taxation now levied on the corporate sector as a whole.
Provided that the Congress takes such action in closing tax loop-
holes, we would support a surcharge on personal and corporate income,
tailored to an ability-to-pay principle which would assure that such
additional tax payments enhance the progressive structure of our in-
come tax schedules, rather than compounding their regressive char-
acteristics.
We believe that sufficient revenue can be thus generated, not only to
meet the cost of our foreign commitments and to ease the tight credit
situation, but also to initiate the kinds of programs needed to achieve
full employment and to tackle the most pressing of the other problems
which continue to plague this society.
We are prepared to acknowledge that, as the Nation moves closer to
full employment, there are likely to be inflationary biases; our re-
sources are not perfectly mobile. Bottlenecks may occur in some indus-
tries while there is idle capacity in others; workers with certain skills
may be in short supply while others cannot find jobs. Businesses have
rather consistently taken advantage of strong demand to raise prices
and to improve their profit margins. Lower unemployment rates may,
in a word, incur the cost of rising prices.
Nevertheless, we are firmly convinced that the Nation can sustain the
burden of a moderate rise in the price level far more readily than the
grave consequences of letting our domestic problems fester for the
duration of the war.
PAGENO="0046"
760
It may be that, in attempting to meet our commitments at home and
to pursue a war abroad, it will become necessary at some date to insti-
tute direct economic controls in order to prevent a disastrous runaway
inflation. Labor has long since indicated its willingness to face that
eventuality-provided that all Americans are called upon to share the
burden equally.
As part of its `anti-inflation program, the CEA reiterates the con-
troversial guidepost concept. The Council moved this year to an im-
plicit absolute maximum of 51/2 percent for "noninflationary" wage
settlements. We in CWA continue to maintain that the guideposts are
inequitable-that they call upon one part of the population to make
a special sacrifice to correct a problem which that sector had no
responsibility in creating.
During the period 1961-66-the guidepost years-corporate profits
increased 77 percent, while employees' compensation rose only 43
percent. In an attempt to achieve higher and higher profits and re-
turns on equity, business raised prices during the slowdown in late
1966 and early 1967 in order to maintain previous profit levels in the
face of a decrease in demand. Wage earners watched impatiently as
their incomes lagged behind other forms of income, including
dividends, professional salaries `and capital gains.
At the same time the purchasing power of workers' earnings was
being eroded `by rising food prices and the costs of essential services,
especially medical care services. By late 1966 it was obvious to labor
that a catchup to the mounting cost of living was necessary. Yet
despite the negotiated settlements averaging 51/2 percent last year-
which the administration considers alarming-a recent Labor Depart-
ment study showed that real wages were no `higher last December than
the two previous Decembers.
There is a growing imbalance in income distribution in this country;
the guideposts penalize the very group whose incomes must be ad-
justed if the imbalance is to be corrected.
The movement back to one magic number that is to apply to all
industries-the efficient and the inefficient-flies in the face of the
economic realities by which resource allocations are made in a free
economy. We cannot accept 3.2 percent or 5.5 percent or any other
single figure as being the "right" wage increase for all workers in all
situations.
We are somewhat puzzled over the role of the newly created Cabinet
Committee on Price Stability. The President states that one of its
functions will `be to inform labor and business of the "consequences
of irresponsible wage and price behavior," `and "to seek ideas and initi-
atives to correct persistent structural problems that cause prices to
rise." Yet he assures that the Committee will not `become involved in
specific current wage or price matters. We fear that the door has
nonetheless been left open for this body eventually to grow into some
kind of "final judgment" panel to give a "pass" or a "fail" to a
negotiated settlement, on the basis of whether the `Committee believes
it to be inflationary.
On the other hand, `there is much `that we do not yet understand
about our complex economy. If, through study and discussion, the
Committee can add to this understanding, and can propose remedies
PAGENO="0047"
761
to correct existing misallocations and inefficient use of resources, `CWA
will be glad to cooperate to the fullest extent possible.
It might appear from our criticisms of the report that we are ignor-
ing those areas in which we find ourselves in agreement with the admin-
istration and the Council. This is not the case. It is perhaps because we
recognize the common bonds which we share with the President and
with the Council that we dwell especially on those policies and pro-
grams which seem to us to fall short of our common objectives. We
appreciate the enormity of the task of formulating viable economic
policy for the United States in these difficult times.
Our underlying point, however, is that the annual report of the
Council of Economic Advisers serves a unique purpose, in the dialog
among our citizenry on "whither the economy". In our view, this
report should serve, not only as a policy guide for the year ahead, but
the report ought to make explicit a broader and longer range perspec-
tive on those targets which the American people have the capacity to
achieve. The report might provide, as well, some of the guidance and
the impetus needed to set us thinking and acting on the achievement of
those targets.
It is in this vein that the Communications Workers of America
addresses these comments on the 1968 Economic Report to the Joint
Economic `Committee of `the Congress.
(Appended hereto is a supplementary and more detailed statement
by the Communications Workers of America on the issue of wage and
price guideposts.
We submit these `observations as a contribution to the continuing
public discussion of an issue vital to the health and stability of our
economy, the resolution of which extends well beyond the immediate
concerns of the 1968 Economic Report.)
THE WAGE-PRICE GUIDEPOST ISSUE
A COMMENTARY BY THE COMMUNICATIONS WORKERS OF AMERICA
The Council of Economic Advisers, reiterating the "guidepost" con-
cept in its 1968 annual report, calls upon labor and management to act
responsibly `and with restraint to stem the inflationary trends of
1966-67. The principal burden is placed upon labor, however, via an
implicit 5.5-percent ceiling on negotiated settlements, while there is no
comparable guidepost stipulated for prices. To quote from the Coun-
cil's report:
This (price stability) can only be achieved if the average of new union settle-
ments is appreciably lower than the 51/2 percent average `of 1967 and if business
firms avoid any `widening of their gros's margins over direct costs and indeed
absorb cost increases to the extent feasible.
We in CWA are deeply concerned, as are all citizens, that the steady
march of rising prices has erod'ed the purchasing power of all workers'
wages. It is our firm conviction, however, that wage guideposts are not
the proper policy for achieving meaningful growth while maintaining
relative price stability.
Although `the record of the last 7 years has been marked `by sustained
growth, with only minor slowdowns, this prosperity has not been
equally distributed among the various sectors of the economy. It is this
PAGENO="0048"
762
imbalance, plus the dislocations and pressures of the Vietnam con-
flict, which provided the initial impetus for spiraling prices-not reck-
less union demands.
Between 1962 and 1965 corporate after-tax profits increased 45
percent. The 1966 profit take was 9 percent above that of 1965. Dur-
ing the slowdown in late 1966 and the first half of 1967, when there
was substantial idle plant capacity, business firms were still attempt-
ing to maintain the record-breaking profit levels of earlier years.
To do so, faced with a lower level of total demand, the businessman
sought to maintain his inflated "share" via a boost in the price struc-
ture in his particular bailiwick.
Prices did not decline during the "plateau period" in 1966-and
profits are now rising again. A Dow Jones survey of 581 corpora-
tions indicated that profits in the fourth quarter of 1967 were 5.2
percent above the same period in 1966. The consensus of business
forecasters is for a rosy a.nd profitable 1968.
To compound the squeeze on the worker, interest rates for con-
sumer credit have recently broken 40-year record highs. Food prices
jumped 9 percent from January 1965 to December 1967. Even more
dramatic has been the skyrocketing in the price of consumer serv-
ices. In 1967, increases in the cost of consumer services accounted
for almost half the total rise in the Consumer Price Index. The
fantastic increase in the cost of medical care has been the primary
contributing factor. Physicians' fees and hospital service costs rose
8.1 percent during 1966 and another 7.9 percent during 1967.
Meanwhile, wages have lagged. Average hourly earnings of non-
farm workers increased only 10.4 percent from 1962 to 1965, and 4
percent between 1965 and 1966-while productivity was increasing
at a rate of 3.6 percent annually.
In short., wages have, in fact, stayed within the guidelines, but
the rise in the price of essential goods and services has wiped out real
wage gains-while corporate profits were taking a larger share of the
economic pie. It is not surprising, then, that by late 1966 unions found
the situation intolerable; it was imperative that union members
catch up to the rise in the cost of living. And catch up is all that they
did.
A recent Labor Department study found that, although average
hourly earnings of nonfarm workers increased more sharply in 1967
than in any other year in the last decade, real earnings (earnings ad-
justed for price changes) were about the same in December of 1967 as
in the previous two Decembers.
In our view, the proper method for maintaining a balanced growth
in GNP without inflation is through the use of monetary and fiscal
tools-not special "controls" directed at specific groups. CWA sup-
ports, in the area of fiscal policy, a wartime surtax, geared to the
ability-to-pay principle and coupled with urgently neede4 reforms
to close tax loopholes under which substantial amounts of income
escape the kind of tax burden assessed on wages and salaries. This
kind of tax policy can prevent a monetary crisis, and help keep at
least one important price down-the cost of credit.
Orderly, noninflationary growth cannot he achieved so long as the
purchasing power of wage earners does not keep up with the in-
crease in profits and other forms of income.
PAGENO="0049"
763
The critical role of monetary and fiscal policy in stemming the
price spiral was emphasized by two of the economists testifying on
the guideposts issue before the Joint Economic Committee on Jan-
uary 31 of this year.
Prof. John Kendrick, of George Washington University, stated:
The guideposts obviously cannot replace noninflationary monetary and fiscal
policy.
Prof. George Perry, of the University of Minnesota, elaborated
further:
If present price prospects require a remedy * `~ the main burden must fall
on restraining total demand through conventional fiscal and monetary means
* * If, with all the benefit of hindsight, we could rewrite the history of the past
2'/2 years, applying fiscal restraint when the surge of demand first appeared in
late 1965, I believe we could operate at today's output and employment levels with
less inflationary risk than we actually face.
What are the operative results of wage guideposts, whether officially
or unofficially enunciated as a decimal point ceiling?
Those sectors which have contributed most to the rise in consumer
prices are food and services-both areas where guideposts pressure can
seldom be brought to bear, due largely to the fragmented nature of
price decisions in these industries.
In effect, the situations which receive the most concentrated atten-
tion from the Government's guidepost activities are the "visible" in-
dustries-those organized industries whose negotiations involve, at one
time, all or a substantial portion of the workers in a particular
industry.
Thus the wage guidepost stratagem seeks from organized labor a
special sacrifice-in the form of hold the line-to cure a general eco-
nomic problem of which labor is the victim, not the instigator.
In addition to a catchup in purchasing power, the labor movement
will gear its bargaining in 1968 to assure to its members recognition
of their contribution to rising productivity in the industry in which
they work.
It is in this context that CWA approaches its negotiations this year
with the communications industry. From 1959 to 1966, output per
man-hour-productivity-grew more rapidly in communications than
in any other industry, increasing 5.3 percent per year. The 1968 Coun-
cil of Economic Advisers' report points out what CWA has been say-
ing for a number of years:
* * * public utilities (communications and electric, gas, and sanitary serv-
ices) have not passed the full benefit of improved productivity on to their cus-
tomers. Although their capital costs per unit of output have undoubtedly risen,
their profits have increased at an exceptional rate.
The Bell System is an excellent example of just how exceptional the
rate of profit in the public utilities industry has been. Between 1962
and 1967 A.T. & T.'s profits grew 47.6 percent, or better than 9~/2 per-
cent per year. The Council's choice of the word "exceptional" is clearly
not an attempt to understatement.
During the period 1959 to 1966, output per man-hour in the commu-
nications industry rose an average of 5.3 percent per year, while com-
pensation per man-hour rose only 4.3 percent-and thus unit labor
costs declined 1 percent per year. The correlation between declining
unit labor costs and burgeoning profits in the communications industry
is clear and direct.
90-191-68--Pt. 3-4
PAGENO="0050"
764
The guidepost concept attempts to tie the average increase in pro-
ductivity for the economy as a whole to a sanctioned rate of increase
for wages. From 1964 to 1966, 3.2 percent was the magic number to be
applied to all contract negotiations, irrespective of conditions in each
industry. The CEA has abandoned the explicit 3.2 percent in favor of
an implicit 5.5 percent ceiling-although the Chairman of the Council
acknowledged in testimony before the Joint Economic Committee that
he thought a 3.2 percent figure would be "about" the right guidepost
figure, if one had been published for 1968.
We reject any and all such "numbers games" by dint of which an
attempted uniformity is to be imposed on a richly variegated economy.
We in the Communications Workers of America are active and avowed
supporters of that economy, of the economic freedom which is integral
to it, and of free collective bargaining, a critical ingredient in assuring
that the fruits of our economy return to those who have produced
them.
PAGENO="0051"
CONFERENCE ON ECONOMIC PROGRESS
By LEON H. KEYSERLING,' PRESIDENT
CONTENTS
Page
Introduction 767
Chapter I. SUSTAINING PROSPERITY: RECORD AND PROSPECTS
CEA's excessive optimism about economic growth performance 767
CEA's inadequate awareness of excessive unemployment 768
CEA's neglect of problem of economic equilibrium 769
CEA's bias with respect to wage trends 770
CEA's low targets for the future 772
Chapter II. THE STRATEGY OF STABILIZATION POLICY
Self-praise may be slight recommendation 774
Wrong diagnosis and wrong cure, 1966-67 774
Still wrong, 1967-68 775
Failure to resist wayward monetary policy 775
Chapter III. THE PROBLEM OF RISING PRICES
Price trends are not very meaningful per se 776
Price trends significant in their impact upon resource and income allocation_ 777
CEA exaggerates inflationary trends 777
Price trends in an international perspective 778
A higher growth rate and less unemployment do not import more inflation. 778
Otherflawsin CEA cost-push thesis 780
Comment on new Cabinet Committee on Price Stability 780
Coordinating public and private economic policies 781
CHAPTER IV. ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AND INDIVIDUAL OPPORTUNITY
Interplay of economic and social problems 782
Ineffectual CEA treatment of economic-social issues 782
The issue of what the Federal Government can afford 783
The issue of urban-rural balance 783
The issue of the war against poverty 783
The issue of housing and urban renewal 784
Minimum ambits of CEA responsibility 784
CHAPTER V. THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY
Balance-of-payments problem grossiy exaggerated 785
We should run a much larger unfavorable balance of payments 785
Our international goods and services account 786
Methods of accounting need recasting 787
The unworkability of settlement in gold 787
Comments on Economic Report of the President 788
1 Former Chairman, Council of Economic Advisers; consulting economist, and
attorney.
(765)
PAGENO="0052"
766
COMMENTS ON ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT
CHARTS
(Appearing at end of statement)
1. Basic U.S. economic trends, 1953-67.
2. Large national economic deficits during period 1953-67.
3. Comparative growth in various aspects of U.S. economy, 1961-67.
4. The growth in consumer spending has been much too slow, 1953-67.
5. Inadequate consumption growth stems from inadequate income growth.
6. Shares in income by quintiles, 1947, 1953, 1960, and 1966.
7. Deficiencies in wages and salaries are large share of deficiencies in total
consumer incomes before taxes.
8. Rates of change in GNP, productivity, wages and salaries, 1960-67.
9. Price, profit, investment, and wage trends during 1960-67.
10. Trends in productivity for the entire private economy, 1910-67.
11. U.S. economic growth rates, 1922-1967, and needed rates, 1967-75.
12. How much we have to work with, 1967-75, based on economic growth pro-
jections.
13. The "Freedom Budget," 1970 and 1975 goals, employment, production,
and spending projected from levels in 1967.
14. The "Freedom Budget" maintains balance of public and private responsi-~
biities.
15. Goals for a Federal budget geared to economic growth and public needs.
16. Selected price trends, 1917-67, U.S. and selected other countries.
17. Relative trends in economic growth, unemployment, and prices, 1952-67.
PAGENO="0053"
CONFERENCE ON ECONOMIC PROGRESS
INTRODUCTION
The opportunity which the Joint Economic Committee has given
me, year by year, to express my views with respect to the Economic
Report of the President and the annual report of the Council of
Economic Advisers is deeply appreciated.
My comments will deal mainly with the CEA report, for it develops
the underlying analyses upon which the brief Economic Report of the
President is `based and, quite properly, there is virtual consistency
between the two documents.
In terms of the history of the Employment Act and its legitimately
ambitious purposes, the 22 years of cumulative experience with opera-
tions under that act, and the profound economic challenges imposed
upon the U.S. economy by current and foreseeable international and
domestic conditions, I regretfully regard the current CEA report
as inadequate and disappointing. In my view, the performance goals
which it sets are too low, the priorities which it establishes are not
properly ordered, and the analysis which it undertakes is in important
respects very deficient.
My comments upon the CEA's report will be set forth under the
five chapter headings contained in that report.
CHAPTER 1: SUSTAINING PROSPERITY: RECORD AND PROSPECTS
CEA's excessive optin-tisni about economic growth performance
The report is excessively impressed with the average annual U.S.
economic growth rate in real terms of 4.6 percent during 1960-67.
The real growth rate averaged 4.5 percent during 1922-29, 4.6 percent
during 1947-50, and 5 percent during 1947-53. In none of these earlier
periods did we possess the capabilities for economic growth which have
been our during the more recent years, in terms of technology, indus-
trial skills, and policy know-how. Nor in any of these earlier periods
were we confronted by challenges as imperative as those now con-
fronting us. Indeed, the recent years have `been the first time within
the 20th century that a war of substantial size, and tremendous
domestic needs, have not prompted us toward a national economic
policy which sought to call forth fully the great nonsecret weapon of
America's optimum production capabilities. There is nothing in the
report which gives even an intimation of the seriousness of this omis-
sion. The report focuses mainly upon the defensive purpose of restor-
ing reasonable price stability (subsequently to be discussed), instead
of upon the affirmative and dynamic purpose of obtaining the maxi-
mum objectives of the Employment Act of 1946.
The report exhibits extraordinary complacency in the face of a
real economic growth rate of only 2½ percent 1966-67, which I equate
with a GNP gap of about $70 billion measured in 1965 dollars, coining
to about 8.7 percent of maximum production. It is noteworthy that the
Council in this report has practically abandoned its previous concern
about the GNP gap. To be sure, if the Council undertook to estimate
the gap for 1967, it would undoubtedly come up with a much lower
(767)
PAGENO="0054"
768
estimate than mine, although a very significant one at that. But as I
have shown previously, and will show subsequently in this statement,
the Council has grossly and persistently underestimated the true
growth potentials of the U.S. economy, especially in its interpretation
of productivity trends. Additional perspective is shed upon the seri-
ousness of the gap in 1967 alone by my estimate that, during 1953-67
as a whole, the production ga.p measured in 1965 dollars aggregated
$781 billion, and was accompanied by 36.3 million man-years of lost
employment opportunity (see my charts 1 and 2).
Even more serious is the apparent satisfaction which the Council
takes in its forecast of a real economic growth rate of somewhat more
than 4 percent during 1968, assuming enactment of the President's
fiscal program. Even if we were now enjoying reasonably full resource
use, an average annual economic growth rate in real terms of at least
5 percent would be the optimum or maximum in view of current capa-
bilities a.nd needs, and in view of the growth rate registered during
much earlier periods of reasonably full resource use (when the growth
rate was not artificially accelerated by starting from a base of very
low resource use).
Moreover, assuming current and proposed policies, including the
tax surcharge, I find the Council's forecast (p. 55) of a somewhat
better than 4 percent real rate of economic growt.h during 1968 exces-
sively optimistic. The Council itself estimates that Federal expendi-
tures will rise about $15 billion in 1968, compared with $21 billion in
1967, and the estimated $6 billion slackening in this phase of expansion
would not be counteracted fully by an estimated rise of $5 billion in
transfer payments to persons. Thus, I cannot fully understand the
Council's statement (p. 39) that "as 1968 opens, fiscal policy * * *
is now overly expansionary, in an economy now growing at a rapid
pace." Further, the proposed tax surcharge if enacted (which the
Council incorporates in its forecast) would as estimated by the Coun-
cil add $8 billion to the Federai revenue take in 1968. Coupling these
factors with the Council's estimate that the recovery of business invest.-
ment which commenced in the middle of 1967 will proceed in 1968 at
only a moderate rate, and with the extraordinarily high rate of about 7
percent in personal saving. I cannot find justification for the Council's
view that a 2%-percent rate of real economic growth during 1967 will
be converted into a better than 4 percent rate of real economic growth in
1968 (see pp. 54-57). This seems especially the case, in that the Coun-
cil (p. 43) says that "the strongly expansionary fiscal policy [during
the first half of 1967, to be contrasted with a less expansionary fiscal
policy in 1968] supported the growth of personal income and hence of
consumption." I think that most other competent forecasters share
my concern.
GEA `s inadequate awareness of ea~cessive unem.ploymen t
I am equally concerned about the Council's obvious equanimity in the
face of a full-time unemployment rate of 3.8 percent during both 1966
and 1967, its expectancy of nothing better in 1968, and its apparent
willingness, in the name of fighting inflation (subsequently to be dis-
cussed) to urge policies which might cause unemployment to rise ap-
preciably or seriously above recent and current levels.
PAGENO="0055"
769
The tolerable level of unemployment depends upon the interna-
tional and domestic circumstances confronting the Nation, the impact
of a given level of total unemployment upon its distribution, the
social response to unemployment and a more empirical appraisal of
the relationship between levels of unemployment and inflationary
trends than the Council has troubed itself to undertake. By none of
these tests is a 3.8-percent level of full-time unemployment tolerable
now. It is not tolerable in terms of the production challenge con-
fronting us in view of a large war and our vast unmet domestic
priorities; at the peak of World War II unemployment was reduced
below 1 percent. It is not tolerable because an overall full-time unem-
ployment rate of 3.8 percent means unemployment two to three times
as high among vulnerable groups such as teenagers and Negroes, and
10 or more times as high in some critical urban areas. It is not tolerable
because the fair expectancy of these~ vulnerables means social unrest
and disorder in the event of so high level of unemployment. And it is
not tolerable because a 3.8-percent rate of full-time unemployment
means a true unemployment rate of about 5.6 percent, taking into
account the full-time equivalent of part-time unemployment, and the
concealed unemployment of those who are not participating in the
civilian labor forces and not counted as unemployed because the scarc-
ity of job opportunity discourages them from actively looking for
work.
The Council's attempts to explain no rise in the rate of full-time
unemployment during 1967, despite an economic growth rate in real
terms of only 2)-/2 percent, by noticing the decline in working hours
and in the rate of productivity growth (p. 51). This correlation is in-
deed a said confession, for (as will be shown) the sharply declining
rate of productivity growth, and to a degree the shortening of hours,
in 1967 were attributable to the abysmally low rate of economic
growth. Meanwhile, the declining rate of productivity growth (as will
be shown) contributed to the inflationary pressures which may inhibit
real economic growth. The shortening of hours contributed to a dim-
inution of total. labor input which is not revealed by measurement of
full-time unemployment, and also contributed to the inadequate ex-
pansion of consumer buying power and consumption which in turn
inhibited real economic growth in 1967 and will continue to do so in
1968.
In other words, while we can all be glad that full-time unemploy-
ment did not grow in 1967. it is running around in a circle to be
complacent in the face of the interrelated factors of a low rate of
economic growth, a shortening of hours. a sharply declining rate of
productivity growth, and the mere stabilization of the unemploy-
ment rate (see again my chart 1).
CEA's neglect of problem of economic equilibrium
The shortcomings in the Council's approach to the problems of
economic growth and unemployment are particularly disturbing, be-
cause in none of its report thus far has the Council undertaken a
really penetrating analysis of why we have not been able to obtain
economic equilibrium at maximum resource use, maximum employ-
ment, and maximum economic growth. This failure to maintain the
PAGENO="0056"
770
desired equilibrium has occurred because of a very serious and per-
sistent distortion in the patterns of incomes and spendings. These
distortions certainly lend no support to the Council's statement (p. 45)
that "the years 1961-65 had been characterized by a rema~rkably
balanced expansion among the various sectors * * * business fixed
investment, though rising rapidly in 1964-65, was geared appropriately
to the expansion of markets * *
This cheery statement cannot be reconciled with almost universal
recognition, and recognition even in earlier CEA reports, that the
investment boom in late 1964 and 1965 was inordinant and nonsustain-
able. It is not consistent with the call for the suspension of the invest-
ment tax credit in 1966. It is not consistent with the serious excess of
personal savings over gross domestic investment which emerged by
1967. to which the Council calls attention (p. 48).
My own studies, presented to this committee and elsewhere, have
for years been underscoring these serious disequilibriums, which have
not been redressed. From 1961 to 1967, total national production,
measured in uniform dollars, rose only 34.6 percent, private consumer
*spending only 33.3 percent, Government outlays for goods and services
only 37.9 percent, and transfer payments only 45.5 percent, while
private investment in plant and equipment rose 63.5 percent. Under-
lying these distortions, wages and salaries rose only 38.4 percent,
labor income only 39.6 percent, and farm proprietors' net income only
5 percent, while corporate profits rose 43.7 percent, personal dividend
income 51 percent, and personal interest income 70 percent.
The shrinkage of the economic growth rate to only 2.5 percent in real
terms during 1967 was responsive to these disequilibriums, but did not
cure them. Of course, in reaction to previous excesses, the growth rates
in private investment in plant and equipment and in corporate profits
were slightly negative in 1967. Even so, aggregate profits, and certainly
per unit profits, were at least ample to generate whatever levels of busi-
ness investment might be justified by trends in ultimate demand. As of
now, plants in general are operating somewhere in the neighborhood
of 85 percent of rated capacity, which is far too low.
Meanwhile, private consumer spending rose only 2.8 percent in real
terms in 1967, which was egregiously below the requirements for equi-
librium at maximum resource use. The savings rate above 7 percent
during 1967 did not indicate a sufficiency of private consumer income
in the aggregate; it merely indicated in part the reaction to the rela-
tively excessive investment boom during previous years, and in part
:an unsatisfactory distribution of total consumer income, aggravated
by recent fiscal and monetary policies and by the low economic growth
Tate itself (see my chart 3). (The inadequate trends in consumer
spending and incomes, and the unsatisfactory income distribution, are
illustrated more specifically in my charts 4, 5, and 6).
*UEA's bias with respect to wage trends
The failure of the Council to develop an adequate equilibrium analy-
sis is nowhere more manifest than in its treatment of the whole prob-
1cm of wages during recent years, especially in connection with the
~price-wage guidelines. Faced with the rather chronic problem of in-
adequate expansion of wage rates and wage buying-power to play their
PAGENO="0057"
771
role in achieving maximum resource use, the Council has persistently
forgotten all about wages as a factor in consumer buying-power, and
has dealt with wages only as a factor in business costs. The concern
has been only to avoid such wage rate increases as might result in cost-
push inflation.
This GEA preoccupation has been misplaced, in terms of the realities
of recent economic developments. Based upon my aggregate analysis, I
estimate that, measured in 1965 dollars, the deficiency in wage and
salaries ranged from $42.6 to $55.1 billion during every year from 1960
through 1967, and was $45.1 billion in 1967 (see my chart 7).
This aggregate analysis is fortified by comparative trends in wages
and productivity. During 1960-1966, when the economic growth rate
in real terms averaged annually 5 percent, productivity or output per
man-hour in the private nonf arm economy grew at an avearge annual
rate of 3.2 percent, while real wages and salaries per man-hour in the
private nonfarm economy grew at an average annual rate of only 2.7
percent, representing a very serious lag in real wage-rate gains behind
productivity gains.
During 1966-67, preliminary estimate indicate that productivity
in the private nonf arm economy grew only 1 percent, while real wage
and salaries per man-hour grew 2.8 percent. But it is entirely fallacious
to regard this wage-rate gain as "too high" relative to the productivity
gain. For the productivity gain of only 1 percent did not represent a
break in the technological trend toward increasing rates of productiv-
ity gains, but rather reflected the response of actual productivity to
the underutilization of the labor force resulting from the economic
growth rate of only 2.5 percent in real terms. To have attempted to
repress the rate of gain in wages and salaries to this artificially re-
pressed productivity growth rate would have been institutionally diffi-
cult, if not impossible. And it would also have compounded the difficul-
ties of inadequate expansion of demand, in terms of restoring an
adequate economic growth rate.
Any attempt at thorough equilibrium analysis would have revealed
to the Council that the low economic growth rate and the terribly low
productivity growth rate in 1967 stemmed in large degree from the
lag in consumer buying power and wages behind the productivity
growth-rate during 1960-66. But ignoring all this, the 1968 report
of the Council misappraises the real difficulty, and heightens its ex-
pression of concern about wage-rate gains exceeding productivity
gains.
Beyond all this, when 1966-67 is included, the average annual
increase in productivity or output per man-hour during 1960-67 in
the private nonfarm economy was 2.9 percent, while the average an-
nual increase in real wages and salaries per man-hour was only 2.7
percent.
The true nature of the disparities to be dealt with is demonstrated
even more clearly by looking at tQtal manufacturing. Here, during
1960-66, productivity grew at an average annual rate of 3.8 percent,
while real wages a~nd salary gai~is per man-hour lagged at 2 percent.
During 1960-67, when the productivity gain dropped to 0.9 percent
rn consequence `of the economic `stagnation, real wages and salaries
per man-hour grew 2.7 percent; these disparate trends `should be inter~
PAGENO="0058"
772
preted the same as those in 1967 in the total private nonf arm economy
(discussed above). But during the whole period 1960-67, productivity
m tota.l manufacturing grew at an average annual rate of 3.4 percent,
while real wages a.nd salary gains per man-hour lagged tremendously
at 2.1 percent (see my chart 8).
Still further light upon the disequilibrium may be obtained by look.
ing at relative trends in prices, profits, investment in plant and equip-
ment, and wage rates. From 1960 to 1967 in total manufacturing,
prices rose 5.5 percent., profits after taxes 83.6 percent, investment
in plant and equipment 85.4 percent, and wage rates 25.2 percent. In
motor vehicles and equipment, prices rise 0.9 percent, profits after
taxes 30.8 percent, investment in plant and equipment 86.5 percent,
and wage rates 26.3 percent. In four other key categories examined,
the manifestations in general were similar (see my chart 9).
My foregoing analysis, in its entirety, reveals, in my view, the ex-
tent to which the analyses and emphasis of the Council in its reports
over the years, and especially in 1968, have swung away from the
realities of actual developments and needed adjustments.
(YEA's low targets for the future
But what is past is only prelude. It is far more important to examine
* how the Council's over-exuberance and over-complacency about de-
velopments to date have been accompanied by understatement., or
failure to state, our needed goals for the future-goals explicitly called
for by the Employment Act of 1946. Beyond the shaky forecast of a
somewhat better than 4 percent rate of real economic growth in 1968,
the Council nowhere attempts in the current report to develop the
long-range goals in quantified terms which are essential to rally our full
economic power and to provide adequate indicia for specific economic
policies. Nothing could be more essential than development of such
comprehensive and integrated long-range quantified goals, in view of
a growing international burden of unpredictable size and duration,
plus the ominous intensity of our unmet needs across the whole do~
mestic front.
A starting point for developing these long-range goals is a careful
examination of long-range productivity trends and t.heir genuine im-
port. Over the decades, the average annual rate of productivity gains
in time entire private economy has tended to accelerate. being 0.4 per-
cent during 1910-20, 2.3 to 2.4 percent during 1920-40, 3.2 percent
during 1940-55, and 3.7 percent during 1961-66 (4 percent during
1947-53). The decline to an average annual rate of productivity
growth of only 2.4 percent during 1955-60, and apparently only 1.4
percent during 1966-67, was responsive (as indicated earlier in my
discussion) to the underutilization resulting from an extraordinarily
low rate of real economic growth. It follows that the Council, instead
of predicating our economic growth potential in future upon the
average annual productivity gains actually registered during a num-
ber of decades past-in the neighborhood of 3 percent-should take
fuller account of the more pertinent recent developments and the trend
toward accelerating productivity gains under the impact of a * reason-
ably high real economic growth rate.
On this basis, it appears to me clear that a 3.5- to 4-percent-average-
annual rate of productivity growth in the private economy in the years
PAGENO="0059"
773
ahead is not less than we should aim for and adopt policies accord-
ingly. A 3.5-percent-average-annual rate is conservative indeed, and
it is about this rate which I utilize for establishing economic growth
goals of 5 percent annually after restoration of reasonably full re-
source use, and a somewhat higher rate until that restoration is ac-
complished through the taking up of slack resources (see my charts
10 and 11).
Accordingly, I estimate that, measured in fiscal year 1959 dollars
(which appear to be utilized in the President's January 1968 budget
message, and which roughly indicate current price levels), our total
national production should rise from $820 billion in 1967 to $1,222 to
$1,227 billion in 1975, a gain of $402 to $442 billion. This would mean,
during the 8 years, 1968 to 1975 inclusive, a C-NP averaging annually
$227 to $246 billion higher than in 1967, and aggregating during the
8-year period $1,817 to $1,968 billion more than if C-NP remained at
the 1967 level during these 8 years. This should be the true measure-
ment of what we can afford to do, internationally and domestically,
and programs adjusted from year to year in terms of these potentials
are indeed the steps by which we can achieve them (see my chart 12)
To illustrate the importance of an optimum growth rate, over ap-
proximately a 10-year period, each 1-percent difference in the economic
growth rate means an average annual difference of about $50 billion
in total output during the 10-year period. Thus, over a 10-year period,
an average annual growth rate of 2½ percent as against 5 percent
would cost tis on the average about $125 billion of C-NP a year, or
about $11/4 trillion in the aggregate. The difference between the 4-
percent-growth rate which the Council hopefully projects for 1968 and
a 5-percent-growth rate would cost us about a half trillion dollars of
C-NP in the aggregate over a decade. The difference between a 3-per-
`cent-growth rate, which now seems to represent the dominant 1968
forecast, and a 5-percent-growth rate, would come to about a trillion
dollars in the aggregate over a 10-year period.
The foregoing C-NP goal for 1975 is consistent with the goal set
forth in "A Freedom Budget for All Americans," a 1966 publication
which I had a major role in preparing. But as indicated above, I have
now converted the exercise from calendar 1965 dollars to fiscal 1969
dollars, and substituted as the base year calendar year 1967, instead
of calendar 1965. To make a C-NP goal meaningful in terms of analysis,
and in terms of the policies needed to achieve it, the C-NP goal must
be broken down into major components representing an equilibrium
model. My chart 13 depicts such a model, which I have developed,
refined, a-nd adjusted over the years in the light of evolving economic
developments and pertinent considerations as to priority needs.
This equilibrium model does not contemplate drastic changes in
the ratios of the main components of C-NP to the total, and thus does
not contemplate changes in our institutional attitudes, nor in relative
reliance upon public and private sectors. To illustrate, in 1967 public
outlays at all levels f-or goods and services came to 22.5 pereen~t of
C-NP, and would be somewhere between 20 and 21 percent in 1975.
Gross private investment (including net foreign) came to 16.6 percent
of C-NP in 1967, and would be about 17 percent in 1975. Private con-
sumer outlays came to 62.6 percent in 1967, and would be about 63
percent in 1975 (see my chart 14).
PAGENO="0060"
774
As the Federal budget is the most important single instrument of
national economic policy, and for the indication of our great national
priorities, I have also developed a model Federal budget as part of
my equilibrium model (see my chart 15).
The goal for national defense set forth in this model budget does
not represent intensive work on my part, since I can claim to no expert-
ness of this subject, but represents instead what might be called the
composite judgment of informed experts, assuming continuation of
the cold war and the engagement in Vietnam for a now indetermin-
able period of time. The value of this assumption is that it provides
a foundation for estimating how much of our growing G-NP would
remain available for the great domestic priorities, even if we found it
necessary to continue to bear international burdens rising very sub-
stantially above current levels.
The specific goals for the great domestic priorities set forth in this
model budget are based upon extensive study of needs among the
various priorities depicted, reconciled in terms of feasibility with my
equilibrium model as a whole.
I have always felt that exercises of this type, regardless of the
quantitative differences between my estimates and those which others
might make, are at the very heart of the original intent and cur-
rent potentials of the Employment Act of 1946. After 22 years of
experience under that act, it has become increasingly lamentable that
the Council of Economic Advisers has not yet substantially picked
up this prime responsibility of economics in the public service.
II. THE STRATEGY OF STABILIZATION POLICY
I do not feel impelled to comment extensively upon this chapter of
the CEA report. The analysis contained therein is rather thin and
sketchy, and the chapter in my view achieves neither its avowed in-
tent at the outset~ nor its revealed purpose as it proceeds.
Sel/praise may be slight recommeindation
At the outset (p. 58), the intent is decla.red to deal "with some of
the lessons of recent economic experience as they apply to the cur-
rent and foreseeable problems facing the economy." One would expect,
from this declaration of intent, a penetrating analysis of mistakes in
policy from the viewpoint of equilibrium analysis. For there certainly
must have been some serious mistakes in policy, in that a real annual
rate of economic growth of above 5 percent during 1963-66 was more
than cut in half to a real economic growth rate of only 2.5 percent
during 1966-67.
But instead of moving ahead with the avowed intent of drawing
important lessons from experience, the chapter discloses for the most
part the revealed purpose of rendering a generally complacent and
laudatory account of how sensibly and flexibly national economic poli-
cies were adjusted to meet problems as they arose.
Wrong diagnosis and wrong cure, 1966-67
The Coimdil states (p. 68) that "as of mid-1965, there was every
reason to believe that the record of orderly progress could be extended.
The expansion was characterized by remarkable balance in all sectors
and strong forward momentum."
PAGENO="0061"
775
I challenge most emphatically this appraisal. The economy at that
time was suffering from an ominous inbalance between the rate of
expansion of investment in plant and equipment toward enlargement
of production capabilities, and the rate of expansion of ultimate de-
mand in the form of consumer spending and public outlays combined.
I had warned, at the time of massive tax reductions in 1964, that these
imbalances would be aggravated by the distorted allocation of these
reductions. I pointed out in mid-1965 that this danger was in process,
and subsequent developments have borne this. out. I: feared in mid-1965
that these imbalances would result very shortly in a period of economic
stagnation, if not recession. I still think that this was likely, but for
the unar~ticipated increase in defense spending after mid-1965, which
deferred for a time, but did not avert, the economic stagnation which
set in during 1966-67, and which may well afflict us again during at
least a part of 1968.
But the Council misses the point that this sharp increase in defense
spending saved us for a short while from the consequences of failure
to c~bserve the evolving disequilibrium. Instead, the Council says (p.
68) that "the task of stabilization was immensely complicated by the
sharp increase in defense spending after mid-1965."
Proceeding from that initial error, the Council thus goes on to say
(p. 69) that "the need for restraint and policy was clearly recognized
in the beginning of 1966." In this connection (pp. 69-70), it cites as
effective and wise measures during 1966 the rise in payroll taxes for
social insurance at an annual rate of $6 billion, the reversal of excise tax
reductions, suspension of the tax investment credit, cutbacks in Federal
spending, stringent limitations on net new issues by Federal agencies,
and monetary restraints. It appears to me that, at this point in its
analysis, the Council is proudly claiming credit for the utilization of
national economic policy to help bring on a period of serious and
very costly economic stagnation. The Council does not attempt to
appraise how much worse the stagnation might have been, or whether
it would have been converted into absolute recession, if the still-sought
tax increases had been enacted by the Congress when first asked for.
Still w~rong, 1967-68
Others have made similar mistakes before, but at times have learned
from them. Not so the current OEA. Although hardly any recognized
forecaster even now looks forward to the restoration of maximum
resource use in the very near future, and although most of them expect
that the second half of 1968 will be weaker than the first half of 1968
(which is no roaring boom), ~EA is still plugging away for large
tax increases.
Combined with this reiterated cry for higher taxes now, OEA argues
once again that, if the tax increases are not granted promptly, there
will be need for resort to a more restrictive monetary policy, which
would evoke serious imbalances in the economy (p. 84).
Failure to resist wayward monetary policy
During the past year and even now, I have been led to suspect
that CEA has recognized that large tax increases are not called for
on economic or related grounds. Rather, it may be that CEA is
fearful that, if the administration accepts a fiscal policy more con-
PAGENO="0062"
776
ducive to the needed acceleration of economic growth, the Federar
Reserve System would negate that choice by its "independent" mone-
tary policy, and that an unwise fiscal policy (i.e., tax increases now)
might do less damage than an even more unwise monetary policy..
If this be the case, I feel that CEA should vigorously challenge the
prevalent monetary policy of the Federal Reserve Board during the
past decade or longer, instead of yielding supinely to it, thus making~
the "independent" monetary authorities veritable arbiters of both
fiscal and monetary policy.
But perhaps it may be too charitable to assume that CEA is still
clamoring for tax increases only in order to avoid something even
worse. It may be closer to the truth that CEA does not have that
top-priority commitment to maximum resource use, optimum economic
growth, and minimum unemployment which the times call for-and.
is instead erecting concern about inflation into a blinding obsession
rather than treating it as only one facet of a well-rounded national
economic policy. This comment brings me to the next chapter of the
CEA report.
III. THE PROBLEM OF RISING PRICES
This long chapter in the CEA report, crammed with statistical
trees which make it hard to see the forest, tends to corroborate the
view that the Council's preoccupation with the one problem of rising
prices prevents it from viewing in just proportions the problems of
the economy at large. And ironically, this narrow preoccupation mili-
tates against correct diagnosis and cure of the inflationary malaise
itself.
Pr'ice trends are `not very meaning fvl per se
First of all, it is palpably erroneous to regard a stable price level,.
or even avoidance of inflationary trends in the magnitudes that we
have recently experienced them, as objectives at all comparable with
the objectives of optimum economic growth and maximum resource
use. The real wealth of nations, and their ultimate capacity to prosper
and advance and even to protect themselves against external dangers,
reside in their ability to increase the output, and particularly the
output per capita, of the goods and services which minister to prac-
tically all material requirements and aspirations.
The Council would undoubtedly admit, in purely logical discussion,,
that its concern about rising prices is prompted by its belief that
these interfere with or threaten attainment of the more ultimate objec-
tive states above. But CEA's virtual assumption that rising prices'
necessarily have these unfortunate consequences are rooted more in
theoretical preconceptions than in empirical observation of the Ameri-
can economic performance over the decades. This is clearly revealed
by the nature of t.he Council's discussion (pp. 97-102) of why rising'
prices are bad.
For example, the argument is advanced that inflationary trends
redistribute income regressively, and impose a "cruel tax" upon those
who need help most. This would be an impregnible position, if price
trends were unaccompanied by other trends. But the fact is that they'
are, and these other trends may outweigh the significance of price
trends. Certainly, the millions currently unemployed are infinitely
PAGENO="0063"
777
worse off than if programs were adopted to provide them wit.h jobs,
even if (contrary to my thesis as set forth below) these programs
caused prices to rise somewhat faster thanthey otherwise would. And
economically speaking, the unemployed certainly need help most,
especially in that excessive unemployment today and its side products
are by far the largest explanation of poverty.
Indeed, in view of the certainty that income distribution in the
United States has shifted most progressively during periods of full
employment and maximum resource use, the Council's argument that
such periods tend to accentuate inflation is in conflict with its argument
that. any accentuation of inflation redistributes income in ways which
hurt most those who need help most. Insisting that rising prices
are an unmitigated evil, without delving deeper, is itself a cruel tax
imposed by those who should know better upon those who know less.
Price trends significant in their impact upon resource and income
allocation
All empirical observation reveals that economic progress and
social justice depend, not upon whether prices are stable (or rising or
falling within moderate bounds), but rather upon what is happening
to the allocation of economic resources and the distribution of in-
come under any specific price trends. The greatest economic debacle
we ever witnessed started almost four decades ago, after 7 years of
a remarkably stable price level, except for falling farm prices. This
debacle occurred primarily because of the failure of wage and farm
income, under a stable price level, to keep up with our growing na-
tionwide ability to produce. In other words, gross maldistribution of
resources and income took place despite a stable price level.
Either a stable or a rising or falling price level within moderate
bounds may be conducive to or destructive of that economic equilibrium
at reasonably full resource use which benefits almost all. The Council,
instead of pandering to misconceptions about rising prices per se,
should turn its attention to the real task of resource and income anal-
ysis, and this calls for use of an equilibrium model which CEA is not
yet revealing in its interpretation of economic developments nor in
its development of policies for economic adjustment.
CEA exaggerates inflationary trends
The Council would enjoy much more freedom in moving toward
the really core problems, if it did not so ardently fan the flames of
exaggeration about recent or current price inflation.
During the 50-year period 1917-67, consumer prices in the United
States advanced at an average annual rate of 1.9 percent. This period
included the great depression era during 1929-39 at one extreme and,
at the other extreme, the hyperinflation during some years of World
War II and reconversion and 1 year during the Korean war.
During 1957-67, the most recent 10-year period, the average annual
increase in consumer prices was 1.7 percent; and during 1962-67, the
most recent 5-year period, the average annual increase in consumer
prices was 2 percent. Thus, allowing for problems of statistical
measurement and price-quality issues of immense difficulty, the move-
ment toward rising consumer prices during the most recent 5 years has
not been any greater than during the past 50 years. And during
PAGENO="0064"
778
these 50 years, we have made the greatest record of economic progress,
and perhaps also the greatest strides toward social justice, which have
ever occurred anywhere in human history. (See my chart 16.)
Price trends in an international perspective
Viewed in an international perspective, our price record is even bet-
ter than the above data would indicate, and utterly inconsistent with
the furor during recent years to the effect that we must achieve greater
price stability to maintain our worldwide competitive position.
During the 10-year and 5-year periods ending with 1967, the average
annual increases in consumer prices in the United States were 1.7 and
2 percent, respectively. Meanwhile, the respective trends in the
United Kingdom were 2.9 and 3.3 percent; in France, 4.9 and 3.2
percent; in Germany, 2.4 percent and in Italy 3.5 and 4.7 percent; in
Canada, 2 and 2.7 percent; and in Japan, 4.3 and 4.5 percent. The
relative trends with respect to industrial prices have been closer, but
even as to these, we have in general retained a considerable advantage,
quite apart from issues of quality of product. (See my chart 16.)
A higher growth rate and less `unernploym~ent do not in~port nwre
inflation
But even if I were wrong with respect to all of the foregoing-
which I am sure I am nOt-the point remains that the Council has
clung obstinately to the prevalent but untenable thesis that there is a
strong and ineluctable positive correlation between the rate of real
economic growth and the amount of price inflation, and that a lower
rate of unemployment measured against the civilian labor force tends
to induce more rapid price increases, especially when the rate of
economic growth and the level of employment press close to reason-
ably full resource utilization. Verily, it is this thesis which propels
the Council toward its adamant failure to espouse the more expansion-
ary economiO policy when we now so sorely need.
Since 1953 especially, I have been making continuous studies which
challenge this prevalent thesis, and have recurrently brought them
to the attention of this committee, top officials in the executive branch,
economists throughout the Nation, and the public at large. I shall
now attempt to do so again.
During 1955-58, when our average annual rate of real economic
growth wa*s only 0.2 percent and when the average unemployment
rate was 5.1 percent, the average annual rate of increase was 3.1 percent
in consumer prices, 2.2 percent in wholesale prices, and 1.5 percent
in industrial prices.
In vivid contrast, during 1960-67, when the average annual rate of
real economic growth was 4.6 percent and when the unemployment rate
(although averaging 5.1 percent for the period as a whole) was
brought down from 5.5 percent in 1960 to 3.8 percent in both 196~ and
1967, the average annual increase was only 1.7 percent in consumer
prices, 0.7 percent in wholesale prices, and 0.7 in industrial prices.
Further, the relatively high rate of price inflation during 1960-67
came with the approach and advent of economic stagnation. During
1966-67, with the rate of real economic growth decliningvery severely
to 2.5 percent and the unemployment rate no lower than in 1966, the
annual increase in consumer prices was 2.8 percent, and in industrial
prices 1.5 percent. (See my chart 17.)
PAGENO="0065"
779
It should be noted that even table 10 on page 97 of the CEA Report
supports my thesis, at least to the extent of showing no discernable
positive correlation between the unemployment rate and the amount of
price inflation. For example, during January 1947 to January 1949, the
average unemployment rate was 3.8 percent, while the average annual
increase in consumer prices was 5.5 percent, and in wholesale prices
5.7 percent. But during September 1950 to November 1953, the aver-
age unemployment rate was much lower at 3.2 percent, while the aver-
age annual increase in consumer prices was much lower at 3.2 percent,
and in wholesale prices much lower at 1.3 percent.
These trends during the past 15 years may not be entirely conclu-
*sive. But they are certainly sufficiently conclusive to torpedo the prey-
alent thesis, which sacrifices a higher rate of economic growth and
further reductions in unemployment on the false altar of the insup-
portable presumption that these essential objectives, if vigorously pur-
sued, would net more price inflation.
The trend indications that higher rates of economic growth and low-
er levels of unemployment are in fact anti-inflationary have not been
fortuitous. There is a ready explanation for them. In an economy char-
acterized in large measure by administered price decisions, there is a
pronounced tendency to attempt to compensate for inadequate ex-
pansion of volume (i.e. low economic growth) by initiating price in-
creases so as to increase per unit returns. This tendency is accentuated
by the profit-maintenance or profit-advance targets which have now
become common practice among most key enterprises of very large size.
My conclusions in this direction have been strengthened, not only by
general economic observation, but by more particularistic examina-
tion of relative volume-expansion and price-increase trends in many
key industries during the past 15 years.
Some of the other price increases which have been most conspicu-
ous in recent years, such as in medical care and housing costs, have no
appreciable relationship to the rate of economic growth or the rate of
unemployment. The usually rapid price increase in these areas have
been due to deficiencies in aggregate supply and its distribution, which
in turn has been due to those very deficiencies in public outlays which
have been inflicted in a futile effort to stop inflation thereby.
Another reason why inadequate economic growth exerts upward
pressure upon prices is this:
The most recent manifestations of rising prices, according to the
Council's analysis, have been mainly of the cost-push rather than the
demand-pull type. In this connection, the Council (pp. 111-116) ap-
pears almost to exonerate most of the rising industrial prices during
1967, on the ground that rising costs have resulted from the very sharp
decline in productivity gains accompanied by maintenance or enlarge-
ment of customary wage-rate gains.
But why did the rate of productivity gain fall so dismally in 1967?
There was no diminution in technological advance, nor in labor and
managerial skills. The rate of productivity gain fell so dismally be-
cause of underutilization of employed labor, in consequence of the de-
cline of the real economic growth rate from more than 5 percent to only
2.5 percent.
90-191-68-pt. 3-5
PAGENO="0066"
780
It follows, quite contrary to the thesis of the Council and entirely
in accord with my thesis, that the cost-push aspects of inflationary
pressures would be overcome most effectively by restoring the actual
rate of product.ivity gains to levels consonant with the potential pro-
ductivity gains representing tec.lmoiogical trends, in which event
real wage-rate increases tends to lag behind, rather than to exceed,
productivity gains (see again my chart 8). And the surest, in fact the
only, road toward this achievement would be to lift the economic
growth rate to 5 percent or better.
o they flaws in CEA cost-push thesis
The line of reasoning which I have just advanced should not be
misinterpreted to imply acceptance on my part of the CEA implica-
tion that recent price increases in the main have been caused, or even
justified, by cost push. Even rising labor costs do not justify price
increases, when both profit margins a.nd aggregate profits are as high
in general as they still remain. And the Council is woefully derelict,
and even biased against labor, when it does not accompany its cost-
push analysis with any real examination of relevant profit levels.
Further, as I demonstrated earlier in my analysis, over any period
of recent years long enough to be highly meaningful, real-wage rate
gains have lagged seriously behind productivity gains, which disposes
entirely of the legitimacy of the cost-push argument in general (see
again my chart 8).
Of course, the Council in table 18 on page 123, and in its reassertion
of the "productivity principle" on page 126, reaffirms its position that
productivity trends would need to be related to changes in current
(money) wage rates rather than to changes in real wage rates, if cost-
push inflation is to be reasonably restrained.
This position is indefensible, not only on institutional and social
grounds, but also on narrower economic grounds. Viewed as a factor
in maintenance of adequately expanding consumer purchasing power,
real wage buying power should rise pro tanto with productivity gains
which represent a physical concept of growth in output per hour per
worker. Indeed, this is at least half of the whole rationale of linking
productivity gains and wage-rate gains. Even from the viewpoint of
business costs, which is the other half of the rationale adjusting wage-
rate gains to price increases which have already occurred (in addition
to allowance for productivity gains), can hardly be regarded as
exercising large legitimate cost-push pressures. For all experience
indicates that, to the extent that the price level has already risen, in-
dustrial concerns in general have already attained their fair share,
or more than their fair share, of the increases in dollar incomes re-
sulting from these upward price movements. They are therefore not
unjustly hurt, when asked to make cost-of-living adjustments.
Comment on new Cabinet Committee on Price StabiZity
It is too bad, in a way, that a Council which has been so deficient in
its entire analysis of the inflationary problem should now come for-
ward (pp. 127-128) in support of a new Cabinet-level committee to
deal with this problem. There may be nothing wrong per se in estab-
lishing still another committee. But committees caimot take the place
of analysis, and they cannot forge viable policies without analysis. I
maintain that it is essentially CEA's job, within its own confines, to
PAGENO="0067"
781
set itS own thinkhouse in better order, instead of asking others to help
support its misconceptions.
It is especially discouraging to note that this new Committee is
charged in effect with promoting policies to avoid so-called cost-push
inflation, but is not charged with responsibility to consider the role of
wages in maintenance of adequate expansion of consumer purchasing
power. Nor, in the Council's summary of the functions of this new
Committee, is there any mention of the fact that (as so abundantly
demonstrated by the failure of the price-wage guidelines) any attempt
to deal with prices and wages, without getting into the insep'arate
problems of profit and investment levels and needs, is entirely rnequi~
table on its face and a dangerously astigmatic approach to the whole
problem of needed economic adjustments.
Directing the `attention of such a group, without sufficiently broad
economic perspectives, to segmental problems such as wage and prices,
tends toward futility, and toward mere reiteration of the established
positions of labor and management.
Coordinating pub'ic and p'rivate economic policies
I have long recommended, and now recommend ag~ain, an entirely
different kind `of voluntary labor-management-Government instru-
nientality. The starting point, however, should be development, by
CEA itself, of a long-range and short-range budget of our economic
resources and the economic and social ends which they should serve,
quantified in nature, and integrated with the development of policies
attuned to the achievement of the revealed goals. This is what I have
at times called an American economic performance budget, and this is
no less than the Employment Act of 1946 really calls for.
With this starting point, labor and management and other groups
could be brought into consultation with the `CEA on a regular `basis.
This would confer upon these private and voluntary groups (without
delegating to them the public responsibilities of CEA) a sense of real
participation in the development of the `analysis and policies ultimately
embodied in the Economic Reports of the President and the annual
reports of the Council of Economic Advisers.
Such a process would improve the formulation of public policies,
and promote understanding and support of such public policies by
private economic groups. It would `also help these private groups to
achieve a larger consensus in their own voluntary development of
policies and programs geared more closely to the public interest, more
consistent with concurrent public policies, and more in line with the
great purposes of the Employment Act.
This, I suggest, is the kind of creative relationship between public
and private efforts `which can steer between excessive centralization
in the Federal Goveriiment and excessive reliance upon uncoordinated
private adjustments.
IV. EcoNo~IIo DEVELOPMENT AND INDIVIDUAL OPPORTUNITY
This chapter of the CEA report discusses a wide range of very
important problems, `such as trends in the distribution of population
and their significance, the demography of poverty, and problems of
housing, education, and health.
PAGENO="0068"
782
Interplay of econonv~c and social problems
From the time when I became a member of the Council of Eco-
nomic Advisers in 1946, I made manifest my view that those problems,
sometimes looked upon as "social" or "noneconomic," are just as much
economic problems (though social also), and just as much within the
purview of the Employment Act of 1946, as problems of business
investment, tax policy, or price levels.
In fact, all programs which involve use of substantial goods and
services, and are very substantially affected by economic and financial
decisions, are clearly within the purview of the Employment Act.
Such programs, therefore, should be made part of something equiva-
lent to an American economic performance budget or a freedom
budget. This equivalent, as I have long insisted, should be at the core
of the Economic Reports of the President and the annual reports of
the Council of Economic Advisers. For these reasons, I am in accord
with the inclusion of some discussion of these programs within the
current CEA report, as well as in its previous reports.
.lneffectval CEA treatment of economic-social issues
But I feel compelled to criticize most vigorously the scope and qual-
ity of the treatment of these problems in the current CEA report.
This treatment does not rise to the mandate and challenge of the Em-
ployment Act of 1946. A comparable treatment (aside from such mat-
ters as the details figures on the demography of poverty, which are
available in other Government publications), could be prepared in the
main by assembling a paste-up of recent articles on these subjects in
well-known or semipopular magazines and journals.
Admittedly, the Council exhibits modesty in these matters. Its report
says (p. 139):
There does not appear to be available at the present time an adequate amount
of information to answer [these important questions], nor even a satisfactory
analytical framework within which these answers can `be approached in a toler-
ably scientific fashion.
My view is that `these matters are quite as susceptible to treatment
in depth as others of far lesser importance which CEA does attempt.
to deal with in depth, and that their superficial treatment by CEA is
without justification.
For example, the Council attempts to set forth (pp. 140-142) some
general clarification of problems of migration and redistribution of
population within the United States. These stated general principles
are that migration helps as well as hurts; that local problems are out-
croppings of our more basic national problems; that the most explosive
issues in urban areas relate to racial antipathies and prejudices; that
we suffer from artificial and obsolete political boundaries; that there
should be more study of the per capita cost of service relative to popu-
lation density; that there should be more study of alternative local
distribution of private production and consumption; and that trends
in technology can alter the course of some of the foregoing develop-
ments. It seems to me that any competent graduate student could
include this highly generalized statement of principles in a master's
PAGENO="0069"
783
thesis; the CEA adds little if anything to its exercise of responsi-
bilities by listing them.
The issue of what the Federal Government can afford
While there are many vitally important issues in connection with
serving more adequately our great domestic priorities, the outstanding
single issue today is how much the Federal Government through the
Federal Budget can and should contribute toward these great priori-
ties, in view of the high and rising international burden. This tower-
ing problem should be dealt with in depth in any mature CEA report
at this time, on both a short-range and a long-range basis. It is a
problem incomparably more important than the balance-of-payments
problem, to which the CEA report turns with such meticulous
diligence.
The issue of urban-n~ral balance
it is true that there is a lot that we do not yet know about the
optimum-distribution pattern of population within the United States,
and there is a lot that we will never know about it. But we do know
that, since World War II, the Federal Government has adopted
changes in the national fann program which have contributed to the
brutal deflation of a farm income, in the thought that by thus driving
millions of people off the land we would cure the "overproduction"
of farm commodities and thus bring per capita farm income toward
reasonably parity with that of others. We do know now that this policy
has failed miserably. We do know also that the assumption among most
economists and others that the farmers driven off the land would find
employment and improved living standards in urban areas has been
proved to be a tragic illusion; major portions of them have found un-
employment and despair in the cities, and have aggravated almost
every one of the critical problems in our ui~ban areas.
The intensity of these profound maladjustments would never have
come to pass, if the CEA during the past 15 or 20 years had recognized
that the so-called farm problem was and still is one of our greatest
overall economic problems and if, correspondingly, the CEA had rec-
ognized that farm policy should have had and still should have quite
as important a place in the work and reports under the Employment
Act as price-wage policy or fiscal policy.
The issue of the war against poverty
Another salient example of CEA default is that the treatment of
poverty in the current CEA report adds little or nothing to what can
be found in other current sources. Yet, broadly conceived, what to do
about poverty is the most pressing and stupendous problem involved in
the management of our economic resources, and especially with respect
to the role of the Federal Government in the deployment of these
resources.
For the past 10 years at least, the work under the Employment Act
should have focused very largely upon policies directed toward the
liquidation of poverty. And during the several years since the official
declaration of the war against poverty, taking into account the dis-
illusions and dangers which have arisen in the course of that war, the
PAGENO="0070"
784
CEA above all others should be now offering to the Nation an expert
economic analysis of what, as experience indicates, the central elements
in a more effective war against poverty should be.
Tragically, this task of evaluation is being left far too largely to
sociologists and psychiatrists, artists and amateurs, in the popular
magazines, instead of being taken up by the one agency which, in terms
of its potentials and responsibilities, should be moving most actively
and fruitfully on this whole front.
The issue of housing and urban renewal
Treatment of t.his subject in the current CEA report adds nothing
much to what can be obtained from the reports of other agencies, nor
very much to what those reasonably informed about the subject already
know.
It has long been my view that, in view of technological and other
trends, almost half of the whole problem of achieving and then main-
taining maximum employment and reasonably full resource use during
the decade ahead converges on what we do about the housing problem
and the entire range of related problems, mainly in our urban areas.
These same problems are intimately connected with the whole poverty
problem.
This being the caseS, I submit that CEA. should long since have com-
menced to do effectively what can hardly be done anywhere else in the
full perspective of the whole economy that is, develop a long-range
budget relating to the amount of investment required for urban renewal
during the decade ahead, accompanied by analysis of the respective
roles of the Federal Government and others in the supply of these
needed levels of investment. Lacking this, we are even now moving
ahead with "new" types of approaches to housing and urban renewal.
Some of these are sufficiently far from the realities of what can be ac-
complished, through the identified means, that we face the prospect of
some of difficulties which have arisen from our excessively optimistic-~
or rather excessively careless in terms of the means employed-initia-
tion of the war against poverty.
Minimum ambits of (YEA responsibility
Even if the Council, for one reason or another, feels that it cannot
yet attempt the kind of Performance Budget which I think it should,
there is something else that the Council can and should do at once. It
should select one or two of the specialized but vast problems which I
have identified above, and aim within a year to make a really significant
contribution toward that problem in its next report. This would be of
immense service to the President, the Congress, and the country. That
essential service is rendered in pretense only by the yearly reiteration of
discussions at t.he level of those contained in Chapter IV of the current
CEA report.
V T~ INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY
This chapter of the CEA report contains a competent and through
treatment of the problems of our international balance of payments, in
terms of the viewpoint toward this problem which the Council has
PAGENO="0071"
785
maintained for a number of years. My criticism is not of how the mem-
bers of the Council deal with this problem as they see it; instead, I offer
a fundamental challenge to their way of looking at this problem.
Balance-of-payments problem grossly exaggerated
I submit that a grossly exaggerated importance has been attached to
our unfavorable balance of payments. This, in turn, has been respon-
sible in substantial measure for many shortcomings in policies re-
lated to the domestic economy. In the name of dealing with the balance-
of-payments problem, the Council itself has admitted on occasion
that it was inhibited from recommending domestic policies which
otherwise would have been desirable to expedite the rate of economic
growth, and reduce further the level of unemployment. In the name
of dealing with the balance-of-payments problem, interest rates have
been elevated unconscionably, to the great detriment of economic prog-
ress and distributional justice.
An unfavorable balance of payments, running recently at an an-
nual rate in the neighborhood of $4 billion, comes to only about one-
half of 1 percent of our $800 billion GNP. During recent years, our
unfavorable balance of payments, averaging annually somewhere in
the neighborhood of $2 billion, has been somewhere within the range
of one-third of 1 percent of GNP during these years. I venture the
prophesy that, within a decade, most economists will look back upon
the fear and trembling which has been generated by an unfavorable
balance of payments in these magnitudes in somewhat the manner that
most economists today look back to 35 years ago, when a national
debt about one-twelfth the size it is now was regarded with fear and
trembling by so many.
We should run a much larger unfavorable balance of payments
I believe that it would be in our own national interest to average,
during the decade ahead, an unfavorable balance of payments several
times as large in ratio to our GNP as the ratio today. Upon observa-
tion of its internal structure, it appears that our unfavorable balance
of payments results substantially from the fact that our business
system is a large net investor in other parts of the world. It seems to
me that this is good for the U.S. economy; and it is only natural that
our dominant world position, in terms of wealth, production, and
capital accumulation, should result in our being a very large net in-
vestor in other parts of the world. Moreover in this connection, I be-
lieve that restraint upon the free flow of this type of investment is
tantamount in many respects to the placement of tariffs and other
prohibitions upon the international exchange of goods, a policy which
we have not favored in general over the decades, and declared further
against in the trade act several years ago.
Our currently avowed intent to reduce or even erase our unfavor-
able balance of payments is sorely neglectful of the economic circum-
stances and needs of other countries. It is inconsistent with the scores
of billions of dollars which we have spent since World War II, to
help these other countries avoid economic retrogression and make eco-
nomic progress. For by definition, to the extent that we reduce our
PAGENO="0072"
786
unfavorable balance of payments by x billion dollars, some of other
countries somewhere in the world must simultaneously have their bal-
ance-of-payments positions made less "favorable" by the same a~
billion dollars. And when we look around the world, it is abundantly
clear that these other countries would be far more hurt by this change
than we would benefit by it, even if we take the position (which I
maintain to be wrong) that we would benefit by it at all.
To take some obvious examples, a reduction of $1 billion in our un-
favorable balance of payments would do us only a bagatelle of good,
compared with the damage that would be done to an economy like
that of England if its balance-of-payments position were unfavorably
affected in this same amount. If we were to reduce our unfavorable
balance of payments by cutting back on our investments or aid to a
country like India, the damage done to that country would be in-
comparably greater than any benefit accruing to us. This is quite
apart from the equally valid point that our international economic
and political policies are correctly based upon the proposition that
it is in our own vital interest to speed the economic and social progress
of the most highly populated democracy in the world.
I therefore think that the CEA, instead of participating in the
fears and warnings about our unfavorable balance of payments,
should embark upon a sophisticated analysis of the productive role
of U.S. investment in other parts of the world, if wisely guided, look-
ing a decade ahead. What part of our GNP should flow in these di-
rection? Where should it be encouraged to go? Insofar as this might
have some unfavorable side effects, how can countermeasure be de-
veloped which do not throw out the baby with a bath?
Our international goods and services account
The comments which I have made above are particularly pertinent
to these portions of our international accounts which relate to the
exchange of goods and services. On these, we have run in most years
a very large surplus, perhaps too large in that we should always
remember that commerce and goods and services between nations
must run along a two-way street. These considerations make it par-
ticularly undesirable that we should seek to improve our overall
balance-of-payments position by such restrictive measures as those
under consideration, such as application to American travel over-
seas. Even if this were not true on purely economic grounds-which
I believe it is-placing restrictions upon opportunities for our people
to make contacts with other peoples in their own lands is funda-
mentally inimical to the advancement of friendship and peace among
nations.
It seems to me also that, just as it is natural for us to be large net
investors in other parts of the world, it is also natural for the Nation
with by far the highest per capita income in the world to expect that
its own people will enjoy a much higher standard of living, in terms
of worldwide travel, than is enjoyed by others. While we should en-
PAGENO="0073"
787
courage others to come visit the United States, it seems to me utterly
unrealistic and undesirable for us to anticipate that there will be as
many others economically able to enjoy vacations in the United
States as there are citizens of the United States economically able to
enjoy vacations elsewhere. We should regard our "unfavorable bal-
ance" in this aspect of it as a national asset, not a national liability.
Methods of accounting need recasting
Our unfavorable balance of payments, as recorded, is due in part
to failure to distinguish adequately between short-range and long-
range aspects, such as investments which are minus items in the short
run, but which will yield plus items later on in the form of interest
and amortization. The unfavorable balance is also due in part to
commingling items, without differentiating among those which are
liabilites and others which are assets in a true economic sense. Our
huge investments in military operations overseas, even while essential
to our national security, are a burden upon the U.S. economy, be-
cause almost all military outlays are nonproductive or even waste-
ful in a purely economic sense. But our investments in economic
enterprises overseas, or our repayable loans to others, are of an
entirely different color. Yet both, under current methods, are treated
as minus or unfavorable elements in our balance-of-payments ac-
counts.
The unworkability of settleiment in gold
The real problem confronting us resides, not in our unfavorable
balance of payments, but in the use of gold as a method of settlement.
This is an unworkable anachronism. As the gold supply of the world is
increasing at the rate of only about 1 percent a year, its use is not suit-
able in connection with the need for an expansion of international
transactions in the range of 4 to 5 percent a year on the average. The
use of gold simply means that some nations will not have enough of it
to meet their essential obligations; and it is foolish and shortsighted for
us to think that we would be in the clear if could change things around
so that we had enough gold, or more than enough, while others were
caught seriously short. For any nation which is caught dangerously
short will need to resort to other measures of a restrictive or retaliatory
nature (as we, to a degree, are doing now). These measures inflict far
more damage than they are worth.
In concert with others, we should move as rapidly as possible, and
with great vigor, toward improved international machinery for the
adequate and flexible financing of international transactions. Resort-
ing, for these purposes, to realistic currencies backed by the real wealth
and integrity of nations, we should stop being impaled on a cross of
gold.
The current CEA report intimates correctly that we should do this,
but still clings excessively to traditional approaches to the entire
balance-of-payments program---approaches no longer relevant nor
creative.
PAGENO="0074"
788
CoM~rm~rs ON EcoNoMlo REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT
I shall not comment extensively upon the Economic Report; of the
President, because to do so would be redundant of what I have said in
detail about the annual report of the Council of Economic Advisers.
After all, the two documents are consistent.
The aspect of the President's Economic Report which seems most
significant to me, and which I attribute basically to the Council of Eco-
nomic Advisers for reasons subsequently to be stated, is that the points
of emphasis in the President's report are so wide of our most imperative.
current problems under the Employment Act of 1946.
On the day that I am transmitting this st.atement to the Joint Eco-
nomic Committee-March 1, 1968-there appeared in the press of
the Nation the magnifica.nt and compelling report of the President's
National Advisory Commission on Civil Disorders.
This report on civil disorders states most emphatically that the
causes and manifesta.tions of these disorders tower above and affect
all of our other domestic problems, and indeed threaten the destruc-
tion of basic democratic values if not dealt with promptly and fully~
The report states further that by far the most imperative task of all is
to wipe out the excessive unemployment among vulnerable groups.
This is clearly tantamount to a finding that the total rate of unem-
ployment in the United States is now dangerously high-a point which
I have made all along. For it is manifest that unemployment among
vulnerable groups cannot be cut by more than a million-preferably
by close to 2 million-without corresponding reduction in the nation-
wide rate of unemployment, unless the vuhierables are to take jobs
away from others.
This brings to the forefront a. truly amazing situation. The reduction
of unemployment is fundamentally the task of economic policy, i.e.,
the use of economic resources. although it is fraught also with social and
human implications, as are all of our important economic policies. The
prime responsibility of the Council of Economic Advisers is to focus
upon maintenance of "maximum" employment. Yet the Economic Re-
port of the President makes only casual reference to the towering prob-
lem of reducing unemployment further, and does not even list this task
specifically and pointedly in the ordered priorities of action which he
sets forth on pa.ge 8 of the Economic Report.
This omission is clearly due to the fact that the Council of Economic
Advisers, bot.h last year and this year, has written reports based upon
the thesis that we are enjoying maximum employment now, or at least
that policies designed to drive unemployment substantially lower
would cost more than they would be worth because of alleged inflation-
ary consequences. Thus. `there is an absolute dichotomy between the
view of the civil disorders report that unemployment is our top eco-
nomic problem, and CEA's view that curbing inflation is our top eco-
nomic problem, reflected in the President's second-ordered priority
that "we must slow down the wage-price spiral."
PAGENO="0075"
789
The only way to employ more people, whatever may be the reasons
for their unemployment, is to spend money to employ them. And spend-
ing money to employ the unemployed increases pro tanto the volume
of production and the GNP. Thus, the finding of the civil disorders
report that we must drive unemployment sharply downward is equiv-
alent to the finding that we must substantially accelerate the rate
of economic growth, far beyond the level forecast and espoused by the
Council of Economic Advisers. But, responsive to the advice of the
Council, the five priorities of `action cited `by the President do not even
mention the task of accelerating economic growth.
The first-ordered priority of the President is that "first and fore-
most, we must take the necessary steps to put our fiscal affairs in
order." There is nothing wrong with our fiscal affairs, except as `an
indication of the state of `our economic affairs. If the Federal budget
deficit has become too large, this is mainly in consequence of the
drastic economic slowdown during 1966-67, with slight prospect of
complete economic restoration in 1968. And the only way to reduce
that budget deficit, without damaging the economy, is through a vig-
orous speedup of the rate of economic growth. Thus, the focus of the
President's report upon reducing the budget deficit per se, rather
than upon reducing the deficit of excessive idleness of plant and man-
power in the American economy, reflects abandonment by the Council
itself of what used to be regarded as the hallmark of the "new
economics."
The third-ordered priority of the President's report is that "we
must push forward vigorously to restore equilibrium in our interna-
tional acounts." For reasons which I have stated fully in the body of
my analysis, this, on all economic and social scores, should be a low
priority indeed, compared with the problem of economic growth and
employment. Here again, the upsidedown priorities of the Council
have unfortunately led the President into serious error.
The fourth- and fifth-ordered priorities of the President's report
are to "deal more effectively with our urban problems," and to "con-
tinue the struggle to expand the opportunities available to every citi-
zen." These are assuredly top-priority objectives. But they are not
sufficiently implemented either by the analysis or the. programs offered,
and indeed cannot be adequately implemented without prime reliance
upon maximum employment and optimum economic growth.
It is always an interesting question whether the Council is restrained
by the independently arrived at views of the President, or whether
the President is restrained by the advice he received from the Council.
Based upon my experience .and observation, I believe the latter dom-
inantly to be the case now. I believe that the Council this year has
fallen down on its job, and thus has done a disservice to the President,
all of whose impulses and instincts and motivations would move him
in the right direction if the Council, in economic terms, helped more
to point the way.
PAGENO="0076"
790
BASIC U.S. ECONOMIC TRENDSD I953~967
Nesdod in
Average Annual Growth Rates in GNP~Constcnt Doflars View of New
Technology
and Labor
Period of Force Growth
Post World Peace and
W~r I Limited Waft Allowina for
Post Great Pont Korean War Restoration After
Depression and of Reasonably Restoration of
World Warn Full Resource Reasonably
Eras U Full Resource
se Une
4 ~t 4.6% 5.0% 46% 5.0% 3.0%
~
1922-29 l947~50 1947-53 1953-66 195360 960-67 963-67 966- 1967-1975 1970-1975
937 I
~ij~T~J
Unemployment as Percent of Civilian Labor Force~
j: ~4i~ Millions of Unemployed in Parentheses
(6.8) (671
(6.11 jrue
(4.6) 14.6) ~ 9.0!~ 8% 15.1) ," Unemployment
13.2) 6.9% 61% ~ ~16~i 1~1.5$ 6.7% 144) (4.4) ~ Concealed
49~/ ~O9i~ ~O7. 1.8 : ~ ~ ~ 5.6%' __-`Unempioyment~'
_______________________________________________ mpl
(953 955 957 96) 963 (964 965 (966 1967 Unemployment
-"Seasonally adjusted annual rate.
2/ln deriving these percentages, the Civilian Labor Force is estimated as the officially reported
Civilian Labor Force plus concealed unemployment. Full-time unemployment of 2.9% and true
unemployment of 4.1 % would be consistent with maximum employment.
Production"Gop"As Percent of Maximum Production
In Billions of 1965 Dollars Parentheses
(81.7)
12.9% (765)
(549)
1)2.71
()7) 2.5%
953 1955 1957 1961 (963 (965 (966 1967
PAGENO="0077"
791
LARGE NATIONAL ECONOMIC DEFICITS
DURING PERIOD §953-1967
Dollar Items in 965 Dollars
OTHESE HAVE LED TO LARGE LOSSES
TO ALL ECO~O~HC GROUPS
TOTAL
NATIONAL
PRODUCTION
(64/F)
$78! Billion
Too Low
MAN YEARS
OF EMPLOYMENT
36.3 Million
Too Low
PRIVATE
BUSINESS
INVESTMENT
(mci 4/of Foreign)
$146 Billion
TOo Low
PRIVATE
AND PUBLIC
CONSUMPTION~~
$635 Billion
Too Low
AVERAGE
FAMILY INCOME
$10,250
Too Low
WAGES AND
SALARIES
m
$535 Billion
Too Low
UNINCORPORATED
BUSINESS AND
PROFESSIONAL
INCOME
q1'.Md~
$67 Billion
Too Low
1'lncludes personal consumption expenditures plus government (Federal and, State and local
expenditures $5B2and $53 billion, renpectively).
PAGENO="0078"
TOTAL NATIONAL
PRODUCTION(G.NR).
PRIVATE CONSUMER
SPENDING
Up
63.5%
1~6 1967
1961-1967 Down
0.9%
PERSONAL DIVIDEND
INCOME
Up
51.0%
1961-1967 1966-1967
LABOR INCOME
GROSS PRIVATE
INVESTMENT
(INC. NET FOREIGN)
Up
35.9%
9.2%
CORPORATE PROFITS
(&IVA)
Up
43.7%
.~~.j196~6-i967
1961-1967 Down
.3%
792
COMPARATIVE GROWTH IN VARIOUS ASPECTS OF
U.S. ECONOMY I96fr'~967-~
(Uniform Dollars)
Up
34.6%
Up
33.3%
r~
Up
2.5%
~
1961-1967 1966-1967
GOVt OUTLAYS FOR
GOODS AND SERVICES
Up
2.8%
1961-1967 1966-1967
PRIVATE INVESTMENT
IN PLANT AND EQUIPMENT
Up
37.9%
r~
Up
Hl~.
1961-1967 1966-1967
PERSONAL INTEREST
Up INCOME
700%
1961-1967 1966-1967
WAGES AND SALARIES
Up
38.4%
1961-1967 1966-1967
TRANSFER
PAYMENTS
Up
45.5%
1961-1967 1966-1967
FARM PROPRIETORS'
NET INCOME
Up
5.0%
~ 1966-1967
Up
39.6%
Up
4.9%
~T..
1961-1967 1966-1967
I96t-I967 L:~±~
Down
6.0%
1/Preliminary data for 967.
Source: Dept. of Commerce, Office of Business Economics and CEP.
PAGENO="0079"
793
THE GROWTH IN CONSUMER SPENDING
HAS BEEN MUCH TOO SLOWgl953 1967
Rates of Change in 1965 Dollars
Needed Rate of Growth
AND THE LAG IN CONSUMER SPENDING
DOMINATES THE TOTAL GAP IN GNP
Billions of 1965 Dollars
962 963 964 965 1966
Actual Rate of Growth
76.5 726
PAGENO="0080"
704
INADEQUATE CONSUMPTION GROWTH STEMS
FROM INADEQUATE iNCOME GROWTH
Rates of Change in 1965 Dollars
~ Total Private Consumer Spending ~ Total Personal Income After Taxes
6.7°I~
1961-1962 1962-1963 1963-1964 1964-1965 1965-1966 1966-1967
THE PRIVATE CONSUMPTION DEFICIENCY OF
~565 BILLION~i953-I967 REFLECTED
A $682 BILLION INCOME DEFICIENCY
Billions of 1965 Dollars
Excess
Deficiercyin in Consumer - Deficiencyin Defictencyin - Deficiercyin Deficiency - Deficiencyin
Prixote Interest - Personol Consumer - Consumer Income sTases Poid - Consumer Income
Consumption Payments11 Outtoys Soving After Toxes by Consumers Before Toxes
$17
includes personal transfer payments to foreigners,whicls is a minimal amount.
PAGENO="0081"
795
SHARE OF FAMILIES IN TOTAL FAMILY INCOME
BY QUINTILES, 1947, 1953, 19600and 1966
Money Income)
43
LOWEST SECOND MIDDLE FOURTh FIFTH
FIFTH FIFTH FIFTH FIFTH FIFTH
SHARE OF UNATTACHED INDIVIDUALS IN TOTAL
INCOME OF UNATTACHED INDIV., BY QUINTILES,
1947, 1953, 1960, and 1966
1947 1953
Data: Bureau of the Census.
FIFTH
FIFTH FIFTH FIFTH FIFTH FIFTH
90-191-68-pt. 8-6
PAGENO="0082"
`I
Deficiency in
- - Other Consumer
~ncomes
Deficiency in
Total Consumer
Income Before
Tones.
796
DEFICIENCIES IN WAGES AND SALARIES
ARE LARGE SHARE OF DEFICIENCIES IN
TOTAL CONSUMER INCOMES BEFORE TAXES
Billions of 965 Dollars
1953-1967
Ann. Avg.
35.7
45.4
Deficiency in
Wages and
Salaries.
PAGENO="0083"
797
RATES OF CHANGE ~N GNP,
PRODUC1iVITY~ & WAGES & SALAR~ESe ~9~O~9S7~
GNP, and Wages and Salaries in Uniform Dollars
GNP I
4.6%
11
`4.
/
1960-1967
PRODUCTIVITY, & WAGES & SALARIES
TOTAL PRIVATE NONFARM ECONOMY
1960-1967 1960-1966 196E-1967
Wages Output Wages Output Wages
and and and.
Salaries Salaries Salaries
PER MAN-HOUR PER MAN-HOUR PER MAN-HOUR
PRODUCTIVITY, & WAGES & SALARIES
TOTAL MANUFACTURING
1960-1967 I960-l96~3 1966 1967
2.7%
~
Output Wages
and
Salaries
PER MAN-HOUR
2.8%
Preliminary 1967 data.
PAGENO="0084"
798
PRICE, PROFIT, INVESTMENT, AND WAGE
TRENDS DURING 1960'- 1967
Percentage Change,l960-I967
~ Prices!! ~. Profits afterTaxes~~ ~Investment in Plant and Equipment~' ~Wage Rates ~1
UP
86.5%
UP
42.5% UP
UP 3O.8%~' .P~,
ALtëIft~1/ JLH ri
`JData:U.S.Dept.of Lâbor,wholesale commodity price indexes.
V Data: Federal Trade Commission-SecurIties and Exchange Commission.
~/Data:U.S.Dept.of Commerce and Securities and Exchange Coi+~mission.
~J Data:U.S.Dept.af Labor, Bureau af Labor Statistics; Average hourly
earnings of production workers.
~"Estimated for 967.
~`Data for 1967 are far first three quarters at annual rate, not seasonally adjusted.
UP
UP UP
83 6%~854%
TOTAL
MANUFACTURING
CHEMICALS
and ALLIED PRODUCTS
ELECTRICAL
MACHINERY
IRON and STEEL
MOTOR VEHICLES
and EQUIPMENT
PAGENO="0085"
799
TRENDS IN PRODUCTIVITY FOR THE
ENTIRE PRIVATE ECONOMY, 1910- I967~'
Average Annual Rate of Growth in Output per Man-hour
for the Entire Private Economy
/ND/C4T/4t~A CL ORE CORRELATION BETWEEN
PROOUCT/V/TY GROWTHRATEECONOM/COROWTHRAT,f
A/P'DEXTENTOFUT/L/ZAT/ONOFAVA/LABLERESOURCES
4.0%
~
1947'-I953 953-1961 1961-1966 1966-1967
Period of Period of Recessions, Period of Period of
High Growth and Very Low Growth, Reasonably High khry Low Economic
Reasonably Full and Increasing Gruwth,but Still Growth
Resource Use Economic Slack Substantial
Economic Slack
IND/CAT/EQA OE4'ERALLYAc~ELERAT/N~PRODUC77V/TY
CROI'/TH RATE
0.4%
1910-
1920
Jiproiiminory 1967 data.
Sourco: Dcpn.of Labor estimates relating to man-hours worked (Eotabliohment basis).
PAGENO="0086"
U.S. ECONOMIC GROWTH RATES,I922~I967,~'
AND NEEDED RATES, l967~I975
FOR REASONABLY FULL RESOURCE USE
Average Annual Growth Rates in GNP,Cons~ant Dollars
Pcst World Worn Period of ~tognaliori Renewed
Growth Period Limited War Period Growth Period
Growth Period
4.7%
4.7%
i~iJ
800
Post World Won
GrowTh Period
~
1922-1929 1947-1950
Mont Recent Most Recent
Fcur Years Year
2.5%
NEEDED IN VIEW OF NEW TECHNOLOGY
AND LABOR FORCE GROWTH
Allowing for Restoration After Restoration
of Reasonably of Reasonably
Full Resource Use Full Resource Use
5.5%
~iIITLIII
963-1967 1966-1967 967-1975 1970-1975
estimate is preliminary.
Source: Basic Data from the Office of Business Economics.
PAGENO="0087"
801
HOW MUCHWE HAVE TO WORK WITH,I967~I975
BASED ON ECONOMIC GROWTH PROJECTIONS
Total National Production (GNP) in Billions of EY. 1969 Dolla,s
~ Higher Projection
V/////////////A Lower Projection
`-9'
/71,817
7/
1,262
820
E~4~~fi
~
~
~I14III!I~~
iY~V~VA
V'%
~402~j
GNP
1967
246
~227~
GNP
Excess of
Excess of
Excess of
1975
975 GNP
Over
967 GNP
Average Annual
GNP,1968-l975,
Over 1967 GNP
Aggregate
GNP,1968-l975,
Over Aggregate
if 967 GNP
Persisted,
1968-1975
PAGENO="0088"
802
Dollars Items in Billions of FY. 1969 Dollars
~ Higher Projection ~ Lower Projection
TRUE UNEMPLOYMENT TOTAL PRODUCTION
(In Millicns of Man -Yearsl ._~i'~
p
970 975 ~ $442.0
~-n--~ ~
Down Down
2O~~ 8 T
FULL-~lME REPORTED I $40201
UNEMPLOYMENT
970 975 $1600
970 1975
PUBLIC OUTLAYS FOR
GOODS AND SERVICES
(Calendar Years)
~\ FEDERAL
Up $15.7
Up
______ $19.3
1970
THE ~`FREEDOM BUDGET~ 1970 AND 1975 GOALS
EMPLOYMENT5 PRODUCTION5AND SPENDING
PROJECTED FROM LEVELS iN 1967
Single Projection!' _______
EMPLOYMENT
(In Millions of Mon-Years)
Up
3.0
970 1975
CONSUMER SPENDING GROSS PRIVATE
INVESTMENT
Up ;:- :.- )lnc.Net Foreign)
$281.2 -~`T~ Up
~ ~ Up
1970 1975
$254.1 ~
Up
~ $40.0
$108.3 :......
H:.. RESIDENTIAL
STRUCTURES
$1008 $270 $4~o
970 975 1970
1970 1975
STATE AND LOCAL
Up
$52.8
"The single projections relate to goals of such high priority that they should not be reduced even if only
the lower goals for GNP are attained. In that event,lower priority objectives shnu!d be modified accordingly.
PAGENO="0089"
803
THE "FREEDOM BUDGET~2 MA~NTMNS BALANCE
OF PUBLIC AND PRIVATE RESPONSIBILITIES
I~b~.O
1222.0
/ I
:~.>~.:::...~j~:7945f
7674
980.0 989.0
1116
100.0% l00.0~/~
628 630
F~Jt
-Total GNP
Private Consumer
Outlays
Gross Private
- Investment
(including net foreign)
Public Outlays
- at all levels for ~
goods and services
967
Actual
Lower Higher Lower Higher
970 975
Goal Goal
1'Public outlays are of such high priority that they ore projected identically for the lower and
higher GNP goals with modticotions of ether aools accordingly.
PAGENO="0090"
804
GOALS FOR A FEDERAL BUDGET GEARED
TO ECONOMIC GROWTH AND PUBLIC NEEDS
l969,fiscal year; goals for 1970 and 975, calendar years
All figures in fiscal 1969 dollars.!!
NATIONAL DEFENSE,
SPACE TECHNOLOGY, &
ALL INTERNATIONAL
At
Total Per %of
Expend. Capita GNP
Year (BiL$) (5) (%)
l969~' 89.515 440.53 lO.2~
1970 93.000 448.65 9~C
1975 100.000 446.83 7.92
ALL DOMESTIC
PROGRAMS
Total Per
Expend. Capita
Year (BiL$) (5)
I969~' 96.547 475.13
1970 107.000 516.16
1975 150.000 670.24
PUBLIC ASSISTANCE;
LABOR, MANPOWER, AND
OTHER WELFARE SERVICES
ALL FEDERAL OUTLAYS
Total Per ¶6 of
Expend. Capita GNP
Year (OiLS) (5) 1%)
l969~'l86.062 915.66 21.39
1970 200.000 964.79 20.22
1975 250.000 1117.07 19.81
¶6 of
GNP
1%)
11.10
lo.8a
11.89
ECONOMIC OPPORTUNITY
PROGRAM
if
~
71
HOUSING AND
COMMUNITY
DEVELOPMENT
J~~~Li1
~
AGRICULTURE; AND
NATURAL RESOURCES
~
~
Total Per
Expend. Capita
Year (2iL$) (5)
I969~' 1.997 9.83
¶6 of
GNP
(%)
0.23
Total Per
Expend. Capita
Year (Bil.$) ~$)
2.784 3.70
¶6 of
GNP
(%)
0.32
Total Per ¶6 of
Expend. Capita GNP
Year (Bil. 5) (5) ~
l969~" 8.099 39.86 0.93
970 3.500 16.88
0.35
1970 5.500 26.53
0.56
1970 12.000 57.89 1.21
1975 4.600 21.45
0.38
1975 7.000 31.28
0.55
1975 13.750 61.44 1.09
HEALTH SERVICES
AND RESEARCH~~
EDUCATION
Total Per
Expend. Capita
Year (Bil. $1 ($1
l969~' 4.699 23.12
1970 9.800 47.27
1975 12.000 53.62
1~~
Total
Expend.
Year (Bil. $1
l969~' 4.895
1970 5.500
975 8.500
¶6 of
GNP
(%l
0.54
0.99
0.95
Per
Capita
($1
24.09
26.53
37.98
Total Per
Expend. Capita
Year (BiL$) Cs)
I969~' 6.276 30.89
1970 9.200 44.38
1975 12.250 54.74
¶6 of
GNP
1%)
0.56
0.56
0.67
¶6 of
GNP
1%)
O7Z
O~93
0.97
Dollarx of purchasing power opparontlycoxomed in Prexident's fiscal 1969 Budget.
.21 Administrations Proposed Budgetcs of Jan.29, 966. Beginning with fiscal 1969,the Budget includex the
immense trust funds,nel lending,and cfher relalivoly minor new items.
.2.' Exclusive of the Medicare trust funds,which are included in all dxmextic programx,but including Medicaid.
PAGENO="0091"
805
SELECTED PRICE TRENDS, I9I7~I967
U.S. AND SELECTED OTHER COUNTRIES
AVERAGE ANNUAL RATES OF CHANGE
Up
Up 2.8%
2.0% ~4
~
Up U
7% Up t.s~
LI~..
Up Up
2.0% l1;~,, 7%
~LIL~
1947-1967
1957-1967
1962-1967
~..::: Consumer Prices
Wholesale Prices
UNITED KINGDOM
FRANCE
GERMANY
~~rJ2
Up
4.9%
fLi~~1i
957-1967 962-1967
1957-1967 1962-1967
1957-1967 1962-1967
ITALY
CANADA
JAPAN
1957-1967 1962-1967
Up
Up 4.7%
fLit
Down Down
~l5LDi
19571967 1962-1967
Up
Up 5.4%
43%
fI:~fL#~~
1957-1967 1962-1967
-0.2% -0.2%
~.. Consumer Prices ~ Wholesale Prices Fixed Non-Residential Investment
Price Deflator
Up
1.9% Up
1-I 1.0%
I ~ na.
Up Up
6% .8%
n.a.
1917-1967 1927-1967
~-Vholcsale prices of finithed goods (wholesale prices of basic materials increased 0.1 percent a year during (957-67
and .6 percent a year during 1962-'67.)
211967 data cr3 preilminary estimates based upon first nine to eleven months.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics;Off ice of Business Economics;and the United Nations; Department of Labor;
end Organicotisre for Economic Cooperation and Deve(spment.
PAGENO="0092"
806
RELATVVE TRENDS IN ECONOMIC GROWTH
UNEMPLOYMENT,& PRICES9 I952~I967~'
E:::: Consumer Prices ~ Wholesale Prices Industrial Prices
3.1%
2.6'425'/ 25% 2.8%
_fl~fl~'~
-02%
1952-1955 1955-1958 1956-1958 1958-1960 1960-1967 1966-1967
Average Annual Rates of Change
~\. Total National Production in Constant Dollars, Average Annual Rates of Change
~*** Industrial Production,Average Annual Rates of Change
Unemployment as Percent of Civilian Labor Force,Annual Averages*
7.7%
6.0%
5.l% 5.1%
46/~r43/iO
-3.2'/~
1952-1955 1955-1958 1956-1958 1958-1960 1960-1967 1966-1967
-1./Preliminary 967 data.
~These annual averoges(as differentiated from the annual rates of change) are based on full-time officially
reported unemployment measured against the officially reported Civilian Labor Force.
Source: Dept. of Labor, Dept. of Commerce, 8 Federal Reserve System.
PAGENO="0093"
CUNA INTERNATIONAL, INC.
By J. ORRIN SHIrE, MANAGING DIRECTOR
As our economy nears the end of the first quarter of 1968, with many
of the same inflationary factors in force as in the last half of 1967,
the primary concern of our Nation's credit union movement is infla-
tion. By slowly eating away at the value of their small savings and
by increasing the cost of practically everything they buy or want to
buy, inflation robs credit union members of every extra penny they
have earned through their daily practice of thrift.
Inflation encourages families to act directly opposite to credit
union teachings. Why save, if the dollars you save immediately begin
to lose their full value? Why bother to shop wisely, if the dollars you
save by shopping wisely are lost to inflation during the time it takes
you to do your shopping? Why exercise restraint in buying on credit,
if, by buying now and paying later, you can pay off your debts in dol-
lars of lesser value?
Attempts to curtail inflation solely through monetary policies also
hurt credit union members by seriously affecting their credit union's
operations. Tight money causes higher interest rates. Higher interest
rates increase credit union operating costs. Increased operating costs
must be passed on to the credit union's members, through higher in-
terest charges on their loans and/or lowered dividend rates on their
savings. Higher interest rates also force credit unions to operate in a
tight cost-price squeeze. By law, the maximum income a credit union
can earn on a loan is 1 percent per month on the unpaid balance, or a
true annual interest rate of 12 percent. Higher interest rates force
credit unions to pay higher dividends to their members in order to
compete with the interest rates being offered by other institutions,
and to pay higher costs for borrowed money. Either one pushes credit
unions into a tight squeeze between the maximum income they can
earn on their loans and the interest rate they must pay to continue to
attract savings or to borrow. Because credit unions are dependent al-
most entirely on member savings for their operating capital, they are
severely affected by the tight money-high interest rate effects of anti-
inflationary monetary policies.
The credit union movement supports all efforts to hold inflation
within reasonable bounds. Rather than relying solely on monetary
practices, however, it supports the full utilization of all methods, in-
cluding necessary fiscal measures. In addition, we would urge con-
tinued research into monetary polices so as to bring about a greater
refinement in their implementation in such areas as timing and co-
ordination of action.
Proper steps in this direction will, we believe, do much to help this
Nation put into practice the same wise management of its resources as
we expect of our credit union members. As a matter of fact, the Pres-
(807)
PAGENO="0094"
808
ident might very well have been talking about our Nation as a credit
union officer would talk about his credit union members when he said
in his Economic Report: "Our achievements demonstrate that we can
manage our economic affairs wisely-that we can make sound choices."
We hope the Congress will assist in making those sound choices.
While our primary concern lies in the area of domestic policies to
fight inflation, we recognize fully the interdependence between our
domestic and international economic affairs. They are-and should
be-permanently and inextricably intert;wined. Stabilization of the
delicate equilibrium in our international affairs is as important to credit
union members, as citizens of the United States, as is the achievement
of the best domestic balance possible to assure economic growth with-
out inflation. Any imbalance in any part of our economic programs
and policies adversely affects some segment of our credit union
membership.
Credit unions are deeply involved in our Government's foreign as-
sistance program on the international level and in the war on poverty
on the national level. We seek increased participation in both of these
programs, because we feel that the credit union idea provides people-
both those living in underdeveloped countries and those living in
poverty pockets-with a lever through which they can lift themselves
to a more bountiful standard of living. The credit union movement
has invested heavily in its own programs in these areas, and it welcomes
financial assistance from the Federal Government to speed up these
programs. It also strongly supports the Government's goal of obtain-
ing greater economic assistance for underdeveloped countries from
the wealthier nations. And it supports the Government's efforts to get
State governments and the private sector of the economy to help
finance and fight the war on poverty.
As consumer-oriented membership organizations, credit unions
would be delighted to see this Congress "go down in history as the
consumer-conscious Congress." Because we have supported a strong
truth-in-lending proposal ever since the first bifi was introduced in
Congress several years ago, we would, of course, delight in seeing
Congress complete its action on this legislation early this year. We
hope the bill will be passed in the strongest form possible, covering
all kinds of consumer credit transactions.
In conclusion, we would like to point out that we have purposely
avoided taking a selfish-interest position on the President's Economic
Report. Like our Nation as a whole, the credit union movement em-
braces people and institutions in all walks of life. Our purposes like
that of the Federal Government is to serve all these people. For that
reason, we hope and trust that "This administration will never forget
that the purpose of our economy and of our economic policies is to
serve the American people-not the reverse."
PAGENO="0095"
FEDERAL STATISTICS USERS' CONFERENCE
This statement is submitted on behalf of the Federal Statistics
Users' Conference whose membership is composed of organizations
from all sectors of the economy. Our members have `a common interest
in the development of adequate, reliable, and timely statistics from
Federal sources.
The conference appreciates the opportunity to express its views re-
garding certain statistical materials which provide much of the in-
formation upon which the President's Economic Report and the report
`of his Council of Economic Advisers is based. This vast storehouse of
information is used `by private as well as public planners and policy-
makers in making important decisions that affect the course of the
economy. It is important for all of us that our actions and policy deci-
sions are based upon the best measures of the economy that it is possible
to obtain.
We consider these two documents and the Federal budget of such
importance to our members, `and others, that for the third straight year
we recently sponsored a 1-day conference at which t'hese documents
were `discussed by James S. Duesenberry, member of the Council of
Economic Advisers and Charles J. Zwick, Director of the Bureau of
the Budget. Our purpose is to help raise the level of understanding
of the public policy issues involved in these documents and to assist
users of them in making more effective use of the information they
contain.
The United `States is fortunate in `having `available a vast quantity
of demographic, economic and social statistical data. The appendix
to the Economic Report `of the President contains 90 statistical tables
relating to income, employment, and production. Those concerned
with policy `decisions and the carrying out of Government programs
take `our wide data `base for granted and freely utilize the data in
analyzing problems and as a guide to determining positions or actions.
However, little attention or concern is given by the majority of these
data users to certain inadequacies or weaknesses in some of our statis-
tical data `and the need for improving them.
We were pleased to note that President Johnson, in identifying
five "longstanding goals" in `his recent budget message, included the
following: "Providing improved statistics to aid business, labor and
government in sustaining economic growth." In his Economic Report,
the President said:
Accurate, comprehensive, and timely statistics are essential `to the development
of so'und economic policies by government, `business, and labor. Our economic
statistics are the best and most comprehensive in the world, but they can be
and need to be further improved. The costs will be exceedingly small relative
to the benefits.
More specifically, the Economic Report, on pages 91 and 92, out-
lines its program for improvements in economic statistics. We respect-
(809)
PAGENO="0096"
810
fully urge that the Joint Economic Committee give careful considera-
tion t.o these recommendations and specifically support them in its
report.
~ believe the Economic Report has properly and carefully spelled
out the need for these improvements which is stated as follows:
That need is accentuated by the current state of the economy and the current
aims of policy. Sustaining expansion close to the economy's potential growth path
is a more difficult task than that of merely attempting to moderate wide swings
in output. In a slack economy, it was often sufficient for the indicators merely
to point in the right direction. Now more accurate information about the speed
of the movement and the distance from full employment is called for. The need
for early and careful diagnosis of the extent and location of inflationary dangers
also requires comprehensive information about the price, cost, and productivity
performance of various sectors of the economy. Capital markets and especially
the mortgage market have taken on a key role, calling for more comprehensive
data and indicators. The current importance of our international trade position
places added emphasis on the need for better information about export and
import prices.
We agree with and recognize the need for economy and establish-
ment of priorities in connection with Federal programs. The 10 items
proposed for improvement in the area of economic statistics are indeed
priority items and the Federal Statistics Users' Conference has, in the
past, urged and supported the majority of these items. We further
agree with the Economic Report in its statement that each improve-
ment has been recommended because it meets these tests: "that it assist
current policy formulation, that the proposal be capable of rapid
implementation and that its costs be moderate, given the present budg-
etary stringency." The total program of improvements will involve
an annual budget cost of about $2.5 million which is approximately 2
percent of the total 1969 budget estimate for current statistical pro-
grams.
The fiscal 1968 budget included appropriation requests for certain
statistical programs that would meet the needs of some of the priority
items included in the 1968 Economic Report. Unfortunately, the Con-
gress failed to approve these requests. The range in costs of these denied
programs was from $120,000 to $200,000. We agree with Congressman
Curtis who has said that the budget treatment of our statistical agen-
cies is "one of the best examples I know of being penny wise and pound
foolish." We further agree with the Economic Report that the small
investment of $2.5 million for its recommended improvements "could
make a critical difference in guiding decisions involving billions of
dollars."
We wish to emphasize that expenditures for the total statistical
programs of the principal statistical agencies is small in comparison
with the total governmental administrative budget expenditures or
the administrative budget expenditures exclusive of military expendi-
tures. In 1967, statistical expenditures were about one-tenth of 1 per-
cent of the former and about one-quarter of 1 percent of the latter.
The proportion has never been higher than this.
~\T~ earnestly urge the committee to support the following 10 key
items in the President's program for improvements in economic statis-
tics:
PAGENO="0097"
811
(1) Nonnwnufacturing industries-additional information on em-
ployment, wages, investments, sales, and other indicators for trade,
services, and finance that will bring the data closer to the coverage and
quality of the data now available for manufacturing industries.
(2) Construction-an enlarged effort to collect more accurate and
more timely information on the value of construction activity.
(3) Business investment-i~xtension of coverage of the plant and
equipment survey to all nonf arm industries, and collection of separate
quarterly data on business investment in plant, as distinguished from
equipment.
(4) International price competitiveness-a better comparison of
price trends of internationally traded goods.
(5) Improved price inderes-covering individual industries sys-
tematically, emphasizing actual transactions rather than quoted prices,
and developing methods to make more adequate allowance for quality
changes in our measurement of prices.
* (6) Quarterly data on national product by industry-a new eco-
nomic tableau that will ultimately provide comprehensive information
on output, labor input, prices, and productivity by major sectors on a
quarterly basis.
(7) Manufacturing inventories-r~xpanded coverage and increased
detail.
(8) Mortgage flows and commitments-a comprehensive system of
quarterly and ultimately monthly statistics.
(9) Bank deposits-more adequate information on ownership and
turnover to be collected by the Federal Reserve; and
(10) Securities markets-new information on purchases and sales
by institutional investors, and more comprehensive and accurate data
on naw issues and retirements.
The Joint Economic Report of last year pointed out some of our
deficiencies and needs in the statistical area. It emphasized that high
priority should be accorded to research in the area of prices and price
indices and also that Government agencies should push rapidly ahead
with the development and regular publication of industry data on
output, productivity, prices, capital, labor, and incomes. The minority
views also stressed the need for greater effort to improve existing
economic statistics. We hope that the Joint Economic Report for 1968
will place particular emphasis on the need for improvements in our
statistical data and specifically spell out major priority areas for im-
provements which might even go beyond those outlined in the
President's program.
In its recent report on the "Coordination and Integration of Gov-
ernment Statistical Programs," the Subcommittee on Economic
Statistics of the Joint Economic Committee pointed out that the
most significant increases in statistical programs in recent years have
been for labor and demographic statistics, and particularly in the social
area such as health, welfare, education, and poverty. Recognizing that
this is appropriate, the subcommittee emphasized, and we agree, that at
the same time, major advances in eco~nomic statistics must not be ne-
glected. The problem, as the subcommittee pointed out, is that "Too
often it is difficult to engender support for general statistical programs,
90-191-68-pt. 8-7
PAGENO="0098"
812
since they do not appear to have a specific and immediate impact on
particular individuals or groups."
In this connection, we think particular attention should be given to
the budget, programs and value of the work of the Office of Business
Economics. This agency that prepares the national income estimates,
the balance-of-payments accounts and other vital economic statistics,
has operated on a budget ranging from $2 million in 1963 to an esti-
mated $2.9 million in 1968. Four modest improvement programs pro-
posed for 1968, totaling $372,000, were denied by the Congress. The
four programs denied called for: (1) beginning the preparation of
real GNP by industry on a quarterly basis, (2) strengthening the anal-
ysis of determinants of business investment, (3) personal income by
States on a quarterly basis, and (4) initiating work on estimates of the
total tangible capital stock of the United States. These certainly are
priority items for improving the national income and business
financial accounts.
The Joint Economic Committee has made some invaluable contri-
butions leading to improvements in the Federal Statistical System. In
its 1967 Economic Report, is directed the Subcommittee on Economic
Statistics "to look into the possibilities of a truly integrated system
providing genuinely comparable statistics consistent with and meshed
into an overall system of economic statistics, including the Federal,
State, and local governments." The Report of the Subcommittee on
Economic Statistics on the Coordination and Integration of Govern-
ment Statistical Programs stated "Investigations by this subcommit-
tee and by others have indicated that further significant improvements
in our statistical services depends upon a higher degree of integration
and coordination of our statistical programs. Indeed, there are strong
indication~ that this is the aspect of the statistical system where prog-
ress is needed most." (Emphasis supplied.)
In view of the above, we strongly urge that this committee, in its
report, recommend that additional resources be provided the Office of
Statistical Standards of the Bureau of the Budget to enable it to be
more effective in carrying out its responsibilities for the coordination
and improvement of our statistical system. Total budget for that office
was $649,000 in 1967 which was 1.7 times greater than in 1948. On the
other hand, total obligations for current statistical programs in 1967
was five times greater than it was in 1948. The OSS budget in 1968
declined to $632,000 and the 1969 budget request calls for $693,000.
This budget increase does not include the addition of any new
employees.
The Office of Statistical Standards also is responsible for minimizing
reporting costs to the Government and the public under the Federal
Reports Act of 1942. It is averaging about 2,600 actions annually on
report forms submitted for approval. Despite its broad and important
responsibilities, this office is operating with a staff of 35 persons-23
professional and 12 clerical employees. In 1942 it had 42 employees
and in 1959 it had 37 employees. We would certainly question whether
the current staffing of the OSS of the Bureau of the Budget is suffi-
cient to enable it to exercise the maximum potential for the Government
and the public.
PAGENO="0099"
THE MACHINERY AND ALLIED PRODUCTS INSTITUTE
By CHARLES W. STEWART, PRESIDENT
THE NEW GOVERNMENT PROGRAM To IMPRoVE THE U.S. BALANCE-OF-
PAYMENTS POSITION: A CJirnQUE
SUMMARY
1. Essentially, the administration's program for improvement of our
international balance of payments consists of controls-controls on
foreign travel, foreign investment, and bank loans. Moreover, a cen-
tral fallacy in the new program is its failure to recognize that all ele-
ments of foreign trade, including direct investment abroad, are parts
of an integrated whole and the same is true of the various elements of
the balance of payments. The institute regards any program grounded
wholly in the "controlist" philosophy as unsound in principle. Such a
program would:
a. Lack incentive and rely on compulsion.
b. Ignore long-range effects.
c. Impose intolerable burdens on individuals and businesses.
d. Provoke foreign reprisals.
e. Gravely erode personal freedoms.
f. Probably be unworkable.
2. The institute opposes travel restrictions proposed by the admin-
istration because they would:
a. Fall with unequal effect on citizens of varying means.
b. Fragment tax treatment of passenger transportation.
c. Establish a method of taxation that is poorly conceived,
highly arbitrary, and nearly impossible to comply with.
d. Represent an unjustifiable intrusion on a fundamental right.
e. Call forth foreign countermeasures.
f. Probably, in `the net, fall short of the fiscal goal which they
seek to attain.
3. Similarly, we are opposed to the principal feature of the admin-
istration~s balance-of-payments program-the system of mandatory
controls on foreign direct investment. In our judgment, these controls
focus on the wrong target, are likely to become permanent in effect,
substantially reduce business' ability to compete in international trade,
represent an invitation to protectionism, tend to obscure long-standing
domestic fiscal disorder which substantially affects our balance-of-
payments difficulty, and constitute an extraordinary assertion of Ex-
ecutive authority without congressional approval. The system of man-
datory investment controls is so structured as to:
a. Adversely affect U.S. exports.
b. Produce widespread inequity by reason of the `base periods
chosen.
(8 13)
PAGENO="0100"
814
c. Harm most those U.S. direct investors who responded most
effectively to the Government's entreaties under the voluntary
balance of payments program.
d. Provide no incentives for individual efforts to improve the
balance of payments.
e. Raise the near certainty of foreign reprisals.
f. Impose a crushing burden of administration on government
and business alike.
4. In the light of conclusions sunimarized above, the institute recom-
mends that:
a. Congress not approve administration proposals for restric-
tions on travel.
b. Congress call upon the administration to either:
(1) Abandon promptly the mandatory system of controls
on foreign direct investment and return to the pre-existing
voluntary balance-of-payments program, or
(2) Rethink and restructure the mandatory system so as to
make it equitable in principle and workable in practice.
c. Congress insist upon further substantial reductions in non-
essential Govermnent spending, not only as a precondition to ac-
tion on the surtax proposal, but as a means of correcting our
balance-of-payments program over the longer term by improv-
ing our international competitive position.
d. Congress call for immediate consideration and prompt im-
plementation of measures to expand U.S. exports.
e. Congress inquire into tax aspects of the direct investment
program and other tax actions which might be taken to assist the
balance of payments. Such an inquiry should consider affirmative
measures designed to overcome the adverse effects of enforced
repatriation of earnings, to induce the repatriation of foreign
earnings not subject to the controls program and to encourage the
increase of U.S. exports.
INThODUO~oN
It is a privilege for the Machinery and Allied Products Institute
and its affiliate, the Council for Technological Advancement, to pre-
sent their views on the administration's balance-of-payments program
in connection with hearings on the 1968 Economic Report. These or-
ganizations are national in character and represent the capital goods
a.nd allied product industries. Their stake in foreign trade is extraor-
dinary. Machinery exports are the largest single category of manufac-
tured exports from the United States; in 1966 capital goods exports
reached a level of $8.83 billion. Moreover, these industries have a very
substantial interest in private investment abroad, in licensing, sub-
contracting, and other arrangements necessary to maintain a. strong
position in world trade.
Based on the experience of these industries and in reference to cer-
tain of the issues which will be discussed in our presentation, we should
like to emphasize at this point that no private organization and no
governmental program, whether the latter is drawn in the form of
a control or an incentive, can afford to ignore one central fact about
PAGENO="0101"
815
foreign trade. To achieve, sustain, and improve a company's or an in-
dustry's position in international trade, the approach must be on a
wholly integrated basis, integrated in terms of exports, private in-
vestment, licensing, subcontracting, etc., and also integrated in terms
of the world, whether the countries are developed, or at some inter-
mediate stage in industrial development. No industrial organization
or governmental program in the face of this irrefutable fact of life
can attempt to segment or splinter the total foreign trade effort. As we
shall develop, this is precisely the central blunder of conception im-
plicit in the administration's approach to balance-of-payments cor-
rection particularly as reflected in the foreign investment controls an-
nounced on January 1, 1968.
Perverse effect on exports.-Subject to later, more detailed, treat-
ment, let me emphasize a.t this point the seriousness of the perverse
or counterproductive character of the foreign investment controls and
to some degree the proposed restrictions on travel. In `brief the problem
breaks down as follows:
1. There will be an immediate adverse effect on exports from
the United States flowing from the direct investment controls.
This effect will enlarge at the intermediate stage and grow very
seriously in the longer run. It is documented by Government
studies that there is `a very direct relationship between private in-
vestment abroad and exports, it being estimated that approxi-
mately 25 to 30 percent of exports from the United States are tied
to foreign affiliates of U.S. companies. Also when you affect the
growth, viability, and flexibility of those foreign affiliate opera-
tions there will be an immediate adverse effect on exports from
the United States, and as just indicated that adverse effect will
grow in intensity.
2. Certain elements of the structure of the control program also
will affect exports adversely, particularly rules governing open
account transactions covering merchandise transfers.
3. As to `all foreign countries affected by the controls program,
it seems probable that reduction in inflows of capital from the
United States, limitations on the growth of U.S. affiliates abroad,
and restrictions on the flexibility of their management will in
turn `affect the economic growth of the host countries and in turn
their importing capability. It is our judgment that this impact
will be present to some degree in all foreign countries affected by
the program but of course will be intensified in certain countries
experiencing economic difficulties such as England and Canada.
4. The controls on foreign investment will disrupt in a general
way the effective integration of individual companies' programs
involving foreign trade. The energy, the time, and the money
which will have to be expended to adjust or react to these controls,
the adverse effects that they will have on the interacting elements
of a company's foreign trade program-all of these things-un-
doubtedly will cut into the export performance of U.S. companies,
their earnings, their job-creating potential in the United States,
and their international competitive strength.
5. We have been discussing the boomerang effects of the con-
trols program largely in terms of investment controls. To some
PAGENO="0102"
816
degree at least, perhaps to a significant degree, there will be boom-
erang effects created by the controls on tourist expenditures.
There can be no question but that these restrictions, if they work,
will have an effect on the economies of foreign countries. There
can be no question that these restrictions, if they work, will affect
the capability of those countries to buy U.S. exports even if they
are in a trade surplus position.
In general, the policymakers, with reference to the direct investment
controls and to some degree at least also as to the controls on tourist
expenditures, have not thought through on the counterproductive
effects which will flow from these controls. They apparently live and
think in a dream world that involves artificial separation of trade
from capital flows into direct investment abroad. The two are
inextricably related.
PHILOSOPHY AND CHARACTERISTICS OF THE ADMINISTRATION'S APPROACH
Let us first turn to the philosophy governing the administration's
approach to the balance-of-payments difficulty which has worsened
in recent months and examine the éharacteristics of that approach.
Essentially the administration has ta.ken a "controlist" and negative
approach to the problem. For all practical purposes, the "new" pro-
gram consists only of controls, principally in the area of foreign direct
investment abroad and also in respect to tourist travel and
expenditures.
Focus on controls-absence of i'ncen.tives.-Although the President
in his message on January 1 attempted to describe a more rounded
program including certain incentives to exports and certain incentives
that might be offered to induce repatriation of accumulated earnings,
and although the special representative to the President for trade
policy, Ambassador Roth, in hearings before the Ways and Means
Committee referred to some negotiations with foreign Governments
on nontariff barriers and tax rebates on exports, there is no current
implementation of these noncontrol aspects. As developed in more
detail later, the export assistance planks referred to by the President
have been pending for years. The President's program now before the
Congress consists solely of tourism controls; moreover, when and if
the negotiations with foreign colmtries on nontariff barriers will pro-
duce anything in the way of substantial results is purely conjectural.
This is hardly an approach involving a proper balance between pun-
ishing controls and incentives. Thus it is fair to say that the private
sector, principally the business community, and the individua.l citizen
who wishes to travel abroad are being asked to carry the principal
burden of the program. We shall develop that this is paradoxical, at
least as far as the business community is concerned, `because the pri-~
vale sector has been the substantial plus factor in our balance-of-pay-
ments situation.
Absence of long-range view.-In addition to this fundamental as-
pect of the administration's approach toward the balance-of-pay-
ments difficulty, the action program that has been outlined is essen-
tially short range in its objectives although lipservice is paid to t.he
long range. The administration itself concedes the very salutary effects
PAGENO="0103"
817
on balance of payments which flow from foreign direct investment,
but it is ~erfeetly willing to restrict that foreign direct investment
for wh'at it considers to be a necessary short-term advantage. In our
view, no substantial long-range program is outlined. And the adminis-
tration is not even realistic about the disadvantages and boomerang
potential for the short term of many aspects of the control program.
Burden.-Any system of controls involves heavy bureaucracy, pain-
ful paperwork, and serious disruption of normal activity. We can look
for nothing better than the traditional incidents of control programs
from the direct foreign investment `and travel restrictions. Moreover,
inequities will abound. In respect to burden, both in industry and Gov-
ernment, I suggest that the committee examine, or possible admit for
the record, base period form FDI-1O1 with six supplements and in-
structions which has just come off the press and is due on a mandatory
basis by March 22.
Effect on freedom.-Controls `always involve serious restrictions on
freedom. In any system of democracy, even in its purest form, it is
impossible to practice complete freedom. But it has always been an
essential part of the U.S. approach to government, to its institutions,
and to all types of activity, human and institutional, to attempt to
achieve maximum freedom consistent with the public interest. Any
program which curtails freedoms must be undertaken only after the
most careful examination of need, an appraisal of the probability of
accomplishment of goals, and a determination to limit restrictions on
freedom to the bare minimum. In our judgment, the control programs
which have been launched by the administration, including the one in
effect and the one now proposed to the Congress, meet none of these
tests; indeed, they fail miserably. `They were hastily conceived, weakly
structured, and poorly rationalized. They are offered without any ap-
parent appreciation of their perverse effects both in general `and in
respect to the policy objective of improving our balance of payments.
They are offered without any real and credible assurances as to termi-
nation and without a definitive program for their supersession `by
longer range and more permanent solutions to a problem that has
plagued this country for many, many years; namely, the balance~of~
payments situation. It should be added that due consideration has not
been given to the effect of these travel controls on foreign countries
including their ability to import U.S. goods. We therefore consider
it not only appropriate but we feel an obligation to contribute to the
record of the joint committee and express our disapproval in principle
and in substance with respect to these ill-conceived programs.
Do mandatory controls work i-In the annual report of the Council
of Economic Advisers transmitted to President Johnson on January
25, 1968, under the heading "Price and Wage Policy," at page 119, the
following statement appears:
D frect controls
The most obvious-and least desirable-way of attempting to stabilize prices
is to impose mandatory controls on prices and wages. While such controls may
be necessary under conditions of an allout war, it would be folly to consider them
as a solution to the inflationary pressures that accompany high employment under
any other circumstance. They distort resource allocation; they require reliance
either on necessarily clumsy and arbitrary rules or the inevitably imperfect de-
cisions of Government officials; they offer countless temptations to evasion or
PAGENO="0104"
818
violation; tney require a vast administrative apparatus. All these reasons make
them repugnant. Although such controls may be unfortunately popular when
they are not in effect, the appeal quickly disappears once people live under them.
One need usk only the simple question: Is there any reason why
* mandatory controls as to foreign direct investment are more likely to
work in a pragmatic sense or less likely to be repugnant to our system?
It is our firm conviction that direct controls under the foreign direct
investment program are certain to fail not only for some of the same
reasons cited by the President's Council but because, as we have pointed
out separately, they are addressed to an international scene involving
the most complex elements one can imagine and having an inipact on
-foreign governments and foreign entities as well as the interrelated
factors of international commerce.
Reasons for co7mn~.enting on travel rest-rwtzons.-Obviously from
the standpoint of business spokesmanship, we believe that we can bring
more experience, more knowledge and background to the commit-tee
on the subject of the foreign direct investment controls than is true in
the case of the administration's proposals to restrict foreign travel by
Americans. Moreover, there would be an undbrstandable temptation
for an organization such as MAPI to treat the tourism proposals of
the Administration as more of a nuisance than anything else and there-
fore address ourselves only to other aspects of the administration's pro-
gram. But we reject this temptation because it is our firm conviction
that the philosophy which pervades the foreign direct investment con-
trol -program is also present in the travel proposals which are directly
before the Congress. And we do not believe that it is proper for the
Institute cavalierly to say that the international travel controls can
- be lived with and all that needs to be done is to tinker with these pro-
posals. We, therefore, submit criticisms and recommendations regard-
ing restrictions on travel and travel expenditures.
PROPOSED TRAVEL TAX AND TIGHTENING OF CUSTOMS TREATMENT OF
- TOURIST EXEMPTIONS
Before proceeding to a more detailed consideration of the proposals
before the Congress regarding travel and travel expenditures, let us
state briefly our broad conclusions as to t-hese recommendations.
As indica-ted in the introductory sect-ion of this statement, we feel
that both the program of direct private investment controls and the
foreign travel provisions reflect a preoccupation with a controls ap-
proach to an effort to improve the balance-of-payments program. The
announced goal of the administration in respect to the statutory travel
restrictions is a saving of $400 million in the balance-of-payments
account. Although $400 million is by no means a small sum, in absolute
terms it is a relatively modest goal in respect to the dimensions of our
long-standing and continuing balance-of-payments problem. More-
over, it is our judgment that the actual saving will not approach the
$400 million goal. Any technical or gross saving must be offset by t-he
cost of administrat-ion to Government which we expect to be large, by
the burden on the private citizen which will be substantial, and by the
PAGENO="0105"
819
cost to American business. One is tempted to conclude that the only
persons who will be deterred from travel as a result of these restrictions
will be the low-income groups. The businessman who must travel will
travel. The persons of reasonable to affluent means will undoubtedly
decide to pay the cost.
Even allowing for the stress of the administration on the objective
of curtailed spending rather than trip cancellation, we think the goal
will not be approached. In the net, therefore, we have a program con-
ceived in a fundamental philosophy of controlism which will not even
achieve its relatively modest goal and which will trigger a burden-
some and complex system of procedures. These procedures not only
will be annoying but they will be an encumbrance on the right of the
American people to move freely on a domestic and international level
except where the national interest absolutely makes it necessary to
place restrictions on such movements. Beyond this, as usual, in terms
of Government's approach to the solution of the balance-of-payments
problem as we see it, not enough attention is being given on an action
basis to affirmative means by which we may improve our net balance-
of-payments position with regard to travel, taking into consideration
both U.S. trips abroad and foreign trips to this country. Although
there are practical limitations, we have done far from a good job in
attracting tourists to the United States. One might conclude that it is
a case of too many studies, too many "pronouncements" and not
enough action. Let us hope that a really affirmative program will de-
velop and be aggressively implemented in connection with the report
of the White House Task Force headed by Ambassador McKrnney. It
should also be indicated that through the foreign direct investment
control program, as we have pointed out above, businessmen will be put
on a forced-draft schedule of foreign travel in order to try to compen-
sate for the mischief which the Government is creating through its
investment controls. In a word, the foreign travel restrictions aren't
worth the price which will have to be paid for creating them, admin-
istering them, and living with their restrictive burden. There must be
some more imaginative, some more affirmative, some more sensible ap-
proach to balance-of-payments improvement than is reflected in this
proposal.
Broadening of the transportation taa~.-The administration has
proposed that the current 5-percent transportation tax on domestic
air travel be extended to foreign air travel as well, and that it also
be applied in the case of transportation by water. We can see some
validity to taxing transportation by air and water th and from a
foreign destination on the same basis as that applied to purely do-
mestic air travel at the present time. So long as the tax is levied
on fares paid in the United States, `the collection problem would
appear to be relatively simple. However, we have distinct reserva-
tions about attempting to deal with the problem of transportation
taxes as part of a short-run program to cope with deficits in our
balance of payments. We think it would be far better for Congress to
consider taxes on air and water transportation in connection with
PAGENO="0106"
820
examining the current tax treatment of other types of passenger trans-
portation. At that time, basic relevant features relating to equity, rela-
tive competitive positions, financial strength, etc., can be given ade-
quate consideration within the framework of transportation facilities
and needs as a whole. For this primary reason, we suggest that the
Congress defer action on this proposal at the present time.
Tax on foreign travel expenditures.-Under the administration pro-
posals, a tax would he imposed on the daily average expenditures for
living, entertainment, and gifts, incurred by an American while travel-
ing outside the Western Hemisphere. If this daily average expendi-
ture figure exceeds $7. a tax of 15 percent would be imposed, while
any excess over $15 would be taxable at a 30-percent rate. The. tax
would purport to be temporary with a scheduled expiration date
of September 30, 1969, and it would not cover foreign travel of a
student or businessman on a trip for more than 120 days.
The traveler would be required to make a declaration of the funds
in his possession on leaving the United States. He would also have
to pay an estimated foreign expenditure tax to the Internal Revenue
Service at that time. On arrival back in the United State.s, the traveler
would again report on his cash balance as he is processed through
customs. Within 60 days he would be required to file a final return with
the IRS. and the tax would be. applied to the difference between the "de-
parting" cash balance and the "returning" cash balance pius credit
card charges and all other expenses attributable to the t.rip. A penalty
of $200 would be imposed for failure to make a declaration of esti-
mated tax and a statement as to cash balance. In addition, a penalty
of 10 percent of the underpayment of estimated tax would be im-
posed for underestimation. Any difference between the original esti-
mated ta.x and 80 percent of the actual tax shown subsequently on the
return would be considered an "underpayment" for this purpose.
In general, we think that the proposed foreign expenditure tax
should be rejected on the grounds that it is poorly conceived, highly
arbitrary, difficult to comply with, and burdensome in the extreme for
persons who have legitimate reasons to travel abroad. American in-
dustry, of course, would be forced to absorb the significant part of the
burden of these proposals that would result from the application of
the tax to American businessmen traveling abroad in the interest of
their employers for periods of less than 4 months. The implications of
this fact, of course, are significant in a number of ways: it penalizes
the American businessman and his corporate employer at a time when
he will be compelled by the foreign direct investment control program
to travel more rather than less in order to attempt to make arrange-
ments for borrowing and deal with administrative problems which will
flow from the direct investment controls program; it runs up the costs
of corporate American employers whose executives will be traveling;
and adds to the inflationary impact both domestically and in terms
of the company's ability to compete internationally.
What these proposals would evoke in the way of foreign counter-
measures is a matter of conjecture, but we believe that the foreign
PAGENO="0107"
821
reaction would likely be swift and significant. Basically, we think
that the tax would be an unjustified intrusion on the fundamental
right of Americans to travel abroad, and we think for this reason
alone the tax should be rejected.
Apart from matters of principle, we think it is clear that the
techniques of requiring travelers to report cash balances on leaving
and returning to the United States are going to cause tremendous
administrative problems for the Internal Revenue Service and the
Customs Service, and just as certainly there are going to be very diffi-
cult problems for travelers in attempting to distinguish between
those expenditures which are subject to the tax and those which are
not. Further, we request that the requirement for the final tax return
to be file.d within 60 days after the traveler's return to the United
States is wholly unrealistic in terms of whether he can be expected as
a practical matter to make a final accountino' of his expenditures so
soon after completing the trip. Clearly the and $15 tax brackets
as applied to daily average expenditures are wholly unrealistic in
terms of what it costs Americans to travel abroad with any decent
accommodations. Obviously it would be helpful to increase these dollar
brackets considerably as well as to modify other aspects of the pro-
posed procedures including the "60 day" final filing requirement, but
frankly we think that the proposed tax is so bad fundamentally that we
are reluctant to offer any palliatives which might make it endurable.
Tightening of customs exemptions.-Finally, the administration
proposes to reduce the duty-free exemption on property brought into
the United States by travelers returning from abroad from $100
to $10. A companion proposal would lower the duty-free exemption
on gifts mailed from overseas from $10 to $1. These measures would not
affect the interests of the companies we represent to any significant
degrees. However, we think that they should be rejected on the ground
that they are an integral, though an auxiliary, part of the overall
package including the foreign expenditure tax and the brOadened
transportation tax.
We urge that the entire set of proposals now under consideration
be rejected and that Congress express its desire that the administra-
tion come up with a broadened, imaginative, and "action" program
of attracting foreign travel to the United States.
THE BASIC PoLIcY DEcIsIoN ON INVESTMENT CoNmoLs
We have grave reservation about the basic policy decision to adopt
a system of mandatory foreign direct investment controls and we
also object to the structure of the control program implementing the
basic policy decision. We deal first with the basic decision. Reasons
for our opposition are sketched below and a more detailed analysis
is set forth in the supplement to this statement.
A. The wrong target.-In the net, foreign direct investment is
a favorable factor in our balance-of-payments situation when the
PAGENO="0108"
822
outflow of capital is measured against the return to the United
States of subsidiary earnings, licensing fees and royalities. In
addition there is the increase in exports attributable to foreign
direct investment. This favorable position is true both presently
and historically. The income returns on direct private invest-
ments abroad, on a cumulative basis for the last 13 years, ex-
ceed total outflow by $16 billion.
B. Gontrols breed contro7s.-Controls beget controls and once
having established a control mechanism with respect to foreign
direct investment abroad there is a grave danger that these con-
trols will be tightened further, continued for an indefinite period
of time, and lead to controls over other aspects of foreign trade.
Our concerii in this area is reinforced by the fact that there has
been a trend toward control of private decision-making with re-
spect to private investment abroad for a number of years. This
trend1 has been evidenced, for example, by the Interest Equal-
ization Tax Act, the Revenue Act of 1962, the voluntary invest-
ment controls program, banking controls, etc. Moreover, it is im-
possible to accept with any credibility the "assurances" that are
being offered currently that this is a temporary program. The
country has had experience with "temporary" programs pre-
viously adopted that are now firmly embedded in our system.
C. Protectionism~ in reverse.-The control system that has been
inaugurated represents protectionism in reverse. It is an attack
on the ability of American industry to maintain and improve its
position in international trade. It is a give-away to the competi-
tion. As for Europe, it is almost tantamount to a forced retrench-
ment of American industry's position in Europe.
In carrying on world trade in the broadest sense, American busi-
ness confronts foreign competition abroad and at home. National-
ism and restrictionism abroad have created a wide variety of trade
barriers. Regional trading blocs are growing in significance. U.S.
private investment abroad has been a critical tool in our business
effort to counter these obstacles. Now U.S. business' freedom to use
that tool is being seriously disabled. The schedule of import-export
ratios for certam capital goods products, shown on the next page,
underscore a trend which should make it unthinkable for Govern-
ment to support a mandatory investment controls program. There
is a limit to what business can sustain.
D. Invitation to protectionism.-These controls represent an
open invitation for the Congress to proceed toward protectionist
measures with respect to imports, and a similarly open invitation
to industries concerned with import problems to press for quotas
and tariff increases. The administration cannot have it both ways.
It cannot expect to adopt a restrictionist approach to foreign
investment and hold the line with regard to the theory of free
trade in other respects.
1See the MAPI statement to the Joint Economic Committee, February 28, 1967.
PAGENO="0109"
823
IMPORT-EXPORT RATIO FOR MAJOR CAPITAL EQUIPMENT CATEGORIES
llmports and exports in millions of dollars; ratios in percentj
1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966
Engines and parts:
Imports 24 35 28 49 136 195 331
Exports 490 565 694 661 676 841 975
Ratio 4. 9 6. 2 4. 0 7. 4 20. 1 23. 2 33. 9
Agricultural machines and tractors:
Imports 135 115 152 172 195 249 327
Exports 565 541 558 645 825 865 860
Ratio 23. 9 21. 3 27. 2 26. 7 23. 6 28. 8 38. 0
Office machines:
Imports 68 75 85 98 104 136 191
Exports 208 310 324 362 434 471 557
Ratio 32. 7 24. 2 26. 2 27. 1 24. 0 28. 9 34. 3
Metalworking machinery:
Imports 37 34 41 48 40 63 135
Exports 293 391 435 347 408 332 338
Ratio 12. 6 8. 7 9. 4 13. 8 9. 8 19. 0 39. 9
Textile and leather machinery:
Imports 70 82 94 93 127 157 221
Exports 180 210 200 190 228 207 227
Ratio 38.9 39. 0 47. 0 48. 9 55. 7 75. 8 97. 4
Other nonelectrical machines:
Imports 104 114 140 174 269 360 472
Exports 1,650 1,725 1,876 2,004 2,289 2,458 2,822
Ratio 6. 3 6. 6 7. 5 8.7 11. 8 14. 1 16. 7
Power machinery and switchgear:
Imports 23 28 25 22 41 67 105
Exports 250 255 264 326 356 472 488
Ratio 9.2 11.0 9.5 6.7 11.5 14.2 21.5
Telecommunications apparatus:
Imports 127 160 216 220 225 314 486
Exports 228 274 367 390 404 345 381
Ratio 55. 7 58. 4 58. 9 56. 4 55. 7 91. 0 127.6
Other electrical apparatus:
Imports 136 146 174 177 177 259 425
Exports 612 696 730 777 905 844 1,030
Ratio 22.2 21.0 23.8 22.8 19.6 30.7 41.3
Machinery, nonelectrical, total:
Imports 438 455 540 635 871 1,160 1,166
Exports 3, 386 3, 743 4, 087 4, 229 4, 860 5, 274 5, 779
Ratio 12.9 12. 2 13. 2 15. 1 17. 9 22.0 29, 0
Electrical apparatus, total:
Imports 286 334 415 419 443 640 1,016
Exports 1,090 1,225 1,361 1,493 1,665 1,660 1,899
Ratio 26. 2 27. 3 30. 5 28. 1 26. 6 38. 6 53. 5
Machiaery, total:
Imports 724 789 954 1,054 1,314 1,800 2,693
Exports 4,476 4,968 5,447 5,702 6,525 6,934 7,678
Ratio 16. 2 15. 2 17. 5 18. 5 20. 1 26. 0 35. 1
E. A long-range problern~-The balance-of-payments problem
has been with us for a decade. In our judgment, no long-range pro-
gram for its solution has been developed by Government. and yet
it is clearly a long-range problem, not a short-range difficulty
which lends itself to opportunistic, ad hoc, short-range palliatives.
Not only does it not lend itself to this type of correction but the
short-range prescription would be bad medicine in the long run.
Not only has there been weakness in Government policymaking
with respect to the long-range solution of this problem, but Gov-
ernment insists on trying to isolate from the balance-of-payments
problem many domestic economic policies which have a direct. and
significant impact on our international payments position. Only
when the administration desperately tries to find a new rationaliza-
tion for a tax surcharge and avoid a substantial program of reduc-
tion m nonessential Government expenditures does it attempt in
PAGENO="0110"
824
its rationalization to relate domestic economic policy to interna-
tional economic policy. On matters of domestic interest rates, for
example, the Government posture is to proceed on the basis that
the mterest rate policy m this coimtry must be set for domestic
reasons irrespective of international balance-of-payments consid-
erations. With respect to budgetary policy the same approach is
adopted.
F. An unbalanced progi'ani.-The President's message of Jan-
uary 1 referred to a multifaceted program to deal with the balance-
of-payments situation. From an implementation standpoint, the
multifaceted program has, for all practical purposes, been dis-
carded and reliance has been placed on controls, and in this respect
controls primarily on private mvestment abroad. This is not a
balanced program. It is not a program sound in its long-range
implications. It even has strong disadvantages for the short run.
And it would seem to reflect a preoccupation with control for con-
trol's sake.
G. Bias against p~i*vate investment abroad.-Aside from the
clear drift toward controls over private decisioiirnaking affecting
private investment abroad, we are concerned that there is prese.nt
in Government, at least to some degree, a tendency to frown upon
private investment abroad, to punish it in some respects, and to
nitempt to direct, influence or control it for a variety of reasons.
As we look back over the last several years, we believe that the
record evidences these tendencies. For example, there is the attempt
to control private investment abroad because of our policy with
reference to developing countries. This involves a desire to direct
private foreign investment into the developing areas and away
from the developed coimtries, an objective which unfortunately
not only is unrelated to balance of payments but is in conflict
with balance-of-payments objectives because of the much greater
ability of developed countries to produce a prompt and significant
payback from investment therein. As previously suggested, the
Revenue Act of 1962 is in some respects a control device with
respect to private investment abroad. There have been statements
made by Government officials to the effect that business has not
done a good job in making its private investment decisions with
respect to foreign countries, particularly in Western Europe in
the last few years. This suggests that Government ma.y undertake
to second-guess decisions on matters as to which business is more
experienced than Government; namely, where and why and how
to invest their resources abroad.
Beyond this retrospective audit tendency, Govermnent policy-
makers have said on occasion that private investment abroad has
been overdone. Such a statement, referring, specifically to the early
sixties, was included in the 1967 Economic Report of the Council
of Economic Advisers and. quoted with approval by the "Blue
Book" 1 of the Treasury just published. There undoubtedly is in
the minds of some a conflict in reference to allocation of 11.5. re-
sources between domestic investment and foreign investment, be-
1"Maintainlng the Strength of the tIS. Dollar in a Strong Free World Economy," U.S.
Treasury Department, January 1968.
PAGENO="0111"
825
tween domestic programs and projects abroad. And there un-
doubtedly are some in Government who would like to see Govern-
ment reshape this allocation of resources to the detriment of pri-
vate investment abroad and for the theoretical benefit of the domes-
tic side. These tendencies, these signs, are not always crystal clear.
But `as we observe the Washington scene, as we read Government
pronouncements, `as we study the implications of the law and
regulation affecting private investment abroad, we are obliged `to
assert that there is at least some evidence that the road along which
we are now being led with reference to private direct investment
is not only the wrong one but that our course is being fixed by con-
siderations beyond balance of payments.
H. Temporary or indeflnite.-In all candor, we have no con-
fidence that Government has a determination to end this program
of mandatory controls at the earliest possible date. As pointed out
above, the record of Government with respect to such promises
is poor. Moreover, as we have su'ggested, controls by their very
nature seem to create an `apparatus or bureaucracy which tends to
perpetuate itself, and finally there is the built-in reluctance of
Government to dismantle a program once `it `has been instituted.
The judgments made `here-which we believe to `be widely shared
in the business community, although not necessarily widely articu-
lated-are underlined and strengt'hened by a conviction that there
is no strong will to use this control program on a very short term
basis, and to replace it at a very early date with something that
makes more sense from a long-range standpoint. That `something
in the form of `a long-range program does not appear to be on the
horizon. We are not reassured `by the exchanges between W'ay's and
Means Committee members and administration witnesses on the
issue of the temporary `character `of this program.
I. Lega~ as'pects.-We are concern'ed as to the legal aspects `of
this program. At best it seems that the legal authority cited for
the inauguration of this program without new legislation from
the Congress is strained. It may `be `subject to challenge at `least
as to repatriation requirements. But `let us take the more charitable
view `of `the legal situation and assume that, by straining, the
program can be justified on legal grounds and that furthermore
there is `realistically a natural reluctance on `th'e part of business
to try to assert contrary views on `such a subject through lawsuits.
Even if this is t'he case, we `believe the administration should have
accorded `the Congress and the business communi'ty an opportunity
to suggest alternatives to the mandatory program throu'gh public
hearings or `some other system of administrative procedu're. In
our judgment, whatever may `be the answer `to the legal question, to
undertake `a program of this type without hearings, without dis-
cussion of the issues, `both from the Government `and industry
viewpoints, is unconscionable in terms `of American institutions
and American processes. We cannot overstate our deep concern
with this aspect of the launching of this extraordinary system of
controls on the part of the Federal Government.
J. Administrative problems.-Finally, no program, either in
,terms of conception or structure, particularly one involving con-
PAGENO="0112"
826
trols, can survive if it is bogged down by tremendous administra-
tive problems. Although it is a little early to judge conclusively,
there are signs that this program is almost unadministerable. In
the first place, the processes of international investment are ex-
tremely complex. They involve foreign entities and foreign Gov-
ermnent relationships. By their very nature these processes
constitute a continuum over periods of years as distinguished from
"stop and go," "in and out," moves which can safely be inter-
rupted and turned on and off. As we will attempt to develop in
discussing in more detail the structure of the control program,
these characteristics of the foreign direct investment process, these
complexities, these interrelationships make equitable, consistent,
and reasonable administration almost impossible. And this diffi-
culty is aggravated by the fact that the objectives of the program
of controls are mixed, even partially contradictory, and are not
exclusively tied to balance-of-payments considerations.
K. Bc&sic decision should be reevaluated.-In the net, what is
really needed is a reevaluation of the original basic policy deci-
sion. If Government is determined against that reevaluation, then
clearly the structure of the control program itself must be thor-
oughly reevaluated and overhauled. Anything less than this will
not only produce short; and particularly long-range disadvan-
tages to the public interest, but it may very well produce chaotic
conditions in reference to the stream of business decisions which
must go on. Those decisions, we should emphasize are not just. cold,
calculating, private decisions-they affect intercountry relation-
ships, they affect employment here as well as abroad, they affect
the balance of payments; in general, they affect the public interest.
CRITICIsMs OF THE Smuorum~L CONCEPT AND DETAILS OF THE CONTROL
PROGRAM AND REGULATIONS
General theory of the structure of controls.-The building blocks for
the control structure over U.S. direct investments are these: First, the
controls are addressed to capital outflows, reinvestment, repatriation
of earnings, and the reduction and repatriation of certain liquid for-
eign balances. Second, restrictions on investment and mandatory re-
quirements as to repatriation are defined by formulas which in turn
depend upon the direct investor's experience during prior base periods.
The base periods selected are 1965-66 for capital transfers and limita-
tions on liquid foreign balances and 1964 through 1966 for repatriation
of earnings by affiliated foreign nationals. Third, the countries of the
world are divided into three schedules, with each schedule of countries
given different treatment under the control formulas. For schedule C,
consisting primarily of Western Europe and South Africa, there is
an absolute moratorium on capital transfers from the United States
and the toughest requirement as to repatriation is applicable. Sched-
ule B, given a somewhat more moderate treatment, includes Japan,
Great Britain, Canada, Australia, and certain oil-producing countries.
Schedule A, for all practical purposes, consists of the so-called devel-
oping countries and they receive within the control system the most
generous treatment. In applying the controls the company is required
PAGENO="0113"
827
to treat all of the countries in a given schedule as an aggregate. Four, it
is the theory of the system that the impingement of controls on private
decisions in the foreign investment field can be partially relieved by
permission for companies to borrow abroad-or to guarantee borrow-
ing abroad-with no immediate effect on the individual direct inves-
tor's current investment quota. Pertinent regulations contain, of course,
detailed and complex provisions respecting application of the foreign
direct investment program but the propositions just outlined comprise
the heart of the control structure. In developing our criticisms of that
structure, we give attention first to these basic elements and then turn
to other aspects.
The base period.-Base periods arbitrarily selected for the applica-
tion of controls always create inequities whether one deals with the
excess profits tax, foreign direct investment controls, or any other area.
The base periods adopted in this case are especially faulty because they
discriminate against those companies whose performance under the
Commerce Department's voluntary balance-of-payments program
made especially important contributions to improvement of our in-
ternational balance of payments. The base period for capital transfers
discriminates against seasoned investors who did not substantially in-
crease their foreign investment during 1965-66; similarly, the base
period covering repatriation imposes a harsh standard on those com-
panies which have good records of repatriation and especially when
such a record is improved further by artificial increases during the
base period in response to the voluntary program. Since so much of
the inequity resulting from base period selection results from its iden-
tification with the period of the voluntary balance-of-payments pro-
gram, it would seem that something approaching entrapment is
involved.
The base period seems to have been chosen in part because certain ag-
gregate data was available under the voluntary program for the base
period years-a statistical reason that has no relevance to selection of
a base for control purposes.
Aside from those inequities growing out of established base periods
already cited, it may be useful to identify some additional problems
from this source that have come to our attention. They include such
cases as:
1. Direct investments before or after the `base period which do
not enter into calculation of the direct investment quota.
2. Abnormal earnings during the base period upon `which the
repatriation formula is `based.
3. Ownership by two TJ.S. direct investors of unequal shares in
an affiliated foreign national where both such investors have other
foreign investments within the same schedule of countries. How
are the investment and repatriation quotas to be distributed?
4. The latecomer to foreign investment with little or no invest-
ment during the base period and thus no base against which to
work inthe future.
Division of the world into schedules with preference for developing
countries.-The adoption of the direct foreign controls program in
one breath implies a balance-of-payments crisis but in another seems
to say `the situation is not so serious that we cannot accommodate the
90-191-68-pt. 3-8
PAGENO="0114"
828
policy objective of assisting developing countries. Doesn't the Federal
Government have to make up its mind as to which policy objective is
more important? The result is to blunt the objective of balance-of-
payments improvement by accommodation of the developing country
policy. The structuring of the program into schedules appears to
reflect a determination to force a "retreat of American business from
Europe," an area from which substantial dividends benefiting our
balance of payments have been received. Paradoxically, the program
gives favored treatment to investments in countries which are not,
because of the stage of local economic development, capable of a quick
and generous payout on such investments.
If there is to be a control program it would seem the administration
should give absolute priority to the balance-of-payments objective.
At the same time it should structure the control program in such a
manner as to give business maximum flexibility with regard to its for-
eign investment decisior~making. This argues clearly for abandonment
of the schedule system and the adoption of a worldwide single applica-
tion. Indeed, the voluntary program-acknowledged a resounding
success by government-had the great virtue of preserving flexibility
in corporate decisiomnaking. With the mandatory program that flexi-
bility is gone.
Obviously, a division of the globe, dictated by political considera-
tions, arbitrarily prevents the normal flow of funds to those points
which offer the greatest return on investment. Moreover, by "sched-
uling" the globe in the maimer in which the regulation does, the admin-
istration has created a very great administrative problem for com-
panies which have investments in more than one schedule because of
the substantial lateral dealings between members of a group of affili-
ated foreign nationals across these arbitrary lines.
We are critical of the scheduled approach which compromises be-
tween the balance-of-payments improvement objective and the objec-
tive of favoring developing countries. We do not believe, for the
reasons stated, that this further sacrifice of flexibility for American
business within the control program can be justified and that the sched-
uled approach ought to be abandoned in favor of a single worldwide
approach. Thus, assuming the controls program is continued, the total
goal of the administration would not be changed. Business would be
put in a more flexible position and the administrative nightmare
created by the schedule approach would be avoided.
We recognize that the Federal Government has a longstanding na-
tional policy of helping developing countries which is believed to be
in the interest of the United States as well as international develop-
ment. We adhere without hesitation and irrevocably to the proposition
that pursuit of this objective should not result in a further burden on,
or creation of a further inflexibility for, business with regard to the
total private investment effort, particularly under a control system. If
the Government wishes to give some extra boost to the developing coun-
tries in the light of the imposition of a controls program, it should not
discriminate against developed countries under the controls program
but should provide some direct incentive for investment in the develop-
ing countries. This is already being proposed through negotiation of
tax treaties and undoubtedly the Treasury Department, together with
PAGENO="0115"
829
other interested departments, could develop a more potent incentive in
this respect. At the same time that we make this comment, we insist
that first things must come first and if the administration feels that the
balance-of-payments problem is the central problem, then it ought to
treat it as such and not attempt to splinter its effort.
A realistic look at foreign borrowing.-A central part of the theory
of the foreign direct investment program is the proposition that the
program is designed primarily to reduce outflows and increase repatri-
ation of earnings and that foreign direct investment may be carried
on at a reasonably high level by recourse to foreign borrowing. This
proposition stands up better in theory than it does in reality because
of certain very important restrictions on borrowing facilities and on
the borrowing freedom and capacity of companies involved:
1. In the first place capital facilities abroad are limited although
they are developing. This is true even in sophisticated areas like
Western Europe, and it is even more true in areas like Latin
America and the Orient. Foreign capital markets obviously al-
ready serve domestic customers and as their requirements increase,
so the load on the capital market from domestic institutions and
companies grows. The United States, as a result of the pressures of
the voluntary balance-of-payments program, has added very sub-
stantially to the burden on foreign capital markets. While the
Eurodollar market is still available to larger companies at rates
not greatly above those of the United States, it is not yet clear
what the effect of increased borrowings by U.S. firms will be on
the cost and availability of these funds. With respect to borrow-
ings in national currencies, we understand that there is already
speculation that some countries may be compelled to ration credit
in the near future in ways that would adversely affect the access
of U.S. companies to local capital markets.
2. Beyond these limitations in terms of size, flexibility, and
similar factors, we understand that certain foreign countri.es have
specific restrictions by law, regulation, or practice against bor-
rowing for certain specific purposes; for example, borrowing to
pay dividends may be limited or prohibited.
3. As previously indicated, many companies have already bor-
rowed heavily abroad in response to the voluntary program. The
servicing of these obligations will place a substantial burden on
foreign affiliates' financial structure and to some degree the parent
company, and might in turn require further borrowing when other
factors are taken into consideration including the points below.
4. The repatriation requirement of the mandatory control pro-
gram places an effective limit on all types of foreign borrowing
in many cases. Clearly, payments of principal under foreign bor-
rowing agreements are not accounting deductions prior to the cal-
culation of earnings so that the foreign creditor and the United
States-under the mandatory program-will be competing for the
same dollars. The effect is to partially close the escape hatch pre-
sumably provided by foreign borrowing.
5. Because of the maimer in which the repatriation requirement
affects many, many companies subject to the mandatory controls
program, the repatriation requirement plus debt service cannot
PAGENO="0116"
830
be met out of current earnings abroad. Thus, there will be addi~
tional pressure for this reason on borrowing outside the United
States.
6. Further, one should not overlook the costs of borrowing-
either in the form of increased interest charges to the parent cor-
poration or in the form of reduced earnings of the foreign affili-
ates. At a time when the administration is addressing itself so
persistently and strongly to the inflation problem and at a time
when the administration is very much concerned about exports
and the effect of costs increases on the ability of companies to in-
crease their export position, the additional costs which will be in-
volved in borrowing abroad are wholly inconsistent with either of
these considerations.
Only in the light of these limitations and influences can one examine
realistically the degree to which foreign capital markets will sustain-
and foreign affiliates or their parents will have the capability and the
flexibility to borrow to sustain-increased borowing by U.S. affiliates
for necessary expansion or new investment in order to maintain a so~md
position in international trade.
To sum up, the ability and freedom to borrow abroad in order to
compensate for the restrictions imposed by mandatory investment con-
trols is limited. Moreover, it will be especially limited for the small-and
medium-sized company. Further, the impact on the foreign countries
may very well be adverse and produce restrictions or resentment and
the impact on the total costs of the American worldwide operation
could very well be substantial.
It should be said in conclusion with respect to the so-called borrow-
ing alternative that these limitations on borrowing coupled with the
severe restrictions of the direct investment program create an even
more serious factor. American business just can't maintain its position
in international trade in a total sense if a dynamic approach to foreign
direct investment is thwarted. This point, of course, is relevant
throughout our statement, but it is emphasized here in the context that
borrowing is not the panacea which some in Government and other
circles may believe to be the case.
Adverse effect on exports.-In the context of the structure of con-
trols, and at the risk of repetition, may we emphasize again the perverse
effects on exports. The overriding point is that there is a definite rela-
tionship between investment abroad and exports with the two rising
together. Studies made by the Department of Commerce have docu-
mented this fact strikingly. ("U.S. Exports to Foreign Affiliates,"
Survey of Current Bwsiness, December 1965.) Reduced foreign invest-
ments cannot fa.il to affect exports unfavorably both in terms of sales
to U.S.-owned affiliates and in terms of reducing foreign exchange.
availa.blity to foreign countries. Moreover, at least one element of the.
control program, specifically that provision of the regulation which
is interpreted to mean that increases in open account balances between~
a U.S. parent and its foreign affiliate represent capital investment, will
tend seriously to curtail exports. Indeed, it could tend to place a ceiling
on exports to schedule C countries where there is a moratorium on
capital outflows.
As we have indicated previously, and as the free trade philosophy of
this country reflects, exports are limited by the ability of foreign coun-.
PAGENO="0117"
831
tries to import. Both the direct foreign investment controls and the
proposed tourism programs will reduce the capacity of foreign coun-
tries to buy from the United States. In conclusion on this point, it is
our judgment that merely cleaning up technical points in the regulation
cannot correct the inequitable conflict between a desire on the part of
this country to increase its exports and net trade balance and the actions
taken to restrict foreign direct investment and the proposals regarding
tourist expenditures. `We are obliged to observe that the administration
ought to read its own pronouncements about the need for maintaining
free flow of trade, about the interrelationship between various elements
of trade, and about the fact that we cannot isolate the United States
from the rest of the world and maintain our position in world trade and
improve our balance of payments.
Other shortcomings.-There is a wide range of other deficiencies or
fallacies in the structure of the controls program. They can be sum-
marized as follows:
A. The foreign direct investment program clearly raises the
possibility of foreign reprisals `by countries disaffected or disad-
vantaged by one or more elements of the program. An example is
provided by the requirement of repatriation of earnings. Foreign
countries wishing to react against the U.S. interests could adopt
any one or a combination of approaches. There could be an em-
bargo or partial embargo placed on repatriation to the United
States of an affiliated foreign national's earnings or a possible
increase in taxes on such items as management fees and earned
royalties, and, of course, a possible restriction on investments in
the United States by foreign nationals. Clearly, forced and en-
larged repatriation of earnings to the United States is disadvan-
tageous to the host countries. We can't believe that foreign
countries will not react by some means.
B. There will undoubtedly be special unfavorable impacts on
some foreign countries. The Canadian problem which has already
been recognized in a special statement by the Treasury Depart-
ment is a perfect example.1 Belgium may be another; England
certainly another. It is not necessary to elaborate on the fact that
England is already in serious trouble. The controls on investment
and possible restrictions on tourist expenditures are certain to
hurt England further. In addition, the general reduction in our
capital flows abroad and the proposed restrictions on tourist ex-
penditures will reduce foreign countries' ability to import from
the United States.
Finally, it will be very difficult for this country to respond in
an entirely even-handed manner to meritorious arguments ad-
i Treasury Department release, Jan. 21, i96S:
"There have been reports that, during the past week or two, some Canadian sub-
sidiaries of U.S. corporations have beea transferring abnormally large amounts of
funds from Canada to the United States and that these transfers have resulted in some
pressure on the Canadian dollar in the exchange market.
"The new U.S. balance-of-payments program does not call for and Is not Intended to
have the effect of causing abnormal transfers of earnings or withdrawals of capital by
U.S. companies having investments in Canada. Moreover, the U.S. Government has
already made it clear, and now repeats, that Canadian subsidiaries of U.S. corporations
are expected to act as good corporate citizens of Canada. The new U.S. balance-of-
payments pro~ram covering private capital flows and the Canadian exemption from the
interest equalization tax provide scope for continued large flows of capital to Canada,"
PAGENO="0118"
832
vanced by countries unfavorably affected by our new control pro-
grams. We have already responded to the Canadian difficulty and
in a manner which is hardly consistent with the investment con-
trols philosophy and approach. It is entirely possible that some
private actions in the planning stage which will be interrupted,
restricted, or canceled because of the new controls are of such sig-
nificance to foreign governments that they will receive attention
at the diplomatic level. The international politics will vary from
country to count.r and from complaint to complaint as they cle-
velop among our friends abroad. it is absolutely naive to proceed
on the assumption that our friends abroad will do nothing while
being adversely affected by the controls program.
The relationship between U. S. direct investors abroad and the
host country, both in the short and long term, is a very important
factor in the ability of a company or an industry to operate flexibly
and with dynamism in the foreign area.. Sometimes clearances or
government approvals abroad are necessary in order to establish
the proper kind of relationship. When these procedures are inter-
rupted or hobbled by wit.hdrawa.l action of the U.S. Government
affecting our U.S. direct investors, the impact will not stop with
the short run. The relationship between the U.S. company or
industry and the foreign host country may be interrupted or set
back for a great. many years to come. This, of course. is implicit in
the whole process of international trade including direct invest-
ment abroad which cannot be operated on a.n "off-again-on-again"
basis.
C. So restricted are the foreign direct. investment regula-
tions that they permit no credit to the direct investor's current.
investment quota for such inflows of capital as purchases by
foreign affiliates of American equipment.. receipts of royalties or
management fees and receipts representing a.n increase in export
sales. Each of these. items makes a positive contribution to our
international balance of payments and should, in our judgment.
authorize at least a partially offsetting liberalization of the current
investment quot.a. Indeed, if this program is to be continued in
effect, this kind of safety valve could go far to mitigate the very
harmful long-range effects of the mandatory program by provid-
ing an incentive for enlarged current contributions to our balance
of payments which in turn would make possible current invest-
ments not otherwise authorized and which would yield returns in
the future.
D. Now let us turn to a. central problem with regard to the
direct investment controls program; namely, its admninistrabilit.v,
both from the standpoint of government and industry. Before
proceeding with our criticisms, we should like to make it clear
that the Institute is very much aware of t.he tremendous admin-
istrative burden placed suddenly-almost overnight-on the
Department of Commerce. The personnel involved in this pro-
gram are making a. valiant try in administering what we con-
sider to be a. nonadministrable program and a program which is
thoroughly fallacious in conception. They have been particularly
zealous to t.ry to assist in urgent situat.ions where, as President
PAGENO="0119"
833
Johnson indicated, firm commitments were involved and almost
immediate answers were required in the form of special author-
izations. But we are obliged to conclude that no matter how con-
scientious or industrious the administrative organization within
government is, it cannot possibly make this new creature of gov-
ernment work either in the public interest or in the private inter-
est. The almost incredible variety of businesses and business situa-
tions to which this program must be applied makes it virtually
impossible to come up with a single program fairly applicable to
all. And it is our firm conviction that the program as originally
announced cannot be patched up. It needs to be dismantled and
reevaluated on a 100-percent basis.
It is by now obvious that issuance of a general authorizahon-
for action not otherwise permitted under the regulations-is an
excruciating experience for the Department of Commerce-made
so probably for the very same reasons described above in respect
to the difficulty in establishing a single broad program. As a result
we have had to go the special exemption, case-by-case route and
we shall probably have to continue on that basis under the pres-
ent program.
The reporting burden on business will be immense. For ex-
ample, there is the necessity of converting to accounting reports
responsive to a~counting principles generally accepted in the
United States, the products of accounting systems responsive to
foreign rules of accounting, the delays involved in the collection
of information necessary to complete reports from all affiliated
foreign nationals and the magnification of that latter problem in
the case ~f those affiliated foreign nationals in which the U.S.
direct investor has only a minority interest.
An obvious administrative problem involves a combination of
two points already discussed. Where `a U.S. direct investor holds
a minority interest, he may find it impossible to comply with the
repatriation requirement either because of foreign law or the
intransigence of a foreign boards of directors. In either case, it will
be necessary for him to obtain a specific exemption from the literal
application of the regulations which adds in turn to the case-by-
case administrative burden already noted.
E. Despite the fact that we have been encountering balance-
of-payments difficulties for some years, the Treasury Depart-
ment has not been as flexible `as it might be in making tax changes
with regard to section 482 and other aspects of the Code to encour-
age repatriation of foreign earnings on a purely voluntary basis.
TJnder the controls now in effect there will undoubtedly be some
unfavorable tax impact on U.S. companies triggered by the re-
patriation requirements. This is discussed in more detail else-
where in this statement. Suffice is to say that in some situations
where, for example, manufacturing income abroad is involved
and the repatriation is not voluntary but forced under the regula-
tion, there will be tax consequences in the United States. There is
no provision in the control program for relief from these effects.
This problem is doubly serious from the standpoint of public
policy because the program was instituted by government on the
PAGENO="0120"
834
basis of alleged legal authority grounded in an ancient statute and
without consultation or approval by the Congress in which is
vested the taxing authority. Finally, as indicated elsewhere in
this statement, the administration has apparently dropped its
tentative plan to offer tax inducements to repatriate accumulated
earnings.
ArrIn~L~IvE RECOMMENDATIONS
We turn now to an identification and discussion of certain affirma-
tive recommendations which we believe should be considered, first as
an alternative to the controls programs that have been instituted or
proposed, or as accompanying steps in the event the investment con-
trols remain in effect for at least a limited period of time and the pro-
posed tourist restrictions are legislated. We recognize, of course, that
Congress may choose to permit the foreign direct investment program
to continue solely as an executive branch effort, although it may see
the need for legislation in some areas such as those aspects of the pro-
gram involving taxation. IVe will deal first with the nontax aspects.
1. A proirtpt return to a voluntary system affecting direct invest-
ment abroad.-Although we have certain misgivings about even a vol-
untary system of restrictions on foreign investment, it is clearly pref-
erable to mandatory controls. It preserves maximum flexibility for
decisions to be made in the marketplace and for management to con-
sider various approaches to meet established goals. It avoids the very
costly machinery of control from the Government viewpoint and it re-
lieves business of the tortured process of formal compliance, Gov-
ernment conferences, tedious paperwork, exacerbation of relationships
with partners abroad, etc. By preserving an important degree of flexi-
bility, it will make business better able to avoid some of the perverse
effects of the mandatory program-as, for example, a reduction of ex-
ports and a disruption of total world trade planning-which will in-
evitably flow even in the short run from a rigid system of controls.
Both from the Government and private viewpoint, it will facilitate
the avoidance of gross inequities arising either from the fabric of the
control system or from the varying circumstances attendant on indi-
vidual company positions.
As already acknowledged by Government, a voluntary program can
accomplish a substantial adjustment in the balance-of-payments situ-
ation at an acceptable cost in terms of both national policy and private
impact. In sum, when all of the adverse factors of mandatory direct
foreign investment controls, as outlined herein, are taken into con-
sideration, it is our firm belief that the net performance of the volun-
tary system will be at least as productive as that which can be achieved
under mandatory controls. We recommend, therefore, that the
spectacular move which the administration felt obliged to take on
January 1 should be reversed at the earliest possible date.
2. Foreign investment and domestic fisca~ policy.-Up to a point we
agree with the administration's position concerning the fiscal situa-
tion in the United States. We accept the proposition that perhaps the
most serious aspect of our balance-of-payments problem is to be found
in domestic policy. Continuing budgetary deficits-huge deficits-
which inflate the economy and thus raise the costs of exporting corn-
panies are a grave threat to our international competitive position.
PAGENO="0121"
835
We do not accept the proposition that the 10-percent surcharge is
necessarily the keystone of a program of correction of deficiencies and
fallacies in our domestic economic policy. On the contrary, we believe
that the weight of Government action in this area should be placed
on substantial, very substantial, reductions in nonessential Government
expenditures. We do not believe that the administration has gone far
enough in this direction and we sympathize with the attitude of the
Ways and Means Committee as reflected in its deliberations thus far
which seem to conclude that:
First, a clear and unmistakable economic case must be made
in terms of business conditions in the United States for a tax
increase; and, second, that even with such an economic case per-
suasively made any tax surcharge must be conditioned upon a sub-
stantial decrease in nonessential Government expenditures.
The institute feels that a much more substantial reduction in nones-
sential Government expenditures must be promptly undertaken. If a
tax surcharge is enacted, it is to be hoped that expenditure reductions
would at least equal revenue from the tax increase.
In brief retrospect, the exports of the United States have been
maintained at a remarkable level when one considers the disadvantage
at which U.S. exporters are placed by domestic economic policies
which include high-wage policy, inflationary fiscal policies, and an
inescapable subordination of international commercial poliCies. As
previously indicated, until the administration sought a new argument
for its surcharge proposal and pressed for the tax surcharge as the
centerpiece of its balance-of-payments program, the general posture
of the Federal Govcermiient has apparently been to consider the domes-
~ic economy in isolation from international economic commercial con-
siderations.
3. Prompt implementation of export expansion proposals.-The
President's program, as outlined in his message of January 1, includes
a number of recoilimendations affecting export financing, including a
special $500 million fund for liberalized export insurance and export
credit guarantee facilities, and prompt development of improved redis-
count facilities. In addition, intensified export promotion activities
under the aegis of the Department of Commerce was proposed.
All of these ideas, all of these recommendations, have been urged
upon Government by business for a number of years. They have not
been dynamically implemented, in some respects they have not been
implemented at all. One is entitled to ask whether there is an element
of window dressing in the current revival of these proposals.
The President's message acknowledged that the United States was
at a disadvantage because of the practice of foreign countries, per-
mitted under GATT, to provide export rebates of indirect domestic
taxes. The testimony of Ambassador Roth before the Ways and Means
Committee is not reassuring as to the likelihood of early action for
improvement in this area. This problem has existed for a decade or
more. The fact that nothing has been done about it is unmistakable
evidence that the Federal Government has not attacked the balance-
of-payments problem on a consistent, hard~hitting, long-range basis.
On the contrary, when an aggravation occurs it is dealt with on an ad
hoc, panic basis.
PAGENO="0122"
836
Why have these export assistance objectives and programs referred
to in the President's message not been fully implemented before?
Why has this problem of nontariff barriers not received more atten-
tion? Why does this practice of foreign countries with respect to
export rebates or border taxes go unattended from a policy viewpoint
for so many years?
We can only conclude as we have already stated that these problems
have been brushed under the rug and they are now being restated
and related programs revised in order to provide a sense, and we
believe an artificial sense, of balance to this program of controls on
foreign direct investment and tourist expenditures. Without going
into detail, obviously action should be taken along these lines par-
ticularly with regard to the export assistance programs, but the fact
that such action is taken is neither an excuse nor a rationalization
for the controls aspects of this program. Nor should they be permitted
to obscure the fact that the heart of the new balance-of-payments pro-
gram is the control structure which applies primarily to direct invest-
ment abroad and banking activities.
4. Modification of the control structure if it ~s continued.-We have
~dready alluded to certain points which we believe should be given
central attention if a control system on direct investment abroad is
to be continued even for a short period of time. If the administration
is unwilling to acknowledge its mista.ke, scrap the mandatory system
of controls and revert to voluntary controls or none at all, then it
should dismantle the present structure of controls and do the job all
over again, allowing sufficient time and thought to develop something
a great deal more equitable. in concept and workable in practice. The
notion of segmenting the globe into schedules of countries should be
scrapped. In restructuring the controls, if they are to be. continued,
`a group of incentives should be built into the system. For example,
a bonus or special allowance for private investment abroad-in terms
of increased investment quotas or reduced repatriation requirements-
might he granted to the company which improves its export position.
Some direct allowances or bonuses in the system should be given to
increase~ in royalties and licensing fees which are returned to the
United States. In brief, a company's total performance in contributing
to impro~ement of the Nation's balance of payments should be given
direct. and express recognition.
5. Tax aRpects of the required repatriation of foreign subsidiary
earnings.-In his message on the balance-of-payments problem, the
President. reported that he had directed the Secretary of the Treasury,
in effect, to consider the possible desirability of legislative proposals
to induce or encourage the repatriation of accumulated earnings by
TJ.S.-owned foreign businesses. We understand from the administra-
tion testimony before the Ways and Means Committee that Treasury
has looked into the problem and has decided not to make any such
proposals, at least not at this time. We think that this is unfortunate
because there are obviously a number of things that can be done to
encourage American companies to repatriate pre-1968 accumulated
earnings which are not subject to the requirements of the mandatory
direct investment control program. These `same measures could also
be used to lessen the tax impact on current earnings that are subject
to the mandatory controls.
PAGENO="0123"
837
The Department of Commerce regulations require what it describes
as repatriation of earnings. So far as we know, there is no requirement
that such earnings necessarily be remitted in the form of dividends.
This apparently means that loans or advances from the subsidiary to
the American parent company would satisfy the requirements of the
Commerce regulations. However, in many situations the payment of
such advances or loans would be impossible or impractical from the
viewpoint of the foreign subsidiary because of the laws or policies of
the country within which it is located, and also because of financial and
other operating considerations relating to the subsidiary itself. In any
event, we think that certain things might well be done by the U.S.
Government to make it easier for companies to comply with repatria-
tion requirements. We suggest that the Treasury and the Internal
Revenue Service should issue an official announcement to the effect
that interest-free advances from a subsidiary to the parent would not
be considered "constructive dividends," at least to the extent that such
advances were made pursuant to the direct investment control pro-
gram. In addition, the Treasury might well attempt to persuade
foreign governments to follow policies which would permit companies
within such jurisdictions to make loans or advances to American
shareholders in connection with the U.S. balance-of-payments program
in cases where such loans or advances might not be permitted at the
present time.
Where because of foreign law or because of other circumstances the
repatriation of funds must be in the form of a dividend, it certainly
would be appropriate to permit deferral of the U.S. tax on that
dividend. Such deferral might extend for a stated period of time such
as 5 years or possibly even for a period of time that would be deter-
mined for each individual company on the basis of its past experience
~with respect to dividend payments from foreign subsidiary earnings.
Here we are talking about dividends from foreign subsidiary earnings
that are not "foreign-base company income" and therefore are not
taxable to the American parent company until received in the form
of dividends. If for some reason it is determined that such deferral
is impractical or undesirable, the Government should consider grant-
ing some type of tax reduction with respect to foreign subsidiary
dividends.
6. Taa~ incentives for exports.-Just over 2 years ago the Action
Committee on Taxation of the National Export Expansion Council,
chaired by Mr. Carl A. Gerstacker, board chairman of the Dow
Chemical Co., presented to the Department of Commerce and the
President a series of proposals relating to taxation and designed to
encourage U.S. exports. In brief, these proposals were as follows:
We recommend three specific areas of administrative action
which will help to remove tax barriers to exports:
1. The realistic administration of laws providing for reallo-
cation of income and expenses between related companies:
Recent Treasury efforts to clarify practices in this area have
been helpful but guidelines on the reasonableness of selling
prices are needed.
2. The adoption of rules on the repatriation of funds and
the use of foreign tax credits when reallocations have been
PAGENO="0124"
838
made by the Internal Revenue Service between related com-~
panies, consistent with policies now governing tax years prior
to 1963.
3. More liberal policies on the transfer of industrial prop-
erty to foreign corporations in tax-free exchanges to permit
favorable rulings in more cases.
We also recommend four specific areas for legislative changes
in the tax provisions:
1. Less complicated and more liberal rules for export trade
corporations under section 970 of the Internal Revenue Code.~
2. An additional capital allowance for equipment produc-
ing goods for export.
3. An incentive deduction for promotion expenses in con-
nection with export sales.
4. The extension of the investment tax credit to purchases
of U.S.-produced equipment abroad.
The administration has taken at least limited action in response to
the committee's recommendations for administrative action. With
regard to the second administrative recommendation, the Treasury
has extended special procedures relating to repatriation of funds and
us of foreign tax credits following a "section 482" allocation to 1963
and 1964. We strongly urge that such procedures be extended to all
periods prior to the promulgation of new section 482 regulations which
the Treasury has not yet issued.
However, the administration's reaction to the first three of the
legislative proposals has been negative-at least there has been no
official comment on them, much less any indication that the adminis-
tration will support them. We note that in this connection Senator
Smathers of Florida, a senior member of the Senate Finance Com-
mittee, has introduced 5. 2574 which would implement that part of
the committee's proposals relating to the liberalization of the present
Internal Revenue Code provisions relating to export trade corpora-
tions. We think that favorable action along the lines of this set of
proposals would do much to stimulate U.S. exports which cannot
fail to be adversely affected by the direct investment control program.
SUPPLEMENT TO MAPI STATEMENT
THE U.S. BALANCE OF PAYMENT5 AND THE GOVERNMENT'S MANDATORY
RESTRICTIONS ON DIRECT PRIVATE INVESTMENT ABROAD-A DETAILED
EXAMINATION
INTRODUCTION
The administration's U.S. balance-of-payments program announced
on January 1 represents but another in a series which have entailed
progressively more restrictive controls over the movement of dollars
in international markets. The major difference in the latest program
is that the measures just taken far exceed a.nything which has been
attempted heretofore. They are mandatory and unprecedented. These
Steps were taken, of course, in response to a renewed attack on the
dollar and a deteriorating balance-of-payments situation which ac-
celerated sharply in the fourth quarter of last year. In light of this
deterioration, and if one accepts a continuation of the enlarged U.S.
PAGENO="0125"
839
military commitments abroad as essential, it would be irresponsible
to oppose any or all measures to halt and reverse this decline in our
payments position. The question is whether these particular measures
are sound. When viewed within the context of the Government's ap-
proach over the past decade toward this country's chronic balance-
of-payments problem, the current program has, in our opinion, serious
implications for the future. Certain elements are in our judgment
particularly regrettable and could, in the retrospect of the early
1970's, prove to have been tragically wrong.
MAPI has, of course, reviewed this problem on several occasions.1
However, the extent and the nature of the actions just taken are suffi-
ciently serious that it is desirable to reconsider once again the nature
of the problem we are facing. This analysis is confined to the man-
datory controls over direct private investment abroad.
MAJOR SHORTCOMINGS OF THE CU1~RENT PROGRAM
Program Deals With Symptoms Rather Than Causes
Our basic concern about the current program is that it is directed
at symptoms rather than the causes of the problem. This is not new.
It is the history of the Government's approach toward the recurring
U.S. balance-of-payments difficulties.
The assumption appears to be that we are dealing with a temporary
iphenomenon which presumably calls for short-term restrictive meas-
ures. (Indeed, the current program, as in the case of earlier programs,
was announced as a temporary one.) But history shows us that this is
not the case. The U.S. balance of payments was first recognized as a
serious problem following the huge balance-of-payments deficit in-
curred in 1958. More than a decade has passed and we are still seeking
ways to correct it. More than once we have been led to believe that the
restoration of a healthy payments position was imminent, but that
hope never has been realized.
The problem has been attributed to various causes from one period
to another. At one time a declining trade surplus was fingered as the
major difficulty. At another time rising capital outflows were assigned
the blame. Most recently, of course, our difficulties have been attrib-
uted to the Vietnam war. The persistence of the deficit, however, makes
it clear that we have been suffering from a basic imbalance-that is, our
international commitments consistently have exceeded our current re-
sources. We have, in a very real sense, been continually drawing on our
capital without, in the interim, taking steps to match our commitments
to our current availabilities.
Given the fact that we are confronting more than just a short-term
problem calling for temporary emergency measures, it should be clear
that palliatives are insufficient, and that our basic economic policies
must be responsible and realistic. In this connection, it is regrettable,
for example, that at a time when unemployment remains relatively low
and we have suffered a particularly rapid increase in costs and prices
we are simultaneously experiencing a domestic budget deficit of huge
proportions which only can have further damaging effects in terms of
the international competitiveness of the U.S. economy.
1 See, for example, U.S. Manufacturing Investments Abroad and the Government Progra'm
for Balance of Payments Improvement, Machinery Institute, 1965.
PAGENO="0126"
840
Our concern would be somewhat relieved if the current program
were really a temporary measure designed to buy time while we "get
our house in order" or until there is a lessening of Vietnam war require-
ments. However, even should we attribute most of our current difficul-
ties entirely to the Vietnam war, there is as yet no clear indication that
this war will be any less of a drain on our resources in the foreseeable
future. More important, the balance-of-payments problem long pre-
ceded the Vietnam war, and there is no solid evidence to indicate that
it will not outlast it. We have entered the 11th year of deficits which
have been considered unacceptably large, and a solution is not yet in
sight. Such a history, together with the new program, provides ample
evidence that the Government has not taken sufficient advantage of the
time purchased by earlier programs.
Hasty Action; Widesweeping Uoverage
Of further concern to us is the apparent haste with which the cur-
rent program was drawn up and its broad coverage. It is particularly
difficult to understa.nd, with respect to controls over sectors which do
not appear to have been under any undue pressure, why more time
was not taken to consider their positive contribution in the light of all
the facts. At the very least, greater deliberation in the drafting of
additional controls would have avoided many of the administrative
problems which have already arisen.
The current program, which was undertaken in response to a. huge
fourth quarter deficit of $7.3 billion (at seasonally adjusted annual
rates), was drawn up so hurriedly that not even preliminary figures
were publicly available for the fourth quarter at the time of its an-
nouncement. Indeed, preliminary data were not made publicly avail-
able until February 15 or 11/2 months following the initiation of the
program.
While the preliminary data fail to identify movements in certain
sectors, including the direct investment sector, they do show that an
important part of the fourth-quarter deficit resulted from a nonre-
curring type transa.ction, namely the liquidation by the British Gov-
ernment of some $500 million of U.S. securities in order to defend the
exchange value of the British pound. Another important factor was
a $720 million decline in our non-military merchandise trade surplus
reflecting a sharp rise in imports and a small decline in exports.
These two items account for some two-thirds of the total deficit.
~Thile other major adverse movements have not yet been identified.
there is no reason to suppose that capital outflows into direct private
investment (that is. investment in brick and mortar a.s opposed to
portfolio investments and the buildup of other dolla.r assets abroad)
contributed to the large adverse movement in the fourth quarter. On
the contrary, one would expect direct investment, unlike other types
of private capital, to be generally insensitive to currency devaluations.
Accordingly, it is particularly unfortunate that the administration
applied hastily devised controls to the direct investment sector. In-
deed, there is still no indication that stringent direct investment con-
trols were called for at all. Developments in this sector were very
favorable in the first three quarters of last year, as described below.
PAGENO="0127"
841
Growing Controls Over Private Sector
This is the crux of the problem in our view. Recent history leads
us to question whether the Government really has the will to make and
execute the difficult decisions necessary to assure a healthy payments
position in the absence of controls. A more likely prospect seems to be
a continuation of strict controls on the private sector while the Gov-
ernment attempts some restraints in certain areas within the public
sector but continues to increase its overall world commitments.
Certain steps have, of course, been taken from time to time within
the government sector but they have been entirely inadequate as is
conspicuously demonstrated by recent events. Further, prospects are
not good for a matching of commitments with availabilities in the
foreseeable future.
The Vietnam war has, of course, resulted in a rapid acceleration in
our international commitments. At the same time, there has been no
clear evidence that, prior to the new program, any really strong ef-
forts were made to cut back significantly in ot.her public sector areas.
We may note, for example, that U.S. Government grants (excluding
military) and long-term capital outflows increased from $4.2 billion
in 1964 to $4.4 billion in 1966 and to an annual rate of $5.6 billion in
the first three quarters of 1967. While much of this was probably Viet-
nam related, the fact that the size of last year's increase was so large
suggests that efforts to undertake cutbacks in other areas probably
were minimal. Yet, additional steps could have been taken as evidenced
by the fact that several measures have just been initiated. But., relying
in part, no doubt, on beneficial effects from the voluntary balance-of-
payments program, the Government simply had an inadequate sense
of urgency until it felt forced to take further strong measures, and
again the major burden of these measures is placed on the private sector.
There is little reason to believe, against this background, that Gov-
ernment intends that the present controls will be lifted in the near
future. Insofar as U.S. international commitments are concerned, there
is certainly nothing on the horizon to indicate that they will be reduced
any time soon. Indeed, the contrary would seem to be indicated in view
of the continuing Vietnam conflict, trouble in Korea, and Britain's
increasing withdrawal from world commitments which creates strong
pressures for a corresponding increase in U.S. commitments. Further,
the longer controls on the private direct investment sector remain in
effect the more difficult it will be for control-minded Government to
rationalize removing them. For the favorable impact of such invest-
ments will tend to diminish with time as a result of their reduction,
while the potential investment opportunities will accumulate. It fol-
lows that the adverse short-run effects of removing the controls will
increase over time.
Danger of Restricting Ability of Private Sector To Contribute to Re-
ductions in Payments Deficits
The tragedy of maintaining these controls over an extended period
is evident. As our international commitments continue to mount, a
major means of supporting them (in the form of currency inflows
generated by direct investment activity abroad) is being seriously
impaired. This* fact, combined with the lack of an adequate sense of
PAGENO="0128"
842
urgency on the part of the Government and the consistent tendency
to act belatedly and with insufficient vigor to correct our basic pay-
ments imbalances, can ultimately have serious repercussions.
By way of pointing up our concern about the continuing ability
of the private sector to support public commitments abroad we should
point out that our balance of payments was already showing a deterio-
ration prior to the fourth quarter due in a maj or degree to the increas-
ing deficits in the public sector accounts. The overall deficit (on a
liquidity basis) has shown some decline in 1964 and 1965 but reflected
no further improvement in 1966 and then moved in a strongly adverse
direction in the first three quarters of last year to a seasonally adjusted
annual rate of $2.3 billion, and increase of $0.9 billion over the entire
year 1966. (See table below.)
SELECTED U.S. BALANCE-OF-PAYMENTS TRANSACTI ONS
1966
19671
Change
Merchandise trade surplus
Capital outflows into direct private investment, neL
Income from direct private investment (including fees and royalties) ---
Other long-term private capital outflows, net
Short-term private capital outflows, net
Government grants and capital outflows, net2
Military expenditures
Military sales
Overall balance 3
+3. 66
-3. 46
+5. 09
-. 26
-. 41
-3.45
-3. 69
+. 85
+4. 35
-2. 89
+5. 40
-1. 14
-1. 02
-4.25
-4. 25
+1. 17
+0. 69
~-. 57
±. 31
-. 88
-. 61
-.80
-. 56
+. 32
-1.36
-2.28
-.92
I First 3 quarters at seasonally adjusted annual rates.
Excluding "Military grants of goods and services," "U.S. Government pensions and other transfers," and "Official
reserve assets."
3 Detail does not add to total because only selected items are shown.
This overall deterioration in our payments balance occurred despite
a major improvement in the first three quarters of 1967 in both the
merchandise and direct investment sectors. Our merchandise trade
surplus (converted to a seasonally adjusted annual rate) showed an
increase of $0.7 billion over 1966. At the same time, capital outflows
into direct private investment abroad declined by $0.6 billion, and in-
come from direct private investment (including fees and royalties
from such investment) rose by $0.3 billion for a net improvement of
$0.9 billion in the direct private investment sector. These improve-
ments were more than offset, however, by large adverse movements in
other sectors. There was a major adverse movement in Government
grants and capital outflows which increased by $0.8 billion in the first
three quarters of last year (at seasonally adjusted annual rates) over
1966, and there was a large increase in the rate of military expenditures
abroad (by some $0.6 billion) although this was offset to a significant
degree by an increase in the rate of military sales abroad ($0.3 billion).
Adverse movements were also experienced in "other private capital
outflows" with other private long-term outflows increasing by $0.9
billion and short-term outflows by $0.6 billion over 1966 in the first
three quarters of last year (both at seasonally adjusted annual rates).
These offset in part the favorable movements in the trade and direct
private investment sectors. It can be seen, however, that major elements
contributing to the adverse movements were in the Government sector.
Inasmuch as the Government sector contmued to be the prime con-
PAGENO="0129"
843
tributor to the balance-of-payments deficit (the merchandise trade
and private investment `sector together have consistently contributed
to the plus side of the payments balance) and in light of the large in-
crease in the payments deficit on Government account last year, the
Government should, in our view undertake further intensive efforts to
reduce the deficit in its own sector. We so conclude even though we
must recognize the necessarily adverse effects of Vietnam developments
on the Government sector.
More importantly, in view of the private sector's historic role in re-
ducing the payments deficit incurred in the public sector, the Govern-
ment should be careful to avoid taking steps which will impair the
ability of the private sector to fulfil that role in future years, particu-
larly since the history of thelast decade strongly supports the proposi-
tion that that role will be at least as essential and probably more so in
the future.
A CLOSE LOOK AT DIRECT PRIVATE INVESTMENT ABROAD
In seriously restricting direct private investments abroad and, more
specifically, in flatly prohibiting further direct private capital out-
flows to most of Europe (excluding the United Kingdom and certain
less advanced countries) the Government is taking a step which could
have most unfortunate effects for the future of this country's interna-
tional payments position.
Role of U.S. Corporatio~iw in Mininvi~ing Payments Deficits
It is ironic that the Government should be taking such drastic action
against U.S. corporations at this particular juncture. According to
President Johnson's statements and the U.S. Department of Commerce
reports on the Government's voluntary program to improve the U.S.
balance of payments, American business has cooperated closely and
has stayed well within the targets set under that program. Further,
corporations made a substantial contribution toward minimizing the
balance-of-payments deficit in 1967, as noted earlier, with direct pri-
vate capital outflows declining significantly and remittances from
direct investment abroad continuing their long-term climb. Finally,
there is every indication that capital flows to Europe, which have been
heavy in recent years but which appear to `have declined sharply last
year from 1966, will continue at more moderate levels in the future.
There is a growing consensus that Europe's future growth rates will be
markedly slower than they were prior to the 1966-67 recession. This
should be reflected in reduced U.S. corporate investments in that
region. The latter is suggested, for example, by recent surveys (e.g., the
U.S. Department of Commerce) indicating a reduced rate of expansion
in plant and equipment spending by U.S. subsidiaries and affiliates in
Europe in 1967 and very little growth in 1968. At the same time, re-
mitted earnings from past investments in Europe could have been ex-
pected to continue their rapid increase with a reduction in European
capital requirements, particularly as recent investments became sea-
soned and hence more profitable.
It is true, of course, that U.S. capital outflows to Europe in the first
three quarters of 1967 ($1.5 billion at annual rates) continued to ex-
ceed remittances from such investments ($0.7 billion at annual rates)
90-191---68-pt. 3-9
PAGENO="0130"
844
but the size of the difference is diminishing as outflows are beginning to
decline and remittances are continuing to show substantial increases.
Further, this difference is highly misleading because dollar inflows
generated by investment in Europe exceed dollar outflows into such in-
vestments by a substantial volume when one takes account of the
export impact of such investments and of royalties and management
fees deriving from these investments.
For example, we estimate that U.S. exports to European affiliates
of U.S. companies exceeded $1.5 billion last year and this estimate
excludes exports that, would have occurred in the absence of these
affihiates.1 This itself is far greater than the adverse differential be-
tween remittances from and outflows to direc.t U.S. investments in
Europe last year. Further, there is the added income in the form of
royalties and management fees from direct European investments
which were at an annual rate of some $450 million in the first three
quarters of last year. Hence, it is clear that the positive contribution
to the balance of payments deriving from direct European invest-
ments is very large indeed.
A Strong Adverse Impact (Jan Be Expected From Controls art Direct
Investment
It is perfectly apparent that a flat prthibition on capital outflows
to Europe will have an immediate favorable impact on the U.S. bal-
ance of payments by eliminating outflows while inflows continue. This
favorable impact must be discounted even in the short run because
of detrimental effects on exports which will flow from the control pro-
gram. Moreover, given the long-term nature of our `balance-of-pay-
ments problem and the unfortunate fact that payments controls, once
established, often take on a permanent aspect, the ultimate effects of
the mandatory controls 011 direct investment can be highly detri-
mental. For they will reduce. the ability of this key sector to help in
offsetting the large Government sector payments deficits which have
trended strongly upward and, on the basis of the historic record, can
be expected to continue in that direction.
By way of illustration, we will consider the new controls on foreign
investments. We recognize, of course, that conclusions drawn from a
partial analysis of the balance-of-payments accounts must necessarily
be qualified because of the interdependence of the various sectors. For
example, restrictions on the outflows of direct private investment
capitul tend to lower interest rates in this country by increasing the
supply of domestic funds, thereby discouraging the inflow of foreign
capital. Similarly, to taken another example, a cutback in Government
aid programs overseas tends to depress exports to the extent. that they
are tied to the purchase of U.S. goods. (Indeed, we feel that the Presi-
dent's objective of an overall improvement of $3 billion in our pay-
ments balance as a result of tile new program is far too optimistic be-
cause it is based on this sector-by-sector approach.) Nonetheless, de-
spite the limitations of a partial analysis, it should give some indication
of the self-defeating aspects of the proposed controls insofar as the
direct investment sector is concerned.
i we developed a rough estimate of $1.7 billion using U.S. Department of Commerce data.
This represents only the roughest of approximations but does give some notion of the order
of magnitude of the export impact. Assumptions underlying these estimates and other details
concerning their derivation are described in the attached appendix and tables.
PAGENO="0131"
845
We will further confine our attention to controls on European in-
vestments since this has been the area of greatest investment activity in
recent years and is now subject to the most rigid controls. We pose the
question, "What would have been the result had the controls instituted
on January 1 of this year been introduced on January 1, 1959, follow-
ing the large balance-of-payments deficit in the preceding* year?"
(These controls prohibit capital flows to direct investment in most
European countries, excluding the United Kingdom and certain less-
advanced countries, and permit reinvestment, of earnings in an amount
no more than 35 percent of average annual investments in Europe
during 1965-66. The remainder must be remitted to this country.) The
consequences of introducing this program 9 years ago, when the TJ.S.
balance of payments was first recognized to be a problem, would have
been roughly as follows.1
Adverse impact on balance of payments.-The book value of direct
investments in Europe (excluding the United Kingdom) would have
been in the neighborhood of $4 billion at yearend 1966 instead of $10.5
billion. Earnings from such investments would have been about $517
million in 1967 instead of actual earnings in the neighborhood of
$750 million. Remittances would have totaled $233 million in 1967
instead of roughly $473 million. Exports to European affiliates of U.S.
companies would have totaled some $417 million instead of roughly
$1.1 billion. (1iVe have excluded from both export estimates, those
which could have been expected to take place in the absence of U.S.
affiliates.) ~a Management fees and royalties from U.S. investments iii
Europe (excluding the United Kingdom) would have been roughly
$119 million instead of $297 million.
In 1967 the dollar inflow from these three factors combined-i.e.,
remitted earnings, royalties and management fees, and exports would
have been in the neighborhood of $769 million instead of some $1,878
million. Assuming actual outflows in 1967 of $1,129 million to Europe
(excluding the United Kingdom) the balance-of-payments effects
Would have beeii only slightly more favorable if the ban on capital
outflows (inflows totaling $769 million) had been instituted in 1959
than they actually were in the absence of the controls (i.e., $1,878
million income less $1,129 million outflows for a favorable balance of
$749 million) 2
It is true, of course, that our international reserve position would
have been somewhat improved inasmuch as the net impact of the con-
It should be stressed that these figures represent only the roughest of approximations.
Again, our purpose is only to give some general notion of the magnitudes Involved. Assump-
tions underlying these computations are described in the appendix. Results are shown in
the tables attached to the appendix.
la We should note in this connection that, given the nature of the export impact, even the
immediate effect of the ban on capital outflows is vitiated to a marked degree by a significant
reduction in the exports that otherwise would have taken place. This is because a significant
portion of U.S. capital invested in U.S. affiliates abroad has been in the form of capital
equipment for installation in new, expanded, or modernized facilities and there has also
been a substantial export of materials, parts, and components for further processing or
assembly in U.S. facilities in Europe.
2 Less onerous restrictions have been applied to investments in other developed countries
including the United Kingdom, Canada, Australia, Japan, and the oil-producing countries of
the Middle East. The adverse impact would have been correspondingly less than that for
investments in continental Europe. For example. rough estimates suggest that If these con-
trols had been instituted on Jan. i. i959, the value of direct U.S. private investments in
these countries at yearend i966 would have been roughly ,$2i.8 billion instead of an actual
value of some $26.8 billion. It appears on the basis of historical data that the restrictions on
investments in countries other than those comprising these two groups would have a mini-
mum impact on the investments of a majority of companies.
PAGENO="0132"
846
trols would have been favorable in the earlier years. Indeed, although
the favorable differential diminishes under our hypothetical illustra-
tion during the period under review,3 it persists through 1967. None-
theless, our present posture would have been far worse. Our cumulative
deficit on direct investment account (in the absence of offsetting re-
actions in other sectors) would have been reduced by about $3.1 billion
from the end of 1958 through the third quarter of last year (from
$22.2 to $19.1 billion). The nature of the deterioration in our inter-
national reserve position since yearend 1958 suggests that some 36
cents out of every dollar accumulated abroad was converted into gold
(with much of the remainder held in the form of dollars and short-
term dollar claims) .~ On this basis we may speculate that our gold
holdings would have been about $1.1 billion greater and our short-
term liabilities about $2 billion less at the end of last year's third
quarter than they actually were. Our gold holdings would have de-
clined from $22.5 to $16 billion (instead of to $14.9 billion) and our
short-term liabilities would have grown from $15.4 to $26.8 billion
(instead of to $28.8 billion).
This difference of $3.1 bfflion out of a cumulative deficit of $22.2
billion would hardly have been sufficient to set at ease the world's
concern about the US. position in view of our immense international
commitments and the direction in which we have been moving. Further,
this favorable cumulative differential would `have been increasingly
dissipated as the favorable `annual differential turned adverse. The
favorable annual differential would have virtually disappeared in
1967, and almost surely would have turned adverse this year based on
our illustration. And, of course, if such rigid controls over direct in-
vestment had already been instituted along the lines of our assumption,
the Government would have been unable to fall back on such controls
(voluntary or otherwise, permanent or temporary) in an attempt to
alleviate the situation which we face today.
One final point should be made concerning our hypothetical illustra-
tion. It might be argued that, being unable to use US. capital and
for accomplishing their investment objectives in Europe, U.S. com-
panies and their affiliates would have borrowed abroad to this end with
favorable effects for the U.S. balance of payments. Such borrowing
would not have been reflected in increased book values of U.S. invest-
ments, inasmuch as the Commerce Department treats foreign loans
as liabilities to foreigners rather than U.S. companies. However, it
might have served to increase earnings to book value ratios to the
extent that the added earnings attributable to the use of the borrowed
funds exceeded interest costs and it might also have raised somewhat
the ratio between U.S. exports to European affiliates and the value
of their investments in those affiliates, insofar as the borrowed funds
3This favorable differential Is, of course, less than the difference between the actual value
of investments at the end of a given year and what that value would have been under the
controls. That is to say, the reduced level of investment values resulting from the controls
is by no means a measure of the improvement in the payments balance that we might have
expected as a result of their imposition. The reduced investment resulting from an elimina-
tion of capital outflows brings in its wake a comparable reduction in earnings and a cor-
responding reduction In funds available for reinvestment (and for remittance to the United
States) leading in turn to a further reduction in Investments greater than the reduction in
capital outflows resulting from the controls. This adverse effect is cumulative, of course,
as the divergence between actual foreign earnings and those which would have occurred in
the absence of controls becomes ever wider. Eventually, the adverse effects from the reduc-
tion of earnings from which remittances (and reinvestments) can be made more than offsets
the favorable effects resulting from the prohibition of outflows and the controls thereby
prove ultimately to be self-defeating.
See appendix for explanation.
PAGENO="0133"
847
facilitated increased purchases from the United States. On the other
hand, some companies presumably would have been unwilling to bor-
row abroad, more would have at least reduced their commitments, and
companies without established reputations or contacts abroad would
simply have been unable to gain access to foreign capital. Indeed, given
the limited development of capital markets in Europe and elsewhere,
capital would not have been available on anywhere near the scale
needed to replace U.S. sources and the borrowing costs would, of
course, have been increased, perhaps sharply. Finally, we feel that
we have, in any case, been very conservative in our estimates to the
pomt where we have tended to understate the adverse effects that could
have resulted from the controls. In short, we do not consider that in-
cluding the effects of foreign borrowing in our illustration would have
significantly modified the conclusions.
We do not wish to unduly labor the point insofar as our specific
illustration is concerned. We feel, however, that the thrust of our
argument is so important that it was better brought home when stated
in specific terms, thereby indicating the dimensions of the problem
that could be created if such a program were maintained for longer
than a short period of time. On the basis of this illustrative example,
and given further growth in U.S. international commitments and
the glaring failure of the Government to correct the basic causes of
the current problem over the past decade, it would be appropriate to
ask how in the light of the new program, the private sector could
be expected indefinitely to continue to offset the deficits caused by
the public sector.
Adverse Impact on International Competitiveness of U.S. Industry
While the direct balance-of-payments impact of the restrictions
is of major importance in considering the significance of the new con-
trols, other factors are of at least equal weight. The inability to in-
vest any capital in European facilities from the United States reduces
very greatly the flexibility of response essential for U.S. industry if
it is to maintain its competitiveness against foreign industry in both
domestic and foreign markets. The inability, for example, to estab-
lish new plants abroad in order to serve areas which can no longer be
served from U.S.-based facilities because of cost or other considera-
tions enables foreign companies to move at once to preempt that mar-
ket. Or, to take another example, the inability to enter into a partner-
ship or joint venture with a foreign firm whereunder each partner
supplies new capital to the venture, may result in the prospective
foreign partner's turning to another foreign company to serve this ob-
jective. In this connection, it should be stressed that such a total ban
on capital outflows can seriously damage the international position
of U.S. companies even if it is of relatively short duration. Timing
is a central ingredient in maintaining a company's competitive posi-
tion, and an opportunity not grasped when it presents itself is often
lost forever.
As such lost opportunities accumulate, we will find a greater por-
tion of the imports into this country and of sales into third country
markets will be from foreign-owned industry, and the earnings and
dividends deriving from such sales will accrue to foreign companies
rather than U.S. companies to the detriment of the U.S. payments
balance and the strength of U.S. industry. By the same token, we will
find that a greater proportion of equipment, components, and parts will
PAGENO="0134"
848
be purchased from other than U.S. suppliers. The results will be
strongly adverse for the LT.S. balance-of-payments position and the
international competitiveness of American industry.
Further, it is those industries which are not yet established abroad
but which are finding foreign operations increasingly necessary in
the face of stiffened foreign competition which will be hindered most
by these restrictions because. more often than not they will have less
access to foreign capital markets and, of course, internally generated
funds from their foreign operations are minimal. Yet, it. is these. very
companies whose need is greatest for establishing themselves in foreign
markets in order to maintain a competitive position both abroad and
at home in the face of rapidly increasing foreign competition.
CONCLUSION
In conclusion, we cannot. emphasize too strongly two of the basic
underlying reasons for our grave concern over these developments;
namely (1) the indefinite nature of the controls and (~) the inability
or unwillingness of Government authorities to take adequate. steps to
develop a healthy balance-of-payments position within the. context of
freely competitive markets, and to set. realistic public policy objec-
tives consonant with available TJ.S. resources. Considering the first,
one has only to look at the history of controls over the past decade.
Once imposed they have normally been maintained. This has been the
case, for example, with the~interest equalization tax and the voluntary
program to improve the balance of payments which were both in-
troduced as "temporary" measures and which have evolved into the
rigidly restrictive mandatory programs which have now been imposed.
As to the question of developing a healthy balance of payments, the
Government seems incapable of bringing itself to . undertake in a
vigorous manner the necessary steps to this end. Instead of adequately
using the time purchased with the increased restrictions to pursue
policies which can increase the international competitiveness of the
U.S. economy (or, alternatively, to cut back on our international com-
mitments), the Government seems to find temporary improvements in
the payments balance resulting from such restrictions and excuses to
continue on the same economic course only to conclude that controls
have to be tightened even further at a later time.
It must, of course, be recognized that the: Vietnam war is an im-
portant factor underlying the present difficulties and, unfortunately,
there is no clear indication that the resources directed to this wa.r can
or will be reduced significantly in the near term future. However, this
is almost beside the point. While the extent of our foreign commit-
ments have no doubt been increased because of Vietnam, they have
been heavy throughout the post-World War II period, taking the form
or large-scale military and economic commitments in extended areas
of the world.
It has long been apparent that even the United States has limited
resources and that realistic public goals must be established with this
fact in mind in order to avoid sapping the strength of the private
sector in the pursuit of short-term goals to the point where there will
ultimately be no alternative to a sharp, involuntary reduction in in-
ternational commitments to the detriment of the country. We must
find a proper balance between our foreign and domestic objectives.
PAGENO="0135"
849
If we feel certain international requirements to be sufficiently urgent
we must `either `accept certain sacrifices on the domestic front or cut
back on other international objectives. We must, in short, establish a
realistic scale of priorities in terms of available resources, and post-
pone less urgent requirements.
Our major concern is that we will continue to put too great a bur-
den on the private sector in order to carry out publicly established
objectives both at home and abroad without regard to the adequacy of
our resources. In so doing we may place such a burden on the private
sector as to significantly impair its ability to compete commercially
and to support important publicly established objectives in the future.
It is our contention that we are doing precisely that today. We are
impairing the future ability of American industry to support im-
portant public policy requirements. In accord with this general line
of thiiiking, and the recent course of history, it appears likely in our
view that, in lieu of easing controls with a lessening of Vietnam war
requirements, the U.S. Government may well, on grounds of urgency,
take on added international (as well as domestic) obligations and
maintain the present controls with unfortunate effects both for in-
dustry and the country over the longer term. We are convinced that
if these controls are maintained beyond the very near term future the
effects will be very serious.
APPENDIX
ESTIMATED BALANCE-OF-PAYMENTS IMPACT FROM INSTITUTING CoN-
TEøLS OVER DIRECT PRIVATE INVESTMENTS IN EUROPE AT YEAREND
1958
The following is a description of the methods used in estimating
the impact on the U.S. balance of payments that would have occurred
had the new controls over direct private investments in most of Europe
been established at yearend 1958. Results from our computations are
shown in the attached tables.
1. The new controls specify the following: New capital outflows
from United States to direct private investments in most of continental
Europe are prohibited. Earnings in excess of 35 percent of average
annual investments in 1965-66 (or the percentage of earnings re-
mitted during 1964-66) must be remitted annually from most of con-
tinental Europe. The larger figure is controlling.
2. It was assumed that the current program was instituted at year-end 1958 and
maintained to the present time. This would have meant (a) that new capital out-
flows to Europe were prohibited beginning in 1959, and (b) earnings in excess
`of 35 percent of average annual investments in 1956-57 had to be repatriated or
the same percentage of each year's earnings had to be repatriated as was repatri-
ated during 1955-57. The larger figure is controlling. (In our computations it
devel'oped that the 35 percent requirement was controlling through 1904 when
the percentage of earnings requiremeilt became controlling.)
3. It was assumed that U.S. corporations remitted only the minimum required
amount. This `amounted to $191 million annually for the years 1958 through 1964
and $202 million, $217 `million, and $230 million in 1965, 1966, and 1967, `respec-
tively. The remainder of the earnings from these investments was reinvested.
`4. The rate `of return in each year was assumed to be 13 percent as measured
against book value at the beginning of the year in question. The actual annual
rate `of return averaged 13.2 percent during 1956-61 and then `began t~ decline,
reaching 8.2 percent by 1966; it averaged 10.5 percent during 1962-66. Part of
the `decline was a result of th'e large increase in investment's during thi's period
which `led to an increasing proportion of facilities which were not yet fully pro-
PAGENO="0136"
850
ductive. Another part can be explained by some decline in the rate of return
on European investments generally during the last few years. Of course, the in-
crease in U.S. investments would have been reduced in the face of the above
investment restrictions, thereby reducing the extent of the decline in the rate of
return. Hence, we simply assumed that the rate of return was 13 percent through-
out. The volume of earnings so computed less the volume of computed remittances
was added to beginning-of-year book value to estimate book value at the beginning
of the following year.
5. A relationship between U.S. exports and U.S. investments in
Europe (excluding the United Kingdom) and the value of these
investments at the beginning of the year in question was "guessti-
mated" on the basis of data published by the U.S. Department of Com-
merce covering the years 1962, 1963, and 1964. Department of Com-
merce data show estimated total exports to U.S. a.ffiuiates~ in Europe
(including the United Kingdom which is not shown separately) in
those 3 years. (Sample data were expanded to estimated totals by the
Commerce Department.) We deducted from the estimated totals one-
half of the value of exports other than exports of capital equipment
and parts, components, and materials for further processing or assem-
bly in the case of exports to affiliates other than trading affiliates, and
we deducted two-thirds of exports other than capital equipment and
parts, components, and materials for further processing or assembly in
the case of exports to trading affiliates.
The deductions were made on the basis that they would have taken
place even if said foreign affiliates had not been established. This ad-
mittedly involved guesswork. However, we feel that the deductions
were more than adequate. The local incorporation of U.S. affiliates to
promote greater local identification and greater acceptance of the
company and its products, and the creation of a permanent interest
on the part of the company in European markets unquestionably have
been important elements in the export volume enjoyed by those com-
panies. Further, such local acceptance no doubt helped to promote the
sale of U.S. manufactured goods through channels additional to those
included in the Commerce survey.
We then computed the ratio of the residual exports values in each
year (1962, 1963, and 1964) to the value of total U.S. investments in
Europe at the beginning of the year in question and averaged the
three ratios. Estimated exports derived on this basis were $860 million,
$880 million, and $1,103 million in 1962, 1963, and 1964, respectively,
and the computed ratios were 11.1, 9.9, and 10.7 percent, respectively,
for an average of 10.6 percent (rounded to 10.5 percent). On the basis
that the ratio for total Europe was reasonably representative of that
for Europe excluding the United Kingdom we applied it to begin-
ning-of-year investments in Europe excluding the United Kingdom
for each year including in our review to estimate the volume of exports
generated by such investments over this period which would not have
taken place in their absence.
6. Finally, we computed the ratio of fees and royalties from U.S.
investments in Europe (excluding the United Kingdom) to the begin-
ning-of-year value of such investments for each year from 1960
through 1966. Such data are not readily available for the years prior to
1960. The ratio was 2.8 and 2.9 percent in 1960 and 1961, respectively,
and ranged from 3.2 to 3.4 percent thereafter. We used a figure of 3
percent which we applied to the estimated book value data to get esti-
mated royalties and fees.
PAGENO="0137"
851
ESTIMATED EFFECT ON TJ.S. INTERNATIONAL RESERVE PosmoN FROM
INSTITUTING NEW CONTROLS AT YEAR-END 1958
It was assumed in the discussion of the U.S. international reserve
position (pp. 9-10) that 36 percent of the increase in foreign dollar
holdings resulting from the cumulative deficit between yearend 1958
and the end of September 1967 was converted into gold with the re-
mainder held in the form of dollars and short-term dollar claims. This
assumption was derived in the following manner:
The cumulative deficit from the end of 1958 through the third quar-
ter of 1967 ($22.2 billion) has been accompanied by increased short-
term liabilities and reduced gold holdings of a comparable magnitude
over this period (i.e., an increase of $13.4 billion in short-term liabili-
ties and a decline of $7.6 billion jn gold holdings for a total adverse
movement in our reserve position on this account of $21.0 billion).
On the basis that the relative change in dollar liabilities versus gold
holdings over the period reflects the propensity of foreigners to hold
dollar claims in lieu of presenting such claims for gold, it follows that
:36 percent of this cumulative deficit was converted into gold with the
remainder being held largely in the form of short-term dollar claims.
Thus, the statistics show the following:
[In billions of dollarsj
End of period
Short-term liabilities
Gold
Net adverse change
1958
15. 4.
22. 5
September1967
28.8
14.9
Net change
+13. 4
-7. 6
21. 0
Note-Of the total net adverse change, 36 percent ($7,600,000,000) comprised a reduction in gold, the remaining 64
percent ($13,400,000,009) comprising an increase in short-term liabilities.
TABLE I-U.S. BALANCE OF PAYMENTS ON DIRECT PRIVATE INVESTMENT ACCOUNT WITH EUROPE EXCLUDING
UNITED KINGDOM-RELATION BETWEEN BOOK VALUES, EARNINGS, REMITTANCES, AND REINVESTMENTS
UNDER HYPOTHETICAL ILLUSTRATION
[In millions of dollars]
Year
,
Beginning of
yearbook value
(value in pro-
ceding year plus
reinvestments
(col. 5))
Earnings (0.13
Xcol. 1)1
0.45
Xcol. 2 2
Minimum
remittance
requirements 3
Earnings less
remittances 4
(reinvestment
or additions
to book value)
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
1959
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
02,426
2,550
2,691
2,850
3,029
3,232
3,461
3,709
3,974
315
332
350
370
394
420
450
482
517
142
149
158
166
177
189
202
217
233
191
191
191
191
191
191
191
191
191
124
141
159
179
203
229
248
265
284
1 Assume return on investment equals 13 percent. (See appendix text.)
3 Assume 45 percent of earnings must be remitted if this exceeds 35 percent of investment in 1956-57. (See appendix
text.)
3 Assume 35 percent of investment in 1956-57 (or $191,000,000) must be remitted unless or until 45 percent of earnings
exceeds $191,000,000; 45 percent of earnings exceeds $191,000,000 beginning in 1965 and hence the larger amount must
be remitted. (See appendix text.)
4 Col. (2) less col. (4) or col. (5). (See footnote 3.)
Actual value.
PAGENO="0138"
1- *~
00
~ 0
~ U)
-JO
0~
o U)
~
LU
-
5=
U)
H
1-0 < =
~ I
DCI-
=
=
0~
UJL)
~0
>- =
00
C) ~`-
v~0
0
2
-~ 0
-0
LU
0
1-
S
1-
C,,
rn
I I I
E
0
~;`
~
~..0
~*3I
~
~~2+_:
~()
+
~`
~-`
0
=
E
~
C)
~
LU
0~
0
~
~
LU
~a
~
1-~
5
~0
0C.)
C.)
~C/)
~
1_0
EL).
2~
-
&)0
*.;~
~
)C~
=
`C
.00
~`2~
~=
E~
~I
~
-%
:~
000000000
~i
~
`.
~
C)
-
~
.!!
~
~
~
a)
~
*g~~~=:~
~
~
~p>
~
~
:
U)U)C))~~
~
,)`).)~,
)`$`~~`
::::::::
::::
I I I : : :
:
~a~u~r-I
U)O)C)0)O~
!
~
<
~
~j
~
~
U)~2
~
-
~
~
L~IILZC
- `C-
~;~7
~
~
<
U~
~
.!
=
~
<
1-
.0
I
.~2'1 ~3
~ r x
E
E
E
~0
C~o=
.0
C~00
PAGENO="0139"
NATIONAL ASSOCIATION OF MUTUAL SAVINGS BANKS
By GROVER W. ENSLEY, EXECUTIVE Vion PRESIDENT
In the expectation that other aspects of the President's and Council's
1968 Reports will be considered elsewhere, this statement will be di-
rected primarily to the President's recommendations for improving
the flow of residential mortgage credit, and particularly to his recom-
mendation that the Federal savings institutions bill (}I.R. 13718) be
enacted as a means of accomplishing this vital goal of national policy.
This major and urgent piece of legislation deserves full and prompt
consideration by the Congress.
It would go a long way toward mitigating the basic problem of the
residential mortgage market which,'stated quite simply, is a tendency to
swing rapidly between periods of abundance and periods of scarcity.
`While mortgage flows have always been sensitive to cyclical develop-
ments in the economy, this sensitivity has significantly worsened during
the 1960's. It was, of course, most dramatically evident during the great
financial squeeze of 1966. And today, little more than a year after
homebuilding began to recover from the depths it had plumbed in late
1966, concern is 011CC again growing over the possibility of yet another
decline in mortgage flows and housing.
`While the major recent and prospective concern centers on the prob-
lem of mortgage credit scarcity, it should not be forgotten that only a
few short years ago the principal problem was an overabundance of
mortgage money relative to basic housing demand. This led not only
to a significant reduction in the quality of mortgage credit in some
areas of the country, but also strongly affected the ability of many in-
stitutions having narrow investment powers to extend mortgage credit
during the subsequent period of financial stringency in `1966. Since
scarcity is likely to be the major mortgage market problem in the fore-
seeable future, attention in this statement will be directed toward this
serious aspect of the problem, with the reminder that any long-range
program to counter the worsening cyclical instability of mortgage
credit must also be responsive to the problem of potential over-
abundance as well.
The problem of cyclical swings in residential mortgage credit, and
particularly the danger of a chronic shortage of mortgage funds in
the years ahead, has worsened during the 1960's primarily because the
major suppliers of residential mortgage credit-mutuaj savings banks
and savings and loan associations-have found it increasingly difficult
to generate funds for mortgage lending in the new economic, financial,
and savings market environment that has appeared in recent years.
Both types of institution channel almost all of their savings growth
into residential mortgages. Together, during the postwar period, they
have supplied almost three-fifths of the total increase in residential
(853)
PAGENO="0140"
854
mortgage credit., with savings banks dominating FHA and VA mort.-
gage markets and savings and loan associations dominating the market
for conventional loans. As 1966 so graphically demonstrated, when they
are unable to compete for lendable funds, the flow of mortgage credit
and the level of homebuilding are severely restricted.
SHORT-RUN Por~ic~ IMPLICATIONS
The immediate short-run cause of savings institutions' and housing's
troubles in 1966 was the failure to adopt adequate fiscal restraints to
dampen inflationary pressures in a. full-employment economy. This
forced the Federal Reserve to shoulder most of the responsibility for
containing inflation, with the result that open market interest rates
were pushed to levels not seen in more than a generation. The rise in
open market rates in turn triggered a massive round of "financial dis-
intermediation," as individuals shifted a record volume of funds from
savings accounts into direct open market instruments.
This process was temporarily reversed in 1967 a.s short-term open
market rates fell sharply earlier in the year, but by yearend individuals
were again responding to rising interest rates by shifting funds into
open market investments. Preliminary data for the Federal Reserve's
flow of funds accounts, for example, indicate that households chan-
neled almost $15 billion into such direct investments (at seasonally ad-
justed annual rates) in the fourth quarter of last year, only slightly
less than the peak volume reached in the second quarter of 1966. Flows
into savings accounts at thrift institutions and commercial banks, by
contrast, fell by more than half to an annual rate of less than $18
billion in the fourth quarter of 1967, slightly less than the low reached
in the fourth quarter of 1966. Savings flow data for Janua.ry, moreover,
indicate that savings and loan associations experienced a net savings
outflow of more than $200 million-the largest net outflow for the
month on record-and that the net savings gain at mutual savings
banks was almost two-fifths less than the January 1967 record.
A repetition of the 1966 mortgage credit squeeze in 1968 hopefully
can be avoided, however. Thrift institutions have strengthened their
liquidity and are not so heavily committed as they were in 1966, while
the Federal Home Loan Bank System is also in a substantially stronger
position to extend needed assistance. Nevertheless, the current high
level of short-term open market interest rates, and the possibility of
further increases under the pressures of a stronger shift to monetary
restraint and continued heavy Treasury deficit financing in the short~
term area, indicate that financial disintermediation and renewed de-
clines in housing may well be a serious matter of concern in 1968.
Together with the prospects for strong inflationary pressures out-
lined so clearly in the President's and Council's reports, and the need
to maintain international confidence in the strength and stability of
the dollar, these considerations strongly reinforce the need for a tax
increase in 1968 combined with strict Federal expenditure control.
In this regard, our soundings of the 1968 economy are generally in
accord with the picture outlined by the President and the Council.
Gross national product should rise by about 8 percent this year, in con-
trast with last year's increase of about 51/2 percent, with more than 3
percent of the increase representing inflation. While business activity
PAGENO="0141"
855
should be slightly stronger in the first half of the year, second-half
activity should also advance significantly. This would be particularly
likely should defense outlays rise more rapidly than anticipated in the
fiscal 1969 Federal budget, a growing possibility in the light of recent
developments in Vietnam and Korea.
The economy, in our opinion, therefore, will be strong enough to
absorb a tax increase needed to restrain inflationary pressures and
strengthen the dollar. Without such action, the Federal Reserve will
be faced with a number of cruel and conflicting policy choices in 1968:
It will have to facilitate the financing of yet another massive Treasury
deficit, bear the major responsibility for containing inflation and an
accelerating wage-price spiral, guard against the danger of a possible
crisis of confidence in our balance of payments, and consider the effect
of its actions on financial institutions and homebuilding. Given the
necessity of balancing these conflicting goals, the probability is that
all will suffer to greater or lesser degree, and that, as in 1966, housing
will suffer more than most. A better balanced fiscal-monetary policy
mix, on the other hand, would contribute significantly to an easing of
all of these problems, and to the maintenance of a stronger, better
balanced economy not oniy in 1968 but in subsequent years. It would
lessen, moreover, the possibility that other, less palatable and more
direct means of restraint might have to be implemented in the future.
THE NEED FOR LONGRUN STRUCTURAL CHANGE
While shortrun considerations point to the need for a better bal-
anced fiscal-monetary policy mix, the fact remains that housing ac-
tivity will be unduly vulnerable to cyclical developments in the econ-
omy until basic changes are effected in the Nation's home mortgage
financing system. Although by far the most important in terms of
dollar volume, the mortgage sector has increasingly become the step-
child of the capital markets. It is highly encouraging, therefore, that
the President's and the Council's reports place so much emphasis upon
the need to strengthen the channels of residential mortgage credit.
indeed, as outlined on pages 92-95 of the Council's report; the admin-
istration's approach to the problem of assuring an improved flow of
residential mortgage credit is quite similar to the comprehensive tn-
part program outlined by the National Association of Mutual Savings
Banks and included in "A Study of Mortgage Credit," published in
May 1967 by the Subcommittee on Housing and Urban Affairs of the
Senate Committee on Banking and Currency.1
The administration correctly recognizes that there is no one quick
and easy solution to the ills that periodically beset the residential
mortgage market, and that a coordinated, multifaceted approach is
required. The three basic elements of the similar programs outlined
in the Council's report and by NAMSB include:
-the strengthening of mortgage-oriented savings institutions;
-the development of new types of mortgage instruments to tap
new, supplementary sources of mortgage funds; and
-the termination or relaxation of Federal and State interest rate
ceilings on mortgage loans.
1 "A Study of Mortgage Credit," Subcommittee on Housing and Urban Affairs, Committee
on Banking and Currency, U.S. Senate, 90th Cong., ist sess., May 22, i967, pp. 289-30i.
PAGENO="0142"
856
In view of the central role played by mortgage-oriented savings
institutions in residential mortgage financing, it is obvious, as the
Council recognizes, that any program to strengthen the flow of resi-
dential mortgage credit must be anchored to a strengthened thrift and
home-financing system. As noted earlier in this statement, and as in-
dicated on pages 71-76 of the Council's report, savings institutions
have found it increasingly difficult to compete for savings in the new
environment that has emerged in re(~ent years. In part, as indicated,
this reflects their increased vulnerability to high and rising open mar-
ket interest rates. As the Council points out on page 93 of its report
in reference to the 1966 mortgage market crisis:
Because their funds are primarily invested in mortgages with
fairly long maturities and fixed interest charges, the thrift in-
stitutions were unable to raise their earnings enough to permit
payment of interest rates in line with those available from [com-
mercial] banks and open market instruments.
The Council's reference to commercial banks highlights the other
major development of recent years that has adversely affected the flow
of residential mortgage credit. And this, of course, is the new, intense
commercial bank competition for savings as a major source of lendable
funds. This revolutionary departure from past tradition and practice,
underway for more than a decade now, is traceable to the 1951 Treas-
ury-Federal Reserve "accord" and to the slowdown in commercial
bank demand deposit growth that resulted from the subsequent rising
trend of open market interest rates and implementation of a flexible,
contracyclical monetary policy by the Federal Reserve.
Faced with this challenge, and aided by successive increases in the
regulation Q ceiling on their savings and time deposits, commercial
banks responded by competing vigorously for savings and time de-
posits through interest rate increases and effective promotion of the
wide range of financial services that they are able to offer savers. As a
result, they have succeeded in sharply increasing their share of savings
account growth, which rose from 29 percent in the 1946-56 period to
43 percent in the 1957-67 period. As shown in the revealing table on
page 73 of the Council's report, moreover, the commercial bank share
has risen sharply further during the past 3 years of full employment
and high interest rates, averaging well over half of total savings
account flows.
The implications for housing of this diversion of savings from
mortgage-oriented thrift institutions to commercial banks are obvious,
in view of the fact that commercia.l banks channel only a fractional
share of their savings gains into residential mortgages while savings
banks and savings and loan associations channel almost all of their
funds into housing. In this regard, it is hardly a coincidence that the
share of total savings account growth absorbed by the residential
mortgage market fell from more than nine-tenths in the 1946-56
period to only three-fifths in the 1957-67 period.
As the implications of the basic changes in the economic, financial,
and savings market environment since the lnte 1950's became more
fully realized, support for legislation to strengthen savings institu-
tions and the flow of residential mortgage credit grew and became more
widespread. Until 1967, this effort centered largely on Federal savings
bank legislation, first introduced in the Congress in 1957. During the
PAGENO="0143"
857
ensuing decade, this legislation gained the support of all of the major
national housing, mortgage, and real estate group's, was recommended
by the privately sponsored Commission on Money and Credit in 1961
and by President Kennedy's Cabinet Committee on Financial Institu-
tion's in 1963, and became an administration-sponsored and drafted
bill twice specifically endorsed by President Johnson in his January
1966 and January 1967 Economic Reports.
The 1966 mortgage and housing crisis intensified the urgency of
achieving legislation that would strengthen the Nation's thrift and
home-financing system. F'ol1owin~ congressional hearings on Federal
savings bank and alternative legislation in July 1967, a unified ap-
proach toward this goal was embodied in the Federal savings institu-
tions bill through the joint efforts of thrift industry, congressional,
and administration leadership. This administration-sponsored and
drafted legislation was `introduced in the Congress in `September and
reported favorably by the Hou'se Banking and Currency Committee
in late November 1967. It is due to be considered by the full House of
Representatives in the present session of the Congress.
Like the predecessor Federal savings bank hills, the Federal savings
institutions bill (H.R. 13718) enjoys widespread public-interest sup-
port, including major mortgage, real estate and housing groups, the
savings bank and savings and loan industries, `Congressmen from both
p'arties, and key Federal agencies with responsibilities `in the economic
and financial areas. And it is particularly gratifying that President
Johnson urged enactment of H.R. 13718 in his February 1968 Eco-
nómic Report. (See p'age 22.)
This bi-partisan, public-interest support reflects a recognition of
the fundamental `ways in which the bill will help strengthen the flow
of residential mortgage credit. in this regard, we strongly recommend
the House Banking and Currency Committee's Report on H.R. 13718
as "must reading" for those interested in meeting the problems of `hous-
ing and residential mortgage credit in the critical years ahead.2 As
the committee noted in its report, the bill will 1benefit the residential
mortgage'niarket in three inter-related ways:
-it will encourage an increased and better distributed flow of
financial saving;
-it will channel an increased share of the enlarged savings pool
through savings institutions and into housing; and
-it will help even out `the flow of residential mortgage credit over
the course of the business cycle.
`The bill will accomplish these goal's by authorizing the Federal
Home Loan B'ank Board to charter Federal mutual savings institu-
tions-either newly organized institutions or converting mutual sav-
ings banks and mutual savings and loan associations-having the
modern `and flexible powers needed to compete for savings in the new,
intensely competitive savings `market environment of the 1.960's and
beyond.
The long record of actual experience shows, and scholarly studies
have substantiated, that the presence of vigorous, competitive thrift
institutions in a community stimulates an increased volume of locally
2 Federal Savings Institutions, report on HR. 13fl8 of the Committee on Banking and
Currency, House of Representatives, 90th Cong., first sess., Dec. 13, 1967.
PAGENO="0144"
858
held savings. By promoting such institutions, the bill can be expected
to increase the total volume of financial saving. Such a result would
have great benefits not only for the housing market but, more broadly,.
for the economic health and stability of the Nation as a whole, since
private saving is the lifeblood of noninflationary e1conomic growth,.
productivity increase and real capital formation. While always impor-
tant, encouraging an increased flow of private saving assumes an even
more critical role under conditions of full-employment such as we have
now are likely to have in the foreseeable future.
And perhaps never before in our history as a Nation has it been
more important to channel an increased volume of savings into housing.
As noted by the President on pages 21 and 22 of his report, and by the
Council on pages 92 to 95 of its Report, the demands for residential
mortgage credit in the years ahead will be truly staggering. The rat&
of household formation, by far the single most important determinant
of housing and mortgage demand, is projected to rise steadily through
the last years of this decade and all of the 1970's. Based on the two
alternative projections published last year by the Census Bureau, for
example, the annual rate of household formation during the last half'
of `the 1970's will range between three-tenths to almost one-half higher
than the average annual rate of the 1960-67 period.
And government demands for private mortgage credit will' also be
rising sharply as Federal, State, and local programs expand and multi-
ply in the drive to rebuild our cities and realize the national goal of
providing "a decent home for every American." As President Joimson
states on page 22 of `his 1968 Economic Report, providing for 20 million
new privately financed homes over the next decade" . .. will balloon
the need for mortgage money." And the 10-year goal of providing 6'
million new federally assisted housing units for low- and mod~rate-
income families, first outlined by `the President in his 1968 state of the
Union Message, will require an additional large infusion of private
capital if `heavy and perhaps unacceptable strains on the `Federal
budget are to be avoided.
But even as the demand for mortgage funds mounts in the years'
ahead, basic population trends during much of this period will be
relatively unfavorable for savings growth at mortgage-oriented sav-
ings institutions, with the number of low-saving young adults growing
rapidly and the high-saving 30 to 59 age group growing much `more
slowly.
Against this projected background of sharply rising mortgage de-
mands and shifting population composition, moreover, it is reasonable
to expect continuation of a generally high level of economic activity
and of intense commercial bank competition for savings as a major'
source of lendable funds. While it is true that commercial banks have.
increased their interest in mortgages somewhat, it is also true, as noted
previously, that the diversion of savings from~ savings institutions to
commercial banks represents a substantial net diversion of funds from
the residential mortgage market. And this will be parti~ularly true
during periods of relatively high economic activity and strong busi-
ness loan demands, for commercial banks remain essentially oriented
to supplying short- and intermediate-term business credit.
Thus, demographic, political, and competitive considerations all
PAGENO="0145"
859
highlight the urgency of channeling a larger share of savings back
into the residential mortgage market through savings institutions~
Failure to do so could well mean~ that the realization of vital na-
tional housing and urban revitalization goals will be thwarted by a
chronic shortage of mortgage money. The Federal savings institu-?
tions bill will help to forestall such a potentially serious development
by providing savings institutions with the flexible and modern de-
posit and investment powers they will need to attract an increased
volume of funds for investment in residential mortgages in the years
ahead.
In a very real sense, the savings account instrument offered by
thrift institutions is an extension of the mortgage instrument and the?
flow of mortgage credit. Improving the one, therefore, will surely
improve the other. In this regard, the Federal savings institutions bill
provides for a wide variety of savings accounts bearing varying rates
of interest, for the right to contract in advance the rate of interest
on certain types of accounts, for savings certificates that can be issued
to individuals or business organizations, and for the right to use
modern banking nonmenclature. These provisions will enable savings
institutions to tailor savings plans that will appeal to all segments of
the savings market, and thereby generate an increased volume of sav-
ings. The right to use modern banking and deposit terminology in
their operations will be of particular value to the many savings and
loan associations that are currently denied this opportunity.
Equally important, the Federal savings institutions bill will pro-
vide savings institutions with needed investment flexibility, and with
the ability to offer a wider and more attractive range of financial
services to individuals and their families. This too will increase?
their ability to generate an increased volume of funds for residential
mortgage investment. As the Council notes on pages 93 and 94 of its
report:
The scope for improved portfolio structure of thrift institutions would be en-
larged through the chartering of Federal savings associations . . . Adoption of
the legislation would increase the institutions' over-all efficiency and competi-
tive strength . . . To the extent that thrift institutions shift to more diversified
portfolios, the amount of funds available to the mortgage market will be ini-
tially reduced. In the longer run, however, the savings and loan associations
will better serve the mortgage market by maintaining a steadier intlow of funds
and by strengthening their own competitive position. [Emphasis added.]
The bill's provision of limited consumer loan authority is par-
ticularly crucial, since the availability of consumer credit will be es-
sential if savings institutions are to maintain their role as the Nation's
leading suppliers of housing credit. In this regard, it is essential to
recognize that savings institutions can only lend out in mortgages
what they are able to attract as savings, and that provision of a
more comprehensive range of family-oriented financial services will
be one of the most effective means of increasing their attractiveness
to savers.
It is widely recognized that consumer credit is one of the most
important financial services required by young people, and by families
in the earliest stages of the economic life cycle. Meeting the needs of
young people, always important, will be more important than ever
for savings institutions in the years immediately ahead~ In the dee-
90-191-68-----pt. 3-10
PAGENO="0146"
860
ade ending in 1975, the number of people in the relatively low-sav-
ing 20 to 29 age group will have grown by almost 12 million, compared
with an increase of less than 4 million in the relatively high-saving
30 to 59 range. In the following decade, however, the picture will be
reversed, with the number of young adults growing by about 5~/2
million and the number of people in the 30 to 59 age group increasing
by almost 13 million.
The implications of these figures are clear. If savings institutions
can provide the financial services needed by the rapidly growing group
of young adults in the years immediately ahead, their chances of gain-
ing the savings of this same group in later years will be substantially
enhanced. And this would mean a significantly increased longrun flow
of housing credit, since savings institutions would continue to channel
the bulk of their savings growth into residential mortgage loans-the
single most important family financial need.
The increased investment flexibility provided by the Federal savings
institutions bill would also promote a more stable flow of housing
credit over the business cycle, thus alleviating the chronic and worsen-
ing tendency of the residential mortgage market to swing widely be-
tween conditions of feast and famine. In part., this would result from
an increased ability to strengthen earnings and maintain savings
growth and mortgage flows over all stages of the business cycle. In
addition, with more fle.xibile loan and investment powers, savings in-
stitutions would be able to supplement reduced saving flows in pe-
riods such as 1966 by converting nonmortgage assets into mortgage
loans, thereby cushioning the decline in mortgage credit and housing
during such periods. On the other hand, in periods when savings
growth is large relative to basic mortgage demands-such as in the
early 1960's-savings institutions could continue to promote thrift
by channeling funds into alternative investments, funds which could
later be converted into mortgage loans should be need arise.
As the House Banking and Currency Committee stressed in its re-
port on the Federal savings institutions bill, these advantages of
flexibile investment powers for the flow of residential mortgage credit
were dramatically demonstrated during the mortgage credit squeeze
of 1966. Reflecting their relatively broader and more flexibile loan and
investment powers-including the right to make consumer loans in 10
States-mutual savings banks were far better able to maintain savings
growth and a high level of local mortgage flows than were savings and
loan associations. Local savings bank mortgage lending was further
bolstered during this period of severe financial strain through the con-
version of other assets into mortgage loans, as savings banks chan-
neled an amount equivalent to 108 percent of savings growth into
mortgages. Savings and loan associations, by contrast, were able to
channel only 89 percent of the combined increase in their savings and
borrowings into mortgages in 1966.
In view of the bill's likely benefits for housing, it is little wonder
that the House Banking and Currency Committee Report summed up
the need for H.R. 13718 in the following manner:
More money for housing. Those four words sum up the primary basis of the
need for this legislation. Its passage is badly needed, and long overdue, to help
the average American family obtain a decent j~ace to live at a price it can afford.
PAGENO="0147"
861
And it is hardly surprising that the Council of Economic Advisers
echoed this view in its 1968 Annual Report, summing up on page 92
the need for the bill in this fashion:
The recent sharp fluctuations in the availability of mortgage funds have demon-
strated the need for action to reduce the excessive vulnerability of the mortgage
market and the home building industry to variations in monetary conditions.
The basic demand for mortgage financing is expected to grow rapidly in time
next few years, while the ability of thrift institutions to meet this demand may
diminish as commercial banks compete more effectively for time deposits. Thus
both long-term and cycUcal considerations suggest the need to strengthen the
thrift institutions which supply the bulic of mortgage funds and to devise new
means of attracting funds into mortgages. [Emphasis added.]
The Federal savings institutions bill will not be a panacea for the
problems afflicting the residential mortgage market. But it will go a
long way toward alleviating many of the worst aspects of these prob-
lems. As noted earlier in this statement, other measures will also be re-
quired to improve the flow of residential mortgage credit. As the
Council notes on page 94 of its report, devising new security-type
mortgage instruments that will appeal to p,ension funds and trust ac-
counts is a highly promising approach. Similarly, as noted by the
President on page 22 of his report and by the Council on pages 94-95
of its report, prompt action to remove or relax statutory interest rate
limitations on mortgage loans is clearly required. Originally enacted
to protect borrowers, these provisions are self-defeating in the new
:high-interest-rate environment. Their major effect is not to protect
borrowers but to prevent them from obtaining the credit they need to
provide a home for their family.
Given a tn-part program along the lines outlined by NAMSB and
by the Council in its report, there is good reason to hope that the Na-
tion's crucial housing and urban revitalization goals can in fact be
`realized in the years ahead. Mutual savings banks, as the Nation's
leading suppliers of FRA and VA housing credit, have long been in
the forefront of urban renewal efforts and of Government programs to
provide housing for low- and moderate-income groups. Together with
the savings and loan industry, they are currently considering ways in
which the joint efforts of `both industries can be applied to meeting the
problems of our urban society in the years ahead. Passage of the Fed-
oral savings institutions bill would provide the logical framework for
such a joint thrift industry effort to advance the public interest.
PAGENO="0148"
NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT BUSINESS.
By C. WILSON IjARDEII, PRESmENT
Our comment will be based on information secured from the federa-
tion's annual economic surveys of its members in all 50 States. who
number now almost one quarter of a million independents. It will he
limited to points critical to the successful financial opera.tions of small
business.
We believe that small business, being the relatively more marginal
sector of our business structure, provides general lead indicators of
economic contraction and lag, but solidly confirmatory, indicators of
economic expansion. This theory has been borne out, in part at least,.
by experience during the past several years.
For instance, survey responses through 1964 to mid-1966 provided
indicators suggesting strong economic expansion. As we wrote to your
committee about this same time last year, however, about 1966, second
quarter, these indicators commenced suggesting a cresting out of the
rise. Later on in 1966, they showed definite signs of economic contrac-
tion, followed by a precipitous drop exiting 1966 and entering 1967...
Through 1967 the indicators drifted sidewise, bumping up and down
as against a ceiling.
Entering 1968, however, the response-January sample-provides.
mixed indicators.
On the one hand, there is tentative suggestion on the part of three
indicators-inventories higher than 1 year earlier, purchased equip-
ment during the past year, and receivables higher than 1 yea.r earlier-
of a renewal of the expansionary trend, with two of these three up
sharply from December 1967, levels. There is improvement in a fourth
indicator-that dealing with job formation.
On the other hand, there is continuing evidence of the mounting
cost squeeze reported through the past year. While 81 percent of Janu-
ary respondents reported cost of goods higher than 1 year earlier, and
78 percent reported labor costs higher, only 59 percent reported selling
prices higher than 1 year earlier. At the same time, interest rates
continued at the high 6.7 percent average characteristic of 1967. And
the proportion of respondents reporting collections slower thaii 1
year earlier stood at 34 percent, equal to the highest proportion of re-
spondents reporting difficulties with collections during the latter part
of 1966. Against all this, over half of these respondents reported their
business dollar volume the same as or lower than 1 year earlier-a
figure less favorable than in 1966, first quarter. Indicated spending on
plan and equipment continued falling.
Consideration of these factors, plus recognition of the additional
burdens placed on smaller business by social security tax increases,.
and State and local tax increases, leads the federation to question the
Council's position that "the economy is in a strong position to move~
(862)
PAGENO="0149"
863
Into its eighth year of uninterrupted expansion." As previously stated,
our behalf is that no recovery or expansion is solidly based until it
is shared in by the small business sector-and. we questi'on whether
small business is so sharing at present.
In view of the foregoing, we do not think this is quite the time to
rock the boat by enactment of the recommended across-the-board
surtax, the "improvement" in the unemployment compensation system,
and the further speedup in corporate tax payments, each and all of
which would definitely further drain the already strained resources of
small business.
For instance, based on data on hand concerning corporate* income
tax burdens, it would appear that `a 10 percent surcharge would in-
crease the cumulative financial liability of corporations with tax
liabilities of $5,500 or less by $110 million a year or more.
This is to say nothing of the burden that would be added to pro-
prietorships and partnerships. . It is to say nothing, either, of the fact
*that social security revisions of the past year are already increasing
`the employer's tax burden by a maximum $53.20 per employee. It
~must be kept clearly in mind that independents, according to the
Small Business Administration, employ-and pay social. security taxes
on-34,000,000 or more wage and' salary earners.
It seems to us, too, that these recommendations should be con-
sidered from the standpoint of what they will gain Government in
revenues against the damage they ~tand to do small business-which
has been likened, truly, to the' "seed-bed" of our economy. For ex-
ample, according to data available, 76 percent of all corporations have
`tax liabilities of $5,500 or less-these are typically the small business
corporations-but they account for only 5 percent `of corporate tax
payments. Intensification of the tax drain on these firms would. seem
much akin to squeezing theturnip dry.
Our Washington office is requesting that if corporate tax collections
be speeded up, there be provided an exemption for the first $25,000 of
lax liability. Such an exemption would shelter smaller firms which
account for between 87 percent and 98 percent of all corporations,
which average between $10,000 or less than $40,000 or less in tax lia-
bilities, but which account for only between 7 percent and 19 percent
of all corporate tax collections. This would seem small enough price
to pay for maintaining the financial stability of these firms which are
vital to our economy, but who stand to lose the most.
We might mention, that in seeking the exemption mentioned above,
the federation is not making a special plea for corporations at the
expense of proprietorships and partnerships. We are asking only for
maintenance of the status quo, and for recognition of the fact that
historically the corporate form of organization has been treated dif-
ferently taxwise from other forms of business organization.
Rather than acting on these recommendations of the council, we
would urge tha't action be taken to invigorate and strengthen small
business. Among the many things which must be done:
1. In order to ease current threats to small business liquidity,
pressures for higher taxes must be eliminated, and pressures on
interest rates relieved, through the deepest possible reductions in
Federal spending programs;
PAGENO="0150"
864
2. In order to improve the financial position of small business,
earliest possible attention must be given to "plowback" legisla-
tion, such as in H.R. 4105 (Corman, Calif.) applying to increases
in investment in inventories and accounts receivable;
3. In order to strength the job creating potential of small busi-
ness, insofar as the marginal and submarginal workers are con-
cerned, the minimum wage burden be eased by enactment of
H.R. 6967 (Anderson, Ill.) which would amend the Fair Labor
Standards'Act to maintain at $500,000 the annual volume test;
4. In order to stem the migration from rural to urban areas, job
opportunities must be enlarged in the former; to this end there
must be enacted legislation such as H.R. 9060 (Evins, Tenn.),
which would provide incentives for business expansions in rural
areas;
5. In order to provide a more equitable climate of competition
for small business growth, there must be enacted bills such as
H.R. 6843 (Patman, Tex.), which would require sellers to notify
their customers of changes in price schedules for any buyer, and
H.R.. 9048 (Patman, Tex.), which would make it possible for busi-
nessmen to sue for damages suppliers who violate the Robinson-
Patman Act by selling at unreasonably low prices; and
6. In order to provide more effective representation in the Con-
gress for small business, steps must be taken to raise both the
Senate and the House Small Business Committees to the status
of standing committees, with the same responsibility and authority
in their areas as are enjoyed.by. the Labor, Agriculture, and other
standing committees in their areas.
Finally, we commend the Council for its attention to the economic
adjustments which are bound to follow peace in Vietnam-a peace
which we hope will come sooner than anticipated. This is as we sug-
gested to both the President and the Council over 2 years ago.
PAGENO="0151"
NATIONAL FEDERATION OF INDEPENDENT BUSINESS-COMPARISON OF STATISTICS, 1966, 1967 AND 1968
1966 (cumulative)
1967 1968
(January)
1st quarter 2d quarter 3d quarter 4th quarter
1st quarter Half
3d quarter Full year
Business volume compared with 1 year ago:
Same percent.... 30 31 31 32 (1) (1) (t) (1) 26
Higher do -- - 51 48 48 47 (1) (1) (1) (1) 49 C)
Lower do...... 17 18 19 20 (1) (1) (1) (1) 24
Inventories compared with 1 year ago: Higher do... 40 39 39 36 23 23 23 23 32
Receivables compared with 1 year ago: Higher do...... 43 41 41 40 20 18 18 17 38
Purchased equipment during past year do...... 55 54 53 52 46 46 47 45 60
Difficulties with collections (1968 question: Are your collections slower than 1 year
ago?) percent... 30 32 34 31 (1) (1) (1) (1) 34
Employment same as 1 year ago do...... 69 71 69 70 72 73 71 70 70
Job formation indicator +2.7 +2.5 +2.2 +1.8 +0.8 +0.6 +0.3 +0.1 +0.5
Average additional investment in business billions... $9.2 $8.8 $9.6 $8.6 $10.9 $10.4 $9.9 $9.8 $7.5
1 Not availale.
PAGENO="0152"
UNITED AUTOMOBILE, AEROSPACE AND AGRICUL-
TURAL IMPLEMENT WORKERS OF AMERICA (UAW)
By WALTER P. REUTHER, PRESIDENT
There is an anxiety in the Nation, strangely mingled with com-
placency and an indifference to the unsolved social and economic
problems that contribute to our troubled mood. The President defined
the mood as restlessness and questioning in his state of the Union
message, and touched upon some of the reasons for it in listing a num-
ber of our persisting problems, including:
* * * the gulf for some Americans between the promise and the reality of
our society.
Stating that we could not "change all of this in a day," the President
added:
The issue is not whether we can change this; the issue is whether we will
change this.
I know we can. I believe we will.
In confronting these two gaps-the gap between promise and reality
and that between "can" and "will"-we rea.ch the heart of the Ameri-
can dilemma. It is inescapable. It crops up in every issue before the
Congress. It is implicit in every assumption underlying every budget-
.ary allocation. It surfaces on every page of the Economic Report. It
haunts our preoccupation with "crime in the streets"; it is at the center
of the racial crisis; it dominates the national debate over our proper
course in Southeast Asia.
It is not an economic dilemma, although it involves economic
`choices. It is not a. technological dilemma, although it has to do with
our response to the new technologies. It is not a military dilemma,
although it is expressed in our attitudes toward what President Eisen-
.hower called the military-industrial complex. It transcends partisan
political alinements, although all parties, major and minor, who
recognize its existence may claim a monopoly of wisdom in dealing
with it.
It presents itself to us in all these aspects because it permeates the
body and soul of the Nation. It is a crisis of values and purpose, of ends
and means. It poses the question: What kind of America do we really
want? It asks: What do we seek to do with the unprecedented wealth
and power at our disposal? It demands to know if we really believe in a
constitutional democracy with equal justice under law, or only in an
"I'm all right, Jack" regime of selfishness, a feudalism of special
interests in which the poorest and weakest among us are ignored, ne-
glected, or driven to the wall.
(866)
PAGENO="0153"
867
The answers cannot be indefinitely evaded or postponed, for several
good reasons:
1. The argument that we lack the resources to fulfill our com-
mitments is not valid.
2. The problems thrown up by our reckless and shortsighted
exploitation of science and technology do not go away. They re-
main, and worsen.
3. The victims of the gap between promise and reality are no
longer docile and reconciled to their fate. They impatiently de-
mand fulfillment of the promise. This is true in a double sense.
This wealthiest of nations has an unfulfilled responsibility to the
poor of our cities and rural areas and to the struggling peoples
of the have-not lands where peace depends on greater assurance
of social and economic development.
The rub here is not lack of progress, as doctrinaire extremists
allege. There has been much progress, and progress continues. The
rub lies in the relativity of progress. There is a revolution of rising
expectations here in the United States as well as in Africa, Latin
America, and Asia. It derives from a quickening sense on the part of
the poor, the deprived, and the discriminated against, concentrated
in our cities and scattered in rural areas, that science and technology
have put material affluence within the reach of all. That they are still
denied it, they now understand, is not the fault of science and tech-
nology but of economic policy and political decision.
The progress of recent years, while real, has constituted only a slow-
moving, marginal attack on poverty, unemployment and underemploy-
ment, inferior education and housing, the general deterioration of our
urban centers, and the patterns of discrimination and segregation
that keep racial and ethnic minorities from equal opportunity and
first-class citizenship. We are not moving fast or far enough to correct
the injustices and inequities that frustrate and embitter their victims
and divide our communities.
The presidential messages are replete with evidence of the volume
of unfinished business on the national agenda.
The President reminds us:
Despite o~ir prosperity, there are still niore than 10 million families whom we
classify as poor.
`~ * * whether we will move constructively to deal with the urgent problems
of our cities and compassionately to bring hope to our disadvantaged; or whether
we are willing to risk irreversible urban deterioration and social explosion.
With respect to unemployment, the President states:
The question for our day is this: in an economy capable of sustaining high
employment, how can we assure every American, who is willing to work, the
right to earn a living?
We have always paid lip service to that right. But there are many Americans
for whom the right has never been real ~ * *
The President notes that the United States ranks 1~th among the
nations of the world in saving the lives of babies. Regarding housing,
he reports:
New housing construction is far less than we need-to assure decent shelter
for every family.
PAGENO="0154"
868
Regarding our living environment, he tells us:
Many rivers-and the air in many cities-remain badly polluted.
Referring to the responsibilities of government in promoting the
general welfare, the President states:
I regard it as a primary purpose of government to expand the opportunities
for all citizens to share in our economic and social progress. For most, this means
the opportunity for rewarding employment. For millions who are retired, dis-
abled, or otherwise unable to seek active work, a share in prosperity requires
wise and humane programs of income maintenance and social insurance. For all,
it means full access to education and to health care.
This is an all-too-familiar inventory, partial and restrained, of the
flaws and anomalies that mark our state of general material affluence.
It understates the magnitude and urgency of our situation, because it
scants the elements in our dilemma which cannot be measured statisti-
cally-and because it takes insufficient account of the degree .to which
the life of the whole Nation, of affluent majority and deprived minority
alike, is improverished, degraded, and distorted by our common failure
to set our national house in order.
This common failure, and our awareness of it, are surely among the
chief sources of the spiritual disquiet that reigns among us, alienating
ghetto youth a.nd the youth of the affluent suburbs alike, infecting all
of us but the incurably complacent with an irritable frustration at the
thought that we, citizens of this wealthiest andmostpowerful of na-
tions, do not live up to the most elementary and fundamental of our
democratic professions and commitments.
This malaise lies deeper than governments, budgets and gross na-
tiolial product. Government alone cannot cure it. Yet governmental
leadership and initiative, governmental planning, and adequate
budgets to meet priorities, must inevitably play a key role in any
genuine, practical efforts to make America whole by coping with the
many problems that beset us.
What, then, are our true priorities? What must we do that we are
not doing to make America whole and to promote our true national
interest?
We have increasingly allowed ourselves to be ruled by two assump-
tions:
1. That the future of America is more at stake in the cities of
Vietnam than in the cities of the United States-to the point that
in the next fiscal year the Federal Government will be spending in
Vietnam-in 1 month-almost twice its contemplated annual out-
lay to improve the elementary and secondary education of children
from low-income families; and
2. That our outlay for war in Asia requires a reduction in our
commitment in Detroit, Newark, Watts, and the other American
centers of poverty, discontent and incipient rebellion.
Surely the greatest threat to American democracy today lies in our
failure here at home to sense our true priorities and to mobilize our
resources to keep our commitments to our own people.
Yet, whatever may be said of the first assumption-it is being venti-
lated in this election year-we should all be clear about the second; it is
false.
American wealth and power are unique in world history and in the
world today. There is enough wealth in this country, enough slack and
PAGENO="0155"
869
fat still in our economy, and enough leeway in the Federal budget-as
indicated below-to do what we are doing in Vietnam without gutting
and scuttling our domestic efforts to bring the benefits of democracy,
advancing technology, and rising productivity to the over 30 millions
of Americans who remain poor by conservative definitions.
Our preoccupation with Vietnam has offered a convenient and dra-
matic pretext for cutting back on domestic spending f or what until
lately were known as Great Society programs. The pretext was avidly
seized upon by those forces in the country and the Congress who
stubbornly resisted progressive social legislation long before our Viet-
nam involvement gave them what they regarded as a respectable
excuse. These forces instinctively look for militaristic solutions, at
home and abroad, to deal with problems which are essentially political
and social. Before this suicidal impulse brings catastrophe on all of us,
we should a~akeh to the fact that outlays for Vietnam amount to but
~3 percent of GNP. In the 97 percent that remains, our computers-
and our common sense-can certainly manage to identify a comparable
amount which can be diverted from less essential purposes to the high-
priority ends of saving America from large-scale disintegration and
chaos.
We have demonstrated over the past 7 years of economic growth
uninterrupted by recession that the so-called new economics gives us
the means to manage economic expansion. If we use, these tools with
precision and compassion to enhance the quality of American life-
rather than handling them as blunt instruments merely to raise total
production without regard to the social utility and human value of
its component parts-then there is no doubt that we can pay our way
toward the Great Society out of the annual increment in productivity
and GNP. An annual real GNP increase of 5 percent-a rate that is
well within our capabilities-would mean an increase in gross national
product of $150 per person. If this increase, instead of going indis-
~riminately to fat around our already comfortable middle, were chan-
neled into critical sectors such as jobs, housing and quality education
in our central cities, and income maintenance for those unable to work,
we could more than match our Vietnam outlay, and escalate the war
against poverty and despair in our own backyards.
We don't have to beat the Russians to the moon. We can wait a little
longer for supersonic transports. We can slow the pace of converting
the countryside into concrete. It has even been observed by some Sena-
tors that we can cut our troop strength in Europe without precipitat-
ing the end of the world-considering the fact that we and the Rus-
sians have long had enough destructive capacity in the form of nuclear
missiles to destroy each other many, many times over. We should also
draw back from the expensive fool's errand of seeking security from
a Chinese ICBM attack in the proposed ABM. defense system. As
analyzed by Ralph Lapp, long a nuclear specialist for the Defense
Department, the defensive possibilities of such a system are question-
able, and the Sprite missiles that would be used for atmospheric
interception pose the threat of wholesale mutilation and incineration
of our own population.
In addition to changing priorities and removing fat on the spending
side of the budget, attention could also be usefully devoted to the fat
PAGENO="0156"
870
on the revenue side. For what else are the notorious tax loopholes
which annually add to the riches of many of the richest among us and
cost the Government billions of dollars?
We can do these things, and more, to check the creeping demoraliza-
tion of our national spirit and make this Nation whole. We can change
our priorities and thereby divert resources to more essential purposes.
We can manage our economy to assure optimum growth, in order to
meet whatever commitments, at home or abroad, we deem essential.
Let us not delude ourselves, however, that these changes can he
made by continued recourse to the slapdash, piecemeal, business Key-
nesianism of the recent past, in which our essential benchmark has
been gross national product, whether increases in GNP came from
more napalm and cigarette advertising or from cleaner air and better
education. We need to plan according to a standard of social account-
ing in which our performance is measured not by the buying and
selling of the market but by such progress as the number of mothers
and babies we save at childbirth; the number of dropouts we prevent
or lure back to school; the number of decent homes we build in decent
neighborhoods; the number of children we rescue from malnutrition
in Mississippi or India; the number of job opportunities we create;
the number of sick we heal; the number of poor, here in America and
throughout the world, we help in their efforts to raise themselves
above the degrading experience of economic and spiritual poverty.
To plan for the purpose of improving the quality of life, govern-
ment must do more than step in when the private sector falters; we
must accept the need for a continuing, conscious guidance of invest-
ment and resource allocation in the public and private sectors, with
decisions democratically involving the regular participation of all
functional groups in the society. It is only through this kind of
deliberate, comprehensive yet democratic planning that we can have
assurance that both private and public needs will be met.
Large corporations not only plan, they are essentially planning
organizations. Democratic states, however, rarely went beyond piece-
meal planning except for the emergencies of war-until the devasta-
tion and massive dislocation of societies and economies brought on
by the Second World War forced at least the beginnings of compre~
hensive forms of planning on the nations of Western Europe. The
United States encouraged such planning as a necessary counterpart
of the Marshall plan, and cooperated in creating not only national
but international planning through the Organization for European
Economic Cooperation.
We have also encouraged forms of national planning as a. condi-
tion for allocation of our foreign aid in underdeveloped countries. We
continue, however, to live by the delusion that the United States is
the sole exception to the general rule that complex, dynamic, advanced
industrial (or post-industrial) societies must plan or invite equally
complex troubles.
The troubles we thus invited are upon us. They cannot be papered
over with good intentions or camouflaged by a bland recital of our
wealth and achievements. We will not be saved by past accomplish-
rnent.s, only by present decision and effort.
We must translate our good intentions into appropriate priorities.
We must plan to fulfill the promise of American life, or all our
PAGENO="0157"
871
wealth and power will not save us or serve a wholesome purpose in
the world.
America in this crisis must demonstrate the maturity and sophisti-
cation to free itself from the economic folklore that would have us
believe all the answers will be found in the wondrous workings of
the marketplace. Our marketplace economy has contributed much to
America's progress and continued major reliance upon its operation
is justified. However, exclusive reliance upon the blind forces of the
marketplace would be dangerous, irresponsible, and even disastrous.
We must recognize that no one is challenging or threatening our
economic system. A free society whose genius has achieved unity in
diversity must demonstrate the capability of making compatible public
planning to meet public needs with private planning for private gain.
If we should fail, the serious gap between private affluence and public
neglect will inevitably worsen and place our free institutions in grave
jeopardy.
BALANCE OF PAYMENTS
The main factor that today blocks .progress toward genuine full
employment and full use of our resources to meet our urgent national
needs is fear generated by the balance-of-payments deficit.
We in the UAW have repeatedly called attention to the exaggerated
emphasis the Council of Economic Advisers places on a deficit in the
balance of payments amounting to a fraction of 1 percent of the gross
national product. On reading certain parts of the Council's report it is
hard to resist the conclusion that there has been a reversal of two cen-
turies of progress in economic thought-a retreat from the new eco-
nomics to a new mercantilism in which the payments balance and the
stock of gold displace full~ employment, growth, and the proper alloca-
tion of resources as the prime concerns of economic policy.
Emphasis on the payments deficit as a major determinant of eco-
nomic policy is all the less justifiable for two reasons. First, the size
of the deficit in 1967 was based on an unusual combination of factors,
most of which are not likely to be repeated. Among them were trans-
actions connected with the devaluation of the British pound, a decrease
in exports due to the slowdown in the economies of our major trading
partners, and an increase in imports due to the copper strike and in
anticipation of a possible steel strike. Moreover, the war in Vietnam,
which hopefully is not to become a permanent feature of our national
life, accounted directly for more than two-fifths of the total deficit (on
a liquidity basis) and probably a significant additional proportion
indirectly.
Second, as President Johnson pointed out in his Economic Report,
we do not have a deficit in the true sense but rather a shortage of
liquidity such as a prosperous businessman might suffer who "has been
borrowing extensively at short term to help finance his long-term in-
vestments." Liquidity is measured essentially in terms of the national
stock of gold in relation to potential claims against it.
We do not agree that the United States must sacrifice the growth of
its economy, and the welfare of its people and those of the developing
countries, as well as its domestic tranquility, solely in order to conserve
its hoard of a myth-encrusted metal that has very few practical uses.
The time has come, in our judgment, to think-and to do-the unthink-
PAGENO="0158"
872
able in order to prevent mankind here and abroad from being crucified
upon a cross of gold-a phrase that. is becoming increasingly relevant
today even though it may not have been when first uttered.
We congratulate Congressman R.euss for his courage and imagina.-
tion in holding hearings of the Subcommittee on International Ex-
change and Payments of the Joint Economic Committee at which op-
portimity has been given for the presentation of bold proposals to win
freedom from the shackles of the gold myth. More particularly, the
Nation owes him a debt of gratitude for the daring he displayed, in
his press release of December 12, 1967, when he offered concrete pro-
posals to deal with the gold problem. Faithfulness to its obligations
under the Employment Act would require the Council to show com-
parable courage and imagination rather than retreat headlong into
advocacy of damaging, negative, and restrictive policies as solutions
for the payments deficit.
The position of the present members of the Council stands in sharp
contrast to that taken by two former members who made up the major-
ity of President Kennedy's original Council. Neither of them has been
afraid to suggest that serious consideration should be given to breaking
the link between the dollar and gold. Walter Reller, former Chairman
of the Council, wrote recently:
we need to think about the. unorthodox:
Perhaps we should go beyond saying that our $12 billion-plus of gold is
fully available to defend the dollar and, in effect, invites the world to "come
and get it" as a demonstration that the dollar is not only as good as, but
better than, gold.
Perhaps we also need to expose gold speculators, both official and unofficial.
to a down-side risk-one approach would remove our pledge to buy gold at
$35 an ounce (while maintaining our pledge to sell at that price) ."
This, in essence, is also the approach Congressman Reuss suggested to.
"dethrone" gold.
Former Council member James Tobin was quoted in the Wall Street
Journal for February 5, 1968, as saying:
The outlook for the world economy would be very much brighter today if the
dollar were once and for all cut loose from gold.
The Journal article continued:
Much more traumatic than the uncertain fluctuations of a floating dollar, say
Mr. Tobin and other analysts, are the financial disruptions caused by the cur-
rency devaluations-such as the recent devaluation of the pound-that periodi-
cally occur under the present monetary system. In passing, it is noted that the
Canadian dollar floated' freely for about a dozen years after World War II and
that Canada prospered greatly in those years. A further claim: Other countries
would not permit a floating dollar to depreciate drastically in relation to their own
currencies-as some authorities fear might happen-because such a dollar would
give Uncle Sam too great an advantage in world markets.
Without the "discipline" of gold, is it not likely that American politicans in
power would pursue dangerously inflationary economic policies? Not at all, say
some economists. "In effect, U.S. policy makers were under no constraint from
gold from 1933 until the late 1950s," claims Yale's Mr. Tobin. "Yet, the country's
economic policies were hardly reckless during that time." In those years, it is
noted, U.S. prices generally were more stable than those in any other major
country.
While not advocating complete elimination of gold from the world
monetary system, even so conservative a spokesman for the financial
community as the Chairman Martin of the Federal Reserve Board
PAGENO="0159"
873
agrees on the irrelevance of the gold "mystique and fetish" to economic
discipline. According to the New York Times, Mr. Martin said:
* * * that the United States "must not bow down to the idol of gold" as the
only discipline against inflationary national economic policy.
He scored the reliance on gold * * `~ as "the be-all and end-all" of national
monetary policies.
* * *
"I think it's barbarous to think that we haven't got the intelligence to manage
our economy so that we have to depend on a metal-this barbarous metal," he
said.
When confronted with restraints on capital exports-which affect
their interests-leading private bankers, also, have been led to ac-
knowledge that there are some things more important than the link
between the dollar and gold. Early in April 1967, the Chase Manhat-
tan Bank published a suggestion that ". . . the United States could
cease buying and selling gold." Two days later, President Rudolph A.
Peterson of the Bank of America suggested "a gold strategy that em-
braces a variety of tactics." One of the tactics was the same that pro-
posed by Congressman Reuss to "dethrone" gold. As Mr. Peterson put
it, this tactic:
* * * recognizes that, while we are committed to iñaintaining the gold value of
the dollar there is no over~vhelinin~ reason why we should sustain the dollar
value of gold; that is, we may have to reconsider our gold buying policy." [em-
phasis in original]
The ~roposal that the United States cease buying gold has highly
reputable academic origins. One means of implementing the proposal,
and some of its probable effects, were spelled out by Congressman
Reuss in the press release referred to above:
The United States could announce that all foreign monetary authorities hold-
ing dollars-which they have at least in part acquired as a result of the U.S.
commitment to turn them into gold-have a set period of time in which to demand
gold. This, announcement should be accompanied by an announcement that the
United States no longer agrees to buy gold at $35 an ounce, and u-ill not make
gold available for official dollar holdings to be acquired in the future. In all likeli-
hood, only a small fraction of the roughly $15 billion in official dollar holdings
would be presented for gold-because the future of the gold price would become
extremely dubious, and because most foreign official dollar holdings are neces-
sary either for current transactions or will be held because their holders have
confidence in the dollar, and wish to take advantage of the interest rate that is
payable on dollar holdings. The presentparity values of the dollar would then
be supported, under International Monetary Fund rules, not by gold but by ex-
change operations, just as all other exchange rates are now maintained.. If we
maintain an economy aimed at full employment without inflation, there is no
reason why the current exchange value of the dollar with other currencies can-
not readily be maintained. If France, for example, thinks that the dollar should
be devalued, let it press its position within the International Monetary Fund. I
doubt very much that it would wish dollar devaluation, since this would simply
cut down on American tourism into France, and on the sale of French wines and
perfumes in this country.
Under these circumstances it would soon become clear-perhaps
even to General do Gaulle-that, in Walter Holler's words, "the dollar
is not only as good as, but better than, gold." As the Chase Manhattan
Bank pointed out:
Gold has an intrinsic value far below that of the purchasing power of the dol-
lar. Yet, because of the belief that its official price might rise, gold is the only
international asset that can compete with the dollar. No sophisticated investor or
central banker, if he were certain that the price of gold in terms of dollars would
PAGENO="0160"
874
not be officially raised, would regard gold as a better store of value than the dol-
lar, which, in addition to its relatively stable purchasing power, also can be in-
vested to earn interest.
We concur with the bankers quoted above that there are some things
more sacred than the link between the dollar and gold. We would give
top priority, in that regard, to full employment, growth, and the allo-
cation of our resources to relieve poverty at home and abroad and to
improve the quality of life in America.
We are not prepared at this time to espouse any specific method
of divorcing the dollar from gold. We are convinced, however, that
study of alternative methods, and prompt action on the conclusions
that emerge from study, are matters of the highest urgency which
should be pursued with all possible speed and vigor.
A multilateral solution of -the gold problem, developed by, and
applied with the concurrence of, the great majority of nations, obvi-
ously would -be preferable to unilateral action by the United States.
But the auguries for such -an outcome are not favorable. Agreement
on the very modest reform of the international moneta-ry system repre-
sented by the creation of IMF Special Drawing Rights was slow and
painful in coming, has yet to be ratified, and is still further a-way from
implementation. A clearly expressed determination on the part of
the United -States to dethrone gold unilaterally-if it cannot be done
by international agreement-may be the cata-lyst required to induce
cooperation in working out an agreement.
Meanwhile, we emphatically re~ject the notion that the gold prob-
7cm requires adoption of a restrictive budget, which would deny or
delay solutions of pressing social problems.
We in the UAW have stressed repeatedly the necessity for a response
to the balance-of-payments deficit that would be compatible with the
Nation's domestic needs and goals a-nd its obligations to the peoples of
the developing countries. We have warned that the deficit must not
be met by a panicky retreat to restrictive and repressive fiscal and
monetary policies. We have urged instead that (primarily to eliminate
it as an excuse for such policies) the deficit be attacked by selective,
direct measures less costly in human hardship, economic waste, and
social disruption than restraints on domestic demand imposed while
we are still short of genuine full employment. In particular, we have
urged mandatory action to cut off the flow of capital exports to
industrialized countries.
The steps taken a-nd proposed by the President to reduce the deficit
conform, in general concept, to the prescription proposed by the UAW.
They are selective and they include controls on capital exports, both
direct investment and loans. Although we believe that the President's
measures could -be improved in a number of respects, they should pro-
vide all the breathing space necessary to permit us to push on toward
full employment while we work toward freeing the world from its
obsession with gold. In fact, one of the President's proposals, removal
of the gold cover requirement against Federal Reserve notes, could
be a useful first step toward dethroning gold. It would enable us to
follow the suggestions of Congressman Reuss and Walter Heller that
we invite the world to "come and get it." .
We do not intend to engage here in a detailed analysis of the Presi-
dent's package of balance-of-payments measures. A few brief com-
ments seem to be in order, however.
PAGENO="0161"
875
We regret that mandatory action with respect to capital exports
was so long delayed. Had the capital export controls been instituted
when we in the UAW first proposed them in March 1964, the cumula-
tive payments deficit of recent years would have been much smaller
and, in consequence, the Nation's international monetary reserves
would today be much larger There would therefore be less pressure
for repressive fiscal and monetary policies. IViloreover, the effects of
capital export controls on other developed countries which have relied
upon our deficits for their liquidity might have impelled them tO co-.
operate' sooner and more wholeheartedly both in reducing their pay-
ments surpluses (which are the obverse side of our deficits) and in re-
forming the international monetary system.
1~\Thile favoring effective controls on capital exports, we find it diffi-
cult to `understand some of the details of their present application.
liVe do not see why the military dictatorship in Greece is favored with
an exception from the prohibition against direct investment applicable
to the rest of non-Communist Europe. We question the necessity to
give the feudal oil-producing countries the same relatively liberal
treatment accorded to certain developed countries with special prob-
lems suôh as the' United Kingdom and Canada. We doubt the wisdom
of a fiat formula limitaiton on investment in the developing countries.
We believe it would be sounder to establish machinery for case-by-
case review of proposed investments in such countries, with approval
granted for investments which would contribute to development and
denied for those which are essentially exploitative. Considering the
reluctance of U.S. corporations to invest in developing countries,' it is
(unfortunately) unlikely that the aggregate capital' outflow under
such a review procedure would be significantly greater than under the
formula now in effect. But there would be less danger of hampering
the progress of some of the recipient nations. We hope the administra-
tion will reconsider these matters.
Insofar as the deficit~ on' tourism is concerned, we are in accord with
the administration's preference for restricting spending' abroad rather
than restricting freedom to travel. We believe, however, that more
equitable means could be applied to accomplish the desired result than
the tax measures that the administration has proposed. The proposed
tax on plane and ship tickets obviously would be uneven in its impact,
depending upon the income of the would-be traveler. It could deter-
and would most certainly restrict the extent of-travel by those with
low incomes, no matter how legitimate their reasons to travel. The tax
would have no effect at all upon the wealthy, no matter how frivolous
the purpose of their travel.
The proposed tax on spending abroad is a form of progressive
spending tax proposed later in this statement for application to the
domestic economy. It is questionable, however, whether the proposed
spending tax on tourists' is the most equitable ai~d effective measure
to restrict tourist spending. Much has been published already about
the difficulties of administering such a tax (difficulties that would not
apply to the Treasury `and UAW proposals outlined below) ; and the
wealthy will more easily find' the methods, and have readier access
to the means, for evasion than travelers in the low- and middle-income
brackets. Moi~eover, even the 30-percent top rate proposed would have
90-191-68--pt. 3-11
PAGENO="0162"
876
little or no effect on amounts spent by the wealthy. This point was
forcefully expressed by an executive of a travel agency, quoted in the
Wall Street Journal for February 6, 1968, who said:
It's not going to deter the Jet Set. . . They'll pay the tax. If you've got $1,000
a day income, what's the difference?
If the sole effect of the tax on the wealthy is to increase their con-
tributions to the U.S. Treasury, it will have failed to accomplish its
purpose. The objective is not to raise revenue, but to deter excessive
tourist spending.
`While administrative difficulties will beset any attempt to restrain
tourist spending, we believe a search should be made for alternatives
to the administration proposal that would be both more likely to
achieve the intended purpose and more evenhanded in their impact
upon individuals at different income levels. One device that deserves
consideration is setting a reasonable flat limit on the amount per-
mitted to be spent per day abroad, with fines heavy enough to hurt
(perhaps expressed as percentages of the traveler's total annual in-
come) for each day spent on any trip during which the average daily
amount spent exceeded the the limit. The flat limit would apply equit-
ably to all, while the severe penaltlies involved would help to deter
evasion. In a democratic society, the need to restrain tourist spending
does not remove the requirement that any form of restraint must apply
equitably to all citizens, regardless of income.
The details of measures applied to reduce the payments deficit,
however, are far less important than a clear understanding, by the
piThlic and in Government circles, that. the deficit need not and should
not inhibit us in the pursuit of our national goals. The strength of
the dollar depends upon the strength of the American economy. Peo-
ple and governments all over the world will continue to want dol-
lars-whether or not exchangeable for gold-so long as those dollars
will buy American goods and services. This does not mean that we
are free of any necessity to seek to maintain reasonable price stabil-
ity. Avoidance of inflation is desirable for reasons more important.
than the payments balance. But we should not forget that the record
of U.S. prices compared with those of other countries shows that the
dollar is a better store of value than any other important national
currency-and, in most cases, by a wide margin.
We learned during the past 7 years that the sacrifices of wealth and
jobs and the welfare of our people made during the 1950's in mis-
guided efforts to avoid deficits in the Government budget were wholly
unnecessary. It is time now that we learn the same lesson about the
payments deficit.
THE Couxcir4's NEGATIVE PoLIcIEs
The fixing of national priorities is essentiai if we are to make an
effective attack on our pressing problems. Yet the fixing of priorities
will not by itself a.ssure rapid progress toward our goals. For that
we need positive policies directed towa.rd maximum sustainable
growth. Although much can be accomplished by reallocation of exist-
i7hg resources in accordance with national priorities, vigorous growth
provides additional resources with which to attack priority needs.
But growth cannot be sustained if income imbalances are permitted
to arise which cause misallocation of resources and the generation of
PAGENO="0163"
877
inflationary pressures which lead, in turn, to repressive and restric-
tive policies. Positive policies are needed to assure that growth is;
vigorous and sustained, and that it proceeds in balanced fashion.
The policies advocated by the Council, unfortunately, have beem
negative on both counts. The Council has consistently tended to be~
less expansionary or more restrictive than the economic circumstances-
of the time required. It has advocated a negative wage policy (as weliL
as certain tax measures) that have encouraged imbalances in income
distribution. Those imbalances have contributed toward unsustain-
able investment and inventory booms which facilitated and stimu-
lated inflationary price increases; and fears of further inflation were
made the basis for more restrictionism.
RESTRICTIVFJ EMPLOYMENT POLICY
The Council has always been more afraid of possible inflation that
of existing unemployment. True, the Council has given recognition
to the goals of full production and full employment, but the Council's
fear of seeing the economy move forward as far or as fast as it could
have been implicit in the policies it has advocated, at least for the past
several years. It was in 1962 that Council first proposed an "interim
goal" of reducing unemployment to 4 percent-it then stood at close to
6 percent. This reduction the Council expected to see achieved by
mid-1963, but the economic policies actually followed, largely on the.
advice of the Council, did not succeed in reducing unemployment to the
4 percent level until the beginning of 1966.
Even then, it is questionable whether the reduction of unemployment
to 4 percent was due to the policies of the Council as much as to events
in Vietnam completely outside its control or its ability to forecast. In
its 1968 Report, summarizing economic developments of that period,
the Council says:
Around mid-1965, the growth of demand for industrial products suddenly
accelerated as the direct and indirect consequences of the enlarged commitment
of U.S. forces in Vietnam. Manufacturing output and employment spurted
sharply in the last quarter of 1965 and the first quarter of 1966, and continued
to rise steadily through most of 1966.
Early in 1966 the Council was beginning to back away from the goal
of further reductions in the unemployment rate. It did not quite call for
acceptance of 4 percent unemployment, but it did suggest "prudent
reduction in the unemployment rate to a level below `~. per~enJ-"
and "a cautious move toward lower unemployment . . ."
By .1967 the Council h'ad fully retreated from the goal of reducing
unemployment below 4 percent, and had indeed announced that 4
percent unemployment constituted "essentially full employment." The
first paragraph of its report read:
The United States in 1966 enjoyed the benefits of the fullest employment in
more than a decade. The unemployment rate reached a 13-year low of 3.9 percent.
At. that level, demand finally matched supply in most labor markets, a situation
which most economists define `as essentially "full employment."
Subsequently, in discussing the economic outlook for 1967, the
Council said:
PAGENO="0164"
878
Finally and most important, the Nation should continue to experience sub-
stantially full employment in 1967. The unemployment rate should be essentially
the same as in 1966, when it averaged 3.9 percent. V
The Council's forecast was correct. in both 1966 and 1967 the final
figure for average unemployment was 3.8 peVrcent rather than 3.9,
but the difference represented merely a change in the statistical method
of counting the unemployed. V V V V
In 1968, the Council has reaffirmed its contention thaVt 4 percent
uiiernployment constItutes "full employment." As in previous years,
it has accepted the concept; that "potential GNP" can be achieved with
4 perceiit Of the labor force still unemployed, and it forecasts that
in 1968, if it.s advice is accepted, "the unemployment rate for the year
as a whole should be essentially unchanged from its present level."
Ironically, this prediction is made in the face of achievements that
should make possible a continuing reduction in the unemployment
rate. In its 1962 Report the Council said: V
V If we i~nove firmiy to reduce the impact of structural unemployment, we will
be able to move the unemployment target steadily from 4 percent to successively
lower rates.
~A majOr purpose of the various manpower programs is to reduce
structural causes of unemployment. This year's report of the Council
says: V
In the last four years, manpower programs tailored to the needs of the eco-
nomically disadvantaged have been greatly expanded. During the fiscal year
1968, close to a million persons, most of whom are disadvantaged, will be served
by the Manpower Development and Training Act, the Job Corps, and similar
programs. V V
According to the budget, the number served in fiscal 1967 was even
larger-1,062,000. Granted that these programs are not 100 percent
effective, nevertheless they should have made considerable impact on
the structural problems which the Council considered in 1962 to be
the major obstacle tO be overcome before we could expect to "move
the unemployment target steadily from 4 percent to successively lower
rates." VV V
WE HAVE OPPOSED SUCH NEGATIVISM
The IJAW has consistently opposed this negativistic approach. As
early as 1962 I said to this committee:
The programs presented to Congress by the present Administration to estab-
lish a national purpose and meet the needs of our people represent a vigorous
and imaginative advance in leadership, both in terms of restoring health and
strength to our economy and of finding compassionate answers to the needs of
human beings in trouble. But even those programs fail to comprehend either the
full magnitude of the problems we face or the full dimensions of our potentalities.
We have raised our national sights, bitt we have not raised theia nearly enough.
We are still aiming far too low. We are still accepting ideas of what the economy
can and should do at levels which fall far short of our true capacity, levels which
would leave far too much of our productive resources, both human and phy-
sical, unused or underused. [Emphasis added.] V
Those words could be repeated today, except that, if we accept the
advice of the Council of Economic Advisers, we are no longer rais-
ing our sights. We are decla~ring that they are already high enough.
And behind that declaration lie policy proposals which will mean in
practice that we are lowering our sights, that we are prepared to re-
strict our growth and to see unemployment rise again.
PAGENO="0165"
879
COUNOIL~S WAGE POLICY NEGATIVE
A second negative aspect of .the policies advocated by the Council
is its wage policy-which has contributed to imbalance in the dis-
tribution of income and, in consequence, to other distortions in the
economy. There is no need to repeat here at this time the battle of the
guideposts. Suffice it to say that the Council has consistently insisted
that, in order to achieve price stability, labor must be prepared to
accept an annual rate of increase in current dollar wages no greater
than the trend rate-variously defined from time to time as suits the
Council's purposes-in national output per man-hour.
True, in this year's report the Council does admit that:
In calling for restraint in wage and price decisions, the Council recognizes
that, in 1968, as in 1967, it would clearly be inappropriate to set the trend of
productivity as a numerical target for wage increases. In the face of the 3-percent
increase of consumer prices that occurred during 1967, it would be patently
unrealistic to expect labor to accept increases in money wages which would repre-
sent essentially no improvement in real hourly income."
However, the Council continues:
Nevertheless, despite the justification .for compensation increases in excess
of the productivity trend, such increases are inevitably inflationary. As the
Council stated in its 1967 Report:
"The only valid and noninflationary standard ~for wage advances is the pro-
ductivity principle. If price stability is eventually to be restored and maintained
in a high-employment U.S. economy, wage settlements must once again conform
to that standard.~'
In other words, the Council reaffirms, price stability can be restored
and maintained oniy if labor is prepared to permit its share of pro-
ductivity advance to be eroded away by the price increases currently
taking place. Behind .its position lies the implicit assumption that,
although money wage increases in excess of the rate of productivity
advance must push prices up, the reverse is not necessarily true-
price increases need not be reflected in corresponding wage increases.
This insistence that labor must bear all the sacrifices required to re-
store price stability has been a cornerstone of the Council's wage policy.
It continues to be so. Thus, for example, although the Council in this
year's report discusses the guidepost question under the heading, "In-
comes policies," and in the opening paragraphs gives passing recogni-
tion to the principle that such policies should apply to "industry, labor,
and possibly other groups," as soon as it gets into the substance of :the
discussion, everything is focused on wages, and the necessity for a
policy that will apply to the incomes of "other groups" than labor is
forgotten. The Council continues to ignore the crucially important
point made by the President's Advisory Contrnittee on Labor-Manage-
ment Policy, which, on August 18, 1966, in a report on the Council's
guideposts, said:
We believe that in a free society any policy to achieve price stability will be
acceptable and effective only if it bears equitably on all forms of incomes.
The Council's contrary attitude is best illustrated in the bland, non-
judgmental manner in which it describes the sharp `and sustained in-
crease in cost of medical services. Treating the doctors as tenderly as
any doctor ever treated a patient, the Council makes elaborate detours
to avoid arriving at the essential point: physicians as a group-al-
though with honorable exceptions-seized upon the introduction of
medicare and medicaid to increase their fees unconscionably. The Wail
Street Journal for February 27, 1968, recites in appalling detail how
PAGENO="0166"
880
doctors, including those who opposed the legislation, have taken ad-
vantage of medicare and medicaid to enrich themselves.
This is a clear case of one group, with maximum power to make
unilateral price decisions, using that power to take `advantage of a
market situation for its own benefit, and in so doing perverting the
purpose `of an essential socia.l reform. The Council passes no judgment
whatsoever. But when organized workers attempt merely to protect
their `standards of living and their share in advancing productivity
against the inroads of just such price increases, the Council condemns
their action as "inevitably inflationary."
The matter of salaries pa.id to corporate executives is also pertinent.
The Council is troubled by the fact that average hourly employee
compensation-wages, fringe benefits, and employer contributions for
social insurance-for all employees in the total private economy rose
6 percent in 1967. Included in, and affecting the size of that figure, is
executives' compensation about which the Council, to our knowledge,
has never uttered a word or offered a single statistic. The Wall Street
Journal for February 27, 1968, however,reports on a survey of execu-
tives' salaries in 600 companies which show that such salaries far out-
distanced the average worker's gains in 1967 and have done so for
many years. The survey, according to the Journal:
* * * shows management salary increases last year averaged the lowest since
1961.
How low was that? The Journal went `on to say tha:t the survey:
* * * put the average executive pay boost at 8.7 percent, down from' 10.8
percent in each of the prior two years.
Executives' salaries are included not only in "employee compensa-
tion" but also in the `Colmcil's figures on unit labor costs. According to
the Council's theory, therefore, such sizable increases in executives' pay
must have contributed to the upward movement of prices. Why, then,
does the Council reserve its admonitions about "inflationary" wage
gains exclusively for lower echelon workers-particularly organized
workers?
LABOR COSTS DID NOT TRIGGER INFLATION
Implicit in the Council's approach is the assumption that if only
workers would accept money wage increases in line with the rate of
productivity advance, without insisting on compensation also for
rises in living costs, then the upward pressure on prices would be
relieved and price stability would `be quickly achieved and easily main-
tained. If that were not implicit in the Council's approach, it would
mean that the Council was not asking labor to accept a temporary
sacrifice, but rather a permanent sacrifice of part of its share of ad-
vancing productivity `to compensate for the actions of others in con-
tinuing to force up prices.
Yet, table 18 of the Council's own report makes it clear that prices
from 1947 to 1966 in fact rose consistently faster than-or despite
declining-unit labor costs, both in the private domestic nonfa.rrn
economy as a whole, and in all but one of the major industry divisions.
For the period as a whole, in the total private domestic nonfarm
economy, the table shows that unit labor costs rose at an average rate
of 2 percent per year, while prices rose at an average rate of 2.2 percent
per year. For each of the subperiods it also shows that overall prices
rose 0.2 percent per year faster than unit labor costs.
A difference of 0.2 percent may seem small, `but this `is a cumulative
PAGENO="0167"
881
figure. It means that over the entire period prices rose by over 7
percentage points more than unit labor costs. The BLS release from
which the data were taken shows that for the period, while unit
labor costs rose only 45 percent, unit nonlabor costs, rncluding profits
and interest, rose by 65.5 percent-almost half again as fast. As a
result, prices as measured by the GNP deflator rose 52.1 percent.
Of the nine industry divisions shown in the Council's table-in five,
prices rose faster than unit labor costs for the entire period; in two
more, prices rose even though unit labor costs fell; in one, prices rose
at the same average rate as unit labor costs; and in one, prices rose a
little more slowly than unit labor costs.
Since there were nine major industry divisions and three subperiods,
there were industry data for a total of 27 subperiods. In six sub-
periods, prices rose even though unit labor costs fell; in one, prices
averaged no change while unit labor costs fell; in 10, both rose, but
prices rose faster; in one, both fell, but unit labor costs fell faster.
Prices either rose faster or failed to fall as fast as the movement of unit
labor costs would have justified. In two more, both rose at the same
rate, and in seven, unit laibor costs rose faster than prices.
Nothing in these data suggests that, if unit labor costs had remained
stable, prices would also have achieved an equal stability, or that, in
industries where unit labor costs fall, price reductions can also be
counted on.
PRICE BOOSTS PRECEDED LABOR COST INCREASES
A unique opportunity to determine whether it is prices or wages
that initiate the upward movement of a price-wage spiral is to be found
in the relationship between wholesale prices of manufactured goods
and unit labor costs in manufacturing over the past several years,
because the upward movement of prices which began to accelerate early
in 1965 did so from a condition of almost complete and long-sustained
price and labor costs stability.
As shown in the chart on the following page, from the middle of 1958
through August 1964, both prices and unit labor costs were remarkably
stable. During this period, wholesale prices of manufactured goods
rose only 0.9 percent, from an index of 100.1 (1957-59100) in July
1958 to 101 in August 1964. Prices had in fact been relatively stable
even prior to July 1958, but unit labor costs had shown some fluctua-
tion due to the adverse effects of the 1957-58 recession on productivity.
By July 1958, however, these fluctuations had diminished, and be-
tween July 1958 and August 1964, while more volatile than prices-
because of both statistical error and productivity changes associated
with changes in volume and rates of capacity utilization-unit labor
costs fell by 0.6 percent, from 100.3 (also 1957-59= 100) at the begin-
ning of the period to 99.7 in August 1964, and during this time fluctu-
ated only between a low of 97.5 and a high of 102.8.
After August 1964, however, the picture changed drastically. Prices
began to rise, slowly at first, then more rapidly. By July 1966 prices
had reached 106.4, an increase of 5.3 percent.
Unit labor costs, however, continued to remain stable, and even
to fall farther for a time. In July 1965 they stood at 98.6, 1.1 percent
below the August 1964 level. By March 1966 they were still only at
99.9, only two-tenths of 1 percent above August 1964. After that, how~
PAGENO="0168"
882
ever, they began to rise more rapidly as workers found it necessary
to compensate for rising living costs. Between March 1966 and Janu-
ary 1967, unit labor costs rose 4.9 percent. The rise continued in 1967,
but this was in considerable part due to the sharp falling off in the
rate of productivity increase resulting from the 1967 economic slow-
down.
The picture is remarkably clear. After nearly 6 years of stable prices
and actually declining unit labor costs, prices began to rise. The cause
certainly was not wages, since unit labor costs had been falling. For
more than a year after prices had begun to rise, unit labor costs re-
mained stable, but eventually they also began to rise. Quite clearly,
it was not wages that pushed up prices, it was prices that pulled up
wages. If the Council of Economic Advisers had been as assiduous in
discouraging unnecessary price increases as it has been in discourag-
ing quite justifiable and, in fact, necessary wage increases, the price-
wage spiral might never have started on its upward course.
WhoIesi~'h~ Prices of Manufactured Goods
a~d Unit Labor C@sts in Manufacturing
1957-1959.100
July 1958 - December 1967
Data: BLS Handbook of Labor Statistics. 1967;
Bureau of the Census, Business Cycle Dou'e!oprents, January 1908
PAGENO="0169"
883
CONTRIBUTION TOWARD IMBALANCE
The Council's negative wage policy contributed to an imbalance as
between income from employment and income from property. (This
imbalance was compounded by the tax reduction of 1964 which favored
corporations and the wealthy, liberalized depreciation treatment, and
the investment tax credit.). As a result, profits (and corporate and
upper bracket family savings) soared. The sharp increase in profits
stimulated and financed an unsustainable investment boom. When
matters threatened to get out of hand, monetary policy intervened
to put on the brakes with drastic adverse effects upon growth and upon
high-priority spending for housing and by State and local govern-
ments. The inflationary spiral had gathered momentum, however, and
the Council now calls for the blunt instrument of a tax surcharge to
slow it down.
DEFECTS OF AGGREGATIVE APPROACH
The distortions and imbalances that have led the Council to urge
negative and restrictive policies are in large `part the result of the blunt
instrument approach to guidance of the economy. Monetary and fiscal
measures have been framed, advocated, and' applied primarily on the
basis of their effects on the level of total demand and the size of total
GNP. The Council has tended to be concerned mainly with how much
was being produced without paying enough attention to what was
being produced, for what purpose it was being used, and who was
getting it.
When, as in the early 1960's, expansion was the goal, the main policy
instrument was a tax cut-without too much concern as to the distri-
bution of the benefits. As already noted, corporations and families in
the upper income brackets got the lion's share both of the tax cut and
other tax changes. When, partly as a result `of the nature of'those tax
measures, investment began to get out of hand and the price level be-
gan to rise, the blunt instrument of monetary policy was brought into
play by the Federal Reserve Board. When tight money plunged hous-
ing into a depression, hampered State and local governments in ful-
fillment of their obligations, threatened to strangle many small busi-
nesses, and began to stifle growth-without accomplishing very much
in the way of retarding price increases-the Council responded with
advocacy of another blunt instrument. According to both last year's
and this year's reports, an across-the-board tax surcharge is the sover-
eign remedy for what ails the economy.
What is forgotten in the concern with aggregates-total demand and
total GNP-is that distortions and imbalances can accompany either a
planned step-up or a planned slow-down of the overall rate of growth.
Balanced growth and, in particular, protection of the priority areas
of the economy, requires attention to the composition as well as the
total of demand and GNP.
A long list could be made of the distortions, imbalances, and set-
backs to priorities resulting from inattention to the composition of
demand, while gross monetary and fiscal policies were applied in an
effort to manipulate the total. The following arc a few examples.
DISTORTIONS OF INCOME DISTRIBUTION
A major imbalance has resulted from the distortion of the income
distribution which has favored property incomes at the expense of
PAGENO="0170"
884
labor incomes and has favored wealthy individuals and big corpora-
tions at the expense of those with small and moderate means.
Department of Commerce data show that, between the second quar-
ter of 1960-the peak of the last previous expansionary period-and
the third quarter of 1967, employee compensation in private industry
rose by 55.9 percent. But in the same period corporate profits after
taxes rose by 69.4 percent, dividends rose by 73.3 percent, and per-
sonal interest income surged upward by 102.2 percent. As we pointed
out in making a similar comparison for this committee a year ago,
the discrepa.ncy was even greater for the period from the second quar-
ter of 1960 to the second quarter of 1966, because subsequently the
pressure of rising living costs finally forced wages up at a faster pace.
In addition, the business slowdown of 1967, a consequence of the im-
balances which had developed in the economy, resulted in some drop
in profits.
DISTORTION IN RESOURCE ALLOCATION
The distortion in income distribution has led in turn to imbalances
in the allocation of resources. Typically, increases in incomes of those
with small or moderate means go primarily into increased consumer
spending. Wealthy individuals, on the other hand, already have suffi-
cient income to meet their personal needs, and corporations do not en-
gage in consumer spending at all-if you except expense account
spending and similar indulgences extended to top executives. Thus,
increased incomes of wealthy individuals and corporations primarily
go to increased investment, both at home and abroad, or into specula-
tion or savings, neither of which add to the stream of job-creating
demand.
This is not to say that investment is not per se as economically use-
ful a.nd necessary as consumer spending; of course it is. But the two
must be kept in balance in order to provide market outlets for addi-
tions to supply resulting from investment. It is no coincidence that,
as a result of failure to achieve balance, our economy repeatedly suf-
fers from the chills and fevers of insufficient consumer spending not
adequately offset by Government spending and unsustainable booms
in investment and inventory speculation which collapse into recession.
The overall results have been slower growth than we should have en-
joyed; higher and longer lasting unemployment than we should have
suffered; and substantial underutilization of our productive capacity.
As the year 1967 began, we had just emerged from 3 years during
which business fixed investment grew twice as fast as GNP, and an
unprecedented rise in business inventories. A collapse was avoided
(although we did go through what has come to be called a mini-
recession); but rates of capacity utiliza.tion fell sharply; and unem-
ployment was on the rise during the first 10 months of the year. Now,
although capacity utilization is still low and many workers still idle,
the Council, anticipating a repetition of the old familiar pattern,
feels it necessary to advocate a tax surcharge to head off a new, unsus-
tainable burst of business spending on plant, equipment, and inven-
tories.
BALANCE-OF-PAYMENTS EFFECTS
Not all of the excessive income siphoned off into corporate treas-
uries and upper bracket family accumulations during the past 7 years
has gone into domestic investment. In recent years there has been a
PAGENO="0171"
885
persistent outflow of capital for investment in other developed `coun~
tries which has contributed substantially toward our balance-of-pay-
ments difficulties. Clearly there has been a misallocation of resources
resulting from the basic maldistribution of income as between those
who primarily spend and those who primarily save, invest, and spec-
ulate.
SHORTAGE OF HOUSING
Another serious distortion to which monetary policy, in particular,
has contributed is the chronic shortage of housing-certainly one of
our top-priority needs-and the failure of the economy to remedy it.
In his first "state of the Union" message, on January 30, 1961, Presi-
dent Kennedy said:
Twelve long years after Congress declared our goal to be "a decent home and
a suitable environment for every American family," we still have 25 million
Americans living in substandard homes.
And, in his budget message this year, President Johnson said:
Most Americans lead a comfortable life, in comfortable homes and comfortable
surroundings. But millions of families are still crowded into housing unfit to live
in, located in squalid surroundings, and burdened with wornout facilities and
inadequate services. Without some assistance and the development of new tech-
niques, our private economy cannot now provide good housing at costs these
families can afford.
It is true that some progress has been made, but not nearly enough.
The report of the Council, after summarizing the developments of the
past 17 years, states:
Despite these developments, the number of occupied dilapidated units appar-
ently declined by less than 100,000 a year in the 1950's, and by only about 60,000 a
year in the 1960's. Moreover, virtually all of this decline occurred outside metro-
politan areas. Detailed data for the 1960's are not available for most areas, but
surveys of New York City and some areas in Los Angeles indicate an actual
increase in the number of occupied dilapidated units in those cities. The results
suggest that, in large cities, much of the improvement in housing quality from new
building in excess of the rate of household formation is offset by the deteriora-
tion of existing housing.
In other words, construction of new housing, especially in our large
cities, has not been sufficient to offset the combined effects of population
growth and deterioration of existing housing.
Nor is the situation improving. The trend line (computed by the
method of least squares) for private nonfarm housing starts actually
declined between 1960 and 1967 at a rate averaging approximately
one-half of 1 percent per year. The number of private nonfarm hous-
ing starts in 1966 was the lowest in 20 years, and the 1967 rate was
lower than that of all but 3 of the last 20 years.
The problem is not merely one of dilapidated and substandard hous-
ing, but of insufficient housing, resulting in overcrowding. The 1960
Census of Housing showed that 11.5 percent of occupied housing units
were overcrowded to the extent of having more than one person per
room. But we are not even approaching a remedy for this problem.
According to the data in the Council's 1968 report, the country's total
stock of housing increased between 1960 and 1966 by an amount barely
sufficient to keep pace with population growth. Our total housing stock
increased by 9.5 percent, but our population grew by 9 percent.
The housing problem is not a problem of the poor alone, as President
Johnson recognized in his budget message when he called for a new
PAGENO="0172"
886
program to build 6 million new housing units "for low- and middle-
income families" over the next 10 years. The fact is that housing has
become so expensive that many families with moderate incomes have
been priced right out of the market, while many more have had to
settle for smaller, less adequate, quarters than they actually needed.
There are numerous causes of our failure to produce houses m the
numbers needed and at reasonable prices. They include the depreda-
tions of land speculators, obsolescent local building codes, and obsolete
technology in the construction industry. But a major cause of the
shortage of decent housing is the devc&stating effect of gross monetary
policy upon the housing market.
Housing is perhaps the classic example of the defects of the blunt
instrument approach. The money managers are motivated to tighten
the money supply and to raise interest rates by what they consider an
excess of aggregate demand. But tight money and high interest rates
do not operate evenhandedly upon all components of the aggregate.
Home construction is the most vulnerable victim.
The enormous backlog of unfilled needs for housing is without ques-
tion attributable in large part to efforts to regulate total demand in the
economy by raising interest rates and restricting the supply of credit.
These actions periodically ph.mge housing starts to recession and even
depression levels-both by restricting the availability and by raising
the cost of credit. The impact of what may seem like small increases in
interest rates upon the cost of housing is often not fully appreciated.
A family which can afford to pay only $100 per month in principal
and interest payments, for example, could finance a 30-year mortgage
of approximately $15,670 at the present FHA maximum interest rate
of 6½ percent (including insurance premium). Raise the interest rate
to 8 percent, and the same monthly payment will ffna.nce a mortgage
of only $13,510-over $2,100 less.
It is no coincidence tha.t the rising interest rates of the past 2 years
(and the monetary cnmch of 1966) have been accompanied by a sharp
decline in private housing starts from the levels of the preceding
3 years.
Yet, despite the urgent national need for housing, indiscriminate use
of the tight money and high interest brakes is still widely regarded as
an appropriate instrument of economic policy.
OTHER DISTORTIONS AND IMBALANCES
Other distortions and imbalances, not only in the economy as such
but in the whole fabric of our national society, have resulted from our
failure to recognize that the structure of demand is important as well
as the volume of demand. This is true both of the balance between pri-
vate and public demand, and of the composition of demand within each
sector. It may be that the spending of $100,000 on a luxury yacht will
in the long run create as many jobs as if the same amoi.mt were spent
on a new school addition, or diverted by taxation to raise the incomes
of the poor, but the value to society will he far different. The expendi-
ture of some billions of dollars to put a man on the moon or la.nd a. ship
on Mars may have the same effect on the national budget and on the
volume of total demand as using the same money to help remodel our
PAGENO="0173"
887
cities, but the social consequences will not be the same. As was said
earlier, this country has got its priorities out of order. It is time we put
them right.
PuiomTlEs REQUIRE `SELECTiVE MEASURES
Priorities in themselves are not enough. They are nothing more than
expressions of good intentions if they are unaccompanied by effective
tools to assure that priority needs do, in `fact, exert priority claims
upon resources. The aggregative fiscal and monetary policies of the
new economics obviously are not the refined tools required to channel
resources toward fulfillment of our priority purposes. Seven years of
experience with the new economics has proved that a government
applying the aggregative approach can determine how much is pro-
duced. But aggregative policies rely on the `blind forces of the market-
place to determine what is produced, for what purpose, and by whom
it is used. Those forces thave not served us well. Our national affluence
is misal:located, and that misallocation is reflected in, among other,
things, the discontents, anxieties, frustrations and social tensions th~t
pervade our society, and the persistence of poverty, the spread of
environmental pollution, and the condition of our `cities.
Our national priorities can be made meaningful and given practical
effect only through development and use `of `a kit of selective economic,
tools adequate to shape `the composition and distribution of demand
and `therehy `of production. Monetary and fiscal measures need `not be
used `as `blunt instruments. They can be applied selectively and they
can be supplemented by other `types of measures to guard the health
and stability of the economy `and to assure that priority `needs will be
met before demands of lesser `urgency.
Our government has not hesitated to apply selective mone.tary and
fiscal policies for certain purposes. `Consumer credit controls, which
restrict spending by low- but not by high-income families, provide an
example of a selective `monetary measure `which has been used. The
investment tax credit is a selective fiscal measure designed to channel
an increased flow of resources into `business investment. The oil dep'le-.
tion allowance is not only a machine `for `making Texas millionaires `but
also `a `selective tax measure defended by those who benefit from `it as
necessary to channel resources `into exploration a'nd drilling f'o'r oil.'
It is also true that there is a degree of selectivity in the effects of
every fiscal and monetary action-even though often unintended and
not infrequently in conflict with other objectives sought by govern-
ment.
In the case of `fiscal measures, the economic impact `of government
spending will be affected by what the Government buys, and the impact
of taxation will be determined by who is taxed and what form the
taxes take. A tight money policy is selective in that it has an impact on
vulnerable industries such as housing and on the plans of State `and
local governments out of all proportion to its effect on, say, the plans
of major corporations which are largely able to finance new invest-
ment from internal sources. What we have lacked, however, is a con-
sistent policy designed to make deliberate use of selective fiscal and
monetary measures so as to achieve predetermined goals based on a
carefully-thought-out set of economic and social priorities.
PAGENO="0174"
888
It is not our purpose in this statement to enumerate and to describe
in precise terms all the tools that should be in a kit of selective fiscal
and monetary measures. We seek instead merely to show that we need
not remain prisoners of market forces and that selective measures can
be devised which are fully compatible with freedom. Outlined below
are a number of suggestions (which could undoubtedly be improved
upon) intended to illustrate those points. These suggestions are de-
signed to guide the flow of resources rather than to coerce individuals.
Other illustrations, with particular pertinence at this moment, are
presented later in this statement as alternatives to the proposed income
tax surcharge-which seems to be directed mainly toward preventing
an unsustainable investment boom.
- INVESTMENT RESERVE FEND
Restraining unhealthy investment booms, however, is only half the
job of keeping levels of investment on a-n even keel. Equally dangerous
to the economy is the sharp drop in investment which normally accom-
panies a recession and helps prolong it. What is needed here is a special
inducement to businessmen to invest at such times, as well as to refrain
from investing when the economy is threatened with overheating.
Such inducements can be provided through the operation of an invest-
ment reserve fund such as has been established in Sweden.
In Sweden, a corporation is permitted each year to place up to a
given percentage (the figure was 40 percent not long ago, but may have
been changed) of its before-tax profits in a special investment reserve.
No tax is paid on the funds going into this reserve, but a portion of it
equal to the profits tax that would normally be paid must be deposited
in a special non-interest-bearing account with the Central Bank.
In a year when the government determines that the economy is in
need of an economic stimulus, it may permit all or part of these re-
serves to be withdrawn for the purpose of financing investment ex-
penditures, and a corresponding amount of the money deposited with
the Central Bank is returned to the company. The company is always
free to withdraw its funds from the investment reserve, but if it does so
at a time when the government wishes to discourage investment it does
not get a return of the money deposited in the Central Bank. Instead,
all or a portion of that deposit, equal to the normal profits tax on the
amount withdrawn from the reserve, is forfeited. Thus, in effect, if the
company restricts its investment of the portion of its profits subject to
the reserve fund machinery to a period when the economy requires such
investment, that part of its profit is free of tax; but if it chooses to in-
vest those profits at any other time, it must pay the normal tax on them.
PROGRESSIVE SPENDING TAX
If the economy should become so overheated that measures to reduce
consumer spending are necessary, there are methods of doing so much
more equitably than through an across-the-board increase in the in-
come tax. One of the -deficiencies of -the latter is that it taxes income
which would otherwise be spent for necessities, as well as income that
would be spent on luxuries. As an alternative, a progressive spending
tax, which the Treasury proposed during World War II and the UAW
PAGENO="0175"
889
has urged on several occasions, would help to divert resources from
luxury consumption to higher-priority purposes. Such a tax would
allow tax-free exemptions, based upon the number of persons in each
family, sufficiently high to enable the family to maintain a comfortable
standard of living. Amounts spent by the family above its exemptions
would be taxed at graduated rates which would increase as the amount
spent per family member rose.
Such a tax would be desirable, within the framework of an overall
fiscal policy aimed at full production and full employment, to achieve
a useful and desirable reallocatiOn of resources.
A progressive spending tax can be administered more effectively if
it is kept in force permanently. If that were done, the tax rates could
be varied from time to time depending upon whether national priorities
(including full employment) called for more or less consumer spend-
ing. These factors suggest that consideration might usefully be given
to enactment of such a tax now.
Although we do not now have full employment, and therefore have
no present need to suppress nonessential consumption, the progres-
sive spending `tax might nevertheless be a useful tax today if the
revenues from it were earmarked to `be spent (in addition to what
is `already planned to be spent, so that there will be no reduction in
total demand) for some `purpOse of high national urgency. Through
such a tax, those `who spent on luxuries `could simultaneously be re-
quired to contribute, for example, to a stepped-up war on poverty-
on the principle that those who enjoy a `superabundance of cake should
be mindful of their neighbors' needs for bread. To the extent that the
tax deterred luxury spending, t'he resultant additions to savings could
be channeled, through use of selective monetary devices, into housing
and other social deficit sectors of the economy.
TAX REFORM
Another measure which equity demands `and which has `been far too
long delayed is a reform of the tax system and plugging of loopholes
which now permit `some favo'red groups of citizens `and corporations-
many `of them extremely wealthy-to avoid carrying their fair share
of the tax burden. The `Council recognizes this `as a possible `alterna-
tive to the proposed tax surcharge, `but shrugs it off `by saying `that
such reforms should be enacted on a permanent basis, not to meet a
temporary need, and that it would take too long to get such reforms
through `Congress.
Of course, such reforms `should be on a permanent basis. But that
is no reason why they should not be started on today. A's for the
argument tha't it will take too long to get tax reform legislation
through C'ongress, there is strong reason to doubt that it will be
possible to get the proposed tax increase legislation through Congress
at all, but that has not prevented the Council from proposing it. If
the `Council h'ad been as assiduous in pushing for tax reform since
President Kennedy first proposed it as `it has been in supporting other
more dubious proposals, suc'h `as the wage-price guideposts, we might
have h'ad tax reform on the statute books by now.
Here `again, however, so long as we fall short of full employment,
the revenues from loophole closing must be added to government
PAGENO="0176"
890
spending already planned in order to avoid reducing total demand and
employment. On that basis, loophole-closing could speed our progress
toward the Great Society.
MEETING THE REAL PRICE PROBLEM
Much of the inflationary threat to the economy, however, does not
come from overheating at all, but from the unilateral actions of a
comparative handful of giant corporations which have achieved so
much economic power that they are able to dominate the industries
to which they belong and virtually to insulate themselves from the
effects of competitive market forces, especially in the area of price
decisions. Such corporations are able to abuse their economic power by
setting prices at levels higher than a free market would permit.
Typically, they establish prices at levels which will protect them
against loss even if the economy should clip into a recession. As a re-
sult,in periods of expansion their profits skyrocket to fantastic levels,
helping to create some of the imbalances in the economy previously
described. Year after year, in its discussion of price problems, the
Council of Economic Advisers has had to lament the fact that such
corporations, which frequently also enjoy above-average rates of
productivity advance, have not made their proper contribution to
overall price stability by reducing prices-thus offsetting the un-
avoidable price increases in industries with less-than-average rates
of productivity advance-but instead have maintained prices at in-
ordinately high levels, or even raised them.
Regrettably, one of the major offenders in this regard has been the
auto industry. Not only has the industry failed to cut prices over a
period of years when, as its fantastic profits show, it could well have
afforded to do so, but it has twice announced price increases in the
past 6 months. In addition, there has been a series of unannounced,
stealthy price increases which the industry apparently hoped to put
over without public knowledge of what was happening. Prices of
replacement parts have been increased, formerly standard equipment
has been made optional with no corresponding price adjustment, and
buyer warranties have been diluted. On January 30 the Wall Street
Journal reported:
Since September, the auto makers have increased car prices twice, the first
two-step increase in a model year since 1956. The first price boost averaged more
than $100 a car and was the largest of three in the past three years. On Jan. 1
prices went up another $23 to S32 when the shoulder belts were installed to meet
Federal safety regulations.
In recent weeks Ford Motor Co. also dropped as standard equipment some
devices on many of its cars without lowering the prices, making the devices extra-
cost options. It also raised the prices of some models after making larger engines
or other optional equipment standard. And all four auto makers have quietly
raised parts prices from 4% to 7% since mid-November.
These pric.e increases cannot be justified by financial necessity.
FTC-SEC financial reports show that, in spite of a decline from the
preceding year, auto industry profits in the first three quarters of 1967
were still running well ahead of the average rate of return on invest-
ment for all manufacturing. And the Wall Street Journal on February
13, 1968, under the heading, "Corporate Profits Again Appear To Be
Heading From Record to Record," reported:
PAGENO="0177"
891
Industries such as autos and rubber that turned in a good profit performance
in the fourth quarter expect to do still better now * *
Clearly, the increase in car prices is just another example of cor-
porate greed on the part of the auto industry.
PRICE-WAGE REYIEW BOARD NEEDED
To counter such abuses of economic power, the TJAW has long ad-
vocated the establishment of a Price-Wage Review Board. It would
operate essentially as follows:
Whenever any corporation controlling, say, 25 percent or more of
the sales of a major industry or product wished to raise its price, it
would first have to notify the Board, and appear at a public hearing
if the Board thought necessary.
The Board would hold public hearings, would have power to obtain
all the pertinent facts, and would issue a report. The corporation
would then be at liberty to raise prices, up to the limit of its proposal,
if it saw fit. But if the facts were such as to persuade any reasonable
man that a price increase was not justifiable, and if the public had
access to those facts, we do not think any increase would take place. In
most such cases, the mere existence of the hearings procedure would
probably mean that the price increase would never be proposed.
CONSUMER COUNSEL WOULD WORK WITH BOARD
The Price-Wage Review Board machinery could be given added
strength by the creation of a separate Office of Consumer Counsel,
whose function it would be to represent the interest of consumers in
hearings before the Board. He should also be given the authority to
initiate hearings before the Board when a prima facie case could be
made that prices charged by a corporation covered by the system
were already too high in relation to costs. In such a situation, the
Consumer Counsel, after making his own preliminary investigation,
would lay the facts before the Board. If it agreed that there was
substantial reason to believe that prices charged by a corporation
covered by the law were unduly high, it would then notify the cor-
poration and make arrangements for a public hearing.
Unions would also be subject to the hearings procedure. Whenever
a corporation subject to the hearings procedure claimed that acceptance
of any union demand would require it to raise prices, both the corpora-
tion and the union would be summoned to a hearing and required to
produce the facts relevant to their claims. As the Council of Economic
Advisers has acknowledged, there are, of course, situations where wage
increases are justified even though they may require price increases.
Where that was the fact, the hearing would reveal it. On the other
hand, if the union's demands were not justifiable, the facts would show
it. Or if the company's profit position were such that it could well
afford to meet the union's demand without a price increase, the facts
would show that. The parties would resume negotiations with the
knowledge that an informed public was prepared to pass judgment
on the outcome.
In a free society we must find a middle ground between a reckless,
socially irresponsible, laissez-faire, "public be damned" attitude and
90-101-68-pt. 3-12
PAGENO="0178"
892
arbitrary action by Government to set the levels of prices and wages.
The approach we propose stands on such middle ground and relies not
upon the coercion of Government compulsion but upon the moral lev-
erage of enlightened public opinion which, in a free society, must be
the repository of authority in the broad area where private power and
public responsibility must be equated and harmonized if freedom is
to survive.
The establishment of the Cabinet Committee on Price Stability an-
nounced by the President indicates the administration's recognition
that more effective means have to be found of curbing unjustifiable
price increases. We urge this committee to recommend to the Cabinet
Committee that it give serious consideration to the establishment of a
Price~WTage Review Board and Office of Consumer Counsel.
MEASURES TO MEET HOUSING NEEDS
As indicated previously, the causes of our housing problem are
multifarious, and there is no single, simple solution to them. A variety
of selective measures are required. We need tax legislation designed
to deter those who speculate in land and thereby drlve up land prices
or who milk slum properties for maximum profits without bothering
even to keep them in a decent state of repair. WTe need to sweep away
the multitude of local building codes, many of them obsolescent, which
help to prevent the use of new methods, materials, a.nd technologies in
the building industry, and replace them with a national performance
standards code-making allowance for regional climatic variations.
And we need a new approach to the financing of housing, which for
many families represents the major stumbling block in the way of
getting a good home in a good neighborhood. In particular, we need to
safeguard the availability of adequate mortgage funds at reasonable
interest rates even when it becomes advisable to restrict the flow of
credit to other sectors of the economy.
The Council of Economic Advisers has recognized the importance
of providing adequate funds to finance housing. One of the reasons
it gives in support of the proposed tax increase, in fact, is that, if the
anticipated budget deficit is financed through borrowing, it will dry up
the money market to the extent that the housing industry will be
stifled for lack of mortgage money.
Again, we see the blunt instrument approach at work. Implicitly,
the Council recognizes that all demands for credit do not have the
same social utility or urgency as housing, and that the market cannot
be relied upon to channel the flow of available credit in accordance
with social considerations. The Council stops there, however. It seems
to assume that nothing can be done to protect housing against coin-
peting demands for credit for purposes of far lesser utility or ur-
gency-inventory, stock market or land speculation, for example, or
disproportionate fixed business investment (in anticipation of the
future growth of markets) which could be deferred until credit be-
comes more readily available. That assumption, obviously, is false. It
is not beyond the imagination of the Council to devise, or the ability of
the Government and the Federal Reserve Board to apply, selective
measures to direct the flow of credit to where it will do the most good.
`What is required for the selective approach is an order of nationa.l
priorities-on which housing would rank very close to the top. Given
PAGENO="0179"
893
those priorities, proper measures can and should be taken to insure
an adequate supply of funds to finance the volume of housing required.
A variety of measures might be used to achieve that end. For ex-
ample, ceilings on interest rates payable on commercial bank time
deposits could be related to rates (fixed at reasonable levels) paid
on deposits in savings and loan associations so as to assure an adequate
flow of funds to the latter. Or, given whatever limits might be neces-
sary on the total supply of credit, the government might channel an
adequate flow of subsidized low-interest loans to mortgage lenders,
using the mortgages as collateral, provided the lenders in turn made
mortgage loans within a specified interest rate limit. Or the Govern-
ment might act through the Federal Reserve Board to make more funds
available. This was the intention of Congress in 1966 when it passed
legislation authorizing the Federal Reserve Board to buy securities
of the Federal home loan banks and the Federal National Mortgage
Association. Unfortunately, the legislation left decisions whether to
do so or not to the discretion of the Board, and its Chairman testified
even before the legislation was enacted that he had not intention of
doing so in any volume unless directed to. The legislation should be
amended so as to require the FEB to take such action when directed
to do so by the President.
Congress should not, however, adopt the remedy proposed in the
budget message and supported by the Council of raising the statutory
interest ceilings on FHA and VA loans, and on conventional loans in
States now imposing a ceiling of 6 percent or less. Such action would
open the way for market forces to play havo'c with housing. Although
it might temporarily attract more funds into the mortgage market,
it would at the same time drive more borrowers out. And as Represen-
tative Wright Patman has pointed out, the competition of mortgage
interest rates, which he predicted would go to at least 7 percent, would
soon send other rates higher. On February 8, he told the House:
As a result, rates on Treasury notes and PC's would skyrocket overnight to
c~~mpete with the new 7 percent rate FHA paper backed by the government insur-
ance. We would experience a quick leapfrogging of all government rates, thus
costing the taxpayers billions of dollars in added costs on Treasury borrowings.
* After the Treasury notes and PC's have jumped, the FHA paper would again
find itself in a disadvantageous competitive position. Once again, the lenders and
the liomebuilders would seek a new increase in the PHA rate.
We have serious doubts also about the proposal in the budget
message for:
An orderly transfer of ownership of the Government's activities in the sec-
ondary mortgage market to private hands, so that private capital can be raised
and mortgages purchased as required by market conditions.
This proposal is so indefinite that it is difficult to know precisely
what is contemplated. But surely the history of the past 20 years and
more provides convincing evidence that if provision of funds to finance
housing is left to the vagaries of the private money market, the funds
will not be forthcoming at rates most families can afford, and the
housing we need will not be built.
In his "Crisis in the Cities" message, the President proposes that 6
million homes be built in the next 10 years with Federal assistance, in
addition to the 20 million he hopes private enterprise will build un-
aided. We believe the total goal is too low, and the expectation of what
PAGENO="0180"
894
private builders will do on their own is too high. It is disappointing
also that in the first year of the program it is proposed to `assist with
only 300,000 units-just half the annual rate required to meet the
10-year goal.
The proposals to subsidize all but 1 percent of the interest charged
on homes bought by needy families and on homes to be rented by fami-
lies with incomes between $4,000 and $8,000 per year are sound and
commendable in themselves. However, if at the same time these mort.-
gages are transferred from FNMA to a private corporation, as is pro-
posed, the Government might be exposed to excessive interest costs.
The President's proposal to "authorize Federal insurance of bond
obligations issued by private mortgage companies or trusts holding
sizeable pools of FHA and VA insured mortgages" seems to us to be a
useful means to make more funds available for housing. But it need
not be coupled with the removal of the ceilings on interest rates per-
mitted to be charged on such mortgages in order to attract invest-
ment in such obligations by pension funds and other institutions de-
sirous of avoiding "the bookkeeping a.nd paper work associated with
hundreds of individual mortgages."
MODERNIZE AND DEMOCRATIZE THE ERB
The refusal of the Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board to ac-
knowledge the clearly expressed will of Congress with regard to pro-
vision of mortgage funds is just one example of the need to modernize
and democratize the Board so that it will be more responsive to the
needs of the people as expressed through their democratically elected
representatives. Not only is the Board unresponsive to modern needs,
but its power to seriously undermine the economic policies of the
national administration has no place in a democratic society of the
20th century. Repeatedly the Board has insisted on following policies
which pulled in the opposite direction from those of the administra-
tion in office at the time. In an economy as complex and as delicately
balanced as ours, this is irresponsible and intolerable folly. We would
urge that two basic changes be made. The Chairman should hold
office only at the will of the President of the United States. And mem-
berships in the governing bodies of the system, which are now domi-
nated by bankers, big businessmen, and monetary experts, should
be opened up to people from other sectors of the American economy,
including the labor movement.
Ourr~ooK FOR 1968
The Council's main policy proposal for 1968 is enactment of a 10-
percent surcharge on personal and corporate income taxes. This rec-
ommendation is the combined result of a value judgment and an eco-
nomic forecast, both of which are highly questionable.
The value judgment is that there is no urgency about reducing the
unemployment rate below last year's level-that reduction of unem-
ployinent deserves only a low ranking on the scale of national priori-
ties-that 3.8 percent unemployment is more tolerable than any ad-
ditional price level increase that might be associated with a lower
unemployment rate. That view, we submit, is in conflict with the basic
PAGENO="0181"
895
purpose of the Employment Act to which the Council owes its ex-
istence. It reflects a policy of attempting to buy price stability with
the hardships of the unemployed and the risk of renewed disruption
of the peace of our cities. For it is almost universally agreed that un-
employment was a major cause of the urban riots that have marred
every recent summer. As the Council well knows, the 1967 overall un-
employment rate of 3.8 percent involved a 7.4-percent rate for non-
whites and a' 26.5-percent rate for nonwhite teenagers. In the 20 largest
Standard Metropolitan Statistical Areas (SMSAs) unemployment
of nonwhite teenagers averaged 32.7 percent in 1967. It is perhaps not
without significance that Detroit and Newark, the two cities that suf-
fered the most devastating disturbances last summer, ranked third
and fourth highest (with 10.9 and 9.8 percent, respectively) amon
the 13 SMSAs for which the Labor Department has published 196
nonwhite unemployment rates.
The Council acknowledges that the tax surcharge would have the
effect of eliminating job opportunities that would otherwise be avail-
able. In describing what would happen in the absence of the surcharge,
the Council says that:
* * * it might be possible to mobilize some additional manpower from among
the remaining unemployed [and that] some poorly qualified workers would be
hired.
The "remaining unemployed" and the "poorly qualified workers"
are, of course, those for whom jobs most urgently need to be found
both on humane grounds and in order to reduce the social tensions
that pose a continuing threat to urban peace. They are the "hard
coie" unemployed for whom it is proposed to create 100,000 jobs by
July 1969 through subsidies to employers at the rate of $3,500 per job.
The Council has conceded that during 1968 "as a whole" the surcharge
would cost the economy 150,000 jobs. (The number would be larger
toward the end of the year and still larger later on because of the
multiplier effect.) This is half again as many jobs as the subsidies
are intended to create by mid-1969. As will be shown below, there is
reason to believe that the surcharge will, cause a loss of potential jobs
in 1968 significantly greater than the 150,000 projected by the Council.
The loss of those jobs and continuance of last year's unemployment
rate would be bad enough. But analysis of the Council's view of `the
economic outlook (as well as projections made by other economists
and reviewed below) suggests a strong possibility that the tax sur-
charge which the Council urges could result not only in a loss of po-
tential job opportunities hut in significantly increased unemploy-
mont-and with only negligible gains in price stability.
LAST YEAR'S FORECAST
To begin with, the forecast the Council made in its 1967 report
does not inspire much confidence in its predictions for 1968. It will be
recalled that last year, also, the Council called for a tax surcharge to
avoid "overheating" of the economy. It predicted that, if its surcharge
proposal were adopted, real gross national product would be 4-percent
higher in 1967 than in 1966. Presumably it anticipated a greater in-
crease in the absence of the surcharge. The surcharge was not adopted,
PAGENO="0182"
896
and real gross national product grew only 2.5 percent-the smallest
increase since the 1960-61 recession. (The difference can be accounted
for only partially by the fact that Congress delayed enacting social
security benefit increases which the Council had expected to be in
effect by mid-1967). Had the surcharge been enacted, growth un-
doubtedly would have been less than 2.5 percent.
Looking back at 1967, the Council, which last year urged the fiscally
restrictive surcharge, congratulates itself in this year's report on "the
avoidance of recession (as) a major favorable development," and
adds:
It was only because fiscal and monetary policy were operating in a stimula-
tive direction that the expansion endured. [Emphasis added.]
The Council turned out to be correct in predicting that unemploy-
ment in 1967 would be "essentially the same as in 1966." But it was
correct on that score largely because the lower-than-expected rate of
growth retarded the rise of productivity and resulted in a reduction
in average weekly hours worked.
FORECAST FOR 1968
The Council foresees an uneven pattern of economic activity in
1968 and concedes that, under that circumstance, "forecasting involves
special uncertainties." More than half of the increase in C-NP which
the Council predicts for 1968 is accounted for by its forecast of con-
sumer spending. But the Council is careful to note that:
For 1968, the consumer sector is clearly an area of particular uncertainty in
forecasting private demand.
Since consumer spending will have an important influence on busi-
ness spending, both for fixed investment and inventories, the un-
certainties are compounded.
Given these uncertainties, it is reasonable to ask whether enact-
ment of the tax surcharge would not involve a serious risk of raising
the unemployment rate significantly above last year's 3.8 percent. The
evidence suggests that the risk is very real.
The Council makes much of the "brisk pace" of the economy in
the second half of 1967, noting, among other things, that "final
sales increased substantially." The fact is, however, that in real terms
the increase in final sales from the second to the fourth quarters of
1967 was only 1 percent-at an annual rate of only 2 percent. If
allowance is made for the effects of the Ford strike-whic.h the Council
says "curtailed the annual rate of rea.l growth by 1 percentage point
over this period"-the annual rate of increase in real final sales would
still be only 3 percent. This is a matter of some importance since
the Council's case for the surcharge rests in large part on continuance
of the impetus of the last half of 1967 into this year. That impetus
was not very great.
Total C-NP rose at a faster rate than final sales during the second
half of 1967 because of a spurt in inventory accumulation during the
last quarter of the year. In part, the additions to inventory were an
aftermath of the Ford strike. They also reflect early preparations
for a possible steel strike. The disappointing level of retail new
car sales thus far this year suggests that further additions to the
PAGENO="0183"
897
stock of autos may be involuntary, with the result that production
will be cut back. This could mean less buoyancy in the first half
of 1968 than the Council expects. Steel inventories will continue
to increase in the months ahead; but they will inevitably be reduced
later in the year, either during a strike or following a settlement.
Production, employment, and the general level of demand will all
be adversely affected, whether or not a strike occurs. Thus, in the
absence of other reasons for accumulation of inventories, the main
source of the acceleration of growth during the second half of 1967
would be operating to retard growth in ihe second half of 1968.
Enactment of the tax surcharge would compound the effects of
inventory reduction.
Examination of the Council's sector-by-sector forecasts, which are
premised upon enactment of the surcharge, adds to misgivings about
the wisdom of the surcharge proposal.
BUSINESS FIXED INVESTMENT
The Council expects business fixed investment to be $4 to $5 billion
higher in 1968 than in 1967. Insofar as the first half of 1968 is
concerned, this forecast is based upon anticipated investment as
reflected in the Commerce-SEC survey. In 1967, however, the antici-
pations reflected in that survey turned out, quarter-by-quarter, to be
substantially overoptimistic when data on actual investment became
available. In the first and second quarters of 1967, increases over the
respective preceding quarters had been anticipated by actual invest-
ment decreased. The average error for the first three quarters (fourth
quarter actual data are not yet available) was more than $2 billion
at an annual rate.
Preliminary figures for 1967 (with the fourth quarter taken at the
anticipated level) show an increase of little more than 1 percent over
1966 in current dollar business expenditures for new plant and equip-
ment, which would mean a decrease in real investment. The reason is
readily apparent. From 1963 through 1966, real plant and equipment
investment had been increasing twice as fast as real GNP. Such a
discrepancy was clearly unsustainable.
Excessive investment and lagging demand inevitably resulted in
a sharp decrease in capacity utilization. In manufacturing, for ex-
ample, Federal Reserve Board data show that capacity increased by
6.4 percent from the fourth quarter of 1966 to the fourth quarter of
1967. Output during the same period declined by one-half percent.
As a result, capacity utilization dropped from 90 percent to 84.3
percent.
With a wide margin of existing capacity unused, it is not at all
surprising that anticipated increases in plant and equipment spend-
ing fail to materialize. The Council may be in for a disappointment in
the nonelectrical machinery industry, for example. This is one of the
industries mentioned by the Council for which the Commerce-SEC
survey "reported plans for considerable increases in investment in the
first half of 1968." However (according to MeG-raw-Hill figures),
the operating rate in nonelectrical machinery dropped from 93.5 per-
cent of capacity in December 1966 to 80.5 percent in December 1967.
PAGENO="0184"
898
Given this 13-percentage-point drop in the operating rate, actual fixed
investment expenditures in the industry in early 1968 could turn out
to be lower instead of higher than in late 1967.
In broader terms, the Council's prediction of a $4 to $5 billion in-
crease in total business fixed investment in 1968 is particularly sur-
prising (except for such part of those figures as may be accounted
for by price increases) in the light of the statement on page 125 of
the report that "capacity utilization will show relatively little change"
from 1967. The rate of capacity utilization in manufacturing aver-
aged only 85.1 percent in 1967, according to the Federal Reserve Board.
It is not known, moreover, to what extent the respondents in the
survey of investment plans for the. first half of 1968 based their replies
upon the assumption that the tax surcharge would be enacted. If any
significant proportion assumed there would be no surcharge, the sur-
vey results would be overoptimistic in relation to the Council's fore-
cast which is premised upon enactment of the surcharge. For the sur-
charge would have a. double effect on investment expenditures. It would
reduce directly the funds available for investment; and it would reduce
incentives to invest by reducing both corporate and private demand
for the output of new facilities.
The Council presents no quantitative estimate of the effect of the
surcharge on fixed business investment. The forecast prepared by the
research seminar in quantitative economics of the University of Mich-
igan indicates that such investment would be reduced in real terms
(measured in 1958 dollars) by $2.4 billion below the level that would
be reached if there were no surcharge. Imposition of the surcharge,
according to this forecast, would convert an increase over the 1967
level of real investment into a decrease. Thus, any current dollar in-
crease in investment, if it occurs at all, would be very small.
HOUSING
The Council expects private nonfarm housing starts in 1968 to
exceed 11/2 million and total residential building and modernization
expenditures to increase $5 to $6 billion over last year's level. This
forecast assumes enactment of the tax surcharge early in the year.
availability of sufficient mortgage funds, and, apparently, continuance
of present high-or possibly even higher-mortgage interest rates.
Here, too, it is possible that the Council may be overoptimistic. That
National Association of Homebuilders predicts 1,400,000 housing starth
for 1968 and recent signs of a leveling off in starts and in permits lend
support to a forecast lower than the Council's. Month-to-month
changes in both starts and permits tend to be erratic, making it difficult
to form firm conclusions from the most recent data. However, the data
for December 1967 and January 1968 (which were not available when
the Council's Report was prepared) suggest that the rising trend of
earlier months may have come to an end. Total private starts (on a
seasonally adjusted annual rate basis) decreased by nearly 350,000
between November and December and the 200,000 unit recovery in Jan-
uary did no more than bring them back to the September 1967 level.
The average of 1,344,000 for the most recent 2 months was below the
July level. Permits, which are a signal of future starts, took a reverse
course, rising in December by 165,000 (also seasonally adjusted annual
PAGENO="0185"
899
rate) and declining in January by more than 210,000. The January
figure was below that for August 1967 and only 2,000 above that for
June 1967. The average for December and January, at 1,217,000 was
only 5,000 above the level of October 1967. A leveling off at approxi-
mately that number of permits during the remainder of the year would
be consistent with the starts forecast of the National Association of
Homebuilders.
The Council attempts to minimize the effects of high interest rates on
housing demand and actually proposes lifting the interest ceilings on
FHIA and VA mortgages. Its report says:
The events of 1967 have shown quite clearly that housing demand is strong
enough to support a high and rising level of building even when mortgage interest
rates are high-provided funds are available at thrift institutions.
But the 1967 rise in housing starts prior to December may have been
merely catchup for the immediately preceding period when home con-
struction was sharply depressed by the restricted availability of mort-
gage funds. Families who could afford high interest rates could proceed
with their housing plans as mortgage,money became available in 1967;
but many less well-off undoubtedly were kept out of the housing market
by interest costs. Given the steady, sharp decrease in real housing ex-
penditures after 1963 (which persisted into 1967) ~nd the urgent need
for housing, demand undoubtedly would have been significantly higher
last year if not for the leyel of interest ra,te~. The Jeyeling off of housing
starts and permits in the past 2 months may reflect the rise in mortgage
interest rates which began in Jiin~e 1967 a~ter .a decline earlier in the
year. it ~n~y alsQ indicate th~t tl~ie catchup phase is ~uding and that
high interest rates are now becoming the predominant influence on
home construction. If that should prove to bn the case, fulfillment of
the Council's apparent expectation that interest rates will continue to
be high could result in a downturn rather than ~a mere leveling off of
housing expenditures.
GOVERNMENT SPENDING
The Council predicts that .Stat~ and local purchases of goods and
services will rise at about the same rate as last year. Federal purchases,
however, are expected to increase by only $6 billion as compared to
$13 billion from 1966 to 1~67. This marked slowdown in the rise of
Federal spending will retard the growth of GNP both directly and in-
directly. The 1967 increase in purchases by the Federal Government
accounted directly for nearly one-third of the total increase in GNP
and, indirectly, it undoubtedly contributed substantially to increases in
other components of GNP. The much smaller increase in Federal pur-
chases projected for 1968 will reinforce the factors tending to slow the
rise in fixed business investment and inventory accumulation.
CONSUMER SPENDING
Of the $61 billion total increase in GNP that the Council projects
for 1968, about $33 billion, or more than half, is expected to come from
an increase in consumer spending. As previously noted, however, the
Council concedes that the consumer sector is "an area of particular
uncertainty." It acknowledges also that "the latest evidence indicates
that consumers are still spending cautiously." Surveys of consumer
PAGENO="0186"
900
buying intentions indicate, that they will continue their caution in the
months ahead. Yet, the Council bases its surcharge proposal on the
assumption t.hat the rise in consumer spending will be large enough to
trigger a capital goods boom au d inventory speculation if the surcharge
were to fail of enactment.
The Council's projected $33 billion increase in consumer spending
assumes a small decline from the 1967 saving rate "essentially" as a
result of a catchup in automobile purcha.ses from the effects of the
Ford strike. This view must be examined in the light of the facts that
~1) the Council was grossly in error last year in predicting the 1967
savings rate; (2) savings were still on the rise at t.he end of last year
and the continued caution of consumers reflected in the surveys pro-
vides no basis for projecting a decline; and (3) the expected catchup in
auto sales does not appear to be materializing.
In its 1967 report, the Council predicted that:
The saving rate in 1967 should remain close to the 1966 level of 5~ percent, a
little below the average of recent years.
As it turned out, the saving rate shot up to 7.1 percent, which was
not only far above the average for recent years but, in fact, the
highest rate since 1953. During the fourth quarter of 1967 the rate
was 7.5 percent. The Census Bureau survey of consumer buying ex-
pectations certainly provides no indication of a spending spree that
would reduce the saving rate in the months ahead. And Professor
George Katona, who conducts consumer behavior studies for the TJni-
versity of Michigan's Survey Research Bureau, is quoted in Newsweek
magazine for February 26, 1968, as saying that, in the absence of some
dramatic news such as a Vietnam peace proposal, "we could have
several quarters more of high savings".
The record of retail new car sales thus far this year provides little
support for the belief that auto sales catchup will reduce the saving
rate. During the first 20 days of January, when catchup should have
been most strongly felt, seasonally adjusted unit car sales (excluding
overseas imports) ran at an annual rate of only 7.8 million compared
to actual sales of approximately 7.6 million last year. Subsequently,
factory-promoted dealer sales contests were widely in effect. Despite
the combined effects of catchup and the sales contests, the annual rate
of sales from the sta.rt of the year through February 20 was only 8.1
million. This figure, boosted though it was by temporary factors, is
nevertheless short of foreca.sts by the major auto producers which
called for sales in 1968 of 8.2 t.o 8.5 million cars (again excluding over-
seas imports). Based upon the sales record thus far this year, Mr.
Lynn Townsend, chairman of the board of the Chrysler Corp., has
already reduced his original forecast for 1968.
The Council's forecast of a "sizeable advance in consumer spending"
rests in part on expectation that:
Expenditures on household durables should receive particular support from
the continued high level of homebuilding.
However, homebuilding, as noted above, may fall short of the Coun-
cil's expectations, and the census survey of consumer buying plans
shows no signs of a spurt in purchases of durables. In fact, the survey
(as analyzed by Prof. Paul W. McCracken for the Commercial Credit
Co.) indicates dollar purchases of major appliances and furniture in
PAGENO="0187"
901
the first half of 1968 no higher than the average level of the second
and third quarters of 1967, with purchases of other nonautomotive
durables up only 1 percent for the same period. Measured in real terms,
this would mean a decrease in spending on nonautomotive durables.
Taking the above durable goods outlook together with prospective
new car sales of 81/2 million (which works out to about 7.7 million ex-
cluding overseas imports) indicated by the census survey, Professor
McCracken concludes that they present "a picture of sluggish, flaccid
demand." 1
The Council provides no clue to its expectations regarding 1968 con-
sumer spending for nondurables and services. Spending in both areas
will undoubtedly increase in 1968 because of population growth and
price increases, if for no other reasons. But there are no strong indica-
tions that either will provide any special upward impetus to the econ-
omy. If the 1967 pattern persists, nondurable spending could be par-
ticularly disappointing. From the second to the fourth quarters of
1967, while the rise in GNP was accelerating from the laggard pace
of the first half of the year, current dollar spending for nondurables
slowed markedly. In real terms, nondurables spending was actually
lower in the third and fourth quarters. than in the second.
RATIONALE FOR SURCHARGE
At the very least, the evidence summarized above creates a reason-
able doubt as to the likelihood of a dangerous upsurge of consumer
spending. Yet, the Council appears to base its case for the surcharge
on the theory that it is needed to siphon off potential consumer demand
in order to avoid setting off an inflationary and unsustainable boom
in business investment. The report says:
Without the [surcharge] withdrawal from personal incomes, consumer spend-
ing in the second quarter and thereafter would be substantially higher than
that contemplated in the forecast given in Chapter 1. Responding to the addi-
tional consumer demand, business would attempt to raise output and employ-
ment. The resulting increases in wages, dividends, and other income payments
would swell consumer incomes, and, in turn, lead to still further additions to
consumer expenditures. Rising consumer spending, together with the failure of
corporate tax rates to rise, would add to after-tax profits, providing both in-
centives and means for financing more business investment expenditures than
would be the case if the tax increase were enacted. It is likely, in addition, that
the grea:ter consumer and business spending would lead to more rapid accumu-
lation of inventories.
Thus the interacting forces of consumer and business spending would, via the
wel-known multiplier process, generate tncreases in money income and total
demand that would far exceed the magnitude of the surcharge.
EFFECT OF TAX SURCHARGE
The Council has never spelled out publicly the method by which it
makes its forecasts. Nor has it, in this year's report, shown quantita-
tively the changes in the various components of GNP and in the un-
employment rate which it would expect in the absence of the tax
surcharge.
1 The new census survey, published as this statement was being reproduced, shows only
slight improvement in the outlook for consumer spending. By far the greatest change was an
increase of 3.1 percent in expected home purchase expenditures as compared to the preceding
survey.
PAGENO="0188"
902
At least two other reputable forecasting groups, however, have de-
veloped detailed projections for 1968, with and without the surcharge
assumption. They a.re the Research Seminar in Quantitative Eco-
nomics of the LTniversity of Michigan and the Econometric and Fore-
casting Unit of the Wharton School of Finance and Commerce of the
University of Pennsylvania. Both of these groups develop their fore-
casts through the use of econometric models (systems of equations)
carefully designed to project the fututre performance of the economy
on the basis of past experience. The Michigan group, which has been
making forecasts for a long enough period to permit evaluation of
their reliability, has an outstandingly good record.
The findings of these groups do not agree in every detail. Despite
the great progress made in recent years, forecasting is still more art
than science. Significance must be attached, however, to the fact that
the conclusions of both the Michigan and Wharton School groups are
widely at variance with most of the Council on the two most crucial
points. The first is the effect of the surcharge on employment and un-
employment. The second is the effect of the surcharge on the price level.
The findings of both the Michigan and Wharton groups show that
the surcharge would involve a heavy cost in unemployment (and
GNP) in return for only a negligible gain in price stability.
MICHIGAN rROJECTIONS
Certain of the assumptions made by the Michigan group (.e.g., an
increase in social security taxes from 4.4 to 4.8 percent) are now out
of date. But the relevant general tendencies implicit in the forecast
would not be affected by revision of those assumptions.
The Michigan model yields a 1968 GNP of $705.4 billion (in 1958
prices) assuming that the surcharge is not imposed and that monetary
policy is consistent with a 3-month Treasury bill rate of 4.5 percent.
Another projection which, in order to determine the effects of tight
monetary conditions, substitutes 5 percent for 4.5 percent in the latter
assumption, yields approximately the same GNP-$704.4 billion.
A third projection, with assumptions the same as in the first de-
scribed above except for the addition of a 10-percent surcharge on
personal and corporate income taxes, yields a GNP of $692.5 billion.
Thus, enactment of the surcharge would reduce C-NP for the year by
$12.9 billion of 1968 purchasing power. The equivalent in terms of
fourth quarter 1967 dollars would be $15.3 billion (probably close to
$16 billion in 1968 dollars).
The three Michigan projections also show that the surcharge would
be far more costly in terms of employment than has been indicated by
the Coimcil which, as previously mentioned, has stated that the sur-
charge wou'd reduce employment growt.h in 1968 by 150,000 jobs. Ac-
cording to the Michigan model, the cost in 1968 would be 800,000 jobs-
more than five times as large as the Council's estimate.
According to either of the projections which assume to surcharge,
civilian employment would be 75.6 million. Addition of the surcharge
to t.he first of the projections described above would reduce
employment to 74.8 million. Unemployment would be 800,000 to 900,000
higher with the surcharge tha.n without it. (The range is apparently
PAGENO="0189"
903
a reflection of rounding errors in the employment and labor force
figures.)
The unemployment rate would be 3.6 or 3.7 percent, respectively,
according to the first two (no surcharge) projections described. It
would be 4.7 percent according to the projection which assumes the
surcharge is placed in effect. The 4.7 percent unemployment rate isan
average for the year. Thus, assuming the surcharge-based projection
turns out to be reasonably within range of actual developments in 1968,
the unemployment rate could well be above 5 percent by the end of the
year. All the progress of the past 3 years in reducing unemployment
would be reversed.
The impact of this unemployment would, of course, be borne dis-
proportionately by the most disadvantaged groups in our society. The
consequences for peace in our cities can readily be imagined.
We in the TJAW do not believe that full employment is incompatible
with reasonable price stability. We believe it is the responsibility of
economists to develop and to propose means to promote such com-
patibility, and of the political authorities to work for the implementa-
tion of those means. We have outlined in this statement and in others
submitted previously some of the measures that could promote price
stability under full employment. We have made clear our conviction,
however, that if there must be a trade off between full employment and
price stability, priority must be given to full employment. The balance-
of-payments deficit does not, in our view, provide sufficient reason to
surrender that conviction.
But how much gain in price stability would be bought in 1968 at the
cost of an 800,000 to 900,000 increase in unemployment? According to
the Michigan projections, enactment of the surcharge would lower the
1968 rate of rise in the C-NP implicit price deflator by only 0.3 percent-
age point. The rate of rise in the implicit deflator for consumer
expenditures would be reduced by only 0.4 percentage point.
We ask: Would such a negligible gain in price stability be worth
the sacrifice of 800,000 jobs and $15 to $16 billion in GNP? To ask
that question is to answer it.
WHARTON SCHOOL PROJECTIONS
As noted, the Wharton School projections do not agree in all de-
tails with the Michigan. projections. But, in view of the elaborate
and careful analyses of past experience upon which both the Michigan
and Wharton School models are based, it would be perilous to ignore
dangerous tendencies signaled by both.
The Wharton projections show less-though still very substan-
tial-losses in C-NP and jobs resulting from the surcharge than do
the Michigan projections; but they also show even less gain in price
stability.
As of the fourth quarter of 1968, the Wharton projections show
that the C-NP annual rate (in then current dollars) would be $9 bil-
lion less with than without the surcharge. The unemployment rate
would be 4.5 percent with the surcharge instead of 4.1 percent with-
out it-a difference of more than 300,000 jobs. The GNP implicit
price deflator (1958 equals 100) would be 122.5 with the surcharge
and 122.6 without it-an improvement of only 0.1 percentage points.
PAGENO="0190"
901
Without the surcharge, the increase in the deflator from the fourth
quarter of 1967 to the fourth quarter of 1968 would be 3.1 percent-
no grea.ter than between the same quarters of 1966 and 1967.
THE RISKS
No one is in a position to say today which group of forecasters will
turn out to have been most accurate when the final economic score
for 1968 comes in. The members of the Council and of the Michigan
and Wharton groups are all responsible, have reputations at stake,
and must be presumed to have done their best.
But this committee and the Congress must act before the score is
added up. The question this committee and the Congress must. answer
is: Has the Council ju~ti/led a gamble with the jobs of hundreds of
thousands of workers, with the welfare of their families, with the
tranquility of the Nation's cities, and with billions of dollars of
potential GNP.~
The answer, in our opinion, is that the Council has not made a per-
suasive case for the surcharge-that recent and current developments
in the economy as well as carefully prepared a.nd solmdly based fore-
casts by other reputable economists argue against the Council's posi-
tion-and that it would be irresponsible to assume the risks that would
be involved if the Council's advice were to be followed.
What of the risks on the other side? What if the Council should
turn out to be correct that failure to enact the surcharge would lead
to the generation of serious inflationary pressures? To these questions
there are two answers. The first is that it is sounder to risk rising
prices than to risk rising unemployment. The second is that, a.s will be
shown, there are alternatives and better means than the surcharge to
deal with the problem the Council anticipates, if that problem should
materialize.
AN ALTERNATIVE APPROACH
In the statement submitted to this committee last year, we stressed
that we were not opposed to tax increases as such but only to tax pro-
posals that were designed to drain demand out of the economy and
thereby to reduce employment opportunities while we were still far
short of genuine full employment. WTe opposed cuts in total Govern-
ment spending because they also would destroy employment oppor-
~unities and, in addition, would defer or prevent solution of urgent
national problems. We emphasized that we would heartily support
selective monetary and fiscal measures-including equitable tax in-
creases-designed to reallocate resources so as to speed achievement of
the Nation's high-priority social and economic goals. We pointed out
also that selective measures can be used to minimize inflationary pres-
sures and dangers, thus removing the inhibitions that stand in the way
of an all-out drive toward full employment.
That is still our position. This year, the nature of the inflationary
problem, as envisioned by the Council, argues all the more strongly
for the application of selective measures rather than use of the blunt
instrument of the surcharge advocated by the Council.
The Council's prognosis has been quoted above. What is foreseen
is that, in the absence of the surcharge, rising consumer spending
PAGENO="0191"
905
would trigger a new boom in fixed business investment and in inven-
tory accumulation-which may be translated as inventory speculation
in anticipation of higher prices.
The Council can hardly argue that, with present unemployment and
the present wide margin of unused capacity, the increase in consumer
spending alone would put unbearable pressure upon resources. The
danger, if there is any real danger, is that disproportionate spending
on plant and equipment and on inventories would prove unsustain-
able. Distortions would thereby be created which could lead to a reces~
sion. As the Council says, "soaring profits" could generate a capital
goods boom "in 1969, if not sooner [which] could sow the seeds of a
subsequent collapse of investment in plant and equipment." Inven-
tory speculation, similarly, could be replaced by disaccumulation put-
ting additional downward pressure on the level of economic activity.
A capital goods boom could also affect the balance of payments. As
the Council pointed out in its 1967 report, a 50-percent increase in
imports of capital goods occurred during the 1966 investment splurge
which accounted for 20 percent of that year's total increase in imports.
It is notworthy also that the rise in nonfarm wholesale prices, which
began in late 1964 after 5 years of stability, and which has continued
since, was touched off by the capital goods industries in response to
inordinately high investment demand.
The problem as described above calls for preparation to head off
an investment boom and inventory speculation if and when there
should be signs that they are imminent. This can be done most effec-
tively by standby, selective fiscal and monetary measures. Standby
measures are appropriate since the Council apparently does not expect
that absence of the proposed surcharge would lead to a business spend-
ing spree before late 1968 at the earliest.
If there is clear danger of an unsustainable investment boom, it
would be utterly ridiculous to continue `the investment `tax credit which
was designed to stimulate investment. Instead of stepping on the
accelerator, the brakes should be applied. The situation would call for
the reverse of the tax credit-for example, a special `tax on investment
spending. Similarly, inven'tory speculation could be deterred, for ex-
ample, by a tax on inventories in excess of `the individual firm's ratio of
inventories to sales during an appropriate base period. Legislation au-
thorizing such taxes could be enacted now with the proviso that they
would not go into effect until a Presidential decision to impose them
had been concurred in by ~ joint resolution `adopted by both Houses
of Congress. Thus, the Nation would be armed on the fiscal front to
meet the danger the Council envisions.
Similarly, on the monetary front, the Federal Reserve Board could
make it known now that it is prepared to make selective use of all the
powers at its disposal to curb lending for investment and excessive
inventory ,acumulajtion, if and when they threaten to get out of hand,
while maintaining an adequate flow of credit for housing, for the needs
of State and local governments, and for other high-priority purposes.
In the unlikely event that consumer spending should threaten to put
undue pressure upon capacity, a progressive spending tax-~along
lines described above-which could also be enacted on a standby basis,
could meet that problem.
PAGENO="0192"
906
Any or all of the above measures could and should be accompanied
by implementation of the price-wage review procedure-also described
above-which would prevent abuse of administered pricing power to
pervert rising demand into inflation rather than full employment.
The above suggestions are not offered as definitive proposals. There
may be better ways to serve the intended' purposes. The measures de-
scribed above are advanced solely in order to illustrate the point that
the present state `of economic knowledge makes available a large arsenal
of selective weapons which can be aimed with precision at the specific
problems the Council envisions and at other problems that may arise
as we press on `toward full employment.
We call, in short, for a rifle' shot rather than a blunderbuss ap-
proach to those problems. If the' danger is that pursuit of maximum
profits will cause excessive business spending, it would `b~ inexcusable,
to say the least, to meet that danger by a measure `suéh as the sur-
charge, which would inflict hardship and unemployment upon the
most disadvantaged among us-upon families that are in no way to
blame for creating the danger.
Selective measures can be'applied equitably to avoid needless hard-
ship and unstabilizing distortions in the economy and to' advance us
toward our national goals. Gross fiscal and monetary measures are
inequitable in their impact, victi1nize the innocent, do not prevent dis-
tortions, and allow for no distinction between high-priority national
purposes and matters of lesser importance.
The proposed surcharge is afflicted with all the defects that apply
in general to gross measures. In addition, its enactment now would
create grave risks. On those grounds we oppose it and urge considéra-
tion of standby selective measures.
THE WAR ON POVERTY
The war on poverty is a. casualty of failure to keep our national
priorities in order. As we in the TJAWT have emphasized repeatedly,
victory in that war requires':
Jobs for all who can work;
Decent wages for those at work; and
Decent incomes for those unable or denied the opportunity to
work. ` `
Because we have failed to move with sufficient Vigor on all of these
three fronts, we are not winning but losing the war on poverty. `When
poverty is measured `in relative terms, as it should be, there were a~s
of 1966 and probably are now acti~ally more families who s/i'ovld be
con-siclered poor than when the' Na~tio'n first committed itself to make
war on poverty.
On the job front, acceptance of the Council's goal of 3.8 percent un-
employment fo'r 1968 would mean to condemn to continued poverty
those who are capable `of earning their own way but for whom there
are no jobs.
Yet there is no lack of work to be done `in America. We can provide
more jobs than there `are able-bodied poor to fill by doing the work that
most needs doing in our society-remodeling our cities, building the
homes and schools and hospitals and other facilities we so desperately
PAGENO="0193"
907
need, cleaning up our air and water, and the other myriad of necessary
task's that must rank high on our list of national priorities.
So long as, and to the extent that, private industry fails to provide
the needed jobs, government should provide them by acting as em-
ployer of last resort.
The crucial actions required on the wage front are to broaden the
coverage and to increase the minimum wages provided for under the
Fair Labor Standards Act. According to the Social Security Adminis-
tration, 1.9 million families with 9.5 million members in all, including
5.4 million children under age 18, were poor in 1966, even though the
family head worked full time throughout the year. By the most recent
estimate available, another 600,000 persons not attached to families
were in the same plight in 1964.
The minimum wage for those covered by the Fair Labor Standards
Act prior to 1966 went to $1.60 per hour `as of February 1968. A worker
fully employed 52 weeks a year at that wage earns slightly less than the
Council's 1966 minimum consumption standard of $3,335 for a non-
farm family of four, and with prices continuing to rise the gap will
grow. For workers first brought under coverage of the act in 1966,
the current minimum wage is only $1.15 per hour. Altogether, approxi-
mately two-fifth's `of all persons in families classified `by the Council
as poor in 1966 either worked full time themselves or were members
of families headed by full-time workers. Yet, although the Council
concedes that minimum wage legislation contributes to the elimination
of poverty, it. fails to call for further improvement of that legislation.
On the income maintenance front, the war on poverty has only
begun to `nibble at the flanks `of the enemy. The last session of Congress
enacted a disgracefully inadequate increase in social security benefits.
When the new benefit levels become effective, those whose entire in-
comes consist of benefits at the `bottom of the scale will receive roughly
two-fifths-if they are single-to `one-h'alf-if they have eligible
spouses-of what they need to lift them out of poverty, in accordance
with the standard applied by the Council.
As the Council's report says, if Congress had accepted the minimum
$70 social security benefit and other improvements proposed by the
administration, an additional 500,000 aged people would have been
freed from poverty. But $70 a month for a single person, or $105 for
a couple, is still a poverty income. Canada, with a substantially lower
per capit~a income than ours, is able to pay a minimum benefit of $210
per month as a matter of right to every retired couple without other
income.
The pitifully small increases in social security benefits enacted
last year were coupled with punitive measures against welfare recipi-
ents reminiscent of the Elizabethan poor laws. Welfare payments,
unemployment insurance, workmen's compensation benefits and other
income maintenance programs, as well as social security, still provide
only poverty incomes to large numbers and, in some cases, to the great
majority, of those dependent upon them. Many more are denied even
the grossly inadequate payments provided under existing programs.
The glaring gaps and inadequacies in the Nation's income mainte-
nance programs must be filled without delay. If we mean what we say
about waging war on poverty, we will proceed with all possible speed
90-191----68-pt. 3-13
PAGENO="0194"
908
both to provide above-poverty m~inimum benefits under all social in-
surance programs and to establish a soundly designed pro gram~ pio-
viding an adequate gvaranteed minimium income for all. \\Te hope the
Commission on Income Maintenance Programs recently appointed by
the President will recommend bold and swift action in both areas.
HOW M~OH PROGRESS?
Given the Nation's failures to mount effective attacks on the three
fronts where the war on poverty must be won, it is not surprising that
we are making only slow progress when measured by the Council's
absolute and frozen standard for defining poverty and no progress at
all when measured by a more rational and more humane relative
standard.
Even by the most commonly used standard, which the Council has
adopted as its own, we are making progress at a rate which will not
result in the elimination of poverty before about 1980 or 1985. The
Council of Economic Advisers describes this standard as follows:
For statistical purposes, households are defined as poor if their income falls
below the cost of a certain minimum consumption standard-$2.185 in current
prices for a nonfarm couple under 65 years of age, ~3,335 for a nonfarm family of
four, and so on.
In other words, although the standard varies by size of family,
age, and location, and the dollar amounts are adjusted for changes in
living costs, the actual buying power below which a family in a
given category is considered poor does not change. The present stand-
ard was a.dopted on the basis of 1962 living standards, and it repre-
sents the same standard today as it did in that year.
By this standard, the Council reports considerable progress. It
states:
Between 1059 and 1966, the number of poor declined sharply from 38.9 to 29.7
million, or from 22.1 to 15.4 percent of the population.
But, is this an acceptable way to fix a standard for measuring
poverty? Its implication is that the standard of living below which
we consider families to be poor is not to be permitted to rise with the
improvement in living standards of the rest of society. It would mean
that once those now considered poor have seen their incomes raised to
a level fixed 6 years ago, the rest of us will be free, in all good con-
science, to turn our attention elsewhere.. \\Te would be relieved of all
obligation to assure them even a minimum share in the fruits of
society's growing productivity-since 1962 a.nd forever into the future.
Yet., as tile standards of the whole Nation rise and they are left behind,
they will still be considered poor both by their neighbors and in their
own eyes.
The lack of realism in such a frozen standard is easily appreciated
if the same process is traced backward in time. Tables attached to
the Council's report give us data on living costs and earnings as far
back as 1929. In that year the Consumer Price Index, at 59.1, was
just about one-half of today's level. To be precise-$3,335 per year,
which marks the poverty line for a family of four at average 1967
prices, is the equivalent of an income of $1,711 a year at 1929 prices, or
just under $33 per week.
PAGENO="0195"
909
A family of four with an income of $33 a week would not have been
considered poor in 1929. Average gross weekly earnings in manii-
facturing industries were only $24.76 in 1929, and the average factory
worker who had a steady job, though he undoubtedly would have
like to be better off, certainly did not consider himself to be poor.
By comparison, average weekly earnings in manufacturing in 1967
were $114.90 per week, or $5,975 a year for a fully employed worker.
The poverty level for a family of four, at $3,335, is just 56 perceiit of
this. Thus, a family of four is considered poor, by the Council's stand-
ard, if it has less than 56 percent of the income of an average factory
worker. That does not seem unreasonable. But an income of $33 per
week which provided the same standard of living in 1929 was one-
third higher than that of the average factory worker. To consider $33
an appropriate "poverty line" for that time is entirely unreasonable.
Part of the difference, of course, is that it was in fact impossible
for anyone in 1929 to enjoy the same standard of living as we do today.
Many of the conveniences which we take for granted, frequently to the
extent of considering them necessities, did not exist for anyone in
1929. Advancing technology has given us a multiplicity of new things-
new household equipn'ient, new textiles, new foods, the list could be
extended indefinitely-that have revolutionized our way of life in less
than 40 years.
To adopt a rigid, unchanging standard of consumption to repre-
sent the poverty level for any given family would be to deny the poor
any share in the benefits of the technological revolution.
One of the major causes of trouble in our central. cities has been the
alienation of large sections of our people who, by reason of poverty,
discrimination, and neglect, have felt themselves denied the right to
participate in the mainstream of America's progress. The concept of
a fixed poverty consumption standard carries with it the implication
that the poor must continue to be cut off from that progress. It pro-
claims that if we bring the poor up to a level of consumption that was
barely tolerable 6 years ago, we will have done enough. But the poor
will not consider it enough-nor should we.
POVERTY IS RELATIVE
Poverty is a relative matter. It can have no absohite standard. It
might conceivably be possible to draw up and price a consumption
standard that was just barely sufficient to maintain human existence-
just enough calories and vitamins to sustain the spark of life, just
enough clothing to cover nakedness, just enough shelter to prevent
death by exposure. Such a standard is conceivable. In fact, it must be
admitted to our everlasting shame that there are still sections of our
country where people are living at such a standard-and dying when
they fall below it. But to adopt such a standard, to say that only below
such a level is anyone poor, would be intolerable to the conscience of
America.
Yet, the moment a higher standard is accepted, the moment it is
admitted that even the poor should have something beyond the bare
necessities, there must be admitted also the necessity to raise that staiicl-
ard along with the living standards of all the rest of the people. As
PAGENO="0196"
910
those standards rise, what were once luxuries become comforts, com-
forts become common conveniences, conveniences become nece,ssities.
And so it is for the poor as well as for the more affluent.
People are considered poor, and consider themselves poor, not by any
arbitrary measure of what. they have, but by how far what they have
fails below the commonly accepted standard of the society in which
they live. This does not mean that everyone, is poor who falls below
the average. It means that the standard of poverty is: How far does
he fall below the average?
An ingenious and entirely reasonable method for establishing such
a standard was proposed by Victor IR. Fuchs in the Summer 1967 issue
of "The Public Interest." 1-le wrote:
I propose that we define as poor any family whose income is less titan one-It aif
the median. family income. No special claim is made for the precise figure of
one-half; but the advantages of using a poverty standard that changes with the
growth of real national income are considerable.
Fir~t, it explicitly recognizes that all so-called `minimum' or `subsistence'
budgets are based on contemporary standards which will soon be out of date.
Second, it focuses attention on what seems to be a fundamental factor under-
lying the present concern about poverty-i.e., it represents a tentative groping
toward a national policy with respect to the distribution of income.
Finally, it provides a more realistic basis for appraising the success or failure
of anti-poverty programs. [Emphasis in original.]
The median income is that level which places exactly half the fain-
ilies above it and half below it. For some purposes it represents a more
satisfactory concept of what. we consider the average family than does
the. arithmetic mean, because, unlike the latter, the median is not
affected by how wealthy the very wealthy are, or how poor the very
poor.
If we accept. `the concept of the median income as that of the average
family, then Mr. Fuchs' formula means. in essence, that any ~family is
cons~.dered poor if it has les.i than half the income of the average fa.m-
`ii at any given tim~.
As Mr. Fuchs himself admits, it would be desirable to refine his
formula somewhat before implementing its use. He points out that
there is nothing sacred, for example, about the precise figure of one-
half. It is useful, however, in that one-half the median income in 1962
wa.s only slightly over $3,000, the family poverty level accepted at that
time.
Obviously, also, the same poverty figure cannot be applied to fam-
ilies of all sizes, ages, and locations. This was a deficiency of the official
poverty concept when it was first established, and it was corrected by
careful research on the part of Social Security Administration tech-
nicians. We now have different poverty levels for different types of
families, based on nmnber and ages of children, ages of adults, farm
or nonfarm location, and so on. The same research could be applied to
Mr. Fuchs' formula, except that instead of expressing the poverty level
in different dollar amounts for different types of families, it would be
expressed in different percentages of the median family income.
The startling fact about Fuchs' definition of poverty, however, is
that if we accept it we find that we have made virtually no progress at
all in eliminating poverty. He published with his article the attached
table (to which TJAW technicians have added one more year of data)
PAGENO="0197"
911
showing `since 1947 the percentage of families each year with incomes
below half the median, as well as the percentages with inqomes below
$3,000 and $2,000 (in constant 1965 dOllars), respectively. The table
shows that, between 1947 and 1966, families with less than $3,000 of
1965 buying power fell from 30 percent of the total to 15.1 percent.
But the proportion of fan-~ilies with less than one-half the median
income showed no significant change, fluctuating between 18.9 and
20.9 percent of the total.
PERCENTAGE OF U.S. FAMILIES CLASSIFIED `POOR" BY CHANGING AND FIXED STANDARDS, 1947-66.
Ito 1965 dollarsj
Year
Median income
Percent
age of families with ináome-
Less than 3'~ the
median 1
Less than $3,000
Less
than $2,000
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
1947
1948
1949
1950
1951
$4,275
4,178
4,116
4, 351
4 507
18.9
19.1
20.2
20. 0
18 9
30.0
31.2
32.3
29. 9
27 8
17.2
18.1
19.5
18. 1
16 3
1952
1953
1954
1955
1956
1957
1958
1959
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
19662
4,625
5,002
4, 889
5,223
5,561
5,554
5,543
5,856
5, 991
6,054
6,220
6,444
6,676
6,882
7,231
18.9
19.8
20. 9
20.0
19.6
19.7
19.8
20.0
20. 3
20.3
19.8
19.9
19.9
20.0
19.2
26.3
24.6
26. 2
23.6
21.5
21.7
21.8
20.6
20. 3
20.1
18.9,
18.0
17.1
16.5
15.1
*
~
15.8
15.4
16. 7
14.6
13.0
13.0
12.8
12.1
12. 1
11.9
10.9
10.2
9.2
9.1
(3)
I Estimated by interpolation.
2 UAW estimates.
3 Not available.
Source: U.S. Bureau of the Census, Current Population Reports series P-60, No. 51, "Income in 1965 of Families and
Persons in the United States," January 1967. (From the Public Interest, summer 1967.)
In other words, the proportion of families who are poor because
they enjoy less than half the income of the average family is no smaller
today than it was 20 years ago, and in absolute numbers of poor fami-
lies we are actually losing gronnd. In percentage terms,. the improve-
ment since we began talking about a war on poverty has been minus-
cule. In fact, the percentage of poor families has been higher in recent
years than in some years of the late forties and early fifties.
It is true that a closer study of family income distribution does show
one encouraging sign. There has been some upward movement within
the ranks of the poor, for the proportion with incomes between one-
quarter and one-half of the median has increased somewhat, with a
corresponding decrease in the proportion having less than one-quarter
of the median. But we have a long way still to go.
SENSE OF URGENCY. NEEDED
We know what actions are needed. The present administration and
its predecessor have called again and again for them to be done. TJn-
fortunately, they have not always called for as much to be done as
90-191-68---pt. 3-14
PAGENO="0198"
912
was needed, and they have not been able to obtain from reluctant
Congresses even the full amount that they have asked for. This has
been especially true in the most recent years, when our national
priorities have been getting more and more seriously out of order.
It is a sense of urgency that is essential-a sense of urgency in the
administration, a sense of urgency in the Congress, a sense of urgency
in State and local governments, a sense of urgency in the people.
Lieut. Gen. James M. Gavin, USA (ret.), felt it when, with Arthur
Had1~y, he wrote in Saturday Review February 24,1968:
In the urban ghetto, migrants slowiy begin to ieave-if they have not already-
what we like to think of as "our America". They become among those uncounted
by the census. Denied participation in the American dream, they become `they'
and `them'. So the cities-and, through them, the nation-tragically divide into
"we" and "they". And inflaming this division to the raw edge of violence is the fact
that overwhelmingly "we" are white and "they" are black. This underculture of
poverty has now gone on for so long that the Negro poor are already practically
a separate society. They are not yet a separate nation with aspirations different
from ourowli. But unless we both work together-"we" and "they"-America will
in fact divide more fatally than at any time in our history.
I wish there were some eloquence I could use, some fact I could cite, some
verbal Pearl Harbor I could deploy, so that all Americans would rise and say:
"That is true, I personally must do something about it." The riots in Watts and
Detroit are there for all to look at. A recent report to President Johnson by a
White House-appointed board of experts opened with the words: "You are the
last President to have the option of governing one nation." I would not be that
definite. But I do not believe that the report-at this writing, unreleased-
exaggerates by much.
Time is, indeed, running out. History will judge our generation of
Americans by what we do in human terms with the vast wealth at our
command. Its judgment will be deservedly harsh if we, who are closer
than any people ever were to the possibility of creating a paradise on
earth, permit our country, instead, to become a social jungle.
PLANNING THE DEMOCRATIC Ftrruun
To cope with the distress and injustice in our midst-with poverty,
our deteriorating cities, our sick, our unemployed, the disaffection of
our young, the insecurity of our aged-we must lift these prdblems to
the center of our concern.
We must appreciate the fact that not gold or the dollar or our bal-
ance of payments, but the people of this country, constitute our funda-
mental security, our fundamental investment, our fundamental hope.
Their education, skills, discipline, commitment, well-being, aspiration
are the bedrock of our economy and the wellspring of our way of life.
We must, secondly, see in their true magnitude and full dimensions
the wealth and economic capabilities of this Nation. There exists no
historical or contemporary parallel to the human and teclmological
resources we command. To paraphrase the poet, the fault lies not in our
resources but in ourselves, if we fail to realize our promise.
So great is our present productivity that, despite all the inefficien-
cies of our economy, our current Gross National Product stands at
$4,000 per person, or $16,000 for a family of four. Yet the GNP, thus
evenly parceled out, is a statistical abstraction that hides the mocking
realities of poverty, deprivation, unemployment, frivolous luxury, and
senseless waste.
PAGENO="0199"
913
We have, thirdly, an overriding responsibility to use the unparal-
leled resources at our disposal more wisely, more sensibly, more justly.
We must turn our attention from our aggregate wealth and its aggre-
gate accretion year by year to its more effective use. Our thoughts must
go to what a better and happier America we can build, not in some
remote future but now and in the very next tomorrows, by consciously
diverting resources from unessential or foolish purposes to the chal-
lenging tasks of social and human renewal.
Yet, thinking won't make it so. Thought, unless quickly followed by
appropriate actions, will be only a sentimental and even a dangerous
evasion. It is too late in the date for leisurely study. We must lose
no time in putting our house in order. We shall continue to mvest
the democratic future badly until we move from wishful thinking to
deliberate planning in applying our vast resources to the areas of
critical human need.
We are still trusting too much to the random forces of the private
market. It is our peculiar delusion that the private sector of our econ-
omy can buy and sell us into a better tomorrow. Yet the evidence
under our feet and before our eyes testifies that we cannot manage
the expansion, distribute the abundance, and solve the growing prob-
lems of a late 20th century postindustrial society according to the
simple notions of laissez faire economic activity handed dawn to us
from the 18th century.
We must accept the plain fact that the private sector is not so con-
stituted that it can plan as a sector in the national interest. Corpora-
tions plan ingeniously for their own ends, but there is no easy cor-
respondence between what separate employers may regard as their
particular advantage and the larger needs and interests of the Nation.
Government, therefore, must assume the ultimate responsibility
for developing and conducting a democratic form of planning to as-
sure that investment and resources are shared between and within the
private and public sectors to meet priority needs and achieve national
goals.
The terrible summer of 1967 demonstrated beyond any doubt our
urgent need to~ plan as a nation to meet national needs. Until that
summer, employers of the private sector had gone blithely on their
way, decentralizing their operations, building new plants in the
segregated suburbs, ignoring the unemployed of the ghettos. In the
light of last summer's fires, the businessmen saw, and many of the
most enlightened among them acknowledged, the error of their ways.
They have begun to face two basic facts: their need to involve them-
selves directly in the reconstruction of American cities, both in the
physical and the human sense; and their need to cooperate with labor
and Government in attacking the social and economic ills that beset
the Nation.
Many of these businessmen have entered the urban coalition and
have endorsed the coalition's statements of intention, which include
the following passages:
We believe the American people and the Congress must reorder national priori-
ties, with a commitment of resources equal to the magnitude of the problems
we face. The crisis requires a new dimension of effort in both the public and
private sectors, working together to provide jobs, housing, education, and the
other needs of the cities.
* * * * * *
PAGENO="0200"
914
Government and business must accept responsibility to provide all Americans
with opportunity to earn an adequate income. Private industry must greatly
accelerate its efforts to recruit, train and hire the hard-core unemployed.
When the private sector is unable to provide employment to those who are
both able and willing to work, then in a free society the Government must of
necessity assume the responsibility and act as the employer of last resort or
must assure adequate income levels for those who are unable to work.
The clear im~p1ication of these statements is that we must develop
a national planning mechanism to insure the necessary coordination of
efforts in the two sectors. For the ends sought cannot be realized unless
we possess the institutional means to assess our national needs, to estab-
lish priorities for meeting those needs within the limitations of our
resources, and then to allocate the resources between and within the
private and public sectors to accomplish our defined purposes. Since
the planning must be democratic, not merely business but all the func-
tioning groups of the society must be heard in the process of establish-
ing priorities and achieving goals.
We are not proposing here, it should be understood, any system of
coercion. Rather we propose use of the democratic process to arrive
at a censensus with respect to goals, priorities, and time schedule for
their achievement. Out of this consensual process there would emerge,
as a byproduct, a common framework of assumptions as to the future
course of the economy. Within such a framework, both Government
decisions and decisions in the private sector could be made with greater
confidence and would be more effective because they would reinforce
each other rather than work, as they now frequently do, at cross pur-
poses. The net effect of such democratic planning would be not restraint
but liberation. Our great resources could be deployed much more effec-
tively in meeting private and public needs.
The plan would provide the basis for determination of the selec-
tive measures, monetary and fiscal among others, needed to assure the
availability at the right time of the resources needed to achieve the
plan's goals. Since the plan will have evolved from democratic cen-
sensus, the selective measures required to carry it out should obtain
ready and widespread acceptance. There should therefore be little
difficulty in enlisting the cooperation of the political authorities in
enacting and applying such selective measures as may be needed to
facilitate implementation of the plan.
Nothing has happened since the summer of 1967 to diminish the
urgency of the challenges the urban coalition asks us to face. On the
contrary. President J~hnson in his February 22 message on urban
problems stressed, "There is no time to lose." He declared:
Today, America's cities are in crisis. This clear and urgent warning rises from
the decay of decades-and is amplified by the harsh realities of the present.
There is no time to lose, but we are losing it. The IJAW seriously
urges upon the Congress as a body, and upon each Congressman and
Senator, `a more sober consideration of the real dangers and oppor-
tunities implicit in our domestic situation, not so much in terms of
what might be regarded as opportune in an election year but rather
in a dispassionate effort to clear `away the cobwebs of fashionable
assumption and get to the bone and marrow of our predicament.
Whether we look abroad to the cities of the struggling and develop-
ing nations or steadily confront the crises of our own communities,
PAGENO="0201"
915
we are bound to understand that the ultimate questions of social and
economic justice underlying all prospects for world or local peace
cannot be answered by firepower. American values and American
hopes depend ultimately not on the answers that come out of the
barrel of a gun but out of a steady commitment to demonstrate their
worth and their relevance in t'he daily lives of people.
We have temporarily forgotten that invaluable truism. Let us
come back to its saving truth. Let us do what has to be done to make
our Nation and our people whole. Our prime concern is not our
balance of payments but the balance between our capabilities as a
democratic society and our efforts to realize those capabilities within
the Nation, where our writ runs without hindrance and our responsi-
bility is therefore absolute.
PAGENO="0202"
UNITED MINE WORKERS OF AMERICA
By W. A. BomE, Piu~smin~r
We appreciate the opportunity to present our views on the Eco-
nomic Report of the President and the Report of the Council of
Economic Advisers.
This year we would like to confine our remarks to four general
areas:
1. Wage-price restraints.
2. Governmental fiscal policy.
3. International trade.
4. Research and development.
WAGE-PRICE RESTRAINTS
Over the past several years the question of wage-price control meas-
ures has appeared in much of the economic literature. The President
himself has added to this literature in his periodic messages on the
subject and through the Council of Economic Advisers.
The thrust of the concept as advocated by the President and the
CEA is that restraint on the part of business and labor is necessary
if we are to avoid a wage-price spiral. Following this line, a strong
suggestion is made that national productivity should be the guiding
limit on wage increases and that companies should refrain from
unnecessary price increases.
There are, of course, several inconsistencies in this policy.
1. We do not believe it to be necessary. In fact, wage-price control
has historically proven to be ineffective short of wartime conditions
and even then of only marginal benefit. We suggest that there are
several very stringent avenues to prevent runaway inflation, avenues
which inspire a far greater discipline than any conceived under either
voluntary or mandatory controls. These are the disciplines of:
(a) The marketplace-where consumers may choose not to buy
if price and quality are not to their liking.
(b) Competition-where a new and better way imposes ceilings
on the price levels in the private sector.
(c) Commonsense-which leads reasonable men to consider
the well-being of the Nation, as well as their own in any action
which they take.
~Te in the coal industry are prima facie evidence of the effectiveness
of such disciplines. Since 1948 the price of coal has declined. During
this period wage levels of coal miners ha.ve increased and the general
price level has skyrocketed. But the chilling impact of stringent com-
petition, the presence of alternate fuels, and the statesmanlike realiza-
tion on the part of industry leaders that the future security of the
industry was at stake held down coal prices.
(916)
PAGENO="0203"
917
2. Wage-price restraints fall unevenly on the population. It is all
too easy to single out a union which is asking `for a long overdue wage
increase. But, very often much larger increases in fees by the service
industries and the professions go unnoticed because they are accom-
plished quietly and without the fanfare associated with collective
bargaining. Yet, as most wage earners, are acutely aware,, such in-
creases bite deeply into the pocketbook of the average American.
3. Wage restraints are burdensome upon the wage earner without~
an equal `burden being placed upon profits. if such restraints are nec-
e~ssary, then the man who works for wages and the man who collects
the profits should share such a burden equally. This is especially perti-
nent in those industries with higher than average productivity, but
with relatively rigid price structures. History has shown that in these
instances there has been developed `a growing disparity between the in-
come of workers measured in wage payments and the income of man-
agers and owners measured in dividends, profits, bonuses, and so forth.
But, short of a declared war emergency and short of a fair and
equitable sharing of the burden, we feel that we should pursue the
interests of our members through the medium of free collective bar-
gaining. This method has served us and the Nation well in the past.
We would be ill advised to deviate from it now without an over-
whelming reason to do so.
GOVERNMENTAL FISCAL POLICY
If one examines the dilemma facing the country today in the eco-
nomic area, one fact is obvious-the fiscal policy of the Governnient
is the major engine of inflation. The, needs of national defense, espe--
cially the conflict in Vietnam, are `the major causes of the distortion,
in our fi~cal framework.
Therefore, it i-s incumbent on the administration to cut its fiscaF
cloth to match available resources. In short, we have come to a time~
for priorities, for choosing those programs of greatest significance
and postponing those Of lesser `vahie~
To some this would mean `a retrenchment in many of the programs
of the Great Society-the war on poverty, the Federal aid to educa-
tion program, and so forth.
We reject this as false economics because we believe that such ef-
forts will return much to our Nation ~nd in fact, are vital, to the
continued viability of our social, political, and economic institutions.
Indeed, if the unfortunate struggle in Vietnam has taught us any
lesson at all, it has taught us the importance of a population dedi-
cated to a system of government as basic to their own individual wel-
fare. If this is lacking, if our ghetto residents, or our rural poor,
look to other systems for a hope in life, our national well-being is
in serious jeopardy. , .-
On the other hand, there are programs `which can be curtailed or
postponed without undue damage to the economy. I refer especially to
the civilian nuclear power program, which consumes hundreds of
millions `of dollars each year. Much of the work being done in this
program can be postponed or `even canceled.
We are sure that there are other similar areas throughout the Fed-
eral budget. We hope that the Members of Congress will diligently
seek them out and prune wherever possible.
PAGENO="0204"
918
INTERNATIONAL TRADE
A large part of the President's message dealt with the subject of
international finance. This concern is ~bvious because of the recent
devaluation of the British pound and the precarious position of the
dollar.
Much has been written and spoken on this subject and we can add
but little to the overall picture.
This much, however, we do know. So long as American political and
military commitments remain at their present levels, the dollar will
continue under sharp attack. In order for it to survive intact, two
things are required:
1. Public policy which will insure the continued viability of the
U.S. economy and which will protect it from the unfair impor-
tation of cheap foreign goods.
2. An aggressive, export-minded American industry with the
ability and the determination to compete successfully in foreign
markets.
The recent trade agreements concluded under the Kennedy Round
will intensify the competitive pressures under which American in-
dustry will have to operate.
American coal is in a unique position to help in the balance of pay-
ments in two ways.
First, U.S. coal is more than competitive abroad. Our coal, because
of the efficiency of the American coal miner, adds $500 million to
the U.S. balance of payments each year. America. ships coal to Japan,
Western Europe, Canada, and most of the coal-using nations of the
free world.
It does this on the bases of quality and price.
The fact that we do not send more coal abroad rests in the political
and not the economic sphere. Most of the nations of the world erect
barriers to the entry of U.S. coal. Frequently, such barriers are non-
tariff in nature, but extremely effective nonetheless.
Space does not permit me to catalog such barriers. Nevertheless,
they do exist and as such tend to minimize the value of coal exports to
the economy. They do so in two ways:
1. By reducing the market potential for U.S. coal.
2. By helping to create an atmosphere in which the export
market is regarded as an undependable market outlet, an outlet
to be exploited for the short run, but not to be developed for the
long pull.
Second, the large reserves of U.S. coal and the modern technology
to mine it should render us nearly self-sufficient insofar as fuels are
concerned.
Unfortunately, just the opposite is true. Energy sources are im-
ported into our markets in a flood, driving coal from its normal outlets.
Often such flooding is done by unfair means, by dumping tactics.
Currently, coal faces a competitive battle from South American
residual fuel oil, from Canadian naatural gas, and from Middle
Eastern oil. Last year there was an attempt to dump German coal into
the U.S. market.
In the face of such competitive pressures, the American coal indus-
try has stood virtually alone. Government officials, ignoring our pro-
PAGENO="0205"
919
tests, permitted and are even now permitting large blocs of foreign
energy to enter our shores. Residual fuel oil, for example, is decon-
trolled, for all practical purposes. So, too, is the importation of
Canadian natural gas.
In allowing TJ.S. coal to face such an unrestricted attack, the U.S.
Government is acquiescing in the weakening of an industry vital to
domestic security and important in world trade. It would seem obvious
that the present course is both illogical and self-defeating.
Many other industries and other trade unions are coming to the
same conclusions. As a result, our entire concept of international com-
merce is being reevaluated in many quarters, including the Congress
of the United States.
Hopefully, this inquiry will continue. For, even though we sub-
scribe to the ideal of freer international trade, we also know that such
trade should be on a truly reciprocal basis, with adequate protection
for essential domestic industries.
RESEARCH AND DEVELOPMENT
Our final section is perhaps the most important of all. We look to
research and development to assure the future in coal, just as America
must look to it for the continued prosperity and security of our
Republic.
The real frontier to be explored today is the border of science, the
effort to push ahead to new scientific breakthroughs. Only in this way
will further significant material and social progress be possible for all
Americans.
Any discussion of research and development inevitably leads one to
probe the role of the Federal Government. This is so because of the
dominant position occupied by the Federal Establishment in research
and development activity. For example, almost $17 billion is budgeted
for this purpose in the Presidential budget for fiscal year 1969.
This money and the scientific know-how which it commands can and
should have deep significance for all Americans. Its proper use should
permit our Nation to move ahead to solutions to some of our pressing
problems and to permit a fuller maximization of our human and
material resources.
But, instead, such full benefit is not accruing because in our opinion:
1. Most of the research effort is expended in three major fields-
space, defense, and atomic energy.
2. Little overall coordination is being done to permit a rational
view of the entire spectrum of research work.
3. Priorities dealing with the best possible alternative among a
great many desirable courses have not been drawn up.
The validity of our contention is quite evident in the energy indus-
try. For decades atomic energy has received the bulk of research
attention, while coal, our most plentiful energy resource, has received
a pitiful portion. This is not to infer that those charged with coal
research in Government have not done all that could be expected of
them. Rather, the resources committed to coal research have been infini-
tesimal compared with the potential benefit of such research.
Coal, as is well known, is a storehouse of chemical products, liquid
fuels, and energy. From coal can come many of the products necessary
PAGENO="0206"
920
in our industrial economy-oil, gas, chemicals, and energy itself. Upon
coal can be built industrial complexes employing hundreds of thou-
sands of men and women and pouring billions of dollars into the
national economy.
The bridge to such a happy situation is research, research which
today is both possible and practical-if-if sufficient resources are
made available to it.
We hope that this will be done in the years ahead.
In conclusion, we look forward to another year of prosperity and
progress for the United States in the economic sphere. We recognize
problems but, we believe that with intelligent action on the part of all
segments of our national life, we may move ahead to eliminate what-
ever barriers are impeding our national progress.
PAGENO="0207"
STATEMENT OF JERRY VOORHIS
I shall confine this statement to brief comments on three subjects:
health, education, and interest rates.
First, a sentence appears on page 160 of the report which reads in
part: "There appear to be significant efficiency gains from group prac-
tice." I wish that the comnuttee report had added the word "prepay-
ment" after "group practice." A number of studies as well as confer-
ences conducted by the Health, Education, and Welfare Department,
have recently demonstrated what some of us in the group health move-
ment have known for a long time, namely, that subscribers to group
practice-prepayment health plans have significantly lower rates of hos-
pital utilization than do other insured groups in the population. Hos-
pital costs are the most rapidly rising and by far the most expensive
item in the health cost of the American people. If health can be main-
tained among large groups in the population with a lesser use of hos-
pitalization, clear gains will have been made. I believe I am correct
that it has now become Government policy to encourage group practice
and prepayment for health care. Not only will this result in lower costs
in connection with medicare and other Government programs as well
as less drain on seriously overtaxed hospital facilities, but it will also
provide a better quality of care for the people who have the benefits of
group practice-prepayment health plans.
Serious consideration should be given toward applying on a much
wider scale a plan in effect in New York City. Inthat city some 15,000
to 20,000 welfare recipients are now given comprehensive high-quality
health care through Health Insurance Plan in Greater New York. The
welfare department of that city has had the wisdom to pool the funds
fomerly paid on a hit-and-miss emergency basis for spasmodic medical
care for its clients and to make direct per capita payments to Health
Insurance Plan. In return HIP contracts to provide all necessary
health care to this group of welfare clients. The net total cost is not
appreciably more than was formerly spent. The difference is these peo-
ple's health is now regularly maintained by carefully chosen groups of
doctors. The money is spent for health, not for sickness.
I can imagine no one measure which would contribute more toward
improving the chances of our poor people to work their way out of
poverty than for a plan of this kind to be more widely used.
Another measure that would make possible expansion of services by
group practice-prepayment health plans would be passage of legisla-
tion already introduced, to provide Government guarantee of private
loans for the construction of needed hospital facilities by nonprofit,
cooperative, community, labor and other types of group practice-pre-
payment plans.
My second comment has to do with education. While the present
program of federal aid to education, coupled with the Headstart pro-
(921)
PAGENO="0208"
922
gram, marked by far the best advance yet. made toward improvement, of
our educational system, they constitute only the beginning of what
the present generation owes to our beleaguered young people. In my
opinion, the Federal aid program should be expanded even more
than has now been done, particularly in assisting local school districts
with the cost of more adequate physical facilities so that their own
resources may be used toward payment of better salaries to more and
better qualified teachers. I also recommend careful study of the so-
called new careers movement as an element in the war on poverty and
the development of an extensive program for the training of educa-
tional aids among the low-income people who, with such training,
could make a significant contribution toward the enrichment and in-
creased practicability of the education provided to children in low-
income areas of both our cities and our rural areas.
The third subject which I wish to discuss is the rate of interest.
Every item in the consumer price index is affected by the rate of in-
terest. The higher the ra.te of interest, the more the cost of living is
forced upward, the greater inflationary pressures become, and the
more difficult it is to produce an adequate supply of the things most
needed by our people-housing, in particular. It needs no proof on
my part to show that low-cost housing especially expands and con-
tracts in inverse proportion to the rate of interest. If interest rates
are low, housing starts can be a.nd are expanded closer to the number
which our country so desperately needs. If interest rates go up, as
they have been so disastrously doing recently, it shuts off the supply
of new low-cost housing more surely than any other single. factor can
do.
Furthermore, interest rates at the high level at which they have
now been pushed quite literally, price out of the market for decent
homes millions of people who might be able to afford good housing
and even to own their own homes if the interest rate were lower. At
61/4 percent interest on a 30-year mortgage a $16,000 house costs $16,-
000 for the house but $20,000 for interest on the debt.
The present high level of interest rate has already pushed our bill for
interest on the Federal Government debt to the astronomica.l figure of
$14,200,000,000. Next only to expenditures on war, this is the largest
single item in the whole national budget. If interest rates had been
held at levels where they were held even under the terrific pressures of
World War II, the bill for interest on our Federal Government debt
would today be only about half it is!
High interest rates bear most heavily on those elements in the popu-
lation which are least able to bear additional burdens: namely, the poor,
the farmers, and small business. High interest rates penalize every
productive agency and institution in the economy. And the point must
somewhere be reached where the sheer weight of interest payments
becomes so great that the whole productive process in a free economic
order is slowed down. Admittedly, we have not yet quite reached that
point in the United States. But if present trends are `allowed to con-
tinue, we certainly shall reach it before long. The time is now when
measures should be instituted to reverse t.he trend toward higher and
higher interest rates and to bring them back into line with national
needs and elemental economic justice.
PAGENO="0209"
923
It simply is not true that higher interest rates act as a curb upon
inflation. Quite the contrary, as stated above, they add to the price of
practically every item in the economy. The only real reason for increas-
ing interest rates is because the Federal Reserve System and the lend-
ing institutions have the power to increase them. Higher rates are not
needed for the sake of economic prosperity of banks or other lending
institutions. Their rate of return to investors was higher than the return
to most investors when interest rates were much lower than they are
now.
There is probably no single economic influence which can encourage
the high level of productive activity which our country so critically
needs as much as a low interest rate can do. It is earnestly to be hoped
that the Joint Economic Commitee will urge upon all agencies of our
Government as well as the Federal Reserve System a prompt reversal
of the present high interest policy.
0
PAGENO="0210"