PAGENO="0001"
THE 1969 EthNOMIC REPORT
OF THE PRESIDENT
HEARINGS
BEFORE THE
JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE
CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES
NINETY-FIRST CONGRESS
FIRST SESSION
INVITED COM1\IENTS
PART 4
Printed for the use of the Joint Economic Committee
GOVERNMENT DEPOSITORY
PROPERTY OF RUTGERS, THE STATE UNIVERSITY
COLLEGE OF SOUTH JERSEY LIBRAI~Y
CAMDEN, N. J. 08102
~j\f~
13.5. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE
24-833 WASHINGTON: 1969
For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office
Washington, D.C. 20402 - Price$1.00
/J/~ (,
7/2 : 9~ 1~ V
PAGENO="0002"
HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES
RICHARD BOLLING, Missouri
HALE BOGGS, Louisiana
HENRY S. REUSS, Wisconsin
MARTHA W. GRIFFITHS, Michigan
WILLIAM S. MOORHEAD, Pennsylvania
WILLIAM B. WIDNALL, New Jersey
DONALD RUMSFELD, Illinois
W. E. BROCK III, Tennessee
BARBER B. CONABLE, JR., New York
SENATE
JOHN SPARKMAN, Alabama
J. W. FULBRIGHT, Arkansas
HERMAN E. TALMADGE, Georgia
STUART SYMINGTON, Missouri
ABRAHAM RIBICOFF, Connecticut
JACOB K. JAVITS, New York
JACK MILLER, Iowa
LEN B. JORDAN, Idaho
CHARLES H. PERCY, Illinois
RICHARD F. KAUFMAN ROBERT H. HAVEMAN
FRAZIER KELLOGG
JOHN R. KARLIR
DOUGLAS C. FRECHTLING (Minority)
JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE
[Created pursuant to sec. 5(a) of Public Law 304, 79th Cong.}
WRIGHT PATMAN, Texas, Cli airman
WILLIAM PROXMIRE, Wisconsin, Vice Chairman
JOHN R. STARK, Executive Director
JAMEs W. KNOWLES, Director of Research
ECONOMISTS
(II)
PAGENO="0003"
CONTENTS
Page
Letter of Representative Wright Patman, chairman of the Joint Economic
Committee, inviting comments on the 1969 Economic Report of the
President; preceded by a listing of organizations from whom statements
or comments were solicited 965
ORGANIZATIONS RESPONDING
American Bankers Association 967
American Farm Bureau Federation 974
American Life Convention and the Life Insurance Association of America~ - 977
Committee for Economic Development: Emilio G. Collado, chairman,
research and policy committee 983
Communications Workers of America 993
Conference on Economic Progress: Leon H. Keyserling, president 999
Cuna International, Inc.: J. Orrin Shipe, managing director 1057
Federal Statistics Users' Conference 1059
Machinery and Allied Products Institute: Charles W. Stewart, president. - 1064
The Inflation Dilemma, by George Terborgh, research director 1066
National Farmers Union: Angus McDonald director of research 1140
National Federation of Independent Business: John W. Harder, president. 1151
National Federation of Independent Unions: Don Mahon, executive
secretary 1154
United Automobile, Aerospace and Agricultural Implement Workers of
America (UAW): Walter P. Reuther, president 1156
United Mine Workers of America: W. A. Boyle, president 1185
Jerry Voorhis, past executive director, Cooperative League of the U.S.A__ 1189
(III)
PAGENO="0004"
PAGENO="0005"
THE 1969 ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT
The letter appearing below was sent to the following organizations:
American Bankers Association, American Farm Bureau Federation,
American Life Convention, Committee for Economic Development,
Communications Workers of America, Conference on Economic
Progress, Consumers Union of the U.S., Inc., Cooperative League
of the U.S.A., CUNA International, Inc., Federal Statistical
Users' Conference, Independent Bankers Association, Life Insurance
Association of America~, Machinery and Allied Products Institute,
National Association of Mutual Savings Banks, National Consumers'
League, National Farmers Organization, the National Farmers Union,
National Federation of Independent Business, Inc., National Federa-
tion of Independent Unions, the National Grange, National League
of Insured Savings Associations, National Planning Association, Rail-
way Labor Executive Association, United Automobile, Aerospace and
Agricultural Implement Workers of America (UAW), United Mine
Workers of America, United States Savings and Loan League. These
organizations were invited to submit their views or comments on
the text and recommendations contained in the 1969 Economic Report
of the President. Fourteen organizations submitted statements and
their views were considered by the Joint Economic Committee in the
preparation of its report on the President's Economic Report.
FEBRUARY -, 1069.
DEAR Under the Employment Act of 1946 the Joint Economic
Committee has the responsibility of filing each year a report containing its find-
ings and conclusions with respect to the recommendations made by the President
in his Economic Report. Because of the limited number of days available for
hearings, the committee is requesting a number of leaders of banking, business,
labor, agriculture, and consumer organizations to submit statements on the
economic problems facing the Nation. These statements will be made a part of our
hearings on the Economic Report in a printed volume containing such invited
statements.
We invite your comments on the economic issues which concern the Nation
and your own organization. Under separate cover we are sending you a copy of
the 1969 Economic Report of the President, filed January 16 by President Johnson.
Also, we will send you the testimony of the Chairman of the Council of Economic
Advisers under the new Administration when the Council appears before the
Committee later this month.
\~\Te would like to distribute copies of your statement to the members of the
Committee and the staff, and would therefore appreciate your sending 30 copies,
by March 1, 1969, to Mr. Hamilton D. Gewehr, Administrative Clerk, Room G-133,
New Senate Office Building, Washington, D.C. 20510.
With kindest regards and best wishes, I am
Sincerely yours,
WRIGHT PATMAN, Uhaiuinan..
(965)
PAGENO="0006"
PAGENO="0007"
AMERICAN BANKERS ASSOCIATION
The American Bankers Association is pleased to submit a statement
in connection with the annual hearings of the Joint Economic Com-
mittee on the state of the economy. The committee request asked for
"comments on the economic issues which concern the Nation and your
own organization." We have, therefore, selected for comment a num-
ber of specific issues upon which we feel the banking industry has
special competence to express itself. Largely these concern either credit
matters themselves or public policy that will ultimately affect the de-
mand and supply of credit. The issues raised, however, are of such
importance they transcend concern by the banking industry alone.
I
Periods of high employment such prevailed in 1968 and presumably
will prevail in 1969 put major strains on all financial institutions.
While the real growth of the economy from the previous year as meas-
ured by gross national product was only 5 percent in 1968 and price
increases added 4 percent to the growth in total GNP, the aggregate
volume of credit increased some 20 percent last year. The growth in
credit demand is the result of a combination of circumstances; high
aggregate demand as a result of strong business and consumer incomes,
the fact that rising prices makes future investment and production
appear abnormally profitable and attempts by businesses and consumer
to anticipate future price and interest rate increases and shortages.
That these conditions are occurring is, of course, the consequence of
unduly expansionary monetary and fiscal policy in 1967 and 1968.
The strain on financial institutions may take several forms. While
the traditional channels utilizing financial institutions under ordinary
circumstances are adequate to move a sufficient volume of savings into
investment, in periods of high employment demands for credit fre-
quently exceed the amount that can be provided by these institutions.
For example, the volume of mortgages or corporate bonds in particu-
lar years may substantially exceed the amount normally purchased
by institutions buying assets of this type. The increased supply of
these instruments pushes their interest rates higher. Some leading in-
stitutions may then shift their purchases from types of obligation that
*they customarily find attractive to the particular asset that happens
to be in strong supply, or the borrower, because of the increased cost
of funds and the inability to attract sufficient buyers for these particu-
lar assets, may switch to other types of instruments. Businesses which
would ordinarily finance in the bond market, for instance, may move
to bank loans or commercial paper as a source of funds.
The role of commercial banks is complex. In addition to servicing
their customers' normal short-term needs, banks tend to be the major
residual supplier of funds for the economy in periods when credit
(967)
PAGENO="0008"
968
demands and interest rates rise sharply. Such periods of high demand
for bank funds, however, are not without concern to commercial banks.
Under these circumstances banks frequently must sell securities from
their portfolios at substantial losses in order to meet their formal and
informal commitments to valued customers. If there are heavy Treas-
ury demands for credit a.t such times the problem of financial institu-
tions is further compounded. When banks respond within the free
market mechanism by rationing credit on the basis of price (interest
rate) rather than by arbitrary decisions, they frequently incur unjusti-
fied criticism for raising rates charge.d to customers.' Yet when the
banks, whose ability to meet expanded borrowing demands of their cus-
tomers requires them to be able to attract funds, succeed in increasing
their time and savings accounts, they are sometimes said to be "obtain-
ing more tha.n their fair share of the savings market.."
It should be recognized that the disruptive strams upon our financial
system are not caused by commercial banks nor by specialized financial
institutions. Rather, they arise from the fact the economy can generate
more uses of credit under an outlook for relatively full employment
than it is possible to suppiv at current interest rate levels. The problem
is compounded by inflation which both increases the demand for funds
and reduces the motives to save. To the extent that monetary policy is
successful in holding clown price increases, the measure of it.s success
may be the shortage of credit itself. To the extent that price increases
occur, credit demands that are satisfied compound inflation. The ad-
ministration and Congress have often been sympathetic but at times
they have added to public misunderstanding of the role commercial
banks play in supplying credit by viewing dimly either interest rate
increases made necessary by market pressures or by suggesting that
banks are obtaining greater than their arbitrarily assumed share of
t.he "market for savings."
The American Bankers Association recommends that the adminis-
tration and Congress bear in mind the strains placed upon financial
institutions in times of excess demand. To this end au active policy
should be pursued to cut back Treasury and Federal agency demands
for funds when the economy achieves rapid growth of demand and
high employment as a result of a strong private sector. Furthermore,
recognition is essential that monetary policy should appropriately be
concerned with both interest rates and the volume of bank credit.
Finally, attention may well be directed toward determining whether
the present structure of financial institutions is appropriate to provide
the optimal flow of credit needed for a high employment economy in
the long run.
II
The statement. of the incoming Council of Economic Advisers pre-
sented to the Joint Economic Committee on February 17, indicates
the priority given to the problem of inflation by the present aciminis-
tration. The statement rejected the economic projection of the retired
Council and instead indicated that a greater attempt would be made
1 In 1966 the American Bankers Association published and distributed to all of its mem-
bers a brochure entitled Tue Banker's Role in Reinforcing Monetary Policy which pointed
out procedures the bankers could use in determining loan priorities. This publication
pointed out the beneficial effects that could be produced by responsible bank management
decisions which would obviate both the need for Government guidelines and ever higher
interest rates. Consideration is now being given to reissuing this publication.
PAGENO="0009"
969
to bring inflation to a halt than merely relying upon an assumed slow-
down in the first half of 1969 as a result of the surcharge instituted last
year. At the same time the Council indicated the administration is well
aware of the consequences of increased unemployment that could re-
sult from too severe use of fiscal and monetary policy in order to break
inflationary expectations. Wisely, the Council has suggested the use of
appropriate monetary and fiscal policy to bring about expectations of
diminishing rates of inflation in the future.
We regard as positive the Council's apparent realization that the
relation between price increases and unemployment is sufficiently flexi-
ble to permit many things to be done to decrease the degree of inflation
without raising unemployment. The Council's emphasis on moderating
rather than crushing the growth of aggregate demand will permit
steady progress toward improved price performance without sacri-
ficing low levels of unemployment.
Our particular concern is that the damping of inflationary expecta-
tions may not be as smooth as the Council implies. At some point as the
rate of growth of prices decelerates, there may be cumulative abandon-
ment of investment plans, restrictive inventory policy and consumer
postponement of purchases. At such times, those who guide both fiscal
and monetary policy may feel that they face a dilemma between imme-
diate reaction to the new conditions and a "steady hand on the tiller"
approach.
It should be the intention of the administration with the help of Con-
gress to pursue many policies-consistent with maintenance of the free
market mechanism-aimed at decreasing inflation in addition to the
principal ones using monetary and fiscal measures. While the aim of
Federal action against inflation is nearly always thought to be the con-
centration on the reduction of excess demand, possible action to im-
prove si~pply can also be in order. The Federal Government can well
occupy itself in the elimination of any conditions that limit the work-
ing of the price and free market mechanism and thus tend to raise both
prices and wages. Both labor and management should be made aware
of the beneficial effect of measures to increase productivity and steps
should be taken to see that practices that conflict with maximum pro-
ductivity growth are eliminated or reduced whether they originate
with Government, labor, or business. Finally, a thorough review is
required of all those areas of public policy aimed at pegging prices and
wages. It is appropriate to question whether the minimum wage law
plays a useful role at the present time; it may only lead to greater un-
employment of marginally productive workers. In any case, while
wage and price supports may be appropriate in periods of underutili-
zation of resources, in periods of high employment of fully productive
workers, there is little excuse for them, and they add significantly to
inflationary pressures.
In the end, however, the fight against inflation will be largely won or
lost by monetary and fiscal policy. If the past decade is any indication,
the greatest single determinant will be the volume of Government
spending. Indeed, Korea, the space and missile race, and Vietnam
essentially determined Government spending. But Federal revenues
were adjusted only slowly, and monetary policy did not fully compen-
sate. Thus lressure was placed upon scarce resources in the name of
national policies endorsed by a sizable percentage of the American
PAGENO="0010"
970
public. The American Bankers Association believes that in recent years
the Federa.l Government has been the major perpetrator of inflation,
because it did not give adequate consideration to the overall impac.t of
major policies.
At some point, the judgment must be made as to whether to err on
the side of a more or less restrictive policy despite all the good wishes
of the current administration in avoiding that problem. In the recent
past, this decision has generally been against that of sufficient restric-
tion and instead policy has fostered more inflation. WTe feel strongly
that undesirable as even a. small rise in unemployment would be, the
administration must be prepared to accept some rise in the number of
jobless and must not weaken its actions against inflation for fear of
such consequences. The association is firmly convinced, moreover, that
inflation has seriously intensified the problems faced by large segments
of our population who have low incomes, whose incomes are fixed, or
who are on some form of public assistance. While we are mindful of
the beneficial effect of a highly expansionary policy in employing mar-.
ginal and submarginal workers, we feel the Federal Government has,
in pursing a "Guns and Butter" policy, achieved a high rate of employ-
ment through over-st.inmlative policies at a. cost of lowered purchasing
power for families who are only one short step up the economic ladder
from low-skilled workers who are also a prime object of Federal con-
cern. A realistic cost benefits analysis might well dictate other ways of
solving the problem of putting the least employable workers into jobs.
III
The commercial banking industry is obviously concerned tha.t the
pursuit of monetary policy be practiced with maximum efficiency. In
the last year despite three separate and distinct Federal Reserve policy
phases, monetary growth overall was much too high for a. year of rapid
inflation. The money supply defined as demand deposits and currency
grew at a nearly stea.dy rate while the money supply plus time deposits
actually accelerated in its growth rate as the year progressed. Viewed
in this light the basic decisions of monetary policy seem clearly to have
been in error. Monetary policy, on the other hand, becomes more under-
standable if its goal was conceived as largely that of trying to affect
interest rates. During the moderately restrictive policy period up to
late spring interest rates particularly in short-term securities rose.
Following passage of the surta.x and agreement on the spending slow-
down when policy shifted because of fear of "overkill," rates fell only
to turn up again barely 2 months later when the economic expansion
proved stronger than anticipated. Of course, Treasury requirements in
1968 unduly limited the hands of the monetary authorities. Neverthe-
less, whether interest rates or the growth in the money supply was the
guiding policy principle, the total effect of last year's actions was
obviously inappropriate for a period of inflation.
During the past year the Joint Economic Committee suggested the
Federal Reserve Board specify regularly its goal in terms of growth of
the money supply and explain reasons for policy changes that produced
divergences from a stea.dy rate of growth. While viewed as a victory
for tlrose who advocate fairly steady growth in the money supply, in a
laroer sense its chief contribution probably was that of putting the
Fe~eral Reserve on notice that fewer, rather than more, frequent shifts
PAGENO="0011"
971
in policy would be desirable and that interest rates are less important
than previously thought in creating an effective monetary policy.
In contrast to the apparent willingness of those who hold this view-
point to focus greater, if not complete, attention upon money supply
growth, the annual report of the retiring Council of Economic Ad-
visers went out of its way to point out the undesirable effects of a sim-
ple rigid rule related to the growth of the money supply by pointing
out the undesirable effects upon the interest rates that could be. pro-
duced under certain situations.
The American Bankers Association has no wish to endorse a par-
ticular viewpoint in monetary theory. We do see definite advantages to
the cause of economic stabilization in a less volatile monetary policy
and therefore less precise concern over interest rates levels per Se. Such
a course, however, requires reducing the institutional rigidities imposed
by various interest rate ceilings incoroprated by law and regulation
in many parts of the financial system. Ceilings on interest rates paid
to savers at various institutions, rate ceilings on Treasury bonds, maxi-
mum lending rates on insured and guaranteed mortgages, student loans
and small business loans, and imposed ceiling rates on consumer loans
as well as mere tradition or convention all tend to make interest rates
unusually important in the present financial system. Since a high em-
p~ oymeut economy is likely to produce interest rates near or even above
legally imposed ceilings or ceilings fixed by lack of timely administra-
tion, it is likely that until many of these restrictions are removed mone-
tary policy will have to be cognizant of sharp and irregular effects set
off by slight changes in interest rates. Therefore, it would seem en-
tirely appropriate for the committee to bear in mind the inconsistency
of advocating policies favoring relatively stable monetary growth but
continuing to favor the institutional rigidities imposed by legal inter-
est rate ceiling on various types of instruments.
As a case in point, the banking industry should point out that the
hoped-for gentle attack against inflation may be turned into a. serious
credit crunch by failure to take appropriate, action to increase the. ceil-
ing rate on large certificates of deposit issued by commercial banks.
Certainly the current course of interest rat.es suggests that instruments
other than bank certificates are more attractive to sophisticated large
investors and wholesale "disintermediation" could well spread as it
did in 1966. Immediate action should be devoted to removing, placing
on a standby basis, or raising this sensitive rate ceiling. Such a move
would not lessen the anti-inflationary stance but would reduce the
threat of another serious credit crunch emanating from serious "disin-
termecliation."
Iv
Recent years have seen a considerable atmosphere of innovation in
banking practices, questioning of existing operating and regulating
procedure, and the invention of new methods of organization. In such
areas as savings instruments, underwriting of revenue bonds, capital
instruments, credit cards, provision of Federal Reserve discount facili-
ties. Loan production offices, provision of noncredit services by banks,
and limits on loans of particular types such as mortgages, the coin-
mercial banking industry has become restive with previous arrange-
ments. In the past year the diversification movement in the commercial
banking industry, generally taking the form of financial congenerics,
PAGENO="0012"
972
has garnered considera~ble attention from the public, the administra-
tion, and Congress.
There is often a temptation to regard these developments in. isola-
tion and see them a.s the mere result of oversight in drafting previous
legislation or regulation, the discovery of ingenious legal arrange-
ment, or nefarious intent on the part of bank managements. Yet, all
of these developments and many more that could be mentioned are
undoubtedly only the external manifestation of major changes that
are taking place in the American economy and the financial system's
attempt to adapt to them.
Without attempting to exhaust the list of fundamental changes
in the economy leading to changed financial practices it is possible
to point out a few obvious ones. First, the rising scale of industry has
meant demands for financing and other financial services are much
larger than before. Technical developments have increased capital
requirements of customers; they have also changed the practice of
banking. Sharp shifts have occurred in the cost curves of the com-
mercial banking industry in particular operations and as the payments
system rapidly becomes automated, as now appears likely in the next
decade, the economics of the industry will be changing rapidly. Bank
managements have incerased their professional character and highly
skilled personnel are required to service customers. On the consumer
level, demands for deposit and credit services have changed ap-
preciably. Indeed, the very output of the economy ha.s changed
appreciably from material things to services of various types and this
development affects the functions of financial institutions.
The American Bankers Association is, of course, seeking to represent
the commercial banking industry in dealing with the Congress and the
banking agencies as legislation and regulations are developed to take
account of necessary changes. We urge that the Joint Economic Com-
mittee as well as other congressional committees dealing with banks
attempt to view the financial structure as a whole ra.ther than on a
piecemeal basis as it reviews the need for specific changes. Generally,
the American banking system over the years has been able to adapt
prudently and efficiently to broad economic and social changes and
the nation has benefited from this flexibility. To continue this favor-
able record requires a depth of vision and willingness to innovate on
the part of legislators and regulatory agencies unwilling to be satis-
fied with the status quo. In their future dealings with the banking
industry we hope the flexibility of approach contained in the principle
of dual regulatory authority will be preserved.
The announced intention of the new administration to contain in-
flation by a policy of gradual reduction of expenditures growth will
have a wholesome effect on the U.S. balance of payments. It is fairly
obvious that only inflow of capital from Western Europe and a will-
inguess by U.S. firms to go beyond what was asked of them in limiting
capital outflows abroad enabled the U.S. payments balance to show
up as well as it did in 1968. The poor showing of the Un1ted States
on trade account last year is a foreboding sign that the threat of a
large-scale deterioration in the balance of payments still hangs over
the Nation.
PAGENO="0013"
973
For 1969 we urge that major efforts be made to expand U.S. exports.
Such efforts should include a thorough examination of the types of
incentives that could be used to encourage American industry to ex-
pand exports. Joint efforts with our trading partners should be aimed
at a thorough review of unilateral changes of indirect taxes which
tend to distort trade patterns among nations. Negotiations to remove
nontariff barriers should also be pressed, so that the advantages of
free international markets can be made more fully available by all
nations.
The Joint Economic Committee in its deliberations on the U.S.
balance of payments may well benefit from examination of The Cost
of World Leadership, an analysis of the problems and solutions of
the problem recently completed as a staff study of the American
Bankers Association.
PAGENO="0014"
AMERICAN FARM BUREAU FEDERATION
We appreciate the opportunity to comment on the Economic Report
of the President for 1969.
Farm Bureau members are interested in the Economic Report be-
cause it deals with matters which determine the economic climate in
which farmers must try to make a living.
Our members also have an interest, as taxpayers, in the many sec-
tions of the Economic Report which call for continued, or increased,
Government expenditures.
At the present time the economic climate is dominated by strong
inflationary pressures. This is recognized at several places in the Eco-
nomic Report. For example, on page 33 1 the Council of Economic Ad-
visers notes that "The pressures of excessive demand pushed up the
price level at the unacceptable rate of nearly 4 percent" (in 1968).
This apparently refers to the Consumer Price Index.
As an industry that suffers from overproduction-some of which
has been induced by Government programs-agriculture is seriously
hurt by inflation because farm costs rise faster than farm prices. This
is well illustrated by the chart on page 48 which shows that farm prices
have consistently lagged behind other wholesale prices since 1963 ex-
cept for a brief period in 1966 when farm prices were boosted by an
unwarranted hysteria over the world food situation.
From December 1962 to December 1968 the Wholesale Price Index
for all commodities, including farm products, rose 9.4 percent, but
the wholesale price of farm products rose only 6.2 percent.
We certainly agree with former President Johnson's statement (p. 9)
that, "The immediate task in 1969 is to make a decisive step toward
price stability."
We strongly urge the Congress to pursue inflation control with
greater vigor in 1969. In achieving this, major emphasis should be
on cutting Federal expenditures in order to obtain a balanced budget
for fiscal 1970. Reductions in expenditures should have priority over
continuation of the surtax for an additional year.
We are well aware of the argument that reducing Government ex-
penditures might increase unemployment. We do not, however, believe
that inflationary policies are a sound approach to the desirable objec-
tive of maintaining a high level of employment. The unemployment
problem is concentrated in groups that have very little to offer the
job market. The major impact of inflation on employment is to increase
the demand for-and consequently the money income of-the better
qualified workers who already find it relatively easy to obtain
employment.
The problem of finding employment for the disadvantaged can best
be approached through efforts to upgrade their skills in order to
1 Economic Report of the President, transmitted to the Congress, 3anuary 1969, together
with the Annual Report of the Council of Economic Advisers: U.S. Government Printing
Office, Washington~ D.C.
(974)
PAGENO="0015"
975
qualify them for the type of work that is available in a technologically
advanced society. In some cases such efforts could be materially assisted
by exemptions from the minimum wage law for handicapped and be-
ginning workers.
While the Council of Economic Advisers indicates that a price level
rise of 4 percent per year is "unacceptable," we do not think the
Council has placed sufficient emphasis on the long-run dangers of
inflationary policies. There is real danger that efforts to increase em-
ployment by inflating the economy may lead to an economic bust which
would increase rather than reduce unemployment.
It has often been argued in the past that an easy money policy is
necessary to hold down interest rates in order to stimulate the housing
industry. Recent experience suggests that an inflationary expansion of
the money supply leads to high, not low, interest rates. If lenders are
convinced that they will be repaid in `cheapei' dollars it is only natural
that they should demand higher interest rates to offset the potential
loss in the purchasing power of loan funds. If prices are advancing at
a rate of 4 percent per year, interest rates must exceed 4 percent if
lenders are to receive any real return for the use of their money.
We agree with former President Johnson's statement (page 10)
that, "the vital guiding mechanism of a free economy is lost when the
Government fixes prices and wages." We do not, however, agree with
the Council of Economic Adviser's statement (page 59) that, "business
and labor should undertake a pattern of voluntary restraint" based on
Government-suggested guidelines.
Government guidelines are an interference with the operation of the
market system that is only a step removed from price and wage con-
trols. The proper role of the Government in inflation control is to
create an economic climate that is conducive to a stable price level-
not to inflate the economy and then ask business and labor to refrain
from responding to inflationary pressures.
We do not agree with former President Johnson's suggestion that
Congress "give the President discretionary authority to initiate limited
changes in tax rates, subject to congressional veto" (page 13). The
record indicates that the Congress can act quickly on tax changes when
a majority of its Members are convinced that proposed changes are
required by the national interest.
Enactment of the present surtax was delayed because many Mem-
bers of Congress-reflecting the views of their constituents-felt that
an increase in taxes should be accompanied by a reduction in Govern-
ment expenditures. We do not think it would be wise for the Congress
to surrender its right to originate changes in tax rates, to decide the
amount of such changes, and to decide whether increases should be
accompanied by cuts in expenditures.
AGRICULTURE
We agree with former President Johnson's statement (page 16) that,
"Agriculture has been the `stepchild of trade negotiations, and deserves
prompt and proper attention."
The most notable agricultural result of the Kennedy round was an
International Grains Arrangement which has resulted in an inverse
subsidy, or export tax, on U.S. wheat exports. We do not see how any-
one could expect to expand wheat exports by taxing them. It is not
surprising that wheat exports have declined since the International
PAGENO="0016"
976
Grains, Arrangement went into effect, although we recognize that
other factors may have contributed to this decline.
The United States should seek to have the wheat provisions of the
International Grains Arrangement suspended or materially modified
at the earliest possible date.
The new administration should give a high priority to efforts to
increase farm exports. Our immediate goal should be to increase farm
exports from $6.3 billion in fiscal 1968 to $10 billion per year. This
would improve our balance of payments as well as strengthen our farm
economy.
In order to achieve this goal, it will be necessary to resist the current
pressures for new restrictions on imports. It will also be necessary to
eliminate the direct payment features of domestic farm programs.
Direct payments to farmers on commodities which are produced for
export are a disguised form of export subsidy, and are recognized as
such by other countries. We cannot expect to persuade other countries
to reduce trade barriers such as the Common Market's variable fees as
long as we are subsidizing exports through direct payments.
We appreciate the Economic Council's recognition (page 116) of
the need for "a restructuring of farm programs"; however, we do not
agree with the Council's inference that direct payments should be
continued.
New farm legislation should be enacted during 1969 so that farmers
will have time to prepare for the changes that should be made in
existing farm programs. Further delay in coming to a decision on this
issue would only make the problem of adjustment more difficult for
farmers.
In developing new farm legislation it should be recognized that the
problems of agriculture can be divided generally into two categories:
First, the problems of commercial farmers and second, the problems
of other farmers.
Farm Bureau supports a transitional program to deal with the
problems of noncommercial farmers. This could take the form of
whole farm cropland retirement, permanent retirement of allotments,
adjustment and retraining assistance, or other means.
For the commercial farmer we recommend a program which would
move as rapidly as possible to the market system by phasing out
acreage ba.ses, acreage allotments, marketing quotas, and compensatory
payments with no limitations on payments to individuals during the
phaseout.
The objective should be to create conditions which will make it pos-
sible for farmers to get their income in the marketplace rather than
being dependent on congressional appropriations. A few farmers
should not be penalized because they are larger than others.
The phaseout of acreage controls should be accompanied by an ex-
pansion of the voluntary cropland adjustment program (authorized
by the Food and Agriculture Act of 1965) with emphasis on whole
farms. We are pleased to note that the Economic Report favors an
expansion of this program (page 116). As a first step toward getting
agriculture on to a sounder footing, ftmds for new cropland adjust-
ment contracts should be included in the Agricultural Appropriation
Act for 1970. This would enable the Secretary of Agriculture to begin
to move in the direction of the adjustments that are needed by offering
farmers new cropland adjustment contracts in the fall of 1969, a year
before the act of 1965 is scheduled to expire.
PAGENO="0017"
AMERICAN LIFE CONVENTION
and the
LIFE INSURANCE ASSOCIATION OF AMERICA
This statement is submitted on behalf of the American Life Con-
vention and the Life Insurance Association of America, two trade
associations with a combined membership of 360 life insurance com-
panies which account for 92 percent of the legal reserve life insurance
in force in the United States. The total assets of the life insurance
business today aggregate more than $187 billion, which represents
the savings that have been entrusted to us by millions of policyholders.
The protection of the economic value of these savings is of vital con-
cern to our business. We appreciate the invitation of the Joint Eco-
nomic Committee to express our views on the materials and recom-
mendations contained in the "Economic Report of the President
Together with the Annual Report of the Council of Economic Ad-
visers" and we hope that these comments will prove helpful to the
committee.
PROSPECTS FOR THE ECONOMY IN 1969
In our view, the No. 1 problem facing our domestic economy in 1969
is the threat of continuing strong inflation and the deepening of the
inflationary psychology that has spread widely through the economy
in recent months. During 1968, the inflationary forces that were per-
initted to develop led to a 4.8-percent increase in the consumer price
level and a 3.9-percent rise in the GNP price deflator for the entire
economy. Inflation was no longer merely a threat-it became a reality.
The inflationary trends of 1968 have already exacted a toll from the
American public in terms of higher prices for everyday living expenses,
rising costs of housing, and decreased value of their savings and fixed
incomes. But another difficulty with a major inflationary surge is the
change in public attitudes that it carries with it. Once the public be-
comes convinced that prices are going up further, there is a natural
urge to anticipate price increases by purchasing in advance of needs,
even if it means borrowing to do so. In such circumstances, rising inter-
est costs become a minor deterrent to borrowing when compared with
the rising prices that are projected in an inflationary climate. Thus an
inflationary psychology can seriously distort the spending and borrow-
ing decisions of consumers and businesses alike. As living costs ad-
vance, pressures for higher wages also build up and persist in later
labor negotiations. Moreover, inflation carries with it a forward mo-
mentum that can be checked only by appropriate economic policies
applied with determination and persistence.
It is our opinion that the primary objective of economic policy
measures in 1969 must be the reduction of the rate of inflation. In its
Annual Report, the Council of Economic Advisers projects that gross
(977)
24-833-69-pt. 4-2
PAGENO="0018"
978
national product will rise in 1969 by about $60 billion to a total of
around $921 billion for the year, and this estimate is in accord with
that of many private forecasters. An increase of about 6 percent is
foreseen between the final quarter of 1968 and the fourth quarter of
1969, with a projected rise of less than 3 percent in rea.l output and an
increase of a little more than 3 percent in overall prices. This estimate
implies a diminution in the rate of inflation during the coming year
as compared with the price advance of recent quarters. While we
wOuld regard this degree of reduction in the inflation rate as a desir-
able objective, we also believe that this goal may prove difficult to
attain unless gradual but persistent restraint is applied through checks
on Federal spending, extension of the 10-percent income tax surcharge,
continued restraint in monetary policy, and prOgrams to improve
productivity.
POLICY FOR RESTRAINT OF INFLATION
Effective action to break the grip of inflation and counter the threat
from a deepening inflationary psychology requires a policy of simul-
taneous restraint in four major areas, as outlined below.
1. Federal spending should be kept in check to avoid greater pres-
sures on aggregate demand and to permit a balance or surplus in
the Federa.l budget. The ability of the Congress and the executive
branch to curb the growth of spending programs has been demon-
strated by the Revenue and Expenditure Control Act of 1968. It is
clear that the pressure of inflation during *the present fiscal year
would have been even greater in the absence of this measure, but the
need for continued holdbacks in Federal expenditures is no less press-
ing today than a year ago.
In our view, the $3.4 billion Federal budgetary surplus that is pro-
jected for fiscal year 1970 in the Economic Report and in the Budget
Message operates in the proper direction of fiscal restraint. But this
planned surplus could be easily jeopardized or even reversed if the
Congress relaxes its careful scrutiny of spending programs in both
the civilian and military areas. Previous budget analyses have demon-
strated how sizable are the budget outlays which are "relatively
uncontrollable" as a result of commitments under Federal programs
adopted in earlier years or enlarged by previous legislation. Accord-
ingly, the need for close review of new proposals or expanded programs
is heightened by the narrowing of congressional discretion over current
spending.
2. Extension of the 10 percent tcw~ surcharge is essential in the
present budgetary situation to achieve the budget surplus needed to
maintain fiscal restraint in an inflationary economy. The life insur-
ance business urged the imposition of an income tax surcharge on
both individuals and corporations in August 1967, and we now favor
extension of the 10 percent surcharge for the fiscal year ending July 1,
1969, as proposed in the Budget Message and the Economic Report.
Failure to renew the surcharge beyond its June 30 expiration would
lead to a Federal deficit in fiscal 1970 of about $5i/~ billion-a fiscal
position which would be wholly inappropriate to the present eco-
nomic outlook of excessive demand a.nd continuing inflation.
PAGENO="0019"
979
Past experience has shown that unexpected developments in mu
tary requirements, budgetary trends, or economic conditions sometimes
call for rapid adjustments in Federal tax policies. But prompt changes
in tax rates, either up or down, are typically difficult to obtain under
present procedures. In order to permit more rapid adjustments in
tax levels, we would urge that consideration be given to some flexible
mechanism to permit removal of the renewed 10 percent surcharge
by the President before the end of the 1970 fiscal year, if changing
circumstances warrant such action. The precise form of such a mecha-
nism would be a question for discussion between the Congress and
the new administration. While we do not presently visualize the
emergence of conditions that would call for early removal of the
surcharge, we feel that this type of flexibility would represent a po-
tential improvement in our fiscal controls.
3. Monetary restraint is vitally needed to hold down the growth
rate of money and credit, perhaps for a considerable period ahead.
Beginning last December with an increase in the discount rate, the
Federal Reserve authorities have moved in the direction of more
restrictive monetary policy which has slowed the growth rate of
money supply and brought greater pressure on member bank re~
serve positions in recent weeks. We believe that monetary restraint
should be applied in a gradual fashion, in order to avoid the violent
disruptions of a "credit crunch" but should be presistently maintained
for a sufficient period to break the inflationary psychology which has
gripped the financial markets in recent months.
As noted earlier, the upsurge of inflation during 1968 has quickened
the desires of consumers, h'omebuyers and corporations to purchase
goods in anticipation of rising prices, and to borrow to finance such
purchases. The rise in interest costs of recent months has been out-
weighed in the minds of many `borrowers by the expectation of higher
prices for goods if the purchase were delayed. At the same time, lenders
have become increasingly aware that they must obtain a higher re-
turn on fixed-debt obligations if they are to be repaid in dollars that
have `been cheapened by inflation. While precise measurement is diffi-
cult, it appears that these attitudes have produced an "inflation pre-
mium" on fixed-dollar investment, which has been an important force
working toward higher interest rates in recent months.
The Annual Report of the CEA expresses the hope that as fiscal
restraint is continued through fiscal 197Q, monetary policy may grad-
iially be able to shift to a less restrictive stance and that a decline in
interest rates `may take place. In our opinion there is a grave danger
that premature easing of monetary policy, at the `first `signs of economic
slowdown or rising unemployment, would revive inflationary ex-
pectation's among savers and lenders and lead to higher interest rates
rather than lower rates. The prospect, of continuing inflation under
these circumstances would impel the public to `borrow more, while
lenders would shun fixed-dollar investments or build in an "inflation
premium" in their fixed-debt lending rates. For these reasons, we
believe it is imperative to maintain a restraining monetary policy
until present inflationary psychology has `disappeared from the finan-
c~al markets. This may require a considerable period to accomplish
against the background of recent developments.
PAGENO="0020"
980
4.~Otiier policies for price stability ëan also contribute to the objec-
tive of reducing the. inflation rate, in addition to the aggregative
effects from fiscal and monetary restraint. Chapter 3 of the Annual
Report of the CEA contains a discussion of the effect on price levels
of wage rates, labor efficiency and mobility, utilization rates of plant
capacity, and competitive pricing policies. We endorse the perceptive
analysis of the Council in that discussion, and feel that the sugges-
tions put forward by the Council deserve the careful consideration of
business and labor groups as well as the Congress. Improvements in
the areas described in that chapter should also be pursued in the search
for price stability consistent with high levels of employment of man-
power and utilization of productive capacity.
THE QUEsTIoN OF UNEMPLOYMENT
The Economic Report expresses the fear that "an overdose of fiscal
and monetary restraint" might bring on a recession with rising un-
employment and growing social unrest. The life insurance business
shares the concern over the economic waste and the damage to family
stability and individual dignity that would result from deliberate
policies to increase unemployment as a means of halting price infla-
tion. It is for these reasons that we urge gradual and persistent policies
of restraint that will permit adjustments in production and labor
markets without the violent disruptions that an economic downturn
would bring.
Recent discussion of these questions has centered on the "trade-off"
or choice between inflation and unemployment. According to this argu-
ment, in the short run, unemployment can be reduced to nominal levels
if demand is allowed to expand rapidly, at the cost of upward pressure
on wages and prices; conversely, if demand is restrained to curb infla-
tion, unemployment may increase. In our view, this argument overlooks
the fact that unsustainable growth rates lead to distortions in the econ-
omy which can bring on extremely painful downward adjustments
with a steep rise in the unemployment rate. In a longer run analysis, an
overheated economy that produces inflation will lead to higher un-
employment in the subsequent economic downturn which follows as a
corrective aftermath of unsustainable growth.
The present 3.3 percent unemployment rate represents the lowest
level in recent years. However, the social consequences of even this de-
gree of unemployment should not be ignored. A great part of the pres-
ent joblessness reflects the problem of "unemployables" who lack skills
or training, as well as pockets of structural unemployment in certain
urban or rural poverty areas. However, this type of unemployment
does not respond readily to variations in a.ggregate demands. The social
and economic problem of the "unemployables" should be attacked
through redoubled efforts to bring this group into the labor force
through programs of job training and relocation. Similarly, hard-core
unemployment among minority groups in urban ghetto areas should be
approached not through pressing harder on total demand but through
direct programs for providing new skills and new job opportunities
for these workers.
It should also be recognized that inflation exacts a heavy toll on the
meager living standards of the jobless and the low-income family
PAGENO="0021"
981
through higher costs of food, shelter and clothing. Efforts to develop
low-income housing are stymied by rising construction costs. Welfare
payments and unemployment benefits provide less help when the prices
of. essential goods continue to mount. Those who are socially and eco-
nomically disadvantaged could be benefited most through a combina-
tion of broad policies to curb~ inflation together with manpower pro-
grams to bring them into the labor force and provide them with needed
job skills. Efforts should also be made to improve Government em-
ployment services and to develop a data bank on job vacancies in order
to identify job opportunities and increase labor mobility.
BALANCE OF PAYMENTS PROBLEMS
The year 1968 produced the first surplus in our balance of payments
since 1957, but there was little cause for elation in view of the con-
tinued weakening of our merchandise trade balance from a $3% billion
surplus in each of the years 1966 and 1967 to less than $500 million last
year. A heavy inflow of foreign capital was primarily responsible for
converting the deficits of earlier years into a narrow surplus in 1968.
However, there is little or no assurance that these offsetting capital
inflows will continue in the future, since they arose to a considerable
degree from political disturbances in Europe rather than from basic
economic relationships.
Inflation and excess demand have doubtless played an important role
in the deterioration of our trade balance this past year, by attracting
an increased flow of imported goods while making our exports more
expensive to many foreign buyers. If we are to maintain our competi-
tive position in world markets, it is essential that we regain control
over inflation to prevent rising export prices.
The Economic Report recommends that controls over foreign lend~
ing and direct investment be maintained and that the interest equaliza-
tion tax be renewed. While these measures may be unavoidable under
present circumstances, we should not lose sight of the desirability of
removing these restrictions on international capital flows as quickly
as circumstances permit. The persistence of this type of "temporary"
capital control illustrates the need to achieve domestic price stability
and to restore a viable balance in our international trading position.
MANAGEMENT OF DOMESTIC MONETARY AFFAIRS
The Economic Report offers proposals to modify the organization of
policy formation within the Federal Reserve System with a view to
enhancing its effectiveness. If any modifications are to be made, how-
ever, we believe it is highly important to maintain the independence of
Federal Reserve policy from political supervision or direct control by
either the executive or legislative branch. This independence permits
monetary policy to respond to changing economic conditions with a
speed and flexibility which would be sacrificed if the System operated
under fixed political directives.
In a related field, greater flexibility is also desirable in the manage-
ment of the public debt and Treasury borrowing operations. For the
past three years, the Treasury has been unable to market securities
with a maturity beyond 7 years, because of the 41/4 percent interest rate
PAGENO="0022"
982
ceiling on bond issues. As a result, the average maturity of the public
debt has been steadily decreasing.
In our view, the Congress should consider changes that would pro-
vide Treasury access to the longer term capital market as a regular
part of its debt management function. One method would be to raise
or remove the 41/4 percent bond ceiling; another would be to extend
the maximum maturity of note issues beyond the present 7-year limit.
Regardless of the method, the ability of the Treasury to lengthen the
maturity of the debt would help not only to improve the debt structure
but also to reduce the frequency and size of Treasury financing opera-
tions in the money and capital markets.
In conclusion, we believe that the foremost objective of economic
policies in 1969 must be a reduction in the rate of inflation. Anti-
inflation policies should be applied in a gradual fashion, to avoid a
downturn in economic activity or sha.rply increased unemployment.
But the campaign against inflation must be pursued with persistence,
to rid the economy of the inflationary psychology which threatens to
distort the spending, lending, and borrowing decisions of the public..
The economy has enjoyed a prolonged period of rapid growth and
prosperity over the past several years. Employment, production and
incomes have advanced to record high levels. But the pressure of ex-
cessive demand has outrun our capacity to produce, leading to an un-
healthy and continuing rise in wages, costs, and prices. If we are to
return to the path of sustainable economic growth with high em-
ployment and price stability, it is essential that we achieve a signifi~
cant reduction in the rate of inflation in the months ahead.
PAGENO="0023"
COMMITTEE FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT
By EMILI0 G. COLLADO, CHAIRMAN, RESEARCH AND POLICY CoM~IrrrEE
We are especially pleased at this opportunity to comment on the
Economic Report of the President and the annual report of the Council
of Economic Advisers, because the subject matter of these important
documents relates to many of the issues discussed in a January 1969
statement of CED's Research and Policy Committee, "Fiscal and
Monetary Policies for Steady Economic Growth." *
This statement, prepared by a subcommittee headed by Douglas
Dillon, was the result of intensive analysis of the opportunities and
problems facing the U.S. economy now and in the years ahead. It
represents a modernization and restatement of our analysis and rec-
ommendations for maintaining a steady rate of noninflationary
growth, and is the latest in a series which began with our first stabili-
zation statement in 1947. Since our analysis and comments on the
Economic Report of the President and the annual report of the Council
of Economic Advisers will draw heavily on the positions taken in this
recent CED document, it is useful to briefly outline its contents and
recommendations.
In "Fiscal and Monetary Policies for Steady Economic Growth,"
the CED Research and Policy Committee asserts that the four basic
economic objectives of the country are a high level of employment,
general price stability, economic growth, and balance-of-payments
equilibrium.
In defining "high employment," the report notes that for many
years an unemployment level of 4 percent of the labor force has been
widely used to represent a high-employment situation. However, there
is little economic justification for setting a target for high employment
in terms of a constant fraction of the labor force. Rather, the ultimate
objective requires the maintenance of a level of demand for labor which
will provide a number of jobs equal to the number of workers looking
for employment at wages which the marketplaces are willing to pay
for their capabilities; that is, their productivity.
With this employment objective, additional measures may `be neces-
sary to increase the productivity of those workers whose productivity
is insufficient to earn a decent standard of living. Before shifting away
from the familiar measure of unemployment as a percent of the la)bor
force, it will `be necessary to compile and utilize data on unfilled job
vacancies, and on unemployment, `by both location and skill. Until this
is done, we shall have to use the present measure of unemployment,
keeping in mind that a satisfactory level of employment will imply
lower levels of unemployment as the adjustment of workers to job
opportunities improves.
*Copy in committee files.
(983)
PAGENO="0024"
984
In a section of our policy statement whose implications we regard
as most important, the Committee concludes that there is little reason
to be concerned with the necessity of trading off some rate of price
inflation to obtain tolerable levels of unemployment. Put in yet an-
other way, there is no necessity for accepting a substantial perma-
nent rise in unemployment to attain relative price stability. The analy-
sis in the statement suggests that expanding demand from levels well
below the country's potential to produce at stable prices does reduce
unemployment. However, as unemployment expands, the economy
begins to approach the position where increases in employment become
harder and harder to achieve by simply expanding money demand.
Potential workers are in the wrong location, have mismatched skills,
or skills not particularly relevant to any of the existing demands
for labor. Under such conditions, further increases in money de-
mand become increasingly inefficient ways to reduce unemployment
and result primarily in increases in the price level. Lasting expan-
sion of employment beyond this "normal" level of unemployment
requires specific steps to improve the efficiency of labor markets and
cannot be obtained by continued expansion of demand. At the point
where expandiii~ demand leads to inflation, further increases in de-
mand have little, if any, lasting effect on employment. Thus, there
is little, if any, trade-off between inflation and employment because
expanding demand to a level generating inflation brings no lasting
rise in employment.
In dealing with the need for price stability, the committee states
that the adverse effects of inflation on domestic economic growth,
on the distribution of income and wealth, on resource allocations, and
on the Nation's competitive position in the world economy are now
fully evident. If policy is to be directed at price stability, it is essen-
tial that a reliable measure of price movements be the basis for meas-
uring whether this objective is met. The Consumer Price Index is
the single most reliable of the major indexes for measuring price
stability, and the economy ought to aim for stability in the Consumer
Price Index after allowing for inability of this index fully to reflect
quality changes in goods and services produced.
The third objective, economic growth, is regarded as a prerequisite
for the attainment not only of economic, but of other fundamental
goals as well. With increasing levels of output, the standards of liv-
ing and opportunity of the great majority of Americans rise. At the
same time, an expanding economy provides the means to meet the
minimum economic needs of all citizens, and to ease the stresses of
a~ variety of current technological, social, and economic changes. For
the postwar years, the measured trend rate of increase in productivity
per man-hour for the private and nublic sectors combined has been
just over 2.5 percent annually. Adding the growth trend of 1.5 per-
cent in total man-hours worked, the annual rate of exapnsion of p0-
t"ntial output has been about 4 percent. The Nation's economic growth
objectives should be to maintain a rate of growth in productivity
per man-hour at least equal to the 2.5-percent trend, and continuing
attempts should be made to improve this performance.
In defining the final objective, equilibrium in the Nation's balance
of payments. the committee notes that in nearly every year of the last
decade the TJnitecl States has experienced an annual deficit in the bal-
PAGENO="0025"
985
ance of payments. In settling these deficits, our gold reserve has de-
clined and our liabilities to foreigners have increased substantially.
However, the acquisition of dollar balances by foreigners has also
served a useful purpose. Private foreigners have volimtarily increased
their dollar holdings to finance world trade and international business.
Because of the dollar's important role as an international reserve asset,
foreign official institutions may also want to add further to their liquid
dollar assets.
Equilibrium in our international payments is attained when, on aver-
age, the deficits in our international accounts are equal to the addi-
tional dollars the rest of the world voluntarily wishes to acid to its
holdings at the existing exchange rates when there are no direct or
indirect government controls over international trade or capital trans-
actions imposed for balance-of-payments reasons. The United States
is not likely to achieve longrun payments equilibrium unless the econ-
omy reaches its other objectives of high employment, stable prices, and
steady growth.
The statement then specifies the role the Government plays in
affecting the economy as being composed of two conceptually separate
sets of forces: those which affect the level of output that the economy
has the potential to produce at stable prices and those forces which
affect the actual level of demand at any time. The Government's impact
on the economic potential of the economy arises from its influence
on the size of the labor force as well as its impact on the productivity
of this labor force. While the factors affecting productivity are many
and diverse, Government expenditures on health, education, urban
development, research and development and the like have direct impact
on the motivation and ability of the work force and thus affect the
potential. Expenditures and tax programs designed to induce innova-
tion and investment also provide significant stimuli to increase produc-
tivity. However, to the extent we spend publicly to achieve these ob-
jectives when the economy is at high employment, less resources are
available to be used in the private sector. Thus, we conclude
Our longrun objective for economic growth requires that the
Federal Government manage its s~penciing, taxing, lending and
borrowing programs in ways which assure that the resources
of the whole economy are used a~s efficiently as possible. This means
that the productivity of Federal spending and lending programs
should be weighed against the productivity of private spending
and that the tax system be one which fosters or least deters mi
tiative, effort, and investment. These objectives can best be served
if the Federal Government manages its spending and taxing so
as to yield approximate balance in the overall budget when the
economy is at a high level of employment and expevwncing stable
prices.
The Federal Government through its taxing, borrowing, spend-
ing, and lending decisions exerts a significant influence on the actual
level of the economic activity in the economy. Monetary policy simi-
larly exerts a substantial impact on the level of demand, employ-
ment, and prices. Our recommendations for public policy with respect
to the objective of achieving high employment at stable prices are
that if, with proposed Federal spending and the existing tax rates,
total demands exceed or fall short of the country's capacity to produce
at stable prices, the Congress should enact legislation affecting either
PAGENO="0026"
986
spending or taxes or both so as to bring the total of public and
private demands within these bounds. The method of temporary in-
come tax change selected by Congress to stabilize the economy should
be easy to initiate, easy to understand, and easy to administer, and it
should not substantially alter the tax structure.
Experience with the use of tax changes for economic stabilization
purposes demonstrates that such action often needs to be taken more
`expeditiously than the usua.l congressional procedures have permitted.
There `should, therefore, be a consensus not only about the form of the
tax change and the economy's need for it, but also a mechanism for
obtaining timely action.
The basic role of monetary policy in a broad program of economic
stabilization should be to create and preserve an environment in which
expectations of monetary developments are themselves stable. This
requires a close coordination in the use of monetary and fiscal policies.
Major failures in fiscal policy cannot be successfully offset by mone-
tary measures. Experience has demonstrated that fiscal and monetary
measures cannot be effective when used in substantially conflicting
ways. This philosophy implies a restrained use of the basic monetary
instruments consistent with long-run objectives, a.voiding drastic
short-run changes in monetary postures.
Given this general introduction to our policy statement it should be
clear that there are many parts of the Report of the Council of Eco-
nomic Advisers with which we heartily agree. The report's emphasis
on the need to restra.in inflation and the necessity of both fiscal and
monetary restraint are most appropriate. WTe especially agree that
some more efficient procedures must be established within the Con-
gress as well as within the executive to assure that the level of Fed-
eral expenditures and tax rates are such as to keep the levels of de-
inand within the country's potential to produce at stable prices. We
agree with the report that this requires congressional review of the
proposed budget as a. whole as well as the need for a prompt mechanism
to enable the executive to propose and the Congress to enact tax
changes.
AGGREGATE DEMAND, EMPLOYMENT, AND INFLATION
We are pleased to concur with the report's conclusion that exces-
sive levels of demand leading to inflation produce little permailent
decline in unemployment. As is suggested by the behavior of unem-
ployment in the 1961-1965 period, when output was below our capacity
to produce, raising demand resulted in a marked decline in unemploy-
ment. Further increases in demand and unanticipated increases in
prices brought some temporary further increase in employment and
output. As the acceleration in prices became more obvious, however,
the increases in employment became much less pronounced and the
wage rates demanded by workers accelerated.
\T\Te now find ourselves in the position where business and labor feel
inflation is likely to persist `and are making price and wage decisions
in this anticipation. The task before the country is to slow down the
growth in total demand so that the rate of price increase gradually
diminishes and anticipations of inflation are adjusted downward. We
agree with the report that this must be a gradual process. Given these
existing inflationary anticipations, if aggregate demand were sub-
PAGENO="0027"
987
stantially reduced in an attempt to eradicate the inflationary anticipa-
~tions quickly, unemployment is likely to jump substantially. Excessive
slowing of the growth in demand and a sharp reduction in prices will
generate unnecessary temporary unemployment until price expecta-
tions are gradually brought into line with the new reality of relative
price stability. A more gradual reduction in the growth in demand
and a more gradual reduction in the rate of price increase is consistent
with little increase in unemployment.
We would like to accentuate more than does the Council's Report,
however, our belief that the elimination of the inflationary expecta-
tions must be persistent and complete as well as gradual. If gradual
action means that inflationary expectations are not reduced sufficiently
by the end of calendar 1969, then aggregate demand policy in 1970
must be consistent with a continued reduction in such expectations to
* the point of elimination.
In this regard we are concerned about two features of the report.
First, while the report is not precise about the pattern of economic
activity throughout calendar 1969, it does suggest that real output
will be accelerating toward `tl~e end of the year. It also suggests that
the price level will still be increasing at a rate inconsistent with rea-
sonable price stability. Should an acceleration of the economy arrest
the decline in the rate of pric~ increase before something close to rela-
-tive price stability is a.chi.eved,we shall not have achieved the primary
* objective of eliminating the inflationary anticipations. To embark on
a path of gradual reduction in the rate of price increase is better than
pursuing a policy of sharp deceleration of demands only if the policy
of gradually reducing demand is pursued long enough to *achieve
its objective. There is no assurance that a gradual reduction in the
rate of price inflation in 1969 followed by an increase in price inflation
in 1970 would be more in our interests than a substantial reduction in
the rate of growth of demand in 1969. If we are to athieve our ob-
jectives for price stability we must take positive action to assure ag-
* gregate demands in the years 1969 and 1970 are consistent with decel-
erating prices.
Given this need for persistent and complete elimination of the in~
flation and inflationary expectations, we agree with the report's con-
clusion that the proper fiscal policy for fiscal year 1970 would be one
that would yield a surplus in the Federal budget. It is mandatory,
therefore, that planned Federal expenditures be reviewed closely in a
search for opportunities to cut spending. Unless ways are found to
reduce planned expenditures by a sufficient amount, it will be necessary,
as the report recommends, to extend the income tax surcharge through
fiscal year 1970 if a budget surplus is to be achieved.
Second, the report suggests that business `and labor must make
sac~flees in their price and wage decisions to assist the economy in
achieving price stability. We think this is an ineffective approach to
price stability. If the Government pursues actions to bring about price
deceleration and if credit policies lead business and labor to anticipate
a reduction in the rate of inflation they will in their own self-interest
set prices and wages consistent with this deceleration; in this sense
there need be no sacrifices. Wages and prices will have been set in
the expectation of decelerating prices and such a deceleration will have
`occurred. There will only be sacrifices if business and labor make
PAGENO="0028"
988
decisions in the belief prices will decelerate and the Government does
not take action to bring this deceleration about. Business and labor
make their decisions, in part at least, on their expectations with respect
to the future. If these decisions are to reflect a belief in diminishing
inflation the Government will gain little by exhorting business and
labor to make sacrifices. It can affect wage and price decisions only
if it shows performance in actually reducing inflation.
Thus the major emphasis in a policy to decelerate the rate of price
increase and restrain inflation must be on controlling Government
expenditures and taxes as well as on a stabilizing monetary policy,
so that the economy exposes itself to very little chance that demands
are excessive. A policy which places heavy reliance on attempts to
administer prices and wages while at the same time managing fiscal
and monetary policies so as to expand aggregat.e demand at danger.
ously high rates would be an inappropriate and highly inefficient plan.
POLICIES To REDnCE THE FRICTIONAL LEVEL OF UNEMPLOYMENT
Unemployment can arise in a va.riety of ways. Total demands may
be less than the country's capacity to produce at stable prices. With
the economy operating at or close to its potential, temporary variations
in unemployment can arise because business and labor are unable fully
to anticipate short-term business variations. In addition, a. more per-
maneEt or persistent ca.use of unemployment arises from the seasonal
character of some work, the difficulties of matching job skills and job
locations, the faulty information about job prospects or labor skills,
from the effects of discrimination by employers and unions, and from
restrictive labor practices.
We agree with the council's report that there are several steps which
can and must be taken to reduce the amount of unemployment arising
from these sources. Such action must be taken for two reasons. The
employment and income these workers could generate would provide
the support they and their families need. In addition, however, pro-
grams to improve the competitive character and efficiency of labor
markets will increase the productivity of those now working as well
as enhance the productivity of the unemployed.
Thus, beyond its beneficial impact on the life and well-being of the
unemployed and underemployed, programs which affect labor produc-
tivity affect all of us in the sense that they change the potential out-
put in which we all have a share. Indeed, it ha.s been estimated that as
we continue to incorporate minority groups into our labor force more
efficiently, this step alone will raise the rate of growth of our economic
potential from about 4 percent to almost 41/2 percent per annum. With
the level of output in 1969 close to $900 billion, this implies that this
more efficient use of our resources will produce an annual increase in
our real output of almost $5 billion. If such a program were to have
this impact over 5 years, output in the 5th year would be almost $30
billion higher than if we had not engaged in such programs. This social
benefit is greater than the private benefit these families obtain from
becoming more productive members of society.
FISCAL AND MONETARY POLICY AND AGGREGATE DEMAND
The Council's report deals at length with the specific inipact of past
fiscal policy actions on the economy. It leads one to the belief that we
possess a knowledge of the impact of fiscal policy in rather sophisti-
cated detail. On the other hand, it suggests that the impact of mone-
PAGENO="0029"
989
tary policy is less clear. The exact mechanisms through which mone-
tary policy works and the exact impact and timing are said to be
unclear. The report concludes that it is likely to be unwise to attempt
to use monetary policy with the hope of very closely controlling ag-
gregate demand, that monetary policy should be flexible and not tied
to any specific rule. We agree with these `comments about monetary
policy, but we think many of the arguments the council poses against
attempts to use monetary policy to "fine-tune" the economy apply to
fiscal policy as well. Just as it is unclear how different definitions of
money supply affect spending decisions, there is at least some uncer-
tainty about the effects on spending by the private sector of Federal
spending as opposed to Federal lending, of Federal spending as op-
posed to Federal taxes, or direct Federal expenditures as opposed to
transfer of payments, or of corporate income taxes as opposed to per-
sonal income taxes. The report itself attests to the difficulties of mak-
ing very precise predictions of the savings behavior of individuals and
the determinants of business investment and inventory accumulation.
The report reflects the uncertainty in most minds about the exact im-
pact of fiscal or monetary policy on interest rates and thus on savings
flows to mortgage lending institutions and thereby to expenditures on
construction.
We are not suggesting that we do not know enough about how mone-
tary and fiscal policy affect the economy to enable us to use these tools
to help us meet our economic objectives. However, we do not know
enough about the precise effects of either monetary or fiscal policy to
try to use them to contain the economy within very precise limits.
ECONOMIC POLICY IN 1969 AND 1970
This difficulty in using either of these policies in very exact ways
has substantial implications for economic policy in 1969 and 1970.
The maj or problem facing the United States in the years immediately
ahead is to eliminate the inflationary expectations which have been
built up over the past 31/2 years. The elimination of inflationary ex-
pectations requires that we expose our economy to very little risk of
excessive demands-that we do not pursue fiscal and monetary policies
which might lead to an acceleration of prices before the middle or end
of 1970. Given our inability to predict exactly how fiscal and monetary
policy work, we must take a fiscal and monetary policy position such
that if we are wrong and if consumers and business expenditures
as well as Government expenditures move differently than we expect,
the economy does not accelerate too rapidly `toward the end of 1969.
Such a policy necessarily exposes us to some risk that the economy
will grow too slowly `and that unemployment will temporarily increase.
Given our unwillingness to take sufficient action to control the infla-
tion in the past 31/2 years, however, the price we may now have to pay
is this exposure to the risk of `a temporary rise in unemployment. To
be sure, we must stand ready to minimize the effects of this risk by
being prepared to take steps to expand demand should it become clear
it is growing more slowly than the return to relative price stability
requires. In addition serious attenti'on should be given to making
existing manpower and training programs more effective in order to
minimize any temporary rise in unemployment. 1-lowever, since we are
PAGENO="0030"
990
not able to use monetary and fiscal policies to control exactly the leveIl
of the economy and since the eradication of the inflationary expecta-
tions is our paramount problem, we must assure ourselves that aggre-
gate demand does not accelerate too rapidly. From our current posi-
tion, therefore, we must be more willing to bear the risk of a temporary
rise in unemployment than to bear the risk of a reescalation of price
rncreases.
The second major economic problem facing the United States is
the necessity for improving the productivity and expanding the eco-
nomic potential of a large fraction of our unemployed and underem-
ployed workers. While a part of the poverty problem is not directly
associated with this productivity problem, a very large part is. Ac-
cording to the report, two-thirds of the poor, nonelderly households
are headed by able-bodied working-age men. The poverty of these
families arises from an inability of these men to find jobs where their
productivity enables them to earn a level of income high enough to
raise their families above the poverty level. Vigorous efforts must be
made to develop in these people the skills and motivation to be more
productive and by working with business and labor to expand the
job opportunities open to them. The Council of Economic Advisers
has provided enlightening documentation of location and demographic
factors associated with those families and persons experiencing low
levels of income in the United States. It defines the "poverty gap"
as the amount by which the income of these families and individuals
falls below minimum income standards. In line with the concern
for the productivity of many of these people, an alternate definition
would be the shortfall of output they and the economy suffer because'
many of them have such low levels of productivity. Their individual
and collective inability to produce efficiently generates serious social
and personal problems as do their low incomes. Social action should
concentrate attention on improving productivity and output of many
of these persons rather than concentrate attention on income supple--
ments.
Tiii~ OVERALL DESIGN OF GOVERNMENT PROGRAMS To INFLtTENOE THE'
EcoNo~rY
There is little doubt but that society collectively, with the Govern-
ment `as its agent, has a substantial responsibility and opportunity'
to affect the economy. We feel it should be a guiding principle of such
action that the Government should enact positive programs which
create the environment of competition and efficiency and which make
the economy more adaptive and self-reliant rather than design a. wide
variety of specific programs to alleviate specific problems with little'
concern for their cumulative impact on the character of economic life.
On the basis of this point of view, there are at least two examples
of such misplaced emphasis in the report. One is the role suggested
for the Wage-Price Cabinet Committee. It is suggested that there'
exists a number of product and labor markets in which "discretion-
ary" power exists-power which presumably does not exist in com-
petitive markets. To dea.l with this prc~blem the report suggests that
the Cabinet Committee might evaluate the wage or price decisions'
made in these specific markets, publicize any supposed deficiencies,.
PAGENO="0031"
991
and attempt to obtain the cooperation of labor and business in reach-
ing decisions which in the eyes of the Cabinet Committee were more
in the public interest. Besides being an invitation to arbitrary and
discriminatory practice on the part of such a committee and inviting
a kind of collusion among producers and labor unions to "play the
system," such a proposal is unlikely to achieve its objectives.
To the extent there exist restrictive practices in labor markets or
product markets, the Labor and Justice Departments have the direct
responsibility to deal with such illegal practices using their legislative
or judicial authority, with due process. To establish a Cabinet com-
mittee with no such legislative or judicial authority is only to blunt
the interest and activity of those who have authority to deal with the
issues involved.
In another area society's attempts to assure adequate living stand-
ards for those living in poverty should concentrate as much as pos-
sible on assuring these people the opportunity of becoming productive
rather than simply attempting to funnel income to them from the
more productive members of society. Social welfare programs clearly
require more than attempts to improve productivity. Some people and.
families will need income beyond what their productivity can earn
and society will necessarily choose to provide this income to them.
However, the major emphasis of the war on poverty ought to be a
positive program directed toward improving productivity and output
and the personal and social dignity which comes from being a produc-
tive member of society. Throughout this program and other Federal
programs, the driving emphasis ought to be on creating mechanisms
which have the effect of improving productivity and efficiency, of
freeing markets and persons from dependence on Government action
and programs, and of making the economy conform as closely as pos-
sible to the pressures of competition.
TOWARD INTERNATIONAL EQIIILIBRrnM
In its examination of the international economy, the Council's re-
port reviews the progress that has been made in the growth of inter-
national trade and capital movements since the end of World War IL
We share many of the views expressed in this section. The contribution
of the present IMF system, the importance of stable exchange rates,
the need for continuing progress on the problems of liquidity, con-
fidence, and adjustment, and the need for freer trade including re-
duction of nontariff barriers are subjects which we have studied and
on which we have taken firm position in recent years. While we share
many of the positions expressed in the report on the necessity of
restoring equilibrium in the U.S. balance of payments, there are some
differences between our veiws that also should be highlighted.
The basic objective of our international trade and financial policy
should be to achieve the full benefits of international exchange for our-
selves and others by reducing restrictions on international trade and
investment. A primary requirement for the effective functioning of
the international payments system is that the United States achieve
equilibrium in its balance of payments and thereby eliminate a major
source of instability which has impaired the effectiveness of that sys-
tem in recent years.
PAGENO="0032"
992
As we indicated in our most recent policy statement, equilibrium in
our international accounts does not require the elimination of the
deficit. Bather its size should be reduced to a level compatible with the
willingness of the rest of the world to voluntarily maintain or to in-
crease their dollar holdings in line with the need for world liquidity.
The reduction in our balance-of-payments deficit by means of restric-
tions on international trade and capital movements is inconsistent
with our objective of securing benefits of grea.ter trade and investment.
Despite some improvement in the underlying balance-of-payments
position in 1968 compared to 1967, the underlying 1968 deficit (which
excludes special transactions which our Government has persuaded
other governments to undertake in order to make the recorded result
look better) was still on the order of $~.7 billion on a liquidity basis.
One encouraging aspect of the 1968 result is the large foreign purchases
of U.S. stocks a.nd there is some reason to believe that this trend will
continue. However, there was also an unusually large inflow of for-
eign capital influenced by high interest rates in the United States and
by reduction of outstanding foreign loans by U.S. banks. We cannot
rely on these factors to provide lasting relief to our balance of
Jayrnents.
The most disturbing aspect of the 1968 result was the virtual dis-
appearance of our traditionally large merchandise trade surplus from
a~ level of $3.5 billion in 1967. Clearly this reversal is critical. It results
in large measure from a surge of imports induced by the inflationary
growth of demand to which we have referred earlier. It is interesting
to note that the growth rate in exports in 1968 was 9.5 percent, sub-
stantially above the rate in 1967.
We do not share the views expressed in the report that restrictions
imposed by the United States for balance-of-payments reasons have
been helpful. While they may have afforded temporary relief, by now it
is evident that the controls have not restored equilibrium in our inter-
national accounts. Further, what started as a few, temporary controls
have now become a network of apparenly more permanent controls
which are wasteful, inefficient, and undermine our avowed objectives of
encouraging international trade and investment.
While the report does stress the need for a domestic stabilization
program to `assist in the achievement of balance-of-payments equilib-
rium, we believe that this is the critica~ `need. A stabilization program
to achieve high employment and stable prices would serve to improve
the trade surplus and to insure maintenance of sufficient dollar hold-
ings by foreigners to reduce the need for controls.
The Council report notes a number of proposals which have been ad-
vanced for changes in the present exchange rate adjustment mecha-
nism. While a review of the adjustment mechanism may be useful, we
share the Council's view that intensive study would be required before
serious consideration could be given to the adoption of any of the pro-
posals which have been put forward. Such intensive study should
focus on the practical effects on trade and investment flows of any
changes from the present system.
PAGENO="0033"
COMMUNICATIONS WORKERS OF AMERICA
In both the statements of President Johnson's Council of Economic
Advisers and the new Council for President Nixon, there are references
to the necessity, under the existing economic circumstances, for quaZz-
tative adjustments in fiscal and monetary policies for 1969. In both
statements there is a preoccupation with the problem of stifling infla-
tionary pressures in the presence of persistence of some continuing
troublesome residue of unemployment. This is expressed in an oft-
repeated caution that it may be impossible to have full employment
without some inflation. The policy considerations are concerned with
the possibility that this problem is increasingly qualitative in nature,
and that "doses" of ant-inflationary or anti-deflationary fiscal and
monetary policy are not quite suitable as the remedy. The apparent
requirement is alternatively expressed as a "fine mix" or "fine tuning."
As has been the case with the development of general fiscal-monetary
policy, direction for the more refined problem must be looked for in
the behavior of the economy. The lessons simply are a little more diffi-
cult to work out. The behavior of the economy in the last 2 years does
appear to offer, however, some viable possibilities if they are carefully
examined.
A central characteristic of the behavior of the economy over the last
2 years, despite inflationary pressuers and the pressures of the Veitnam
war, has been a certain basic balance. Consumer expenditures have
been an important expansionary force in the economy for the last 3
years, although slightly less so in 1967. In 1968, consumer expenditures
rose by $42 billion, while the increases in the previous 3 years had
been in the neighborhood of $32 billion, although only $25 billion in
1967. More importantly, however, as a percentage of disposable income,
while consumer expenditures had declined for the preceding 4 years
from 92.7 percent to 90.1 percent in 1967, they returned to 90.6 percent
in 1968. Savings, on the other hand, which reached an unusual peak of
7.4 percent in 1967-in spite of some inflation-from 6.4 percent in 1966,
held to 6.9 percent in 1968. Included in the increase in consumer
expenditures was a strong $10 billion increase in durable goods
purchases.
By contrast, business investment declined slightly as a proportion
of the total national product, and business fixed investment declined
by approximately the same amount in contrast to its usual tendency
to rise in an expansionary year.
The main point is that investment, which used to be regarded as
the prime mover in the economy and has been regarded as a primary
target for monetary and fiscal policy, may new be less the volatile lever
among economic variables in the economy. It is expected, as a matter
of fact, that the first half of 1969 will see a strong resurgence of busi-
ness fixed investment on the basis of the experience in 1968.
(993)
24-833-69-Pt. 4-3
PAGENO="0034"
994
It is somewhat startling to compare these changes with a number
of other changes that took place during the last 2 years. During 1967,
while the Government's 3.5-percent estimated productivity end of the
wage-price guidelines was being effectively cracked, real average hourly
compensation increased 3.2 percent, while productivity in output per
man-hour increased 1.6 percent. The year saw a 6.1-percent increase
in money earnings. During 1968, following effective "abandonment"
of wage-price guidelines, money earnings increased 7.4 percent; real
average hourly compensation increased 3.3 percent in spite of infla-
tion; and it was supported by a 3.3-percent increase in output per
man-hour. Unit labor costs, which rose 4.4~ percent in 1967, only rose
3.9 percent in 1968.
Nevertheless, in spite of all this, corporate profits rose to an astro-
nomical $92.3 billion from $81.6 billion in 1967, to continue what has
been described as a profit inflation. This amounted to a 14.3-percent
increase over 1967, although there had been a decline in 1967 from
1966. The fact is that the President's Council in 1967 viewed with alarm
a develoj~ment which suggested that the proportion of national in-
come gomg to profits was increasing at the expense of a slightly de-
creasing proportion of income going to all wages and salaries. The
Council wondered if the strong increase in the level of consumer ex-
penditures for both 1965 and 1966 would hold up in 1967. It did not!
What actually has happened to these shares is apparent in the record
below:
[In percentj
Shar
e of national income
Wages
(including
Year
Profits
supplements)
Other
1968
12.95
72.0
15.1
1967
12.5
71.7
15.8
1966
13.8
70.2
16.0
1965
1964
13. 8
12. 9
69. 8
70. &
16. 4
16. 5
The figures for 1968 appear to indicate some evening up of economic
shares in 1968, in the face of an inflation which might otherwise have
produced opposite effects, as well as aggravation of inequalities which
seem to have a fairly direct bearing on the behavior of consumer
expenditures. The record for 1968 might be taken to indicate that
reasonable distribution of productivity in 1968 enabled the economy,
apparently still capable of real expansion, to push ahead in spite of
the pressures on cost from inflation.
Of course, the growth in the second half of the year was dampened
by the new surtax, while inflation slackened slightly. But this is a
better adjustment to inflationary pressures than declines in produc-
tion and employment. Clearly, also, profits have hardly suffered.
While wages and salaries in 1968 finally reached 72 percent of th&
national income (from 71.7 percent in 1967), this was largely at the
expense of interest, rent, and independent incomes, as profits moved
up to 12.95 percent from 12.5 percent in 1967.
PAGENO="0035"
995
We think that these kinds of factors, involving a fine balance in the
flow of goods and incomes in the economy, will have to become a focal
point in the "fine tuning" of fiscal and monetary policy.
For example, a considerable portion of the high profits for 1968
are going to go back into investment, adding additional fuel to an
already overheated economy. We noted earlier that the old Council
contemplates a considerable increase in business fixed investment for
1969. A substantial portion of such investment will be in respo~ise
to 1968's notable increase in purchases of consumer durables-which
were not very strong in 1967, and may not be again in 1969. Indeed,,
some of the buying of durables in 1968 may well have been in re~
sponse to anticipated price increases during 1969.
Increasingly, the economy is becoming consumer oriented-as might
be expected in an affluent society. An additional measure of this may
be found in the increase in the percentage of consumer expenditures
which go for the purchase of services-which was around 371/2 per-
cent of disposable personal income in 1967 and 1968, 37 percent on
the average from 1959 to 1966, and only 34 percent on the average over
the period 1956 to 1958. In addition, new investment in plant and
equipment has an increasing tendency to be capital saving, as well as
laborsaving, and its increased productivity is going to have to be
thoroughly distributed, or the time will come when all the products
will not be purchased back.
These shifts in our economic situation appear to dictate some of the
elements of a policy which may be pursued in an effort that may be
called fine tuning.
In the past, economists have said that the maj or problem in achiev-
ing full employment without inflation was to balance aggregate mone-
tary demand and aggregate supply. A critical factor is held to be
the balancing of decisions to invest with decisions to save. This is
because investment has always been regarded as the volatile element
in aggregate demand. Indeed, if the proportion of consumer savings
from the national income had not been inordinately large in 1967,
we might have had more inflation that year.
Generally, Government policy to influence investment has been
direct monetary policy or indirect fiscal policy. That is to say, Gov-
ernment has sought to influence investment decisions through the
monetary mechanism and interest rates, directly. Indirectly, it has
sought to influence investment decisions by increasing or decreasing
spendable incomes through fiscal policy.
The difficulty with the latter policy, in the present circumstances,
is that fiscal policy is a general onslaught against all spending. The
requirements of "fine tuning" do not seem to permit this. Consumer
expenditures are increasingly critical to stability in the economy. It
is increasingly clear that high profits heavily outweigh the influence
of interest rates in investment decisions. While consumer expendi-
tures as a proportion of the GNP have fluctuated from something over
64 percent to something under, gross private domestic investment has
fluctuated from 13.83 percent in 1961 to 16.56 percent in 1966-and
suffered for it somewhat in 1967.
As the basis of a high proportion of incomes, consumer expenditures
are heavily dependent upon wages and salaries, in order that goods
and services for profit can be "cleared from the shelves" without
PAGENO="0036"
996
inordinate, unanticipated increases in inventories. At the same time
as purchasing power is maintained, it should not, of course, find a
shortage of goods and thus produce imfiation. If more purchasing
power is channeled into time-consuming investment than is going to
be provided from current savings, inflation will be the result. This
condition has been the situation now for some years. Investment has
proceeded apace in response to perhaps the wildest profit boom in our
history.
It is in this context that we have never been able to accept the
Teracity of a voluntary "incomes policy" comprehended in wage-price
guideposts. A sacrificial wage policy will not keep profits up, if con-
sumer expenditures fall below the level anticipated as necessary to
~`clear the market," if the low-wage increases merely leave incorrect
unticipations of higher profits. We think the wage policies of unions
have helped sustain an expanding market by preserving the propor-
tion of the national income going to wage and salary compensation.
The old Council urges labor to accept wage increases (money) of
no greater than 5 percent, and businesses to accept profit margins no
higher than the average achieved in 1967-68--probably as high as
they have been in recent years-and asks that they absorb increases
in unit labor costs up to 1 percent.
The profit margins of 1968 required a 2.6-percent increase in in-
dustrial prices. The corresponding increase in the Consumer Price
Index was 4.2 percent. If these increases are approached in 1969, it
does not appear that an increase in money average earnings of 5 per-
cent would increase real average earnings sufficiently to maintain the
present distribution, as between wages and profits, from the national
income, unless there were less than a 3.3-percent increase in produc-
tivity-in which case the profit margin would not be retained anyway.
We find it gratifying that the new Council of Economic Advisers
has abandoned the idea of wage-price guidelines as a mechanism for
maintenance of distributive shares. Since, as the Wall Street Journal
recently acknowledged, it is prices which lead wages upward, a guide-
lines policy is poorly desigiied for its job-because it always leaves
wages behind. While wages and salaries have gone up by 40.5 per-
cent since 1960, profits have gone up 85.7 percent.
We think profit margins are aheady too high, and offer too high
an incentive for further investment. We note a recent release from
the Internal Revenue Service indicating that, for the fiscal year end-
ing in June 1968, while individual income tax collections increased
by $8.7 billion over the previous year, corporate income tax payments
declined by $5 billion. Note that this period covered the higher rate
of expansion in the first half of calendar 1968.
The current additional "dosage" of indirect fiscal policy contained
in the 10-percent surtax, though probably necessary to curb a runaway
inflation incident to heavy governmental expenditures, does not appear
to be depressing investment aspirations as much as it affects consumer
expenditures, if the last half of 1968 is any indication. V\Te suspect
that this is partially the effect of high returns from investment in
industries with a heavy concentration of Government contracts.
We think it is time to attack inflation on a discriminating basis, by
a frontal attack on the proportion of national income going to profits
as compared to wages and salary compensation, in order to stabilize
PAGENO="0037"
997
consumer expenditures without inflation. Consumer expenditures have
been quite stable as a proportion of the national product-but only
with inflation. We think the problem of maintaining consumer pur-
chasing power for increased consumer goods and services without in-
flation is directly related to the issue of tax reform.
In addition, in the midst of inflation, we continue to have "pockets"
of hard-core unemployment and serious "pockets" of poverty amid
affluence. Continuing unemployment is always a waste in any form.
We think the new Council has correctly made a decision that a dis-
criminating expenditure policy is required here, too, as compared with
some "dosage" of fiscal policy. Both the unemployment and the poverty
problems are also related, in our mind, to tax reform.
The present revenue level from individual income taxation can be
retained with considerable shifting in the progressivity of the indi-
vidual rates. We feel that this should be done on a basis which would
allow negative income taxation at poverty levels, exemption from in-
come taxation on family incomes between $3,000 and $5,000 a year,
the imposition of a minimum tax on all income above a reasonable
level, and the application of higher marginal rates at high-income
levels.
We think the corporate income tax should be overhauled as well.
For one matter, the existing rates are considerably overstated on the
basis of current depreciation and depletion guidelines. These were a
part of an earlier tax reduction `and recession-induced expansion pro-
gram, and are contributing to the present inflation. In particular, the
continuation of the oil depletion allowance is scandalous and an affront
to the poverty ridden, not only of the United States, `but of the world.
Higher corporate income tax rates will reduce the level of invest-
ment expenditures and induce more careful use of resources. If higher
individual income tax rates on higher incomes are to be put into effect,
some partial exemption from a higher corporate tax rate schedule
could be given to distributed corporate profits (dividends). The latter
measure might alleviate a number of the current pressures in the money
market. However, if the latter effect is not forthcoming, we feel there
is an urgent need for Federal subsidization to lower interest charges
on housing and residential construction. Investment in these areas has
been drained by high profits elsewhere.
While we agree that tax credit for investment in training and edu-
cation of the unemployed through private enterprise is a nice idea,
we feel that this would become a very unwieldy mechanism, and we
are in serious doubt as to the interest of private enterprise in this
particular problem. On the other hand, direct cooperation between
Government and private enterprise will `be a necessary base for solu-
tions to the problems of the hard-core unemployed.
We would hope that movements in these directions could be a sub-
stantial step toward dealing with some of our more vexing domestic
problems.
Finally, we offer some comments on the balance-of-payments prob-
lem. It seems clear that the various measures undertaken during 1968,
including direct controls on foreign investment, the cessation of gold
shipments for private markets among the gold pooi nations, and the
ending of the gold-backing requirement for U.S. currency, have tem-
porarily allayed any immediate balance-of-payments crisis.
PAGENO="0038"
998
We cannot help noting, however, the necessity of Government con-
trols on direct foreign investment as an interesting commentary on
the haste of American profits to seek an ever-higher rate of return,
in the midst of developing inflation at home. Actually, it now begins
to appear that this program has less resistance as a result of invest-
ment abroad, perhaps having run most of its course before the restric-
tions were imposed. In contrast, the net balance on foreign investment
income now has attained a level such that it has given considerable
improvement in the balance-of-payments problem. Although it may
be true that we cannot assume the same improvement increments in
future years, there does not seem to be any reason to believe that this
factor will recede very quickly.
The overriding issue in the balance-of-payments problem lies in the
fact that, presumably, we have been importing too much. Ironically,
a larger factor in this has been the importing of I 0 TJ's-"exports"
of capital which have given others claims on us. In a free market for
international exchange, this should have meant that there was a grow-
ing demand for foreign claims in order to pay for foreign debts, and
a consequent premium for exporters who provide the major source
of such foreign claims. Of course, when it becomes too expensive to
liquidate debts through the exchange system, there are, as there have
been, gold payments.
This increasing pressure has suggested that a freeze on gold and
"freely fluctuating exchange rates" would correct the import sit.ua-
tion. We now have, for practical purposes, the gold freeze. The objec-
tions to a proposal for freely fluctuating exchange rates center around
problems of uncertainty, disturbance to trade and investment rela-
tionships, and requirements of shifts of resources among industries
which export and those which compete with imports. Most of these
arguments are invalid from an economic point of view. The only
ultimate remedy in a world economy in which gold no longer is an
adequate medium of exchange is freely floating exchange rates.
However, inasmuch as our international trade still only amounts
to 5.3 percent of GNP, other international considerations may be re-
garded as more pressing. Under freely flexible exchange rates, much
importing would likely be cut off. The present domestic inflation, as
a matter of fact, receives some relief from imports. On the other hand,
we feel some approach to flexible exchange rates will have to be made
in the not-too-distant future.
In summary, it is our view that the "fine tuning" which is called
for under a gradua.listic approach to deflation ought to concentrate
on the profit-push phenomenon, and its insidious ally, the new boom
in corporate investment. Coupled with such an approach must be a
serious and searching restructuring of the entire Federal tax-levying
mechanism, with a view to long-range revision of the distributive
shares of our national income.
PAGENO="0039"
CONFERENCE ON ECONOMIC PROGRESS
By LEON H. Ki~~xs:Iniu4n~a,* PRESIDENT
CONTENTS Page
Introduction 1000
Reasons for main concentration upon CEA Report 1000
Need for a long-term perspective 1000
Plus marks for the "New Economics" 1001
Minus marks for the "New Economics" 1002
Significance of my earlier studies 1002
Outline of my presentation 1003
Chapter I. THE PROBLEM OF OPTIMUM ECONOMIC GROWTH:
The growth record and the growth need in detail 1003
The "longest upward movement on record," and the economic outlook_ - - 1004
Productivity trends, and their significance 1005
Bearing of rate of economic growth upon employment and unemployment_ - 1005
Targeting economic growth through 1967, and its significance 1007
The erroneous views of the CEA on economic growth 1007
Chapter II. THE PROBLEM OF ECONOMIC EQUILIBRIUM, OR BALANCE:
Essentials of economic equilibrium or balance 1008
Factual anatomy of the economic disequilibrium 1009
The rampant profit inflation 1009
CEA neglect of economic equilibrium problem 1010
~2hapter III. THE PROBLEM OF SOCIAL EQUILIBRIUM, OR PLAIN JUSTICE:
Identity of economic and social objectives in the United States 1011
Poverty and income maldistribution 1012
Social equilibrium involves the public sector 1013
CEA position on poverty: talk versus action 1014
Chapter IV. FISCAL POLICY:
Misdirection of tax cuts to date 1015
Narrow view of scope of the total tax burden 1016
The issue of "tax reform" 1016
Neglect of core purpose of the Federal Budget 1017
Appropriate fiscal policies 1018
Increasing fiscal responsibilities of Federal Government 1019
A model Federal Budget, responsive to needs and capabilities 1019
CEA views on fiscal policy 1021
Chapter V. THE PROBLEM OF INFLATION:
Three main errors in approach to problem of inflation 1021
Evaluation of magnitudes of inflationary trends 1022
CEA has not probed deeply into actual consequences of rising prices 1023
The CEA has gravely misjudged the causes of inflation 1023
My thesis with respect to recent and current inflation 1024
Analysis of cost-push inflation 1025
Shortcomings in CEA treatment of inflation 1027
*Chapter VI. PROBLEMS OF MONETARY POLICY:
General considerations 1028
Tight money and rising interest rates work against economic equiibrium_ 1029
Tight money and rising interest rates are in themselves inflationary 1030
Tight money and rising interest rates are appallingly unequitable 1031
CEA comments on monetary policy 1032
* Former Chairman, Council of Economic Advisers; consulting economist, and
attorney.
(999)
PAGENO="0040"
1000
Page
Chapter VII. THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY 1033
Chapter VIII. THE ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT... 1034
Chapter IX. M~ OWN RECOMMENDATIONS~. -- - 1035
CHARTS
(Appearing at end of statement)
1. U.S. economic growth rates, 1922-68, and needed rates, 1968-77, for opti-
mum resource use.
2. Long-term trends in productivity, U.S. private economy, 1910-68.
3. "Economic Growth Dividend", U.S. Economy, 1968-77.
4. Goals for the U.S. economy, 1972 and 1977, projected from levels in 1967.
5. The goals for 1972 and 1977 maintain balance of public and private respon-
sibilities.
6. Comparative growth in various aspects of U.S. economy, 1961-68.
7. Price, profit, investment, and wage trends during 1960-68.
8. Number in United States living in poverty, deprivation, comfort, and affluence,
1967, and goals for 1972 and 1977.
9. Share of families in total family income by quintiles, 1947, 1953, 1960, and
1966.
10. Allocation of tax cuts, 1962-65: investment and consumption purposes.
11. 1964 Tax Act, personal tax cuts.
12. Taxes paid as percent of income, United States 1966.
13. Resources of State and local governments more strained than those of Fed-
eral Government, relative trends, 1947-67.
14. Goals for a Federal budget, 1972 and 1977, geared to economic growth and
priority needs.
15. Selected price trends, 1918-68, United States and selected other countries.
16. Relative trends in economic growth, unemployment, and prices, 1952-68.
17. The lag in wages and salaries behind productivity gains, 1960-68.
18. Comparative trends in GNP, prices, and nonfederally held money supply,
1955-68.
19. Average interest rates on total public and private debt, 1952-67.
INTRODuCTION
Once again, as in previous years, I deeply appreciate the oppor-
tunity accorded to me by the Joint Economic Committee to set forth
my analysis and conclusions related to the Economic Report of the
President and the Annual Report of the Council of Economic Advisers.
Rea~so~w for main concentration i&pon CEA Report
In the very nature of things, there must be almost absolute con-
sistency between these two documents. It is fair to state, without any
implication of criticism, that the President's Economic Report tends
to become virtually a summary of the Annual Report of the Council
of Economic Advisers. This Annual Report contains, entirely appro-
priately, the detailed economic analysis and other statistical appraisals,
as well as the economic forecast, upon which the President's Report is
based. For these reasons, it would appear to be most helpful to the
Joint Economic Committee for me to concentrate upon the CEA
Report, and this I shall do in accord with my practice during recent
years.
Need for a long-ter'm perspective
The 1969 CEA Report brings to a close a clearly distinguishable
era in the development and application of national economic policies,
extending from January 1961 through December 1968. Those who have
been basically responsible for these policies have given them the appeal-
PAGENO="0041"
1001
ing appellation of the "New Economics." It was reasonably to be ex-
pected, and in fact it has so developed, that the final CEA Report of
the "New Economists" should be, in substantial measure, `an explana-
tion, defense, and praise of the policies, accomplishments, and economic
philosophy of the "New Economics."
It would therefore seem most fitting, and I hope most helpful to the
Joint Economic Committee, that I focus mainly, not upon what has
happened during the past year or so, but instead focus in `broad per-
spective upon what has happened during the past 8 years, and in this
larger view appraise the "New Economics" of the recent CEA members.
This course seems particularly desirable at this time, for `at least
three reasons:
First, it has long been my view that economists in general, including
conspicuously the "new economists," `have devoted relatively too much
attention to short-range trends and policies, and far too little atten-
tion to long-range trends and policies. In the main during the most
recent years, the "fine tuning" attempts to adjust policies and programs
to short-range trends have in some important respects been unsuccess-
ful, not primarily because of detailed errors in judgment, `but rather
because of failure to invoke sufficiently a longer term perspective. So-
called fine tuning has fallen short, not primarily because of the nature
of the instruments, `but primarily because the listening apparatus has
been far too circumscribed and insulated. It is my view that the great-
est single improvement in national economic policies would be to turn
more sytematically and comprehensively to longer range analysis and
programs. Indeed, I believe this to have been the core intent of the
Employment Act of 1946.
A second reason why this appears to me to be a very appropriate
time to evaluate the "new economics" in the full perspective of 8 years
is this: It is the very nature of our political system that the recent
change in the national administration should be expected to bring
forth a fundamental reexamination of national economic policies and
programs, and some considerable changes in them. It is my hope that
the type of analysis which I shall bring forward may be helpful toward
changes in proper directions.
In the third place, the fundamental approach I am undertaking
would seem desirable, because we now stand at what appears to be a
clear and important transition in the economy. Despite the current
stress upon curbing inflationary forces, which has come to amount to
almost a sole preoccupation, the even more important challenge now
confronting us is the threat of a serious retardment in the rate of real
economic ~owth, a serious rise in unemployment, and in consequence
an increasing inability-at least in the context of general attitudes-
to meet adequately the great priorities of our domestic and inter-
national needs.
Pius marks for the "New Economics"
There can be no doubt that the "new economics" has accomplished
much, even though these accomplishments have unfortunately been
accompanied by an unusual degree of public self-praise which has im-
peded critical evaluation. For the 8 years as a whole, a high, though
not entirely satisfactory, rate of economic growth has been maintained.
Unemployment has been reduced greatly, even though not sufficiently.
For the 8-year period as a whole, in terms of the realities rather than
PAGENO="0042"
1002
the ideal, a fair measure of average price stability has been main-
tained. Established programs, devoted to the well-being of the peo-
ple, have been greatly expended. Many innovative social programs
have been initiated, some of them successfully. The conscience of
America has been aroused to the problem of poverty, even though the
measures forged to deal with it have thus far been inadequate and dis-
appointing. The responsibility of national fiscal and monetary policies
to contribute to economic stability and growth has fortunately be-
come increasingly recognized, even though the equal or even greater
responsibility of these and other national policies to improve income
distribution and enlarge social justice has been grievously neglected.
The level of economic literacy and interest has been greatly elevated,
largely through national leadership, and an enlarged consensus on
many important matters has been achieved, perhaps enduringly.
But many problems have remained unsolved, some vital problems
have been seriously neglected, and economic analysis and policy-
making have been guilty of many serious errors of commission and
omission.
Minus marks for the "New Economics"
The above critical comments would not seem excessive. Despite
policies put forward to achieve stable and optimum economic growth,
the real growth rate for the 8-year period as a whole has been some-
what on the low side, the 2-year period 1966-68 averaged a palpably
and seriously deficient real rate of economic gTowth, and the short-term
outlook can hardly be called favorable. Meanwhile, instead of seeking
to reverse this low-growth-rate trend, policies and exhortations seem
directed toward carrying it further. Dspite programs and policies put
forth to curb inflation and improve the balance-of-payments situation,
the 2 most recent years, a.nd especially the past year, have evidenced
the highest rate of price inflation since one short period during the
Korean war, and the end is not yet. The international financial situa-
tion remains parlous, and fundamental remedies have been avoided.
Despite the long-avowed promise to get unemployment down to levels
consistent with maximum employment, the rate of unemployment
among some vulnerable groups remains tragically high, and is con-
tributory to political, civil, and social unrest, notoriously in our urban
areas. Despite the promise to move toward a Great Society, which in
proper context clearly means a good society, some of the greatest and
most pressing priorities of our domestic public needs remain sorely
neglected. And there have not thus far emerged, either in the pro-
nouncements of the "new economists" or in the declared intentions of
the new administration, any substantial and specific programs and
policies offering reasonable prospects of overcoming these manifold
difficulties.
Significance of my ear~ier studies
I approach the task of specifying my reasons for the foregoing con-
clusions with mixed feelings. On the one hand, I regret that more and
better have not been done, and this is my primary sentiment. On the
other hand, I feel justified, rather than prideful, in calling to the
attention of the Joint Economic Committee and others that, year by
year for many years, my presentation of matters to the Joint Economic
Committee and to the public at large have identified fairly consistently
PAGENO="0043"
1003
what was going wrong, and have to a high degree been vindicated by
where we now stand. I take no particular satisfaction in this, except
that I feel duty bound to point out that there is a lesson to be learned,
that is, that the extent to which I have turned out to be correct may
be explained mainly by my attempt to work in a long-range perspective.
Thus, it might be profitable and in the public interest for economists
in the public service, and others, to examine more carefully than they
have thus far done what I have made available to the Joint Economic
Committee practically year by year during the past 8 years.
Outline of my presentation
I shall deal specifically with the following:
I. The problem of optimum economic growth.
II. The problem of economic equilibrium or balance.
III. The problem of social equilibrium, or plain justice.
IV. Fiscal policy.
V. The problem of inflation.
VI. Problems of monetary policy.
VII. The international economy.
VIII. The Economic Report of the President.
IX. Summary of my own recommendations.
In dealing with the first seven of these nine topics, I shall in each
instance state first my own analyses and conclusions (responsive,
naturally, to my examination of the CEA annual report), and then
discuss those portions of the CEA report which seem to me most
relevant.
I. THE PROBLEM OF OPTIMD~t ECONOMIC GROWTH
The growth record and the growth need in detail
During 1960-68, the average annual rate of U.S. economic growth
was 4.8 percent in real terms, a marvelous record when compared with
the 2.4-percent average rate during 1953-60. Nonetheless, the evidence
is strong that this performance was somewhat short of the optimum,
particularly when one considers the historic record; the identity of
optimum economic growth with optimum resource use; the current
level of unemployment, and more essentially its distribution; the im-
perative nature of our unmet domestic needs; and the scope and weight
of our international obligations.
Turning first to historical review: Our average annual rate of real
economic growth was 4.7 percent during 1922-29, 4.5 percent during
1947-50, 5.1 percent during 1950-53, 5.1 percent during 1960-66, 4.8
percent during 1960-68, and 5 percent from 1967 to 1968. I should
mention at this point, although I will deal with the inflationary prob-
lem in detail later on, that the periods 1922-29 and 1960-66 were char-
acterized by a quite satisfactory degree of price stability, and that the
price inflation during a portion of the period 1950-53 was mainly a
speculative reaction to the Chinese intervention in the Korean war,
and was not due to an excessive rate of economic growth. All this ap-
pears to support my conclusion that the 4.8-percent average annual rate
of real economic growth during 1960-68 was somewhat on the low side.
In view of technological trends, the unsolved unemployment problem,
and the pressures of our domestic and international needs, I believe
that we should aim toward a real rate of economic growth averaging
PAGENO="0044"
1004
at least 5 percent annually from 1970 to 1977, and averaging about 6
percent during 1968-70, toward restoration of optimum resource use.
The "longest upward movement on record," and the economic outlook
More important still, the 4.8 percent average annual rate of real
economic growth during 1960-68 is not indicative of the most recent
trends, nor of the economic outlook. From 1966 to 1967, the real rate of
economic growth fell to only 2.5 percent, and the average for the 2
years 1966-68 was only 3.7 percent. Taking into account current in-
formed forecasts, and the purpose of recent and current economic poli-
cies to "slow down" the economy further, there is strong evidence that
we may be reverting to the recurrent periods of economic stagnation,
if not absolute recession, to which I commenced to call attention so
insistently from 1953 forward. It is remarkable and indicative that this
possibility has thus far received so little attention.1
Actually, the insistent chorus about "the longest upward movement
on record," from early 1961 to date, has been both misleading and
overly prideful. The recovery movement from early 1961 until circa
the massive tax reductions of 1964 was not the result of important
positive cha.nges in national economic policies. It was more or less a
normal or autonomous recovery after the mini-recession of late 1960,
early 1961, and continuation of the recovery from the substantial re-
cession of 1957-58. This movement from 1901 forward was hardly
more impressive than the upward movements which had followed the
periods of stagnation and then recession during the years 1953-60,
and it was recognition of this lack of impressiveness that finally
prompted the massive tax reduction in 1964.
These massive tax reductions provided a very strong stimulus to the
economy for less than 2 years, but even that amount of money thrown
into the streets and scrambled for would have done that. Because these
tax actions represented a basically erroneous analysis of the entire
problem of economic equilibrium or balance (as I insisted at the time
of their enactment, and as I shall discuss further when I come to the
matter of fiscal policy), the real rate of economic growth turned very
sharply downward early in 1966 and has averaged far too low during
1966-68. Moreover, I believe the developments during 1966-68 would
have been far more unfavorable, and might well have carried us into
an absolute recession, but for the unexpected acceleration of defense
spending due to the Vietnam war and some other factors. After all,
measured in current dollars, national defense spending rose from $50.0
billion in 1964 and $50.1 billion in 1965 to $60.6 billion in 1966, $72.4
billion in 1967, and $78.9 billion in 1968 (calendar years). There is no
particular trick in maintaining an upward movement, albeit at a
declining real rate of growth, in the presence of these kinds of iumps
in defense spending. Those who are still chuckling about their role in
promoting "the longest upward movement on record" should have it
recalled to their attention that we have also had "the longest war on
record."
Regardless of the merits or demerits of that war, these most recent
developments appear to have justified my earlier findings that a more
rapid expansion of Federal spending than earlier had been projected
1 See chart 1, following text.
PAGENO="0045"
1005
would be essential to maintenance of an adequate rate of real economic
growth. The lesson to be learned from this, which has not yet been
learned, is that we should contemplate large increases in domestic
spending for priority needs during the years immediately ahead, and
further that these increases should be much greater than any reductions
which may result from a change in the international situation, or from
our reactions to it.
Productivity trends, and their significance
Careful examination of productivity trends more than support my
findings as to the needed rate of real economic growth, in order to ab-
sorb the annual increments in our productive capabilities under con-
ditions of reasonably full resource use. Over the decades, under the
impact of advancing tecimology, inventiveness and innovation, rising
labor skills, improved management, and more `effective public policies,
tlie average annual rate of productivity growth in the U.S. private
economy has tended to accelerate greatly, except when inhibited by
the repressive influence of inadequate demand and low real economic
growth. Thus, the average annual rate of productivity growth in the
U.S. private economy was 0.4 percent during 1910-20, 2.3-2.4 percent
during 1920-40, and 3.2 percent during 1940-55. (It was 4.0 percent
during 1947-53). It fell to a 2.4 percent during 1955-60, when the real
rate of economic growth was very low and punctuated by two absolute
recessions. But during 1960-66, the average annual rate of productivity
growth rose to 3.7 percent. And it averaged 3.5 percent during the full
8-year period 1960-68, even though it averaged only 2.4 percent during
1966-68, when the real rate of economic growth averaged the unaccept-
ably low level of only 3.7 percent. The only reason why the very low
economic growth rate during 1966-68 did not increase unemployment
was that underutilization in the plant, resulting in much lower pro-
ductivity, was preferred to more overt unemployment. These two dis-
mal alternatives are not acceptable, nor could they be available en-
duringly even if acceptable. This leads me to the conclusion that the
productivity growth-rate potential in the U.S. private economy dur-
ing the years ahead cannot possibly be less than in the neighborhood
of 4.0 percent and may be considerbaly higher, under conditions of
optimum resource use. Even `allowing for a lower productivity growth
rate in the public sector (not yet subjected to enough analysis to verify
this common assumption), it appears that the productivity growth
rate potential in the total U.S. economy for the years ahead must be
in the neighborhood of 3.5 percent, or even higher. Adding to this the
projected growth in the civilian labor force under conditions of maxi-
mum employment, about 1.5 percent, the optimum overall U.S. eco-
nomic growth rate during the years ahead cannot be less than 5 percent,
after restoration of reasonably full resource use, and might even be
considerably higher.2
Bearing of rate of economic growth upon employment and unemploy-
ment
There are even more important reasons for striving to restore and
maintain optimum economic growth than those set forth above. Never
during recent years have we come close to reasonably full utilization
2 See chart 2, following text.
PAGENO="0046"
1006
of our basic productive capacities. In 1968 and on into 1969, many if
not a majority of our key industries were operating at capacity levels
well below the optimum.
Although officially recorded unemployment averaged only 3.6 per-
cent in 1968 (not far from the 3.8 percent in both 1966 and 1967), the
true level of unemployment in 1968 (taking into account the full-time
equivalent of part-time unemployment, and the concealed unemploy-
ment resulting from those not participating in the civilian labor force
because of scarcity of job opportunity and therefore not counted as
unemployed) was in the neighborhood, as I estimated it, of 4.2 per-
cent or higher. Moreover, as we all know, unemployment has tended to
be two to three times as high among teenagers and Negroes as the na-
tionwide average, and has remained as high as 30-40 percent in some
critical sectors of some urban areas. We simply cannot afford to
tolerate the urban consequences already revealed, nor those in the off-
ing, which stem so largely from this amount of unemployment.
One of the most striking illustrations of poor economic analysis is
the viewpoint expressed by many economists, and at least intimated by
the CEA, that the average level of unemployment is not now too high
(or may even be too low from the viewpoint of combating inflation),
and that the excessively high level of employment among vulnerable
groups is a "structural" problem rather than a problem of aggregate
demand or overall economic growth. They therefore conclude (as does
the CEA 1969 report) that this structural problem should be dealt
with by measures which do not aim at a more rapid expansion of ag-
gregate demand or a more rapid rate of economic growth.
The use of the word "structural" may be valid in explaining that
the unemployed are unemployed because of an improper fit between
them and existing jobs, and that programs of training and other forms
of adaptation are needed (even though that explanation is seriously
overworked). Be that as it may, how can the level of excessive unem-
ployment among the vulnerable groups be reduced, without reducing
the nationwide average level of unemployment, unless the reduction
of unemployment among the vulnerable groups is to be accomplished
by more unemployment among others? Further, whatever may be the
reasons why an unemployed person is unemployed, and even if it were
to be assumed that there is a "job vacancy" awaiting for him if he
were more fit, it still remains true that a job vacancy is not a job. A
job vacancy involves no expenditure, while the putting of an unem-
ployed person into a job involves an expenditure sometimes estimated
in the nature of $15,000.
It follows that putting a million people (I take this figure arbi-
trarily, merely by way of example) who are now unemployed into
jobs would involve additional outlays in the neighborhood of $15 bil-
lion, which means an increase of that size in aggregate demand, and
correspondingly means a considerably higher rate of economic growth
in real terms. There is absolutely no merit in the proposition that un-
employment can be reduced to acceptable levels, without expediting
the rate of real economic growth. Those who ignore this fact are curi-
ously inconsistent when they argue that slowing down the rate of
real economic growth to combat inflation would result in more un-
employment.
PAGENO="0047"
1007
Targeting economic growth through 1967, and its significance
The vital importance of an optimum rate of economic growth is in-
dicated by estimating, for the 10-year period 1968-77 inclusive, the
difference between an optimum rate of real economic growth (some-
where in the neighborhood of 5.3 percent as an annual average, and a
3.5 percent average annual rate of economic growth (cf. the rate of
3.7 percent during 1966-68). The difference, measured in fiscal year
1969 dollars (as estimated in January 1969, and for the purpose of
approximating the current price level) comes to $1,255 billion over the
10-year period, or an average of about $125 billion a year, and comes to
$226 billion in 1977 alone. Surely, we cannot afford to forfeit these
amounts in terms of real goods and services, or anything even approxi-
mating them, when we consider the tasks that confront us, and how far
we are from doing more than scratching the surface with respect to
many of them.3
My next two charts depict in more detail my optimum high and low
economic growth projections through 1967, and also indicate how well
they maintain the traditional balance between private and public
responsibilities.4
The erroneous views of the CEA on economic growth
I turn now to what the 1969 CEA report says on the subject of eco-
nomic growth, bearing in mind that what it now says is quite con-
sistent with the position it has been taking in earlier years. What the
CEA now says indicates why I have felt it necessaary to develop this
phase of my analysis so extensively, and perhaps may convince many
others as to the validity of my conclusions.
The 1969 CEA report states that the increase in the U.S. growth rate
potential was at an average annual rate of about 3.5 percent from the
mid-1950's to the early 1960's; that for the last few years it is esti-
mated at 4 percent a year; that it was 4 percent from fourth quarter
:1967 to second quarter 1968; and that it was 4 percent at the end of 1968.
The CEA therefore concludes that this is the growth potential for the
years shortly ahead (pp. 40,45,64, 66).
The CEA bases this finding upon the observation that, since 1950,
the annual growth rate of productivity in the private economy was
3 percent, and for the entire economy 2.5 percent, and that adding to
this a 1.5 percent annual growth in the civilian labor force results in the
4 percent figure (p. 66).
I find it utterly impossible to find any justification for this CEA
finding, in view of the productivity trends which I have depicted (con-
sistent with data appearing in CEA reports). The CEA average of
productivity trends since 1950 is the result of very different produc-
tivity trends during periods of rewarding economic growth, economic
stagnation, and economic recession. Such an average figure would be
ncceptable only if the goals for the future were to contemplate recur-
rence of these same three types of periods. Such an average has nothing
whatsoever to do with the growth potential, nor with sustained maxi-
mum production and employment under the mandate of the Employ-
ment Act of 1946. And such a finding by the CEA appears even more
outlandish, when the CEA itself admits that only a serious departure
~ See chart 3, following text.
~ See charts 4 and 5, following text.
PAGENO="0048"
1008
from optimum growth reduces the productivity performance to levels
consistent with the 3-percent average in the long run. Thus, the Coun-
cil finds: "In early 1967 the diminishing pace of the expansion was
reflected in a slowing of productivity growth rather than a sharp rise
in unemployment" (p. 34).
The CEA does even worse than this. It does not set a target for real
economic growth during 1969 even at this improperly low 4-percent
figure. Whether interpreted as a goal or as a welcome forecast, the
CEA says: "The rise in real output during the four quarters of 1969
should be less than 3 percent," consistent with a 6-percent rise in price
terms (p. 56).
Why does the CEA want us to move in this direction? Its answer is
made clear: "Although economic expansion is expected to moderate
during the first half of 1969, a continuing policy of restraints is essen-
tial to curb inflationary pressures and to strengthen our internationa.]
trade performance" (p. 53). My comments as to the quality of the
finding that we should further reduce the rate of economic growth as
a "promising" way of containing inflation will come later. My other
comment comes now: It is, in my view, frightening that we should be
willing to forfeit what will be forfeited by bringing the real rate of
economic growth so low, risk the unemployment which will result, risk
the recession which may result, and starve our domestic priorities to
the extent built into the achievement of this objective, meanwhile
regarding the problematical strengthening of our international trade
performance as a gain comparable to this forfeiture.
II. THE PROBLEM OF ECONOMIC EQUILIBRIUM OR BALANCE
Essentials of economic equilibrium or balance
No economist of substance would deny that maintaining an optimum
rate of economic growth, and maintaining optimum employment con-
sistent with minimal or frictional unemplyoment, depend essentially
upon an econornicequilibrium or balance in the allocation of the current
or functioning GNP between (a) the investment which adds to our
capabilities to produce and (b) ultimate consumption in the form of
private consumer spending and public outlays combined. Yet there
has never been a time when the "New Economists" or the CEA reports
have offered tangible and substantial quantitative evidence of comino
to grips with this analytical problem, or of adjusting policies an~
programs accordingly. This has been an oversight so glaring that I
have been unable to offer a rational explanation for it.
The closest that the CEA has come to any such attempt was whei1 it
suggested, some years back, that optimum economic growth depended
upon a much hig'her permanent ratio of investment in plant and equip-
ment to GNP. However, as I have frequently pointed out, (a) a
sustainable ratio of such mvestment to GNP depends upon the pro-
ductivity of capital (which is advancing), not upon the overall growth
rate targeted, and (b) the record since 1952 has uniformly shown a
strong tendency toward relative overinvestment of this type, corrected
only when "overcapacity" leads to sharp cutbacks in such investment,
with unfavorable consequences throughout the economy.
The empirical evidence, detailed in my repeated public studies from
1953 forward, has made it very clear that the transition from moder-
PAGENO="0049"
1009
ately adequate though not optimum economic growth to stagnation
and then recession occurred when the failure of ultimate demand as I
have defined it (or, even more pertinently, the private incomes and
public spending which underlie ultimate demand) to keep up with the
investment in plant equipment which is primarily responsible for our
increasing capabilities to produce became abundantly visible.
From the time of the advent of the "New Economics" in early 1961,
I continued my studies along these same lines. Well before 1966, I
pointed out that the same type of disequilibrium augured the very
sharply reduced average annual rate of real economic growth during
1966-68. In fact, my opposition to the massive tax reductions of 1964
and some subsequent tax concessions was based upon the proposition
that, while these would stimulate the economy for a time, they were in
the longer-run so enormously misdirected that they would bring on
another period of serious economic stagnation, and increase infla-
tionary manifestations to boot.
It is true that the "New Economists" and the CEA reports at times,
but almost entirely as a matter of hindsight, observed that investment
in plan and equipment was advancing relatively too rapidly to be
sustainable, and advocated such measures as the suspension of the
investment tax credit. But later on they advocated its reinstitution,
and I could never understand why, because this contributed further to
the economic disequilibrium. I shall deal further in detail with these
tax or fiscal policies later on in my statement.
Factual anatomy of the economic disequilibrium
An examination of relative trends in various key sectors of the
economy illustrates rather dramatically how the economic disequilib-
rium made itself manifest, and indeed was aggravated by key policies
and programs. From 1961 to 1968, measured in constant dollars, total
national production grew 42.2 percent, private consumer spending
grew 39.6 percent, and government outlays for goods and services
at all levels grew 50.1 percent.
Private business investment (including net foreign) grew 42.3 per-
cent, but this reflected home construction on the average far below
our priority needs. Private investment in plant and equipment, and
this is the indicative figure, grew 65.7 percent. The disequilibrium
in income flows was roughly compatible. Wages and salaries grew
45.5 percent, total labor income including fringe benefits grew 51.2
percent, and farm proprietor net income grew only 3.1 percent, while
corporate profits and investory value adjustment grew 55.4 percent,
personal dividend income grew 58 percent, and personal interest in-
come grew 84.9 percent.
The rampant profit inflation
It is equally important to look at the trends during 1967-68 alone.
First, of all, the disparities indicated in the previous paragraph were
even greater during 1961-67, but were "corrected" somewhat by what
happened from 1967 to 1968. But what were the nature of these correc-
tions? The main correction was that private investment in plant and
equipment shrunk to an annual growth rate of only 1.0 percent. That
is far too low. However, this happened just because of the disequilib-
rium created by the relatively excessive advance of this type of invest-
ment for a number of years. This is one of the most striking illustra-
24-833-69-pt. 4-4
PAGENO="0050"
1010
tions of the entire equilibrium thesis which I have set forth for so
many years, and restated in earlier portions of my discussion above.
Moreover, and again in substantiation of my basic thesis, this private
investment in plant and equipment did not turn down so sharply
during 1967-68 because of any general inadequacy of profits or other
investment funds. It turned down because relatively excessive profits
in earlier years contributed powerfully to the various disequilibrium
which brought about the sharp investment reaction during 1967-68.
Equally or even more seriously, the relatively excessive and dis-
equilibrating profit binge continued on into 1968, and so did the price
increases which fed them, despite the ominous warning signal in the
sharp downturn in private investment in plant and equipment. During
1967-68, measured in constant dollars, while wages and salaries grew
only 5.6 percent, labor income only 6.5 percent, and farm proprietors'
income only 1.4 percent, corporate profits and inventory adjustment
grew 7.1 percent, or considerably more rapidly than the average an-
nual rate of advance (allowing for compounding) during the 7-year
period 1961-68 as a whole.5
In short, the disturbing inflationary trends during 1967 and 1968
have been very clear demonstrations of profit inflation. This is one of
the most dangerous and disequilibrating kinds of inflation. One must be
deeply concerned that this whole matter has been so completely disre-
garded in the 1969 CEA report, and equally so in the whole range of
policies which emerge from the highly defective CEA analysis. In-
stead, the CEA urges that real hourly wage rate increases be held to
2.0 percent during 1969.
To reinforce this profit point by returning to the 1961-68 analysis
in another aspect: From 1960 to 1968 (measured in current dollars,
which is satisfactory for the purpose), prices in tota.l manufacturing
rose 7.5 percent, contributing to an advance of 111.6 percent in profits
after taxes. Reflecting in part the profit yield, investment in plant and
equipment grew 84.9 percent, but wage rates grew only 33.1 percent.
In motor vehicles and equipment, prices rose 3.8 percent, profits after
taxes 89.4 percent, investment in plant and equipment 71.9 percent,
and wage rates only 34.4 percent. In three other key industries shown
on the same chart, the respective trends told essentially the same story.
My utilization of wage rates rather than aggregate wage payments in
this exercise appears to me to be justified for a variety of technical
reasons which I shall not cover at this point, although much light is
shed upon this problem by my subsequent discussion of the compara-
tive trends in productivity and hourly wage rates.6
GEA `neg7ect of econontio equilibriu~m prob~em
The poverty of economic analysis displayed by the CEA throughout
the years, with respect to the whole issue of economic equilibrium, is
genuinely distressing. Considering the resources available to the
Council and the importance of the problem, and the rich experience
made manifest in the performance of the American economy under
widely different sets of circumstances, one would have thought that
by now the CEA would have developed and made available a thorough
See chart 6, following text.
See chart 7, following text.
PAGENO="0051"
1011
and discerning study of this whole problem of economic equilibrium.
My own view is that, by now, they should have had a 50-page chapter
in one of their annual reports on this subject.
But only pages 70 to 74 are devoted to the "Problem of Economic
Fluctuations" in the 1969 CEA report. The quality and depth of what
is said is revealing indeed. We learn this:
"Sudden changes in Federal spending have, on occasion, seriously
disrupted the stability of the economy" (p. 71).
"Consumer outlays normally follow the path of household incomes
fairly closely" (p. 71). This statement is so bland that it masks some
of the most serious problems in the whole area of economic equilibrium.
Variations in the rate of saving, at any given level of aggregate con-
sumer incomes after taxes, are profoundly important. Why and how
have these variations occurred? The ratio of aggregate personal saving
to aggregate personal income after taxes is profoundly affected by
income distribution. What is the significance of this, in the actual
context of what has been happening to the economy during the past 8
years?
"But fluctuations in capital spending have often been important
sources of instability. For example, real investment (constant prices)
rose by 42 percent between 1963 and 1966, contributing to a strong
expansion of aggregate demand, but this leveled out in 1967" (p. 71).
This is true, but what conclusion does the CEA draw from it? I pointed
out in 1963 (not in 1969) that the proposed tax reductions would have
just this unfortunate result by way of disturbing further the economic
equilibrium. Is the CEA now prepared to reappraise its fiscal policies,
or does it continue to extoll them, except to the extent of claiming that
the Congress prevented action as promptly as it otherwise would have
been undertaken?
III. THE PROBLEM OF SOCIAL EQUILIBRIUM, OR PLAIN JUSTICE
Identity of economic and socia' objectives in the United States
Even if the policies and programs of the "new economics" in general,
and of the CEA in particular, had not been erroneous during the past
8 years with respect to the restoration and maintenance of economic
e~uilibrium or balance, they were certainly highly vulnerable from the
viewpoint of social equilibrium, or plain justice.
It is conceivable, in some economies, that social justice must tempo-
rarily be sacrificed in the short run, in the interest of economic develop-
mnent and growth, narrowly conceived. That may be true of an under-
developed country, such as India. But it is not true of an economy
so highly developed and richly endowed as our own. If called for, even
some sacrifice of optimum economic growth would be justified in the
cause of social equilibrium, in that we are a wealthy enough economy
to afford to do justice and~as we have recently learned `at great cost~-
too sensitive `a body politic to afford to do without it.
But the case is even `stronger than this. In line with the economic
analysis set forth above, the failure to achieve or maintain economic
equilibrium at optimum resource use and optimum economic growth
has been inextricably interwoven with the failure to achieve an im-
proved allocation of income flows `and human `employments in terms
of the criteria of social equilibrium, or plain justice. It is one of our
essential `assets as `a nation `and `a people, and we should exploit it to
PAGENO="0052"
1012
the hilt, that economic progress and social progress call essentially for
the same policies and programs.
More consumption relative to investment would have been, and still
would be, more conducive to both types of equilibrium. Better income
distribution would enlarge the propensity to consume. Lifting the
poor to at least minimum-decency standards of consumption and living
would open up additional markets for the products of our factories:
and our farms. More rapid expansion of public-priority services in
the fields of health, education, and housing, and some others, would
not only serve the cause of social justice and make deep inroads upon
poverty, but would also improve productivity, open up new job op-
portunities, and augment a more healthful and sustainable rate of
economic growth than we have recently experienced. All of these pro-
positions are so close to universally accepted, and so explicit even in.
the pronouncements at times of the "New Economics" and of the CEA,.
that the question naturally arises as to why these pronouncements have
not been translated into more effective action.
Poverty and income maldi~tribution
The pertinent facts are brutally clear. In 1967, 5.3 million American
multiple-person families and 4.9 million unattached individuals lived~
in absolute and dismal poverty, even according to the low poverty-~
income ceilings officially set by the Social Security Administration in
the Department of Health, Education, and Welfare. The total num-
ber of people living in abject poverty in 1967 aggregated somewhere
in the neighborhood of 26 million people, or about 13.5 percent of the
total population in that year.
In addition, about 11.0 million families and about 2.4 million unat-
tached individuals, coming to about 35.4 million people lived above
the officially established poverty-income ceilings, but in deprivation
nevertheless. Therefore, in the neighborhood of 61.4 million people, or
not very far from one-third of the Nation in 1967, lived either in pov-
erty or deprivation. It is noteworthy, in this connection, that the Bu-
reau of Labor Statistics in the U.S. Department of Labor indicated in
1967 that somewhere in the neighborhood of $9,000 for a four-person
family and about $3,400 for an unattached individual would be re-
quired to maintain a moderate standard of living in metropolitan
areas.7
Even though all empirical evidence proves conclusively that opti-
mum economic growth and reasonably full employment are by far
the most important avenues toward the liquidation of poverty, it
hardly seems conceivable that substantial redistribution programs are
not also essential. They would be essential in any event, because the
concept of poverty is and should be in part a relative concept, which
cannot be blind to the state of the industrial arts and the general
income situation throughout the Nation. It is thus of high import that
we have thus far made very little progress toward improved income
distribution since World War II. Among multiple-person families
in 1947, the top income fifth enjoyed 43 percent of the total money
income of families, while the lowest fifth obtamed only 5 percent. the
lowest two-fifths only 17 percent, and the lower three-fifths only 34
percent. In 1966, the top fifth enjoyed 41 percent, while the lowest:
7See chart 8, following text.
PAGENO="0053"
1013
fifth obtained oniy 5 percent, the lowest two-fifths oniy 17 percent,
and the lower three-fifths only 35 percent. Among unattached individ-
uals in 1947, the highest fifth enjoyed 59 percent, while the lowest
fifth obtained only three percent, the lowest two-fifths only 8 percent,
and the lower three-fifths only 20 percent. in 1966, the respective
figures were 52 percent, 3 percent, 11 percent, and 24 percent.8
Social equilibrium involves the public sector
Adequate programs in the public sector are equally relevant to any
meaningful war against poverty, and indeed to the life and living of
the preponderant portion of the total population. And it is here that
the trends in public expenditures at the Federal level become so dis-
thrbing. During the fiscal years 1947-1953, Federal spending for all
domestic programs came to 6.92 percent of GNP (despite the Korean
ivar during 3 years of this period), while during the fiscal years 1954-
1968, these domestic programs came to only 5.64 percent of C-NP. The
figure of 6.10 percent in fiscal 1968 compared with 8.17 percent in
fiscal 1947 and 6.13 percent as late as fiscal 1959. There. is no legitimate
explanation of these domestic-spending trends in trends in defense
and other international spending, for total Federal spending declined
from 16.52 percent of C-NP during fiscal 1947-1953 to 16.23 percent
during fiscal 1954-1968.
With respect to fiscal 1969, the President's Budget initially pro-
]ec.ted total domestic spending at 10.91 percent of C-NP. But this fig-
ure cannot validly be contrasted with the ratios for the earlier years.
Beginning with fiscal 1969, the Federal Budget included immense
trust funds, which in the main are not supported by Federal outlays
(for example, the payroll taxes under the social security program).
The relative starvation of the public sector must also be taken into
account, toward realization that a meaningful definition of poverty
in America must go far beyond the 13 percent or less of the people of
the United States who are below poverty-income ceilings as of now
in 1969. At least one-sixth of our people are ill-housed. At least one-
*third cannot afford adequate and modern medical care. Perhaps 90
percent of the children in our public schools go to schools where the
teachers and para-professionals are grossly inadequate in number and
still grossly underpaid; and perhaps a majority are in overcrowded
classrooms, a large portion of which are either fire-traps or in other
respects unsafe. As the public schools are increasingly becoming the
habitation of the poor and deprived, a very large portion of those
ivho go to these schools-are drop out-go home to parents who live
in slums, do not enjoy an American minimum decency standard of in-
come, suffer excessively high unemployment, and altogether too fre-
quently are alienated and restive, if not rebellious. Many of our trans-
portation systems are obsolete. Air and water remains poisoned, with
at least the air getting worse. Our central cities are deteriorating if
not already decayed, and are increasingly unable to meet the rising
costs of education, police and fire protection, and other essential pub-
lic services.
In its most recent issue, Fortune magazine, a distinguished business
publication, contained a vivid article reiterating what so many other
individuals, research organizations, and special commissions have been
S See chart 9, following text.
PAGENO="0054"
1014
saying now for so many years-that we can afford to rescue and restore
the public sector, and cannot dare to do less.
GEA position on poverty: talk versus action
The current CEA report sets forth succinctly a quite good outline
of approach to the problem of poverty. It sets forth a strategy in-
cluding sustained high employment and economic growth; education,
training, medical assistance, and access to well-paying jobs; some
form of income maintenance for those not within the employment
stream; and attacks upon poverty pockets in the ghettos and certain
rural areas. The CEA further states that "the number of poor in
poverty pockets ca.n be reduced by promoting public and private'
relocation assistance to those with employment opportunities else-
where" (p. 155).
Elsewhere in the same chapter, the CEA points out that a small
redistribution of the benefits of growth would greatly speed reduction
of poverty (p. 160); that the tax system itself redistributes income
away from the poor (p. 160); that minimum welfare benefits should
be established, financed wholly by the Federal Government (p. 167)
and that there should be guaranteed work programs (p. 171).
All this sounds fine, but where are the quantified and specific pro-
grams needed to carry forward along these lines? How can benefits
of growth be redistributed in favor of the poor by the tax policies and
interest-rate policies during recent years, advocated or approved by
the CEA, which have redistributed income in a very regressive direc-
tion? How can guaranteed work, which implies full employment by
direct Government action if that is the only way to achieve it, be
squared with reluctant insistence that perhaps the current level of
employment needs to be increased somewhat to fight inflation?
How can the degree of population relocation which may be required
be undertaken, without penetrated quantitative analysis of what kind
of relocation should take place, how people are going to get there, and
who is going to finance the costs of such relocation, including not
only the transportation costs and the housing costs, but also the needed
shifts in industry? How can this new awakening to the problem of
relocation he squared with farm policies and other policies which,
during the past 8 years, have "relocated" millions of farm families
to urban areas, where they have contributed so mightily to relief costs,.
unemployment, urban decay, and urban unrest?
The sad fact of the matter is that CEA has not come to realization
that the achievement of social equilibrium through a full-scale war
against poverty is not a side issue to be treated superficially in one
chapter of a CEA report. It must instead interpenetrate with the
whole process of the development of a long-range social and economic
budget for the Nation, and the adjustment of all basic economic
policies thereto, something which the CEA has never attempted.
The inclusion within the current document of the report to the
President from the Cabinet Coordinating Committee on Economic
Planning for the End of Vietnam Hostilities (pp. 181-220) under-
scores two shortcomings. The first is failure to recognize that planning
must be a continuing process, and that the work and the responsibility
of the CEA with respect to so vast a.n issue cannot be done separately
and apart from the work of a Cabinet Coordinating Committee. The
PAGENO="0055"
1015
second defect is failure to recognize that we will not move suddenly
from a state of high defense expenditures to a state of low defense
expenditures, but instead will move very gradually.
The problems of poverty and social disequilibrium, inseparably
connected, as well as the problem of economic disequilibrium, cannot
wait until the Vietnam hostilities are over, or even beyond that to the
time when a truly peaceful world assures a lower level of total defense
outlays. Even now, there is some prospect of an antimissile defense
system, of incalcuabie but huge costs. The war against poverty and
social disequilibrium should have started long ago, it should start now,.
and it should be at the very heart of the study programs and recom-
mendations of the CEA, because it is at the very heart of our total
economic problem-not a year or 10 years from now, but now.
IV. Fiso~r, P0LTOY
1lIisd&ection of tax cuts to date
In all the plethora of detailed examination of national fiscal policy
during recent years, we have in large measure ignored examination
of the purposes and consequences of the fiscal policies, actually put
into motion. Consequently, the recent and current debate and concern
on the subject has arrived at a condition for which the term "im-
maturity~~ would be a charitable description.
By the test of economic equilibrium, for reasons already discussed,
the massive tax cuts of 1962-65, accompanied by earlier tax concessions
from 1962 forward, were fundamentally misdirected. Viewing tax cuts
having a total original value estimated at $19.2 billion-having a very
much higher value now, because of the great expanded tax base-$8.6
billion were allocated, according to my analysis, to investment pur-
poses, and only $10.6 billion were allocated to consumption purposes.
This was in no degree responsive to the economic developments between
1953 and 1962 or 1965 which gave rise to this veritable orgy of tax cut-
ting. Even if we were determined-as we should not have been-to
attempt the major stimulus to the economy in the form of tax cuts,
an entirely different composition would have been much more con-
ducive to economic equilibrium and optimum economic growth in the
long run, as well as to the restraint of inflation, than the tax cuts ac-
cordingly engineered. To illustrate, a very large portion of the tax
cuts should have been devoted to lifting the personal exemptions from
$600 to $1,200, or preferably to $1,800.~
Because of the importance of enlarging the propensity to consume,
the composition of the tax cuts was also highly undesirable from the
viewpoint of long-range economic equilibrium, not to mention the even
more important issue of social equilibrium and economic justice. The
1964 personal tax cuts added only 2 percent to the after-tax income of
the four-person family with $3,000 income; only 1.6 percent in the
case of $5,000 income; and only 2.1 percent in the case of $7,500 income.
But the same tax cuts added 3.8 percent in the case of $25,000 income;
6.2 percent in the case of $50,000 income; 8.3 percent in the case of
$100,000 income; and 16 percent in the case of the $200,000 income.
These comparisons are even more shocking when we take account of
the fact that they are based upon established tax rates, and take in-
See chart 10, following text.
PAGENO="0056"
1016
adequate account of evasions and loopholes available to so many
people in the high-income brackets.1°
Narrow view of scope of the total tax burden
But this is only the beginning of the travesty. Among all the "new
economists" including the CF~A membership who appeared before
the Joint Economic Committee to urge and applaud the changes in
the Federal tax structure which have actually occurred, hardly a one
of them had the breadth of perspective to focus upon the entire tax
structure throughout the Nation. rather than exclusively upon the
Federal tax structure. Yet a. first year course in economics should
have encouraged them to do just that.
In 1966, looking at all persons in all the income classes shown, those
with incomes under $3,000 paid only 3.7 percent of their incomes in
the form of Federal income taxes, and this percentage moved upward
to 14 percent in the case of t.hose with incomes from $15,000 to $19,999,
and to 33.6 percent in the case of those with incomes at $50,000 and
over. This gives the appearance of a quite progressive tax structure,
although again ignoring the fact that these comparisons are based
upon tax rates without adequate allowance for evasion, avoidance, and
loopholes. But looking at total taxes naid, including all Federal income
taxes, social security taxes. State and local income taxes, sales and
gasoline taxes, and personal property and real estate taxes, how differ-
ent the true Picture is. Those with incomes under $3,000 paid 14.1
percent of their incomes in total taxes. Those with incomes of $3,000
to S3~999 paid 19.3 percent. But those with incomes of $5~000 to $9,999
paid only 17.5 to 17.6 percent. Those with incomes of $15,000 to $19,999
paid 19.8 percent., or very little more (ratio concept) than those with
incomes of S3,000 to $3,999. Those with incomes of $20,000 to $49,999
paid 24.2 percent, and those with incomes of $50,000 and over paid
B8.8 percent. again looking only at the tax rates on the books. In the
main, this represents a. horribly unjust and inequitable nationwide
system of ta.xation.'~
The situation is worse now than it was in 1966, although compre-
hensive data are not available to me for the most recent years. The
regressive State and local taxes, and the sales taxes, have continued to
mount.. And when the time came for the Federal Government to lift
taxes in order, avowedly, "to fight inflation," the sound decision was
not made to lift taxes in accord with the same pattern which had
governed their previous reduction. Instead, a 10-percent across-the-
board "temporary" surcharge tax was imposed, which manifestly adds
to the regressive nature of the entire nationwide tax burden, or at
least is certainly not progressive.
The issue of "tax reform"
There is now a great deal of discussion about "reform" in the Federal
tax structure. Such discussion concentrates mainly upon plugging
loopholes which enable large numbers of very wealthy taxholders to
pay no taxes at all, or to pay only token taxes, or to pay distressingly
low taxes relative to those very much lower down in the income struc-
ture. Sometimes this proposa.l is coupled with the idea that there shall
10 See chart ii, following text.
~ See chart i2 following text.
PAGENO="0057"
1017
be a ceiling upon the taxes that anybody shall pay, relative to income-
say, 50 percent.
There is much merit in some aspects of these proposals, but nobody
has yet made clear whether the net impact of them would be to make
the total tax structure more or less progressive. iRelated to those who
really pay the tax rates as written on the books, instea.d of engaging
in avoidance or evasion, it would be a very good bargain for many to
consent magnanimously to the proposition that they should pay some
taxes in exchange for being assured that under no conceivable set of
conditions would they have to pay more than 50 percent of their
income in taxes.
As a matter of stark fact, I believe that the whole issue of tax reform
becomes confusing and misleading, when it is not recognized that the
major j oh of tax reform is to remedy the gross distortions in the Fed-
eral tax structure, both on economic equilibrium and social equilib-
riuin grounds, which have resulted solely from the misguided and
massive tax reductions during recent years, aggravated by the 10-
percent surcharge.
I submit that the most useful reform which could be made in the
Federal tax structure would be to lift the exemptions greatly, and to
restore the rates, at least in the high-income portions of the structures,
a good part of the way to where they were before 1964. The argument
that this paralyzed investment and initiative was mereticious from
the outset. The argument that the high marginal tax rates caused
people to try to evade taxes, by legitimate methods, was foolish from
the outset. Those who hired expensive lawyers and accountants to
get their taxes as low as possible when the marginal rate was 92
percent did not stop doing so when the marginal rate was reduced by
about 30 points.
Neglect of core purpose of the Federal budget
All of what I have thus far said only touches the outskirts of why
the massive tax reductions were so wrong, at. least from the viewpoint
of social equilibrium and plain social justice. The "new economists"
have claimed and propaganded that they have done a great service
in the improved use of national fiscal policy to stabilize the economy
and promote its real growth. But they have entirely forgotten the
real purpose of the Federal budget and of national economic policy,.
as made manifest by the Federal budget. The main purpose of the
Federal budget is neither to stabilize nor promote the growth of the
economy, although this would be a very useful byproduct if the
policies are more correctly devised than they have been thus far. The
main purpose of the Federal budget is to allocate to the public sector
enough expenditures to meet the great priorities of those public needs
which cannot be served, or cannot be served so well, in any other way.
If the only or main purpose were stabilization, we could simplify
matters grea.tly by having 10 or 15 billion dollars' worth of Federal
spending and no Federal taxation when we were threatened with
deflationary forces, and the reverse when we were threatened with
inflationary forces. But this would be forgetting what the Federal
budget is really for.
PAGENO="0058"
1018
Appropriate fiscal policies
The appropriate coures is to determine what portion of our resources,
through Federal spending, should be allocated to public purposes, both
domestic and international. This should be done on a long-range basis.
We should then allocate to these purposes, through the Federal budget,
such percentage of our potential total national product, estimated at
optimum resource use. If, in fact, this leads, in conjunction with all
other spending, to inflationary pressures in the form of excessive ag-
gregate demand, we should then not cut back on these priorities, but
instead increase taxes to curtail the extravagant, wasteful, or at least
expendable, instead of sacrificing the essential. Curtailment of Federal
spending to comba.t inflation negates the priority purposes of Federal
spending. If, on the other hand, t.he determined levels of public spend-
ing plus all over spending do not generate sufficient aggregate demand
to avoid deflationary trends, we should certainly not cut Federal spend-
ing on the ground that the revenues yielded by a deficiently perform-
ing economy are not sufficient to cover this Federal spending. Instead,
we should obviously reduce ta.xes. In short, all taxes are burdensome,
and practically no taxes have intrinsic value in themselves. It is the
tax, rather than the spending side of the Federal Budget, which should
serve the purposes of stabilization.
All this is so elementary that it is almost inconceivable that the
"new economists" and the CEA could have forgotten it. But they did
forget it, almost entirely, and so did their allies and protagonists in
the academic world. In 1964, they arrived at the miraculous conclu-
sion tha.t a lot of people would rather have their taxes reduced than to
witness increased Federal spending. An equal amount of action in
either direction would have had the same deficit impact upon the
Federal budget in the short run, although in the long run the spending
route would have increased revenues faster than an equivalent amount
of tax reduction because the former approach would have been sounder
from the viewpoint of economic equilibrium and growth. But having
arrived at the miraculous conclusion that tax reduction was "easier,"
these economists drew upon their full intellectual and propagandist
resources to argue that it really made no difference to the Nation and
the people which of the two routes were taken, or what blend of the
two routes were chosen, because the impact upon the economy would
he the same at any given dollar level of net action.
Never before in my recollection was there such forgetfulness of the
purpose for which a responsible Central Government exists, nor of
the purpose for which a. responsible CEA should exist. To be sure, it
was not foreseeable how much expenditures would increase for the
Vietnam war. But it was manifestly foreseeable that our international
burdens would remain immensely heavy, and perhaps even grow, for as
far ahead as we could foresee. It was not only foreseeable, but currently
apparent. that our great domestic priorities had been starved at least
since the beginning of the great depression, and that, at least since the
launching of the first sputnik in 1957. the urgency of the need to
allocate much larger absolute amounts of resources to the public sector,
if not larger relative amounts, had been recognized by almost all
responsible people and organizations everywhere.
To cap the climax of this farrago of national fiscal policy, the "new
economists" and the CEA were hoisted on their own petard from 1967
PAGENO="0059"
1019
forward. Having argued that it made no great difference whether we
reduced taxes or increased expenditures when the economy needed
stimulation, they were led to argue that it made no great difference
whether we reduced expenditures or increased taxes when it was felt
that the economy needed restraint. They even came to the point where
they were supinely accepting some of both medicine, which was almost
equivalent to the preposterous proposition that a tax increase would be
more acceptable if spending were reduced and the pressures on the
economy accordingly reduced than if spending were not reduced.
It will take us many years, at best, to work our way slowly and
painfully out of this hole into which the "New Economics" has so
proudly put us.
Increasing fiscal responsibilities of Federal Government
I have only one additional point to make in this phase of my dis-
cussion, but it is one that cannot be overlooked. Another reason why the
recent fiscal policies have been so inadequate is that they have failed
to recognize the inescapable increasing responsibility of the Federal
Government to meet a larger share of the burden of the cost of rescuing
our urban areas and making war against poverty. I can never under-
stand how my friend Walter Heller2 so ardent an advocate of massive
Federal tax-sharing with the States, thus evidencing the recognition
of what I have just stated, could have gone all out for the kind of
incontinent tax reduction which was sure to make the Federal Govern-
*ment have so much less to share.
From 1947 to 1967 (fiscal years), Federal spending increased at an
average annual rate of 6.1 percent, while State spending increased at an
average annual rate of 9.1 percent, and local spending at an average
annual rate of 8.9 percent. During 1953-61, the respective average an-
nual rates of advance were 3.4 percent, 9 percent, and 9.1 percent. From
1961 to 1967 the respective average annual rates of advance were 8
percent, 8.2 percent, and 6.5 percent.
From 1947 to 1967, the average annual increase in the public debt
was 1.1 percent for the Federal Government, 12.6 percent for State
governments, and 9.1 percent for local governments. From 1961 to
1967, the respective average annual rates of advance were 2 percent,
8.4 percent, and 6.9 percent.12
Coupling these trends with the extremely regressive nature of State
and local taxation, and the relatively greater impact of tight money
and rising interest rates upon the State and local governments in view
of the immensely greater percentage increases in their necessary `bor-
rowings than in the case of the Federal Government, the full con-
sequence of recent Federal fiscal policies are clearly revealed.
A model Federal Budget, responsive to needs and capabilities
At an earlier stage in my discussion, I set forth projections for
gross national product aFid its components running ahead to 1977. A
Federal budget showing trends compatible with its responsibility for
economic and social equilibrium is an indispensible element toward
achieving these goals. My next chart sets forth a model for such a
Federal budget. It indicates that outlays for all domestic programs
should rise from 10.91 percent of GNP, as estimated for fiscal year
See chart 13, following text.
PAGENO="0060"
1020
1969, to 13.32 percent in calendar 1977; that expenditures for the
economic opportunity program or its equivalent should rise from 0.23
percent to 0.39 percent of GNP and from $9.86 on a nationwide per
capita basis to $24.04 (measured in fiscal year 1969 dollars); that
outlays for housing and community development should rise from
0.32 percent to 0.64 percent of GNP and from $13.72 to $39.34 on
a per capita basis; that outlays for education should rise from 0.53
percent to 2.36 percent of GNP, and from $23.16 to $143.79 on a per
capita basis; that outlays for health services and research should rise
from 1.21 percent to 1.43 percent of GNP, and from $52.51 to $87.41
on a per capita basis; that outlays for public assistance and labor
manpower and other welfare services should rise from 0.69 percent
to 1.08 percent of GNP and from $30.95 to $66.00 on a per capita.
basis; and that outlays for agriculture and natural resources should.
rise from 0.91 percent to 1.11 percent of G-NP, and from $39.91 to
$67.75 on a per capita basis. These goals include Federal contributions
of $1 billion in 1970 and more than $2 billion in 1977 to the
OASDHI to help increase benefit payments to the aged. This tableau
provides, if it should be needed, an increase from $89.5 billion to
$94 billion for national defense, space technology, and all inter-
national, but this would involve a decrease from 10.11 percent to 6.73
percent of GNP, and from $441.18 to $410.84 on a per capit.a basis.
Yet, in an adequately expanding economy, all Federal budget outlays,
while increasing from $917.01 to $1,223.77 on a per capita basis, would
actually decline from 21.02 percent to 20.06 percent of GNP.'3
With this feasible degree of dedication to do what we ought to do
and cannot afford to do without, we could by 1977 virtually liquidate
poverty in the United States; 14 provide a decent home for every Ameri-
can family (which we have promised since 1939) ; achieve lmnirnuln
standards of uniform excellence in our public schools throughout. the
Nation; and bring adequate health services, at costs within their means,
to all of our people. The projections for all domestic programs cover
also our transportation needs. The projections for agriculture and
natural resources contemplate that we reverse the trend-a. trend
against which I have been protesting for 16 years or longer-toward
the impoverishment of our farm population and the abysmal neglect
of rural life and living standards, toward malnutrition and hunger
among millions of our people despite indescribably abundant agricul-
tural production, and toward the forced movement of millions of farm
families t.oward our great urban areas, where t.hey have contributed.
and contributed disproportionately, to unemployment, relief costs,
overcrowded housing, urban decay, and urban unrest.
In fact, the failure of the CEA, in its preoccupation with fiscal
policy, and erroneous fiscal policy at that, to give adequate attention
as mandated by the Employment Act of 1946 to the other great areas
of major economic policy, such as farm policy, social security policy,
housing policy, and internationally economic policies, has been a signa.l
aspect of the CEA failure to view our economy in a sufficiently broad
and long-range perspective, and to develop an integrated policy and
program in lieu of a spawling proliferation of policies and programs
~` See chart 14, following text.
14 See again chart 8, following text.
PAGENO="0061"
1021
ivhich already have become almost too numerous to count and too corn-
~plex to harmonize.
CEA `views on fiscal policy
The current CEA report reaches the conclusion that fiscal policy
on the whole during the past 8 years has been both wise and effective,
and that "most of the shortcomings of the period were errors of omis-
sion rather than commission" (p. 77). It then makes clear that most
of the errors of omission were due to tardiness, and could be cured
in part by better forecasting, but in the main by conferring upon the
President the discretionary power to make certain kinds of tax changes
(see discussion pp. 78-85).
The conclusions which I have set forth above are very diffierent.
A revealing portion of the CEA discussion says: "The experience
of 1961-65 demonstrated that an effective fiscal policy to stimulate
the economy could be carried out without adding unnecessarily to the
size of the Federal budget. Since the aims of stabilization be imple-
mented either through tax changes or expenditure changes, decisions
regarding Federal expenditures can be properly based on the desired
allocation of resources between the public and private sectors" (pp.
77-78).
My objections are as follows: The period 1961-65 is too short to make
a full evaluation of fiscal policies during the past 8 years; the actual
policies during that period fell far short, for reasons which I have
already stated, and while a proper principle is stated for the desired
allocation of resources between the private and public sectors, such
allocation was not undertaken, and such allocation is of profound
significance with respect to economic equilibrium as well as with re-
spect to social equilibrium.
Even more broadly, the emphasis upon fiscal policy in this chapter
and throughout the report ignores the fact that fiscal policy-and to a
degree monetary policy-are but segments of a wide variety of na-
tional economic policies, including those related to social security,
agriculture, housing, and international economic policy. There can
be no sound and sufficiently comprehensive nor integrated development
of economic and social policy for the Federal Govermnent, as intended
by the Employment Act, until these other profoundly important
policies become as important portions of the economic report of the
CEA report as fiscal policies have been to date. This process is also
essential to the correction of fiscal policy itself.
A striking demonstration of this shortcoming is revealed by the fact
that the treatment of agriculture is confined in the CEA report mainly
to pages 115 to 116 thereof. Yet the problems of agriculture and other
aspects of rural life are among the most urgent and important that
we face.
V. THE PROBLEM OF INFLATION
Three main errors in approach to problem of inflation
The "new economists" and the CEA during the past 8 years have
committed three serious errors in dealing with the problem of inflation:
First, they have grossly exaggerated the problem in the United States,
and gross exaggeration is always undesirable because it distorts the
evolution and disturbs the balance of economic policies and programs;
second, they have offered no serious analysis of whether the amount of
PAGENO="0062"
1022
inflation we have had in the United States during these 8 years has on
net balance done more good or harm, and whether alternative policies
which might have been devised to restrain iuflation further would on
net balance have done more good or harm than has resulted from
avoidance of such policies. It is no answer to this criticism to say that
it is difficult to make this kind of analysis, for there are many types of
economic analysis which are difficult, but which nonetheless must be
undertaken instead of following a course without such analysis; and
third, they have completely misjudged the causes of recent and current
inflation, and, therefore, the policies they have adopted to deal with it
have both aggravated the inflation and caused other damage far more
costly than the inflation itself.
It is highly desirable to consider the problem of inflation in a
long-term perspective, rather than to focus excessively upon the ad-
mittedly high rate of price inflation during 1967, and especially 1968.
In a matter of this kind, short of a runaway inflation which we have
not had even during the past 2 years, the longer term averages are
in my view far more significant and a better guide to policies ad-
dressed to the future than rather extreme aberrations from these
longrun averages during a year or two. It is noteworthy that 1967
and 1968 are by no means the first time when such aberrations ap-
peared, nor the first time when the reaction to them was excessive.
Moreover, it would be very unfair for the CEA to claim-and I do
not assert that it has claimed-that its large attention to the problem
of inflation arose during the past 2 years. Even during 1961-66, when
we experienced unusual relative price stability, there were constant
alarms about the problem of inflation, especially on the ground that
it was a basic cause of our unfavorable balance-of-payments position,
in that it put us at a competitive disadvantage in the international
exchange of goods and services. Yet the fact of the matter was that
we maintained a quite favorable balance in these categories, and our
unfavorable balance was due to causes which had very little to do
with the American price level, such as our international spending
abroad, the flow of American capital to other countries, the with-
drawal of foreign capital from the United States, and so forth. Fur-
ther, some of these unfavorable developments were due to some coin-
petitive disadvantage exhibited in the overall performance of the
American economy, which in turn was due to some of the repressive
measures adopted for the alleged purpose of restraining inflation.
Eva~uation of magnitudes of inflationary trends
The average annual increase in consumer prices in the United
States was 1.7 percent during 1918-68, 1.8 percent during 1928-68,
3.1 percent during 1938-68 (affected greatly by the reflation after the
Great Depression and the World War II era), 1.9 percent during
1948-68, and 1.9 percent during 1958-68. Even during 1960-68, the
average annual increase in consumer prices was only 2.0 percent, and
during 1960-66 it was much less than that. During 1966-68, the aver-
age annual rate was 3.5 percent, and from 1967 to 1968, it was 4.2 per-
cent. My next chart, depicting these trends, also depicts the trends with
respect to wholesale prices and industrial prices, but I am not dis-
cussing these in detail, because the conclusions I would draw from
PAGENO="0063"
1023
such discussion would be essentially the same as those I draw from
discussion of the trends in consumer prices.'5
Viewing this performance sensibly, I do not see how we can con-
clude that our economy has been threatened or will be threatened
in future by anything approximately a "runaway" or even unusual
amount of price inflation in any fair perspective. This fair perspective
is further reinforced by comparisons with other countries. During
the 5-year period 1962-67 (1968 not comprehensively available to
me), compared with the 2.6-percent average annual increase in con-
sumer prices in the United States during the 5-year period 1963-68
(and only 2.0 percent during 1962-67), the average annual increase
in consumer prices was 3.3 percent in the United Kingdom, 3.2 percent
in France, 2.7 percent in Germany, 4.7 percent in Italy, 2.7 percent
in Canada, and 5.4 percent in Japan. Comparisons of the wholesale
price trends in these countries with those in the United States would
lead broadly to the same conclusions.16
CEA has not probed deeply into actual consequences of rising prices
Coming to the second phase of this aspect of my analysis, at no time
during the past 8 years has the CEA undertaken anything approxi-
mating a definitive nor even substantial analysis of the economic or
social consequences of price trends in the United States during this
period. Nor has CEA attempted to evaluate what the alternative con-
sequences of more restrictive price policies would have been. A mere
regurgitation of the word "inflation" as a horror signal, or of the
charge that inflation is "the cruelest tax of all" provides no substitute
for such empirical analysis, especially when in the long run the Amer-
ican experience indicates strongly that periods of rising prices (with
rare exceptions) have been periods `where production, employment,
and income distribution have behaved more satisfactorily `than during
other periods.
The GEA has gravely misjudged the causes of inflation
Coming to the third phase of this aspect of my analysis, which is the
most important of all, the CEA's entire approach to the problem of
inflation throughout has been based entirely upon the rather prevalent
assumption that a more rapid rate of real economic growth is more
~onducive to price inflation than a lower rate, and/or that a lower
level of unemployment is more conducive to price inflation than a
higher rate of unemployment, and/or that an economy operating close
~o reasonably full or optimum resource use is more prone to inflation
than an economy with a larger amount of economic slack.
The empirical evidence irrefutably refutes these unalloyed assump-
tions, even more though it may not conclusively prove the contrary.
During 1952-55, the average annual rate of consumer price iiiflation
was only 0.3 percent, when the average annual rate of real economic
growth was 3.5 percent, and unemployment as officially counted aver-
aged 4 percent. During 1955-58, the average annual increase in con-
sumer prices was 2.6 percent, although the average annual rate of real
economic growth was only 0.8 percent, and unemployment averaged 4.9
percent. During 1956-58, the average annual increase in consumer
prices was 3.1 percent, while the average annual rate of real economic
`~ See charts i5 and 16, following text.
16 See again chart 15, following text.
PAGENO="0064"
1024
growth was only 0.2 percent, and unemployment averaged 5.1 percent.
During 1958-60, the average annual rate of consumer price inflation
fell back to 1.2 percent, while the average annual rate of real economic
growth was 4.3 percent, and unen~ployment averaged 6 percent. Dur-
ing 1960-68, the average annual rate of real economic growth rose to
4.8 percent, and the average annual increase in consumer prices was
only 2 percent. Unemployment averaged 4.9 percent, but was reduced
greatly to 2.6 percent by 1968. During 1960-66, the average annual
increase in consumer prices was only 1.6 percent, while the real rate of
economic growth averaged 5.1 percent. Unemployment averaged 5.3
percent, but was reduced to 3.8 percent by 1966. During 1966-68, the
average annual rate of increase in consumer prices was 3.7 percent,
although the average annual rate of real economic growth fell to 3.5
percent. Unemployment averaged 3.7 percent, or almost the same as
the 1966 level. The trends in wholesale prices and industrial prices are
shown on the same chart, but I do not analyze them in detail because
they tell basically the same story.
Certainly, these trends in the main indicate an inverse or negative
rather than a positive correlation between the rate of real economic
growth and the rate of price inflation. Nor do they indicate in the
main that a movement toward reduction in unemployment promotes
an increase in price inflation.
But it may be argued that, while a higher rate of real economic
growth or a lower level of unemployment does not in itself promote
inflationary tendencies, inflation is nonetheless promoted by an econ-
omy moving to reasonably full or optimum resource w~e. However,
this thesis is also discredited by the trends depicted above. For exam-
ple, during 1956-58, with unemployment averaging 5.1 percent, and
with the sharpest recession since 1952 occurring within that period,
the average annual rate of consumer price inflation of 3.1 percent was
about twice as fast as the 1.6-percent average during 1960-66 when
unemployment averaged 5.3 percent, or about the same. From 1966 to
1967, the price inflation was 2.8 percent, and unemployment stood at
3.8 percent.
The analysis could be further complicated, and my conclusions
might be somewhat modified, by the introduction of time-lag~ factors
and some others. But I submit that my analysis and conclusions are in
the main sustainable, and most assuredly do not justify the unalloyed
position of the CEA which is at times deliberately sought to generate
excessive deviations from optimum real economic growth, and at least
to tolerate excessive unemployment, in the pursuit of a nonsustain-
able proposition bearing upon the relationship between price trends
and these other factors.17
My thesis with respect to recent and current inflation
My own explanation of inflationary trends-which I commenced to
set forth in the mid-1950's before future experience lent much further
support to my position-runs as follows: In an economy characterized
so largely by administered prices, and inadequate volume of real eco-
nomic activity and insufficient employment, or even the clear prospect
of these, tend to generate protective efforts to compensate for these
17 See again chart iG, following text.
PAGENO="0065"
1025
deficiencies through the managerial price-making process., This thesis
is perhaps most clearly borne out by the resumption of a relatively
high rate of price inflation from early 1966 forward, when the signs
became large and unmistakable that the economy was entering a period
of severely reduced real economic growth, and when recession talk was
in the air.
In some other areas, such as medical care and housing, and at times
in the area of farm prices, rising costs or prices have been due to
entirely different factors. In the medical field, there have been short-
ages of facilities and personnel relative to the real need, engendered
by long neglect of adequate public spending for these purposes, such
neglect being fomented by the avowed desire to fight inflation. In the
area of housing, rising costs have not been due to excessive aggregate
demand for housing relative to the Nation's needs, but instead have
been due in large measure to the fantastically rising interest rates,
again allegedly designed to fight inflation.
The thesis that excessive aggregate demand (which in fact we have
not had any time in recent years, when measured against the demand
required to sustain optimum economic growth and bring unemploy-
ment low enough) explains the inflations during recent years, and
particularly during 1967-1968, breaks down at all points. It is further
corroded by the special industry studies which I have made from 1952
forward, indicating even more clearly the propensity to increase prices
more rapidly during periods of relatively high unused capacity and
relatively high unemployment than during periods of relatively less
unused capacity and relatively less unemployment.
Analysis of cost-pwsh inflation
Frequently, it is argued that the inflation has been of the cost-push
variety, occasioned by wage costs per man-hour rising faster than
productivity. Repeatedly and systematically, the CEA has taken this
position. But it is completely torpedoed by the empirical evidence.
During 1960-1968, in the total private nonf arm economy, measured
appropriately in constant dollars, productivity rose at an average
annual rate of 3.1 percent, while hourly wages and salaries rose at an
average annual rate of 2.9 percent. It is even more revealing to break
this period into two parts. During 1960-1966, productivity rose at an
average annual rate of 3.4 percent, while wages and salaries rose at an
average annual rate of only 2.7 percent. This was a period when the
average annual rate of real economic growth was 5.1 percent. But
during 1966-1968, when the average annual rate of real economic
growth declined to 3.7 percent, productivity rose at an average annual
rate of only 2.2 percent, and wages and salaries at an average annual
rate of 3.2 percent.
The trends in manufacturing tell the same story, only more so. Dur-
ing 1960-68, the figures were 3.2 percent for productivity, and 2.2 per-
cent for wages and salaries. During 1960-66, the figures were 3.7 per-
cent for productivity, and 1.9 percent for wages and salaries. During
1966-68, the figures were 1.7 percent for productivity, and 2.9 percent
for wages and salaries.
This leads to the implication that the relative trends during 1966-68
exerted cost-push inflation, and thus explained the rapidly accelerat-
ing inflationary trends (it should be noted that the "New Economists"
24-833 0-69-pt. 4-5
PAGENO="0066"
1026
and the CEA talked a great deal about cost-push inflation, and devel-
oped the unworkable and unfair price-wage guidelines accordingly,
long before 1966, when the rate of real advance in wages and salaries
was lagging far behind the rate of productivity gains). I cannot ac-
cept the CEA position, implied if not made explicit, that the relative
trends in wages and salaries and productivity during 1966-68 justi-
fied in any sense the accelerated price inflation during this period, par-
ticularly in view of profit margins and aggregate profits, which the
CEA appears extremely anxious to avoid discussing in its 1969 re-
port, and handled very gingerly in previous reports. Consumption,
supported so substantially by wages, had certainly not been excessive,
but rather has been deficient, during the past 2 years, by economic
equilibrium tests which the CEA never brings forth.
But let us assume for the moment-contrary to my own view-
that the relative trends in wages and salaries and productivity dur-
ing 1966-68 "caused" or even "justified" the accelerated price infla-
tion. In that event, this happened, not because the rate of advance in
real wages and salaries was too high in terms of any equilibrium model
for reasonably full use of our potentials, but rather because the rate
of productivity growth dropped abysmally. And this happened pre-
cisely because of the abysmal decline in the real rate of economic
growth, coupled with the election (desirable in itself) to translate this
into less efficient utilization of the employed labor force rather than
into more overt unemployment. Of course, such inefficient utilization
is a form of concealed unemployment, although the CEA has not yet
come to think that way.18
Under these circumstances, how wrong and upsidedown it is to try
to stop this kind of cost-push inflation by further repressive measures,
designed to reduce still further a seriously inadequate rate of real eco-
nomic growth.
Further, my basic position is that policies designed effectively to
achieve a stable and optimum economic growth would in the long
run yield less net price inflation than result from erratic ups and
downs in the real economy, rapidly changing labor and business ex-
pectations, and general uncertainty. The evidence to date on this seems
fairly clear. But even if the evidence were less conclusive or more
arguable on rationa.l grounds, we should choose the certain benefits
of steady and optimum economic growth and minimal unemploy-
ment, instead of committing ourselves to a theory as to the cause of
inflation which cannot be squared with what has been happening.
In the foregoing discussion of wage and salary trends, the data are
based upon hourly rates of pay, and do not include other so-called
labor compensation in the form of fringe benefits, while the CEA does
include fringe benefits in its analysis of this problem. I am convinced
that my approach is preferable, because fringe benefits in general do
not enter currently into the disposable income of wage and salary
earners, and it is this disposable income which must keep up with
productivity trends in order to maintain a reasonable balance between
growth in output and growth in consumer demand. From the view-
point of total labor costs including fringe benefits, there is no evidence
that the trends in total labor costs have militated against adequate
18 See chart 17, following text.
PAGENO="0067"
1027
profit margins. To the contrary, the evidence is that profit margins
have in many cases been far too high, and that this has contributed
powerfully to the recurrent tendency of the rate of growth in invest-
ment in plant and equipment to exceed the rate of growth in consump-
tion, particularly in view of the increasing productivity of capital.
But even if it were to be conceded that fringe benefits should be in-
cluded in the comparisons between hourly wage and salary trends and
productivity, the picture which I have set forth above would not be
changed materially in its fundamental import. The picture would still
show that real labor compensation `lagged seriously behind produc-
tivity trends, until the advent of a seriously retarded. rate of real
economic growth.
Finally, in this phase of the discussion, I have used the trends in
real hourly wages and salaries, while the CEA consistently has com-
pared the current dollar trends in wages and salaries (or in total wage
costs) with productivity trends. This posture on the part of the Council
is completely indefensible. Productivity is a real output concept, and
the core problem of maintaining a balanced relationship between pro-
ductivity trends and hourly wage and salary trends must involve the
concept of the real purchasing power of wages. And from the view-
point of business costs, there has been absolutely no evidence that the
adjustment of real rather than current dollar wage and salary trends
to productivity trends impair profit margins. This is true in part be-
cause, when the price level is generally rising or under conditions of
reasonably full prosperity even with a relatively stable price level, the
price makers are in at least as good a position to protect their profit
margins as other income earners are to protect themselves.
Shortcomings in GEA treatment of inflation
With respect to 1968, the CEA report says that "The pressures of
excessive demand pushed up the price level at the unacceptable rate of
nearly 4 percent," and insists that "Total demand must be brought into
better balance with the Nation's productive capacity" (p. 33).
I have stated above my disagreement with this position. Further, and
in accord with my own basic position, the CEA says that erratic ups
and downs in the economic performance "would probably involve a
more serious danger of inflation than would steadier movement that
remained close to the path of potential output" (p. 54). So why, acqui-
esce in, or even promote, such erratic movements? Yet, the CEA's entire
fiscal-policy position, including extension of the 10-percent surcharge
tax for another year, and the extension at present levels of excise taxes
on automobiles and telephone services, has moved in just that direction
(p. 54-55).
Then, the CEA report states that "In a slack economy, rising prices
are hardly a problem," and attempts to support this as follows (p. 94)
The difficulties of combining price stability and high employment in the past
15 years are evident. . . In 1956-1967 and from 1960 to 1908, when the unemploy-
ment rate was between 3.6 and 4.3 percent, price increases ranged between 3.1
percent and 4.1 percent. In contrast, between 1958 and 1964 the unemployment
rate consistently exceeded 5 percent, and price increases were uniformly less
than 2 percent.
I submit most earnestly that this fragmentary a.nd highly selective
use of figures will not stand comparison with my more complete
analysis of relative trends in prices and economic performance, as set
forth above.
PAGENO="0068"
1028
Further, the CEA report says this (p. 97)
But h'istoricafly, unemployment rates of 4 percent or below have been associated
with a price performance that most Americans considered unsatisfactory
price increases at the rate recently experienced clearly impair our international
trade performance, cause a haphazard redistribution of income and wealth, and
may jeopardize sustained prosperity. The first line of defense against
inflation must be fiscal and monetary policies that avoid excessive pressure on a
productive capacity.
My criticisms of the foregoing statement are explicit in all that I
have said. They combme an incorrect, analysis of the causes of recent
and current price inflat.lon with a ver curious set of values as to the
relative importance of the balance-of-payments problem and the prob-
lem of unemployment., inadequate economic growth, and social clis-
equilibrium at home. It is incredible to propose, or even accept, the
proposition that the unemployed should be asked to protect the affluent
from paying the allegedly higher prices which more jobs might cause.
As for impact upon income distribution, the CEA has not examined
that at all.
In line with its analysis, the CEA urges, as a measure against infla.-
tion, an "increase in money wage rates a. little better than 5 percent"
for 1968 (p. 59), which would mean an increase of about 2 percent in
real terms. I suggest that no economist could meet the challenge of
developing a responsible economic equilibrium model based upon an
increase in the hourly-earned purchasing power of wage earners of
only 2 percent a. year, less taxes paid.
In consequence of these deficiencies in its entire analysis of the infla-
tionary problem, the programs to deal with inflation which the CEA
sets forth are in the main a medley of relatively minor and traditional
approaches, for example, increased mobility, training, promotion of
competition, antitrust activity, etc. (pp. 99-122).
\TJ. PROBLEMS OF MONETARY POLICY
General consideration.s
My view-s with respect to the prevalent monetary policy during the
past 15 years or longer have beeii diametrically opposed to those of the
CEA and of most of the "New Economists."
Generally speaking, their view is that. tight money and rising interest
rates help to contain inflation. My view- is that tight money and rising
iiiterest rates exacerbate inflation, and are in themselves highly
inflationary.
My view is that tight money and rising interest rates pow-erfully
inhibit optimum real economic growth and contribute to economic
instability (for the reasons stated above, these. consequences are in
themselves inflationary). Their view on this subject is iiot made ex-
plicit and is certainly not advanced in the in the 1968 CEA Report,
becau~e it seems to b~ worried about the falitasy of too high a rate of
real economic growth and too much employment rather than about the
ominous reality of too low- a rate of real economic growth and too much
unemployment.
My view is that tight money and rising interest rates have been
monstrously inequitable and adverse to social equilibrium andl plain
justice; they appear elttllhely impervious to this aspect of the probl~m.
My view~ is that we need a much more selective monetary policy,
PAGENO="0069"
1029
because an aggregate or blunderbuss monetary policy represses what
ought to be accelerated, and has little or no impact upon what ought
to be restrained, and feeds the fat while starving the lean. The 1969
CEA Report appears impervious to this problem, although it does
make some very slight obeisance to the damage earlier done to housing
by the prevalent monetary policy.
My view is that one of our largest problems is to integrate the policies
of the Federal Reserve System with the policies of the Federal Gov-
ernment, and indeed to make monetary policy the servant of the ob]ec-
tives of the Employment Act of 1946, and of the governmental policies
designed to achieve these objectives. The CEA has never come to
grips with this problem, and its friendly commentaries about the
prevalent monetary policy in its 1969 report ignores this problem.
Tight money and rising interest rates work against economic
equilibrium
Let me now become more specific about the very foundation of the
prevalent monetary policy during the past 15 years or longer-the
entirely erroneous proposition that tight money and rising interest
rates serve admirably to help contain inflation. This erroneous idea is
essentially allied with the erroneous idea (discussed above) that
policies inimical to optimum economic growth and conducive to exces-
sive unemployment help to contain inflation. Consequently, the analy-
sis which I present immediately below is essentially similar in method
to that which I used in discussing the inflationary problem generally.
During the period 1955-68 viewed as a whole, the average annual
growth in the nonfederally held money supply was only 2.5 percent,
and the average annual real growth rate in total national production
was at the deficient rate of 3.8 percent. I believe that there was a strong
relationship between the deficient growth in the money supply and the
inadequate economic performance, but I will not elaborate upon this
particular point, especially because I believe that too much weight has
been attached to monetary policy in the aggregate in this particular
connection. Theoretically, and perhaps practically also, a more or less
rapid growth in the money supply might affect the level of prices con-
siderably, but should not affect the real trends in production and em-
ployment if economic equilibrium were maintained in the fundamental
allocation of resource and in income distribution, which can be
achieved either at a more or less rapid growth in the nonfederally held
money supply.
Nonetheless, what I have just said does not apply to extreme cases.
It seems perfectly clear that the extremely low growth rate in the
money supply during 1955-57, aiid again during 1958-60, was inti-
mately associated with the recession of 1957-58 and the minirecession
in late 1960 and early 1961. It also seems abundantly clear that the
extraordinarily low growth rate in the money supply during 1955-66
was an important factor in initiating the extremely low real economic
growth rate during 1956-67 and the unsatisfactory average annual rate
during 1966-68. The relatively more rapid rate of growth in the money
supply during 1957-58 and during 1960-61, and again during 1962~-65,
appears to have been conducive to more favorable trends in the real
rate of economic growth. The rapid expansion of the money supply
during 1966-68 seems clearly to have helped prevent the very serious
deterioration rate of economic growth during 1966-67 from being con-
PAGENO="0070"
1030
tinued over a longer period of time. On net balance, in a long term
perspective, it seems quite clear that the monetary policy has been
much too tight, a.nd that a relatively liberal monetary policy is highly
conducive to satisfactory economic growth.
More seriously, the monetary policy has worked powerfully against
economic equilibrium, because it has helped to reallocate resources in
directions bearing no relationship to econoniic equilibrium, and in
many cases quite destructive of it. The tightening of the money supply
has had practically no effect upon the relatively excessive investment
booms in plant and equipment, because those indulging in these booms
are not greatly affected either by general shortages of credit or. by
rising interest costs; they finance mainly out of retained ea.rmngs and
out of the price structure. On the other hand, a better rate of economic
credit nor by rising interest costs; they finance mainly out of retained
earnings and out of the price structure. On the other hand, a better
rate of economic expansion in other important sectors, or, more gen-
erally, a relatively larger ultimate demand composed of both private
consumption and public demand, would have been much more con-
ducive to economic equilibrium at steady and optimum growth, and
these developments have been very harshly impeded by both tight
money and rising interest rates.
Tight money and rising interest rates are in themselves inflationary
Most important of all, in the context of the argument that tight
money and rising interest rates restrain inflation, let us look at the
empirical evidence. The extraordinarily contraction in the growth
rate of the money supply during 1955-57, while it impacted severely
upon the real rate of economic growth, was accompanied by a 3.5 per-
cent average annual rise in consumer prices from 1956 to 1957. The
greatly expanded growth rate in the money supply during 1957-58
was accompanied by a reduction in the ra.te of consumer price infla-
tion to 2.8 percent. During 1958-61, there was throughout an inverse
or negative correlation between the trends in the money supply and
the rate of consumer price inflation. During 1962-65, a sustained and
relatively rapid expansion of the money supply was accompanied by
remarkable price stability. During 1955-66, a very sharp contraction
in the rate of growth of the money supply was accompanied by a very
rapid acceleration of the rate of price inflation. During 1966-67, the
money supply expanded about three times as fast as during 1966-67,
but the rate of consumer price inflation was slightly lower. During
1967-68, the rate of expansion of the money supply was the same as
during 1966-67, but the rate of consumer price inflation was tremen-
dously higher.19
Viewing these relative trends in an adequate time perspective, it ap-
pears to be clear that excessive restraints upon the growth of the money
supply worked toward more price inflation in the long-run for prac-
tically the same reasons that excessive restraints upon real economic
growth and employment expansion worked in the long run toward
more net price inflation.
Beyond all this, the almost unbelievably erratic changes in the rate
of growth of the money supply over the years represents an attempt
at "fine tuning" which is utterly impractical, and really indicative of
~ See chart 18, followIng text.
PAGENO="0071"
1031
a wayward and thoughtless long-range monetary policy, and general
economic policy as well.
Tight money and rising interest rates are appalbing~y unequitable
In this connection, I set forth the following:
(1) From 1952 to 1967, the interest rates on new Treasury borrow-
ings rose 144.7 percent for 3-mont.h bills, 167.4 percent for 9- to 12-
month issues, 138 percent for 3- to 5-year issues, and 81 percent for
long-term bonds. The computed average interest rate on the Federal
public debt rose from 2.33 percent in 1952 to 4.15 percent in 1967, an
increase of 78.3 percent. For the 15-year period as a whole, the rising
interest costs to the Federal Government alone aggregated $35.1 bil-
lion, and stood at about $5 billion in 1967 alone. The annual cost to the
Treasury now in 1969 is close to $8 billion. These rising costs to our
Federal Government have in part been paid for by taxes imposed upon
the people, but in the main these rising interest costs have added to
the Federal deficit. Those who claim that Federal deficits are infla~
tionary per se will thus be hard put to explain how rising interest rates
can contribute to the war against inflation.
(2) During the same 15-year period 1952-67, the rising interest costs
have imposed an additional burden of $5.2 billion upon State and local
governments. This additional cost burden stood at $1 billion in 1967
alone, and is very much higher than that now in 1969.
(3) During the same 15-year period, the computed average interest
rate on the total interest-bearing private debt rose from 4.97 to 6.24
percent, a rise of 25.6 percent. Thus, the aggregate burden imposed
upon private borrowers during the period as a whole was $66.4 bil-
lion, and stood at `about $11 billion in 1967 alone. This increased burden
is at an annual rate of between $12 and $13 billion now in 1969.
(4) Looking at all types of borrowings, both private and public,
the computed average interest rate rose from 3.5 percent in 1952 to 5.4
percent in 1967, a rise of 54.3 percent. This imposed in the aggregate
an `additional interest burden o'f $106.6 billion, and $17.7 billion in
1967 alone. The additional interest burden in 1967 alone was about
two and a half times as high as the average annual additional interest
burden during the 15-year period. Now, in 1969, the `annual rate of
the excess interest burden is considerably above $20 billion.20
(5) If the trend toward rising interest rates continues, I estimate
conservatively-and my estimates made many years ago h'ave turned
out to be conservative to date-that the additional or excessive interest
burden might well rise to $25 billion in 1977 alone, averaging annually
well `above $20 billion during 1969-77 inclusive, and aggregating well
above $180 billion over the 9-year period.
(6) The additional interest burden aggregating $106.6 billion dur-
ing the 15-year period I have reviewed equates with an excess interest
cost per capita for the entire U.S. population of $88.90 in 1967 alone,
and $591.89 for the period as a whole. Thus, the additional or excessive
interest costs for a family of four came to $355.60 in 1967 ajone, and
$2,367 for the period as a whole.
(7) Upon whom, in the main, has this unconscionable interest bur-
den fallen? It ha's fallen upon the `small businessman and the farmer;
the person who buys a car on time to get to work; the family who buys
20 See chart 19, following text.
PAGENO="0072"
1032
on time a refrigerator or television set or other consumer durables;
the family who borrows money to pay the hospital bills when there is
a long illness; the family who borrows money to put a child through
college; the States and localities borrowing money to have enough
policemen and firemen and teachers, and trying to pay them adequately
compared with other occupations. The rising interest rates enter into
the cost of living, and yet the workingman is told that cost-of-hvmg
adjustments in his wages are "inflationary." The average family
with an income of $8,000 before taxes, buying or renting a $16,000
home, will pay out over the life of the mortagage about $8,000 more in
interest rates alone than if interest rates had stayed where they were
in 1952.
(8) We are committed to making an effective war against poverty.
The additional interest burden today, at an annual rate, is about 65
percent higher than the amount by which t.he incomes of all the poor
people in the United States would need to be raised to lift them above
the poverty-income level as defined by the Government.
In the entire history of American economic policy, I submit that
there has been nothing more wrongful, more injurious to the public
interest, and more in contrast with our most cherished principles of
equity and fairplay, than the long and tremendous rise in interest rates
which has already occurred. The efforts now, on so many fronts, to push
interest rates still higher needs to be stopped in its tracks.
GEA com~ments on monetary policy
The CEA appears to be very complacent, and even cheerful, about
the prevalent monetary policy. It refers to a "dramatic demonstra-
tion of the effectiveness of monetary policy," and adds that "the record
of the past 8 years demonstrates that flexible, discretionary monetary
policy can make an effective contribution to economic stabilization"
(p.85).
Most of the CEA discussion of monetary policy is extremely the-
oretical and of the textbook variety, with little or practically no at-
tempt to develop a quantitative empirical analysis of just what mone-
tary policy has done during the past 8 years, and what we can learn
from the varied experience. There is no mention of the iniquitous effects
of rapidly rising interest rates. There is no adequate integration of
monetary policy with treatment of all other basic national economic
policies such treatment actually omitted, as I have already pointed
out).
What the CEA has to say about housing is most extraordinary (p.
86):
Although the demand for housing-and for mortgage credit-
does not appear to be especially responsive to mortgage interest rates,
the supply of mortgage funds is quite sensitive to several interest
rate relationships.
This comment is hardly short. of ignorance. Has the CEA forgotten
the vast and salutary changes in homeownership and financing
brought about by the tremendous reduction in interest rates on lions-
ing, in response to the great depression? Why does the CEA ignore
the entire market current situation with respect to housing, demon-
strating so clearly that. a mass market for decent housing for low- and
lower-middle income people requires above all low financing charges?
How can the CEA reconcile its commentary with the very nature of
PAGENO="0073"
1033
the long-range housing program proposed by the President and en-
acted by the Congress not so long ago, the very heart of which is rec-
ognition that a full-scale housing program, adequately directed toward
the slums and poverty, requires a very wide range of charges to the
user? Whether the charges to the user are reduced by lower interest
rates, or by subsidies covering the cost of higher int.erest rates, has
no bearing upon the erroneous nature of the CEA commentary.
Indeed, this CEA commentary about housing reinforces, possibly
more than anything else in the CEA report, my conviction that the
CEA has not assumed the responsibility to develop that expert and
comprehensive treatment of all basic national economic and social
policies which alone can fulfill its responsibilities under the Employ-
ment Act of 194G.
VII. THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY
The treatment of the international economy in the 1969 CEA report
is expert and informative, but excessively conventional, complacent,
and nonenterprising in view of the unsettled state of international
economic arrangements and the recurrent crises during recent years.
I would have been more impressed if the CEA had dealt positively
and firmly with these issues, which I deem to be of central and pressing
importance:
(1) Some nations must run an unfavorable balance of payments,
as that term is conventionally defined, and should not the United
States be one of them? Our preeminence in economic and financial
terms, and many other factors, have led me to the conclusion that, for
a number of years ahead, we should be huge net investors in overseas
areas, especially in underdeveloped areas If we are to pursue such a
policy, we must run a large unfavorable balance of payments for some
time to come, measured short term.
(2) Does the customary method of recording international accounts
correctly reflect our true international position, or is it highly mis-
leading? As in the case of the Federal Budget, especially until the most
recent year or so, the commingling of all types of outflows and receipts
in our international accounts presents an entirely unrealistic and ex-
cessively alarming picture. For example, defense outlays overseas do
not have the same economic nor financial significance as loans or in-
vestments overseas. There is also failure to distinguish realistically
between short-range and long-range positions.
(3) Viewing our unfavorable balance of payments in ratio to our
GNP during reëent years and currently, have we not made a mountain
out of a molehill, to the extent that we have allowed efforts to solve
this problem-substantially unsuccessfully, at that-to militate
against adoption of infinitely more important programs and policies
directed toward the optimum advancement of economic and social
equilibrium, optimum economic growth, and minimum unemployment
at home?
(4) Can we really determine optimum international economic poli-
cies without setting them in the broader perspective of total economic
analysis and programs, which I have stressed throughout this dis-
cussion, and which the CEA has not yet brought forth?
(5) Do we not need to move more vigorously and rapidly toward
the gradual abandonment of the gold anachronism?
PAGENO="0074"
1034
(6) Instead of temporizing and extemporizing, should we not move
more positively and broadly to improve the international mechanisms
of exchange, so as to make them fully contemporary, rather than sub-
stantially obsolete or at least inadequate to the times?
VIII. THE EcoNo~nc REPORT OF THE Pm~smExr
As I said at the outset, it would be both burdensome and cumber-
some for me to attempt a detailed examination of the Economic Report
of the President, in that the foregoing analysis of the council's annual
report makes clear my views.
Succinctly, the President's report recommends a tight budget policy;
extension of the 10 percent tax surcharge for another year; Presi-
dential discretion in the matter of tax policy; voluntary cooperation
and increased productivity, toward price stability; and promotion of
world trade by reducing trade barriers. The President's report also
concludes that "our monetary institutions are working well" (p. 13).
The mere listing of these proposals, combined with what I have said
about the CEA report, indicates fully my attitude toward most 0±
them. They appear to me to represent, in the main, excessive satisfac-
tion with policies already adopted and now in being; a negative atti-
tude toward the imperative need for profound correction of some of
the most important of these policies; and a generally quiescent attitude,
when the country's needs are crying out for a great program of action.
There are only two items on the list which would seem to call for
further comment.
I am opposed to the vesting of discretionary tax authority in the
President. This proposal places relatively too much emphasis upon
fine-tuning and quick and frequent changes in tax policy, when we
need a fairly long-range and stable fiscal and economic policy, geared
to a long-range and continuous pro-prosperity program, rather than
anti or counteracting measures of a ma.ginot line nature. Moreover, the
fact that the administration then in office took from early 1961 to early
1963 to recommend a vigorous fiscal policy, despite the promises made
during the 1960 campaign and the urgency of the need throughout,
plus the fact that it took the Congress only 1 year to enact the recom-
mended progra.m (with some modifications), indicate to me the im-
propriety of blaming delay excessively upon the legislative branch.
Further still, and perhaps most fundamental of all, I do not believe
that something as close to the lives and livelihoods of the people should
be removed from direct consideration and approval by the people's
representatives in the Congress. I think we would lose far more than
we would gain by any such change, and I am heartened by the fact
that the Congress to date has felt the same way.
I am not against voluntary methods of improving price-wage-profit
and other adjustments in the private economy, and I think them to be
a preferable alternative to direct controls under current and foresee-
able circumstances. But meaningful progress in this direction will
require institutional changes toward improved and more continuous
consultation among industry, labor, and Government. The first require-
ment for this will be recognition by CEA of its responsibility to pro-
vide a broader perspective for such consultation, in the form of the
kind of long-range, comprehensive, and integrated economic and social
analysis which thus far has been so sorely lacking.
PAGENO="0075"
1035
The President's report also recommends some improvement in dis-
ability insurance, an average 13-percent increase in social security
benefits, and improved unemployment insurance, with special federally
financed benefits for long-time unemployment. These proposals are all
in the right direction, although they do not go far enough. Short-time
unemployment is bad enough, and I believe that the federally financed
benefits should be applied to it also. Maintenance of income among the
short-term unemployed would also help to reduce the translation of
short-term unemployment into long-term unemployment.
IX. M~r OWN RECOMMENDATIONS
My own recommendations are so explicit in what I have already
said, that unnecessary duplication would result if I set them forth
again compr~li.ensively. However, some of the highlights are these:
(1) The CEA should develop and include in each annual report a
long-range and carefully quantified program and policy for economic
and social equilibrium at sustained optimum resource use. This should
set quantified goals for employment, GNP, and its maj or components,
with explicit regard for the problems of both economic and social
equilibrium. I have at times called this an "economic performance
budget." Without this, all short-range policies tend to be improperly
oriented, and are frequently at cross-purposes. Economic and social
policies and programs are so inseparable that I do not favor the pro-
posal-although it has considerable appeal-that a separate Council
of Social Advisers be established;
(2) Maximum employment, with unemployment as conventionally
defined held down to not more than 21/2 percent of a broadly defined
civilian labor force, should be an unalterable must. Placing upon the
unemployed the burden of protecting the employed and the affluent
against inflation is utterly indefensible. The concept of the civilian la-
bor force should be expanded to include, not only those customarily in
it, but to all those for whom gainful employment would be better for
them, and for the Nation at large, than economic disutilization. As a
last resort, if all else falls short, there should be federally guaranteed
employment;
(3) The long-range economic and social budget referred to above
should include, in proper `balance, every policy and program of the
Federal Government which is economic and financial in the sense that
it utilizes and allocates substantial portions of our economic resources.
It should include the Federal budget, which is but one aspect of basic
economic policy;
(4) Even though in the long run we should be able to accomplish
our social imperatives with the ratio of Federal spending to GNP
no higher in 1977 than it is now, nonetheless in the years more im-
mediately ahead we should shift much more resources to the public
sector, and lift Federal spending accordingly. We should reject with-
out equivocation the proposition that spending and taxation are avail-
able alternatives, even toward stability and growth, much less toward
social equilibrium. The needed `evel of Federal spending should be
determined first, and variations in tax rates should be utilized to com-
bat inflation or deflation as the case may be. We urgently need a very
much more progressive tax policy than we have, and this should
PAGENO="0076"
1036
commence with lifting the exemptions plus elevating some of the rates,
from somewhat above the middle-income levels upward, such eleva-
tion retracing the pattern of the personal income tax reduction of
1964. Corporate taxes should be increased, possibly along the lines
of the 1964 redu~tions, but preferably on a more progressive basis.
Some Federal deficit should be run, until optimum resource use is
restored;
(5) The monetary policy has been and still is atrocious. We need
a much more stable and a much more liberal monetary policy, a much
more selective monetary policy, and insistence upon the proposition
that the Federal Reserve System and all its works must be subordinated
to the requirements of the Nation and its people, through subordina-
tion to the general economic policies and programs of the Federal
Government itself. This probably requires legislation. Monetary pol-
icy should be nationalized, within the Economic Reports of the
President;
(6) We need to reexamine thoroughly the causes and consequences
of inflation, thus transmuting the treatment of this important eco-
nomic and social problems from unrealism to reality, and from slo-
gan to substance. We should establish new institutional devices for
concerted consultation on this subject among industry, labor, and
Government. This consultation should be integrated with consulta-
tion regarding the overall development of the CEA Annual Report
and of the long-range economic and social budget which should be
contained therein;
(7) We need to accelerate greatly the war against poverty, to stream-
line its efforts, to integrate it with general economic and financial pol-
icy, so that the striking force of a unified national policy may be
brought to bear upon the liquidation of poverty in America within
decade;
(8) We need, as part and parcel of the war against poverty, and
for many other reasons, to achieve wtihin a decade decent homes, ade-
quate educational opportunity, and good medical care for all our peo-
ple. These, fully quantified and supported by implementary policies,
should be essential elements in the long-range goals within the CEA
Annual Reports;
(9) We need to dispel the dangerous and diverse dichotomy or com-
petition between our domestic requirements and our international re-
quirements, and recognize that we have the resources to meet both
adequately, if need be, by willingness to limit the nonessential;
(10) We need to concentrate far more than we have upon reversing
the persistent degradation of fa.rm life and incomes and the disparities
in our rural areas, and start building the people who live in these
areas, instead of driving them elsewhere, as we have done by the mil-
lions during recent years. We need, in this connection, to budget and
fulfill the duty to provide a balanced and nutritious diet for every
American. These goals, also, should be essential elements in the CEA
Annual Reports;
(11) We need to guarantee, not only sustained full employment, but
also at least minimum-decency incomes, through a unified nationwide
program initiated and supported mainly or entirely by the Federal
Government, for all those who cannot be brought within the employ-
ment stream. This should not compete with a full-employment policy,
PAGENO="0077"
1037
nor minimum-wage legislation, designed to prevent substandard wages
for those employed;
(12) We need not only to talk about housing and urban renewal (and
not only to enact plenary authorizing legislation without the funds to
carry it fully forward), but also to recognize that an adequate housing
program for the appropriate income groups is absolutely essential to
the problems of liquidating poverty, achieving and sustaining opti-
mum economic growth and full employment, advancing social justice,
and restoring and maintaining civil order;
(13) We need to stop frightening ourselves by talking about what
America "cannot afford," and start encouraging ourselves by just rec-
ognition of what our resources will permit, and what our problems
require that we do;
(14) It goes without saying that what I have set forth above, with
respect to the content and purposes of the OEA Annual Reports, must
carry over naturally-in properly abbreviated form-to the content
and purposes of the Economic Reports of the President.
PAGENO="0078"
1038
Charf 1
U.S. ECONOMiC GROWTH RATES,I922-i968~
AND NEEDED RATES, 1968-1977,
FOR OPTIMUM RESOURCE USE
Average Annual Growth Rates in GNP,Constant Dollars
Post World Wan Post World Warn Period of Stagnation Renewed
Growth Period Growth Period Limited War Period Growth Period
Growth Period
(~. _ _
5.1% 5.1%
I°Iiiot
1922-1929 1947-1950 1950-1953 1953-1960 1960-1966
NEEDED IN VIEW OF
NEW TECHNOLOGY
AND
LABOR FORCE GROWTH
RoasonablyHigh Renewed Low A!IowingforRostoraUso AfthrRootoration
Mixed Period Growth Period of Reasonably of Reasonably
Full Resource Use Full Resource Use
6.0%
1972-1977
1960-1968 1966-1968 1966-1967
estimates is preliminary.
Basic Data: Dept.of Commerce,Otf ice of Business Economics
1968-1972
PAGENO="0079"
1039
LONGTERM TRENDS IN PRODUCTIVITY
U.S. PRIVATE ECONOMY, 1910- I968~
Average Annual Rate of Growth in Output per Man-hour
for the Entire Private Economy
Chart 2
fl~l~ RECORD 1910-1968:
/ND/CAT/N6A CENERALLYACCELERAT/NOPRODUCT/V/TY
CR01 VT/I-RATE TREND
3.7%
350/,
3.2%
777
2.3% 2.4% 2.4%
1jUl11
1910- 920- 1930- 1940- 1955- 1960- 960-
920 930 940 1955 1960 966 968
1-HE POST WORLD WAR fl RECORD
INDICATING THATEXCESSIVEECONOM/CSLACK/NTERFERES
IVITH THE TRUEPRODI/CT/V/TYCROJVTH-RATE TREND
4.0%
3.7%
7 3.3%
2.6% 24%
,*** t.6%
UllillUl
1947-1953 1953-1960 1960-1966 1966-1968 1966-1967 1967-1968
Pnniodof Period of Recessions, Peniodof Periodof Peniodof Period of
High Economic VeryLow Economic Reasonably High Veny Low Economic Extnemely Low Restoned
Gnowth and Gnowth,ond lncneasing Economic Growth Economic Economic
Reasonably Full Economic Slack Gnowth,but St ill Gnowth Growth
Resource Use Substantial
Economic Slack
PAGENO="0080"
1040
"ECONOMIC GROWTH DIVIDEND",
U.S. ECONOMY,I968~'77
Total National Production (GNP) in Billions of EY.1969 Dollars
V//~ø~~ Optimum economic growth rate
V/////////////A Low economic growth rate
Chart 3
$303
GNP Economic Average Annual Aggregate
977 Growth Dividend' 5Economic Economic
1977 Growth Dividend" Growth Dividend"
1968-1977 1968-1977
$3,031
$1,396
$ 567
Projections by Leon H.Keyserling.
PAGENO="0081"
1041
GOALS FOR THE U.S. ECONOMY~1972 8~ 1977
PROJECTED FROM LEVELS IN 1967
Chart 4
972 977
~_I~
Down Down
2.3
FULL-TIME REPORTED
UNEMPLOYMENT
1972 1977
rn-~-=~i-~ ~
Down Down
0.6 0.7
GOVT OUTLAYS FOR
GOODS AND SERVICES
- (CalendarYears)
~ FEDERAL
Up $27.7
972 1977
STATE AND LOCAL
Up
-1'The single projections relate to goals of such high priority that they should not be reduced even if only
the lower goals for GNP are attained. In that eventlower priority objectives should be modified accordingly.
Single
Projection .Li
EMPLOYMENT
I In Millions of Man-Yearsl
I
(Dollars Items in Billions of FY. 1969 Dollars)
~ Optimum Economic ~ Economic
Growth Projection ~ Growth Projection
TRUE UNEMPLOYMENT
lb Millions of Man -Yearsl
TOTAL PRODUCTION
"p
CONSUMER SPENDING
I
PRIVATE BUSINESS
INVESTMENT
~ (bnc.Net Foreignl
Up
$102.4
Up
$53.0 ~
~30.7~ ~
Up
$366.8
1972 1977
1972 1977
~IDENTIAL
STRUCTURES
Up
Up $44.0
$28.0
gj~j ___
Up
$32.1 ~
JI~1j
972
972 1977
24-833 0 - 69 - pt. 4 - 6
PAGENO="0082"
1042
Chart 5
THE GOALS FOR 1972 AND 1977 MAINTAIN BALANCE
OF PUBLIC AND PRIVATE RESPONSIBILITIES
COMPONENTS OF GN~
Billions of FY l969Dollors
Total GNP
-~
$1,099.3
$984.8 ~
$8292 ~
55.8 17~.I
I l25.I~ I I'~ IL_I
~ ~34~1~2
-
967 Low Optimum
Actual 972
Goal
$1,396.0"
$11697 I
8836 _Prwafe Consumer
700.4. ::.~...::...:
184.4 227.5
Low Optimum
1977
Goal
Private Business
- Investment
(including net foreign)
Public Outlays
- at all levels for
goods and services~~
?ERcEt~T~ RELATIONSHIPS..
outlays ore of such high priority that they ore projected identically for the lower and
higher GNP goals, with modifications of other goals accordingly.
Projections by Leon H.Keyserling.
PAGENO="0083"
1043
Chart 6
COMPARATIVE GROWTH IN VARIOUS ASPECTS OF
U.S. ECONOMY 1961 1968
(Constant Dollars)
PRIVATE CONSUMER
SPENDING
TOTAL NATIONAL
PRODUCTION (G.NE)
Up
42.2%
5D%
1961-1968 1967-1968
Up
39.6%
IUP
4.7%
1961-1968 1967-1968
GOVT. OUTLAYS FOR
GOODS AND SERVICES
Up
50.1%
Up
~ 6.1%
~E~1
1961-1968 1967-1968
1961-1968
PRIVATE BUSINESS
INVESTMENT
(INC. NET FOREIGN)
Up
~
I
~
1961-1968 1967-1968
PRIVATE INVESTMENT
IN PLANT AND EQUIPMENT
Up
65.7%
~
Up
0%
1961-1968 1967-1968
CORPORATE PROFITS
(a VA)
Up
55.4%
~
71%
~
1967-1968
-
PERSONAL. INTEREST
Up INCOME
84.9%
.
Up
1967-1968
PERSONAL DIVIDEND
Up INCOME
58.0%
-
~
Up
I I
1967-1968
TRANSFER
U PAYMENTS
70.2%
I ~
~iiJ
1961-1968 1967-1968
WAGES AND SALARIES
445%
~
Up
5.6%
FI~L.~[
IS ~7- 968
LABOR INCOME
5;~1%
~:.:....
Up
.. :*.~~* 6.5%
i i
FARM PROPRIETORS'
NET INCOME
Up
3.6% Up
~ 4
1961-1968 1967 -1968
1961-1968 1967-1968
I.
1961-1968
Source: Dept of Commerce, Office of Business Economics and CEP.
PAGENO="0084"
1044
Thart7
PRICE, PROFIT, INVESTMENT, AND WAGE
TRENDS DURING I96O-I968~
Percentage Change,I960-I968
~ Prices2'~ Profits offer Taxes~' ~ Investment in Plant and Equipments' fl Wage Rates~~
II~% °~ ~
849% 879% `~
UP UP
33.1% 29.7% ~ 30.5%
~~llA~II1 t1~L
DOWN
2.0%
TOTAL PETROLEUM CHEMICALS
MANUFACTURING and COAL PRODUCTS and ALLIED PRODUCTS
UP
41.3%
UP
92.6%
UP 39.0% UP
28.5% 26.4%
~L=Ifl iJit[IL
ELECTRICAL IRON and STEEL MOTOR VEHICLES
MACHINERY and EQUIPMENT
I/All 968 data preliminary.
.~ata:U.S.Dept.of Labor,wtsolesaie commodity price indexes.
.~t)cta:Federal Trade Commission-SecurItIes and Exchange commission.
~ata:U.S.Dept.of Commerce and Securities and Exchange Commission.
..~ota:U.S.Deptof Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; Average hourly
earnings of production workers.
PAGENO="0085"
1045
NUMBER IN U.S. LIVING IN POVERTYV
DEPRIVATIONO COMFORT AND AFFLUENCEO
I967~ AND GOALS FOR 1972 AND 1977
Annual Money Incomes, Before Taxes, in 967 Dollars
C!sart E
Under $2,000 Under $3,335~J
POVERTY
In Millions
~iI:i.. l966~'Actual
~ I972,Goal
~ 1977, Goal
4.9
2.5
J1~~i L~ ~
Under $1,000 Under $l,635~J
POVERTY
2.4 2.5 2]
fJ~~
6.3 7.1
~
2.3 ~
~
4.5
2.8 3.4
1J~4
$1,635-
$3,000-
$5,000 B
2,999
4,999
over
COMFORT &
DEPRIVATION
COMFORT
AFFLUENCE
1-'Poverty-income ceilings vary by size sf family. The figure of $3,335 applies to a family of four, according to the
estimates of the Social Security Administration,Dept.of HEW. The average size of families in poverty being four,
5.27 million families involve about 21.1 million people.
i/The average size of families living in deprivation is about 3.0, coming to about 33 million people.
.~/The poverty-income ceiling of $1,635 accords with the estimates of the Social Security Administration,Dept.of HEW
.~-"l967 not available. All projections,however,in 1967 dollars.
Basic Data: 1966,1967: Social SecurityAdministration,Dept.of HEW.; Bureau of the Census, Dept of Commerce.
In Millions
~ 1967, Actual
1972, Goal
~ 1977, Goal
5.3
3.2
fl02 ni
49.1
In Millions 347
25.0
5.8
110 104
Ui~n~n
$3,335- $6,000- $8,000a
5,999 7,999 over
DEPRIVATION- COMFORTS
DEPRIVATION COMFORT AFFLUENCE
In Millions
PAGENO="0086"
1046
Chart 9
SHARE OF FAMILIES IN TOTAL FAMILY INCOME
BY QUINTILES, 1947, 1953, I96Oand 1966
Money Income)
1947 43 1953
23 I 24
~iIII ~iI~
LOWEST
SECOND
MIDDLE
FOURTH
FIFTH
LOWEST
SECOND
MIDDLE
FOURTH
FIFTH
FIFTH
FIFTH
FIFTH
1960
FIFTH
FIFTH
42
FIFTH
FIFTH
FIFTH
1966
FIFTH
FIFTH
~
El
fl
fl
23
fl
I
24
LOWEST SECOND MIDDLE FOURTH FIFTH LOWEST SECOND MIDDLE FOURTH FIFTH
FIFTH FIFTH FIFTH FIFTH FIFTH FIFTH F1FTH FIFTH FIFTH FIFTH
SHARE OF UNATTACHED INDIVIDUALS IN TOTAL
INCOME OF UNATTACHED INDIV., BY QUINTILES,
1947, 1953, 1960, and 1966
Data: Bureau of the Census.
PAGENO="0087"
1047
ALLOCATION OF TAX CUTS1 1962-1965:
IN VESTMENT AND CONSUMPTION PURPOSES
(Billions of Dollars)
TOTAL TAX CUTS
i-/Through Congressional & Executive Action
.?JThrough Executive Action
.~/ Estimated portion of personal tax cut,for those with incomes of $10,000 and over,
which they would save for investment purposes.
Based on estimates of excise tax cuts passed on to consumers through price cuts.
Personal tax cuts for those with incomes under $10,000.
.~/ Estimated portion of personal tax cuts for those with incomes of $10,000 and over, which they would
spend for consumption.
C~,rt itt
ESTIMATED ALLOCATION
TO INVESTMENT PURPOSES
ESTIMATED ALLOCATION
TO CONSUMPTION PURPOSES
10.6
8.6
Ii 0.5 LI PORTION OF EXCISE
TAX CUTS l965~/
PORTION OF
~ 2.5 ~ PERSONAL TAX
CUTS~l964~/
________ TAX CONCESSIONS
irmir~riumim TO INVESTORS,
11111 I965?'
1111 CORPORATE TAX
I~k~L~J~1 CUT, 1964
TAX CONCESSIONS
~ 2.7 ~ TO INVESTORS,
19621/
Note: Estimates of excise tax reduction allocation by C.E.Fi.(omount might be passed onto
consumers by price reductionslHowever, a large portion of thIs did not go to low income consumers.
PAGENO="0088"
1048
1964 TAX ACT, PERSONAL TAX CUTS
Percent Tax Cut And Percent Gain In After-Tax Income
Married Couple With Two Children At Various Income Levels ~`
25.7%
1.6%
Percent Percent Gain In
Tax Cut After-Tax Income
Chart 11
Percent Percent Gain In
Tax Cut After-Tax lncxme
2.7%
.
Percent Percent Gain In
Tax Cut After-Tax Income
r~i
~
3.8%
Percent Percent Gain In
Tax Cut After-Tax Income
$50,000 Income
$100,000 Income
$200,000 Income~~
144%
II
$3,000 Income
100.0%
$5,000 Income
$7,500 Income
0%
Percent Percent Gain In
Tax Cut After-Tax Income
$10,000 Income
$15,000 Income
$25,000 Income
Percent Percent Gain In
Tax Cut After-Tax Income
6.2%
Percent Percent Gain In
Tax Cut After-Tax Income
8.3%
~-
Percent Percent Gain In
Tax Cut After-Tax Income
Percent Percent ...ain In
Tax Cut After-Tax Income
-1~Adjusted groxs income levels. ~`Estimated
Note: Standard deductions for $ 3,000 income level. Typical itemized deductions
for other income levals.
PAGENO="0089"
1049
TAXES PAiD AS % OF INCOME,U.S. I966~
~ãb?~pjij,Lo~j l74~pfTot~iilncome)~
-1-'lncome relates toTotal Gross Adjusted Incomeof all persons in the income classes shown.
Z.Jlncludes Federal income taxes;social security taoes;State and local income,sales and gasoline totes;
and personal property and real estate taxes.
Basic Data:lnternal Revenue Service and Brookings Institution
Chart 12
33.6%
14.0%
11.7%
~6%flflflflJ -
Under $3,000- $4,000- $5,000- $7,000- $10,000- $15,000- $20,000- $SOpOO
$3p00 $3,999 $4,999 $6,999 $9,999 $14,999 $19,999 $49,999 and
388%
24.2%
9.3 12% 7.5% 17.6% -
Under $3,000- $4p00- $s,000- $7,000- $10,000- $15,000- $20,000- $50,000
$3,000 $3,999 $4,999 $6,999 $9,999 $14,999 $19,999 $49,999 and
over
PAGENO="0090"
1050
STATE LOCAL
12.4%
I 11.1%
9O~~ 9.I%
I~uuIi.°
947- 953- 1961- 947- 947- 953- 1961-
1953 1961 1967 1967 953 1961 1967
RESOURCES OF STATE AND LOCAL GOVERNMENTS
MORE STRAINED THAN THOSE OF FEDERAL GOVT.
RELATIVE TRENDS, 1947-1967
INCREASES IN PUBLIC EXPENDITURES1'
(FiscolYears,AverageAnn~alRale):
FEDERAL
I 9.1%
78% 8.O%l
rbrlrorlI
1947- 1947- 1953- 1961-; 947-
1967 1953 1961 19671 1967
INCREASES IN PUBLICDEBT
(As of Year End, Average Annual Rate)
"Expenditures classified by source of finoncing,i.e., intergovernmental transactions treated in terms of
originating level of government,rather than recipient government.
Basic Data: Department of Commerce
PAGENO="0091"
1051
Chart 14
GOALS FOR A FEDERAL BUDGET, 1972 AND 1977,
GEARED TO ECONOMIC GROWTH ~ PRIORITY NEEDS
1969,fiscal year; goals for 972 and 1977, calendar years
All figures in fiscal 1969 dollars~~'
NATIONAL DEFENSE,
SPACE TECHNOLOGY, &
ALL INTERNATIONAL
Total Per %of
Expend. Capita GNP
Year (Bit $) ($) (%)
969?! 89.515 441.18 10.11
972 90.000 424.73 8.19
1977 94.000 410.84 6.73
ALL DOMESTIC
PROGRAMS
Total Per % of
Expend. Capita GNP
Year (Bll.$) ($1 (%)
l969?J 96.547 475.84 10.91
1972 136.500 644.17 12.42
1977 186.000 812.93 13.32
PUBLIC ASSISTANCE;
LABOR, MANPOWER, AND
OTHER WELFARE SERVICES
Total Per %ot
Expend. Capita GNP
Year (Bit $1 1$) (%)
1969?/6.280 30.95 0.69
1972 9.500 44.83 0.86
1977 15.100 66.00 1.08
ALL FEDERAL OUTLAYS
Total Per % of
Expend. Capita GNP
Year (Bli $) l$( (%)
I969~~ 186.062 917.01 21.02
1972 226.500 1,068.90 20.61
1977 280.000 1,223.77 20.06
ECONOMIC OPPORTUNITY
HOUSING AND
AGRICULTURE; AND
PROGRAM
COMMUN1TY
NATURAL RESOURCES
DEVELOPMENT
~
.
a~
Total Per
% of
Total Per
% of
Total Per % of
Expend. Capita
Year (Bit $1 ($1
GNP
1%)
Expend. Capita
Year (Bit $1 ($(
GNP
1%)
Expend. Capita GNP
Year (Bit $1 1$) (%)
1969?! 2.000 9.86
0.23
969?! 2.784 13.72
0.31
969?! 8.099 39.91 0.91
1972 3.800 17.93
0.35
1972 5.500 25.96
0.50
1972 12.000 56.63 I .09
1977 5.500 24.04
0.39
1977 9.000 39.34
0.64
1977 15.500 67.75 1.11
EDUCATION
HEALTH SERVICES
.
AND RESEARCH
Ii
Total
Per
¼ of
Total Per
¼ of
Expend.
Year (Bit $1
Capita
1$)
GNP
(%(
Expend. Capita
Year (Bit. $) ($)
GNP
(%(
969?! 4.699
23.16
0.53
1969?! 10.655 52.51
1.21
1972 16.200
76.45
1.47
972 14.000 66.07
I .27
1977 32.900 143.79 2.36 977 20.000 87.41 I .43
Dollars of purchasing power apparentlyassumed in Presidents fiscal 1969 Budget.
_g, Administration's Proposed Budget as of Jan.29, l96B. Beginning with fiscal 1969,the Budget includes the
immense trust funds, net lending,ond other relatively minor new items. Note: Goals include Federal contributions atone billion
in 1970, and more than two billion in l977,to the OASDHI to help increase benefit payments to the aged.
Projections by Leon H.Keysenling.
PAGENO="0092"
1052
SELECTED PRICE TRENDS, 1918-1968
U.S. AND SELECTED OTHER COUNTRIES
AVERAGE ANNUAL RATES OF 0-lANGE
~Chart 1 5
-IUN lIED STATES]-~
~~-~HOLESALE PRICES = INDUSTRIAL PRICES
oP
UP UP UP UP 9: id ~
~ ~1~'~t1rI~I!L
__________________________ 1923- 196G
UP
~ UP 14%
L I r~~~///
U
UP UP
~
UP
35h~ UP UP
~ ~ ~
I ~
1912- 1963
I95~'. 196g
1963- 196T
UP *
~
Up
.4.2%
UP
~Lii~r~~
UP
3.1% UP
I~]Eh~
1966 - 1963'
i9~7 -1663
1956 - .1958
ISELE
CTED OTHER COUNTR
E....JCONSLPAER PRIC
ES E-~~~N-4OLESALE PRIC6
UNITED KINGDOM
UP FRANCE
GERMANY
UP
~~L1~ii~
49%
u~ UP
~
~fli~4%
1957-1967 1962-1967
1962.1967
1957-1967 1962-1967
ITALY
CANADA
JAPAN
1957-1967 1962-1967
.
UP
UP
4.7%
~
.
2~% UP ~LZ~ 2~%
15% ~
H ~ L ~
1957-1967 1962-1967
UP 5.4%
4.3%
[1
UP
~LLL~J~
1957-1967 1962-1967
-0.2% -0.2%
.1/~~Lt PRICBS OF FUIISIIED GOODS (VHGLESALE PRICZS OF BASIC MATERIA1.S IPCB~AS1.D O.I~ A Y3A~
J~;~ 1957-'B7 A4D i.B% A YZAR DU~IN9 19B2.'SY), S
~` IB~7 o~TA AIIZ PRZLIUU4ARY ~5T~bAT~S DASZb li~ON FlItSI P~IP1E TO tL~VDl~ r~Q1THZ.
~ ~JREA1J 0? LAEOR STATISTICS; OFFICE OF ~JBI8E6Z ECO~1ICS; AISD T)13 U33ITEO BATI0~ISI oc~.
LR *959 9*9~IZATIEQI FQ~ ~C~I~IC 609PC3ATI ~ *959 BEVELOP~~T
~....:..:.JCONS(JMER PRICES
1913 - 1968
1933- 196~
PAGENO="0093"
1053
:-:rtlE,
RELATIVE TRENDS IN ECONOMIC GROWTH
UNEMPLOYMENT~~ PRICES,I952-I968~'
Consumer Prices Wholesale Prices Industrial Prices
31%
__ ~]sI2sEiIl5L ~i20%fl~j.0~/~
-0.2%
1952-1955 1955-1958 1956-1958 1958-1960 1960-1968 1966-1968
Average Annual Rates of Change
Total National Production in Constant Dollars, Average Annual Rates of Change
Industrial Production,Average Annual Rates of Change
~ Unemployment as Percent of Civilian Labor Force,Annual Averages*
77%
60'/~
54%
5.1/, . 4Q~/
riflG ~il ~J1 fi H nfln n~n'
-10%
1952-1955 1955-1958 1956-1958 1958-1960 1960-1968 1966-1968
-1'Preliminary 968 data.
~These annual averages(as differentiated from the annual rates of change)are based on full-time officially
reparted unemployment measured against the officially reported Civilian Labor Force.
Source: Dept. of' Labor, Dept. of Commerce, 8 Federal Reserve System.
PAGENO="0094"
1054
THE LAG IN WAGES ANDSALARIES
BEHIND PRODUCTIVITY GAINS, I96O-I968~
(average annual increasesconstantdollars)
GNP I
Chart 17
48% 5.1%
i-rni
1960-1968 1960-1966
PRODUCTIVITY, 8 WAGES & SALARIES
TOTAL PRIVATE NONFARM ECONOMY
1960-1968 1960-1966 1966-1968
Output
Wages
Output
Wages
Output
Wages
and
and
and
Salaries
Salaries
Salaries
PER MAN-HOUR
PER MAN-HOUR
PER MAN-HOUR
PRODUCTIVITY, 8 WAGES & SALARIES
TOTAL MANUFACTURING
1960-1968 1960-1966 1966-1968
~-
PER MAN-HOUR PER MAN-HOUR PER MAN-HOUR
1968 data preliminary.
Basic Data: Dept.of Commerce; Dept.of Labor
PAGENO="0095"
8w
C)
0 C)
30.
-C.
II~J~
~
~
-f
m
(J~
C)
.D
c
2
~G~)
w Q
0.
a
C,
z
0
~C)
rn~
rn>
r~-1
Tm
rn-1
Drn
z
0(1)
z-.
rn
-